Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Electoral Studies
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud

Decentralization and democratic participation: The effect of subnational T


self-rule on voting in Latin America and the Caribbean
Alissandra T. Stoyanb,∗, Sara Niedzwieckia
a
Politics Department, University of California, Santa Cruz, USA
b
Department of Political Science, Kansas State University, 802 Mid Campus Dr. South, 101D Calvin Hall, Manhattan, KS 66506, USA

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: Previous literature on the consequences of decentralization has demonstrated a positive effect on voter parti-
Decentralization cipation in subnational elections. However, does this positive effect also extend to national level elections? This
Regional authority paper evaluates the consequences of decentralization-level political participation. Our approach innovates by
Voter turnout disaggregating decentralization to uncover the specific dimensions that matter for voting participation. We argue
Participation
that self-rule (or the authority that subnational units exercise in their own territory) is closely associated with
Democracy
vertical accountability and positively affects voting participation. Moreover, we find that political dimensions of
Latin America
self-rule matter more than fiscal dimensions. Shared-rule (or the authority that subnational units exercise in the
country as a whole) has no significant effect on participation since it is more closely related to horizontal
accountability. We test our theory in 20 Latin American and Caribbean countries using a hierarchical model with
2010 data at the national and individual-level.

1. Introduction to communicate their preferences more effectively and, in turn, elected


officials should become more accountable. Partly for these reasons,
Voting is one of the essential acts of citizenship and the main me- previous authors have argued that decentralization increases partici-
chanism of representation and accountability of political leaders in a pation at the subnational level (Diamond, 1999; Peterson, 1997;
democracy. High levels of participation promote stability and legiti- Goldfrank, 2007; Vetter, 2002). Taking this relationship as a given, we
macy (Dahl, 1971), while low voter turnout presents serious problems focus here on how territorial structure may affect participation in na-
for democracy, particularly because it is biased against poorer citizens tional elections, a much less studied topic in spite of its relevance.
who, in turn, have less political influence (Lijphart, 1997). Participation The few previous studies that have specifically examined the effect
in national-level elections is of particular relevance because there is of decentralization on national voter turnout argued that there is either
more at stake (Reif and Schmitt, 1980) and levels of turnout tend to be no relationship or a negative relationship (Blais et al., 2011; Meguid,
higher than for any other election (Lijphart, 1997). While the vote as a 2007; Foweraker and Landman, 2002). The present paper builds from
mechanism of representation and accountability rarely functions per- this literature's disagreement and analyzes the relationship with addi-
fectly in practice, in theory, it is the most necessary and central element tional nuance. We focus on the specific dimensions of decentralization
of a functioning democracy. After all, “voters have only one instrument that matter for democratic participation through voting in national
to reach two goals: to select better policies and politicians, and to in- elections. We find that aggregate decentralization positively affects
duce them to behave well while in office” (Manin et al.,1999, 45). As participation in national elections; however, this positive relationship
citizens have more opportunities to engage with politics, they may also masks the fact that not all dimensions of decentralization matter for
be more capable of holding their governments accountable. political participation through voting. We go a step further by un-
Decentralization carried the promise of enhancing democratic par- packing the concept of decentralization to analyze ten dimensions of
ticipation through increased proximity between governments and citi- the territorial distribution of power in an effort to discover the specific
zens. It was heralded as a strategy for deepening democracy and de- elements of decentralization that may influence voting participation. In
mocratic participation in Latin America.1 International organizations doing so, we find that certain dimensions of decentralization clearly
argued that devolving power to subnational levels would allow citizens underlie this aggregate effect, having their own distinct positive and


Corresponding author.
E-mail address: stoyan@ksu.edu (A.T. Stoyan).
1
See Selee (2004) for a summary of this literature.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.electstud.2017.12.001
Received 5 July 2017; Received in revised form 19 November 2017; Accepted 13 December 2017
Available online 21 December 2017
0261-3794/ © 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
A.T. Stoyan, S. Niedzwiecki Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

significant effects on voting participation in national level elections. decentralization on voting mainly because these countries exhibit
Each disaggregated dimension of decentralization measures a dis- marked differences in terms of voter turnout as well as in levels of
tinct component of how regions may exert authority.2 These dimensions decentralization across self-rule and shared-rule dimensions. To assess
can be thought of as indicators of a latent variable, and as such are the latter, aggregate measures of decentralization are insufficient; we
strongly associated with each other. Yet, disaggregating allows us to use an original dataset that shows great variation in levels of decen-
observe and analyze substantial variation across countries that have tralization across countries and time. Overall, while subnational gov-
taken very different paths of reform in each dimension. From the con- ernments in Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico have high levels of authority
cept of federalism, the measure takes the already familiar idea that to decide over policy, institutional design, and taxes, for instance, in
subnational authority consists of different forms of rule: the authority Costa Rica, El Salvador, and Guatemala intermediate levels of govern-
that regions have in their own territory to, for instance, elect their own ment are deconcentrated or not autonomous (Hooghe et al., 2016).
representatives or tax their populations (self-rule) as well as in the Additionally, Latin America is an ideal context in which to test this
country as a whole through participation in national institutions such as relationship because voting has now become a regular, institutionalized
the senate (shared-rule) (Elazar, 1987). practice in the region; yet, while cross-national studies of political
We argue that greater self-rule, which is closely associated with participation in developed countries are numerous, less attention has
vertical accountability, or the ability of citizens to hold their leaders been devoted to developing countries.3
responsible, will increase voter turnout. Shared-rule, conversely, is We begin by reviewing the literature on the effect of decentraliza-
more closely related to horizontal accountability, or the control ex- tion for democracy and voting participation. In this section, we also
ercised by other state agencies including subnational agencies, and hypothesize the specific dimensions of decentralization that matter for
therefore we contend that it may not have a direct effect on citizens' voting participation. Next, we describe our data, particularly the
participation. However, self-rule puts the government closer to people Regional Authority Index and the AmericasBarometer survey. In the
and, by providing them with more points of access, it has the potential empirical section, we discuss the results of the hierarchical models for
to directly affect levels of participation. As the authority of subnational Latin American and Caribbean countries.
governments in their own territory increases, citizens can participate
more in issues they care about such as healthcare, education, and in-
frastructure. This increased civic awareness that comes from the actual 2. Democratic participation and decentralization
or perceived influence that their actions have on decentralized polities
can amplify the feeling that voting matters more generally. It may also 2.1. Democracy and decentralization
create opportunities for enhanced participation across the country and
at other levels of government. Latin America has been increasingly decentralized from the early
Within self-rule, we argue that certain dimensions may be more 1980s to the present. The dual process of democratization and neo-
relevant than others. Political decentralization should have more in- liberal reforms has partly fueled this transformation in the structure of
fluence on voting participation than fiscal decentralization. governance in the region. We understand decentralization as the de-
Specifically, while institutional, policy, and representation authority volution of political, fiscal, and administrative powers to subnational
enhance voter turnout, the authority to tax or to borrow may not di- levels of government (Burki et al., 1999; Montero and Samuels, 2004;
rectly affect democratic participation through voting. This is mainly Eaton, 2004; Falleti, 2005). Political decentralization includes the di-
because political authority over a subnational territory provides more rect election of subnational executives and legislatures. For instance,
direct political accountability to the citizens living within that territory. Brazilian states have high level of political authority in part because
In the case of representation authority, or the authority of subnational governors are directly elected. Fiscal decentralization gives subnational
governments to have an elected executive and/or assembly, it is the units greater authority over taxation, borrowing, and spending deci-
main route for citizens to voice their demands. Similarly, the higher the sion. Until the 1990s, Argentine provinces could finance their deficits
autonomy of a subnational government (institutional depth) and the through borrowing with almost no restrictions, thus providing them
larger the range of policies for which it is responsible (policy scope), the with significant room to maneuver (Hooghe et al., 2016, 201). Finally,
larger the sense of empowerment that citizens have. This increased administrative decentralization gives subnational governments the au-
sense of political relevance will likely increase participation in demo- thority to set goals and implement policies. Departments in Bolivia
cratic politics, particularly through voting (Bandura, 2007; Miller and enjoy high levels of administrative authority since 2009, given that they
Miller, 1975). have exclusive competences over economic development, tourism, job
On the other hand, the authority to tax and borrow may not directly promotion, and public health, among others. However, these autho-
affect political participation through voting. At the individual level, rities are exclusively concerned with actions of subnational govern-
different fiscal arrangements could provide a basis for comparison and ments in their own territory. We also incorporate a dimension of de-
competition; citizens may “vote with their feet” and move to areas with centralization that is related to the authority that subnational
more advantageous fiscal arrangements (Tiebout, 1956; Litvack et al., governments exercise in the country as a whole, also along the lines of
1998, 27). Yet, this mechanism of accountability is distinct from ac- fiscal, administrative, and political dimensions. For instance, can pro-
tively participating in democratic politics. vinces decide on constitutional change or on the amount of national
We analyze the individual-level decision to participate in elections transfers to subnational levels of governments? This authority can be
for 20 Latin American and Caribbean countries using a hierarchical exercised in a territorially-representative Senate or in meetings with the
model at a single time point (2010). Data from the Latin American national executive (Niedzwiecki et al., 2016).
Public Opinion Project (LAPOP) allows us to include a number of in- Previous research has mostly focused on the effect of decentraliza-
dividual-level controls that are important in driving turnout. Latin tion for local democracy, including both positive as well as negative
America is a particularly relevant context for analyzing the effect of outcomes for its development (e.g: Goldfrank, 2007; Bardhan and
Mookherjee, 2006). In particular, while some argue that decentraliza-
tion promotes participation through enhancing political engagement,
2
We treat “regional authority” and “decentralization” as synonymous, though they are knowledge, and sense of community4; others offer reservations to the
not strictly equal. The term decentralization assumes that authority is devolved from the
central government to lower territorial levels of government and government within
3
countries is conceived in unidimensional terms. Conversely, the term regional authority For exceptions, see: Fornos et al. (2004); Kostadinova and Power (2007); Pérez-Liñán
allows for the possibility that increased authority follows a bottom-up logic and includes (2001).
4
the region as the unit of analysis (Hooghe et al., 2016). See Spina (2014, 451) for a summary of these three perspectives.

27
A.T. Stoyan, S. Niedzwiecki Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

celebratory schools of decentralization arguing that it opens up op- While self-rule actually empowers citizens, thus increasing their
portunities for clientelism, corruption, and even subnational author- levels of participation, shared-rule should not have any effect on voting
itarian enclaves (Gibson, 2004, 7–8, 2012; Diamond, 1999, 159; behavior. In regions with higher self-rule, citizens are able to vote for
Giraudy, 2014; Gervasoni, 2010). The focus on the effect of decen- autonomous subnational representatives who can define their own
tralization on subnational arenas is understandable given that decen- policies, borrow, and tax their populations. This is the traditional way
tralization initially intended to deepen subnational democracy. How- in which we think about decentralization. Self-rule positions the gov-
ever, we believe that there is value in observing the effect of ernment closer to people, by providing them with more points of access
decentralization on national elections, a topic that has received very to government, thus potentially making their leaders at multiple levels
little attention. This is surprising given that there is typically more at more accountable. As the authority of subnational governments in their
stake in national elections (considered as “first order”) than in elections own territory increases, citizens can participate more in issues they care
for other territorial levels (Reif and Schmitt, 1980). Partly as a result of about such as healthcare, education, and infrastructure. This increased
this, turnout tends to be higher in national compared to regional elec- civic awareness that comes from the actual or perceived influence that
tions (Lijphart, 1997). In addition, focusing on national level elections their actions have on decentralized polities can amplify the feeling that
avoids observing endogenous processes: while it would be plausible to voting matters and create opportunities for enhanced participation
argue that local turnout could increase the pressures for decentraliza- across the country (Diamond, 1999; Peterson, 1997; Goldfrank, 2007;
tion, that is not a likely argument when analyzing national level voting Vetter, 2002). In this way, self-rule increases voters' feeling that their
participation. Therefore, a major contribution of this analysis is the vote actually matters for the future of the polity, not only in subnational
opportunity to depart from potentially endogenous processes in the elections but also at the national level. As self-rule reduces the ratio of
study of decentralization. In particular, we are interested in the ways in citizens to representatives, subnational arenas could serve as the
which the formal authority of subnational units matters for the func- training ground for citizens, a place where voters learn that their par-
tioning of democracy. Constitutional features “… spell out the attri- ticipation can actually matter for governance outcomes (Hajnal and
butions of authority, the limitations of power, the policy scope of dif- Lewis, 2003, 646). This perception, in turn, has a direct effect on the
ferent governmental bodies and levels of government, etc. They express level of political participation, including voter turnout in national
a presumptive division of power between actors and institutions at dif- elections (Bandura, 2007; Miller and Miller 1975, 406–7; Pattie and
ferent points in the federal system” (Gibson, 2004, 8). Indeed, we focus Johnston, 1998). In other words, self-rule can enhance vertical ac-
on the legal characteristics of the division of authority between the countability, or the ability of citizens to hold their leaders responsible
central and subnational governments to unpack its effect on the func- for policymaking and effectiveness in office. As a consequence, it po-
tioning of democracy.5 tentially enhances the sense of relevance of their vote and thus pro-
Previous studies examining how decentralization affects national motes political participation and democracy more broadly.
voter turnout have found either no relationship or a negative relationship Shared-rule allows subnational governments to co-determine deci-
between these two variables (Blais et al., 2011; Meguid, 2007; Foweraker sions at the national level through parliaments or executive meetings.
and Landman, 2002; Spina, 2014; Nikolenyi, 2010). In particular, This dimension does not significantly affect voting at the national level
Nikolenyi (2010) finds that decoupling regional and national elections (a because it is more related to horizontal, rather than vertical, account-
measure of decentralization) depresses turnout in India. Along similar ability (O'Donnell, 1998). It affects elected politicians more than in-
lines, Blais et al. (2011) argue that there is a trade-off between national- dividual voters and should not factor into the calculus of voters with
level and regional-level participation in decentralized countries. For the respect to turning out to vote.
case of Canada, the authors find that there is a small reduction in na-
H1a. Self-rule and voting should have a positive relationship; citizens of
tional electoral turnout as central governments lose importance. In
countries with more self-rule should be more likely to vote in national
contrast, Spina (2014) finds that the effect of decentralization on parti-
elections.
cipation in national level elections in Europe is insignificant. Given the
disagreement in the literature, we do not have a strong expectation re- H1b. Shared-rule and voting should have no significant relationship;
garding the effect of aggregate measures of decentralization on voter citizens of countries with more shared-rule should be equally likely to
turnout. In our analysis of Latin America, we find that although ag- vote in national elections.
gregate levels of decentralization are positive and significant, they mask
Within self-rule we argue that institutional, policy, and electoral
the fact that not all dimensions of decentralization matter for political
dimensions matter for voting participation, while fiscal dimensions
participation. Therefore, we argue for the use of more nuanced measures
(taxing and borrowing authority) may not. The idea that dimensions
of this concept to get at the actual effect of decentralization on voting.
related to political authority are driving the effect of shared-rule on
In order to study the effect of decentralization on voter turnout,
voting participation is supported by previous studies. Brancati (2008)
aggregate measures of decentralization are insufficient. It is paramount
finds that while political decentralization increases the strength of
to unpack the concept of decentralization into its different dimensions.
European regional parties in national legislatures, the effect of fiscal
This is because decentralization in Latin American unfolded through a
decentralization is insignificant. Political decentralization, according to
variety of distinct mechanisms of empowering subnational units.
Brancati, encourages voters to vote for regional parties in part because
Looking only at aggregate decentralization ignores this variety, and
of their potential influence in national politics.6 Litvack et al. (1998)
fails to capture meaningful reforms that may enhance participation in
also find that high levels of political authority have been conducive to
national level elections. Through this approach, we build on recent
developing accountability in the form of participatory budgeting in
work in OECD countries that finds specific or differentiated effects of
Brazil and Mexico, where citizens are invited to discuss budgetary
self-rule and shared rule on corruption (Neudorfer and Neudorfer,
priorities at the different levels of government. We test these expecta-
2014), protest (Quaranta, 2013), subnational representation in the
tions by disaggregating self-rule into three dimensions of political de-
European Union (Donas and Beyers, 2013), and subnational coalition
centralization related to governance: institutional depth, policy scope,
formation (Bäck et al., 2013).
and representation. These are expected to have a direct effect on voting
participation. On the one hand, institutional (or devolution) and policy
5
The Regional Authority Index measures formal authority (formal legislation and authority can facilitate direct participation of voters, interested in
routinized application of law) but not the range of informal conditions—party political
structures, clientelism, the effect of individual leaders – that can affect the functioning of
6
democracy. This distinction is useful given that we wish to evaluate the effect of con- To our knowledge, there is no available data on the existence of regional parties in all
stitutional and legal structures on voter turnout. the countries included in this study.

28
A.T. Stoyan, S. Niedzwiecki Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

ensuring that national policies respond to local needs. On the other democracies or less developed contexts, is questionable.8 Mechanisms
hand, the representation dimension (or whether subnational executives like automatic registration and compulsory voting were once con-
and assemblies are elected) carries the most straightforward connection sidered the key institutional components driving participation (Powell,
between decentralization and voting participation. The incorporation of 1980; Jackman, 1987). Such institutions may help solve the gap in
subnational elections is a fundamental tool for legitimizing the re- voter turnout between social groups, if turnout becomes nearly uni-
levance of the act of voting and thus strengthening subnational de- versal (Lijphart, 1997; Gallego, 2010). Yet, even where these laws exist,
mocracy and for enhancing voting participation at all levels of gov- very few countries effectively enforce participation.9 It is unclear what
ernment. In other words, the practice of voting for subnational type of penalty is sufficient to induce voting (Blais, 2006). In practice,
executives and legislators generates positive feedback effects that en- compulsory voting laws may be less consequential for participation
courages voting at the national level also. than they seem, particularly in less established democracies and parti-
cularly in terms of political participation and engagement more broadly
H2a. Institutional depth and voting should have a positive relationship;
(Carreras, 2016; Norris, 2004; Maldonado, 2011).
citizens living in countries with greater institutional depth at the
Along the lines of institutional factors, concurrent elections national
subnational level should be more likely to vote in national elections.
executive-legislative and/or national-subnational (Norris, 2004;
H2b. Policy scope and voting should have a positive relationship; Nikolenyi, 2010) may increase turnout. For similar reasons, parlia-
citizens living in countries with greater policy scope at the subnational mentary systems typically have higher levels of voter turnout. Uni-
level should be more likely to participate by voting in national elections. cameral systems typically increase voter turnout because legislative
elections in such systems are perceived as more decisive and efficient
H2c. Representation and voting should have a positive relationship;
(Jackman, 1987). Additionally, empirical studies of voting participation
citizens living in countries with greater representation at the
have also identified a positive link with the proportionality of the
subnational level should be more likely to participate by voting in
voting system (Geys, 2006).10
national elections.
Though it is often overlooked, the national economic context may
Conversely, we argue that fiscal dimensions do not directly shape
affect voter turnout. In general, economically developed democracies
the decision to turnout in national elections. They may shape other
have higher levels of turnout than their lesser developed counterparts.
expressions of democracy outside of voting, such as the opportunity of
Likewise, economic downturns may affect voter turnout, but previous
voters to “vote with their feet” and move to areas with more beneficial
studies have generally failed to find conclusive results on this point
fiscal arrangements (Litvack et al., 1998, 27; Tiebout, 1956). In addi-
(Blais and Dobrzynska, 1998; Blais, 2006). We include real GDP per
tion, fiscal decentralization could promote the improvement of public
capita as a control.11
services provided by subnational levels of government; because if citi-
Additionally, individual-level factors also affect voting participa-
zens pay taxes for the provision of these services, then they will be more
tion.12 Resource-based models of voter turnout stress that voters need
likely to participate in monitoring their implementation. However, this
the time, money, and skills in order to vote (Smets and van Ham, 2013,
form of accountability is not expected to have a direct effect on parti-
348). Hence, sociodemographic factors, such as education and wealth
cipation in national elections. In general, the direct link between fiscal
are likely to increase voter turnout both in developed and in developing
dimensions of decentralization and voting participation is much less
countries (Lijphart, 1997; Blais, 2000; Smets and van Ham, 2013). The
clear than with political dimensions.
costs associated with voting are much less consequential for wealthy
individuals. Likewise, education gives voters the necessary skills to
2.2. Voting participation register and properly cast a vote. It also may convince them of the
importance of participation through voting. In general, older in-
Our dependent variable is a self-reported measure of whether in- dividuals are more inclined toward voting participation (Blais, 2000),
dividuals have turned out to vote in the previous national-level elections. but some studies also find a curvilinear effect of age. That is, partici-
In addition to decentralization, a number of sociodemographic, beha- pation in elections declines again as people become elderly, finding it
vioral, economic, and institutional factors may also affect this indicator more difficult to vote (Smets and van Ham, 2013). The degree of ur-
of voting participation. While some authors have focused purely on vo- banization may also condition voting participation (Lehoucq and Wall,
ters' cost-benefit strategic calculations, more recent work acknowledges 2004; Fornos et al., 2004; Power and Roberts, 1995). Notably, turnout
that the decision to vote may be conditional and dependent on the social is typically higher in rural areas because these communities tend to
context and networks within which voters are embedded (Rolfe, 2012). have a greater degree of civic associational life, stronger social ties, and
First, various political factors at the national level may affect voting higher levels of trust in politicians and fellow citizens (Carreras and
participation. Some elections are considered to be more decisive than Bowler, 2017; Geys, 2006; Smets and van Ham, 2013).
others, and turnout tends to increase with political competition or Finally, models of turnout focusing on mobilization and
electoral "closeness" (Blais, 2000, 2006; Lehoucq and Wall, 2004). Thus,
more democratic contexts should increase voter turnout, and we in-
8
clude the Unified Democracy Score (Melton et al., 2014) to account for See Blais (2006) and Smets and van Ham (2013).
9
Measures of enforcement are contradictory among sources (e.g.: IDEA (2017), Birch
this. However, the literature on the effect of party competition on voter
(2008)), reflecting the difficulty of measuring actual implementation. Non-voters may
turnout presents conflicting findings. Some have claimed that there is a escape penalties through loopholes or the enforced penalty itself may be weak or unequal
negative association between the number of parties and turnout (Blais across all sectors of society. In a cross-national study, Blais (2006) acknowledges that we
and Dobrzynska, 1998; Jackman, 1987), implying that fractionalization know very little about how compulsory voting laws are enforced in individual cases. He
suppresses turnout, but this finding does not seem to hold in Latin opts for a dichotomous, de jure measure. We make the same decision in this paper, by
using a measure of compulsory voting law from IDEA (2017).
America (Pérez-Liñán, 2001; Fornos et al., 2004).7 10
To measure proportionality, we employ a dichotomous measure of the voting system
Institutional factors have been the central focus of the literature on from the Database of Political Institutions, but also use the Gallagher Least Squares Index
voter turnout, the extent to which they matter, particularly in newer as a robustness check in the online appendix. This does not change our main substantive
findings.
11
Population may also affect voter turnout (see Geys, 2006, 642). We do not include
7
We exclude party system nationalization from our analysis because: there is no population size, however, because it is highly collinear with the RAI and its component
agreement in the literature regarding its effect on democratic participation, the publicly parts. Having a larger population puts pressure on the development of a multilevel
available measure has not been updated since 2000 (Jones and Mainwaring 2003; structure that can provide public goods at appropriate population scales (Hooghe and
Stegmueller 2013), and it is highly correlated with the RAI, thus increasing our risk of Marks, 2016).
12
multicollinearity. See Carreras and Castañeda-Angarita (2014).

29
A.T. Stoyan, S. Niedzwiecki Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

socialization acknowledge that certain behavioral factors, like political


interest or civic engagement, may increase voting participation (Smets
and van Ham, 2013). Those who pay greater attention to politics should
also be more informed about elections and candidates, and likely feel
more invested in the outcome. Some authors have claimed that this is
potentially a more proximate explanation for the effect of education on
turnout (Sondheimer and Green, 2010). In addition, people who par-
ticipate more in civic associational life are likely not only to have
broader networks, but also more politically active and engaged net-
works (Putnam, 1993).
We rely upon the LAPOP dataset for individual level control vari-
ables: age and age squared, socio-economic status (SES), education, and
size of town in which respondents live, as well as measures of political
interest and civic engagement.
Fig. 1. Self-rule and voting participation across Latin America and the Caribbean.
3. Data and measurement Source: The AmericasBarometer by LAPOP (2010).

The analysis presented below uses a hierarchical model to analyze taxes and determine spending priorities. This is important because a
national and individual levels variables at a single time point (2010) in given government can show high levels of spending (such as Depart-
20 countries in Latin America and the Caribbean. Table 1 below displays ments in Uruguay), while not having authority over how to spend that
basic summary information about all countries included in this analysis. money. The measurement instrument taps de jure authority, that is,
We make innovative use of existing data by combining two datasets for explicit rules or routinized institutional practices governing the exercise
the first time. Data on decentralization is drawn from the Regional of formal power. It does not measure de facto use of that authority or
Authority Index (RAI) (Hooghe et al., 2016). Public opinion data is drawn exogenous influences, such as the charisma of a political leader or many
from the Americas Barometer from the Latin American Public Opinion factors that can affect the ability of a government to achieve its goals.14
Project (LAPOP). Table A.1 in the online appendix details the descriptive The RAI groups indicators into two dimensions: self-rule and shared-
statistics for all variables employed here and in the online appendix. rule. Self-rule builds on and extends the distinction between fiscal,
administrative, and political decentralization (Montero and Samuels,
3.1. Dependent variable: voting participation 2004; Falleti, 2010). The index includes five variables to measure the
authority that governments enjoy in their own territory: institutional
We measure self-reported voting participation in national elections depth (which distinguishes decentralization from deconcentration),
through a question from LAPOP: whether respondents voted in the last policy scope (measures the breadth of regional policy competencies),
presidential elections (responses: "voted" or "did not vote"). representation (looks at whether the subnational government has a
In general, self-reported voting participation is relatively high regionally elected legislature and executive), fiscal autonomy (the au-
among respondents in Latin America. The y-axis in Fig. 1 shows mean thority to set the base and rate of minor and major taxes) and bor-
levels of voting participation across the countries in our sample. Mean rowing autonomy (the extent to which regional governments can
levels are quite high overall, although there is variation within our borrow; and, if they do, whether they can borrow without prior au-
sample. Countries such as Ecuador and Uruguay have the highest mean thorization and restrictions by central government). At the same time,
levels of voting participation while Colombia and Jamaica have the the index includes the authority of subnational governments to shape
lowest mean levels. Table 1, above, also presents a comparison of self- the rules of the game in the country as a whole. Shared-rule includes
reported turnout within the LAPOP data and aggregate measures of five additional variables across whether the region is related to the
voter turnout from International IDEA (2017). central government bilaterally or multilaterally with other regions.
The unit of analysis is the year and subnational government,15
3.2. The regional authority index in Latin America which is defined as government between the local and the national
levels (such as provinces, departments, or regions) having an average
Our primary independent variable is a country-level indicator of the population greater than 150,000.16 In addition, the index includes re-
extent of decentralization, the Regional Authority Index (RAI).13 This gions with special autonomy, such as capital cities or indigenous ter-
index was developed and widely used for OECD countries (Hooghe ritories in many of these countries. The raw value of each region is
et al., 2010). It is regarded as “the most nuanced and comprehensive weighted by population and then added to construct the country score.
measurement of subnational powers,” which may assist in reducing The regional authority index detects considerable variation across
“the trade-off between detail and generalisability common in large-N countries, with a standard deviation of 7.2, a minimum of 0 in Costa
studies” (Spina, 2014, 449). The index has now been expanded to Latin Rica, Guyana, and Jamaica, and a maximum of 23.5 in Argentina (see
America and Caribbean countries, measuring the degree of subnational Table 1).
authority in the region across ten different dimensions on an annual
basis from 1950 to 2010. 14
Estimating the RAI in Latin America faces a particular challenge: the issue of dis-
While previous research has measured decentralization mostly crepancies between informal and formal authority. The measurement instrument does not
through financial data provided by International Financial Institutions engage the range of informal conditions, such as clientelism or the effect of individual
(Daughters and Harper, 2007; Escobar-Lemmon, 2001), one of the main leaders, because it is conceptually useful to keep these separate (see Hooghe et al. 2016
contributions of this paper is to use a measure that taps into regional and Niedzwiecki et al. 2016).
15
The RAI varies annually.
authority directly. Fiscal data can tell us how much subnational gov- 16
This means that the RAI does not measure decentralization at the local level, thus
ernments collect in taxes or spend, while the RAI informs us about the probably underestimating the score of countries that have skipped the intermediate level
authority that these governments have to set the rate and/or base of and have decentralized towards the local level. That said, the RAI does incorporate local
level variation in units with asymmetric authority, such as capital cities (such as the City
of Buenos Aires or Mexico City), indigenous communities (in Bolivia and Nicaragua, for
13
For a thorough description of the Regional Authority Index see Hooghe et al. (2016) instance), internal colonies (in Brazil and Colombia, for instance), and protected geo-
and Niedzwiecki et al. (2016). graphical territories (such as Galápagos in Ecuador).

30
A.T. Stoyan, S. Niedzwiecki Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

Table 1
Summary information for 20 Latin American and Caribbean countries.

Country Executive Form Federalism RAI Election Year Election Type Aggregate Electoral Turnout

LAPOP IDEA IDEA - VAP

Argentina Presidential Federal 23.50 2009 Legislative 75.23% 72.39% 70.89%


Belize Parliamentary Unitary 0.00 2008 Parliamentary 76.44% 77.18% 76.54%
Bolivia Presidential Unitary 13.55 2009 Concurrent 89.19% 94.55% 85.55%
Brazil Presidential Federal 19.50 2006 Concurrent 83.44% 81.01% 81.32%
Colombia Presidential Unitary 12.29 2006 Concurrent 60.23% 45.11% 44.15%
Costa Rica Presidential Unitary 0.00 2006 Concurrent 58.04% 65.21% 63.96%
Dominican Republic Presidential Unitary 3.67 2008 Presidential 76.13% 71.36% 71.63%
Ecuador Presidential Unitary 8.00 2009 Concurrent 92.70% 75.28% 90.47%
El Salvador Presidential Unitary 1.00 2009 Concurrent 79.34% 61.91% 72.39%
Guatemala Presidential Unitary 1.00 2007 Concurrent 69.00% 48.15% 45.54%
Guyana Parliamentary Unitary 0.00 2006 Parliamentary 71.22% 68.82% 66.44%
Haiti Presidential Unitary 5.50 2006 Concurrent 59.38% 59.26% 47.77%
Honduras Presidential Unitary 1.00 2009 Concurrent 60.92% 49.88% 53.17%
Jamaica Parliamentary Unitary 0.00 2007 Parliamentary 57.20% 60.40% 49.56%
Mexico Presidential Federal 20.03 2006 Concurrent 71.03% 58.55% 63.26%
Nicaragua Presidential Unitary 4.69 2006 Concurrent 69.36% 61.23% 74.16%
Panama Presidential Unitary 2.55 2009 Concurrent 81.83% 68.57% 69.04%
Paraguay Presidential Unitary 8.30 2008 Concurrent 66.85% 60.34% 45.94%
Uruguay Presidential Unitary 12.00 2009 Concurrent 93.46% 89.18% 96.10%
Venezuela Presidential Federal 6.52 2006 Presidential 68.65% 74.69% 76.41%

Note: We calculate aggregate self-reported electoral turnout from LAPOP and report aggregate turnout data for the same election from International IDEA for comparison. IDEA measures
turnout as the total number of votes cast divided by the number of names on the voters' register, expressed as a percentage. In contrast, IDEA-VAP measures Voting Age Population (VAP)
turnout as total number of votes cast divided by census estimates of the voting age population, expressed as a percentage. Discrepancies between these two measures may indicate issues
with voter registration, but voter rolls are also updated more regularly than census data, so this can also explain differences.

4. Findings and analysis We begin our analysis by examining the effect of decentralization on
voting participation in Latin America in general. Model 1 in Table 2
The statistical analysis presented in this section begins very gen- includes the aggregate RAI measure of decentralization alongside a
erally to assess the effect of decentralization on voting participation.17 number of control variables. In this model, the degree of decen-
Ultimately, however, our goal is to move toward an analysis of the tralization exerts positive and significant effect, when controlling for
specific components of decentralization to determine which of these individual characteristics and national-level factors known to affect
exerts a significant influence on voting participation. Given the existent voter turnout. We did not have a strong expectation regarding the effect
disagreement in the literature on the effect of decentralization on of aggregate levels of decentralization on voting, given the existent
voting participation, we do not have a strong expectation about this disagreement in the literature.
aggregate relationship. With that caveat in mind, we find that aggregate We expect that the two distinct dimensions of the RAI operate dif-
measures of decentralization increase national voter turnout. However, ferently with respect to voting participation, so we disaggregate the RAI
we do have theoretical expectations of the effect of particular dimen- measure. In doing so, we find clear evidence of the dynamics under-
sions of decentralization on national voting turnout. In line with our lying the positive result for the aggregate measure. Models 2 and 3
expectations, we find that self-rule determines voting participation examine the individual effects of the self-rule and shared-rule dimen-
more than shared-rule. Lastly, among the specific components of self- sions. Taken together, the results of these two models demonstrate that
rule, those related to political authority – institutional depth, policy self-rule is the more relevant dimension, as we previously anticipated.
scope, and representation – affect voting participation to a greater ex- Self-rule has a positive and significant effect on voting participation
tent than those components related to fiscal authority. Self-rule political because it puts the government closer to people and provides them with
authority puts the government closer to voters and thus provides them more points of access to participation in government. If the self-rule
with a direct avenue for voicing their demands. This takes place in a index were to increase by one, this would lead to a positive difference of
context of (perceived) empowerment given the high level of subna- 2.9% in the probability of voting, holding all other variables constant.
tional institutional, political, and policy autonomy. This effect may appear to be small. Yet, recall that self-rule ranges from
We estimate hierarchical logit models given that our data has a 0 to 14.84 in our sample (see Table A.1 in the online appendix). Thus,
binary outcome variable and survey respondents (level one) are nested an increase of 1 on this index is itself a very small change (e.g. ap-
within countries (level two). While variables from the LAPOP dataset proximately a move from Costa Rica to Haiti). More concretely, a one
are measured at level one, all of our measures of decentralization from standard deviation increase in self-rule would produce a positive dif-
the RAI dataset are level two variables and so are our controls for ference of 15.1% in the probability of voting. This change is roughly
compulsory voting, concurrent elections, proportionality, parlia- equivalent to moving from Paraguay to Brazil. In contrast, shared-rule
mentarism, democracy, and GDP per capita. The hierarchical model has no significant effect on voting participation.
with varying intercepts and varying slopes allows us to formulate ac- Lastly, an even more fine-grained analysis demonstrates that poli-
curate estimates and standard errors that take into account the N at tical dimensions of self-rule effect voting more than fiscal dimensions.
level two. Random coefficients yield better predictions (or slopes) for To unpack this, we disaggregate the self-rule dimension into its five
the level two variable of interest (i.e. decentralization). component parts, running a separate model for each.18 In Table 3
above, Models 4–6 test political components of self-rule. In Table 4

17
The results of all the models presented here are robust to model specification. A set
18
of robustness checks mentioned throughout this manuscript are available in the online We do not include these components in the same model because of high-levels of
appendix. multicollinearity. Most correlate around 0.8 and all correlate above 0.5.

31
A.T. Stoyan, S. Niedzwiecki Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

Table 2
Hierarchical models of voting participation: RAI, self-rule, and shared-rule.

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Fixed Effects Political Interest 0.312 *** 0.312 *** 0.312 ***
(Level 1) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016)
Civic Engagement 0.313 *** 0.313 *** 0.313 ***
(0.031) (0.031) (0.031)
Socioeconomic Status 0.002 0.002 0.002
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
Age 0.207 *** 0.207 *** 0.207 ***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Age2 −0.002 *** −0.002 *** −0.002 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Rural 0.041 *** 0.041 *** 0.041 ***
(0.010) (0.010) (0.010)
Education 0.133 *** 0.133 *** 0.133 ***
(0.011) (0.011) (0.011)
Constant −5.212 *** −5.064 *** −5.665 ***
(0.789) (0.755) (1.120)
Fixed Effects Regional Authority Index 0.094 *
(Level 2) (0.048)
Self-Rule 0.116 **
(0.048)
Shared-Rule 0.299
(0.209)
Compulsory Voting 0.307 0.257 0.694
(0.453) (0.439) (0.473)
GDP per capita 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Proportional −0.357 −0.212 −0.507
(0.355) (0.359) (0.362)
Democracy 0.653 0.625 −0.313
(0.603) (0.599) (0.615)
Parliamentary 0.321 0.275 0.405
(0.657) (0.573) (0.608)
Unicameral 0.695 * 0.497 0.544 *
(0.404) (0.350) (0.321)
Concurrent −0.288 −0.295 0.389
(0.617) (0.571) (0.706)
Random Effects Level 1 Variance 0.251 0.233 0.252
(Standard Deviation) (0.119) (0.109) (0.082)
Level 2 Variance 0.001 0.003 0.197
(Standard Deviation) (0.002) (0.003) (0.100)

Wald Chi2 (Prob > Chi2) 3737.77 (0.000) 3737.33 (0.000) 3744.27 (0.000)
N (n) 20 (32797) 20 (32797) 20 (32797)

Note: ***p ≤ .01; **p ≤ .05; *p ≤ .1; Standard errors in brackets.

below, Models 7 and 8 test fiscal components of self-rule. These models policies (Chilean regiones) to a country where subnational government
allow us to further assess which specific aspects of self-rule – either has authority over either economic, cultural, or welfare policies
those related to political or to fiscal authority – might affect voting (Venezuelan estados).
participation. Model 6 includes a measure of representation or the presence of an
In Model 4, we include a measure of institutional depth. This vari- independent and elected regional legislature and/or executive.
able has a positive and significant effect on voting in our sample. As the Representation has a positive and significant effect on voting partici-
regional government becomes more autonomous, rather than decon- pation. That is, as regions are endowed with an independent legislature
centrated, citizens are more likely to participate through voting. More and executive, voting participation tends to increase on average in our
precisely, a one-unit increase in institutional depth leads to a positive sample. For a one-unit increase in representation, there is a 7.9% in-
difference of 17.1% in the probability of voting, holding all other crease in the probability of voting, holding all other variables constant.
variables constant. For example, this is roughly equivalent to moving One unit increase means, for instance, the difference between having no
from a region where the central government can veto subnational de- elected assembly or executive (e.g. Costa Rica) to indirectly elected
cisions to a region where the central government cannot veto. assembly (e.g. Consejos Regionales in Chile).
In Model 5, we include a measure of policy scope, the range of In Table 4, we test fiscal dimensions of self-rule. Model 7 includes a
policies for which regional governments are responsible. Policy scope measure of fiscal autonomy, or the extent to which regional govern-
has a positive and significant effect on voting. As the regional govern- ments can independently tax their population, while Model 8 includes
ment's responsibility extends to a broader range of policies, voting borrowing autonomy, or the extent to which regional governments can
participation tends to increase. Specifically, holding all other variables borrow. Neither of these fiscal dimensions of self-rule have a statisti-
constant, a one-unit increase in policy scope leads to an increase of 10% cally significant effect on voting.
in the probability of voting. For instance, this change reflects the dif- Taken as a whole, the models in Tables 3 and 4 indicate that com-
ference between a country with very weak subnational competencies on ponents of self-rule related to political governance have a significant

32
A.T. Stoyan, S. Niedzwiecki Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

Table 3
Hierarchical models of voting participation: Political components of self-rule.

Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

Fixed Effects Political Interest 0.312 *** 0.312 *** 0.312 ***
(Level 1) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016)
Civic Engagement 0.313 *** 0.313 *** 0.313 ***
(0.031) (0.031) (0.031)
Socioeconomic Status 0.002 0.002 0.002
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
Age 0.207 *** 0.207 *** 0.207 ***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Age2 −0.002 *** −0.002 *** −0.002 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Rural 0.040 *** 0.040 *** 0.040 ***
(0.010) (0.010) (0.010)
Education 0.133 *** 0.133 *** 0.133 ***
(0.011) (0.011) (0.011)
Constant −4.765 *** −2.21 *** −2.534 ***
(0.756) (0.718) (0.646)
Fixed Effects Institutional Depth 0.682 ***
(Level 2) (0.223)
Policy Scope 0.407 *
(0.222)
Representation 0.316 ***
(0.119)
Compulsory Voting 0.010 −0.015 0.387
(0.160) (0.403) (0.363)
GDP per capita 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Proportional −0.215 −0.313 −0.135
(0.369) (0.324) (0.354)
Democracy 0.837 *** 0.728 0.616
(0.260) (0.478) (0.541)
Parliamentary 0.417 0.086 0.292
(0.543) (0.551) (0.531)
Unicameral 0.413 0.686 ** 0.479
(0.190) (0.279) (0.302)
Concurrent −0.284 −0.503 −0.225
(0.294) (0.550) (0.519)
Random Effects Level 1 Variance 0.247 0.209 0.226
(Standard Deviation) (0.088) (0.070) (0.094)
Random Effects Level 2 Variance 0.103 0.176 0.021
(Standard Deviation) (0.064) (0.072) (0.021)

Wald Chi2 (Prob > Chi2) 3747.92 (0.000) 3733.25 (0.000) 3737.31 (0.000)
N (n) 20 (32797) 20 (32797) 20 (32797)

Note: ***p ≤ .01; **p ≤ .05; *p ≤ .1; Standard errors in brackets.

and positive effect on voting participation. These components are 5. Conclusion


driving the positive association of self-rule and, in turn, of aggregate
decentralization. We hypothesized in the theory section that the poli- Democracy requires government accountability and responsiveness,
tical components of self-rule matter for voting participation because both of which rely in large part on citizens' ability and willingness to
subnational elections strengthen the perception that voting matters and participate in the political system. Robert A. Dahl (1971) recognized
thus enhance voting participation at all levels of government. In addi- two fundamental dimensions of democracy: contestation and partici-
tion, institutional and policy authority enhances participation in elec- pation. The latter may take many forms, including either formal par-
tions because voters may want to make sure that national policies re- ticipation (e.g. voting in elections) or informal participation (e.g. pro-
spond to local needs. testing). The idea of free and fair elections still lies at the core of our
Finally, in all models presented above, we find that the effects of understanding of democracy because elections are often the primary
control variables, particularly at the individual level, are relatively formal mechanism of accountability and allow citizens to express their
strong and consistent with previous findings. As expected, we find a preferences to elected representatives at routine, regular intervals. It is
curvilinear effect of age; until it becomes difficult for individuals to get important to understand the factors that influence voting participation
out to vote, older individuals are more likely to vote than younger in- because it is essential to the functioning of democracy.
dividuals. Education, living in rural areas, political interest and parti- This paper advances our understanding of the factors that drive
cipation in civic associational life all have positive effects on voting voting participation in national level elections. It does so by under-
participation. National level control variables are more inconsistent scoring the need to disaggregate decentralization to study voting par-
across models. However, when these factors are significant, they are in ticipation. Incorporating different dimensions of decentralization, en-
line with our expectations; we find that voters are more likely to riches our understanding because decentralization in Latin American
turnout in countries with unicameral legislatures and higher levels of unfolded through a variety of distinct mechanisms, and looking only at
democracy. aggregate decentralization fails to capture meaningful reforms.
We use a nuanced measure of decentralization –the Regional
Authority Index—to capture the underlying dynamics that matter for

33
A.T. Stoyan, S. Niedzwiecki Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

Table 4 also enhance the key mechanism of government accountability and re-
Hierarchical models of voting participation: Fiscal components of self-rule. sponsiveness at the national level. In other words, regional processes may
generate effects on political behavior at the national level as well.
Model 7 Model 8
Moreover, the substantive size of the effects of decentralization on the
Fixed Effects Political Interest 0.312 *** 0.312 *** probability of voting are not trivial. Living in a context with one standard
(Level 1) (0.016) (0.016) deviation more political decentralization - in terms of self-rule, institu-
Civic Engagement 0.313 *** 0.313 ***
tional depth, policy scope, or representation - has arguably more of a
(0.031) (0.031)
Socioeconomic Status 0.002 0.002 substantive impact on voting participation than a one standard deviation
(0.003) (0.003) increase in civic associational life or years of education.
Age 0.207 *** 0.207 *** Another contribution of the present analysis is our combination of
(0.001) (0.001) micro-level and macro-level predictors of political behavior into a
Age2 −0.002 *** −0.002 ***
single model. Aggregate trends in political participation are explained
(0.000) (0.000)
Rural 0.041 *** 0.041 *** by a conscious decision that citizens make about whether or not to
(0.010) (0.010) turnout to vote on election day. A variety of influences affects each
Education 0.133 *** 0.133 *** person's decision-making calculus, including individual socio-demo-
(0.011) (0.011)
graphic and behavioral factors, as well as other national-level economic
Constant −5.162 *** −5.196 ***
(0.930) (0.848) and institutional factors. However, even controlling for these influ-
Fixed Effects Fiscal Autonomy −0.045 ences, we find that self-rule persists in positively influencing voting
(Level 2) (0.233) participation. Devolving power to the subnational level brings the
Borrowing Autonomy 0.523 government closer to the people and allows citizens to view more
(0.442)
clearly the impact of their vote. Overall, our analysis demonstrates that
Compulsory Voting 0.534 0.717
(0.524) (0.451) these dynamics lie at the heart of decentralization's effect on voter
GDP per capita 0.000 0.000 turnout and, ultimately, democratic participation.
(0.000) (0.000) Voters in places with a higher degree of self-rule may feel that their
Proportional −0.339 −0.243
vote matters more. In general, higher levels of self-rule correlate sig-
(0.410) (0.404)
Democracy 0.178 0.373
nificantly with higher perceived importance of voting.19 For example,
(0.658) (0.643) in the highly decentralized country of Argentina, more than 70% of
Parliamentary −0.190 0.407 respondents considered that “the way you vote can change the way
(0.689) (0.604) things will be in the future.” In contrast, in highly centralized Costa
Unicameral 0.009 0.397
Rica, a majority of the population considered that “no matter how you
(0.376) (0.344)
Concurrent 0.291 −0.238 vote, things will not improve in the future.” A possible implication of
(0.633) (0.577) this finding is that as citizens are more involved in politics, their gov-
Random Level 1 Variance 0.420 0.314 ernments are more subject to accountability.
Effects (Standard Deviation) (0.134) (0.105)
Yet, this data is preliminary and incomplete; future research should
Level 2 Variance 0.000 0.345
(Standard Deviation) (0.000) (0.125)
focus on uncovering the micro-level mechanism at work behind the
trends elucidated here. More generally, there is a need for research that
Wald Chi2 3735.04 (0.000) 3750.55 (0.000) evaluates the effect of disaggregated dimensions of decentralization on
(Prob > Chi2) other governance outcomes, both at the national and subnational levels,
N (n) 20 (32797) 20 (32797)
such as fiscal capacity and transparency. Finally, another limitation of
Note: ***p ≤ .01; **p ≤ .05; *p ≤ .1; Standard errors in brackets. this paper is that the Regional Authority Index only takes into account
formal rules. In this way, it cannot inform our understanding of in-
formal practices, such as, clientelism, corruption, patronage politics,
explaining national voting. The combination of a relatively new dataset, political coalitions, and illicit non-state actors. Future research that
the Regional Authority Index, with one of the best sources of public develops systematic measures of these concepts should analyze their
opinion data in the region allows us to reevaluate a long-standing dis- relationship with national voting participation.
puted finding in the literature. The present analysis focused on Latin
American and Caribbean countries, which remain relatively under-
Funding
studied with respect to the effects of decentralization and political be-
havior. However, the experience of countries within this region has
This research did not receive any specific grant from funding
implications for other established democratic regimes and transitional
agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.
democracies as well.
We find that increased regional authority through self-rule posi-
tively affects voting participation in Latin America, and the political Acknowledgements
dimensions of self-rule primarily drive this relationship. In showing the
specific dimensions of decentralization that matter for increasing voting We thank the Latin American Public Opinion Project (LAPOP) and
participation, a main contribution of the present analysis is to demon- its major supporters (the United States Agency for International
strate that aggregate measures of decentralization are insufficient. We Development, the Inter-American Development Bank, and Vanderbilt
unpack decentralization by illustrating how devolving institutional, University) for making the AmericasBarometer data available. The
policy, and representation authority to subnational levels may increase authors would also like to acknowledge the research assistance of
voter turnout. By increasing citizens' sense that their vote matters, self- Nicole Gayer and excellent comments from Mariana Borges, Miguel
rule may increase political participation at all levels of government, Carreras, Wendy Hansen, Liesbet Hooghe, Gary Marks, Eduardo
including voting in national-level elections. Moncada, Jana Morgan, Heidi Smith, and the anonymous reviewers.
Overall, individuals living in countries with higher levels of authority,
particularly political authority, in their own territory are more likely to 19
See Table A.5 and Figure A.2 in the supplemental analysis in the online appendix.
turnout to vote. Thus, a key contribution of our analysis is the idea that, Unfortunately, this indicator is not available from LAPOP in 2010, so we rely on data
while decentralization devolves authority to subnational regions, it may from 2003.

34
A.T. Stoyan, S. Niedzwiecki Electoral Studies 52 (2018) 26–35

Appendix A. Supplementary data Postfunctionalist Theory of Governance. Volume II. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
International IDEA, 2017. Compulsory Voting. https://www.idea.int/data-tools/data/
voter-turnout/compulsory-voting, Accessed date: 19 October 2017.
Supplementary data related to this article can be found at http://dx. Jackman, R.M., 1987. Political institutions and voter turnout in industrial democracies.
doi.org/10.1016/j.electstud.2017.12.001. Am. Polit. Sci. Assoc. 81, 405–424.
Jones, M.P., Mainwaring, S., 2003. The nationalization of parties and party systems: an
empirical measure and an application to the Americas. Party Polit. 9 (2), 139–166.
References Kostadinova, T., Power, T.J., 2007. Does democratization depress participation? Voter
turnout in the Latin American and Eastern European transitional democracies. Polit.
Bäck, H., Debus, M., Müller, J., Bäck, H., 2013. Regional government formation in Res. Q. 60 (3), 363–377.
varying multilevel contexts: a comparison of eight European countries. Reg. Stud. 47 The AmericasBarometer by the Latin American Public Opinion Project (LAPOP), 2010.
(3), 368–387. www.LapopSurveys.org.
Bandura, A., 2007. Self-efficacy: the Exercise of Control. W.H. Freeman, Princeton, N.J. Lehoucq, F., Wall, D.L., 2004. Explaining voter turnout rates in new democracies:
Bardhan, P., Mookherjee, D. (Eds.), 2006. Decentralization and Local Governance in Guatemala. Elect. Stud. 23 (3), 485–500.
Developing Countries: a Comparative Perspective. Massachusetts Institute of Lijphart, A., 1997. Unequal participation: democracy's unresolved dilemma. Am. Polit.
Technology, Cambridge, MA. Sci. Rev. 91 (1), 1–14.
Birch, S., 2008. Full Participation: a Comparative Study of Compulsory Voting. Litvack, J.I., Ahmad, J., Bird, R.M., 1998. Rethinking Decentralization in Developing
Manchester University Press, Oxford. Countries. World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Blais, A., 2000. To Vote or Not to Vote? the Merits and Limits of Rational Choice Theory. Maldonado, A., 2011. Compulsory voting and the decision to vote. Am. Barom. Insights
University of Pittsburgh Press, Pittsburgh, PA. 63, 1–9.
Blais, A., 2006. What affects voter turnout? Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 9 (1), 111–125. Manin, B., Przeworski, A., Stokes, S.C., 1999. Elections and representation. In:
Blais, A., Dobrzynska, A., 1998. Turnout in electoral democracies. Eur. J. Polit. Res. 33 Przeworski, A., Stokes, S.C., Manin, B. (Eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and
(2), 239–261. Representation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Blais, A., Anduiza, E., Gallego, A., 2011. Decentralization and voter turnout. Environ. Meguid, B.M., 2007. Bringing government back to the people? the impact of political
Plann. C Govern. Pol. 29 (2), 297–320. decentralization on voter engagement in Western Europe. For presentation at the
Brancati, D., 2008. The origins and strengths of regional parties. Br. J. Polit. Sci. 38 (01). 19th Biennial Meeting of the European Union Studies Association, Montreal, Canada
Burki, S., Perry, G., Dillinger, W., 1999. Beyond the center. Decentralizing the State. May 2007.
World Bank, Washington D.C. Melton, J., Meserve, S., Pemstein, D., 2014. Unified Democracy Score. http://www.
Carreras, M., 2016. Compulsory voting and political engagement (beyond the ballot box): unified-democracy-scores.org, Accessed date: 10 November 2017.
a multilevel analysis. Elect. Stud. 43 (Sept 2016), 158–168. Miller, A.H., Miller, W.E., 1975. Issues, candidates and partisan divisions in the 1972
Carreras, M., Bowler, S., 2017. Social capital and the geography of political participation American presidential election. Br. J. Polit. Sci. 5 (4), 393–434.
in Latin America. In: For Presentation at the Latin American Studies Association Montero, A.P., Samuels, D. (Eds.), 2004. Decentralization and Democracy in Latin
International Congress, Lima, Peru, April 2017. America. University of Notre Dame Press, South Bend, IN.
Carreras, M., Castañeda-Angarita, N., 2014. Who votes in Latin America? A test of three Neudorfer, B., Neudorfer, N.S., 2014. Decentralization and political corruption: dis-
theoretical perspectives. Comp. Polit. Stud. 47 (8), 1079–1104. aggregating regional authority. Publius 45 (1), 24–50.
Dahl, R.A., 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. Yale University Press, New Niedzwiecki, S., Chapman Osterkatz, S., Marks, G., Hooghe, L., 2016. The RAI travels to
Haven, CT. Latin America. measuring regional authority under regime change. In: For pre-
Daughters, R., Harper, L., 2007. Fiscal and political decentralization reforms. In: Lora, E. sentation at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association;
(Ed.), The State of State Reform in Latin America. Stanford University Press, Philadelphia, PA, August 2016.
Stanford, CA. Nikolenyi, C., 2010. Concurrent elections and voter turnout: the effect of the de-linking of
Diamond, L.J., 1999. Developing Democracy: toward Consolidation. The Johns Hopkins state elections on electoral participation in India's parliamentary polls, 1971-2004.
University Press, Baltimore. Polit. Stud. 58 (1), 214–233.
Donas, T., Beyers, J., 2013. How regions assemble in Brussels: the organizational form of Norris, P., 2004. Electoral Engineering: Voting Rules and Political Behavior. Cambridge
territorial representation in the European Union. Publius 43 (4), 527–550. University Press, Cambridge.
Eaton, K., 2004. Politics beyond the Capital: the Design of Subnational Institutions in O'Donnell, G.A., 1998. Horizontal accountability in new democracies. J. Democr. 9 (3),
South America. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA. 112–126.
Elazar, D.J., 1987. Exploring Federalism. University of Alabama Press, Tuscaloosa, AL. Pattie, C., Johnston, R., 1998. Voter turnout at the British general election of 1992: ra-
Escobar-Lemmon, M.C., 2001. Fiscal decentralization and federalism in Latin America. tional choice, social standing or political efficacy? Eur. J. Polit. Res. 33 (2), 263–283.
Publius 31 (4), 23–41. Pérez-Liñán, A., 2001. Neoinstitutional accounts of voter turnout: moving beyond in-
Falleti, T.G., 2010. Decentralization and Subnational Politics in Latin America. Cambridge dustrial democracies. Elect. Stud. 20 (2), 281–297.
University Press, Leiden. Peterson, G.E., 1997. Decentralization in Latin America: Learning through Experience.
Falleti, T.G., 2005. A sequential theory of decentralization: Latin American cases in World Bank Latin American and Caribbean Studies. D.C. World Bank, Washington.
comparative perspective. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 99 (3), 327–346. Powell, B., 1980. Voting participation in thirty democracies: effects of socio economic,
Fornos, C., Power, T.J., Garand, J.C., 2004. Explaining voter turnout in Latin America, legal and partisan environments. In: Rose, R. (Ed.), Electoral Participation: a
1980 to 2000. Comp. Polit. Stud. 37 (8), 909–940. Comparative Perspective. SAGE Publications, London, pp. 5–34.
Foweraker, J., Landman, T., 2002. Constitutional design and democratic performance. Power, T., Roberts, K.M., 1995. Compulsory voting, invalid ballots, and abstention in
Democratization 9 (2), 43–66. Brazil. Polit. Res. Q. 48 (4), 795–826.
Gallego, A., 2010. Understanding unequal turnout: education and voting in comparative Putnam, R.D., 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy.
perspective. Elect. Stud. 29, 239–248. Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J.
Gervasoni, C., 2010. Measuring variance in subnational regimes: results from an expert- Quaranta, M., 2013. The impact of institutional decentralization on protest in Western
based operationalization of democracy in the Argentine provinces. J. Polit. Lat Am. 2 Europe. Int. Polit. Sci. Rev. 34 (5), 502–518.
(2), 13–52. Reif, K., Schmitt, H., 1980. Nine second-order elections. A conceptual framework for the
Geys, B., 2006. Explaining voter turnout: a review of aggregate-level research. Elect. Stud. analysis of European election results. Eur. J. Polit. Res. 8, 3–44.
25, 637–663. Rolfe, M., 2012. Voter Turnout: A Social Theory of Political Participation. Cambridge
Gibson, E.L., 2004. Federalism and democracy: theoretical connections and cautionary University Press, Cambridge, UK. http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/46275/.
insights. In: Gibson, E.L. (Ed.), Federalism and Democracy in Latin America. The John Selee, A., 2004. Exploring the link between decentralization and democratic governance.
Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, pp. 1–28. In: Tulchin, J.S., Selee, A. (Eds.), Decentralization and Democratic Governance in
Gibson, E.L., 2012. Boundary Control: Subnational Authoritarianism in Federal Latin America. Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars Latin American
Democracies. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Program, Washington, D.C, pp. 3–36.
Giraudy, A., 2014. Democrats and Autocrats: Pathways of Subnational Undemocratic Smets, K., van Ham, C., 2013. The embarrassment of riches? A meta-analysis of in-
Regime Continuity within Democratic Countries. Oxford University Press, Oxford. dividual-level research on voter turnout. Elect. Stud. 32 (2), 344–359.
Goldfrank, B., 2007. The politics of deepening local democracy: decentralization, party Sondheimer, R.M., Green, D.P., 2010. Using experiments to estimate the effects of edu-
institutionalization, and participation. Comp. Polit. 39 (1), 147–168. cation on voter turnout. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 54 (1), 174–189.
Hajnal, Z.L., Lewis, P.G., 2003. Municipal institutions and voter turnout in local elections. Spina, N., 2014. Decentralisation and political participation: an empirical analysis in
Urban Aff. Rev. 38 (5), 645–668. Western and Eastern Europe. Int. Polit. Sci. Rev. 35 (4), 448–462.
Hooghe, L., Marks, G., Schakel, A., 2010. The Rise of Regional Authority: a Comparative Stegmueller, D., 2013. How many countries for multilevel modeling? A comparison of
Study of 42 Democracies. Routledge, New York. frequentist and bayesian approaches,. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 57 (3), 748–761.
Hooghe, L., Marks, G., Schakel, A., Niedzwiecki, S., Chapman Osterkatz, S., Shair- Tiebout, C.M., 1956. A pure theory of local expenditures. J. Polit. Econ. 64 (5), 416–424.
Rosenfield, S., 2016. Measuring Regional Authority: a Postfunctionalist Theory of Vetter, A., 2002. Local political competence in Europe: a resource of legitimacy for higher
Governance, vol. I Oxford University Press, Oxford. levels of government? Int. J. Publ. Opin. Res. 14 (1), 3–18.
Hooghe, L., Marks, G., Community, Scale, and Regional Governance, 2016. A

35

You might also like