Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

Economic Development

http://edq.sagepub.com/
Quarterly

Education Spending and State Economic Growth: Are All Dollars Created Equal?
John Deskins, Brian Hill and Laura Ullrich
Economic Development Quarterly 2010 24: 45 originally published online 14 October 2009
DOI: 10.1177/0891242409347370

The online version of this article can be found at:


http://edq.sagepub.com/content/24/1/45

Published by:

http://www.sagepublications.com

Additional services and information for Economic Development Quarterly can be found at:

Email Alerts: http://edq.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts

Subscriptions: http://edq.sagepub.com/subscriptions

Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav

Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav

Citations: http://edq.sagepub.com/content/24/1/45.refs.html

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


Research and Practice
Economic Development Quarterly

Education Spending and State Economic 24(1) 45­–59


© The Author(s) 2010
Reprints and permission: http://www.
Growth: Are All Dollars Created Equal? sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0891242409347370
http://edq.sagepub.com

John Deskins,1 Brian Hill,2 and Laura Ullrich3

Abstract
This article contributes to the literature on the effect of state and local education spending on U.S. state economic growth
by separately analyzing higher and K-12 education spending and by taking into account the possibility that education spending
may generate spillover effects to neighboring states. Results from a series of fixed-effects regressions using a 1992-2002 panel
of state-level data indicate that increased spending on higher education generally exhibits a relatively large negative effect on
private sector employment or gross state product growth when the increase in education spending is financed through own-
source revenue. Results do not identify a statistically significant relationship between K-12 education spending and economic
growth. This finding is an important clarification in the literature because an analysis of combined higher and K-12 education
spending yields an overall negative effect. Results do not provide consistent evidence of cross-state spillover effects associated
with either form of education spending.

Keywords
industrial location, industry, government policy (parks, schools), quality of life, industrial location, industry, public finance, state
and local economic development policy, university role in economic development, economic development incentives/tools

A sizeable body of research has examined the effect of public education. According to the National Center for Education
education spending on state economic activity (see Fisher, Statistics (NCES), around 5% of gross domestic product
1997, for a broad review). Education spending is often viewed (GDP) is spent on public education.1 On average, 60% of
as a way to promote economic development by enhancing the state education expenditures are directed toward K-12 edu-
human capital stock that is crucial for productivity growth and cation whereas the remaining 40% is spent on public higher
economic prosperity. Especially among U.S. states, increases education, and there is significant variation in this break-
in education expenditures are often under consideration down across U.S. states. Distinguishing between K-12
because policy makers may view this as a way to provide a spending and higher education spending has typically been
more attractive workforce in order to attract more business neglected in the empirical literature: Many empirical studies
activity to a region. However, increased education expendi- ignore potentially differing effects of spending on K-12 and
tures also have the potential to reduce economic activity if higher education and simply aggregate the two types of
accompanied by increases in taxes, which may reduce eco- spending (Blankenau & Simpson, 2004; Cassou & Lansing,
nomic activity, or by reductions in other areas of government 2004; Glomm & Ravikumar, 1992, 1997). Other empirical
spending, which may positively affect economic activity. studies only consider state public education spending on
In this study, we revisit this line of inquiry with an analy- K-12 education (Fernandez & Rogerson, 1999; Rangazas,
sis of the effect of education spending on state economic 2000). A couple of studies have been identified that separate
growth by estimating several econometric models using a K-12 and higher education spending, but only from a theo-
panel of U.S. state-level data for the years 1992 through retical standpoint (Blankenau & Cassou, 2007; Su, 2004).
2002. We contribute to the literature in two important ways.
First is through the recognition that government spending on 1
Creighton University, Omaha, NE, USA
K-12 education and spending on college education may have 2
Salisbury University, Salisbury, MD, USA
different impacts on economic growth. As described in 3
Winthrop University, Rock Hill, SC, USA
Blankenau (2005), governments have two decisions to
Corresponding Author:
make. First, they must decide the level of government John Deskins, Economics and Finance Department, Creighton University,
spending on education, and second, they must decide how to 2500 California Plaza, Omaha, NE 68178, USA
allocate the spending between K-12 education and college Email: johndeskins@creighton.edu

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


46 Economic Development Quarterly 24(1)

Taylor and Brown (2006) is the only study that has been this literature concludes that, among all expenditure catego-
identified that separately considers higher and K-12 educa- ries that have been considered, the evidence of a relationship
tion spending in an empirical analysis, but the distinction is between education spending and economic growth is the
a minor part of the analysis, which has a different primary weakest. Fisher summarizes the results of 19 studies con-
focus. ducted between 1985 and 1995 that analyze the effects of
Our second important contribution is that we consider the education spending on state economic activity. Of the 19
possibility that education spending may generate cross-state studies, 12 show a positive relationship between education
spillover effects. If an increase of education spending (on spending and economic growth, but only 6 of these are posi-
either K-12 or higher education) increases the human capital tive and significant. Some of these studies examine only
of a state, the state may become more attractive to businesses; K-12 or higher education spending whereas others examine
thus, more business activity may locate in the state, and this combined K-12 and higher education spending. The results
could reduce economic activity in surrounding states. No are also sensitive to which growth variable is used (e.g.,
other studies have been identified that examine this possibil- employment, GSP, and others). In addition, many of the
ity. Failure to account for the possibility of interstate spillover early studies fail to control for the general equilibrium effects
effects could lead to a biased estimate of the overall impact of associated with an increase in public education revenues.
education spending on state economic growth. More specifically, researchers often fail to control for all ele-
We also contribute to the literature by (a) providing a ments of the state budget, even though a change in education
comparison of results when education spending is measured spending necessarily corresponds to some other change in
in per capita terms versus relative to state personal income the government budget (see Helms, 1985, and Mofidi &
(SPI) and (b) comparing the effect of education spending on Stone, 1990, for examples of studies that do properly control
alternate measures of economic growth. Existing research for all budgetary elements). The wide variation in early sta-
has considered both measures of education spending and tistical results and the availability of stronger econometric
alternate measures of economic growth, but any one study techniques have led researchers to conduct several additional
typically only considers one measure of each. Verifying that studies since 1995, which we review below.2
results are not sensitive to the selection of economic growth Blankenau and Simpson (2004) provide a theoretical anal-
or education spending measurement provides for greater ysis of the relationship between education spending and
confidence in our results, especially because variation in economic growth using an endogenous growth model. They
econometric specifications along these dimensions in earlier conclude that the mixed empirical results seen in the literature
research has potentially contributed to some of the differ- previously are due to general equilibrium effects. Specifically,
ences found in earlier results. they find that any positive effect of education expenditures
The analysis proceeds as follows: the next section pro- on growth can be eliminated when other growth determi-
vides a review of the relevant literature. The following nants are negatively affected by general equilibrium effects.
section details the empirical strategy and the data that are For example, most education spending increases are funded
used. Next is a discussion of the results, and the final section through increases in tax rates. If the increase in tax rates
offers a conclusion. Results indicate that increased spending decreases economic growth at a rate higher than the increase
on higher education has a negative effect on private sector rate associated with the rise in education expenditures, then
gross state product (GSP) or employment growth when a negative relationship may be observed. Because of the
financed through own-source revenue. However, results do complicated nature of these general equilibrium effects,
not identify a statistically significant relationship between Blankenau and Simpson conclude that there is no current
economic growth and K-12 spending. Furthermore, results empirical evidence that a positive link between education
do not provide consistent evidence of cross-state spillover expenditures and economic growth exists.
effects associated with either higher or K-12 education Bensi, Black, and Dowd (2004) use bivariate regression
spending. These results are robust to (a) the use of either to examine the relationship between state-level-per-pupil
private sector GSP growth or private sector employment expenditures and real personal income. They conclude that
growth as economic growth measures, (b) different methods when growth and expenditure data are calculated relative to
to capture spatial relationships among states in terms of edu- the U.S. average, there is a positive relationship between
cation spending, and (c) the measurement of state education education expenditures and real growth. Fisher and Ditsler
spending as a share of SPI as well as in per capita terms. (2003) recognize the complicated general equilibrium effects
that are associated with increases in education spending.
Contrary to Bensi et al., Fisher and Ditsler deduce that if tax
Existing Literature cuts lead to decreases in education spending and are accom-
There is a sizeable literature related to the effect of education panied by program cuts, then the effect on economic growth
spending on economic growth. Fisher’s (1997) review on may be negative.

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


Deskins et al. 47

In a commissioned report for the National Education government expenditures (at the combined state and local
Association, Hungerford and Wassmer (2003) conclude that level) that began in the late 1980s. They hypothesize that the
if states must choose between cutting education expenditures existing level of government expenditure growth has a sig-
to avoid a tax increase or raising revenue through additional nificant impact on the effect of an increase in government
taxes, the state would be better served to increase tax reve- spending. More specifically, they conclude that increases in
nue. Specifically, they find that cutting statewide education government spending will have a muted effect on growth in
spending by $1 per $1,000 of a state’s personal income an economy with high existing levels of government expen-
would reduce personal income by about 0.3% in the short diture growth. Therefore, they expect government spending
run and 3.2% in the long run. They also find negative and in the mid- to late 1990s, during which government expendi-
significant effects associated with decreases in state educa- tures were moderated, to lead to more positive impacts on
tion spending on the state’s manufacturing investment, economic activity relative to a period of rapid spending
employment, and small-business starts. Similarly, Harden growth. Although school expenditures are only a small part
and Hoyt (2003) study the impact of cutting school expendi- of Taylor and Brown’s large study, higher education and
tures on state employment levels. They use statewide data K-12 education expenditures are included as explanatory
from 1980 through 1994 to jointly estimate employment and variables. Their results show, using 10-year rolling windows,
revenue within a balanced budget framework. They find that that an increase in K-12 education expenditures in the early
cutting K-12 education expenditures is more detrimental to years of the analysis (1979-1992) led to a decrease in pri-
long-run statewide employment levels than is an equivalent vately held capital. Past that point in the data, an increase in
decrease in other state expenditure programs including high- K-12 education spending increased (or at least did not affect)
ways and hospitals. private capital. Although they do not find substantial evi-
Early research on the relationship between education dence that the level of government spending affected the
spending and growth tends to find a positive relationship impact of subsequent education spending, they do find sig-
between the two. Later research, however, shows a less stable nificant results regarding several other spending categories
relationship, with many analyses showing a negative rela- (including welfare, transportation, and public safety).
tionship, especially if the author(s) is careful to specify the As mentioned previously, very few studies in the literature
structure of the analysis such that an increase in education examine the differential impact of K-12 education spending
spending is achieved via an increase in taxes. These differ- and spending on higher education. These expenditure catego-
ences may partially be accounted for by considering the ries are most frequently lumped together or spending on
more sophisticated econometric techniques employed in the public higher education may be ignored all together. Two
more recent studies. studies, however, thoroughly examine the effect of both
In a study focused on the economic impact of higher educa- K-12 and higher education from a theoretical perspective. Su
tion spending on economic growth, Vedder (2004) finds that (2004) points out that K-12 education is a prerequisite for
increased state-level spending on higher education decreases attending an institute of higher education, and therefore, the
economic growth. He concludes that this is likely due to state’s primary focus should be providing a sufficient level
the low level of higher education dollars spent on actual of K-12 public education. Once a sufficient level of primary
instruction (around $0.21 of every $1.00, according to his and secondary education is achieved, states may then shift a
calculation). He points out that many increases in higher edu- portion of their focus toward providing higher education
cation funding have been put toward noninstructional pursuits using public funds. Furthermore, he concludes that a less-
such as fancier facilities and the subsidization of college ath- developed economy should focus only on K-12 education for
letics. Vedder concludes that higher education funding is a “sufficiently long duration.” Su points out that many econ-
inefficient because these institutions generally have little omies prematurely invest in public higher education or
incentive to cut costs. In addition, he finds that some previous overinvest in higher education, before that sufficient dura-
studies are flawed in that they assume that the difference in tion has been reached. Based on Su’s theoretical results, an
productivity between high school graduates and college grad- increase in higher education spending when spending on
uates is entirely due to their level of education rather than K-12 education is below the sufficient level will result in a
other factors such as intelligence and motivation. decrease in educational efficiency. It may also result in a
Taylor and Brown (2006) investigate the possibility that decrease in educational equality because state-level K-12
the differing results may additionally be due to the differing spending generally redistributes from rich to poor and
economic conditions that prevailed during the time of analy- higher education spending generally benefits the rich more
sis. The early papers typically use data from a period of slow than the poor.
growth in government expenditures (late 1970s to late Blankenau and Cassou (2007) analyze K-12 versus higher
1980s). According to Taylor and Brown, the different results education from a different perspective by examining the dif-
found in later papers may be due to the rapid growth in fering mechanisms of K-12 and higher education provision.

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


48 Economic Development Quarterly 24(1)

An important differentiation between K-12 education and level using the consumer price index. Appendix A presents
higher education is made by examining the nature of educa- summary statistics for all variables for the first and last years
tion funds in these markets. K-12 expenditures are provided of the data set and Appendix B provides variable descriptions
entirely by government. Higher education expenditures, how- and source notes.
ever, come from both public and private sources. According
to the NCES around 40% of all higher education funds are
publicly provided, whereas the rest come from private dona- Economic Growth Measures
tions and tuition and fees. Blankenau and Cassou deduce As illustrated above, we examine economic growth from
from their model that when total education expenditures are time t to time t + 1 rather than the level of economic activity.4
low (K-12 and higher education combined), voters prefer for We choose this approach because policy makers often target
all funds to be spent on K-12 education. However, when edu- economic growth rates rather than changes in the level of
cation expenditures pass some threshold, voters prefer some economic activity. This approach is also useful in that by
education funding to be directed toward public higher educa- specifying our dependent variable in this fashion we avoid
tion. This may partially explain the propensity of state the familiar problem of endogenity of education spending
legislatures to cut higher education spending more com- with respect to economic activity. Economic activity is mea-
monly than K-12 education spending, given the preferences sured as nongovernment GSP as well as total private sector
of their constituents. employment in the state.5 Existing research has used both of
Although the Su (2004) and Blankenau and Cassou (2007) these measures of economic activity, but any one study typi-
articles examine the differences in spending on K-12 and cally only considers one measure; we consider both to
higher education at the state level, they do not investigate to provide for greater robustness.
what extent, if any, these expenditures increase economic
growth within the jurisdiction or whether one source of edu-
cation spending may be more stimulative than the other. Our Education Spending Measures
examination improves on the current literature by investigat- Education spending is our variable of interest. In our primary
ing these issues. We also further the analysis by examining models, we separately consider spending on higher education
any spillover effects that may occur from increased spending and spending on K-12 education. In all models, we combine
in neighboring states. state government expenditures with all local government
expenditures within a state, which we view as especially
appropriate in the context of education spending. We measure
Empirical Design and Data education spending both in per capita terms as well as relative
In this study, we quantify the effect of public education spend- to SPI. As with our measures of economic growth discussed
ing on state economic growth through the estimation of a series above, the existing literature considers both of these measures
of regression models of state economic growth on state educa- of education spending, but usually in isolation. We examine
tion spending and a number of appropriate control variables. both measures to allow for greater degree of robustness.
Our primary regression model is summarized as follows: Statistics for both higher and K-12 education spending, mea-
sured both in per capita and SPI share terms, are presented in
Economic Growthi,t+1 = β0 + β1 Higher Education Spendingi,t Table 1 by state and for the first and last years of our data set.
+ β2 K-12 Spendingi,t + β3 Neighboring Higher Education As illustrated, there is a significant amount of variation in
Spendingi,t + β4 Neighboring K-12 Spendingi,t these figures both among states and across time.
+ β5 Total Federal Transfersi,t + β6 Noneducation
Government Spendingi,t + β7 Total Budget
Surplusi,t + β8Xi,t + β9Si + β10Tt + εit, Spatial Considerations
One of our contributions is our consideration of the effect of
where i and t are state and year indices, respectively, ε is a education spending in neighboring states on a state’s eco-
random error term, and X represents a vector of other nomic growth. Education spending may have a direct effect
controls, which are discussed below. All regressions include on a state’s own economic activity but there is also evidence
state- and year-fixed effects, as denoted by Si and Tt, that education spending may create interjurisdictional spill-
respectively, to control for state- and time-specific factors overs (Case, Rosen, & Hines, 1993).6 As discussed in Case
that are not included in the model. All models are estimated et al., spillovers may result from residents in one state receiv-
using a panel of state-level data from the 48 contiguous U.S. ing an education in that state but moving later in life and
states for the years 1992 through 2000, and also for 2002, potentially benefiting their new state. Another spillover
resulting in 480 observations.3 All variables that are measured occurs if educated workers from neighboring states compete
in dollar terms are adjusted for inflation to the 2004 price with each other for jobs. Yardstick competition may also

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


Deskins et al. 49

Table 1. Higher Education and K-12 Education Spending Across States—1992 and 2002

Education Education
Spending Per Capita Spending/SPI (%)

1992 2002 1992 2002

Higher education spending


Alabama 4.69 6.38 1.99 2.48
Arizona 5.15 4.22 2.11 1.97
Arkansas 4.32 5.59 1.95 2.33
California 4.84 6.11 1.58 1.81
Colorado 5.68 6.67 1.96 1.93
Connecticut 3.16 4.73 0.82 1.07
Delaware 7.61 8.21 2.44 2.43
Florida 3.07 3.65 1.10 1.22
Georgia 3.13 4.79 1.20 1.62
Idaho 4.61 5.43 1.98 2.13
Illinois 3.89 5.44 1.26 1.58
Indiana 5.23 6.18 2.01 2.13
Iowa 6.02 8.35 2.35 2.91
Kansas 6.54 6.86 2.43 2.30
Kentucky 4.28 6.18 1.83 2.37
Louisiana 3.92 4.91 1.71 1.91
Maine 3.89 4.55 1.57 1.63
Maryland 4.69 6.82 1.43 1.87
Massachusetts 2.92 4.12 0.87 1.01
Michigan 5.61 7.64 2.05 2.45
Minnesota 4.98 6.18 1.70 1.79
Mississippi 4.41 6.75 2.22 2.96
Missouri 3.35 4.91 1.27 1.66
Montana 4.06 5.87 1.76 2.34
Nebraska 5.82 7.26 2.19 2.41
Nevada 3.82 3.93 1.25 1.29
New Hampshire 3.32 4.63 1.11 1.30
New Jersey 3.76 4.94 1.05 1.23
New Mexico 6.41 8.30 2.89 3.45
New York 3.79 4.39 1.12 1.17
North Carolina 5.05 6.51 1.96 2.29
North Dakota 7.86 8.47 3.29 3.11
Ohio 4.36 5.38 1.60 1.78
Oklahoma 4.57 6.71 1.93 2.57
Oregon 5.33 7.59 2.02 2.59
Pennsylvania 4.50 4.93 1.55 1.53
Rhode Island 3.89 4.72 1.36 1.50
South Carolina 4.72 5.46 2.04 2.11
South Dakota 3.50 5.01 1.44 1.79
Tennessee 4.06 5.37 1.60 1.91
Texas 4.38 6.03 1.70 2.05
Utah 6.52 9.69 2.95 3.88
Vermont 6.36 7.31 2.44 2.44
Virginia 4.41 6.00 1.49 1.78
Washington 5.31 6.91 1.80 2.08
West Virginia 4.12 5.84 1.89 2.43
Wisconsin 5.26 7.18 1.96 2.35
Wyoming 7.12 7.60 2.70 2.48
K-12 education spending
Alabama 7.90 11.94 3.35 4.64
Arizona 11.18 11.13 4.57 4.20
Arkansas 9.39 11.47 4.23 4.79
(continued)

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


50 Economic Development Quarterly 24(1)

Table 1. (continued)

Education Education
Spending Per Capita Spending/SPI (%)

1992 2002 1992 2002

California 11.68 15.95 3.81 4.72


Colorado 12.04 13.73 4.16 3.97
Connecticut 16.02 18.13 4.15 4.10
Delaware 12.20 15.70 3.92 4.66
Florida 11.04 11.73 3.96 3.92
Georgia 10.79 15.16 4.13 5.12
Idaho 10.50 12.80 4.51 5.01
Illinois 10.82 14.99 3.52 4.35
Indiana 11.89 13.66 4.57 4.70
Iowa 11.55 13.64 4.52 4.76
Kansas 11.55 13.39 4.29 4.49
Kentucky 8.83 10.02 3.78 3.85
Louisiana 10.26 12.27 4.48 4.77
Maine 13.15 14.67 5.31 5.24
Maryland 11.86 15.70 3.61 4.30
Massachusetts 10.98 16.81 3.27 4.13
Michigan 12.88 16.75 4.71 5.37
Minnesota 13.96 16.30 4.77 4.72
Mississippi 8.65 10.82 4.36 4.75
Missouri 10.55 13.71 4.00 4.65
Montana 12.51 13.12 5.41 5.22
Nebraska 12.51 15.10 4.71 5.01
Nevada 12.08 13.45 3.94 4.41
New Hampshire 11.99 14.94 4.01 4.21
New Jersey 15.72 19.62 4.38 4.90
New Mexico 11.29 14.23 5.09 5.92
New York 16.56 21.04 4.87 5.59
North Carolina 10.80 12.15 4.18 4.26
North Dakota 10.81 12.43 4.53 4.56
Ohio 11.51 15.21 4.21 5.03
Oklahoma 10.54 13.21 4.45 5.05
Oregon 13.01 14.37 4.93 4.91
Pennsylvania 11.70 14.04 4.02 4.36
Rhode Island 12.73 15.50 4.44 4.92
South Carolina 10.71 14.76 4.62 5.69
South Dakota 11.08 13.02 4.57 4.67
Tennessee 8.17 11.17 3.21 3.97
Texas 11.98 15.50 4.64 5.26
Utah 11.16 12.94 5.06 5.18
Vermont 13.79 15.98 5.30 5.34
Virginia 11.83 15.01 3.99 4.46
Washington 14.11 14.21 4.77 4.27
West Virginia 11.73 13.18 5.39 5.53
Wisconsin 13.72 16.39 5.11 5.35
Wyoming 17.69 18.08 6.70 5.89
Note: SPI = state personal income. Spending per capita is measured in thousands. Per capita figures are adjusted for inflation to the 2004 price level.

contribute to interjurisdictional spillovers. Besley and Case As a result, voters make decisions about politicians’ abilities
(1995) describe yardstick competition through their model to set taxes and expenditures in a relative way; that is, a poli-
that describes how states set fiscal policy in the presence of tician’s performance is measured relative to politicians from
multiple states, where asymmetric information regarding other states. In this world, a voter may be unhappy if her
politicians’ decisions exists between voters and politicians. education expenditures are not rising while other states are

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


Deskins et al. 51

experiencing growth in education spending. Because voters Other Budgetary Elements


decide whether to vote for an incumbent based on their state’s
fiscal policies compared with other states’, incumbents may We control for all elements of the state budget to obtain an
consider other states’ fiscal policies when setting policy. unbiased estimate of the effect of education spending. There-
Given evidence of the interjurisdictional relationship fore, we include total noneducation government expenditures,
among states in setting education spending, it may be sug- federal transfers, and the total budget surplus. We omit one
gested that one state’s education spending will have an element of the government budget to avoid perfect multicol-
impact on economic growth in other states. To properly linearity. The choice of which variable to omit is arbitrary. We
account for this impact, known as spatial correlation, we choose to omit total own-source revenue so that our results
apply spatial econometric techniques to our standard panel can be interpreted as a change in education spending financed
estimation. With spatial correlation, observations are related through own-source revenues (because own-source revenue
by geography and their spatial relationship to one another. is the only other budgetary element allowed to vary in our
Thus, an observation in one state may be influenced by econometric model). We feel this approach is appropriate
observations in a neighboring state. For our research, it because the policy debate more often takes this point of view.
might be that an increase in education spending in one state The K-12 education spending variable and the total non-
would affect the economic growth of a neighboring state if education government spending variable have ambiguous
interjurisdictional spillovers exist. Failing to account for this theoretical effects on economic activity: Firms and individu-
possibility could lead to a biased estimate of the total impact als may be more likely to locate in a state with greater
of education spending on state growth. expenditures due to the benefits of public education and
Before modeling the interstate spillover, we must other public goods and services. Alternatively, recognizing
settle on the extent to which we believe the spillover per- the tax costs associated with these public services, individu-
tains or, in other words, which states should be considered als and firms could seek to avoid higher tax burdens and
neighbors. Here, we follow previous research in restrict- choose to locate elsewhere. However, as stated in the review
ing our definition of neighboring states to geopolitical above, studies have found both positive and negative effects
neighbors because we view these potential spillover of education spending on economic activity, though more
effects as primarily local in nature (see, e.g., Bruce, recent studies tend to find a negative relationship.
Deskins, Hill, & Rork, 2009; Case et al., 1993; Rork, The theoretical effect of spending on higher education is
2003).7 Next, we assign weights to capture the relative also ambiguous for the reasons just described. However, an
importance of each neighbor’s role in interstate spillovers. additional issue exists with regard to public spending on
We follow the common practice in the spatial literature to higher education. Previous theoretical explorations have
use row-standardized weights, meaning the sum of our pointed to the likely negative impact of increases in higher
weights equals 1. Thus, the “Neighbor’s Education Spend- education spending given the relatively low levels of spend-
ing” variable captures the weighted average of the bordering ing on K-12 education across the country. As described by
states’ education spending. Su (2004), if a certain level of K-12 spending and achieve-
In our first weighting scheme, we simply assign an equal ment has not been reached, spending publicly raised funds
weight to all contiguous states, referred to below as contigu- on higher education is not Pareto improving and will be
ity weighting. Specifically, all neighboring states are assigned expected to decrease economic growth.
an equal weight and nonbordering states are assigned a
weight of zero. For example, for Nebraska, each adjoining
state—Colorado, Iowa, Kansas, Missouri, South Dakota, Other Controls
and Wyoming—would receive equal consideration whereas The other control variables in our model are consistent with
all other states would receive no consideration. Thus, “Neigh- the literature that explains the determinants of economic
bor’s Education Spending” is the simple average of education activity as discussed above.8 Most of this literature models
spending in neighboring states under this weighting method. locational decisions by constructing profit functions (or
We use a second weighting scheme, for added robustness, in related functions) to determine profitability and, corre-
which we weight neighboring states by their population spondingly, the decision to locate into a region. The literature
(nonadjacent states still receive a weight of zero). We refer to includes variables such as measures of regional market
this approach below as population weighting. Under this demand, costs of producing in a particular location, and
weighting scheme, again using Nebraska as an example, public policies.
Nebraska’s neighbor Missouri would receive a higher weight Because high input costs may reduce economic activity,
in constructing the neighboring education spending variable two measures of input costs are included: the average hourly
for Nebraska than, say, South Dakota, because Missouri’s wage for manufacturing workers in a state and a measure of
population is higher. overall energy prices in a state.9 State population and median

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


52 Economic Development Quarterly 24(1)

income are included to control for state size and demand. indicate that higher education spending has a negative and
Population density is included because a high population statistically significant effect on GSP growth when higher
concentration may influence the ability of firms to achieve education spending is financed through own-source revenue.
economies of scale in operation. State unemployment rates More specifically, results indicate that a $100 increase in
are included to proxy for the general economic health of the higher education spending per capita is associated with
state. Measures of the intensity of the agricultural and manu- roughly a 1.5 percentage-point decline in a state’s GSP
facturing sectors (e.g., the share of a state’s GSP that is in the growth rate, based on our contiguity weighting method. This
agricultural and manufacturing sectors) are added to control translates into a large elasticity of about −2.7 based on over-
for the differential impacts each sector has on state econo- all averages for GSP growth and higher education spending
mies. We also control for the age distribution of the population per capita (the average GSP growth rate is 2.9%; average
as different age groups may affect economic growth dif- higher education spending per capita is $520). Similarly,
ferently. Specifically, we include three variables denoting results indicate that a 1 percentage-point increase in higher
(a) the percentage of the population that is between the ages education spending as a share of SPI is associated with a 3.1
of 25 and 44 years, (b) the percentage of the population that is percentage-point decline in a state’s GSP growth rate (trans-
between the ages of 45 and 64 years, and (c) the percentage lating into an elasticity of about −1.9 based on overall
of the population older than the age of 64 years. averages and our contiguity weighting method). In contrast,
however, results from all four models indicate that K-12
spending does not exhibit an effect on GSP growth that is
Results and Discussion statistically distinguishable from zero (again when K-12
Results from our regression models are presented in Tables spending is financed through own-source revenues). This
2, 3, and 4. With the models presented in Table 2, we com- likely indicates that the positive effects of K-12 education
bine higher education expenditures with K-12 education spending on GSP growth are just offset by the negative
expenditures. We present this series of models as a compari- effects of own-source revenues. This makes for an interest-
son to much of the earlier research on the topic because ing contrast to our earlier finding as presented in Table 2:
many researchers have combined these two types of educa- The negative overall effect shown in that model was driven
tion spending as discussed above. Here the results are by higher education spending. Results are very similar across
separated based on our measurement of fiscal variables in both specifications for our contiguity and population weight-
per capita terms versus as a share of SPI and also by the GSP ing methods.
versus the employment measures of economic growth. Contrary to our hypothesis, results fail to identify any sta-
Results from all four models indicate a negative relationship tistically distinguishable effect of higher education spending
between combined higher and K-12 education spending in a in neighboring states on own-state GSP growth in any of the
state and economic growth, which is consistent with much of four models. A statistically significant relationship is identi-
the previous research on the topic. Furthermore, we fail to fied between neighboring states’ K-12 education spending
identify a significant relationship between combined educa- and GSP growth in only one of the four models. Turning to
tion spending in neighboring states and a state’s own our other fiscal controls, results do not identify a statistically
economic growth rate. We return to results with other control significant relationship between noneducation spending and
variables below.10 GSP growth in any of the four models. This likely indicates
In Tables 3 and 4 we present results from our primary that, on average, the benefits of all other types of state and
models in which we separate higher education and K-12 edu- local government spending roughly equal the associated tax
cation expenditures. Results in Table 3 are for models that costs in terms of their impact on GSP growth. Furthermore,
explain private sector GSP growth whereas Table 4 presents results identify a statistically significant and positive rela-
results from the models that explain private sector employ- tionship between GSP growth and the combined state and
ment growth. Each table is divided into the models in which local budget surplus in all four models.
fiscal variables are measured in per capita terms (Columns 1 Although not the focus of our analysis, results regarding
and 2 of each table) and as a share of SPI (Columns 3 and 4). some of the other control variables deserve mention. First,
The last division is between the models that use contiguity results indicate that state population density is positively
weighting for the neighboring education spending variables related to GSP growth in all four models. Also, a larger share
versus those that use population weighting. of GSP in either the agricultural sector or the manufacturing
sector is associated with slower GSP growth in all four
models. Results indicate that states with a larger share of the
GSP Growth Results population in the older than age 64 category exhibit higher
We begin with results for the models that explain GSP growth, rates of GSP growth relative to states with larger population
as reported in Table 3. Results from all four specifications shares in the younger than age 25 category in all four models.

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


Deskins et al. 53

Table 2. Regression Results: Economic Growth on Combined Higher and K-12 Education Spending

Per Capita Models SPI Share Models

Employment Employment
Variable GSP Growth Growth GSP Growth Growth

Combined education −0.433* (0.222) −0.147* (0.078) — —


spending per capita
Neighbor’s combined education −0.325 (0.269) −0.064 (0.095) — —
spending per capita
Federal grants per capita 2.031 (1.798) 0.714 (0.635) — —
Noneducation −0.154 (0.818) −0.343 (0.289) — —
spending per capita
Total budget surplus per capita 0.857** (0.333) 0.225* (0.118) — —
Combined education — — −1.370** (0.609) −0.464** (0.214)
spending/SPI (%)
Neighbor’s combined — — −0.756 (0.852) −0.554* (0.299)
education spending/SPI (%)
Federal grants/SPI (%) — — 0.506 (0.497) 0.184 (0.175)
Noneducation spending/SPI (%) — — 2.802 (23.219) −3.545 (8.158)
Total budget surplus/SPI (%) — — 0.229** (0.101) 0.060* (0.035)
Population (millions) 0.410 (0.442) 0.070 (0.156) 0.506 (0.429) 0.082 (0.151)
Average manufacturing wage −0.232 (0.350) −0.099 (0.123) −0.273 (0.348) −0.110 (0.122)
Median income (thousands) 0.029 (0.072) 0.090*** (0.025) −0.016 (0.074) 0.069*** (0.026)
Population density 49.449** (19.583) 28.759*** (6.911) 41.679** (19.002) 27.658*** (6.676)
Energy price −0.274 (0.342) −0.078 (0.121) −0.322 (0.342) −0.093 (0.120)
Unemployment rate (%) −0.311 (0.220) −0.184** (0.076) −0.329 (0.221) −0.193** (0.078)
Agricultural share (%) −0.878*** (0.226) −0.018 (0.080) −0.913*** (0.227) −0.029 (0.080)
Manufacturing share (%) −0.346*** (0.099) 0.009*** (0.035) −0.370*** (0.102) −0.014*** (0.036)
Age 25-44 years (%) 0.196 (0.275) 0.176* (0.097) 0.384 (0.283) 0.248** (0.099)
Age 45-64 years (%) 0.063 (0.260) 0.038 (0.092) 0.166 (0.261) 0.064 (0.092)
Age 65+ years (%) 3.235*** (0.709) 2.986*** (0.708) 3.360*** (0.707) 1.177*** (0.248)
Constant −34.169* (20.320) −22.104*** (7.171) −40.006** (19.662) −21.657*** (6.608)
R2 .341 .642 .340 .645
Note: SPI = state personal income; GSP = gross state product. Entries are fixed-effects panel regression coefficients with standard errors in parentheses.
All models include state and year fixed effects. All percentages are on a 0 to 100 scale. Education spending variables are measured in hundreds. All
other government expenditure variables are measured in thousands. All variables measured in dollars are adjusted for inflation to the 2004 price level.
*p ≤ .1. **p ≤ .05. ***p ≤ .01.

Employment Growth Results models, we are unable to identify a statistically significant


relationship between K-12 spending and employment growth.
Next we turn to results from the models in which we model Results are again very similar between contiguity and popu-
employment growth, as reported in Table 4. Similar to our lation weighting schemes.
GSP models, we identify a statistically significant and nega- Results continue to provide only scattered evidence of a
tive relationship between higher education spending and relationship between education spending in neighboring
state employment growth. Here, results indicate that a $100 states and a state’s own employment growth rate. In particu-
increase in higher education spending per capita is associ- lar, in the population weighted model with the per capita
ated with a 0.6 percentage-point decline in a state’s private measures of fiscal variables, we find a statistically signifi-
sector employment growth rate, based on our contiguity cant and negative relationship between higher education
weighting method. This translates into an elasticity of about spending in neighboring states and state employment growth.
−1.6 based on overall averages (the overall average employ- We do not, however, place much importance on this result,
ment growth rate is 2.0%; average higher education spending along with the small evidence of a cross-state spillover effect
per capita is $520). Similarly, results indicate that a 1 per- in Table 3, given the limited nature of the finding among the
centage-point increase in higher education spending as a various specifications considered. Also similar to the GSP
share of SPI is associated with a 1.1 percentage-point decline results, results do not identify a statistically significant rela-
in a state’s employment growth rate, which translates into an tionship between noneducation spending and employment
elasticity of about −0.9 (again based on overall averages; growth in any of the four models. In contrast to the GSP
also based on contiguity weighting). Also similar to the GSP growth models, results here do not identify a statistically

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


54 Economic Development Quarterly 24(1)

Table 3. Regression Results: GSP Growth on Education Spending

Per Capita Models SPI Share Models

Variable Contiguity Weight Population Weight Contiguity Weight Population Weight

Higher education spending -1.486*** (0.429) -1.522*** (0.427) — —


per capita
K-12 education spending -0.183 (0.217) -0.213 (0.218) — —
per capita
Neighbor’s higher education -0.155 (0.685) -0.197 (0.639) — —
spending per capita
Neighbor’s K-12 education -0.326 (0.298) -0.944** (0.398) — —
spending per capita
Federal grants per capita 2.372 (1.795) 2.375 (1.787) — —
Noneducation spending -0.132 (0.810) 0.088 (0.807) — —
per capita
Total budget surplus per capita 0.764** (0.333) 0.753** (0.331) — —
Higher education — — -3.110*** (1.193) -3.221*** (1.190)
spending/SPI (%)
K-12 education — — -0.564 (0.599) -0.554 (0.597)
spending/SPI (%)
Neighbor’s higher education — — 0.680 (2.294) -1.186 (1.964)
spending/SPI (%)
Neighbor’s K-12 education — — -0.493 (0.975) -0.184 (0.863)
spending/SPI (%)
Federal grants/SPI (%) — — 0.558 (0.499) 0.573 (0.499)
Noneducation spending/SPI (%) — — -2.100 (22.874) -1.864 (22.734)
Total budget surplus/SPI (%) — — 0.216** (0.101) 0.213** (0.101)
Population (millions) 0.419 (0.438) 0.531 (0.430) 0.447 (0.437) 0.528 (0.445)
Average manufacturing wage -0.282 (0.347) -0.224 (0.346) -0.347 (0.348) -0.318 (0.347)
Median income (thousands) 0.044 (0.072) 0.040 (0.071) 0.007 (0.074) 0.011 (0.073)
Population density 39.820** (20.146) 46.956** (20.723) 40.444** (20.032) 35.076* (19.946)
Energy price -0.262 (0.340) -0.234 (0.339) -0.335 (0.343) -0.314 (0.343)
Unemployment rate (%) -0.277 (0.221) -0.309 (0.222) -0.328 (0.221) -0.313 (0.222)
Agricultural share (%) -0.899*** (0.227) -0.908*** (0.224) -0.917*** (0.230) -0.935*** (0.229)
Manufacturing share (%) -0.361*** (0.099) -0.428*** (0.104) -0.357*** (0.102) -0.365*** (0.102)
Age 25-44 years (%) 0.273 (0.274) 0.277 (0.272) 0.415 (0.283) 0.414 (0.284)
Age 45-64 years (%) 0.117 (0.258) 0.057 (0.257) 0.177 (0.260) 0.172 (0.260)
Age 65+ years (%) 2.869*** (0.714) 2.859*** (0.705) 3.140*** (0.715) 3.054*** (0.718)
Constant -27.704 (20.800) -24.018 (19.983) -38.574* (20.001) -35.704* (20.124)
R2 .355 .362 .345 .345
Note: SPI = state personal income; GSP = gross state product. Entries are fixed-effects panel regression coefficients with standard errors in parentheses.
All models include state and year fixed effects. All percentages are on a 0 to 100 scale. Education spending variables are measured in hundreds. All
other government expenditure variables are measured in thousands. All variables measured in dollars are adjusted for inflation to the 2004 price level.
*p ≤ .1. **p ≤ .05. ***p ≤ .01.

significant relationship between employment growth and the a larger portion of the population in the age 25 to 44 category
combined state and local budget surplus in any model. exhibit higher rates of employment growth (relative to states
Many of the results regarding the other control variables with a larger population share in the younger than age 25
are robust across the GSP and employment growth specifica- category). These results are also common in the literature
tions but there are some exceptions. One such difference is (see, e.g., Dalenberg & Partridge, 1995).
that median income is found to exert a positive effect on
employment growth in all four models. Unsurprisingly, the
state unemployment rate exerts a negative effect on employ- Conclusions
ment growth. This result is virtually universal in this In this article, we examine the relationship between public
literature. Results indicate that the agricultural and manufac- education spending and state economic growth. We con-
turing shares of GSP do not exhibit a statistically significant tribute to an already sizeable literature on the subject,
relationship to employment growth. The last difference bet­ primarily by examining the potentially differing impact of
ween the GSP and the employment models is that states with K-12 and higher education spending on economic growth

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


Deskins et al. 55

Table 4. Regression Results: Employment Growth on Education Spending

Per Capita Models SPI Share Models

Variable Contiguity Weight Population Weight Contiguity Weight Population Weight

Higher education spending -0.636*** (0.150) -0.646*** (0.150) — —


per capita
K-12 education spending -0.040 (0.076) -0.055 (0.077) — —
per capita
Neighbor’s higher education -0.318 (0.240) -0.423** (0.224) — —
spending per capita
Neighbor’s K-12 education -0.058 (0.104) -0.079 (0.140) — —
spending per capita
Federal grants per capita 0.864 (0.628) 0.813 (0.628) — —
Noneducation spending -0.304 (0.284) -0.263 (0.283) — —
per capita
Total budget surplus per capita 0.191 (0.117) 0.190 (0.116) — —
Higher education — — -1.098*** (0.420) -1.126*** (0.419)
spending/SPI (%)
K-12 education — — -0.042 (0.211) -0.047 (0.210)
spending/SPI (%)
Neighbor’s higher education — — -0.202 (0.807) -0.729 (0.691)
spending/SPI (%)
Neighbor’s K-12 education — — -0.407 (0.343) -0.288 (0.304)
   spending/SPI (%)
Federal grants/SPI (%) — — 0.203 (0.176) 0.212 (0.176)
Noneducation spending/SPI (%) — — -6.217 (8.053) -6.639 (7.997)
Total budget surplus/SPI (%) — — 0.058 (0.036) 0.057 (0.036)
Population (millions) 0.073 (0.153) 0.127 (0.151) 0.060 (0.154) 0.089 (0.156)
Average manufacturing wage -0.104 (0.121) −0.091 (0.122) -0.136 (0.122) -0.128 (0.122)
Median income (thousands) 0.097*** (0.025) 0.099*** (0.025) 0.080*** (0.026) 0.082*** (0.026)
Population density 22.843*** (7.052) 21.032*** (7.276) 25.970*** (7.052) 23.786*** (7.017)
Energy price -0.062 (0.119) -0.053 (0.119) -0.093 (0.121) -0.083 (0.121)
Unemployment rate (%) -0.154** (0.077) -0.144* (0.078) -0.190** (0.078) -0.184** (0.078)
Agricultural share (%) -0.039 (0.080) -0.049 (0.079) -0.026 (0.081) -0.033 (0.081)
Manufacturing share (%) -0.0002 (0.035) -0.004 (0.036) -0.005 (0.035) -0.007 (0.036)
Age 25-44 years (%) 0.198** (0.096) 0.194** (0.096) 0.251*** (0.100) 0.244** (0.100)
Age 45-64 years (%) 0.051 (0.090) 0.054 (0.090) 0.064 (0.091) 0.062 (0.091)
Age 65+ years (%) 0.998*** (0.250) 0.983*** (0.248) 1.073*** (0.252) 1.041*** (0.253)
Constant -17.210** (7.281) -17.106** (7.016) -20.531*** (7.041) -19.493*** (7.079)
R2 .656 .658 .646 .647
Note: SPI = state personal income. Entries are fixed-effects panel regression coefficients with standard errors in parentheses. All models include state
and year fixed effects. All percentages are on a 0 to 100 scale. Education spending variables are measured in hundreds. All other government
expenditure variables are measured in thousands. All variables measured in dollars are adjusted for inflation to the 2004 price level.
*p ≤ .1. **p ≤ .05. ***p ≤ .01.

and also by incorporating the possibility that the effect of indicate that higher education spending negatively affects
education spending in one state may generate spillover state private sector GSP and employment growth when
effects on economic growth in neighboring states. Failure financed through own-source revenues. Results do not iden-
to account for spillover effects associated with education tify a statistically significant relationship between K-12
spending could lead to biased estimates of the overall education spending and either measure of economic growth.
effect of education spending on economic growth. In our This finding contrasts with results from models in which the
analysis we are careful to control for all elements of the two types of education expenditures are aggregated. Further-
public budget to avoid omitted variable bias and to pro- more, our analysis does not provide consistent evidence that
duce clear estimates of the effect of a change in education education spending generates a spillover effect on economic
spending when specifically financed through own-source growth in neighboring states. Our general results are robust
revenues. across several specifications.
Results from a series of fixed-effects regressions using a Our finding that public spending on higher education
panel of state-level data for the years 1992 through 2002 reduces economic growth may simply be because such

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


56 Economic Development Quarterly 24(1)

expenditures, on balance, have exceeded efficient levels, and state-allotted funds for higher education may not achieve
therefore the marginal economic development costs associ- these goals and therefore may not lead to significant increases
ated with the taxes used to finance such expenditures in economic growth.
outweigh marginal benefits for economic growth of higher This empirical finding of a negative effect, however,
education spending. could also be related to the theoretical work of Su (2004) and
The negative impact observed may also be due to the Blankenau and Cassou (2007). As discussed, Su’s basic
fact, as described in Vedder (2004), that additional state argument is that the public will prefer strictly K-12 educa-
money allocated to higher education is spent inefficiently. tion spending until K-12 spending reaches some threshold.
There is general consensus that a state will experience eco- Then, under several assumptions, once an economy passes
nomic growth if a more educated workforce can be achieved. that threshold, any money spent on higher education will be
This can be heard in many local, state, and national political Pareto improving and should result in an increased rate of
arenas. For example, Jennifer Granholm, the governor of economic growth. Our finding of a negative relationship
Michigan, recently stated that “our higher education system between economic growth and higher education spending
is the jet fuel that propels our economy. If we want a may lend credence to the theory that the sufficient level of
high-performance economy, we must work now to improve K-12 education spending was typically not reached during
the strength, depth, and adaptability of our colleges and our period of analysis, thus higher education spending nega-
universities” (Michigan Office of the Governor, 2004). tively affected economic growth. However, we leave further
This may very well be the case; however, simply increasing investigation of this hypothesis to future research.

Appendix A
Summary Statistics
1992 2002

Mean SD Mean SD

Private employment growth (%) 2.410 1.335 0.523 1.049


Nongovernment gross state product growth (%) 2.749 2.492 3.014 2.040
Higher education spending per capita (hundreds) 4.756 1.184 6.077 1.343
K-12 education spending per capita (hundreds) 11.862 1.974 14.359 2.234
Neighbor’s higher education spending per capita (hundreds) 4.493 0.713 5.794 0.892
Neighbor’s K-12 education spending per capita (hundreds) 11.937 1.703 14.850 2.331
Higher education spending/SPI (%) 1.810 0.542 2.071 0.605
K-12 education spending/SPI (%) 4.427 0.637 4.775 0.522
Neighbor’s higher education spending/SPI (%) 1.636 0.353 1.879 0.409
Neighbor’s K-12 education spending/SPI (%) 4.282 0.520 4.722 0.553
Federal grants per capita (thousands) 0.976 0.240 1.370 0.335
Noneducation spending per capita (thousands) 3.334 0.767 5.094 0.861
Total budget surplus per capita (thousands) 0.179 0.261 −0.687 0.434
Federal grants/SPI (%) 3.704 1.099 4.679 1.472
Noneducation spending/SPI (%) 12.435 2.572 0.170 0.025
Total budget surplus/SPI (%) 0.704 0.988 −2.228 1.282
Population (millions) 5.265 5.669 5.956 6.442
Median income (thousands) 42.900 4.740 61.587 8.510
Population density 0.172 0.240 0.189 0.259
Average wage 11.287 1.281 15.026 1.679
Energy price 8.248 1.374 11.129 1.610
Unemployment rate (%) 6.765 1.554 5.346 0.992
Agricultural Share (%) 2.774 2.681 1.418 1.383
Manufacturing share (%) 17.834 6.454 13.297 5.150
Age 25-44 years (%) 31.728 1.698 27.340 1.442
Age 45-64 years (%) 19.009 1.037 44.238 0.855
Age 65+ years (%) 12.806 1.773 12.619 1.608
Note: SPI = state personal income. All dollar amounts are expressed as current year dollars. Neighbors’ variables are calculated using the simple
contiguity weight matrix as described in the text.

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


Deskins et al. 57

Appendix B
Data Descriptions and Source Notes
Variable Definition

Private employment growth (%) Growth rate of private state employment from t to t + 1 (1)
Nongovernment gross state product growth (%) Growth rate of nongovernment gross state product from t to t + 1 (2)
Higher education spending per capita Total state and local government spending on higher education
   divided by state population (3)
K-12 education spending per capita Total state and local government spending on K-12 education
   divided by state population (3)
Higher education spending/SPI (%) Total state and local government spending on higher education divided
   by state personal income (4)
K-12 education spending/SPI (%) Total state and local government spending on K-12 education divided
   by state personal income (4)
Noneducation spending . . . Total government spending − total higher and K-12 education spending* (3 and 4)
Total federal transfers to . . . Total federal transfers* (3 and 4)
Total budget surplus . . . Total government revenues − total government spending* (3 and 4)
Population (millions) State population (5)
Median income (thousands) State median income (5)
Population density Population/square miles in a state (6)
Average wage Average hourly wage for manufacturing workers (7)
Energy price Estimate of energy costs for all forms of energy, measured per million BTU (8)
Unemployment rate (%) State unemployment rate (7)
Agricultural share (%) State agricultural production as a share of total gross state product (2)
Manufacturing share (%) State manufacturing production as a share of total gross state product (2)
Age 25-44 years (%) Share of state population between the ages of 25-44 years (6)
Age 45-64 years (%) Share of state population between the ages of 45-64 years (6)
Age 65+ years (%) Share of state population older than the age of 64 years (6)
Note: SPI = state personal income.
*Expressed in both per capita and state personal income share terms.
SOURCE NOTES:
1. Author’s calculations based on data from Employment and Wages, Bureau of Labor Statistics, various years.
2. Author’s calculations based on data from Regional Economic Accounts, Bureau of Economic Analysis, various years.
3. Author’s calculations based on data from State Government Finances, U.S. Census Bureau, various years.
4. Author’s calculations based on data from State Government Finances, U.S. Census Bureau, various years, and Regional Economic Accounts, Bureau of
Economic Analysis, various years.
5. Statistical Abstract of the United States, U.S. Census Bureau, various years.
6. Author’s calculations based on data from Statistical Abstract of the United States, U.S. Census Bureau, various years.
7. Employment and Wages, Bureau of Labor Statistics, various years.
8. Energy Price Estimates by Source, U.S. Department of Energy, various years.

Acknowledgments
4. Specifically, we use the economic growth rate from time t to
We would like to thank three anonymous referees for helpful com- time t + 1, which we calculate as follows: Ln(Economic Activi-
ments and suggestions. tyt+1/Economic Activityt).
5. We focus on private sector economic growth but all of the esti-
Declaration of Conflicting Interests mations below were also performed on total economic growth.
The authors declared no conflicts of interest with respect to the These estimations resulted in very similar results compared
authorship and/or publication of this article. with those that use private sector economic growth and are
available from the authors on request.
Funding 6. For further information on the relationship between states’
The authors received no financial support for the research and/or spending programs other than education spending, see Baicker
authorship of this article. (2005), Saavedra (2000), and Figlio, Kolpin, and Reid (1999).
7. Although it is true that spillovers can occur beyond geographic
Notes neighbors, we have chosen only geographic neighbors because
1. Available at http://nces.ed.gov/ of substantial evidence indicating that bordering jurisdictions
2. See also Bartik (1994). are economically integrated. For example, the 2000 Census in-
3. Data for local government expenditure variables for 2001 and dicates that 42%, 43%, 41%, and 57% of out-of-state movers
2003 were not reported by the Census Bureau. to Alabama, Connecticut, Maryland, and Oregon, respectively,

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


58 Economic Development Quarterly 24(1)

came from bordering states. Obvious exceptions include Flori- Fernandez, R., & Rogerson, R. (1999). Education finance reform
da and California where only 8% and 15%, respectively, of out- and investment in human capital: Lessons from California. Jour-
of-state movers came from bordering states. In addition, see nal of Public Economics, 74, 327-350.
Devereux, Lockwood, and Redoano (2007) for recent evidence Figlio, D. N., Kolpin, V. W., & Reid, W. E. (1999). Do states play
of cross-border shopping occurring between bordering states. welfare games? Journal of Urban Economics, 46, 437-454.
8. See, for examples, Fisher (1997), Dalenberg and Partridge (1995), Fisher, P., & Ditsler, E. (2003, May). Taxes and state economic
or Wasylenko and McGuire (1985). growth: The myths and the reality. Policy Brief, Iowa Policy
9. The energy price index represents the cost of producing one Project, Mount Vernon, IA.
million BTUs of energy based on a weighted average of the Fisher, R. C. (1997). The effects of state and local public services
cost of energy from different sources such as coal, natural gas, on economic development. New England Economic Review,
nuclear, and so on, in each state. March/April, 53-82.
10. In Table 2, we only present results for models in which education Glomm, G., & Ravikumar, B. (1992). Public versus private invest-
spending in neighboring states is constructed using our contigu- ment in human capital: Endogenous growth and income inequal-
ity weighting method. Results for models in which that variable ity. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 818-834.
is constructed using our population weighting method are virtu- Glomm, G., & Ravikumar, B. (1997). Productive government
ally identical and are available from the authors on request. expenditures and long-run growth. Journal of Economic Dynam-
ics & Control, 21, 183-204.
References Harden, J. W., & Hoyt, W. H. (2003). Do states choose their mix of
Baicker, K. (2005). The spillover effects of state spending. Journal taxes to minimize employment losses? National Tax Journal,
of Public Economics, 89, 529-544. 71, 7-26.
Bartik, T. J. (1994). Jobs, productivity, and local economic develop- Helms, L. J. (1985). The effect of state and local taxes on economic
ment: What implications does economic research have for the growth: A time series-cross section approach. Review of Eco-
role of government? National Tax Journal, 47, 847-861. nomics and Statistics, 72, 574-582.
Bensi, M. T., Black, D. C., & Dowd, M. R. (2004). The education/ Hungerford, T. L., & Wassmer, R. W. (2003, September). K-12 edu-
growth relationship: Evidence from real state panel data. Con- cation in the U.S. economy: Its impact on economic develop-
temporary Economic Policy, 22, 281-298. ment, earnings, and housing values. Report conducted for the
Besley, T., & Case, A. (1995). Incumbent behavior: Vote-seeking, tax- National Education Association.
setting and yardstick competition. American Economic Review, Michigan Office of the Governor. (2004). Granholm, Cherry
85, 25-45. announce commission on higher education and economic
Blankenau, W. F. (2005). Public schooling, college subsidies and growth. Retrieved August 20, 2009, from http://www.michigan.
growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 29, 487-507. gov/ltgov/0,1607,7-169—88248--,00.html
Blankenau, W. F., & Cassou, S. P. (2007). Allocating government Mofidi, A., & Stone, J. A. (1990). Do state and local taxes affect eco-
education expenditures across K-12 and college education. Eco- nomic growth? Review of Economics and Statistics, 72, 686-691.
nomic Theory, 31, 85-112. Rangazas, P. (2000). Schooling and economic growth: A King-
Blankenau, W. F., & Simpson, N. B. (2004). Public education Rebelo experiment with human capital. Journal of Monetary
expenditures and growth. Journal of Developmental Econom- Economics, 46, 397-416.
ics, 73, 583-605. Rork, J. C. (2003). Coveting thy neighbors’ taxation. National Tax
Bruce, D., Deskins, J., Hill, B., & Rork, J. (2009). (Small) business Journal, 56, 775-787.
activity and state economic growth: Does size matter? Regional Saavedra, L. A. (2000). A model of welfare competition with
Studies, 43, 229-245. evidence from AFDC. Journal of Urban Economics, 47, 248-
Case, A. C., Rosen, H. S., & Hines, J. R., Jr. (1993). Budget spill- 279.
overs and fiscal policy interdependence. Journal of Public Eco- Su, X. (2004). The allocation of public funds in a hierarchical edu-
nomics, 52, 285-307. cational system. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 28,
Cassou, S., & Lansing, K. (2004). Growth effects of shifting from 2485-2510.
a graduated-rate tax system to a flat tax. Economic Inquiry, 42, Taylor, L. L., & Brown, S. P. (2006). The private sector impact of
194-213. state and local government: Has more become bad? Contempo-
Dalenberg, D. R., & Partridge, M. D. (1995). The effects of taxes, rary Economic Policy, 24, 548-562.
expenditures, and public infrastructure on metropolitan area Vedder, R. (2004). Going broke by degree: Why college costs too
employment. Journal of Regional Science, 35, 617-640. much. Washington, DC: AEI Press.
Devereux, M. P., Lockwood, B., & Redoano, M. (2007). Horizontal Wasylenko, M., & McGuire, T. (1985). Jobs and taxes: The effect of
and vertical indirect tax competition: Theory and some evidence taxes on states’ employment growth rates. National Tax Journal,
from the USA. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 451-479. 38, 497-514.

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011


Deskins et al. 59

Bios of Tennessee in 2006. His research primarily focuses on state and


local tax policy. Recent research has focused on the extent to which
John Deskins is an Assistant Professor of Economics at Creighton local governments use tax rates to compete for tax bases, the degree
University in Omaha, Nebraska. He specializes in empirical policy to which entrepreneurial activity affects state economic growth, and
research. Recent topics have examined state tax policy and small the effect of property tax limits on local government finance.
business activity, tax planning activity in response to state corporate
income taxation, and state practices in determining transportation Laura Ullrich is an Assistant Professor of Economics at Winthrop
expenditures. University. She obtained her PhD in Economics from the Univer-
sity of Tennessee and her BBA in Economics from the University of
Brian Hill is an Assistant Professor of Economics at Salisbury Uni- Georgia. Her primary research interests involve education policy
versity, which he joined after earning his PhD from the University and issues related to state and local taxation.

Downloaded from edq.sagepub.com at Airlangga University on March 15, 2011

You might also like