Is Tourism Growth Able To Shrink Economic Inequalities - A DSGE Analysis

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights


journal homepage: www.sciencedirect.com/journal/annals-of-tourism-research-empirical-insights

Is tourism growth able to shrink economic inequalities? A DSGE analysis


Hongru Zhang a, *, Yang Yang b
a
School of Liberal Arts, Macau University of Science and Technology, Macau 999078, China
b
Department of Tourism and Hospitality Management, Temple University, Philadelphia, PA 19122, USA

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Editor: Dr. Liu Anyu The aim of this paper is to investigate the relationship between inbound tourism and economic inequalities
(income and wealth). We construct a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) small open-economy model
Keywords: that includes the tourism industry and the housing market. We focus on the recent Icelandic tourism boom, and
Inbound tourism our simulation results suggest a reduction in income inequality and an increase in wealth inequality. Inbound
Income inequality
tourism thus has opposite effects on domestic income inequality and wealth inequality, so the Icelandic gov­
Wealth inequality
ernment faces a trade-off when formulating tourism-related policies to reduce inequalities, and the consequences
Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE)
modeling may depend on the type of inequality that policymakers prioritize. Lastly, implications are provided based on
results.

1. Introduction income inequalities in developing economies, in which the tourism


inequality nexus is of the Kuznets type (Alam & Paramati, 2016; Uzar &
Tourism development has been long regarded as an effective tool for Eyuboglu, 2019).
poverty alleviation and can thus reduce income inequality in a society. In order to shed more lights on the insights of how tourism growth
The United Nations World Tourism Organization (UNWTO) has, for can reshape the economic inequality, we propose and build a dynamic
example, recognized the potential of tourism for poverty alleviation as it stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model to capture the channels of
develops (UNWTO, 2002). First, natural resources and culture can be the dissemination of how inbound tourism affects income and wealth in­
basis for tourism products and are assets held by many under-developed equalities in a small open economy. Previous studies relied heavily on
regions (Deller, 2010). Second, tourism income can trickle down to reduced-form econometric models. The weakness of the reduced-form
poorer groups in society through the employment of local people in model is that it lacks usefulness in the presence of feedback loops,
tourism enterprises or through small community-based enterprises. especially when rational agents try to reoptimize in response to envi­
Third, tourism can represent a significant source of foreign exchange ronmental changes like exogenous shocks or policy shifts. Feedback
earnings and government revenue through taxes, which can be redis­ loops pose difficult endogeneity problems that generally make them
tributed to alleviate poverty. Issues concerning economic inequality difficult to estimate using reduced-form methods. The structural
have increasingly received public and academic attention (Alvaredo, approach we use specifies complete models of economic behavior and
Chancel, Piketty, Saez, & Zucman, 2018). estimates or calibrates the primitives of such models, in which we can
Research into tourism economics has typically applied the reduced- simulate the effects of changes in the economic environment on
form econometric model to reveal the relationship between tourism behavior and welfare if needed. Our DSGE model specifies a system of
development and income inequality. For example, although Croes and equations that are dependent on each other based on rigorous macro-
Vanegas (2008) detected a long-run stable and one-way positive economic theories. In the model, the economy contains three main
Granger causal relationship between tourism development and poverty economic decision-makers: foreign tourists, domestic households and
reduction in Nicaragua, Oviedo-García, González-Rodríguez, and Vega- entrepreneurs. Foreign tourists consume a “tourism bundle” consisting
Vázquez (2018) concluded that income from tourism failed to reduce of tourism goods/services (excluding accommodation) and housing,
inequality in wealth distribution in the Dominican Republic, and thus which are complementary to each other. Households are divided into
rejected the assumption of poverty alleviation through tourism. Some two groups according to their skill status. They work, consume, and
studies even find a non-linear relationship between tourism revenue and reside either in their own properties (skilled) or in rented housing units

* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: hrzhang@must.edu.mo (H. Zhang), yangy@temple.edu (Y. Yang).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.annale.2023.100089
Received 31 December 2021; Received in revised form 29 January 2023; Accepted 9 February 2023
Available online 21 February 2023
2666-9579/© 2023 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Ltd. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-
nc-nd/4.0/).
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

(unskilled). The entrepreneur is the only giant supplier in the economy For example, high-income households in Galicia, Spain were found
and produces both tourism and non-tourism goods while also accumu­ through a social accounting matrix model to benefit more from inbound
lating real estate and renting it out to both households and tourists. The tourism than low-income households (Carrascal Incera & Fernández,
model is fully micro-founded with all three decision makers optimized 2015). A Kuznets-type relationship between tourism and income
intertemporally and interacting to reach equilibrium in all markets inequality has also been identified in which tourism may increase in­
when facing a naturally stochastic environment. Income and wealth come inequality at an early stage of development but significantly
inequalities are captured by the wage premium of skilled workers and reduce it in later stages (Alam & Paramati, 2016). More recent studies
the asset/housing value they own, respectively. We use statistical data relate the nexus between tourism and income inequality to countries'
from Iceland to parameterize the model, and can thus closely mimic the institutional qualities and show the complexities of the relationship
real situation. Various types of simulations are conducted to better un­ based on various income levels (Nguyen, Schinckus, Su, & Chong, 2021).
derstand how a boom in inbound tourism can ultimately contribute to Also see J. Zhang (2021) for a meta-analysis of the tourism effects on
income and wealth inequalities in society. income inequality with different econometric tools.
This study makes several contributions to the tourism literature. Wealth inequality has also attracted research attention in public
First, it presents a comprehensive structural investigation of the link economics. Wealth refers to a stock of valuable possessions, such as a
between a tourism boom and income/wealth inequity. Although some of house or financial assets, while income refers to the flow of money
the factors moderating the tourism-inequity relationship have been received, such as wages from employment. The patterns of wealth
examined, few, if any, studies have constructed rigorous macro- inequality are often substantially different from those of income
economic model with solid theoretical foundation. Compared to other inequality. Wealth is typically more unequally distributed than income
macro-economic models investigating the tourism-inequality nexus, and creates a larger gap between different economic classes. Inequality
such as Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) models, the DSGE model in the redistribution of the wealth generated by tourism can increase
has the advantage of stochasticity, allowing for random variation to existing inequalities between classes and also divide ethnic groups
account for uncertainty. Second, instead of only examining income (Oviedo-García et al., 2018). In the tourism literature, although several
inequality, we consider both income and wealth inequalities simulta­ recent studies recommend the investigation of tourism's impact on
neously. This study represents one of the pioneering efforts on looking wealth inequality (Gu, Li, Chang, & Guo, 2017; Uzar & Eyuboglu, 2019),
into effect of tourism growth on wealth inequality. Finally, we conduct no empirical studies have been conducted so far in this area. Thus, in this
simulations in which the model economy confronts various stochastic study, we examine the income and wealth inequality together for the
shocks, including inbound tourism demand, based on a Bayesian esti­ first time in the tourism literature.
mation of structural parameters. This provides insights into how dis­
turbances in the tourism sector can influence income and wealth 2.2. Economic analysis of the tourism-inequality relationship
inequalities.1 Thus, we provide empirical evidence of the complex ef­
fects of inbound tourism on inequality, which has policy implications in The effects of tourism growth on income inequality have been
terms of leveraging tourism as a strategic tool that can tackle inequality investigated using various empirical methods in tourism economics,
and enhance the well-being of those involved. which can be categorized into four groups. Recent studies providing key
empirical evidence are summarized in Table 1. Those in the first group
2. Literature review apply time-series econometrics, such as cointegration and Granger
causality tests, to identify the relationship between tourism develop­
2.1. Tourism growth and income/wealth inequality ment and different measures of inequality. For example, Croes and
Vanegas (2008) established long-run stable relationships and Granger
The contribution tourism makes to economic growth and develop­ causality among tourism development, economic expansion, and
ment has been investigated in numerous studies (Akkemik, 2012), but poverty reduction in Nicaragua, and suggested that public and private
whether tourism-induced growth and development can contribute to intervention is required in tourism expansion development strategies. A
poverty alleviation and the reduction of income inequality has not been similar relationship was also found for Malaysia, in which tourism
fully assessed (Kinyondo & Pelizzo, 2015). Our study extends the liter­ has a long-run cointegration with income distribution, and lowers in­
ature that examines the connection between tourism and inequality. come inequality over time (Shahbaz et al., 2019). However, a study of
From a theoretical perspective, tourism development is found to influ­ the Dominican Republic suggested that income from tourism has not
ence income inequality, and the economic outcomes of tourism activities alleviated poverty and has clearly failed to reduce inequality through
can both decrease or increase inequality through different channels the redistribution of wealth (Oviedo-García et al., 2018). A Kuznets
(Njoya and Seetaram, 2018a). Arrangements through which disadvan­ relationship between tourism and income inequality was found for
taged groups benefit relatively more from tourism activities can help Turkey, where the expansion of tourism activities initially increases
reduce income inequality (Blake, 2008). Unemployment is often a factor income inequality and later reduces it, indicating a new strategy that
that exacerbates income inequality as it both represents a direct loss of policymakers can implement to distribute income more equally (Uzar &
income and deprives people of the means to generate income (Helpman, Eyuboglu, 2019). However, one disadvantage of Granger causality
Itskhoki, & Redding, 2010). The tourism sector primarily reduces in­ analysis is that as it is an atheoretical method based on temporal
come inequality through the creation of new job opportunities, as more ordering, and structural notions of causality are not considered (Hoover,
labor is required if tourism investment and services increase (Garsous, 2017).
Corderi, Velasco, & Colombo, 2017). However, the redistributive effect Studies in the second group apply panel data econometric modeling
of tourism may favor the rich, thus leading to further income inequality. to establish the relationship between tourism and inequalities. Lee and
O'Leary (2008) focused on economic equity in tourism- and recreation-
dependent communities to assess how tourism and recreation develop­
1 ment contribute to economic equity in specific communities in the U.S.
Important types of economic inequality other than the above two are con­
They found that development contributed to increased income
sumption. We refrain from using consumption inequality because it tends to be
dominated by income inequality: the change in income inequality reflects both inequality, unlike manufacturing-related development, which is likely
transitory and permanent shocks, while the change in consumption inequality to reduce it. Kim et al. (2016) used panel data from 69 countries and
should reflect only permanent shocks (Hall, 1978). We put income and wealth found that tourism expenditure had an insignificant effect on poverty
inequalities as our spotlights to reflect the general picture of economic reduction in general, but that the pure effect of tourism on the poverty
inequality. ratio depends on a country's economic development. This finding is

2
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

Table 1 supported by the study of Mahadevan and Suardi (2017), based on 13


Recent key empirical studies on the impact of tourism on poverty and income tourism-intensive economies, which found little evidence to suggest that
inequality. growth in tourism reduces headcount poverty. Their results were robust
Empirical Studies Data Findings to different specifications of the Gini coefficient. Positive results in the
methods literature include the findings of Zhao and Xia (2019), who indicated
Cointegration/ Croes and Vanegas Nicaragua Tourism granger that tourism has a positive effect on poverty reduction in western
Granger (2008) 1980–2004 causes poverty provinces of China, where the relationship between the two is close, thus
causality reduction reflecting the Chinese pro-poverty tourism policy. Despite the mixed
Oviedo-García et al. Dominican Tourism fails to
findings, Kuznets-type relationships between tourism and income
(2018) Republic reduce wealth
2000–2013 inequality inequality have been confirmed for 49 developing economies, indicating
Shahbaz, Solarin, Malaysia Tourism lowers that tourism development increases income inequality until a specific
Azam, and Tiwari 1991–2017 income inequality threshold is reached, and then decreases it (Alam & Paramati, 2016).
(2019) Thus, the tourism-inequality relationship has been established and its
Uzar and Eyuboglu Turkey Tourism-related
(2019) 1974–2015 Kuznets curve valid
moderators after controlling for other variables identified, but the
Panel Lee and O'Leary Selected areas Tourism raises reduced-form equation used does not provide meaningful insights into
econometric (2008) in US income inequality the relationship based on structural analysis that is invariant to policy
model 1990–2000 changes.
Vanegas (2014) Five Central Tourism matters for
Studies in the third group apply social accounting matrices (SAM),
American poverty reduction
countries which capture the various distributional effects of tourism through the
1980–2012 backward and forward links of tourism activities with the rest of the
Alam and Paramati 49 developing Kuznets type economy (Carrascal Incera & Fernández, 2015). Blake (2008), for
(2016) economies relationship example, examined the effects of tourism-related industries and other
1991–2012 between tourism
export industries on households in East Africa and found that the former
and income
inequality provide substantially less income to poorer households than the latter.
Kim, Song, and 69 developing Tourism industry This leads to the concern that tourism expansion may not help alleviate
Pyun (2016) countries reduces poverty poverty in these countries. Saayman et al. (2012) confirmed the findings
1995–2012 ratios only in the
of Blake (2008) in the context of South Africa, finding that the poor
least developed
countries benefit very little in the short term from additional tourism income.
Li, Chen, Li, and 30 provinces in Tourism reduces Tourism receipts can be used as strategic tools to alleviate poverty
Goh (2016) China regional income through policies that focus on the labor market and human resource
1997–2010 inequality development (Muchapondwa & Stage, 2013). Croes and Rivera (2016b)
Mahadevan and 13 tourism- Tourism doesn't
examined the distributional effects of tourism expansion by applying a
Suardi (2017) intensive reduce income
economies inequality SAM model to Ecuador and found that tourism has a large multiplier
1995–2012 effect on the economy and can potentially benefit the poor substantially.
Zhao and Xia Chinese Tourism has a Wealth is spread across all households in urban and rural areas and
(2019) provinces positive effect on
benefits the least wealthy households the most.
1999–2014 poverty reduction
Nguyen et al. 97 countries Tourism has mixed
Studies in the last group extend the SAM analysis by applying a
(2021) 2002–2014 effects on income computable general equilibrium (CGE) model to examine the economic
inequality and distributional impacts of tourism activities. Various parameters in
Social Blake (2008) Kenya 2003, Tourism is not pro- the model are calibrated using SAM. Blake et al. (2008) developed a CGE
accounting Tanzania 2001 poor
model that considers both the impact of tourism expansion and the
matrix Uganda 1992
Saayman, Rossouw, South Africa Tourism is not pro- distributional effects among rich and poor households in the Brazilian
and Krugell (2012) 2004 poor economy. They show that the effects on all income groups are positive,
Klytchnikova and Panama 2008 Tourism is pro-poor but the lowest income households benefit less than those in higher-
Dorosh (2013)
income groups. Poverty relief can only be effective if governmental
Muchapondwa and Botswana Tourism is not pro-
Stage (2013) 1996–1997, poor
policies that can redistribute greater shares of the revenue to the poor
Namibia 2004 are considered. Similarly, in Thailand, increased inbound tourism de­
South Africa mand raises aggregate household income but worsens its distribution
2005 (Wattanakuljarus & Coxhead, 2008), because the general equilibrium
Carrascal Incera Galicia in Spain Tourism is not pro-
effects of tourism expansion undermine the profitability of other trad­
and Fernández 2008 poor
(2015) able sectors, which generate a substantial proportion of the incomes of
Croes and Rivera Ecuador 2008 Tourism is pro-poor those in poverty. The finding that poverty reductions are accompanied
(2016a) by increases in income inequality illustrates the difficulty of this trade-
CGE model Blake, Arbache, Brazil 2002 Tourism is not pro- off from a tourism boost poses. A CGE study of domestic and foreign
Sinclair, and Teles poor
(2008)
tourism in Indonesia also identified this trade-off, as policies such as
Wattanakuljarus Thailand Tourism is not pro- investments in tourism-related sectors aimed at increasing labor pro­
and Coxhead poor ductivity are required to address both poverty and income inequality
(2008) (Mahadevan et al., 2016). Njoya & Seetaram, 2018b), however, provide
Banerjee, Cicowiez, Haiti 2012/ Tourism reduces
contrasting findings in their study of Kenya, in which they used a CGE
and Gachot (2015) 2013 poverty
Mahadevan, Amir, Indonesia Tourism is not pro- model to investigate whether tourism development can provide a route
and Nugroho poor to poverty reduction. They demonstrated that the effects of tourism
(2016) expansion on the poverty gap and poverty severity are significant in
Njoya and Seetaram Kenya Tourism is pro-poor both rural and urban areas, indicating that poor households can move up
(2018a)
closer to the poverty line after tourism expansion. Banerjee et al. (2015)
also applied a CGE model to Haiti and indicated that tourism has a
positive impact on sectoral activity, particularly in the hotel and

3
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

restaurant sector. Tourism investment helped some of the region's 2.15


poorest people, thus significantly reducing the poverty headcount.
However, one drawback of CGE modeling is the lack of stochasticity, 32
2.10

which prevents the estimation and the fitting of the model to time series
2.05
data. Although an econometric estimation of CGE models has been
suggested, insufficient data are typically available for the estimation of 30
2.00
large complex equation systems with deep parameters, thus leading to
the routine use of calibration (Rickman, 2010). 28
1.95

2.3. Macro-economic modeling of tourism 1.90

26
1.85
Rooted in the concept of the “multiplier effect,” the macro-economic
modeling efforts help understand how tourism is interrelated with other
24
parts of the economy. Different macro-economic models have been 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
introduced in tourism economics. The input-output (I-O) analysis ex­
amines the inter-sectoral relationship between different components of Gini index
Wage premium of tertiary education and above
the economy by analyzing the flows of products across different sectors,
and it evaluates the direct, indirect and induced impacts of tourism
(a)
(Yang, Fik, & Altschuler, 2018). A more complicated model, the
computable general equilibrium (CGE) method, which encompasses .7 .18
multiple equations, was applied in tourism economics to depict the
behavior of consumers and producers under the principles of micro­ .6 .16
economic optimization (Pratt, 2011). A further extension to CGE is the
dynamic CGE model that includes a time dimension to capture various .5 .14

types of economic dynamics in the model (Njoya & Seetaram, 2018a).


Unlike CGE providing the estimates based on the entire economy, the
.4 .12

tourism satellite accounts (TSA) method was developed to provide the .3 .10
estimates at the industry level with standardized databases related to the
tourism industry (Dwyer, Forsyth, & Spurr, 2007). TSA became partic­ .2 .08
ularly popular to generate a series of official tourism statistics to
monitor, manage, and project tourism and related activities. .1 .06
To date, only a few papers have explored tourism issues within the
DSGE framework. Liu, Song, and Blake (2018) proposed a DSGE model .0 .04
2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
estimated by a Bayesian approach to explore the relationship between
tourism development and economic growth. H. Zhang and Yang (2019) Real housing prices
adopted a small open economy DSGE framework to investigate the Inbound tourism expenditure to GDP ratio

impact of an inbound tourism boom on Dutch disease and the welfare (b)
consequences on the hosting economy. Liu and Wu (2019) constructed a
Bayesian DSGE endogenous growth model to investigate the association Fig. 1. Historical pattern of inequality and tourism measures in Iceland.
between tourism productivity and economic growth. Results recognized
spillover effects from tourism owing to physical and human capital ex­ wealthiest 5% of the country owned 43.5%, and the wealthiest 1%
ternalities and public services. Likewise, Inchausti-Sintes and Pérez- owned 19.2% of all available assets (Grapevine, 2018). This trend is
Granja (2020) applied a Bayesian DSGE model to evaluate the impact of consistent with the other Scandinavian countries (Bird, 2014). Fig. 1-b
monetary policy and exchange rate on tourism demand, and the model plots the Icelandic house price index between 2002 and 2018. We focus
unveiled the optimal response to tourism across four different monetary on the housing price index because the inequality in net housing wealth
policies. In a more recent paper, Yang, Zhang, and Chen (2020) devel­ and in net wealth are highly correlated across OECD countries (Causa,
oped a DSGE model to understand how the COVID-19 pandemic affects Woloszko, & Leite, 2019). Meanwhile, the increase in the housing price
tourism, and the results show that the tourism voucher policy helps after 2010 arguably contributed to the increase in wealth inequality in
alleviate the negative impact from the pandemics. Western European countries (Fuller, Johnston, & Regan, 2019). Ice­
land's circumstances are unique, as the reduction in income inequality is
2.3.1. Tourism development in Iceland accompanied by an increase in wealth inequality, which poses research
We select Iceland as our case in this study for our model setup and challenges. We aim to reconcile these two issues in this study.
parameter estimation, although our DSGE model is generalizable to any The recent Icelandic tourism boom can help to explain the changes in
small open economy. Iceland has a significant tourism sector and has inequality. The tourism boom pushes up the housing price (benefiting
experienced particular events over the past decade that distinguish it the wealthier) while reducing the wage premium of skilled labor
from other Scandinavian countries. The financial collapse of 2008 (benefiting the poorer). Increasing house prices enlarges the net worth
reversed the downward trend of income inequality that had occurred of the rich, and raising the living cost of the poor reduces the net worth
from the late 1990s to 2007. In the last few years, signs of improvement of the poor, leading to more severe wealth inequality. Wage premium is
have been seen, as the Gini index has gradually lowered from a peak of the average wage difference between high-skilled and low-skilled
29.6% in 2008 to 24.1% in 2016, and the wage premium of tertiary workers. Therefore, if anything can help reduce the wage premium
education and above shows a similar pattern (see Fig. 1-a). The dy­ actually narrows down the income gap between the two group and
namics of income inequality in Iceland do not follow the general pattern benefit the lower class. Thus, we investigate the relationship between
of other Scandinavian countries, as the Gini indices in Denmark, inbound tourism and economic inequality (income and wealth) during
Finland, Norway, and Sweden increase, or at least do not decline, after the recent boom in Icelandic tourism. Tourist numbers have increased
2008 (Pareliussen, Hermansen, Andre, & Causa, 2018, p. page 21). on average by >20% annually since 2010, and the number of foreign
Wealth inequality continues to grow in Iceland, and in 2016 the

4
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

visitors more than quadrupled between 2010 and 2017, reaching 2.2 subject to the budget constraint
million. Fig. 1-b also plots the ratio of inbound tourism expenditure to
GDP in Iceland between 2003 and 2018, which provide good indications
F
pT,t CT,t + rH,t HtF = YtF (2)
of the importance of inbound tourism to the Icelandic economy. The
growth rates of both these factors were relatively flat before the financial where βF is the foreign tourists' subjective discount factor. ω determines
crisis and have risen rapidly since 2010/2011, coinciding with the the share of tourism consumption in the bundle, and υ is the inverse of
reduction of income inequality (measured by GINI index or wage pre­ the elasticity of substitution between goods and accommodation of
mium) and increase in wealth inequality (proxied by real housing price). tourism expenditure in the bundle. In addition, pT, t is the (relative) price
Different from the other four Nordic countries, Iceland is the only one to of tourism goods and rH, t is the (real) rent of accommodation. We further
have experienced a surge in inbound tourism and an improvement in assume that CFT, t and HFt are complementary to each other. Foreign
income inequality over the last decade. Tourism has boosted the econ­ tourists select optimal CFT, t and HFt to maximize eq. (1) subject to eq. (2).
omy and alleviated some of the effects of the financial crisis. The
question we address is whether inbound tourism in Iceland, while easing 3.2. High-skilled workers
the problems caused by the financial crisis, also contributes to the recent
dynamics of income/wealth inequality? The economy is inhabited by two types of infinitely lived workers.
High-skilled workers (HSWs) derive utility from consumption CH t ,
3. The model housing HH H
t , and leisure (disutility of working Nt ). Their consumption
consists of tourism goods CH T, t and non-tourism manufacturing goods CM,
H
A small open economy DSGE model is developed in this study, and it t , aggregated by CES functions. In the real estate market, we assume
includes a tourism goods sector and a housing market. The model also that HSWs own houses HH t and are owner-occupied residents. In the
allows for household heterogeneity and capital-skill complementarity in labor market, HSWs only supply hours to manufacturing firms. Their
production (Lindquist, 2004). The two types of domestic households are utility maximization problem is given by
high-skilled workers NH, t and low-skilled workers NL, t, the two types of ( ( H )1+η )
∑ ∞
( H )t N
final goods provided are tourism goods (excluding accommodation) YT, V H = E0 β lnCtH + jt lnHtH − μH t
1+η
t, and generic manufacturing goods, YM, t. Tourism goods are produced t=0

by combining low-skilled workers with capital, whereas manufacturing


[ ( )1− ζ ]1−1 ζ
goods also require additional high-skilled workers. Skilled technical )1− ζ (
CtH = φ CT,t
H H
+ (1 − φ) CM,t (3)
ability is complementary to capital such as high-tech equipment (Kru­
sell, Ohanian, Rios-Rull, & Violante, 2000). The housing market is
divided into an owner-occupied part and a rental part that serves tourists where βH is their subjective discount factor, jt captures the stochastic
from other countries as well as domestic households. housing preference shock, and η measures the Frisch elasticity of the
The multiple groups of decision-makers in the model economy are labor supply (Frisch, 1959). For the consumption bundle, φ determines
inbound tourists, domestic households consisting of high-skilled and the share of tourism goods and ζ is the inverse of the elasticity of sub­
low-skilled workers, as well as entrepreneurs. Foreign tourists make stitution between tourism goods and manufacturing goods. The inter­
optimal decisions between tourism goods and accommodation under a temporal budget constraint is given by
budget constraint. The utility of domestic households comes from con­ ( )
H
pT,t CT,t H
+ CM,t + qt HtH − Ht−H 1 + Bt = wHt NtH + rB,t− 1 Bt− 1 (4)
sumption, housing services, and leisure time (disutility from working).
High-skilled workers consume a composite of tourism and
where qt is the real housing price, Bt is the debt from entrepreneurs with
manufacturing goods and own houses, whereas low-skilled workers
a return rate of rB, t, wH t is the real wage for the HSWs in the
purchase manufacturing goods only and obtain housing services through
manufacturing sector. HSWs select CH H H H
T, t, CM, t, Ht , Nt and Bt to maximize
renting (instead of buying). The labor supply goes to both the tourism
eq. (3), subject to eq. (4).
and manufacturing sectors, and low-skilled workers work in both sec­
tors, and high-skilled workers work in the manufacturing sector only. As
3.3. Low-skilled workers
the delegated supplier in the economy, entrepreneurs produce both
tourism and manufacturing goods, participating real estate activities
To distinguish low-skilled workers (LSWs) from HSWs, we make the
(including renting houses/properties to tourists). All four decision
following assumptions. First, LSWs work in both the tourism and
makers maximize their objective functions under their budget con­
manufacturing sectors, and it is frictionless for them to switch between
straints, and the details of the optimization problems are defined in the
sectors. Second, LSWs do not own housing properties or hold the debts of
following sub-sections.
entrepreneurs. Third, LSWs only consume generic goods. In our model
LSWs appear to be like rule-of-thumb consumers who do not have access
3.1. Foreign tourists to credit markets supporting intertemporal choices (Gali, Valles, &
Lopez-Salido, 2007). LSWs also derive utility from consumption CLt ,
Foreign tourists derive utility from consuming a bundle of tourism- housing HLt , and leisure (disutility of working NLt ), and the utility
related goods and services in Iceland subject spending budget YFt , maximization problem is given by
determined exogenously and stochastically as Webber (2001) noted. The ( ( L )1+η )
bundle CFt includes the accommodation. ∑ ∞
( L )t H Nt
L L L
lnCt + jt lnHt − μ (5)
HFt and the tourism-related consumption CFT, t, including trans­
V = E0 β
t=0
1+η
portation, dining, and entertainment, etc. The utility maximization
problem is specified as follows: where βL is the subjective discount factor of LSWs. The budget constraint


( )t ( ) is given by
V F = E0 βF lnCtF
t=0 CtL + rH,t HtL = wLt NT,t
L
+ wLt NM,t
L
(6)

[ ( )1− υ ]1
( )1− υ 1− υ where NLt = NLT, t + NLM, t indicates that LSWs can switch between the
CtF = ω CT,t
F
+ (1 − ω) HtF (1) tourism and manufacturing sectors without friction, and wLt is the real
wage for LSWs. They select CLt , HLt , NLT, t and NLM, t to maximize eq. (5),

5
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

subject to eq. (6). raise the skill premium, or the capital-skill complementarity effect (Krusell
et al., 2000).

3.4. Entrepreneurs
3.5. Market-clearing conditions
The group of entrepreneurs can be treated as part of big families of
HSWs. They are delegates of the big families to run the supply side of the Lastly, the tourism, manufacturing and the housing markets clear
economy. They accumulate capital KT, t, KM, t, and housing, HEt . They with the following conditions
produce tourism goods YT, t and manufacturing goods YM, t, by hiring
labor of HSWs NH L
H F
(14)
t and LSWs Nt . They also provide rental services to
YT,t = CT,t + CT,t
LSWs and foreign tourists. Their intertemporal objective function is:
YM,t + YtF = CM,t
H
+ CtL + CtE + Kt+1 − (1 − δ)Kt (15)


( )( )
E
V = E0 β E t
lnCtE (7)
t=0 H = HtH + HtL + HtF (16)

where βE is the entrepreneurs' subjective discount factor and CEt their


4. Empirical strategies
consumption of generic goods. We suppose entrepreneurs not
consuming tourism goods and optimize subject to the following
4.1. Model calibration
constraint:

pT,t YT,t + YM,t + rH,t HtE + Bt = CtE + rB,t− 1 Bt− 1 + wHt NtH + wLt NtL We collected the four major economic indicators in Iceland between
2002 and 2018 from Statistics Iceland, and they are real consumption,
( )
+ qt HtE − Ht−E 1 + KT,t+1 − (1 − δT )KT,t + KM,t+1 − (1 − δM )KM,t (8) real investment, the real housing price, and the average wage premium.
We do not use the GDP series because government spending is absent
where δT and δM are the rates of depreciation in capital used in tourism from the model. All data were log-linearized and HP-filtered in the
and manufacturing production, respectively. In addition to the flow of timeseries (Hodrick & Prescott, 1997). The calibration procedure starts
funds constraint, the entrepreneur is also restricted by the following with assigning values to major parameters of the DSGE model. Two
borrowing constraint: methods were used: (1) empirical evidence and theoretical suggestions
( ) from previous studies and (2) first moment indicating the stylized facts
HE
Bt ≤ mt Et qt+1 t (9) of long-term steady state based on data (Gomme & Rupert, 2007). We
rB,t
calibrate the model parameters based on annual data set from Iceland
over approximately the past decade. A Bayesian estimation was used for
where mt represents the loan-to-value ratio. Entrepreneurs are endowed
the remaining parameters.
with production technologies in the two sectors. The production func­
The model is specified on yearly basis. We set δT = 0.2, and δM = 0.1
tion for tourism goods is given in standard Cobb-Douglas fashion:
to reflect the intensive utilization of facilities in tourism-related activ­
( )αT (
L
YT,t = AT,t NT,t KT,t
)1− αT
(10) ities in busy seasons (Turner & Hesford, 2018). The labor share in the
tourism sector is set αT = 0.7. The manufacturing sector hires both HSWs
and LSWs, so the labor share should account for them together. We set
where AT, t measures the stochastic productivity shocks to the tourism
αM = 0.3, and π = 0.5, and the latter two numbers imply that the labor
production and αT captures the labor income share. The production
share in the manufacturing sector is αM + (1 − αM)π = 0.65. These two
function for generic goods features the skill-capital complementarity, in
values, 0.7 and 0.65, are plausible because they straddle the aggregate
which growth in the stock of capital such as equipment increases the
labor share of 0.67 in Seneca (2010). Tables 2 summarizes the calibrated
marginal product of skilled labor, but decreases the marginal product of
parameters and the steady-state ratios of the model.
unskilled labor. Specifically,
( )αM [ ( )1− γ ( )1− γ ]1−1−αMγ
L
YM,t = AM,t NM,t ϕ KM,t + (1 − ϕ) NtH (11) 4.2. Bayesian estimation

where AM, t measures the stochastic productivity shocks in the generic As mentioned earlier, the Bayesian method is embraced to estimate
sector and αM and ϕ are share parameters. The elasticity between NLM, t parameters that have not been covered by previous empirical studies
and NH L
t , and between NM, t and KM, t is one, as in Cobb-Douglas fashion, (An & Schorfheide, 2007).
whereas that between NH t and KM, t is less than Specifically, to generate the posterior mode in this estimation, we
one− complementarity− measured by 1/γ. In this setup, the skill/wage used the Monte Carlo-based optimization routine with Metropolis-
premium wpt is connected to the factor inputs as follows: Hasting algorithms. During the estimation, 20,000 draws in each of
[ ( )1− γ ]− 1
L
two Markov chains were used to simulate the parameters' posterior
wH 1 − αM NM,t
wpt = tL =
ϕ KM,t
+ 1 (12) distribution. Fig. 2 illustrates the multivariate convergence diagnostic
wt αM 1 − ϕ NtH NtH test, which reflects the reliability of the estimation results (Brooks &
Gelman, 1998). The acceptance ratios of the two chains are 0.676 and
To illustrate the implications of this expression for the skill premium,
0.666, respectively, which are acceptable as they are not close to 0 or 1
we log-linearize it, and it yields
(Herbst & Schorfheide, 2016).
( )
(
1 − αM
) L
NM,t ϕ
(
KM,t
)1− γ The parameters requiring Bayesian estimation include (1) the inverse
lnwpt ≃ ln + ln − (13) of foreign tourists' elasticity of substitution between tourism consump­
αM NtH 1 − ϕ Nt H
tion and accommodation υ; (2) the inverse of the elasticity of substitu­
We find that an increase in the ratio of low-skilled to high-skilled tion of HSWs between tourism and non-tourism goods ζ; and (3) the
labor in the manufacturing sector will ceteris paribus raise the skill pre­ inverse of the elasticity of substitution between capital and HSWs labor
mium, or the relative supply effect, which is relatively intuitive. We also in the manufacturing production function γ. The parameters of first-
see that when γ > 1, indicating that KM, t and NH t are complementary, a order autoregressive coefficients ρf, ρT, ρM, ρm, and ρj, and standard
rise in the stock of capital relative to high-skilled labor will ceteris paribus deviations σf, σ T, σ M, σ m, and σj, specified as follows:

6
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

( )
Table 2 lnYtF = ρf lnYt−F 1 + ef ,t ef ,t ∼ N 0, σ2f
Calibrated parameters and steady-state ratios.
Parameter Description Value Source ( )
lnAT,t = ρT lnAT,t− 1 + eT,t eT,t ∼ N 0, σ2T
β Workers' discount factor 0.966 Seneca (2010)
βE Entrepreneurs' discount 0.932 Iacoviello and Neri (2010) ( )
lnAM,t = ρM lnAM,t− 1 + eM,t eM,t ∼ N 0, σ 2M
factor
j Weight on housing 0.71 Iacoviello and Neri (2010) ( )
and the authors' calculation lnmt = ρm lnmt− 1 + em,t em,t ∼ N 0, σ 2m
η Inverse of Frisch elasticity of 3 Seneca (2010)
labor supply
( )
m Entrepreneurial loan-to- 0.7 Elíasson and Pétursson lnjt = ρj lnjt− 1 + ej,t ej,t ∼ N 0, σ2j
value ratio (2009)
αT Labor share in tourism 0.7 Seneca (2010) and the In terms of the prior means, capital-skill complementarity implies the
production authors' calculation elasticity of substitution between HSWs, and capital in the
αM LSW share in manufacturing 0.3 Seneca (2010) and the manufacturing production function is less than one. Complementarity is
production authors' calculation
also applicable to foreign tourists, between tourism consumption and
π HSW share in skill capital 0.5 Seneca (2010) and the
composite authors' calculation accommodation. Thus, we set the prior means for both γ and υ to 2. We
δT Tourism capital depreciation 0.2 Seneca (2010) and the establish households' elasticity of substitution between tourism and
rate authors' calculation manufacturing goods based on the statistical data on the share of Ice­
Manufacturing capital 0.1 Seneca (2010) and the
δT
landers' tourism consumption and their price elasticity of tourism de­
depreciation rate authors' calculation
mand (Song, Kim, & Yang, 2010). Thus, we set the prior means for ζ to
0.5. For shock processes, we use standard prior means for the first-order
Variable
autoregressive coefficient and standard deviations for innovations (Sun
YF/Y Inbound tourism 11.8% Statistics Iceland
expenditure output ratio & Tsang, 2017). Table 3 provides the prior distributions of these pa­
pTYT/Y Tourism production output 17.7% Statistics Iceland rameters and shock processes used in DSGE modeling.
ratio The right panels of Table 3 report the posterior mean and 90%
C/Y Consumption output ratio 68.1% Statistics Iceland probability intervals. The posterior mean of γ is 2.25, implying that
NT/N Tourism share of 11.0% Statistics Iceland
employment
capital and HSW are indeed complementary in producing
p TC H
T /C Domestic tourism 8.7% Statistics Iceland manufacturing goods. Similarly, the posterior mean of υ is 1.92. This
expenditure consumption value confirms the complementarity between tourism consumption and
ratio accommodation for foreign tourists. The posterior mean of ζ is 0.7,
IT/I Share of investment in 19.5% WTTC T&T Iceland
demonstrating moderate substitution between tourism and
tourism sector
rHHFR/YF Share of accom expenditure 21.1% Statistics Iceland manufacturing consumption for HSWs. All shocks are relatively persis­
for inbound tourists tent and the resulting posteriors are close to their priors. The innovations
HH
P /H Home ownership rate 80% Statistics Iceland of the inbound tourism demand shock and the domestic house prefer­
ence shock are extremely volatile.

Fig. 2. Multivariate convergence diagnostic test of the model.

7
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

Table 3
Prior and posterior distribution for Bayesian estimation.
Prior and posterior distribution of the structural parameters

Prior distribution Posterior distribution

Parameter Distribution Mean SD Mean 10% 90%

υ Gamma 2 0.4 2.2552 1.6052 2.8572


γ Gamma 2 0.4 1.9165 1.2740 2.5135
ζ Beta 0.5 0.1 0.7046 0.5308 0.8933

Prior and posterior distribution of the shock processes


ρf Beta 0.8 0.2 0.7936 0.6523 0.9469
ρT Beta 0.8 0.2 0.6957 0.5483 0.8463
ρM Beta 0.8 0.2 0.7274 0.5973 0.8851
ρm Beta 0.8 0.2 0.6964 0.5376 0.8429
ρj Beta 0.8 0.2 0.8241 0.7084 0.9266
σf Inv. Gamma 0.1 0.02 0.3241 0.2124 0.4361
σT Inv. Gamma 0.1 0.02 0.0644 0.0333 0.0986
σM Inv. Gamma 0.1 0.02 0.0748 0.0543 0.0962
σm Inv. Gamma 0.1 0.02 0.1213 0.0774 0.1639
σj Inv. Gamma 0.1 0.02 0.2666 0.1857 0.3564

5. Model results although the effect is quantitatively weaker. A tourism boom from the
supply side therefore, also contributes to the simultaneous improvement
5.1. Impulse responses in income inequality and deterioration of wealth inequality in Iceland.
Due to space limitations, the IRFs for the remaining structural shocks in
We are interested in understanding tourism's impact on the fluctu­ the model are presented in the supplementary material section.
ation in the wage premium (as the proxy for income inequality) and the
housing price in Iceland (as the proxy for wealth inequality). We first use 5.2. Variance decomposition
impulse response functions (IRFs) to illustrate how the shocks to in­
bound tourism demand and tourism productivity explain the wage Variance decomposition enables the evaluation of the proportion of a
premium and housing price dynamics (Cogley & Nason, 1995). Fig. 3 variable's forecast error variance that can be attributed to random in­
displays the IRFs to the inbound tourism demand shock. The boom in the novations in the system (Torraleja, Vázquez, & Franco, 2009). We use
tourism sector attracts resources from the manufacturing sector, so that the unconditional forecast error variance decomposition to demonstrate
labor is reallocated to the tourism sector and low-skilled wages become how different types of shocks influence the volatility of the wage pre­
higher in both sectors. Higher skilled wages initially decline, but mium (proxy of income inequality), housing value (proxy of wealth
demonstrate persistence in line with the movement of manufacturing inequality), and the general economy. We focus mainly on six variables
capital, due to complementarity. Thus, the wage premium drops, which of interest— two price variables of wage premium and the real housing
is also reflected in the relative supply effect of labor and the capital-skill price, four quantity variables of tourism output, manufacturing output,
complementarity effect in the manufacturing sector. The boom in the consumption, and investment. The remainder are available upon
rental market has prompted entrepreneurs to accumulate more housing request. Table 4 presents the results of the variance decomposition. For
stock for rent, reducing the supply of owner-occupied housing and the wage premium, which represents income inequality in our model,
pushing up prices. We observe a decline in the wage premium (proxy of the main driving force is the inbound tourism demand shock, which
income inequality) and a rise in housing value (proxy of wealth accounts for over 56% of the variance; housing preference ranks second
inequality) conditional on the inbound tourism demand boom. Given with 20%; tourism and manufacturing productivity shocks account for
the continuous growth in inbound tourism, the simultaneous improve­ 10% and 11%, respectively; and the LTV ratio shock has only a minor
ment of income inequality and the deterioration of wealth inequality in role. The other variable of interest, the wealth inequality (proxied by the
Iceland over the past decade is not surprising. real housing price), is mainly driven by the housing preference shock,
Productivity analysis is essential for evaluating tourism sustainabil­ which accounts for 45% of the variance. The inbound tourism demand
ity and reshaping tourism activities, as there is a direct link between shock is also significant and accounts for 17% of the variance. However,
productivity and the tourism industry's competitiveness and profit­ it ranks behind the manufacturing productivity shock with 21% of the
ability (Assaf & Tsionas, 2018). We also examine how tourism sector variance, and ahead of the LTV ratio shock with 16%. Thus, inbound
productivity shapes the dynamics of income and wealth inequality in tourism demand shock plays a major role in determining the uncondi­
our model, and Fig. 4 plots the IRFs of a positive tourism sector pro­ tional variance of both the wage premium and the housing price, while
ductivity shock resulting from more efficient accommodation and food only the tourism productivity shock affects the variance in the wage
serving standards, travel and reservation activities, and transport ser­ premium significantly. Thus, tourism factors, both in terms of foreign
vices. Higher productivity in the tourism sector directly increases demand and domestic supply, account for much of the variance in in­
tourism production and low skilled wages in the sector. Like the inbound come inequality, whereas only inbound tourism demand significantly
tourism demand shock, the tourism boom leads to resource reallocation determines the variance in wealth inequality.
from the manufacturing sector to the tourism sector. This is confirmed
by the relative supply effect and capital-skill complementarity effect,
5.3. Historical decomposition
and
the wage premium (proxy of income inequality) also declines. The
Fig. 5 shows the historical contribution of each structural shock to
housing price (proxy for the wealth inequality) increases along with the
the variability of selected endogenous variables (Hasumi, Iiboshi, &
rental price, although the effects are indirect. The low wage premium
Nakamura, 2018). As panel (a) shows, the inbound tourism demand
that goes along with the high housing value is also observed to be
shock is the primary driving force of the fluctuations in the wage pre­
conditional on a positive productivity shock in the tourism sector,
mium. Housing preference shock also has a significant role, but only in

8
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

Fig. 3. Impulse responses to the inbound tourism demand shock.


Note: The y-axis measures the percent deviation from the steady state. The thick lines represent the estimated responses and shaded areas demarcate the 90%
confidence intervals.

the first half of the sample. Panel (b) demonstrates that house preference 6. Conclusion
represents the most important factor shaping the housing price fluctu­
ation, followed by the shock to inbound tourism demand, along with the The tourism-inequality nexus has been investigated extensively in
manufacturing productivity and LTV ratio shocks. This confirms the the literature, but the inequalities in income and wealth have rarely
earlier results of the variance decomposition. Panel (c) and (d) show that been examined together. Most of the research is based on either the
consumption and investment shocks are largely associated with the hedonic method or the traditional reduced-form econometric model,
manufacturing productivity shock, while the inbound tourism demand with inequality being a function of tourism, and largely overlooks the
shock also plays a significant role in the dynamics of investment. The dynamics of the tourism-inequality relationship from a broader sto­
results together demonstrate that the inbound tourism demand shock chastic environment. The ongoing division between income inequality
explains a. and wealth inequality in Iceland provides an ideal scenario for our
considerable amount of the variations in wage premium in Iceland. study, and the dynamics of the inequalities are accompanied by an influx
This again confirms the major role of inbound tourism demand in of visitors, which motivates our exploration of the dynamic relationship
shaping the dynamics of income and wealth inequalities. between inbound tourism and the two types of inequalities in Iceland.
We investigate this relationship within a DSGE framework.
From theoretical perspective, our model can reconcile the division

9
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

Fig. 4. Impulse responses to the tourism productivity shock.

Table 4
Variance decomposition of the forecast errors (in %).
Variables σf σT σM σm σj
Inbound tourism demand shock Tourism productivity shock Manufacturing productivity shock L.T.V shock Housing preference shock

Wage premium 56.23 10.03 11.39 2.05 20.30


House price 17.29 0.84 21.26 15.86 44.75
Tourism production 32.26 32.76 34.16 0.52 0.31
Manufacturing production 2.01 0.31 94.75 0.60 2.34
Consumption 6.87 0.36 85.98 2.30 4.48
Investment 14.14 1.51 58.48 8.63 17.24

between income inequality and wealth inequality by driving the de­ of inbound tourism shocks on the dynamics of the Icelandic wage pre­
parture between wage premium (proxy of income inequality) and mium, housing price, and the total economy. The impulse response
housing prices (proxy of wealth inequality) conditioning on inbound function demonstrates that the wage premium declines while the
tourism demand shift. We then utilize the model by using Bayesian housing price increases after a positive inbound tourism demand shock.
econometrics and conduct several simulations to understand the impact Higher demand by inbound tourists creates a higher demand for low-

10
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

Fig. 5. Historical decomposition of key variables.


Note: The solid lines plot model variables, expressed in percentage deviation from their steady-state values. The bars show the contributions of the estimated
structural shocks.

11
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

skilled workers, leading to low-skilled workers moving from the Bird, M. (2014). Why socialist Scandinavia has some of the highest inequality in Europe.
Blake, A. (2008). Tourism and income distribution in East Africa. International Journal of
manufacturing sector to the tourism sector, and an increase in their
Tourism Research, 10, 511–524.
relative wages. Capital-skill complementarity in the manufacturing Blake, A., Arbache, J. S., Sinclair, M. T., & Teles, V. (2008). Tourism and poverty relief.
sector then pushes down high-skilled wages. Both reduce the wage Annals of Tourism Research, 35, 107–126.
premium and thus income inequality. The increase in inbound tourism Brooks, S. P., & Gelman, A. (1998). General methods for monitoring convergence of
iterative simulations. Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics, 7, 434–455.
increases the consumption of tourism goods and complementary ac­ Carrascal Incera, A., & Fernández, M. F. (2015). Tourism and income distribution:
commodation, leading to a boom in rentals. Higher rentals further result Evidence from a developed regional economy. Tourism Management, 48, 11–20.
in more real estate purchases by entrepreneurs, pushing up the housing Causa, O., Woloszko, N., & Leite, D. (2019). Housing, wealth accumulation and wealth
distribution: Evidence and stylized facts. OECD Economics Department Working Paper No.
price, and thus the wealth inequality. The variance decomposition and 1588.
historical shock decomposition show that the shock in inbound tourism Cogley, T., & Nason, J. M. (1995). Output dynamics in real-business cycle models.
demand is the key driving force of the fluctuations in the Icelandic wage American Economic Review, 85, 492–511.
Croes, R., & Rivera, M. A. (2016a). Tourism’s potential to benefit the poor. Tourism
premium, whereas the housing preference shock plays the most signif­ Economics, 23, 29–48.
icant role in determining the house price volatility. The estimated in­ Croes, R., & Rivera, M. A. (2016b). Tourism’s potential to benefit the poor: A social
bound tourism demand shock thus explains much of the variation in the accounting matrix model applied to Ecuador. Tourism Economics, 23, 29–48.
Croes, R., & Vanegas, M. (2008). Cointegration and causality between tourism and
wage premium, housing price, and macro indicators such as consump­ poverty reduction. Journal of Travel Research, 47, 94–103.
tion and investment in Iceland. The dynamics of both income and wealth Deller, S. (2010). Rural poverty, tourism and spatial heterogeneity. Annals of Tourism
inequalities are well accounted for by this shock. Research, 37, 180–205.
Dwyer, L., Forsyth, P., & Spurr, R. (2007). Contrasting the uses of TSAs and CGE models:
In terms of policy implications, any disruptions to the tourism in­
Measuring tourism yield and productivity. Tourism Economics, 13, 537–551.
dustry could easily spill over to other sectors as highlighted in our DSGE Elíasson, L., & Pétursson, T. G. (2009). The residential housing market in Iceland:
model results. As inbound tourism has opposite effects on domestic in­ Analysing the effects of mortgage market restructuring. Housing Studies, 24, 25–45.
come inequality and wealth inequality, the Icelandic government faces a Frisch, R. (1959). A complete scheme for computing all direct and cross demand
elasticities in a model with many sectors. Econometrica, 27, 177–196.
trade-off when formulating tourism-related policies to combat such in­ Fuller, G. W., Johnston, A., & Regan, A. (2019). Housing prices and wealth inequality in
equalities. Inbound tourism is very likely to be synchronized with global Western Europe. West European Politics, 43, 297–320.
business cycles, so the cyclic approach taken in tourism management Gali, J., Valles, J., & Lopez-Salido, D. (2007). Understanding the effects on government
spending on consumption. Journal of European Economic Association, 5, 227–270.
depends on the goals of the Icelandic government regarding inequality. Garsous, G., Corderi, D., Velasco, M., & Colombo, A. (2017). Tax incentives and job
Our work provides a first step towards analyzing the relationship creation in the tourism sector of Brazil’s SUDENE area. World Development, 96,
between tourism activities and inequalities within the DSGE framework, 87–101.
Gomme, P., & Rupert, P. (2007). Theory, measurement and calibration of
but the study has some limitations. First, we only use proxies of income macroeconomic models. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 460–497.
and wealth inequalities in the model and do not generate precise mea­ Grapevine. (2018). Iceland’s richest 5% own about half the Country’s wealth.
surements of inequalities, such as general distribution of income and Gu, X., Li, G., Chang, X., & Guo, H. (2017). Casino tourism, economic inequality, and
housing bubbles. Tourism Management, 62, 253–263.
wealth in the economy. Second, we do not consider the role of govern­ Hall, R. E. (1978). Stochastic implications of the life cycle-permanent income hypothesis:
ment in the model. For example, the government can propose different Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 971–987.
taxation and regulation policies in different sectors. How government Hasumi, R., Iiboshi, H., & Nakamura, D. (2018). Trends, cycles and lost decades:
Decomposition from a DSGE model with endogenous growth. Japan and the World
policy can help improve the inequality issues in the economy is a further
Economy, 46, 9–28.
area of interest. Third, our analysis is only based on the model structure Helpman, E., Itskhoki, O., & Redding, S. (2010). Inequality and unemployment in a
and parameter values for Iceland, and a better understanding of the global economy. Econometrica, 78, 1239–1283.
range of impact of different structures and parameters can help gener­ Herbst, E. P., & Schorfheide, F. (2016). Bayesian estimation of DSGE models. Princeton
University Press.
alize the model settings to other economies, particularly those dissimilar Hodrick, R. J., & Prescott, E. C. (1997). Postwar US business cycles: An empirical
to Iceland, especially underdeveloped countries that are tourism- investigation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29, 1–16.
dependent. Lastly, the 2008 deep recession might validate a structural Hoover, K. D. (2017). Causality in economics and econometrics. In M. Vernengo,
E. P. Caldentey, & B. J. RosserJr (Eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics (pp.
break in Iceland. However, our primary goal is to examine how inbound 1–13). London: Palgrave Macmillan UK.
tourism demand disturbances can shape the wage premium and house Iacoviello, M., & Neri, S. (2010). Housing Market Spillovers: Evidence from an Estimated
prices over the whole sample. Therefore, we refrain from time-varying DSGE Model. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2, 125–164.
Inchausti-Sintes, F., & Pérez-Granja, U. (2020). Monetary policy and exchange rate
estimates of parameters values or covariance matrices in our current regime in tourist islands. Tourism Economics, 28, 325-348.
study. We consider these limitations as possible areas for future Kim, N., Song, H., & Pyun, J. H. (2016). The relationship among tourism, poverty, and
research. economic development in developing countries. Tourism Economics, 22, 1174–1190.
Kinyondo, A., & Pelizzo, R. (2015). Tourism, development and inequality- the case of
Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https://doi. Tanzania. Poverty & Public Policy, 7, 64–79.
org/10.1016/j.annale.2023.100089. Klytchnikova, I., & Dorosh, P. (2013). Tourism sector in Panama: Regional economic
impacts and the potential to benefit the poor. Natural Resources Forum, 37, 70–79.
Krusell, P., Ohanian, L. E., Rios-Rull, J.-V., & Violante, G. L. (2000). Capital-skill
Declaration of Competing Interest complementarity and inequality: A macroeconomic analysis. Econometrica, 68,
1029–1053.
Lee, S., & O’Leary, J. T. (2008). Determinants of income inequality in U.S.
N/A
nonmetropolitan tourism- and recreation-dependent communities. Journal of Travel
Research, 46, 456–468.
References Li, H., Chen, J. L., Li, G., & Goh, C. (2016). Tourism and regional income inequality:
Evidence from China. Annals of Tourism Research, 58, 81–99.
Lindquist, M. J. (2004). Capital–skill complementarity and inequality over the business
Akkemik, K. A. (2012). Assessing the importance of international tourism for the Turkish
cycle. Review of Economic Dynamics, 7, 519–540.
economy: A social accounting matrix analysis. Tourism Management, 33, 790–801.
Liu, A., Song, H., & Blake, A. (2018). Modelling productivity shocks and economic
Alam, M. S., & Paramati, S. R. (2016). The impact of tourism on income inequality in
growth using the Bayesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium approach.
developing economies: Does Kuznets curve hypothesis exist? Annals of Tourism
International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 30, 3229–3249.
Research, 61, 111–126.
Liu, A., & Wu, D. C. (2019). Tourism productivity and economic growth. Annals of
Alvaredo, F., Chancel, L., Piketty, T., Saez, E., & Zucman, G. (2018). World inequality
Tourism Research, 76, 253–265.
report. Berlin: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Mahadevan, R., Amir, H., & Nugroho, A. (2016). Regional impacts of tourism-led growth
An, S., & Schorfheide, F. (2007). Bayesian analysis of DSGE models. Econometric Reviews,
on poverty and income inequality. Tourism Economics, 23, 614–631.
26, 113–172.
Mahadevan, R., & Suardi, S. (2017). Panel evidence on the impact of tourism growth on
Assaf, A. G., & Tsionas, M. (2018). The estimation and decomposition of tourism
poverty, poverty gap and income inequality. Current Issues in Tourism, 22, 253–264.
productivity. Tourism Management, 65, 131–142.
Muchapondwa, E., & Stage, J. (2013). The economic impacts of tourism in Botswana,
Banerjee, O., Cicowiez, M., & Gachot, S. (2015). A quantitative framework for assessing
Namibia and South Africa: Is poverty subsiding? Natural Resources Forum, 37, 80–89.
public investment in tourism – An application to Haiti. Tourism Management, 51,
157–173.

12
H. Zhang and Y. Yang Annals of Tourism Research Empirical Insights 4 (2023) 100089

Nguyen, C. P., Schinckus, C., Su, T. D., & Chong, F. H. L. (2021). The influence of tourism Turner, M. J., & Hesford, J. W. (2018). The impact of renovation capital expenditure on
on income inequality. Journal of Travel Research, 60, 1426–1444. hotel property performance. Cornell Hospitality Quarterly, 60, 25–39.
Njoya, E. T., & Seetaram, N. (2018a). Tourism contribution to poverty alleviation in UNWTO. (2002). Tourism and poverty alleviation.
Kenya: A dynamic computable general equilibrium analysis. Journal of Travel Uzar, U., & Eyuboglu, K. (2019). Can tourism be a key sector in reducing income
Research, 57, 513–524. inequality? An empirical investigation for Turkey. Asia Pacific Journal of Tourism
Njoya, E. T., & Seetaram, N. (2018b). Tourism contribution to poverty alleviation in Research, 24, 822–838.
Kenya: A dynamic computable general equilibrium analysis. Journal of Travel Vanegas, M. (2014). The triangle of poverty, economic growth, and inequality in Central
Research, 57, 513–524. America: Does tourism matter? Worldwide Hospitality and Tourism Themes, 6,
Oviedo-García, M.Á., González-Rodríguez, M. R., & Vega-Vázquez, M. (2018). Does sun- 277–292.
and-sea all-inclusive tourism contribute to poverty alleviation and/or income Wattanakuljarus, A., & Coxhead, I. (2008). Is tourism-based development good for the
inequality reduction? The case of the Dominican Republic. Journal of Travel poor? Journal of Policy Modeling, 30, 929–955.
Research, 58, 995–1013. Webber, A. G. (2001). Exchange rate volatility and cointegration in tourism demand.
Pareliussen, J. K., Hermansen, M., Andre, C., & Causa, O. (2018). Income inequality in Journal of Travel Research, 39, 398–405.
the Nordics from an OECD perspective. Nordic Economic Policy Review, 17–57. Yang, Y., Fik, T. J., & Altschuler, B. (2018). Explaining regional economic multipliers of
Pratt, S. (2011). Economic linkages and impacts across the TALC. Annals of Tourism tourism: Does cross-regional heterogeneity exist? Asia Pacific Journal of Tourism
Research, 38, 630–650. Research, 23, 15–23.
Rickman, D. S. (2010). Modern macroeconomics and regional economic modeling. Yang, Y., Zhang, H., & Chen, X. (2020). Coronavirus pandemic and tourism: Dynamic
Journal of Regional Science, 50, 23–41. stochastic general equilibrium modeling of infectious disease outbreak. Annals of
Saayman, M., Rossouw, R., & Krugell, W. (2012). The impact of tourism on poverty in Tourism Research. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.annals.2020.102913
South Africa. Development Southern Africa, 29, 462–487. Zhang, H., & Yang, Y. (2019). Prescribing for the tourism-induced Dutch disease: A DSGE
Seneca, M. (2010). A DSGE model for Iceland. Central Bank of Iceland Working Paper No. analysis of subsidy policies. Tourism Economics, 25, 942–963.
50. Zhang, J. (2021). The effects of tourism on income inequality: A meta-analysis of
Shahbaz, M., Solarin, S. A., Azam, M., & Tiwari, A. K. (2019). Tourism-induced income econometrics studies. Journal of Hospitality and Tourism Management, 48, 312–321.
distribution in Malaysia: A practical experience of a truly Asian economy. Current Zhao, L., & Xia, X. (2019). Tourism and poverty reduction: Empirical evidence from
Issues in Tourism, 1–20. China. Tourism Economics, 26, 233–256.
Song, H., Kim, J. H., & Yang, S. (2010). Confidence intervals for tourism demand
elasticity. Annals of Tourism Research, 37, 377–396.
Dr. Hongru Zhang is associate professor in School of Liberal Arts at Macau University of
Sun, X., & Tsang, K. P. (2017). What drives the owner-occupied and rental housing
Science and Technology. His research interests include tourism economics, and macro-
markets? Evidence from an estimated DSGE model. Journal of Money, Credit and
economic modeling.
Banking, 49, 443–468.
Torraleja, F.-A. G., Vázquez, A. M., & Franco, M. J. B. (2009). Flows into tourist areas: An
econometric approach. International Journal of Tourism Research, 11, 1–15. Dr. Yang Yang is associate professor in Department of Tourism and Hospitality Man­
agement at Temple University. His research focuses on tourism analytics.

13

You might also like