Corruption Artcile IASR

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/341878534

Corruption research: A need for an integrated approach

Article in International Area Studies Review · June 2020


DOI: 10.1177/2233865920926778

CITATIONS READS

9 956

1 author:

Andris Zimelis
University of Illinois at Chicago
11 PUBLICATIONS 52 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Far-right politics View project

anti-corruption View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Andris Zimelis on 03 June 2020.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


926778
research-article2020
IAS0010.1177/2233865920926778International Area Studies ReviewZimelis

Review Essay
International Area Studies Review

Corruption research: A need


1­–19
© The Author(s) 2020
Article reuse guidelines:
for an integrated approach sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/2233865920926778
https://doi.org/10.1177/2233865920926778
journals.sagepub.com/home/ias

Andris Zimelis
Visiting professor, Upper Iowa University, USA

Abstract
This article reviews the main corruption literature trends and theoretical foundations and points
out the challenges of existing explanations of corruption. The emphasis on broad national-level
variables limits our understanding of corruption and anti-corruption processes at the local level.
Corruption studies also suffer from the bias of focusing on developing countries and nation-states.
These shortcomings can be remedied by using an integrated approach to studying corruption in
western countries and cities.

Keywords
Corruption, anti-corruption, democracies, research methodology, developing countries

Introduction
Political corruption has been widely discussed in the media and each year numerous corruption
studies get published. This increased attention is likely caused by the frequent exposure of corrup-
tion scandals in the media and the subsequent recognition that corruption shows little sign of disap-
pearing. Although it has been argued that corruption could be useful for “greasing the wheels” of
bureaucracy and getting things done (Huntington, 1968; Leff, 1964; Leys, 1970; Nguyen et al.,
2016; Rose-Ackerman, 1978), the general agreement among scholars and policy analysts is that the
consequences of corruption are harmful to society, the economy, the government, and public trust.
Most scholars agree on the negative effects of corruption (Dimant and Tosato, 2018; Liu, 2016;
Mauro, 1996; Oji and Oji, 2010; Pedersen and Johannsen, 2018; Rose-Ackerman and Kornai, 2004;
Rothstein, 2005; Rothstein and Uslaner, 2005). Researchers have convincingly demonstrated that
corruption negatively affects economic growth and growth rates by decreasing private investment,
and that corruption distorts international trade and investment flows (Glynn et al., 1997; Mauro,
1996; Pinto and Zhu, 2016; Qian and Sandoval-Hernandez, 2016). Others argue that corruption
erodes social capital by lowering trust (Banerjee, 2016; López and Santos, 2014; Nix et al., 2017;
Rothstein and Uslaner, 2005), distorts public priorities (Karklins, 2005; Tickner, 2017; Wang and
You, 2016), and benefits the selected few as opposed to the many (Borcan et al., 2017; Newell, 2018).

Corresponding author:
Andris Zimelis, Upper Iowa University, 5040 Warren Street, #401, Skokie, IL 60077, USA.
Email: zimelisa98@uiu.edu
2 International Area Studies Review 00(0)

It reduces the resources allocated to education and health sectors and fosters policies that increase
income inequality (Batabyal and Chowdhury, 2015; Mauro, 1996; Ortega et al., 2016). Corruption
also adversely affects the societal benefits of natural resources in resource-rich countries (Williams
and Le Billon, 2017).
Corruption also makes the economy inefficient, human talent is misused as a result of nepotism,
and corrupt dealings lead to substandard workmanship (Ariely and Uslaner, 2017; Kaufmann,
1997). Warren (2004: 328) considers corruption dangerous because it “reduces the effective domain
of public action by reducing public agencies of collective action to instruments of private benefit.”
In democracies in particular, all citizens possess the right to take part in collective actions regard-
ing their welfare but corruption unfairly excludes the not-connected people from the opportunity to
participate in these processes. Thus, in addition to creating mismanaged government, corruption
undermines the very essence of democratic process and leads to a disengaged and cynical popula-
tion. Indeed, unfettered corruption poses a major threat to democracy (Teachout, 2014).
This article will review the empirical findings and current trends in the corruption literature to
provide a holistic overview of what we know and do not know about the causes of corruption. It
will highlight the shortcomings of existing approaches and will explain the need to integrate macro
and micro approaches to understanding corruption. It will also point out specific areas that could
benefit from additional corruption research.

Corruption definitions
The most common definition of corruption revolves around the rules guiding public officials in
their public duties. Under this definition, behavior becomes corrupt when it deviates from the offi-
cial rules in order to further private interests or monetary gains. Corruption is then defined in terms
of “misuse of public power for private gain” (Johnston, 2005; Karklins, 2005; LaPalombara, 1995;
Philp, 2016; Scott, 1972; Transparency International, 2009, 2015). Scholars acknowledge that:

although corruption comes in many shapes, shades, and sizes, and with different degrees of tolerability,
corruption is always defined with one feature – the inappropriate mix of public and private as it is corrupt
for officials to profit personally from public office. (Johnson and Sharma, 2004: 3)

The underlying idea is that officials entrusted with overseeing public goods should not exploit
their public positions for selfish and/or private goals. Hence, Kurer and Jain (2001: 73) explains
corruption as “those activities in which public officials, bureaucrats, legislators and politicians use
powers delegated to them by the public to further their own economic interest at the expense of the
common good.” This concept explicitly considers corruption as a divergence from behavior that is
in the public’s best interest (Lancaster and Montinola, 1997). With this definition, public corrup-
tion includes deviant behaviors such as bribery, clientelism, extortion, nepotism, and theft taking
place within the public domain and involving at least one public official (Langseth, 2016). The
reference to “public versus private” constitutes the basis of virtually all definitions of corruption.

Measuring corruption
Measuring corruption, which is characterized by illicit activities the perpetrators are actively trying
to hide, remains a difficult task for scholars and there is no universal agreement on how to measure
it. Having appropriate measures, analytical frameworks, and conceptual models based on the spe-
cific corruption challenges is important. For example, Amundsen (2019) shows how political
Zimelis 3

corruption can be divided into two related but separate processes – extractive and power-preserv-
ing corruption – and he argues that this distinction requires different analytical approaches.
The Transparency International (TI) Corruption Perception Index (CPI) attempts to measure the
extent of government officials’ involvement in corrupt practices. The index is a “poll of polls”
based on the experiences of business executives, country risk analysts, experts, and investigative
journalists who do business in the countries being surveyed, and utilizes at least 13 different sur-
veys from at least 10 different institutions (Transparency International, 2017). The CPI index
includes information from resident and non-resident experts and the survey data is thoroughly
cross-checked and methodologically validated.
The CPI measure is not perfect and has some methodological challenges. For example, reliance
on the country’s business environment as a proxy of national corruption can be useful but it ignores
other segments of government where corruption could potentially exist, for example healthcare.
Likewise, the business experts could behave differently from regular citizens and could be report-
ing corruption based on their personal or political inclinations or limited experiences, and could
potentially bias corruption survey reports (Charron, 2016). The indices grounded in perceptions
could also expose the ineffectiveness of a country’s public institutions instead of the true extent of
corruption.
Another way of measuring corruption is to identify the corruption occurrences from data such
as the number of convictions of public officials (Cordis and Milyo, 2016; Glaeser and Saks, 2006;
Simpson et al., 2015). This measure is straightforward and gives a quantifiable overview of corrup-
tion in a specific location. Nevertheless, this measure may reveal more the effective work of the
judicial and prosecutorial systems than the actual levels of corruption (Galtung, 2016). The com-
parative application of the conviction-based data remains problematic due to the differences in the
definition of corruption in different locations (United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime, 2018).
The low levels of conviction rates can indicate that the preventative corruption control measures
are working well by preventing corruption from occurring, but the presence of high conviction
rates can also indicate successful anti-corruption measures (for example, Singapore and Hong
Kong simultaneously have some of the highest corruption conviction rates and lowest levels of
corruption) (Cordis and Milyo, 2016; Galtung, 2016; Galtung et al., 2016). The conviction-based
data – both low and high levels – could suggest the effectiveness of anti-corruption efforts and
therefore does not work well for international comparative purposes, in which cases the CPI-based
index is superior (Lambsdorff, 2016). Indeed, the problems with employing conviction-based data
are especially evident for international comparisons, where the use of the CPI index is preferred
(Kostadinova, 2012).

Understanding the history of corruption literature


The problem of public corruption has long preoccupied scholars and writers. For example, a
Google Ngram search for the keyword “corruption” shows that this phenomenon has been dis-
cussed in books since around 1550 and its popularity has waned and grown over centuries.
Interestingly, as seen in Figure 1 below, the popularity of the word “corruption” in English lan-
guage books increased in the late 1700s and 1800s and has been gradually climbing since the late
1990s.
Corruption studies have adopted a variety of theoretical and empirical approaches and it is not
surprising that most single-discipline corruption studies have produced contradictory findings
(Johnston, 2005). More precisely, corruption researchers study how official policies and laws
affect corruption and most of what we know about corruption is grounded in the studies of these
formal factors. A concurrent development has been new possibilities for empirical macro-level
4 International Area Studies Review 00(0)

Figure 1. Google Ngram search results for “corruption.”


Source and graphic: Google Ngram.

(structural) research made possible by the use of Transparency International’s corruption percep-
tion index, which ranks corruption worldwide. The macro-level studies using quantitative models
tend to dominate corruption literature, perhaps due to the fact that micro-level (agency) studies are
more difficult to conduct. I will argue that to better understand the nature of corruption and anti-
corruption, we need to integrate the micro- and macro-level approaches.
We can review the history of corruption scholarship by considering the bifurcation of corruption
explanations into the agency (micro-level) or structure (macro-level) approaches. The micro-level
or agency argument centers around the notion that human agency in general is driving corrupt
actions (Ward, 1989). The agency approach considers human behavior to be the consequence of
individual decisions and explains differences in behavior as the outcome of individual peculiarities
and diverging incentives (Collier, 2005). The agency approach to understanding the causes of and
remedies to corruption consists of moralist and economic/rational choice approaches. On the one
hand, the moralists view corruption through normative lenses and consider individuals – known as
bad apples – to be the main sources of corruption (Johnston, 1982; Johnston and Heidenheimer,
2017). These bad apples are typically inadequately educated or inadequately trained public offi-
cials with weak character traits (Alatas, 1990; Johnston, 2005; Leys, 1965).
On the other hand, the economic/rational choice theory of causes of corruption focuses on
actions by agents intended to increase the agent’s self-aggrandizing interest, considering opportu-
nity costs and information (Monroe, 1991). The rational choice approach is exemplified by the
principal–agent model (Klitgaard, 1988; Rose-Ackerman, 1978), game theory (Geddes, 1991;
Manion, 1996), and cost–benefit (Nye, 1967) analyses of corruption. The most popular rational
choice approach example is Klitgaard’s (1988) principal–agent model. It will be examined in more
detail later in this section.
Proponents of structural explanations hold a view that social behavior is governed by specific
institutional circumstances that influence the incentives for agent behavior (Johnston, 1982).
Different behavior results from different institutions and circumstances. Modernization theory
influences this approach, which subsumes revisionist and culturalist branches (Collier, 2005;
Huntington, 1968). The role of individual agents in explaining social behavior is not deemed essen-
tial by structuralists in this “rotten barrel” approach (Johnston, 1982). In other words, it is the
institutional circumstances that determine the level of corruption.
The modernization idea implies that corruption is highest when a country is in an intense phase
of modernization characterized by weak institutions in flux, but decreases with the attainment of a
Zimelis 5

developed country’s status exemplified by stable and efficient institutions. Corruption levels will
be affected by the makeup and nature of the country’s economic and political institutions, and
particularly high corruption levels usually indicate “the absence of effective political institutional-
ism” (Huntington, 1968: 59). Corruption thus will be higher in places that lack effective political
parties and institutions.
The revisionist branch of the structural approach attempts to explain what causes corruption by
looking at the functional needs for corruption, that is, how corruption fulfills a specific need not
met by the government (Leff, 1964; Merton, 1968; Scott, 1972). The main assumption of revision-
ists is that corruption can promote a more efficient functioning of dysfunctional political and eco-
nomic systems, consequently sustaining the corruption and dysfunction of the system. For example,
a comprehensive study of American urban political machines demonstrates that corruption grows
from the practical need to provide services when the government is unable to do it (Merton, 1968).
The culturalist branch of the structural school argues that the extent of corruption in society
depends upon the nature of a country’s culture and increases when the self-interests of various
groups, such as ethnic groups or clans, dominate (Huntington, 1968). The challenge of cultural
relativity is partially explained by arguing that modern societies with high civic standards and
strict views of corruption generate lower corruption (Heidenheimer, 1970; Johnston and
Heidenheimer, 2017).

Current corruption literature: macro- and micro-level approaches


I will now provide a more detailed assessment of explanations of corruption within the current
framework of the structural and agency approaches to studying corruption. In contrast to the previ-
ous section, this review focuses on the current state of corruption literature. For the purposes of this
study, I use the words structural and macro-level, and agency and micro-level interchangeably.

Macro-level explanations of corruption


In general, modern macro-oriented research tends to focus on identifying the variables affecting
corruption risks such as economic factors, democracy, institutions, and political parties. The
macro-level analysis improves knowledge about the relationships between corruption and public
institutions, political capability circumstances, and cultures (Ades and Di Tella, 1999; Batory,
2018; Della Porta and Vannucci, 2016; Drury et al., 2006; Paldam, 2001; Pellegrini and Gerlagh,
2004; Suleiman and Othman, 2017). However, while new studies of corruption help us better
understand the persistence of corruption, this research still contains conflicting findings on the
specific causes of corruption.
The macro-oriented corruption literature branch has demonstrated the damaging impact of cor-
ruption on economic growth, although this relationship is not linear and with many caveats
(Bardhan, 1997; Mauro, 1995). One key factor in explaining the varying levels of corruption has
been economic development, particularly income levels measured in Gross Domestic Product
(GDP) per capita variations (Ades and Di Tella, 1999; Campos and Giovannoni, 2017; Damania
et al., 2004; Kunicova and Rose-Ackerman, 2005; Lederman et al., 2005; Paldam, 2002; Persson
and Tabellini, 2003; Swamy et al., 2001; Treisman, 2000). Countries with greater per capita income
are correlated with lower citizen/voter corruption despite some researchers questioning the correla-
tion (Kaufmann, 1999) and several scholars having discovered the opposite (Braun and Di Tella,
2004; Frechette, 2001). Similarly, some scholars find that another economic factor – income equal-
ity – decreases corruption (Paldam, 2002; Rothstein and Uslaner, 2005), whereas other scholars
find no statistically significant relationships (Brown et al., 2005).
6 International Area Studies Review 00(0)

Democracy is frequently described as the crucial antidote to corruption due to improved trans-
parency and responsibility, which make corruption harder to maintain. Moreover, civil liberties in
democracy are thought to reduce corruption (Damania et al., 2004; Goldsmith, 1999; Kunicova
and Rose-Ackerman, 2005; Lederman et al., 2005; Paldam, 2002; Svensson, 2005; Swamy et al.,
2001). On the other hand, Treisman (2000) fails to uncover a statistically significant relationship
between corruption levels and democracy, that is, whether the country was democratic or not did
not have any impact on corruption levels.
It is also possible that democracy does not help stem corruption because the electoral system
does not function as envisioned: if corrupt politicians are not penalized at the polls, they therefore
stand favorable chances of being reelected (Chang and Golden, 2007). Analyses of this contradic-
tion – unpopular corruption and popular corrupt politician – emphasize the factors of both supply
and demand. While the latter views the voters with peculiar societal norms or incomplete informa-
tion on the extent and consequences of corruption as the key obstacle to a corruption-free society,
the former criticizes the overall political system for being unable to provide corruption-free alter-
natives to the voters (Kurer and Jain, 2001). Generally, democracy seems to reduce corruption,
although the difficulty is separating the impact of democracy from other important factors such as
the level of economic development and media freedoms. Some researchers argue that the negative
impact of democracy on corruption levels vanishes when we take into consideration wealth and
Protestant religion (Lane et al., 2000) or income inequality (Donovan and Karp, 2017).
Relevant research has explored work security-related incentives in electoral victories in democ-
racies and has concluded that the necessity for electoral resources can thwart virtually all reforms
of patronage networks in South America (Geddes, 1991). Patronage, which is usually defined by
the exploitation of various government resources such as public contracts, jobs, and construction
licenses to reward loyal political supporters, exists as part of political power structures all over the
world (Collier, 2002; Flinders and Geddes, 2014). Any attempts to reform and undermine patron-
age remain problematic because, even if honest politicians desire to implement meaningful reforms,
they usually cannot afford the reforms due to their political survival being jeopardized by the loss
of electoral resources ( Flinders and Geddes, 2014; Geddes, 1991).
When it comes to public institutions, legal structures and official rules decide, at least partially,
what behavior is considered corrupt. Vital institutional features include local or national electoral
arrangements and election format, and type of party funding (Alexander and Shiratori, 1994;
Galeotti and Merlo, 1994; Gidlund and Koole, 2001; Gunlicks, 1993; Nassmacher, 1993; Williams,
2000). Effective anti-corruption agencies are especially vital for substantive anti-corruption efforts
as they can independently focus efforts to combat corruption (Gregory, 2015; Meagher, 2004;
Transparency International, 2015; United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime, 2012). The anti-
corruption agencies are especially effective in democracies where they are supported in their anti-
corruption efforts by free media and robust democratic processes (Krajewska and Makowski,
2017; Kuris, 2015; Quah, 2017). Effective e-governments can lower overall corruption levels in
the country (Agarwal and Maiti, 2020; Funk and Owen, 2020; Sanmukhiya, 2019), although some
scholars find that e-governance is effective at reducing corruption only if the country has a strong
rule of law (Park and Kim, 2019).
Political and administrative explanations of corruption highlight such factors as a government’s
administrative efficiency, the nature and degree of political competition in the country, the govern-
ment’s scope, interactions between elected politicians and government bureaucrats, and public–
private interactions. We need to understand whether the political parties are institutionally separate
from the government’s public administration arrangements (Heywood, 1997; Krylova, 2018); the
degree of accountability, competition, and openness in the public domain; the extent of actual
rivalry among the country’s authority centers (Della Porta and Vannucci, 2016; Kim and Sharman,
2014); and how long the government has been in power (Aranha, 2017; LaPalombara, 1995).
Zimelis 7

Moreover, variations in the institutional features and political power situations can impact cor-
ruption risks (Rose-Ackerman and Palifka, 2016). For example, when political parties begin losing
members and become increasingly reliant on government financing or private donations, they can
in some instances resort to illegal means of financing their activities. Legislative changes have not
always coincided with the unofficial laws regulating party behavior (Eicher, 2016). Frequently,
regulation of contribution limits to political parties develops into an issue only after financing
scandals occur (Gidlund and Koole, 2001).
Scholarly literature also discusses the effects of relations between the public and private spheres
on governance. Privatization is often researched for its effects on corruption levels and the research
argues that privatization can exacerbate corruption by muddling the boundaries between the pri-
vate and public, and private contracts can worsen the corruption risk and perceptions (Belousova
et al., 2016; Doig and Wilson, 1998; Heywood, 1997, 2002; Kamal et al., 2018; Khlif et al., 2016).
Others have argued that privatization is correlated with the decrease of overall corruption levels
(Kaufmann and Siegelbaum, 1997; Koyuncu et al., 2010; Peña Miguel and Cuadrado-Ballesteros,
2018). Still others have argued that privatization can both increase the risks of corruption and
decrease the perception of corruption at the same time (Martimort and Straub, 2006).
Finally, other variables and findings from the macro-level research include the degrees of eco-
nomic and bureaucratic regulation (LaPalombara, 1995; Schlicht, 1985), the design and arrange-
ment of public sector functions (Heywood, 1997), the legal system (Lane et al., 2000), and the style
of economic system (Bardhan, 1997). Lipset and Lenz (2000) utilize quantitative measures to
demonstrate the relevance of culture in a nation’s overall wealth and explore the association
between a country’s religion and individualistic and familistic relations (see also Dincer and
Johnston, 2016). Others, however, suggest that societal culture does not explain the levels of cor-
ruption as connected to GDP variations (Andersson, 2008; Paldam, 2001; Persson et al., 2013;
Rehman and Naveed, 2007).
Although structural explanations of corruption can help explain different levels of corruption,
there is little consensus regarding which specific structural factors are the most significant in
explaining varying corruption levels across the world. These structural relationships also do not
fully explain causal mechanisms (Rose-Ackerman and Palifka, 2016). Additionally, the useful-
ness of structural factors for designing anti-corruption programs is questionable. There is little
practical utility in telling a country or city to become wealthier, strengthen democracy, and con-
vert to Protestantism.
Generally, this macro-level corruption literature helps researchers to identify the institutional
factors that can be useful in accounting for the differences among the nation-states (Menocal et al.,
2015). Structural explanations can work quite well at the national level, but their effectiveness in
explaining local levels of corruption (e.g. city-level) remains largely untested. The corruption lit-
erature in general and the macro-level approach specifically have a bias of using nation-states as
research cases. The macro-level approach is typically not used in local corruption studies and the
important institutional factors from the literature are not tested at the local level. Applying the
macro-level approach to local corruption would test the robustness of key theoretical concepts and
would help generate new theoretical and practical knowledge.

Micro-level explanations of corruption


In micro-level explanations, the focus is mostly on the actors making their choices based on
specific incentives for and attitudes toward corruption, or individual choices. This approach
emphasizes the actors and the choices they make in various contexts, and, thus, is concerned
with individuals and their possibilities, incentives, and attitudes about corruption (Akbar and
8 International Area Studies Review 00(0)

Vujić, 2014; Cartier-Bresson, 1997; Cuervo-Cazurra, 2016; Della Porta et al., 1996; Fleming and
Zyglidopoulos, 2009; Gamboa-Cavazos et al., 2006; Jancsics, 2014; Nabli and Nugent, 1989;
Rose-Ackerman, 1999). The important factors for an actor considering whether to engage in cor-
ruption in these kinds of analysis are the likely losses and gains and the capability to discover
corrupt associates (Della Porta et al., 1996).
The anticipated benefit from corrupt behavior depends on what an actor believes other people
to do, which influences the person’s probability of participating in corrupt deals. Honest govern-
ment officials benefit more than corrupt public officials when few officials are engaging in corrup-
tion, but this benefit decreases as the number of corrupt public officials grows (Bardhan, 1997). In
other words, the larger the proportion of corrupt public officials, the easier it becomes for another
official to engage in corrupt deals. The number of individuals believed to be corrupt influences
attitudes and norms that consequently affect the ethical cost for the actor considering whether to
participate in corruption (Andvig and Moene, 1990; Bardhan, 1997; Della Porta and Vannucci,
2016; Gorsira et al., 2018; Lui, 1986). As the proportion of corrupt public officials increases, the
expectations of corruption being detected and prosecuted decreases (Cadot, 1987). Interestingly,
there is growing evidence that the higher the number of women in the labor force and government,
the lower the levels of corruption (Barnes and Beaulieu, 2018; Swamy et al., 2001).
Corrupt practices established by earlier generations may lead to an environment in which
younger generations could become more likely to view corruption as a normal part of life, thus
sustaining corruption. Because individual reputations are decided by collective reputations, and
vice versa, an actor’s motivation to sustain a good reputation becomes larger if the actor’s group or
community has a reputation of high ethics (Tirole, 1996). The individual’s desire to participate in
corruption is important to the individual but “the effect of that individual choice on the decisions
of others is equally important” (Corbacho et al., 2016: 1081). The higher the number of individuals
who deem corruption as an ethically acceptable choice, the lower the individual ethical cost of
becoming involved in corrupt behavior (Gorsira et al., 2018).
The individual-level analysis in the corruption literature also assumes that behavior can be
molded by diverse social influences such as media reporting and peer behavior (Dong et al., 2012;
Gorsira et al., 2018; Tavits, 2010). Corruption can be lowered by democratic processes such as
political openness, checks and balances, and accountability, but typically this happens through
changing social norms (Cain et al., 2001; Dimant and Schulte, 2016; Neeman et al., 2008; Olsson,
2014). For example, individuals can vote out corrupt politicians after they become informed about
politicians’ corruption by the media. The difficulty lies in effectively altering the social norms, with
media reporting playing a major role (Stapenhurst, 2000). Being a politically well-informed indi-
vidual influences perception of government corruption (Ionescu, 2017).
A non-traditional explanation of disparities in corruption levels between various sectors within
the same country is Alam’s (1995) approach considering the losers from corruption and their
actions to minimize their losses. The countervailing actions losers from corruption can engage in
determine the level of corruption in a country. The factors that determine the capacity of people to
participate in countervailing actions and consequently explain the differences in corruption levels
include the types of losses from corruption, education levels, income distributions, and political,
human, and property rights (Alam, 1995; Ahmad, 2004).

Principal–agent approach
The principal–agent approach is an individual (micro) level approach taking into consideration the
effects of authority delegated from a principal to an agent. It is the most widely used approach to
study corruption and it is also the approach most often used by policymakers designing
Zimelis 9

anti-corruption policies. The principal–agent models view corruption as an informational problem


when the principal fails to monitor the agent properly (Gurgur and Shah, 2005; Klitgaard, 1988;
Marquette and Peiffer, 2015; Rose-Ackerman, 1978). For example, the people are considered the
principal as they vote to elect a political representative, who in turn is considered to be the agent.
The principal–agent approaches explain the levels of corruption based on information availability
problems. The politicians (agents) have a monopoly over information, which in turn can create an
information disconnect between the agent and the principal (voters). The principal–agent
approaches recommend monitoring political power and competition in the government as a possi-
ble solution to corruption (Gurgur and Shah, 2005).
The principal–agent approach has also been used to explore private companies, particularly the
likely collusion among the participants (Laffont and N'Guessan, 1999; Tirole, 1996). If the agent
can act in such ways that the principal cannot monitor their actions or the agent has access to better
information than the principal, corruption can occur (Andersson and Bergman, 2009; Kiewiet and
McCubbins, 1991; Mungiu-Pippidi and Dadašov, 2016). An information asymmetry may lead to
the agent abusing their public position in ways not explicitly approved by the principal (for
instance, corruption) and colluding against the citizens (principal) (Kiewiet and McCubbins, 1991:
25–26). Informational asymmetries can exacerbate corruption with groups or multiple agents or
principals (Andersson, 2008; Philp, 2017).
Generally, the principle–agent approach can help explain when and why an individual decides
to engage in corruption. However, although micro-level approaches to studying corruption can
help advance explanations of a specific action, they tend to focus on only a small part of a much
larger political corruption problem. The principal–agent approach is also considered too reduction-
ist (Anderson and Gray, 2006), and agency models ignore the existence of broader institutional
structures that could condition agent behavior. For example, Robert Klitgaard’s (1988: 75) classi-
cal conceptualization of corruption Corruption = Monopoly + Discretion – Accountability omits
important macro-level factors such as the types of political systems and societal attitudes.

Conclusion: where do we go from here?


This article reviewed trends in corruption literature to offer an overview of what we know and do
not know about the causes of corruption. The review of corruption literature leads to the following
recommendations: we need to integrate macro and micro approaches to understanding corruption
and the research should focus on the specific areas that could benefit from additional studies: cor-
ruption in western democracies, causes of anti-corruption as opposed to causes of corruption, and
local level corruption.

Integrating micro- and macro-level perspectives


Although there have been informative single-approach studies of corruption, neither micro- nor
macro-level models by themselves have the capacity to fully account for the causes and persis-
tence of such a complex phenomenon as corruption (Andersson and Bergman, 2009). Classic
micro-level or agency explanations regard people’s behavior as dependent on their individual
preferences, whereas classic macro-level or structural explanations are considered deterministic,
unable to account for the reasons why two individuals in comparable circumstances decide on
different courses of action (Pinto et al., 2008; Rothstein, 2011). Scholars cannot fully know
whether they should focus on individuals or structures before they begin their corruption research
because the individual’s level of autonomy would determine the correct focus (Andersson, 2008).
The majority of corruption studies do not analyze both the structures and micro-level elements
10 International Area Studies Review 00(0)

affecting individual choices, and thus leave gaps in corruption scholarship (Jancsics, 2015;
Lambsdorff, 2007). Due to the narrow focus of individual approaches to studying corruption, no
single approach offers a comprehensive picture, thus warranting the creation of an integrated
model (Gorsira et al., 2018).
The agent–structure (micro–macro) division and the resulting challenges necessitate developing
a new approach to studying the association between social actors and institutions in order to explain
social behavior given that “the properties of agents and those of social structures are both relevant
to explanations of social behavior” (Wendt, 1987: 338). Logically, a research framework incorpo-
rating more than one theoretical approach should have a superior explanatory power over a frame-
work with just one approach, because a multipronged model offers researchers multiple views of
the phenomenon under study (Peters, 1998).
For these reasons, research studies that adopt an integrated approach in which both agents and
structures are included are recommended. For example, combining institutional assessment with
analysis of media and its impact on citizens would prove move informative than any single
approach. Such an approach would consider both the macro-level perspective of institutions and
micro-level perspective of the media’s impact on individual perceptions, contributing to a richer
and fuller explanation of why anti-corruption efforts fail.
The traditional principal–agent model can be improved by addressing the challenge of informa-
tion asymmetry between citizens and public officials in a more sophisticated way by analyzing the
specifics of how the media reports corruption. Media analysis is important because, in the princi-
pal–agent model, the causes of corruption stem from an information asymmetry where the agents
(politicians and public officials) have an information advantage over the principal (the citizens/
voters), which can lead to corruption. These negative effects of information asymmetry can be
mitigated by the principal having more information and better access to information because citi-
zens’ access to information is the cornerstone of all principal–agent models. A free press improves
people’s access to news, which makes it harder for politicians and government officials to hide
corruption (Lindstedt and Naurin, 2006). This logic supports the notion of combating corrupt
behavior via democracy: citizens, particularly when educated by the media, are able to punish cor-
rupt politicians by voting them out of office (Besley and Prat, 2006). However, existing studies
cannot highlight the specifics of the most effective ways for the media to close this information
gap. Using the integrated approach to studying corruption in western democracies and cities is
likely to produce unique knowledge about corruption and a more nuanced contribution to the cor-
ruption literature.

Western democracies, not just developing countries


Public corruption remains a major threat to efficient and responsive public policies across the world.
While most corruption stories in the media describe the plight of developing countries, the more
developed nations also have their share of corruption. The popular CPI index is possibly the reason
why corruption has been largely explored in developing non-western countries. An overview of
existing corruption studies shows that corruption is mostly studied in developing countries, which
might be contributing to the impression that corruption is a “third world” problem. Thus, a Google
Scholar search for the keywords “corruption” and “democracies” from 2000 to 2018 yielded 21,000
results of articles and books mentioning these terms. The same search for the keywords “corruption”
and “developing countries” yielded 172,000 results in the same time period. The bias of studying
corruption in developing countries is clearly reflected in the academic literature.
However, this disproportionate emphasis on studying developing countries is odd given the
recurrent corruption scandals and sliding CPI rankings in western societies. After all, corruption is
Zimelis 11

“endemic in all governments” (Nye, 1967: 417). Allegations of an offer to amend a piece of legisla-
tion in exchange for money in Britain’s House of Lords, as well as the case of putting up a senate
seat for sale for potential personal and campaign benefits by the former governor of Illinois Rod
Blagojevich, illustrate the pervasiveness of high-level corruption in established democracies. Even
a country that consistently occupies a spot among the top 10 least corrupt nations according to
Transparency International, Finland, experienced a national-level corruption scandal when several
parliamentarians admitted they had violated the legislation on disclosure of political campaign
finances. Despite the perceptions of corruption affecting mostly poor non-western nations, it is “a
pathology most likely to be found thriving in democracies” (Warren, 2004: 328).
We need to acknowledge that corruption is not an epidemic confined only to weak democracies
and developing countries. This lack of research on corruption in strong democracies prevents
scholars and policymakers from verifying the usefulness of knowledge about the causes of and
remedial mechanisms for corruption discovered in developing countries. How will we know if cor-
ruption in western democracies requires the same anti-corruption methods as developing countries
if we do not study corruption in both? It is important we move away from this bias and study cor-
ruption in established democracies. Even countries that receive high scores on the CPI devised by
Transparency International, such as Denmark and New Zealand, are not immune to corruption
because no country receives a perfect score. A perfect score on the CPI index would imply a com-
plete absence of corruption and, to date, no country has ever achieved this.

Anti-corruption, not just corruption


The majority of corruption studies tend to focus on the causes of or factors that contribute to cor-
ruption. Corruption researchers have studied how various elements of governance, such as the
quality of democratic or judicial institutions or government transparency, impact levels of corrup-
tion. Reading the existing corruption studies makes it clear that the emphasis is on explaining the
causes or correlates of corruption. For example, a simple Google Scholar search on books and
journal articles featuring the word “corruption” and “anti-corruption” in titles from January 2016
to January 2018 yielded 18,200 and 5590 results respectively. The studies focusing on causes of
corruption are important and help policymakers and scholars to understand better what variables
could lead to higher levels of corruption, but, at the same time, there is the need to explore specific
anti-corruption elements in greater detail.
In theory, knowing what factors cause corruption should help us to design better policies to
reduce corruption. In practice, however, the substantial corruption literature and agreements on
many factors causing corruption have not helped reduce corruption significantly, especially in
developing countries (Bracking, 2008). Corruption persists even when policymakers know what
contributes to it. One explanation could be that the policy makers are simply not capable of imple-
menting the required changes (Schmidt, 2007). Changing democratic institutions or revamping
judicial systems requires enormous political will and resources. We need to study specifically ele-
ments of anti-corruption, especially those that lead to more effective anti-corruption, to obtain a
more comprehensive picture of the causes of and remedies to corruption. Several international
organizations, including the World Bank and Transparency International, have devoted significant
resources to studying anti-corruption, but there is also a need for academics to contribute to the
growing body of knowledge. As explained above, the focuses of most anti-corruption efforts and
studies tend be developing countries (see for example World Bank, 2017), which is strange given
the ongoing corruption scandals in developed countries. Studying factors that contribute to anti-
corruption would complement the literature on causes of corruption and would allow researchers
and policymakers to obtain a fuller picture of potential remedies to corruption.
12 International Area Studies Review 00(0)

Local corruption, not just (inter)national corruption


Additionally, a particularly useful focus on anti-corruption research is the analysis of cities from a
comparative perspective. The phenomenon of corruption has been studied primarily at the interna-
tional or national level and very few studies explore it at a local level. It is therefore not surprising
that most anti-corruption recommendations involve international anti-corruption treaties and, by
extension, national governments. It is puzzling, however, why most corruption studies analyze cor-
ruption based on the national-level framework and without explicit focus on local governments.
Although important and necessary, the emphasis on (inter)national factors does not help us to
understand the effectiveness of anti-corruption initiatives at the local level. It is an important area
to study because “people form opinions about government, decide their level of political participa-
tion, and calculate their social capital in terms of what is happening to them in their cities and
towns” (Huberts et al., 2008: 3). The nature of public governance and social capital in a community
will be mainly determined by where people live and interact with local governments and not by
hearing about obscure international conventions. After all, all politics is local (O’Neill and Hymel,
1994). Local governments make decisions on services in areas as diverse as licensing, waste
removal, zoning and building permits, construction, and local planning, and these areas are particu-
larly prone to corruption (Andersson, 2008; Transparency International, 2018a).
Furthermore, people typically have more direct contact with their local government officials
and politicians than bureaucrats at the national level. Due to the frequency of these contacts, the
honesty of local politicians and government officials warrants extra attention and research. Local
governments often involve personal ties and have less transparency than national governments,
which increases their susceptibility to corruption (DeLeon, 2015). The interaction between levels
of government can be complex, with state or regional government involvement in local policies,
but the presence of local concern when dealing with the legitimacy of local policymakers is almost
always present. There have been few anti-corruption studies focusing solely on cities; conse-
quently, we need more research on local corruption. Although several scholars have begun to
address city corruption (see Huberts et al., 2008; Klitgaard et al., 2000) and a few organizations
have also embarked on local corruption research projects (such as the Local Integrity Initiative by
Global Integrity, 2015), there is still a shortage of corruption research focusing on local govern-
ments. The discussions about local anti-corruption systems have remained limited and analytical
attempts to compare local anti-corruption policies and institutions are rare.

Funding
The author received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

ORCID iD
Andris Zimelis https://orcid.org/0000-0002-4017-1432

References
Ades A and Di Tella R (1999) Rents, competition, and corruption. American Economic Review 89(4):
982–993.
Agarwal A and Maiti D (2020) ICTs and effectiveness of governance: A cross-country study. In: Maiti D,
Castellacci F and Melchior A (eds) Digitalisation and Development. Singapore: Springer, 321–343.
Ahmad N (2004) Corruption and competition in bureaucracy: A cross-country analysis. Pakistan Economic
and Social Review 42(1–2): 61–86.
Akbar Y and Vujić V (2014) Explaining corruption: The role of national culture and its implications for inter-
national management. Cross Cultural Management 21(2): 191–218.
Zimelis 13

Alam MS (1995) A theory of limits on corruption and some applications. Kyklos 48(3): 419–435.
Alatas H (1990) Corruption: Its Nature, Causes, and Functions. Avebury.
Alexander HE and Shiratori R (1994) Comparative Political Finance among the Democracies. Boulder.
Amundsen I (ed.) (2019) Political Corruption in Africa: Extraction and Power Preservation. Edward Elgar
Publishing.
Anderson JH and Gray CW (2006) Anticorruption in Transition 3: Who Is Succeeding. . . and Why? The
World Bank.
Andersson S (2008) Studying the risk of corruption in the least corrupt countries. Public Integrity 10(3):
193–214.
Andersson S and Bergman T (2009) Controlling corruption in the public sector. Scandinavian Political
Studies 32(1): 45–70.
Andvig JC and Moene KO (1990) How corruption may corrupt. Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization 13(1): 63–76.
Aranha ALM (2017) Accountability, corruption and local government: Mapping the control steps. Brazilian
Political Science Review 11(2): 1–31.
Ariely G and Uslaner EM (2017) Corruption, fairness, and inequality. International Political Science Review
38(3): 349–362.
Banerjee R (2016) Corruption, norm violation and decay in social capital. Journal of Public Economics 137:
14–27.
Bardhan P (1997) Corruption and development: A review of the issues. Economic Literature 35(3): 1320–1346.
Barnes TD and Beaulieu E (2018) Women politicians, institutions, and perceptions of corruption. Comparative
Political Studies 52(1): 134–167.
Batabyal S and Chowdhury A (2015) Curbing corruption, financial development and income inequality.
Progress in Development Studies 15(1): 49–72.
Batory A (2018) Corruption in East Central Europe: has EU membership helped? In: Warf B (ed.) Handbook
on the Geographies of Corruption. Edward Elgar Publishing.
Belousova V, Goel RK and Korhonen I (2016) Corruption perceptions versus corruption incidence:
Competition for rents across Russian regions. Journal of Economics and Finance 40(1): 172–187.
Besley T and Prat A (2006) Handcuffs for the grabbing hand? Media capture and government accountability.
American Economic Review 96(3): 720–736.
Borcan O, Lindahl M and Mitrut A (2017) Fighting corruption in education: What works and who benefits?
American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 9(1): 180–209.
Bracking S (2008) Corruption and Development: The Anti-corruption Campaigns. New York: Palgrave
MacMillan.
Braun M and Di Tella R (2004) Inflation, inflation variability, and corruption. Economics and Politics 16(1):
77–100.
Brown D, Touchton M and Whitford A (2005) Political Polarizations as Constraint on Government: Evidence
from Corruption. SSRN working paper.
Cadot O (1987) Corruption as a gamble. Journal of Public Economics 33(2): 223–244.
Cain P, Doig A, Flanary R, et al. (2001) Filing for corruption: Transparency, openness and record-keeping.
Crime, Law and Social Change 36(4): 409–425.
Campos NF and Giovannoni F (2017) Political institutions, lobbying and corruption. Journal of Institutional
Economics 13(4): 917–939.
Cartier-Bresson J (1997) Corruption networks, transaction security and illegal social exchange. Political
Studies 45(3): 463–476.
Chang EC and Golden MA (2007) Electoral systems, district magnitude and corruption. British Journal of
Political Science 37(1): 115–137.
Charron N (2016) Do corruption measures have a perception problem? Assessing the relationship between
experiences and perceptions of corruption among citizens and experts. European Political Science
Review 8(1): 147–171.
Collier MW (2002) Explaining corruption: An institutional choice approach. Crime, Law and Social Change
38(1): 1–32.
14 International Area Studies Review 00(0)

Collier MW (2005) Political Corruption in the Caribbean Basin: Constructing a Theory to Combat
Corruption. Routledge.
Corbacho A, Gingerich DW, Oliveros V, et al. (2016) Corruption as a self-fulfilling prophecy: Evidence from
a survey experiment in Costa Rica. American Journal of Political Science 60(4): 1077–1092.
Cordis AS and Milyo J (2016) Measuring public corruption in the United States: Evidence from administra-
tive records of federal prosecutions. Public Integrity 18(2): 127–148.
Cuervo-Cazurra A (2016) Corruption in international business. Journal of World Business 51(1): 35–49.
Damania R, Fredriksson P and Mani M (2004) The persistence of corruption and regulatory compliance fail-
ures: Theory and evidence. Public Choice 121: 363–390.
DeLeon P (2015) Thinking about Political Corruption. Routledge.
Della Porta D and Vannucci A (2016) The Hidden Order of Corruption: An Institutional Approach. Routledge.
Della Porta D, Pizzorno A and Donaldson J (1996) The business politicians: Reflections from a study of
political corruption. Journal of Law and Society 23(1): 73–94.
Dimant E and Schulte T (2016) The nature of corruption: An interdisciplinary perspective. German Law
Journal 17(1): 53–72.
Dimant E and Tosato G (2018) Causes and effects of corruption: What has past decade’s empirical research
taught us? A survey. Journal of Economic Surveys 32(2): 335–356.
Dincer O and Johnston M (2016) Political culture and corruption issues in state politics: A new measure of
corruption issues and a test of relationships to political culture. Publius: The Journal of Federalism
47(1): 131–148.
Doig A and Wilson J (1998) The effectiveness of codes of conduct. Business Ethics: A European Review
7(3): 140–149.
Dong B, Dulleck U and Torgler B (2012) Conditional corruption. Journal of Economic Psychology 33(3):
609–627.
Donovan T and Karp J (2017) Electoral rules, corruption, inequality and evaluations of democracy. European
Journal of Political Research 56(3): 469–486.
Drury AC, Krieckhaus J and Lusztig M (2006) Corruption, democracy, and economic growth. International
Political Science Review 27(2): 121–136.
Eicher S (ed.) (2016) Corruption in International Business: The Challenge of Cultural and Legal Diversity.
CRC Press.
Fleming P and Zyglidopoulos SC (2009) Charting Corporate Corruption: Agency, Structure and Escalation.
Edward Elgar Publishing.
Flinders M and Geddes M (2014) The silent revolution: A political history of the politics of patronage and
reform. Contemporary British History 28(1): 24–55.
Frechette G (2001) A Panel Data Analysis of the Time-Varying Determinants of Corruption, Paris. Paper
presented at the EPCS.
Funk KD and Owen E (2020) Consequences of an anti-corruption experiment for local government perfor-
mance in Brazil. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 39(2): 444–468.
Galeotti G and Merlo A (1994) Political collusion and corruption in a representative democracy. Public
Finance= Finances publiques 49(Supplement): 232–243.
Galtung F (2016) Measuring the immeasurable: Boundaries and functions of (macro) corruption indices. In:
Galtung F, Shacklock A, Connors MC, et al. (eds.) Measuring Corruption. Routledge, 101–130.
Galtung F, Shacklock A, Connors MC, et al. (eds.) (2016) Measuring Corruption. Routledge.
Gamboa-Cavazos M, Garza-Cantu V and Salinas E (2006) The organization of corruption: Political horizons
and industrial interests. Working paper. Harvard University Manuscript.
Geddes B (1991) Paradigms and Sand Castles: Theory Building and Research Design in Comparative
Politics (Analytical Perspectives on Politics). New York: University of Michigan Press.
Gidlund G and Koole R (2001) Political Finance in the North of Europe: The Netherlands and Sweden.
Nassmacher, Karl-Heinz, Foundations for Democracy: Approaches to Comparative Political Finance.
Glaeser EL and Saks RE (2006) Corruption in America. Journal of Public Economics 90(6–7): 1053–1072.
Global Integrity (2015) Local integrity initiatives. Available at: www.globalintegrity.org/research/reports/
local-integrity-initiative/ (accessed 29 August 2018).
Zimelis 15

Glynn P, Kobrin SJ and Naim M (1997) The globalization of corruption. In: Elliott KA (ed.) Corruption and
the Global Economy. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 7–31.
Goldsmith A (1999) Slapping the grasping hand: Correlates of political corruption in emerging markets.
American Journal of Economics and Sociology 58(4): 865–883.
Gorsira M, Denkers A and Huisman W (2018) Both sides of the coin: Motives for corruption among public
officials and business employees. Journal of Business Ethics 151(1): 179–194.
Gregory R (2015) Political independence, operational impartiality, and the effectiveness of anti-corruption
agencies. Asian Education and Development Studies 4(1): 125–142.
Gunlicks AB (ed.) (1993) Campaign and Party Finance in North America and Western Europe. Westview
Press.
Gurgur T and Shah A (2005) Localization and corruption: Panacea or Pandora’s Box. World Bank Policy
Research Paper 3486.
Heidenheimer AJ (1970) Political Corruption: Readings in Comparative Analysis. Transaction Books.
Heywood P (1997) Political corruption: Problems and perspectives. Political Studies 45(3): 417–435.
Heywood P (2002) Analysing political corruption in Western Europe: Spain and the UK in comparative
perspective. In: Della Porta D and Rose-Ackerman S (eds) Corrupt Exchanges: Empirical Themes in
the Politics and Political Economy of Corruption. Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, 37–57.
Huberts L, Anechiarico F and Six F (2008) Local Integrity Systems: World Cities Fighting Corruption and
Safeguarding Integrity. The Hague: BJU Legal Publishers.
Huntington SP (1968) Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Ionescu L (2017) Public perceptions of government corruption: An empirical investigation. Journal of Self-
Governance and Management Economics 5(4): 81–86.
Jancsics D (2014) Interdisciplinary perspectives on corruption. Sociology Compass 8(4): 358–372.
Jancsics D (2015) “A friend gave me a phone number” – Brokerage in low-level corruption. International
Journal of Law, Crime and Justice 43(1): 68–87.
Johnson R and Sharma S (2004) About corruption. In: Johnson R (ed.) The Struggle Against Corruption: A
Comparative Study. New York: Palgrave, 1–19.
Johnston M (1982) Political Corruption and Public Policy in America. Monterey: Brooks/Cole Publishing
Company.
Johnston M (2005) Syndromes of Corruption: Wealth, Power, and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Johnston M and Heidenheimer A (2017) Political Corruption: Concepts and Contexts. Routledge.
Kamal M, Rana EA and Wahid AN (2018) Economic reform and corruption: Evidence from panel data.
Australian Economic Papers 57(1): 92–106.
Karklins R (2005) The System Made Me Do it: Corruption in Post-communist Societies. Armonk, N.Y.: M.E.
Sharpe.
Kaufmann D (1997) Corruption: The facts. Foreign Policy Summer, 114–131.
Kaufmann D (1999) Governance matters. World Bank Policy Research Paper 2195.
Kaufmann D and Siegelbaum P (1997) Privatization and corruption in transition economies. Journal of
International Affairs 50(2): 419–458.
Khlif H, Guidara A and Hussainey K (2016) Sustainability level, corruption and tax evasion: A cross-country
analysis. Journal of Financial Crime 23(2): 328–348.
Kiewiet DR and McCubbins MD (1991) The Logic of Delegation. University of Chicago Press.
Kim HJ and Sharman JC (2014) Accounts and accountability: Corruption, human rights, and individual
accountability norms. International Organization 68(2): 417–448.
Klitgaard R (1988) Controlling Corruption. Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Klitgaard RE, Abaroa RM and Parris HL (2000) Corrupt Cities: A Practical Guide to Cure and Prevention.
World Bank Publications.
Kostadinova T (2012) Political Corruption in Eastern Europe: Politics after Communism. Boulder, CO:
Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Koyuncu C, Ozturkler H and Yilmaz R (2010) Privatization and corruption in transition economies: A panel
study. Journal of Economic Policy Reform 13(3): 277–284.
16 International Area Studies Review 00(0)

Krajewska A and Makowski G (2017) Corruption, anti-corruption and human rights: The case of Poland’s
integrity system. Crime, Law and Social Change 68(3): 325–339.
Krylova Y (2018) Corruption and the Russian Economy: How Administrative Corruption Undermines
Entrepreneurship and Economic Opportunities. Routledge.
Kunicova J and Rose-Ackerman S (2005) Electoral rules as constraints on corruption: The risks of closed list
proportional representation. Department of Political Science, Research paper, Yale University.
Kurer O and Jain AK (2001) The Political Economy of Corruption. London: Routledge.
Kuris G (2015) Watchdogs or guard dogs: Do anti-corruption agencies need strong teeth? Policy and Society
34(2): 125–135.
Laffont JJ and N'Guessan T (1999) Competition and corruption in an agency relationship. Journal of
Development Economics 60(2): 271–295.
Lambsdorff JG (2007) The Institutional Economics of Corruption and Reform. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Lambsdorff JG (2016) Measuring corruption – The validity and precision of subjective indicators (CPI). In:
Sampford C, Shacklock A and Galtung F (eds) Measuring Corruption. Routledge, 81–99.
Lancaster T and Montinola G (1997) Toward a methodology for the comparative study of political corruption.
Crime, Law and Social Change 27(3–4): 185–206.
Lane JE, Ersson SO and Ersson S (2000) The New Institutional Politics: Performance and Outcomes.
Psychology Press.
Langseth P (2016) Measuring corruption. In: Sampford C, Shacklock A and Galtung F (eds) Measuring
Corruption. Routledge, 23–60.
LaPalombara J (1995) Structural and institutional aspects of corruption. Social Research 61(2): 325–350.
Lederman D, Loayza NV and Soares RR (2005) Accountability and corruption: Political institutions matter.
Economics & Politics 17(1): 1–35.
Leff N (1964) Economic development through bureaucratic corruption. American Behavioral Scientist 8(3):
8–14.
Leys C (1965) What is the problem about corruption? The Journal of Modern African Studies 3(2): 215–230.
Leys C (1970) What is the problem about corruption? In: Heidenheimer A (ed.) Political Corruption:
Readings in Comparative Analysis. New York: Holt Reinehart, 31–37.
Lindstedt C and Naurin D (2006) Transparency against corruption – A cross-country analysis. In: IPSA 20th
World Congress, 9–13 July. Fukuoka, Japan.
Lipset SM and Lenz GS (2000) Corruption, culture, and markets. In: Harrison LE and Huntington SP (eds)
Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress. New York: Best Books, pp.112–126
Liu C (2016) Public corruption: Causes, consequences and cures. In: Klassen T, Cepiku D and Lah J (eds) The
Routledge Handbook of Global Public Policy and Administration. Routledge, 109–118.
López JAP and Santos JMS (2014) Does corruption have social roots? The role of culture and social capital.
Journal of Business Ethics 122(4): 697–708.
Lui FT (1986) A dynamic model of corruption deterrence. Journal of public Economics 31(2): 215–236.
Manion M (1996) Corruption by design: Bribery in Chinese enterprise licensing. The Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization 12(1): 167–195.
Marquette H and Peiffer C (2015) Theoretical (mis) understanding? Applying principal-agent and collective
action theories to the problem of corruption in systemically corrupt countries. In: Lawton A, Huberts L
and van der Wal Z (eds) Ethics in Public Policy and Management. Routledge, 131–148.
Martimort D and Straub S (2006) Privatization and corruption. In: Industrial Economic Institute conference,
“Public services and management: Designs, issues and implications for local governance,” Research
paper, January, pp. 12–14. Toulouse, France.
Mauro P (1995) Corruption and growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3): 681–712.
Mauro P (1996) The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Investment, and Government Expenditure. IMF
Working Paper 96/98.
Meagher P (2004) Anti-corruption agencies: A review of experience. College Park, MD: IRIS Center.
Available at: https://scholar.google.com/scholar?hl=en&as_sdt=0%2C14&q=meagher+2004+anti-
corruption+agencies&btnG=
Zimelis 17

Menocal RA, Taxell N, Johnsøn JS, et al. (2015) Why corruption matters: Understanding causes, effects and how
to address them. Evidence Paper on Corruption, Department for International Development. Available at:
https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/406346/
corruption-evidence-paper-why-corruption-matters.pdf
Merton RK (1968) Social Theory and Social Structure. Simon and Schuster.
Monroe KR (1991) John Donne’s people: Explaining differences between rational actors and altruists through
cognitive frameworks. The Journal of Politics 53(2): 394–433.
Mungiu-Pippidi A and Dadašov R (2016) Measuring control of corruption by a new index of public integrity.
European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research 22(3): 415–438.
Nabli MK and Nugent JB (1989) The new institutional economics and its applicability to development. World
Development 17(9): 1333–1347.
Nassmacher KH (1993) Comparing party and campaign finance in western democracies. In: Gunlicks A
(ed.) Campaign and Party Finance in North America and Western Europe. iUniverse, Inc. Lincoln, NE,
233–268.
Neeman Z, Paserman MD and Simhon A (2008) Corruption and openness. The BE Journal of Economic
Analysis and Policy 8(1): 1–40.
Newell JL (2018) Corruption in Contemporary Politics. Manchester University Press.
Nguyen TV, Ho BD, Le CQ, et al. (2016) Strategic and transactional costs of corruption: Perspectives from
Vietnamese firms. Crime, Law and Social Change 65(4–5): 351–374.
Nix AJ, Decker S, Wolf C, et al. (2017) The social foundations of organizational corruption. Academy of
Management Proceedings 2017(1): 12773.
Nye JS (1967) Corruption and political development: A cost-benefit analysis. American Political Science
Review 61(2): 417–427.
Oji MAK and Oji VU (2010) Corruption in Nigeria: The Fight and Movement to Cure the Malady. University
Press of America.
Olsson SA (2014) Corruption and political participation. QoG Working Paper Series, 2014(12): 12.
O’Neill T and Hymel G (1994) All Politics is Local, and Other Rules of the Game (1st ed.). New York, NY:
Times Books.
Ortega B, Casquero A and Sanjuán J (2016) Corruption and convergence in human development: Evidence
from 69 countries during 1990–2012. Social Indicators Research 127(2): 691–719.
Paldam M (2001) Corruption and religion adding to the economic model. Kyklos 54(2–3): 383–413.
Paldam M (2002) The cross country pattern of corruption: Economics, culture, and the seesaw dynamics.
European Journal of Political Economy 18(2): 215–240.
Park CH and Kim K (2019) E-government as an anti-corruption tool: Panel data analysis across countries.
International Review of Administrative Sciences. DOI: 10.1177/0020852318822055.
Pedersen KH and Johannsen L (2018) Administrative processes as an anti-corruption tool? A view from pub-
lic employees in the Baltic states. Baltic Journal of Law and Politics 11(1): 131–156.
Pellegrini L and Gerlagh R (2004) Corruption's effect on growth and its transmission channels. Kyklos 57(3):
429–456.
Peña Miguel N and Cuadrado-Ballesteros B (2018) Is privatization related to corruption? An empirical analy-
sis of European countries. Public Management Review 21(1): 69–95.
Persson A, Rothstein B and Teorell J (2013) Why anticorruption reforms fail—Systemic corruption as a col-
lective action problem. Governance 26(3): 449–471.
Persson T and Tabellini G (2003) The Economic Effects of Constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Peters BG (1998) Comparative Politics: Theory and Methods. NYU Press.
Philp M (2016) Corruption definition and measurement. In: Sampford C, Shacklock A and Galtung F (eds)
Measuring Corruption. Routledge, 61–72.
Philp M (2017) Conceptualizing political corruption. In: Political Corruption. Routledge, 41–58.
Pinto J, Leana CR and Pil FK (2008) Corrupt organizations or organizations of corrupt individuals? Two
types of organization-level corruption. Academy of Management Review 33(3): 685–709.
Pinto PM and Zhu B (2016) Fortune or evil? The effect of inward foreign direct investment on corruption.
International Studies Quarterly 60(4): 693–705.
18 International Area Studies Review 00(0)

Qian X and Sandoval-Hernandez J (2016) Corruption distance and foreign direct investment. Emerging
Markets Finance and Trade 52(2): 400–419.
Quah JS (2017) Learning from Singapore’s effective anti-corruption strategy: Policy recommendations for
South Korea. Asian Education and Development Studies 6(1): 17–29.
Rehman HU and Naveed A (2007) Determinants of corruption and its relation to GDP (A panel study).
Journal of Political Studies 12(2): 27–59.
Rose-Ackerman S (1978) Corruption: A Study in Political Economy. Academic Press.
Rose-Ackerman S (1999) Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences, and Reform. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Rose-Ackerman S and Kornai J (eds) (2004) Building a Trustworthy State in Post-Socialist Transition. New
York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Rose-Ackerman S and Palifka BJ (2016) Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences, and Reform.
Cambridge University Press.
Rothstein B (2005) Social Traps and the Problem of Trust. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rothstein B (2011) The Quality of Government: Corruption, Social Trust, and Inequality in International
Perspective. University of Chicago Press.
Rothstein B and Uslaner E (2005) All for all. Equality, corruption, and social trust. World Politics 58(1):
41–72.
Sanmukhiya C (2019) E-governance dimensions in the Republic of Mauritius. Humanities and Social Sciences
Reviews 7(5): 264–279.
Schlicht E (1985) The shadow economy and morals: A note. In: Gaertner W and Wenig A (eds) The Economics
of the Shadow Economy. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, 265–271.
Schmidt D (2007) Anti-corruption: What do we know? Research on preventing corruption in the post-Com-
munist world. Political Studies Review 5(2): 202–232.
Scott J (1972) Comparative Political Corruption. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Simpson, et al. (2015) Chicago: Still the capital of corruption. Anti-Corruption report number 8. Available
at: https://pols.uic.edu/docs/default-source/chicago_politics/anti-corruption_reports/corruption-rpt-8_
final-052715.pdf?sfvrsn=9485fa9a_0 (accessed 12 February 2018).
Stapenhurst R (2000) The Media’s Role in Curbing Corruption. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute.
Suleiman N and Othman Z (2017) Corruption typology: A review of literature. Chinese Business Review
16(2): 102–108.
Svensson J (2005) Eight questions about corruption. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(3): 19–42.
Swamy A, Knack S, Lee Y, et al. (2001) Gender and corruption. Journal of Development Economics 64(1):
25–55.
Tavits M (2010) Why do people engage in corruption? The case of Estonia. Social Forces 88(3): 1257–1279.
Teachout Z (2014) Corruption in America: From Benjamin Franklin’s Snuff Box to Citizens United. Harvard
University Press.
Tickner P (2017) Fraud and Corruption in Public Services. Routledge.
Tirole J (1996) A theory of collective reputations (with applications to the persistence of corruption and to
firm quality). The Review of Economic Studies 63(1): 1–22.
Transparency International (2009) Global corruption report 2009: Corruption and the private sector. Available
at: www.transparency.org/whatwedo/publication/global_corruption_report_2009#page=25 (accessed
11 May 2019).
Transparency International (2015) Anti-corruption Agencies Strengthening Initiative. Research Implementation
Guide. Available at: www.transparency.org/files/content/activity/2015_ACAs_ImplementationGuide_
EN.pdf (accessed 12 February 2020).
Transparency International (2017) Corruption perceptions index 2016. Available at: www.transparency.org/
news/feature/corruption_perceptions_index_2016#table (accessed 1 February 2020).
Transparency International (2018a) Anti-corruption agency strengthening initiative. Available at: www.
transparency.org/whatwedo/activity/anti_corruption_agency_strengthening_initiative (accessed 7 April
2019).
Zimelis 19

Treisman D (2000) The causes of corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics 76(3):
399–457.
United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (2012) Jakarta statement on principles for anti-corruption agencies
[Press release]. Available at: www.unodc.org/documents/corruption/WG-Prevention/Art_6_Preventive_
anti-corruption_bodies/JAKARTA_STATEMENT_en.pdf (accessed 4 March 2019).
United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (2018) Documents, publications and tools: Prevention and fight
against corruption. Available at: www.unodc.org/unodc/en/corruption/publications.html (accessed 20
September 2019).
Wang Z and You Y (2016) The arrival of critical citizens: Decline of political trust and shifting public priori-
ties in China. International Review of Sociology 26(1): 105–124.
Ward PM (1989) Corruption, Development, and Inequality: Soft Touch or Hard Graft. New York: Routledge.
Warren M (2004) What does corruption mean in a democracy. American Journal of Political Science 48(2):
328–343.
Wendt AE (1987) The agent-structure problem in international relations theory. International Organization
41(3): 335–370.
Williams A and Le Billon P (eds) (2017) Corruption, Natural Resources and Development: From Resource
Curse to Political Ecology. Edward Elgar Publishing.
Williams R (ed.) (2000) Party Finance and Political Corruption. Basingstoke: Macmillan Press.
World Bank (2017) Combating corruption. Available at: www.worldbank.org/en/topic/governance/brief/anti-
corruption (accessed 14 February 2019).

View publication stats

You might also like