Equilibrium Unemployment As A Worker Discipline Device

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

Cambridge Books Online

http://ebooks.cambridge.org/

Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market

Edited by George A. Akerlof, Janet L. Yellen

Book DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594

Online ISBN: 9780511559594

Hardback ISBN: 9780521321563

Paperback ISBN: 9780521312844

Chapter

Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device pp. 45-56

Chapter DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004

Cambridge University Press


Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device
By CARL SHAPIRO AND JOSEPH E. STIGLITZ*

Involuntary unemployment appears to be an individual will not immediately obtain


a persistent feature of many modern labor another job. The equilibrium unemployment
markets. The presence of such unemploy- rate must be sufficiently large that it pays
ment raises the question of why wages do not workers to work rather than to take the risk
fall to clear labor markets. In this paper we of being caught shirking.
show how the information structure of em- The idea that the threat of firing a worker
ployer-employee relationships, in particular is a method of discipline is not novel. Guil-
the inability of employers to costlessly ob- lermo Calvo (1981) studied a static model
serve workers' on-the-job effort, can explain which involves equilibrium unemployment.2
involuntary unemployment1 as an equi- No previous studies have treated general
librium phenomenon. Indeed, we show that market equilibrium with dynamics, however,
imperfect monitoring necessitates unemploy- or studied the welfare properties of such
ment in equilibrium. unemployment equilibria. One key contribu-
The intuition behind our result is simple. tion of this paper is that the punishment
Under the conventional competitive para- associated with being fired is endogenous, as
digm, in which all workers receive the market it depends on the equilibrium rate of unem-
wage and there is no unemployment, the ployment. Our analysis thus goes beyond
worst that can happen to a worker who studies of information and incentives within
shirks on the job is that he is fired. Since he organizations (such as Armen Alchian and
can immediately be rehired, however, he pays Harold Demsetz, 1972, and the more recent
no penalty for his misdemeanor. With imper- and growing literature on worker-firm rela-
fect monitoring and full employment, there- tions as a principal-agent problem) to in-
fore, workers will choose to shirk. quire about the equilibrium conditions in
To induce its workers not to shirk, the firm markets with these informational features.
attempts to pay more than the "going wage"; The paper closest in spirit to ours is Steven
then, if a worker is caught shirking and is Salop (1979) in which firms reduce turnover
fired, he will pay a penalty. If it pays one costs when they raise wages; here the savings
firm to raise its wage, however, it will pay all from higher wages are on monitoring costs
firms to raise their wages. When they all raise (or, at the same level of monitoring, from
their wages, the incentive not to shirk again increased output due to increased effort). As
disappears. But as all firms raise their wages, in the Salop paper, the unemployment in this
their demand for labor decreases, and unem- paper is definitely involuntary, and not
ployment results. With unemployment, even of the standard search theory type (Peter
if all firms pay the same wages, a worker has Diamond, 1981, for example). Workers have
an incentive not to shirk. For, if he is fired, perfect information about all job opportuni-
ties in our model, and unemployed workers
strictly prefer to work at wages less than the
•Woodrow Wilson School of Public and Interna- prevailing market wage (rather than to re-
tional Affairs, and Department of Economics, respec- main unemployed); there are no vacancies.
tively, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ 08540. We
thank Peter Diamond, Gene Grossman, Ed Lazear, Steve
Salop, and Mike Veall for helpful comments. Financial
2
support from the National Science Foundation is appre- In his 1979 paper, Calvo surveyed a variety of
ciated. models of unemployment, including his hierarchical firm
1
By involuntary unemployment we mean a situation model (also with Stanislaw Wellisz, 1979). There are a
where an unemployed worker is willing to work for less number of important differences between that work and
than the wage received by an equally skilled employed this paper, including the specification of the monitoring
worker, yet no job offers are forthcoming. technology.

45

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
46 Carl Shapiro and Joseph E. Stiglitz
The theory we develop has several im- other firms do. The dual role wages play by
portant implications. First, we show that allocating labor and providing incentives for
unemployment benefits (and other welfare employee effort allows wage dispersion to
benefits) increase the equilibrium unemploy- persist.
ment rate, but for a reason quite different Although we have focused our analysis on
from that commonly put forth (i.e., that indi- the labor market, it should be clear that a
viduals will have insufficient incentives to similar analysis could apply to other markets
search for jobs). In our model, the existence (for example, product or credit markets) as
of unemployment benefits reduces the "pen- well. This paper can be viewed as an analysis
alty" associated with being fired. Therefore, of a simplified general equilibrium model of
to induce workers not to shirk, firms must an economy in which there are important
pay higher wages. These higher wages reduce principal-agent (incentive) problems, and in
the demand for labor. which the equilibrium entails quantity con-
Second, the model explains why wages straints (job rationing). As in all such prob-
adjust slowly in the face of aggregate shocks. lems, it is important to identify what is ob-
A decrease in the demand for labor will servable, and, based on what is observable,
ultimately cause a lower wage and a higher what are the set of feasible contractual
level of unemployment. In the transition, arrangements between the parties to the con-
however, the wage decrease will match the tract. Under certain circumstances, for in-
growth in the unemployment pool, which stance, workers might issue performance
may be a sluggish process. bonds and this might alleviate the problems
Third, we show that the market equi- with which we are concerned in this paper.
librium which emerges is not, in general, In Section III we discuss the role of alterna-
Pareto optimal, where we have taken ex- tive incentive devices.
plicitly into account the costs associated with In the highly simplified model upon which
monitoring. There exist, in other words, in- we focus here, all workers are identical, all
terventions in the market that make everyone firms are identical, and thus, in equilibrium,
better off. In particular, we show that there all pay the same wage. The assumption that
are circumstances in which wage subsidies all workers are the same is important, be-
are desirable. There are also circumstances cause it implies that being fired carries no
where the government should intervene in stigma (the next potential employer knows
the market by supplying unemployment in- that the worker is no more immoral than any
surance, even if all firms (rationally) do not. other worker; he only infers that the firm for
A (small) turnover tax is desirable, because which the worker worked must have paid a
high turnover increases the flow of job wage sufficiently low that it paid the worker
vacancies, and hence the flow out of the to shirk). We have made this assumption
unemployment pool, making the threat of because we wished to construct the simplest
firing less severe. possible model focussing simply on incentive
Additionally, our theory provides predic- effects, in which adverse selection considera-
tions about the characteristics of labor tions play no role. In a sequel, we hope to
markets which cause the natural rate (i.e., explore the important interactions between
equilibrium level) of unemployment to be the two fundamental information problems
relatively high: high rates of labor turnover, of adverse selection and moral hazard.3
high monitoring costs, high discount rates The assumption that all firms are the same
for workers, significant possibilities for work- is not critical for the existence of equilibrium
ers to vary their effort inputs, or high costs to unemployment. Firm heterogeneity will,
employers (such as broken machinery) from however, lead to a wage distribution. If the
shirking.
Finally, our theory shows how wage distri-
butions (for identical workers) can persist in 'Other studies have focused on quantity constraints
(rationing) with adverse-selection problems. See Stiglitz
equilibrium. Firms which find shirking par- (1976), Charles Wilson (1980), Andrew Weiss (1980),
ticularly costly will offer higher wages than and Stiglitz and Weiss (1981).

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device 47
4
damage that a particular firm incurs as a e > 0. When a worker is unemployed, he
result of a worker not performing up to receives unemployment benefits of w (and
standard is larger, the firm will have an e = 0).
incentive to pay the worker a higher wage. Each worker is in one of two states at any
Similarly, if the cost of monitoring (detecting point in time: employed or unemployed.
shirking) for a firm is large, that firm will There is a probability b per unit time that a
also pay a higher wage. Thus, even though worker will be separated from his job due to
workers are all identical, workers for differ- relocation, etc., which will be taken as "exog-
ent firms will receive different wages. There enous. Exogenous separations cause a worker
is considerable evidence that, in fact, differ- to enter the unemployment pool. Workers
ent firms do pay different wages to workers maximize the expected present discounted
who appear to be quite similar (for example, value of utility with a discount rate r > 0.5
more capital intensive firms pay higher The model is set in continuous time.
wages). The theory we develop here may
provide part of the explanation of this phe- B. The Effort Decision of a Worker
nomenon.
In Section I, we present the basic model in The only choice workers make is the selec-
which workers are risk neutral. Quit rates tion of an effort level, which is a discrete
and monitoring intensities are exogenous. A choice by assumption. If a worker performs
welfare analysis of the unemployment equi- at the customary level of effort for his job,
librium is provided. In Section II, we com- that is, if he does not shirk, he receives a
ment on extensions of the analysis to situa- wage of w and will retain his job until exog-
tions where monitoring intensities and quit enous factors cause a separation to occur. If
rates are endogenous, and where workers are he shirks, there is some probability q (dis-
risk averse. Section III compares the role of cussed below), per unit time, that he will be
unemployment as an incentive device with caught.6 If he is caught shirking he will be
other methods of enforcing discipline on the fired,7 and forced to enter the unemployment
labor force. pool. The probability per unit time of acquir-
ing a job while in the unemployment pool
I. The Basic Model (which we call the job acquisition rate, an
endogenous variable calculated below) deter-
In this section we formulate a simple model mines the expected length of the unemploy-
which captures the incentive role of unem- ment spell he must face. While unemployed
ployment as described above. Extensions and he receives unemployment compensation of
modifications of this basic model are consid- w (also discussed below).
ered in subsequent sections.
4
Including effort as a continuous variable would not
A. Workers change the qualitative results.
5
That is, we assume individuals are infinitely lived,
There are a fixed number, N, of identical and have a pure rate of time preference of r. They
workers, all of whom dislike putting forth maximize
effort, but enjoy consuming goods. We write W= E(J Xu(w{l),e(l))e\p(- rl) dt,
an individual's instantaneous utility function o
as U(w, e), where w is the wage received and
where we have implicitly assumed that individuals can
eis the level of effort on the job. For simplic- neither borrow nor lend. Allowing an exponential death
ity, we shall assume the utility function is rate would not alter the structure of the model; neither
separable; initially, we shall also assume that would borrowing in the risk-neutral case.
workers are risk neutral. With suitable nor- 'For now we take q as exogenous; later it will be
malizations, we can therefore rewrite utility endogenous. The assumption of a Poisson detection
technology, like a number of the other assumptions
as U = w - e. Again, for simplicity, we as- employed in the analysis, is made to ensure that the
sume that workers can provide either minimal model has a simple stationary structure.
effort (e = 0), or some fixed positive level of 'This will be firm's optimal policy in equilibrium.

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
48 Carl Shapiro and Joseph E. Stiglitz
The worker selects an effort level to maxi- plication of the NSC: unless there is a penalty
mize his discounted utility stream. This associated with being unemployed, everyone
involves comparison of the utility from shirk- will shirk. In other words, if an individual
ing with the utility from not shirking, to could immediately obtain employment after
which we now turn. We define K/ as the being fired, VU = V§, and the NSC could
expected lifetime utility of an employed never be satisfied.
shirker, K/ as the expected lifetime utility of Equation (5) has several natural implica-
an employed nonshirker, and Vu as the tions. If the firm pays a sufficiently high
expected lifetime utility of an unemployed wage, then the workers will not shirk. The
individual. The fundamental asset equation critical wage, w, is higher
for a shirker is given by (a) the higher the required effort (e),
(b) the higher the expected utility associ-
(1) ated with being unemployed (Ku),
(c) the lower the probability of being
while for a nonshirker, it is detected shirking (q),
(d) the higher the rate of interest (i.e.,
the relatively more weight is attached to the
(2) rV»-»-e + b{Vu-Vg). short-run gains from shirking (until one is
caught) compared to the losses incurred when
Each of these equations is of the form "in- one is eventually caught),
terest rate times asset value equals flow bene- (e) the higher the exogenous quit rate b
fits (dividends) plus expected capital gains (if one is going to have to leave the firm
(or losses)."8 Equations (1) and (2) can be anyway, one might as well cheat on the firm).
solved for Kf and F / :
C. Employers
(3) E
r+b+q There are M identical firms, i = l , . . . , M .
Each firm has a production function Q, =
/(£,), generating an aggregate production
(4) V»*
r+b function of Q = F(L).9 Here L, isfirmI'S
effective labor force; we assume a worker
The worker will choose not to shirk if and contributes one unit of effective labor if he
only if Vg > K|. We call this the no-shirking does not shirk. Otherwise he contributes
condition (NSC), which, using (3) and (4), nothing (this is merely for simplicity). There-
can be written as fore firms compete in offering wage packages,
subject to the constraint that their workers
(5) choose not to shirk. We assume that F'(N)
> e, that is, full employment is efficient.
Alternatively, the NSC also takes the form The monitoring technology (q) is exoge-
q(V§ - Vu) > e. This highlights the basic im- nous. Monitoring choices by employers are
analyzed in the following section. We assume
8
A derivation follows: taking Vu as given and looking
at a short time interval [0, /] we have
'That is.
Vr = (1 - n)[blVu + (1 - hi) V,;],
^ max
since there is probability bt of leaving the job during the
interval [0, t] and since e~ " ~ 1 - rt. Solving for Vt;, we
have such that Y.L, = L. This assumes that in market equi-
librium, labor is efficiently allocated, as it will be in the
VE = [wi + (1 - l - ( 1 - r,)(l - bi)]. basic model of this section. The modifications required
for more general cases, when different firms face differ-
Taking limits as (-> 0 gives (1). Equation (2) can be ent critical no-shirking wages, w(, or have different
derived similarly. technologies, are straightforward.

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device 49
that other factors (for example, exogenous D. Market Equilibrium
noise or the absence of employee specific
output measures) prevent monitoring of effort We now turn to the determination of the
via observing output. equilibrium wage and employment levels. Let
A firm's wage package consists of a wage, us first indicate heuristically the factors which
w, and a level of unemployment benefits, determine the equilibrium wage level.
vv.10 Each firm finds it optimal to fire shirkers, If wages are very high, workers will value
since the only other punishment, a wage their jobs for two reasons: (a) the high wages
reduction, would simply induce the disci- themselves, and (b) the correspondingly low
plined worker to shirk again. level of employment (due to low demand for
It is not difficult to establish that all firms labor at high wages) which implies long spells
offer the smallest unemployment benefits al- of unemployment in the event of losing one's
lowed (say, by law).11 This follows directly job. In such a situation employers will find
from the NSC, equation (5). An individual they can reduce wages without tempting
firm has no incentive to set w any higher workers to shirk.
than necessary. An increase in w raises Vu Conversely, if the wage is quite low,
and hence requires a higher w to meet the workers will be tempted to shirk for two
NSC. Therefore, increases in w cost the firm reasons: (a) low wages imply that working is
both directly (higher unemployment benefits) only moderately preferred to unemployment,
and indirectly (higher wages). Since the firm and (b) high employment levels (at low wages
has no difficulty attracting labor (in equi- there is a large demand for labor) imply
librium), it sets w as small as possible. Hence unemployment spells due to being fired will
we can interpret w in what follows as the be brief. In such a situation firms will raise
minimum legal level, which is offered con- their wages to satisfy the NSC.
sistently by all firms. Equilibrium occurs when each firm, taking
Having offered the minimum allowable w, as given the wages and employment levels at
an individual firm pays wages sufficient to other firms, finds it optimal to offer the going
induce employee effort, that is, w = w to wage rather than a different wage. The key
meet the NSC. The firm's labor demand is market variable which determines individual
given by equating the marginal product of firm behavior is Vu, the expected utility of an
labor to the cost of hiring an additional unemployed worker. We turn now to the
employee. This cost consists of wages and calculation of the equilibrium VUP
future unemployment benefits. For vP = 0,12 The asset equation for Vu, analogous to (1)
the labor demand is given simply by f'(L:) and (2), is given by
= w, with aggregate labor demand of F'(L)
(6) rVu = w + a(VE-Vu),
where a is the job acquisition rate and VE is
the expected utility of an employed worker
(which equals VE in equilibrium). We can
'"More complex employment contracts, for example, now solve (4) and (6) simultaneously for VE
wages rising with seniority, are discussed in Section III. and Vu to yield
With our assumptions of stationarity and identical
workers, employers cannot improve on the simple em-
ployment provisions considered here. (w-e)(a +
(7) E
~
"We are implicitly assuming that the firm cannot a+b+r
offer « only to workers who quit. This is so because the
firm can always fire a worker who wishes to quit, and it _ (w — e)a + w(b + r)
would be optimal for the firm to do so. (8) " a+b+r '
12
For iv> 0 the expected cost of a worker is the
wage cost for the expected employment period of I/ft,
followed by w for the expected period of unemploy- 13
We have already shown that all firms offer the same
ment, I / a . This generates labor demand given by employment benefits w, so Vu is indeed a single number,
i.e., an unemployed person's utility is independent of his
previous employer.

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
50 Carl Shapiro and Joseph E. Stiglitz
Substituting the expression for Vu (i.e., (8))
into the NSC (5) yields the aggregate NSC
(9) w>w + e + e{a + b + r)/q.
Notice that the critical wage for nonshirking
is greater: (a) the smaller the detection prob-
ability q; (b) the larger the effort e; (c) the
higher the quit rate b; (d) the higher the
interest rate r, (e) the higher the unemploy- • - EMPUOTMENT
ment benefit (w); and (f) the higher the
flows out of unemployment a. FIGURE 1. THE AGGREGATE NO-SHIRKING CONSTRAINT
We commented above on the first four
properties; the last two are also unsurprising.
If the unemployment benefit is high, the hired. Knowing this, workers will choose to
expected utility of an unemployed individual shirk.
is high, and therefore the punishment associ- The equilibrium wage and employment
ated with being unemployed is low. To in- level are now easy to identify. Each (small)
duce individuals not to shirk, a higher wage firm, taking the aggregate job acquisition
must be paid. If a is the probability of rate a as given, finds that it must offer at
obtaining a job per unit of time, I / a is the least the wage w. The firm's demand for
expected duration of being unemployed. The labor then determines how many workers are
longer the duration, the greater the punish- hired at the wage. Equilibrium occurs where
ment associated with being unemployed, and the aggregate demand for labor intersects the
hence the smaller the wage that is required to aggregate NSC. For w = 0, equilibrium oc-
induce nonshirking. curs when
The rate a itself can be related to more
fundamental parameters of the model, in a (e/q){bN/(N-L)+r).
steady-state equilibrium. In steady state the
flow into the unemployment pool is bL where
L is aggregate employment. The flow out is The equilibrium is depicted in Figure 2.14 It
a(N — L) (per unit time) where A' is the is important to understand the forces which
total labor supply. These must be equal, so cause E to be an equilibrium. From the
bL = a(N-L), or firm's point of view, there is no point in
raising wages since workers are providing
(10) a = bL/(N-L). effort and the firm can get all the labor it
wants at w*. Lowering wages, on the other
Substituting for a into (9), the aggregate hand, would induce shirking and be a losing
NSC, we have idea.15
From the worker's point of view, unem-
ployment is involuntary: those without jobs
would be happy to work at w* or lower, but
cannot make a credible promise not to shirk
at such wages.
= e + w + {e/q)(b/u + r) = w,

where u = (N- L)/N, the unemployment


14
rate. This constraint, the aggregate NSC, is Aggregate labor demand is F'( L) only when w = 0
graphed in Figure 1. It is immediately evi- (see fn. 12).
" W e have assumed that output is zero when an
dent that no shirking is inconsistent with full individual shirks, but we need only assume that a
employment. If L = N, a = + oo, so any shirker's output is sufficiently low that hiring shirking
shirking worker would immediately be re- workers is unprofitable.

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device 51
NSC'

L« N L

FIGURE 2. EQUILIBRIUM UNEMPLOYMENT


FIGURE 3. COMPARATIVE STATICS

Note: A decrease in the monitoring intensity q, or an


Notice that the type of unemployment we increase in the quit rate b, leads to higher wages and
have characterized here is very different from more unemployment
search unemployment. Here, all workers and
all firms are identical. There is perfect infor-
mation about job availability. There is a
different information problem: firms are as- attractive as the unemployment pool grows.
sumed (quite reasonably, in our view) not to This provides an explanation of wage slug-
be able to monitor the activities of their gishness.
employees costlessly and perfectly.
F. Welfare Analysis
E. Simple Comparative Statics
In this section we study the welfare prop-
The effect of changing various parameters erties of the unemployment equilibrium. We
of the problem may easily be determined. As demonstrate that the equilibrium is not in
noted above, increasing the quit rate b, or general Pareto optimal, when information
decreasing the monitoring intensity q, de- costs are explicitly accounted for.
creases incentives to exert effort. Therefore, We begin with the case where the owners
these changes require an increase in the wage of the firms are the same individuals as the
necessary (at each level of employment) to workers, and ownership is equally distrib-
induce individuals to work, that is, they shift uted among A' workers. The central planning
the NSC curve upwards (see Figure 3). On problem is to maximize the expected utility
the other hand, they leave the demand curve of the representative worker subject to the
for labor unchanged, and hence the equi- NSC and the resource constraint:
librium level of unemployment and the equi-
librium wage are both increased. Increases in
unemployment benefits have the same im- (12) max (w-e)L + w(N-L)
w,w, L
pact on the NSC curve, but they also reduce
labor demand as workers become more ex-
pensive, so they cause unemployment to rise subject to w > e + w + (e/q){(bN
for two reasons.
Inward shifts in the labor demand sched- /(N-L)) + r) (NSC)
ule create more unemployment. Due to the
NSC, wages cannot fall enough to com- subject to wL + w(N- L) < F(L)
pensate for the decreased labor demand. The
transition to the higher unemployment equi- (Feasibility)
librium will not be immediate: wage de-
creases by individual firms will only become subject to w > 0.

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
52 Carl Shapiro and Joseph E. Stiglitz
Since workers are risk neutral it is easy to INDIFFERENCE
CURVES NSC
check16 that the optimum involves w at the
minimum allowable level, which is assumed
to be 0. The reason is that increases in w
tighten the NSC, so all payments should be
made in the form of w rather w.
Setting w = 0, the problem simplifies to

(12')

subject to w > e + (e/q)((bN/(N~L)) + r);


FIGURE 4. SOCIAL OPTIMUM AT A
and wL<F(L).

The set of points which satisfy the con- employed requires that w > 0, or equivalently
straints is shaded in Figure 4. Iso-utility that profits after taxes be nonnegative.17 The
curves are rectangular hyperboles. So long as optimum can be achieved by taxing away all
F'(L)> e, these are steeper than the average profits and financing a wage subsidy of T,
product locus, so the optimum occurs at shown in Figure 4. The "natural" unemploy-
point A where the NSC intersects the curve ment rate is too high.
w = F(L)/L, that is, where wages equal the In the case where the workers and the
average product of labor. In contrast, the owners are distinct individuals, the tax policy
market equilibrium occurs at E where the described above would reduce profits, in-
marginal product of labor curve, w = F\L), crease wages, and increase employment lev-
intersects the NSC (Figure 2). Observe that els. While it would increase aggregate output
in the case of constant returns to scale, (net of effort costs), such a tax policy would
F'(L)L = F(L), so the equilibrium is opti- not constitute a Pareto improvement, since
mal. profits would fall. For this reason, the equi-
Wages should be subsidized, using what- librium is Pareto optimal in this case, even
ever (pure) profits can be taxed away. An though it fails to maximize net national
equivalent way to view the social optimum is product. We thus have the unusual result
a tax on unemployment to reduce shirking that the Pareto optimality of the equilibrium
incentives; the wealth constraint on the un- depends upon the distribution of wealth. The
standard separation between efficiency and
income distribution does not carry over to
16
Formally, this model.
It should not be surprising that the equi-
if =(w-e)L + w(N-L) librium level of unemployment is in general
inefficient. Each firm tends to employ too
+ A[ w - e - W -(e/q)(bN/(N - I) + r)] few workers, since it sees the private cost of
+ n[F(L)-wL-w(N- L)}. an additional worker as w, while the social
cost is only e, which is lower. On the other
Differentiating with respect of w and w yields hand, when a firm hires one more worker, it
fails to take account of the effect this has on
if.. - L + \ - iiL < 0 and = 0 if w > 0. Vu (by reducing the size of the unemploy-
ment pool). This effect, a negative externality
i ? B - ( A r - Z , ) - A - ( i ( A r - L ) < 0 a n d = 0if w>0. imposed by one firm on others as it raises its
We know w > 0 by the NSC, so Sfw - 0, i.e., t ( l - ji) +
X - 0. Therefore, since \ > 0, /i > 1. But then Jfw = (N "The constraint w > 0 can be rewritten, using the
- Z.)(l - n)- \<0. This implies that w - 0. resource constraint, as F(L)~ wL > 0, i.e., n > 0.

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device 53
level of employment, tends to lead to over- B. Risk Aversion
employment. In the simple model presented
so far, the former effect dominates, and the With risk neutrality, the optimum and the
natural level of unemployment is too high. market both involve iv = 0. Clearly w ••- 0
This will not be true in more general models, cannot be optimal if workers are highly nsk
however, as we shall see below. averse and may be separated from their jobs
for exogenous reasons. Yet the market al-
II. Extensions ways provides w = 0 (or the legal minimum).
The proof above that w = 0 carries over to
In this section we describe how the results the case of risk-averse workers.
derived above are modified or extended when When equilibrium involves unemploy-
we relax some of the simplifying assump- ment, firms have no difficulty attracting
tions. We discuss three extensions in turn: workers and hence offer w = 0, since w > 0
endogenous monitoring, risk aversion, and merely reduces the penalty of being fired.
endogenous turnover. Detailed derivations of When other firms offer w = 0, this argument
the claims made below are available in our is only strengthened: unemployed workers
earlier working paper. are even easier to attract. It is striking that
the market provides no unemployment ben-
A. Endogenous Monitoring efits even when workers are highly risk averse.
Clearly the social optimum involves iv > 0 if
When employees can select the monitoring risk aversion is great enough. This may pro-
intensity q, they can trade off stricter moni- vide a justification for mandatory minimum
toring (at a cost) with higher wages as meth- benefit levels.
ods of worker discipline. In general, firms'
monitoring intensities will not be optimal, C. Endogenous Turnover
due to the externalities between firms de-
scribed above. In general, it is not possible to In general a firm's employment package
ascertain whether the equilibrium entails too will influence the turnover rate it experiences
much or too little employment. In the case of among its employees. Since the turnover rate
constant returns to scale (F(L)-L), how- b affects the rate of hiring out of the unem-
ever (which led to efficiency with exogenous ployment pool, and hence Vu, it affects other
monitoring), the competitive equilibrium in- firms' no-shirking constraints. Because of this
volves too much monitoring and too much externality, firms' choices of employment
employment. packages will not in general be optimal. This
The result is not as unintuitive as it first type of externality is similar to search exter-
seems: each firm believes that the only in- nalities in which, for example, one searcher's
strument at its control for reducing shirking expected utility depends on the number or
is to increase monitoring. There is, however, mix of searchers remaining in the market. In
a second instrument: by reducing employ- the current model, policies which discourage
ment, workers are induced not to shirk. This labor turnover are attractive as they make
enables society to save resources on monitor- unemployment more costly to shirkers.
ing (supervision). These gains more than
offset the loss from the reduced employment. III. Alternative Methods for the
It is straightforward to see how this policy Enforcement of Discipline
may be implemented. If firms can be induced
to reduce their monitoring, welfare will be This paper has explored a particular mech-
increased. Hence a tax on monitoring, with anism for the enforcement of discipline: in-
the proceeds distributed, say, as a lump sum dividuals who are detected shirking are fired,
transfer to firms, will leave the no-shirking and in equilibrium the level of unemploy-
constraint/national-resource constraint un- ment is sufficiently large that this threat serves
affected, but will reduce monitoring. as an effective deterrent to shirking. The

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
54 Carl Shapiro and Joseph E. Stiglitz
question naturally arises whether there are Clearly the firm's reputation as an honest
alternative, less costly, or more effective dis- employer can partially solve this problem;
cipline mechanisms. the employer is implicitly penalized for firing
a worker if this renders him less attractive to
A. Performance Bonds prospective employees. Yet this reputation
mechanism may not work especially well,
The most direct mechanism by which dis- since prospective employees often do not
cipline might be enforced is through the know the employer's record, and previous
posting by workers of performance bonds. dismissals may have been legitimate (it is not
Under this arrangement the worker would possible for prospective employees to dis-
forfeit the bond if the firm detected him tinguish legitimate from unfair earlier dis-
shirking. One problem with this solution is missals, if they are aware of them at all). If
that workers may not have the wealth to post the reputation mechanism is less than per-
bond.18 A more fundamental problem with fect, it will be augmented by the unemploy-
this mechanism is that the firm would have ment mechanism.
an incentive to claim that the worker shirked
so that it could appropriate the bond. As- B. Other Costs of Dismissal
suming, quite realistically, that third parties
cannot easily observe workers' effort (indeed, Unemployment in the model above serves
it is usually more costly for outsiders to the role of imposing costs on dismissed
observe worker inputs than for the employer workers. If other costs of dismissal are suffi-
to do so), there is no simple way to discipline ciently high, workers may have an incentive
the firm from this type of opportunism. to exert effort even under conditions of full
Having recognized this basic point, it is employment. Examples of such costs are
easy to see that a number of other plausible search costs, moving expenses, loss of job-
solutions face the same difficulty. For exam- specific human capital, etc. In markets where
ple, consider an employment package which these costs are substantial, the role of equi-
rewards effort by raising wages over time for librium unemployment is substantially di-
workers who have not been found shirking. minished. The effect we have identified above
This is in fact equivalent to giving the worker will still be present, however, when effort
a level wage stream, but taking back part of levels are continuous variables: each firm
his earlier payments as a bond, which is will still find that employee effort is increas-
returned to him later. Therefore, by the above ing with wages, so wages will be bid up
argument, the firm will have an incentive to somewhat above their full-employment level.
fire the worker when he is about to enter the The theory predicts that involuntary (as well
"payoff' period in which he recovers his as frictionaJ) unemployment rates will be
bond. This is the equivalent to the firm's higher for classes of workers who have lower
simply appropriating the bond. It is optimal job switching costs.
for the firm to replace expensive senior
workers by inexpensive junior ones.19

18
This is especially true if detection is difficult (low (discounted) value of the marginal product of the worker.
q) so that an effective bond must be quite large. Even if If there is a bonus for not shirking, initially the wage
workers could borrow to post the bond, so long as must be below the value of the marginal product. It is as
bankruptcy is possible, the incentives for avoiding de- if the worker were posting a bond (the difference be-
faulting on the bond are not different from the incen- tween his marginal product and the wage), and as such
tives to avoid being caught shirking by the firm in the this scheme is susceptible to precisely the same objec-
absence of a bond. Note once again the importance of tions raised against posting performance bondings. The
the wealth distribution in determining the nature of the employer has an incentive to appropriate the bond.
equilibrium. If all individuals inherit a large amount of Since workers know this, this is not a viable incentive
wealth, then they could post bonds. scheme. For a fine study in which firms' reputations are
" I n competitive equilibrium, the average (discount- assumed to function so as to make this scheme viable,
ed) value of the wage must be equal to the average see Edward Lazear (1981).

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device 55
C. Heterogeneous Workers work, some which tend to make the market
equilibrium unemployment rate too high, and
The strongest assumption we have made is others which tend to make it too small. Each
that of identical workers. This assumption firm fails to take into account the conse-
ruled out the possibility that firing a worker quences of its actions on the level of moni-
would carry any stigma. Such a stigma could toring and wages which other firms must
serve as a discipline device, even with full undertake in order to avoid shirking by
employment.20 In reality, of course, em- workers. Although these externalities are
ployers do make wage offers which are con- much like pecuniary externalities, they are
tingent on employment history. Such policies important, even in economies with a large
make sense when firms face problems of number of firms.22 As a result, we have argued
adverse selection. that there is scope for government interven-
We recognize that workers' concern about tions, both with respect to unemployment
protecting their reputations as effective, dili- benefits and taxes or subsidies on monitoring
gent workers may provide an effective incen- and labor turnover, which can (if ap-
tive for a disciplined labor force.21 Shapiro's propriately designed) lead to Pareto im-
earlier (1983) analysis of reputation in prod- provements.
uct markets showed, however, that for repu- The type of unemployment studied here is
tations to be an effective incentive device, not the only or even the most important
there must be a cost to the loss of reputation. source of unemployment in practice. We be-
It is our conjecture that, under plausible lieve it is, however, a significant factor in the
conditions, even when reputations are im- observed level of unemployment, especially
portant, equilibrium will entail some use of in lower-paid, lower-skilled, blue-collar oc-
unemployment as a discipline device for the cupations. It may well be more important
labor force, at least for lower-quality workers. than frictional or search unemployment in
An important line of research is the study of many labor markets.
labor markets in which adverse selection as
well as moral hazard problems are present. 22
For a more general discussion of pecuniary, or
In this context, our model should provide a more general market mediated externalities, with appli-
useful complement to the more common cations to economies with important adverse selection
studies of adverse selection in labor markets. and moral hazard problems, see Greenwald and Stiglitz
(1982).

IV. Conclusions
REFERENCES
This paper has explored the role of unem-
ployment, or job rationing, as an incentive Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold, "Pro-
device. We have argued that when it is costly duction, Information Costs, and Economic
to monitor individuals, competitive equi- Organization," American Economic Re-
librium will be characterized by unemploy- view, December 1972, 62, 777-95.
ment, but that the natural rate of unemploy- Calvo, Guillermo A., "Quasi-Walrasian Theo-
ment so engendered will not in general be ries of Unemployment," American Eco-
optimal. We have identified several forces at nomic Review Proceedings, May 1979, 69,
102-06.
20
, "On the Inefficiency of Unemploy-
See Bruce Greenwald (1979) (or a simple model in ment," Columbia University, October
which those who are in the "used labor market" are in
fact a lower quality than those in the "new" labor 1981.
market. and Wellisz, Stanislaw, "Hierarchy,
21
This suggests once again that our results may be Ability and Income Distribution," Journal
most significant in labor markets for lower-quality of Political Economy, October 1979, 67,
workers: in such markets employment histories are
utilized less and workers already labeled as below aver-
991-1010.
age in quality have less to lose from being labeled as Diamond, Peter, "Mobility Costs, Frictional
such. Unemployment, and Efficiency," Journal

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015
56 Carl Shapiro and Joseph E. Stiglitz
of Political Economy, August 1981, 89, Unemployment as a Worker Discipline
798-812. Device," Discussion Papers in Economics,
Greenwald, Bruce, C. N., Adverse Selection in No. 28, Woodrow Wilson School, Prince-
the Labor Market, New York; London: ton University, April 1982.
Garland, 1979. Stiglitz, Joseph E., "Prices and Queues as
and Stiglitz, Joseph E., "Pecuniary Ex- Screening Devices in Competitive Mar-
ternalities," unpublished, Princeton Uni- kets," IMSSS Technical Report No. 212,
versity, 1982. Stanford University, 1976.
La/ear, Edward P., "Agency, Earnings Profiles, and Weiss, Andrew, "Credit Rationing
Productivity, and Hours Restrictions," in Markets with Imperfect Information,"
American Economic Review, September American Economic Review, June 1981, 71,
1981, 71, 606-20. 393-410.
Salop, Steven C, "A Model of the Natural Weiss, Andrew, "Job Queues and Layoffs in
Rate of Unemployment," American Eco- Labor Markets with Flexible Wages,"
nomic Review, March 1979, 69, 117-25. Journal of Political Economy, June 1980,
Shapiro, Carl, "Premiums for High Quality 88, 526-38.
Products as Returns to Reputations," Wilson, Charles, "The Nature of Equilibrium
Quarterly Journal of Economics, November in Markets with Adverse Selection," Bell
1983, 98, 658-79. Journal of Economics, Spring 1980, 11,
and Stiglitz, Joseph E., "Equilibrium 108-30.

Downloaded from Cambridge Books Online by IP 128.122.253.212 on Sat May 09 14:53:10 BST 2015.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511559594.004
Cambridge Books Online © Cambridge University Press, 2015

You might also like