SSRN Id2055472

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 108

Liquidity Shocks and Stock Market Reactions

Turan G. Bali∗ Lin Peng† Yannan Shen‡ Yi Tang§


Georgetown University Baruch College Baruch College Fordham University

Abstract

We find that the stock market underreacts to stock level liquidity shocks: liquidity shocks
are not only positively associated with contemporaneous returns, but they also predict fu-
ture return continuations for up to six months. Long-short portfolios sorted on liquidity
shocks generate significant returns of 0.70% to 1.20% per month that are robust across
alternative shock measures and after controlling for risk factors and stock characteristics.
Furthermore, we show that investor inattention and illiquidity contribute to the underreac-
tion: while both are significant in explaining short-term return predictability of liquidity
shocks, the inattention-based mechanism is more powerful for the longer-term return pre-
dictability.
This draft: August 23, 2013

JEL classification code: G02, G10, G11, G12, G14, C13.


Keywords: Stock returns, liquidity shocks, stock market reactions, underreaction, investor attention.

∗ McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University, Washington, D.C. 20057. Email: tgb27@georgetown.edu. Phone: (202)

687-5388. Fax: (202) 687-4031.


† Department of Economics and Finance, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College / CUNY, One Bernard Baruch Way, 10-225, New

York, NY 10010. Email: lin.peng@baruch.cuny.edu. Phone: (646) 312-3491. Fax: (646) 312-3451.
‡ Department of Accounting, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College / CUNY, One Bernard Baruch Way, 12-225, New York, NY

10010. Email: yannan.shen@baruch.cuny.edu. Phone: (646) 312-3242. Fax: (646) 312-3161.


§ Schools of Business, Fordham University, 1790 Broadway, New York, NY 10019. Email: ytang@fordham.edu. Phone: (646) 312-8292.

Fax: (646) 312-8295.


We owe a great debt to David Hirshleifer and two anonymous referees for their extremely helpful comments and suggestions. We thank
Yakov Amihud, Andrew Ang, Tarun Chordia, Phil Dybvig, Pete Kyle, Jennifer Huang, Juan Londono, Robert Schwartz, Siew Hong Teoh,
Sheriden Titman, Robert Whitelaw, Wei Xiong and Jianfeng Yu for their insightful comments. We also benefited from discussions with Reena
Aggarwal, Linda Allen, Jim Angel, Bill Baber, Jim Bicksler, Henry Cao, Preeti Choudhary, Sandeep Dahiya, Ozgur Demirtas, Allan Eberhart,
Pengjie Gao, Gang Xiao, Olesya Grishchenko, Bin Han, Armen Hovakemian, Levent Guntay, Prem Jain, Soon-Ho Kim, Paul Kupiec, Yan
Li, Yuanzhi Li, Lalitha Naveen, George Panayotov, Lee Pinkowitz, Valery Polkovnichenko, Oleg Rytchkov, Mark Seasholes, Tugkan Tuzun,
Haluk Unal, Tan Wang, Yuan Wang, Bin Wei, Rohan Williamson, Liyan Yang, Harold Zhang, Xiaoyan Zhang, An Yan, Jialin Yu, Yuzhao
Zhang, Hao Zhou, and seminar participants at Baruch College, Beijing University, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC),
the Federal Reserve Board, Georgetown University, Southwestern University of Finance and Economics, Temple University, Villanova
University, 2012 Liquidity Risk Management Conference of Fordham University, 2012 FMA Conference, 2012 Deutsche Bank Global Quant
Conference, 2012 The Chinese Finance Association Best Paper Symposium, 2012 State Street Quant Forum, 2013 Triple Crown Conference,
2013 China International Conference in Finance, National University of Singapore seventh Annual Risk Management Conference, and 2013
Summer Institute of Finance. Turan Bali thanks the Research Foundation of McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University.
Lin Peng thanks the PSC-CUNY Research Foundation and Wasserman Endownment BCF for financial support. All errors remain our
responsibility.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Liquidity Shocks and Stock Market Reactions

Abstract

We find that the stock market underreacts to stock level liquidity shocks: liquidity shocks
are not only positively associated with contemporaneous returns, but they also predict fu-
ture return continuations for up to six months. Long-short portfolios sorted on liquidity
shocks generate significant returns of 0.70% to 1.20% per month that are robust across
alternative shock measures and after controlling for risk factors and stock characteristics.
Furthermore, we show that investor inattention and illiquidity contribute to the underreac-
tion: while both are significant in explaining short-term return predictability of liquidity
shocks, the inattention-based mechanism is more powerful for the longer-term return pre-
dictability.

JEL classification code: G02, G10, G11, G12, G14, C13.

Keywords: Stock returns, liquidity shocks, stock market reactions, underreaction, investor attention.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


1. Introduction

The liquidity of a stock refers to the degree to which a significant quantity can be traded within a short

time frame without incurring a large transaction cost or adverse price impact. It is well documented

that the level of individual stock illiquidity is positively priced in the cross-section of expected stock

returns.1 Amihud and Mendelson (1986) first propose this hypothesis and argue that investors demand

a premium for less liquid stocks, so that less liquid stocks should have higher average returns.2

Liquidity is also time-varying, and subject to shocks that have persistent effects (i.e., negative liq-

uidity shocks predict lower future liquidity).3 The most recent financial crisis and the heightened focus

on liquidity during the crisis show the importance of considering the effect of liquidity shocks on stock

returns. Given the documented positive relation between stock level illiquidity and expected returns,

a persistent negative shock to a security’s liquidity should result in low contemporaneous returns and

high future returns, and vice versa, if the effect of shock is immediately incorporated into security

prices. This has been argued by Amihud (2002), Jones (2002), and Acharya and Pedersen (2005),

among others.

However, the above prediction of a negative relation between liquidity shocks and future returns

may not hold in a market in which information is not fully reflected into prices due to market frictions.

Thus, studying market reactions to liquidity shocks can generate important insights on how the market

processes information about liquidity shocks and on the information efficiency of financial markets.

There are two potential market frictions that prevent public information from being incorporated

in security prices: limited investor attention and illiquidity. There has been an increasing body of em-

pirical evidence suggesting that investor inattention can lead to underreaction to information. These
1 See, among others, Amihud and Mendelson (1986, 1989), Brennan and Subrahmanyam (1996), Eleswarapu (1997),
Brennan, Chordia, and Subrahmanyam (1998), Datar, Naik, and Radcliffe (1998), Amihud (2002), and Hasbrouck (2009).
2 Theoretical studies that investigate the relation between liquidity and asset prices include Amihud and Mendelson (1986),

Constantinides (1986), Heaton and Lucas (1996), Vayanos (1998), Duffie, Garleanu, and Pedersen (2000, 2003), Huang
(2003), Garleanu and Pedersen (2004), and Lo, Mamaysky, and Wang (2004), among others.
3 See, for example, Amihud (2002), Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2000, 2001), Hasbrouck and Seppi (2001), Hu-

berman and Halka (2001), Jones (2002), and Pastor and Stambaugh (2003).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


studies show that, due to limited investor attention, stock prices underreact to public information about

stock fundamentals, such as new products, earnings news, demographic information, innovative effi-

ciency, or information about related stocks (e.g., Huberman and Regev (2001), Hirshleifer, Hou, Teoh,

and Zhang (2004), Hou and Moskowitz (2005), Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh (2009), Hong, Torous, and

Valkanov (2007), DellaVigna and Pollet (2007, 2009), Barber and Odean (2008), Cohen and Frazzini

(2008), and Hirshleifer, Hsu, and Li (2012)).

This paper focuses on liquidity shocks, which can be viewed as a type of public information on liq-

uidity.4 Compared to the direct and well-defined information events studied in the previous literature,

liquidity shocks are not well-defined and their pricing implications are harder to interpret by average

investors. As argued by Hirshleifer, Hsu, and Li (2012), investors would “have greater difficulty pro-

cessing information that is less tangible”, the indirect and illusive nature of liquidity news thus makes

the investors’ attention constraints more likely to be binding. As a result, stock market can under-react

to liquidity shocks. Moreover, as argued in the model of Peng and Xiong (2006), an investor who op-

timizes the amount of attention allocation would allocate more attention to systematic shocks and less

to or even completely ignore stock-specific shocks. Thus, a strong case can be made for underreaction

to stock level liquidity shocks based on theories of investor attention. Alternatively, when a stock is

harder to trade due to its illiquidity, price discovery can be delayed, resulting in slow price adjustments

following liquidity shocks.

To investigate how the stock market reacts to stock level liquidity shocks, we first examine the

immediate effect of liquidity shocks and find that it is positive and significantly related to contempo-

raneous stock returns. However, in terms of the relation between liquidity shocks and future returns,

contrary to the negative relation as one would expect in a full, informationally efficient setting, we

find the relation continues to be positive and highly significant. Depending on the proxy for liquidity

shock, decile portfolios that are long in stocks with positive liquidity shocks and short in stocks with
4 Liquidity shocks can be triggered by public information releases such as earnings announcements, company events such
as stock splits and share buy backs, the return performance of stocks, sensitivity of stocks to changes in market liquidity, or
due to concerns about trading against informed traders in times of heightened uncertainty.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


negative liquidity shocks generate a one-month ahead raw and risk-adjusted returns of 0.75% to 1.23%

per month for equal-weighted portfolios, and 0.67% to 1.17% for value-weighted portfolios. The pre-

dictive power of liquidity shocks on future returns remains economically and statistically significant

for up to six months.

This evidence suggests that the market underreacts to stock level liquidity shocks. Although nega-

tive and persistent liquidity shocks do result in decreases in stock prices due to a higher future liquidity

risk premium, the prices adjustment is not complete within the same month. As a result, there is a con-

siderable amount of continuation of negative returns and the effects of shocks are not fully incorporated

into prices until months later. The opposite is true for positive liquidity shocks.

We further investigate the underlying mechanisms that may contribute to the underreaction to liq-

uidity shocks. The investor attention theory predicts that the degree of underreaction to liquidity shocks,

as measured by its return predictability, should be more pronounced for stocks that receive less investor

attention. On the other hand, the illiquidity-based mechanism predicts that the positive return pre-

dictability of liquidity shocks should be stronger for the less liquid stocks.

We divide our sample into subgroups based on investor attention proxies and illiquidity and find

that the positive link between liquidity shocks and future stock returns is indeed stronger for stocks that

receive less attention (small stocks, stocks with low analyst coverage and institutional ownership), as

well as for less liquid stocks. To gauge the relative importance of the attention- versus the illiquidity-

based mechanisms for underreaction, we perform Fama-MacBeth regression analysis and include both

attention proxies and illiquidity as interaction variables to liquidity shocks. We find that both the

attention proxies and illiquidity help explain the cross-sectional return predictability of liquidity shocks.

While both mechanisms are significant for one-month ahead return prediction, the inattention-based

mechanism is more powerful in predicting two- to four-month ahead returns. Our results thus suggest

that both investor inattention and illiquidity can drive stock market underreactions to liquidity shocks,

but investor attention is a more dominant factor compared to illiquidity.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Our results are based on three measures of liquidity shocks. The first is the negative difference

between Amihud’s (Amihud (2002)) illiquidity measure and its past 12-month mean.5 In addition

to this simple, nonparametric measure, we use a parametric methodology to construct a conditional

measure of liquidity shocks using an ARMA(1,1) specification for Amihud’s illiquidity.

One might argue that innovations in the Amihud’s illiquidity measure may be driven by news

announcements, i.e., the market makers update prices upon news without much trading, rather than

real changes in liquidity. To account for this possibility and ensure that our results are robust, we also

use an alternative measure of liquidity shocks based on the changes in bid-ask spreads. The results are

similar to those from the changes in the Amihud’s illiquidity measure.

In addition to the univariate portfolio level analyses, we analyze double-sorted portfolios and per-

form stock level Fama-MacBeth regressions to confirm that the relation between liquidity shocks and

future returns is robust by employing an extensive list of control variables. Liquidity shocks can be cor-

related with several liquidity-related factors that are known to be related to expected returns. Brennan

and Subrahmanyam (1996), Eleswarapu (1997), Brennan, Chordia, and Subrahmanyam (1998), Datar,

Naik, and Radcliffe (1998), Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2001), Amihud (2002) and Hasbrouck

(2009) have shown that the stock level illiquidity is an important determinant of expected returns. Chor-

dia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2000), Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) and Acharya and Pedersen (2005)

argue that systematic liquidity risk is related to expected stock returns. We control for the level of illiq-

uidity as well as exposures to systematic liquidity risks and find that our results remain intact. Expected

returns can also be affected by the volatility of liquidity if agents care about the risk associated with this

variation or take advantage of time varying liquidity. While Chordia, Subrahmanyam, and Anshuman

(2001) and Pereira and Zhang (2010) find a negative relation between the volatility of liquidity and the
5 The Amihud’s measure of stock level illiquidity has been used by Acharya and Pedersen (2005) and Chordia, Huh, and

Subrahmanyam (2009), among others. This measure is motivated by Kyle’s (1985) notion of liquidity, the response of price to
order flow (Kyle’s lambda). By this definition, a stock is considered to be illiquid if a small trading volume generates a large
price change. Amihud (2002) shows that this measure is positively and strongly related to Kyle’s price impact measure and
the fixed-cost component of the bid-ask spread. Hasbrouck (2009) examines a comprehensive set of daily liquidity measures
and finds that the Amihud’s measure has the highest correlation with the price impact coefficient computed with data on
intraday transactions and quotes.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


cross-section of expected returns, Akbas, Armstrong, and Petkova (2010) find a positive relation. Our

results remain significant after controlling for the volatility of liquidity.

We control for other risk factors and stock characteristics that can predict cross-sectional returns:

size and book-to-market (Fama and French (1992, 1993)), price momentum (Jegadeesh and Titman

(1993)), short-term reversal (Jegadeesh (1990)), analysts earnings forecast dispersion (Diether, Malloy,

and Scherbina (2002)), idiosyncratic volatility (Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006, 2009)) and its

changes, and preference for lottery-like assets (Bali, Cakici, and Whitelaw (2011)). After controlling

for a large set of stock return predictors, the positive relation between liquidity shocks and future returns

remains highly significant.

Furthermore, this economically and statistically significant relation between liquidity shocks and

future returns is robust to microstructure effects and across various subsamples including expansionary

and recessionary periods as well as the five decades in our sample. The results also hold when we use

different portfolio weighting schemes, and when we restrict the sample to NYSE/Amex, NYSE, and

S&P 500 stocks.

Given that liquidity is endogenous, it is possible that the return predictability of liquidity shocks

picks up the market’s underreaction to other news or mechanisms that coincide with liquidity changes.

While a comprehensive exploration of the source of liquidity shocks is beyond the scope of this paper,

we attempt to control for two specific sources that have the potential to affect liquidity.

First, as shown by Beaver (1968), Ball and Brown (1968), and Bernard and Thomas (1989, 1990),

a stock’s earnings announcements can lead to both future return predictability and changes in trading

volume. As changes in volume can be associated with liquidity changes, we control for the information

contained in earnings announcements and find that the return predictability of liquidity shocks is still

statistically and economically significant.

Alternatively, changes in trading volume may be driving the effect of liquidity shocks. As shown

by Gervais, Kaniel, and Mingelgrin (2001), stocks experiencing abnormally high (low) trading volume

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


over a day or a week also tend to have high (low) abnormal returns in the following month. To ensure

that the effect of liquidity shocks is not driven by unexpected trading volume, we follow Gervais et al.

(2001) and classify stocks into low, normal and high volume portfolios based on volume changes and

define dummy variables based on the portfolio that a stock belongs to. We further construct a contin-

uous volume shock variable in the same fashion as our liquidity shock variable. Our results remain

robust after controlling for both volume change measures, suggesting that the return predictability of

liquidity shocks is distinct from the abnormal volume effect.

Generally speaking, if markets are rational and react to information promptly, value relevant shocks

(information releases and company events) should have been incorporated into prices already and any

of their predictability should have been captured by the predictability of past returns. It is possible that

our results can be explained by investors underreaction to liquidity shocks or some other exogenous

variable that is correlated with liquidity. Nevertheless, our findings remain significant after controlling

for past returns and past earnings surprises, as well as an extensive list of other factors, suggesting that

the return predictability of liquidity shocks is a new finding that can not be explained by mechanisms

proposed in the existing literature.

The paper contributes to the literature on the effect of investor inattention on stock price dynamics

by introducing a new liquidity dimension and by providing evidence that the theory of investor inat-

tention is important in understanding stock market underreactions to liquidity shocks. In addition, the

paper also contributes to the literature on liquidity and stock returns by focusing on the time variation

of liquidity and by providing the first piece of evidence of stock market underreaction to stock level liq-

uidity shocks. The results suggest that liquidity shocks and how the stock market reacts are important

in predicting the cross section of future stock returns.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides the data and variable defi-

nitions. Section 3 examines the cross-sectional predictive relation between liquidity shocks and stock

returns. Section 4 investigates the underlying causes of the asset pricing anomaly. Section 5 provides a

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


battery of robustness checks for our main findings. Section 6 discusses alternative mechanisms for the

positive relation between liquidity shocks and future returns. Section 7 concludes the paper.

2. Data

Our sample includes all common stocks traded on the NYSE, Amex, and Nasdaq exchanges, covering

the period from July 1963 through December 2010. We eliminate stocks with price per share less

than $5 or more than $1,000. The daily and monthly return and volume data are from CRSP. We adjust

stock returns for delisting in order to avoid survivorship bias (Shumway (1997)).6 Accounting variables

are obtained from the Merged CRSP/Computstat database. Analysts’ earnings forecasts come from

the I/B/E/S dataset and cover the period from 1983 to 2010. Spreads are calculated using Trade and

Quotes (TAQ) data for the period of 1993-2010. The institutional ownership data are from Thompson

13F filings for the period of 1980-2010.

2.1. Measures of liquidity and liquidity shocks

Following Amihud (2002), we measure the illiquidity of stock i in month t, denoted ILLIQ, as the

average daily ratio of the absolute stock return to the dollar trading volume within the month:

 
|Ri,d |
ILLIQi,t = Avg , (1)
VOLDi,d
6 Specifically, when a stock is delisted, we use the delisting return from CRSP, if available. Otherwise, we assume the
delisting return is -100%, unless the reason for delisting is coded as 500 (reason unavailable), 520 (went to OTC), 551-573,
580 (various reasons), 574 (bankruptcy), or 584 (does not meet exchange financial guidelines). For these observations, we
assume that the delisting return is -30%.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


where Ri,d and VOLDi,d are the daily return and dollar trading volume for stock i on day d, respectively.7

A stock is required to have at least 15 daily return observations in month t. The Amihud’s illiquidity

measure is scaled by 106 .

We first use a parsimonious model for liquidity shock (denoted LIQU), defined as the negative

difference between ILLIQ and its past 12-month average:


LIQUi,t = − ILLIQi,t − AV GILLIQi|t−12,t−1 , (2)

where AV GILLIQi|t−12,t−1 is the mean of illiquidity over the past 12 months. Positive (negative) liq-

uidity shocks indicate an increase (decrease) in liquidity relative to its past 12-month average.

We also adopt a parametric methodology to define a conditional measure of liquidity shocks (de-

noted LIQCU). The Amihud’s illiquidity measure of stock i is assumed to follow an ARMA(1,1) pro-

cess:

ILLIQi,t = α0,i + α1,i ILLIQi,t−1 + α2,i εi,t−1 + εi,t , (3)

where εi,t is normally distributed with a time-invariant standard deviation.8 The parameters are esti-

mated via the maximum likelihood method using a 60-month rolling sample that requires a minimum

of 24 observations and is updated on a monthly basis. We define the conditional liquidity shock, de-

noted LIQCU, as the negative difference between the realized ILLIQ of stock i and its conditional mean

estimated from the ARMA(1,1) model in month t, −εi,t in equation (3).9


7 Following Gao and Ritter (2010), we adjust for institutional features of the way that Nasdaq and NYSE/Amex volume
are counted. Specifically, we divide Nasdaq volume by 2.0, 1.8, 1.6, and 1 for the periods prior to February 2001, between
February 2001 and December 2001, between January 2002 and December 2003, and January 2004 and later years, respec-
tively.
8 We used the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and Schwarz Bayesian Criterion (SBC) to determine the optimal lag

length for ARMA specification. Since the improvement in terms of AIC and SBC is minimal when we use larger number of
lags, we decided to use the most parsimonious model in equation (3). Moreover, the results from alternative specifications of
the ARMA model are similar to those based on the ARMA(1,1) specification.
9 At an earlier stage of the study, we construct liquidity shocks as standardized shocks, in which liquidity is demeaned and

standardized by its standard deviation. We estimate mean and standard deviation of liquidity using past 12-month liquidity
values. Alternatively, we model liquidity using a ARMA(1,1)-GARCH(1,1) model in which the conditional mean and condi-
tional volatility of liquidity are used to construct standardized liquidity shocks. The results from the two alternative liquidity
shock measures are very similar to those reported in our tables, and are available upon request.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


We further adopt an alternative measure of liquidity based on the volume-weighted effective relative

spread (SPRD).10 Spreads are calculated using Trade and Quotes (TAQ) data covering the period of

1993–2010. We obtain National Best Bid and Offer (NBBO) following Hasbrouck’s procedure.11 We

apply several filters to delete invalid trades and quotes. We delete trades: if price is negative or zero or

trading volume is negative or zero; if correction indicator is not 0 (no correction) or 1 (contain corrected

value); if sale condition is not blank, “∗”, “@” or “E”; if first trade of the day; and if price is greater

than 1.5 or less than 0.5 times the lagged price. We delete quotes if quote condition is not 3 (closing),

10 (opening), or 12 (regular); if bid (denoted bid) is less than or equal to zero; if bid is greater than or

equal to offer (denoted ofr); and if o f r − bid > 0.5 × bid. In matching trade and quote files, for data

prior to 1999 we follow the 5-second lag rule proposed by Lee and Ready (1991), and for data in 1999

and later years, we follow Bessembinder and Venkataraman (2010) and do not apply time lag. The

volume-weighted effective relative spread is scaled by 102 .

We construct the stock’s negative spread shock (SPRDU) as:

SPRDUi,t = −(SPRDi,t − AV GSPRDi|t−12,t−1 ), (4)

where AV GSPRDi|t−12,t−1 is the average over the past 12 months. A positive (negative) SPRDU is

associated with decrease (increase) in effective spread relative to its past 12-month average, and hence,

increase (decrease) in liquidity.

2.2. Control variables

We employ a large set of control variables in our tests. Unless otherwise stated, all variables are

measured as of the end of portfolio formation month (i.e., month t) and require a minimum of 15 daily

observations for all variables computed from daily data.12


10 Our findings are robust to alternative spread measures, such as the quoted bid-ask spread and the equal-weighted effective

spread.
11 See http://people.stern.nyu.edu/jhasbrou/.
12 A detailed description of the control variables is provided in the Appendix.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


We estimate stock’s market beta following Fama and French (1992), using monthly returns over

the prior 60 months if available (or a minimum of 24 months). The stock’s size (LNME) is computed

as the natural logarithm of the product of the price per share and the number of shares outstanding

(in million dollars). Following Fama and French (1992, 1993, and 2000), the natural logarithm of the

book-to-market equity ratio at the end of June of year t, denoted LNBM, is computed as the book value

of stockholders’ equity, plus deferred taxes and investment tax credit (if available), minus the book

value of preferred stock for the last fiscal year end in t − 1, scaled by the market value of equity at

end of December of t − 1. Depending on availability, the redemption, liquidation, or par value (in that

order) is used to estimate the book value of preferred stock.

Following Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), momentum (MOM) is the cumulative return of a stock

over a period of 11 months ending one month prior to the portfolio formation month. Following Je-

gadeesh (1990), short-term reversal (REV) is defined as the stock return over the prior month. The

stock’s monthly co-skewness (COSKEW) is constructed as in Harvey and Siddique (2000) using the

monthly return observations over the prior 60 months (if at least 24 months are available). The monthly

idiosyncratic volatility of stock i (IVOL) is computed as in Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006).

The stock’s extreme positive return (MAX) is defined as its maximum daily return in a month fol-

lowing Bali, Cakici, and Whitelaw (2011). Following Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002), analyst

earnings forecast dispersion (DISP) is the standard deviation of annual earnings-per-share forecasts

scaled by the absolute value of the average outstanding forecast.

It is possible that liquidity shocks may coincide with earnings shocks and it is well known that earn-

ings shocks are followed by a post announcement drift. To control for this effect, we follow Ball and

Brown (1968) and Bernard and Thomas (1989, 1990) and construct standardized unexpected earnings

(SUE), defined as changes in earnings from four quarters ago, standardized by its standard deviation

over the past eight quarters (with a minimum of four UE observations available).13
13 Our results are robust to using net assets per share, net book value of equity per share, total liabilities per share, and price
per share as the scaling variables.

10

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Since a stock’s liquidity and trading volume are positively related, there is a concern that our liq-

uidity shock variable may be capturing the high volume return premium effect documented by Gervais

et al. (2001). To control for the high volume return premium, we follow Gervais et al. (2001) and clas-

sify stocks into low, normal, and high volume portfolios. If the dollar trading volume on the one-day

formation period is among the highest (lowest) 10% of the daily dollar trading volume over the prior

49 trading days, the stock is classified as a high (low) volume stock, otherwise the stock is classified as

normal volume stock. We then create two dummy variables: the high-volume dummy variable (GKMH )

is 1 if a stock belongs to the high volume group and zero otherwise; the low-volume dummy variable

(GKML ) equal to 1 if a stock resides in the low volume portfolio and zero otherwise. In addition to

the GKM variables, we further control for volume changes by constructing a continuous variable for

abnormal dollar volume (VOLDU) in the same fashion as we define the liquidity shock. That is, we

subtract its past 12-month average from monthly dollar volume.

We also control for a variety of liquidity-based variables. Following Chordia, Subrahmanyam,

and Anshuman (2001), the standard deviation of turnover (SDTURN) is computed as the standard

deviation of monthly turnover (TURN) over the past 12 months. Following Akbas, Armstrong, and

Petkova (2010), the coefficient of variation in the Amihud’s illiquidity (CVILLIQ) is computed as

the standard deviation of the daily Amihud’s illiquidity measure in a month scaled by the monthly

Amihud’s illiquidity measure.

Following Pastor and Stambaugh (2003), we estimate the stock’s liquidity exposure (PS) to inno-

vations in the aggregate liquidity factor.14 To capture covariances of a stock’s own return and liquidity

with the market return and market liquidity, we follow Acharya and Pedersen (2005) and estimate the

four betas. BETA1 is the market beta, BETA2 corresponds to the covariation of a stock’s liquidity with

the market liquidity, BETA3 captures the covariation between a stock’s return and market liquidity, and

BETA4 captures the covariation between a stock’s liquidity and market returns. More specifically, each

month, we classify common stocks listed on NYSE, Amex and Nasdaq into 25 test portfolios sorted on
14 Innovations in aggregate liquidity factor are downloaded from Lubos Pastor’s website.

11

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


the average daily Amihud’s illiquidity over the previous year using NYSE breakpoints. We then nor-

malize the Amihud’s illiquidity measure as suggested by Acharya and Pedersen (2005) and estimate

the monthly innovations of illiquidity for the market and the test portfolios by extracting the residuals

from an AR(2) model using a 60-month rolling window with at least 24 monthly observations. Using

these illiquidity innovations and returns, we estimate the liquidity betas for testing portfolios and assign

the betas of the illiquidity portfolio to stocks that comprise it.

We further control for a stock’s exposure to the fixed and variable components of Sadka’s (2006)

liquidity factor.15 For each month, a stock’s illiquidity risk loadings on the fixed and the variable

components (denoted SADKAF and SADKAV, respectively) are estimated using monthly return data

over the prior 60 months with a minimum of 24 monthly observations available after controlling for the

monthly market, size and book-to-market factors.

Finally, in Section 4, we investigate the pricing effect associated with liquidity shocks in conjunc-

tion with alternative measures of investor attention. We use several measures to capture the degree

of investor attention: (i) stock size (LNME); (ii) analyst coverage (CVRG), computed as the natural

logarithm of the number of analysts covering the stock in the portfolio formation month; and (iii) in-

stitutional holdings (INST), defined as quarterly fractional institutional ownership as of the portfolio

formation month.16

2.3. Summary statistics

We first examine the time series properties of stock level illiquidity measures and find that the ILLIQ

and SPRD variables are highly auto-correlated with an average AR(1) coefficient of 0.69 and 0.74

across all stocks over the full sample period. The autocorrelation coefficients are consistent with evi-

dence established in the previous literature that shocks to liquidity have persistent effects: a negative

liquidity shock leads to lower levels of future liquidity, and vice versa.
15 We download the time series of the monthly fixed and variable components of the illiquidity factor covering the period

of April 1984 to December 2010 from Ronnie Sadka’s webpage.


16 Following Cremers and Nair (2005), INST is set to zero if missing in the database.

12

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Panel A of Table 1 provides the time-series averages of the cross-sectional descriptive statistics

for the aforementioned variables. Consistent with improved stock liquidity over time, the mean and

median of the alternative measures of liquidity shocks are positive over our sample period. Liquidity

shocks also show substantial cross-sectional variation with an average standard deviation in the range

of four (when liquidity shock is measured by SPRDU), eight (when measured by LIQU) and to twelve

(when measured by LIQCU) times the corresponding mean.

Panel B of Table 1 reports the time-series averages of the cross-sectional correlation coefficients for

the variables. Panel B reveals that the alternative measures of liquidity shocks are highly correlated with

an average correlation coefficient ranging from 21% (between SPRDU and LIQCU), 43% (between

LIQU and SPRDU) to 53% (between LIQU and LIQCU). The average correlation coefficients between

the contemporaneous stock return (REV) and LIQU, SPRDU and LIQCU are, respectively, 13%, 12%

and 11%, and highly significant. This is consistent with liquidity is priced, that a positive and persistent

liquidity shock reduces future liquidity risk premium and increases the contemporaneous stock price.

However, there is preliminary evidence that the market continues to react to liquidity shocks in the

future months: the average correlation coefficient between liquidity shocks, proxied by LIQU, SPRDU

and LIQCU, and one-month ahead stock returns (RET) are, respectively, 2.4%, 2.0% and 1.7%, all

positive and significant at the 1% level. The liquidity shock variables are also highly correlated with

many known return predictors such as illiquidity level (ILLIQ), size (LNME), momentum (MOM), and

return volatility (IVOL). LIQU is positively related to VOLDU, but negatively correlated with GKMH ,

suggesting that our liquidity shock variable is distinct from the volume change variable analyzed in

Gervais et al. (2001). These variables serve as our controls in the following analysis.

3. Cross-sectional Relation between Liquidity Shocks and Stock Returns

The significantly positive correlation between liquidity shocks and one-month ahead stock returns sug-

gests that negative liquidity shocks (reductions in liquidity) are related to lower future stock returns, and

13

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


vice versa. In this section, we perform formal analysis, and show that the pricing effect documented in

this paper cannot be explained by other risk factors and stock characteristics that are known to predict

future stock returns in the cross-section.

3.1. Univariate portfolio-level analysis

We begin our empirical analysis with univariate portfolio sorts. For each month, we sort common

stocks trading on NYSE/Amex/Nasdaq into decile portfolios based on one of the three proxies for

liquidity shocks – LIQU, SPRDU and LIQCU, and compare the performance of high liquidity-shock

portfolio to low liquidity-shock portfolio in the contemporaneous and the following months. The NYSE

breakpoints are used to alleviate the concern that the CRSP decile breakpoints are distorted by the large

number of small Nasdaq and Amex stocks.17

We first examine the effect of liquidity shocks on same-month returns. Table 2 reports the averages

of returns, three-factor Fama and French (1993) alphas of each of these LIQU-sorted deciles, as well as

portfolio characteristics: liquidity shock (LIQU), monthly illiquidity level (ILLIQ), and market share.

The t-statistics are calculated using Newey-West (1987) standard errors and are reported in parentheses.

The average liquidity shock (LIQU) increases from -0.90 in Decile 1 to 1.31 in Decile 10, which implies

that stocks in the lowest LIQU decile (Decile 1) have negative liquidity shocks (i.e., decrease in the level

of liquidity), whereas stocks in the highest LIQU decile (Decile 10) have positive liquidity shocks (i.e.,

increase in the level of liquidity).

Table 2 shows a positive relation between LIQU and the same-month returns: the average return for

stocks in the highest liquidity shock decile is 4.51% for the equal-weighted returns and 5.27% for the

value-weighted returns. Those in the lowest liquidity shock decile post an equal-weighted average re-

turn of -0.39% and a value-weighted average return of 0.04%. The equal-weighted and value-weighted

return differences between the highest and lowest LIQU decile portfolios are, respectively, 4.90% and
17 At an earlier stage of the study, we also used the CRSP breakpoints with equal number of stocks in decile portfolios. The

results from univariate and bivariate portfolio sorts based on the CRSP breakpoints are similar to those reported in our tables,
and they are available upon request.

14

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


5.23% that are highly significant and cannot be explained by the Fama-French factors.18 These results

indicate that the initial reaction to liquidity shocks is consistent with the findings of positive illiquidity

risk premium in the prior literature: a negative and persistent liquidity shock increases future expected

illiquidity and therefore leads to an immediate decrease in the stock price due to a higher liquidity

premium.

Table 2 also reports some characteristics of the portfolios sorted by liquidity shocks. As shown in

the last two columns, stocks in the extreme deciles (Decile 1 and 10) are relatively smaller and more

illiquid compared to stocks in Deciles 2 to 9. More specifically, stocks in Decile 1 (with the lowest

liquidity shocks) have an average market share of 4.73% and average illiquidity of 2.65, whereas stocks

in Decile 10 (with the highest liquidity shocks) have an average market share of 2.84% and average

illiquidity of 0.99. Note that liquidity shocks do not seem to have a monotonic relation with stock size

or the level of illiquidity.

Table 3 presents the average one-month ahead returns on portfolios sorted by liquidity shocks. The

first four columns present results with LIQU, based on the changes in the Amihud’s illiquidity measure,

as the measure of a liquidity shock. The equal-weighted (value-weighted) portfolio raw returns increase

almost monotonically with liquidity shocks: from 0.51% (0.43%) per month for the lowest LIQU decile

to 1.69% (1.60%) per month for the highest LIQU decile. The return differential between Decile 10

and Decile 1 is 1.18% for the equally weighted portfolio and 1.17% for the value-weighted portfolio.

The corresponding Fama-French three-factor adjusted returns are 1.23% and 1.17%, respectively. All

the return differentials are statistically significant at the 1% level.

Columns 5-8 present results with liquidity shocks measured as shocks in the bid-ask spreads

(SPRDU).19 The equal-weighted (value-weighted) raw return on the SPRDU portfolios increases with
18 In the online appendix, Panels A and B of Table A1 summarize the contemporaneous relation between liquidity shocks

and stock returns revealed by univariate portfolio sorts on the two other liquidity shock measures: SPRDU and LIQCU.
The results are qualitatively similar to those based on LIQU. The average contemporaneous return differences between the
highest and the lowest liquidity shock portfolios are in the range of 4.42% to 5.26% varying with the liquidity shock proxy
and weighting scheme used in the analysis.
19 We should note that SPRDU are calculated based on TAQ data for the period of 1993-2010, while LIQU and LIQCU are

calculated from CRSP data from 1963-2010.

15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


SPRDU as well: from 0.50% (0.56%) per month for the lowest SPRDU decile portfolio to 1.42%

(1.23%) per month for the highest SPRDU decile portfolio. The equal-weighted (value-weighted) raw

return differences and the corresponding alphas are, respectively, 0.92% and 0.98% (0.67% and 0.79%)

per month between the High- and Low-SPRDU portfolios. These return differentials are strongly sta-

tistically significant as well.

Columns 9-12 report results when liquidity measure is based on LIQCU, residuals from the ARMA(1,1)

regression with the Amihud’s illiquidity measure. The equal-weighted (value-weighted) raw return on

the LIQCU portfolios increases monotonically: from 0.77% (0.60%) per month for Decile 1 to 1.52%

(1.40%) per month for Decile 10. The equal-weighted (value-weighted) raw return differences and the

corresponding alphas are, respectively, 0.75% and 0.76% (0.80% and 0.78%) per month between the

High- and Low-LIQCU portfolios and they are highly significant.

Overall, these results indicate that, regardless of the liquidity shock proxies or the portfolio weight-

ing scheme that we use, a portfolio that buys stocks in the highest liquidity shock decile and shorts

stocks in the lowest liquidity shock decile yields both economically and statistically significant returns

ranging between 0.67% to 1.23% in the next month. Combined with the previous result that liquidity

shocks are also positively associated with contemporaneous month stock returns, our findings suggest

that the stock market under-reacts to liquidity shocks and the reaction continues in the following month.

3.2. Bivariate portfolio-level analysis

As discussed earlier, liquidity shocks are correlated with many well-known characteristics that forecast

cross-sectional stock returns, such as level of illiquidity, past return characteristics (reversal, momen-

tum), co-skewness, idiosyncratic volatility, analyst disagreement, and demand for lottery-like stocks.

As such, there is some concern that our liquidity shock proxies may capture effects other than liquidity

shocks. We control for these other factors with bivariate sorts in this subsection and Fama-MacBeth

regressions in Section 3.4.

16

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


We perform bivariate sorts on LIQU in combination with market beta (BETA), size (LNME), book-

to-market ratio (LNBM), momentum (MOM), short-term reversal (REV), co-skewness (COSKEW), id-

iosyncratic volatility (IVOL), extreme positive daily return (MAX), analyst dispersion (DISP), earnings

shocks (SUE), a variety of liquidity-based variables including Amihud’s illiquidity measure (ILLIQ),

coefficient of variation in Amihud’s illiquidity (CVILLIQ), standard deviation of turnover (SDTURN),

liquidity exposure (PS) of Pastor and Stambaugh (2003), liquidity exposures (BETA1 to BETA4) of

Acharya and Pedersen (2005), and exposures to the fixed and variable components of Sadka’s liquidity

factor (SADKAF and SADKAV), and two variables for abnormal dollar trading volume (GKM and

VOLDU).20

Table 4 reports the results of conditional bivariate sorts.21 Stocks are first sorted into quintile

portfolios based on one of the aforementioned control variables except GKM, for which stocks are first

sorted into high, medium and low groups following Gervais et al. (2001), and then into LIQU quintiles

within each control variable quintile. We report the returns of the LIQU portfolios, averaged across

the control groups to produce quintile portfolios with dispersion in LIQU but with similar levels of the

control variable. The predictive power of LIQU remains intact in bivariate portfolios. The average raw

return differences, ranging from 0.75% to 1.35% per month, are all significant at the 1% level based

on the Newey-West t-statistics. The corresponding alphas are also significantly positive, ranging from

0.85% to 1.36% per month.

Table A2 in the online appendix reports the full return matrix for the double sorted portfolios.

The return difference and the alpha between the High- and Low-LIQU portfolios for each control

quintile are all positive and highly significant. In particular, Panel U of Table A2 shows that the return

differential for High- and Low-LIQU portfolio remains positive and significant at 0.71% per month

even for the lowest abnormal volume groups defined as in Gervais et al. (2001), suggesting that the

predictive power of liquidity shocks is not due to the high volume return premium effect. Overall,
20 Due to space constraints, we report the results of bivariate sorts based on the two alternative liquidity shock measures,
SPRDU and LIQCU in the online appendix, Table A3. It shows that the effect of liquidity shocks on predicting one-month
ahead returns remains robust after controlling for each of these other factors.
21 Our findings remain intact when independent bivariate sorts are used. The results are available upon request.

17

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


the double-sorted portfolio results confirm that these aforementioned control variables alone fail to

subsume the return predictive power of the liquidity shock variables.

3.3. Controlling for volume and volatility shocks

Two of our liquidity shock variables (LIQU and LIQCU) depend on the Amihud’s illiquidity measure

that can be viewed as volatility over volume. Hence, the predictive power of liquidity shocks may

potentially be driven by shocks to volume and/or volatility. We investigate this issue based on the

conditional bivariate sorts on liquidity shocks after controlling for volume and volatility shocks.

We start our analysis by forming 5×5 bivariate portfolios of liquidity shocks (LIQU) and unex-

pected shocks to volume (VOLDU). Stocks are first sorted into quintile portfolios based on VOLDU,

and then into LIQU quintiles within each VOLDU quintile. Panel A of Table 5 reports average re-

turns on 5×5 VOLDU & LIQU portfolios. In the lowest VOLDU quintile portfolio, average returns on

LIQU portfolios increase from 0.45% to 1.27% per month, with an average return difference of 0.82%

(t-statistic = 8.10) between Low and High LIQU portfolios. The corresponding alpha is 0.93% per

month with a t-statistic of 9.72. Similarly, in the highest VOLDU quintile portfolio, average returns on

LIQU portfolios increase monotonically from 0.97% to 1.99% per month, with an average return differ-

ence of 1.02% (t-statistic = 5.64) between Low and High LIQU portfolios. The corresponding alpha is

also positive, 0.87% per month, and highly significant. A notable point in Panel A of Table 5 is that in

almost all VOLDU quintiles, average returns on LIQU quintile portfolios increase monotonically as we

move from the lowest to highest LIQU quintile. The last column in Panel A of Table 5 presents returns

averaged across the VOLDU quintiles to produce quintile portfolios with dispersion in LIQU but with

similar levels of VOLDU. It shows that when moving from the lowest to highest LIQU quintile, the

monthly return averaged across the VOLDU quintiles increases from 0.62% to 1.67%, with an average

return difference of 1.05% (t-statistic = 7.94). The corresponding alpha has a similar magnitude and

highly significant as well. These results provide evidence that after controlling for unexpected shocks

to volume, the predictive power of liquidity shocks remains intact in bivariate portfolios. In the next

18

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


subsection, we will show that liquidity shocks predict future returns after controlling for VOLDU and

all other control variables in Fama-MacBeth regressions.

Since our main findings survive volume controls, one remaining issue is whether investors are just

underreacting to volatility shocks. Previous studies have documented a volatility feedback effect, that

an increase in volatility requires a higher rate of return from the asset, which leads to a fall in the as-

set price in the contemporaneous period (see, e.g., French et al., 1987; and Campbell and Hentschel,

1992). While the contemporaneous relation is well known, the predictive relation between volatility

shocks and future returns at individual stock level is not.22 It is possible that stock market underreacts

to volatility shocks, thus volatility shocks are accompanied by lower returns both in the contempo-

raneous period and in the future.23 To properly control for volatility shocks, we form 5×5 bivariate

portfolios of liquidity shocks (LIQU) and unexpected shocks to idiosyncratic volatility (IVOLU). Sim-

ilar to our liquidity shock variables defined in equations (2) and (4), we measure unexpected shocks to

idiosyncratic volatility (IVOLU) as:


IVOLUi,t = IVOLi,t − AV GIVOLi|t−12,t−1 , (5)

where AV GIVOLi|t−12,t−1 is the mean of idiosyncratic volatility over the past 12 months.

Once we generate volatility shocks (IVOLU), stocks are first sorted into quintile portfolios based on

IVOLU, and then into LIQU quintiles within each IVOLU quintile. Panel B of Table 5 reports average

returns on 5×5 IVOLU & LIQU portfolios. In the lowest IVOLU quintile portfolio, average returns

on LIQU portfolios increase monotonically from 0.65% to 1.96% per month, with an average return

difference of 1.31% (t-statistic = 7.46) between Low and High LIQU portfolios. The corresponding

alpha is 1.33% per month with a t-statistic of 7.52. Similarly, in the highest IVOLU quintile portfolio,
22 The negative relation between volatility shocks and contemporaneous returns can also be driven by the leverage effect
proposed by Black (1976) and Christie (1982), that is, as asset prices decline, companies’ leverage increases and they become
riskier, hence volatility also increases (see, e.g., Nelson, 1991; Engle and Ng, 1993, Bekaert and Wu, 2000, Bollerslev,
Litvinova, and Tauchen, 2006 and An, Ang, Bali, and Cakici, 2013). We control for past returns throughout the analysis to
account for this effect.
23 Bali, Scherbina, and Tang (2009) show that stocks that experience a sudden increase in idiosyncratic volatility earn

abnormally high contemporaneous returns but significantly underperform otherwise similar stocks in the future.

19

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


average returns on LIQU portfolios also increase monotonically from -0.02% to 1.43% per month, with

an average return difference of 1.45% (t-statistic = 6.24). The corresponding alpha is 1.49% per month

with a t-statistic of 6.97. A notable point in Panel B is that in all IVOLU quintiles, average returns on

LIQU quintile portfolios increase monotonically as we move from the lowest to highest LIQU quintile.

The last column in Panel B of Table 5 presents returns averaged across the IVOLU quintiles to produce

quintile portfolios with dispersion in LIQU but with similar levels of IVOLU. As shown in the last

column, when moving from the lowest to highest LIQU quintile, the monthly return averaged across

the VOLDU quintiles increases from 0.57% to 1.78%, with an average return difference of 1.21%

(t-statistic = 7.91) between Low and High LIQU portfolios. The corresponding alpha has a similar

magnitude and highly significant as well. These results indicate that after controlling for volatility

shocks, the predictive power of liquidity shocks remains intact.24

Another potential concern might be the correlation between spread and volatility that may translate

into a correlation between shocks to spread and shocks to volatility. Panel B of Table 1 shows that

the average cross-sectional correlation between SPRD and IVOL is about 40%. Since the spread is

correlated with volatility, it is useful to disentangle the portion of the spread shocks (SPRDU) driven

by volatility (or volatility shocks), and examine the orthogonal component of SPRDU for predicting

future stock returns. To investigate this issue, we first run firm-level contemporaneous cross-sectional

regressions of SPRDU on IVOL, and then use the residuals of these monthly cross-sectional regressions

(that are orthogonal to idiosyncratic volatility) to form a univariate long-short equity portfolio. The

first column in Table A5, Panel A of the online appendix shows that moving from Decile 1 to 10, the

average return on SPRDU portfolios increases from 0.44% to 1.46% per month, with an average return

difference of 1.02% per month with a t-statistic of 5.91 between Low and High SPRDU portfolios.

The corresponding alpha is 0.94% per month with a t-statistic of 5.17. Alternatively, we generate the
24 To test whether these findings are sensitive to alternative measures of liquidity shocks, we replicated our analysis in Table

5 using the shock to spread (SPRDU) and the conditional measure of liquidity shock (LIQCU). Specifically, we form 5×5
bivariate portfolios of VOLDU & SPRDU as well as IVOLU & SPRDU. We also form 5×5 bivariate portfolios of VOLDU &
LIQCU as well as IVOLU & LIQCU. As presented in Table A4 of the online appendix, within VOLDU and IVOLU quintiles,
average returns on SPRDU and LIQCU portfolios increase monotonically as we move from the lowest to highest liquidity
shock quintile. The average return and alpha differences between Low and High liquidity shock portfolios are all positive and
highly significant after controlling for VOLDU and IVOLU.

20

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


orthogonal component of SPRDU with respect to volatility shocks (instead of volatility levels). We

first run contemporaneous cross-sectional regressions of SPRDU on IVOLU, and then use the residuals

that are orthogonal to volatility shocks to form a univariate portfolio. The last two columns of Table A5

show that moving from Decile 1 to 10, the average return on SPRDU portfolios increases from 0.61% to

1.37% per month, with an average return difference of 0.76% per month with a t-statistic of 4.51. The

corresponding alpha is also positive, 0.77% per month, and highly significant with a t-statistic of 4.57.

Panel B of Table A5 presents multivariate Fama-MacBeth regressions with the orthogonal components

of SPRDU. The average slopes on SPRDU (orthogonal to IVOL and IVOLU) remain positive and

highly significant after controlling for all other return predictors.

In sum, our liquidity shock measures continue to predict future returns after controlling for volatility

and volume shocks, suggesting that the return predictability is consistent with stock market underre-

action to liquidity shocks, rather than underreaction to volume or volatility shocks. In the following

subsection, we perform multivariate Fama-MacBeth regressions of liquidity shocks on future returns

while simultaneously controlling for an extensive list of variables.

3.4. Stock level cross-sectional regressions

While portfolio-level analysis has an advantage of being nonparametric, it does not allow us to account

for all the control variables jointly. To check whether the predictive power of liquidity shocks remains

strong after simultaneously controlling for the competing predictors of stock returns, we run monthly

cross-sectional predictive regressions of the form:

Ri,t+1 = αt+1 + γt+1 LIQshock


i,t + ϕt+1 Xi,t + εi,t+1 , (6)

where Ri,t+1 is the realized excess return on stock i in month t + 1, LIQshock


i,t represents one of the three

alternative measures of liquidity shock of stock i in month t: LIQU, SPRDU, and LIQCU. Xi,t is a

vector of control variables for stock i in month t.

21

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


We start with the baseline model, where the control variables are the market beta (BETA), log mar-

ket capitalization (LNME), and log book-to-market ratio (LNBM). We then add the other usual suspects

including the momentum (MOM), short-term reversal (REV), co-skewness (COSKEW), idiosyncratic

volatility (IVOL), maximum daily return in the previous month (MAX), analyst dispersion (DISP), and

the Amihud’s illiquidity measure (ILLIQ). Next, we add a variety of liquidity-based variables includ-

ing the coefficient of variance in the Amihud’s illiquidity (CVILLIQ), standard deviation of turnover

(SDTURN), Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) liquidity beta (PS), Acharya and Pedersen (2005) liquidity

betas (BETA1 to BETA4), exposures to the fixed and the variable components of Sadka’s liquidity fac-

tor (SADKAF and SADKAS), unexpected earnings (SUE), and two alternative measures of abnormal

dollar trading volume: the dummy variables for abnormal trading volume variable constructed follow-

ing Gervais et al. (2001) – GKMH for a stock with abnormally high dollar trading volume, GKML for

a stock with abnormally low dollar volume; and abnormal dollar trading volume for a stock in month t

relative to its prior 12-month average (VOLDU).25

Table 6 presents the time-series averages of the slope coefficients from the stock level Fama and

MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions of one-month ahead stock returns on liquidity shocks with

all cross-sectional predictors controlled for simultaneously, where abnormal trading volume in previous

month is measured by either the dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ) or the continuous VOLDU

variable. The t-statistics computed with Newey-West standard errors are shown in parentheses.26

Table 6 shows that, depending on the two alternative abnormal trading volume proxies used, the

average slope coefficients of LIQU are 0.18 and 0.20 and highly significant. The economic significance

of the average slope coefficients of LIQU can be interpreted based on the long-short equity portfolios.

As reported in Table 2, the difference in LIQU values between average stocks in the high and low LIQU

deciles is 2.22. Hence, the average slopes of 0.20 and 0.18 imply that a portfolio short-selling stocks
25 In some specifications we also controlled for shocks to idiosyncratic volatility and find this variable to be insignificant.
To streamline the presentation, we defer those specifications in Table A6 of the online appendix.
26 Table A7 in the online appendix reports the time-series averages of the slope coefficients from the stock level Fama and

MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions of one-month ahead stock returns on liquidity shocks and various combinations
of the control variables. The average slope coefficients of the liquidity shock proxies remain positive and significant at the
1% level based on the Newey-West t-statistics.

22

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


with the largest decrease in liquidity (stocks in Decile 1) and buying stocks with the largest increase

in liquidity (stocks in Decile 10) will generate a return in the following month by between 0.44% and

0.40%, controlling for everything else.27

Similarly, the average slope coefficients of SPRDU are 0.554 and 0.632, respectively, and highly

significant, implying that a portfolio short-selling stocks with the largest increase in spread (stocks in

Decile 1) and buying stocks with the largest decrease in spread (stocks in Decile 10) will yield a return

in the following month by between 1.04% and 0.90%, controlling for everything else.28 Finally, the

average slope coefficients of LIQCU are 0.18 and 0.15, respectively, and highly significant, implying

that a portfolio short-selling stocks with the largest decrease in liquidity (stocks in Decile 1) and buying

stocks with largest increase in liquidity (stocks in Decile 10) will generate a return in the following

month by between 0.42% and 0.35%, controlling for everything else.29

The average slope coefficients on the control variables are in line with the earlier studies. Specif-

ically, the negative coefficient on stock size is consistent with Fama and French (1992, 1993). MOM

is positive, while REV is negative, consistent with price momentum (Jegadeesh and Titman (1993))

and short-term reversal (Jegadeesh (1990)). Idiosyncratic volatility is negative and significant as in

Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006). Analysts earnings forecast dispersion is negative and signif-

icant as in Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002). The level of Amihud’s illiquidity is positive and

significant, consistent with illiquidity risk premium shown in Amihud and Mendelson (1986) and sub-

sequent studies. While the variation in illiquidity is positive but insignificant, standard deviation in

turnover is negative and significant as in Chordia, Subrahmanyam, and Anshuman (2001) and Pereira

and Zhang (2010). The exposure to systematic liquidity risk as proposed by Pastor and Stambaugh
27 Note that Table 6 does not include SPRD as a control variable when liquidity shocks are measured as LIQU or LIQCU,
as employing SPRD greatly reduces the length of the sample. For robustness check, We include SPRD as a control variable
for these two liquidity shock measures and find the results to be similar. The results are shown in Panels A and C of Table
A7.
28 At an earlier stage of the study, we construct liquidity shock based on equal-weighted quoted spread (QSPRD), calculated

as the negative QSPRD, demeaned using the past 12-month QSPRD as the mean. The results are qualitatively similar to those
based on volume-weighted relative effective spread, and are summarized in Table A8 of the online appendix.
29 As reported in the online appendix, Panels A and B of Table A1 show that the differences in SPRDU and LIQCU values

between average stocks in High and Low liquidity shock deciles are 1.64 and 2.36, respectively.

23

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


(2003) is positive, albeit insignificant. The exposure to the four Acharya and Pedersen (2005) betas

are largely insignificant, with the exception of BETA3 when liquidity shocks are measured as SPRDU.

Similarly, the Sadka (2006) fixed and variable liquidity betas are insignificant. Earnings surprises are

positive and highly significant, consistent with earnings momentum as documented by Bernard and

Thomas (1989) and subsequent papers. The high volume dummy variable, GKMH , and abnormal trad-

ing volume variable, VOLDU, are both positive and significant, consistent with the high volume return

premium proposed by Gervais et al. (2001).

Overall, the Fama-MacBeth regression results confirm that, even after jointly controlling for a large

set of variables, our liquidity shock variables have economically and statistically significant predictive

power for future stock returns. Furthermore, although liquidity shocks may appear to be related to

changes in trading volume, the effect of liquidity shocks on future returns remain robust after control-

ling for the Gervais et al. (2001) high volume return premium effect.

4. Investigating the Underlying Mechanism of Underreaction

Our finding of the positive link between stock level liquidity shocks and future stock returns is incon-

sistent with the setting in which public information is incorporated into prices immediately. In such

setttings, given that liquidity shocks have persistent effects and that the level of illiquidity has found to

be positively priced, negative liquidity shocks should lead to a higher risk premium and thus an instan-

taneous price decrease (lower contemporaneous return) and higher future returns. The opposite should

also be true for positive liquidity shocks.

As described earlier, Table 2 shows a positive contemporaneous relation between liquidity shocks

and stock returns. This initial reaction of liquidity shocks is consistent with the argument put forth in the

prior literature: a negative liquidity shock should lead to an immediate decrease in the stock price due

to a higher liquidity risk premium and vice versa. However, Tables 3–6 show that the market reaction is

incomplete in the contemperaneous month and future stock returns continue to drift positively with the

24

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


past liquidity shocks. Our evidence thus suggests that the market underreacts to the liquidity shocks.

The full effect of liquidity shocks is reflected in prices only gradually over time, resulting in return

continuations in the following months.

To gain insight on the horizon of the underreaction, we examine the effect of liquidity shocks

on future returns over various holding periods. We form long-short equity portfolios based on past

liquidity shocks and investigate the performance of high vs. low liquidity shock (LIQU) portfolios over

months t + 1 to t + 12. Figure 1 depicts the monthly return differences between the highest LIQU and

lowest LIQU deciles for 1 to 12 months after portfolio formation. The dashed lines indicate the 95%

confidence bands, calculated based on the Newey and West (1987) standard errors. The figure shows

that the return differentials between the highest LIQU and lowest LIQU deciles continue to be positive

for up to 7 months after the shock. This evidence suggests that there exists considerable underreaction

to stock level liquidity shocks and the underreaction can last for a substantial amount of time. The

horizon of underreaction documented here is consistent with the pattern established by other empirical

papers. Bernard and Thomas (1989) find that underreaction to earnings announcements can last for

up to a quarter, until the next earnings announcement. Hong, Lim, and Stein (2000) find that slow

information diffusion can lead to stock market underreaction, which results in return predictability for

10 months or longer (especially for stocks with low analyst coverage). Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh

(2009) show that the underreaction to earnings news surrounded by other information events can be

significant in the 60-day cumulative returns after the announcement.

We explore two possible causes of stock market underreaction to liquidity shocks: limited investor

attention and illiquidity. One mechanism proposed in the literature to explain underreaction to infor-

mation is investor attention. Kahneman’s (1973) theory of attention argues that attention is a scarce

cognitive resource. Subsequently, a large body of psychological research shows that there is a limit to

the central cognitive-processing capacity of the human brain.30 The implication of attention theory in

financial markets is that limited availability of time and cognitive resources imposes constraints on how
30 See Pashler and Johnston (1998) for a review of these studies.

25

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


fast investors can process information. Theoretical models have shown that limited investor attention

can lead to securities market underreaction to information and thus slow price adjustments (Hirshleifer

and Teoh, 2003, Peng, 2005, Peng and Xiong, 2006, and Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh, 2011). These

predictions have been confirmed by recent empirical findings that securities prices underreact to value

relevant public information due to limited investor attention.31

Compared to the types of information studied in the aforementioned literature (earnings news,

demographic information, new products, returns of related stocks, etc.), liquidity shocks are not well-

defined, less tangible, and their pricing implications are harder to interpret by average investors. As a

result, investors are more likely to ignore this “news”. In this case, when stock level liquidity decreases,

the effect of increased risk premium and lower stock prices is not fully incorporated by the stock

market immediately, and the negative price impact spills over to future months. The attention-based

underreaction hypothesis further predicts that the return predictability of liquidity shocks should be

stronger for stocks which investors pay less attention to.

Illiquidity may also result in delays in price adjustments: if information is revealed through trading,

then for illiquid stocks that are harder to trade, information is revealed more slowly. This mechanism

makes sense especially for private information. The only way for these types of information to be

incorporated into prices is through trading, and the informed investors trade less aggressively when liq-

uidity is low or when transaction costs are high. The mechanism is less obvious for public information

such as publicly observable changes in liquidity (especially given that our liquidity shocks are simple

to compute). In a market in which participants such as market makers and traders immediately react to

public information, prices can be updated without trading. However, if market participants are hetero-

geneous in processing information, together with limits to arbitrage, illiquidity may still lead to slow

price adjustment following public information arrival. Hence, it is plausible that illiquidity can hamper

price discovery, which leads to slow price adjustment following liquidity shocks. The illiquidity-based
31 See,
for example, Huberman and Regev (2001), Hirshleifer, Hou, Teoh, and Zhang (2004), Hou and Moskowitz (2005),
Hong, Torous, and Valkanov (2007), DellaVigna and Pollet (2007, 2009), Cohen and Frazzini (2008), Hirshleifer, Lim, and
Teoh (2009), and Hirshleifer, Hsu, and Li (2012).

26

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


underreaction hypothesis predicts that the positive return predictability of liquidity shocks should be

stronger for less liquid stocks.

To empirically test the attention-based underreaction hypothesis, we form subsamples that vary

by the degree of investor attention and compare the relation between liquidity shocks and subsequent

returns in these subsamples.

Following Hirshleifer and Teoh (2003), Peng (2005), and Hirshleifer, Hsu, and Li (2012), we adopt

stock size and analyst coverage as proxies for investor attention. Smaller stocks and stocks with lower

analyst coverage receive less attention from investors. As a result, we expect these stocks to exhibit

more delayed reaction to information contained in liquidity shocks, and thus liquidity shocks can gener-

ate greater return predictability. Small stocks and stocks with lower analyst coverage have slower infor-

mation diffusions, which is also consistent with evidence found in price momentum effect (Hong, Lim,

and Stein (2000)), stock return lead-lags (Brennan, Jegadeesh, and Swaminathan (1993); Hong, Torous,

and Valkanov (2007); Hou (2007); Cohen and Frazzini (2008)), post earnings announcement drifts

(Chambers and Penman, 1984; Bernard and Thomas, 1989), and the accrual anomaly (Mashruwala,

Rajgopal, and Shevlin (2006)). In addition, since institutional investors are more likely to pay more

attention to individual stocks than retail investors due to their expertise and economies of scale in gath-

ering information, stocks with more institutional ownership tend to receive more investor attention.

Thus, we use institutional ownership as our third attention proxy, with the caveat that institutional

ownership may also capture the relaxation of short sale constraints. The attention-based underreaction

mechanism predicts that there should be a stronger positive relation between liquidity shocks and future

returns for small stocks, and stocks with low analyst coverage and low institutional ownerships.

To test this prediction, we first sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on an attention proxy, and

then within each proxy quintile, stock are sorted into liquidity shock quintile portfolios. We follow the

prior literature (for example, Hong et al. 2000) and use the NYSE breakpoints. Table 7 presents 5 × 5

bivariate portfolio returns and return differentials, with Newey-West t-statistics reported in parentheses.

27

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Panels A-C use stock size, analyst coverage, and institutional ownership as alternative proxies for

investor attention.

Panel A shows that a portfolio that is long in stocks with positive liquidity shocks (increase in

liquidity) and short in stocks with negative liquidity shocks (decreases in liquidity) leads to a monthly

return of 145 basis points for stocks in the smallest size quintile and a return of only 43 basis points

for stocks in the largest size quintile, the difference is 102 basis points per month, and statistically

significant. Results are similar with the risk-adjusted returns; the Fama-French three-factor alpha on

the long-short portfolio based on LIQU is 1.50% per month in the smallest size quintile, whereas the

corresponding alpha is only 0.52% per month in the biggest size quintile, the difference is a significant

98 basis points per month.

Panels B and C show similar results. The return differential for the long-short portfolio based on

LIQU is high for the quintile with the lowest analyst coverage and institutional ownership, 128 and

147 basis points per month, respectively, and low for the quintile with the highest analyst coverage

and institutional ownership, 49 and 71 basis points per month. The difference of long-short portfolio

return differential across analyst coverage and institutional ownership quintile is highly significant for

both the raw returns and for the abnormal returns. It is also worth noting that, Kaniel, Ozoguz and

Starks (2012) find that the high volume return premium effect originally documented by Gervais et al.

(2001) is actually increasing in analyst coverage, contrary to our finding that the return predictability

of liquidity shocks is decreasing in analyst coverage. This contrast further suggests that the two effects

are distinct.

Overall, these results support the attention-based underreaction hypothesis that, market’s underre-

action to liquidity shocks is stronger and more significant for stocks that receive less investor attention:

small, less-covered stocks, and stocks minimally held by institutional investors.

To test whether illiquidity-driven slow price adjustment can also contribute to market’s underre-

action to liquidity shocks, we analyze how the degree of underreaction is related to the level of the

28

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


stock’s illiquidity. We first sort stocks into quintiles every month based on the Amihud’s illiquidity

measure (ILLIQ), and then within each ILLIQ quintile, stocks are sorted into quintiles on liquidity

shocks (LIQU). Panel D of Table 7 reports the average returns for each of the 5 × 5 portfolios of ILLIQ

and LIQU, the return difference (High−Low) between the highest and the lowest LIQU quintiles within

each ILLIQ quintile, and the three-factor alpha. The return differences and three-factor alphas remain

significantly positive across all ILLIQ quintiles. Moving from the lowest to the highest ILLIQ quintile,

the return difference between Quintile 5 and Quintile 1 LIQU portfolios increases from 52 to 136 basis

points per month, and the corresponding three-factor alpha increases from 49 to 138 basis points per

month. These return and alpha spreads are also highly significant without any exception. These results

are consistent with the illiquidity-based underreaction hypothesis that the market’s underreaction to

liquidity shocks is stronger for less liquid stocks.

The evidence thus far seems to be consistent with both the attention- and the illiquidity-based un-

derreaction hypotheses. One might argue that the attention proxies we employ (size, analyst coverage,

and institutional ownership) are highly correlated with the liquidity of a stock: Table 1, Panel B shows

that the average correlations between illiquidity (ILLIQ) and stock size (LNME), analyst coverage

(CVRG), and institutional ownership (INST) are −0.41, −0.26 and −0.24, respectively. Although

these correlations are not high in absolute terms, what the attention measures capture can potentially

be the effect of liquidity, and vice versa. To disentangle the effect of investor attention from illiquidity

and gauge the relative importance of the two mechanisms in contributing to markets’ underreaction

to liquidity shocks, we include both underreaction proxies and illiquidity as interaction variables with

LIQU in Fama-MacBeth regressions.

In Table 8, the cross-section of one-month ahead excess returns are regressed against the liquid-

ity shock proxies (LIQU, SPRDU, LIQCU), the illiquidity level (ILLIQ), the interaction between the

illiquidity level and liquidity shock, and the interaction between one attention proxy (LNME, CVRG,

INST) and liquidity shock, along with the same set of controls that are used in Table 6.

29

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Panel A reports the Fama-MacBeth regression coefficients when liquidity shocks are measured by

LIQU.32 The results show that the average slope coefficient on (LIQU × AT T ENT ION) is negative

and highly significant across all three attention proxies (LNME, CVRG, and INST), suggesting that

the return predictability of liquidity shocks is stronger for low attention stocks, even after controlling

for any potential effect of illiquidity levels. The average slope on (LIQU × ILLIQ) is positive and

marginally significant when investor attention is proxied by LNME, but it is statistically insignificant

when investor attention is proxied by CVRG and INST. This suggests that illiquidity-driven slow price

adjustment may also be a contributing factor to markets’ underreaction to liquidity shocks although its

impact is weaker compared to the attention mechanism.

In Panel B of Table8, we use SPRDU as the proxy for liquidity shock and run the same set of cross-

sectional regressions with interaction variables. Similar to our earlier findings reported in Panel A, the

average slope coefficient on (SPRDU × AT T ENT ION) is negative and significant for both Models 1

and 2, across all three attention proxies. On the other hand, the average slope coefficient on (SPRDU ×

ILLIQ) is only positive and significant when investor attention is proxied by LNME, and insignificant

for the other two attention proxies.

In Panel C of Table 8, we use LIQCU as the proxy for liquidity shock. Similar to findings in Panels

A and B, the average slope coefficient on (LIQCU × AT T ENT ION) is negative and significant across

all three attention proxies, except in Model (1) when investor attention is proxied by CVRG. The co-

efficient on SPRDU × ILLIQ is positive and significant when size and institutional ownership are used

as attention proxies, but not when analyst coverage is used. The different level of significance of the

attention interaction variable and the illiquidity interaction variable suggests that these two interaction

variables are not capturing the same effect.

To summarize, the positive relation between liquidity shocks and one-month ahead stocks returns

remains significant for all specifications, and the relation is stronger for low attention stocks and for
32 We suppress the coefficient estimates of the cross-sectional controls. They are presented in Table A10 of the online
appendix.

30

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


illiquid stocks. The results imply that the positive relation between liquidity shocks and future returns

are due to markets’ underreaction to liquidity shocks, which can be attributed to investor inattention

and illiquidity.

Following Hong, Lim, and Stein (2000), and Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh (2009), we further inves-

tigate the attention and liquidity based mechanisms by studying long-term cumulative returns. Table 9

reports the Fama-MacBeth average slope coefficients on LIQU with and without the interaction terms,

and controlling for a large set of control variables listed earlier.33 Similar to Table 8, models (1) and

(2) use GKMH , GKML and VOLDU to capture abnormal dollar trading volume, respectively.

Panel A of Table 9 presents the benchmark model without interaction variables. It shows that,

consistent with Figure 1, the positive link between liquidity shocks and future cumulative stock returns

remains significant for at least six months into the future.

Panels B through D include attention and liquidity interaction variables. In Panel B of Table 9,

LNME proxies for investor attention. The average slope coefficient on (LIQU × LNME) is negative

and highly significant for six months into the future, indicating that the attention-based mechanism is

important for explaining return continuations over the next six months. On the other hand, the slope

coefficient on (LIQU × ILLIQ) becomes insignificant starting month 2, indicating that the illiquidity

driven underreaction is short-lived.

Panels C and D of Table 9 present qualitatively similar evidence when analysts’ coverage and

institutional ownership are used as proxies for investor attention. The average slope coefficient on

(LIQU × CV RG) is negative and highly significant up to five months into the future, and the average

slope coefficient on (LIQU × INST ) is negative and highly significant for two months into the future.

Overall, the results in Tables 8 and 9 suggest that, while inattention and illiquidity both contribute to

short term return predictability of liquidity shocks, the inattention based mechanism is more important

for the longer-run predictability. The regression results from long-term stock return prediction confirm
33 We obtain similar results when liquidity shocks are measured either with SPRDU or LIQCU, the results are shown in

Table A11 of the online appendix.

31

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


the portfolio results in Figure 1 and demonstrate that the horizon of return predictability is consistent

with other studies that document security market underreaction due to investor inattention (Bernard and

Thomas (1989), Hong, Lim, and Stein (2000) and Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh (2009)).

5. Robustness

In this section, we show that our results are robust to market microstructure effects, for different stock

exchanges, and during different subsample periods.

5.1. Market microstructure effects

Previously, we address the concern that our results may be driven by market microstructure effects such

as bid-ask bounce by controlling for past month returns, as well as various microstructure measures

(illiquidity, spreads, etc.). In this subsection, we provide an additional robustness check by measuring

liquidity shocks in month t − 2 and predicting the cross-section of stock returns in month t. In other

words, we skip a month between the liquidity shock estimation and the return prediction. Table 10

presents the average returns on the equal-weighted and value-weighted portfolios after skipping the

month. As shown in the last two rows of Table 10, the equal-weighted (value-weighted) raw return

differences and the corresponding alphas are, respectively, 0.60% and 0.70% (0.58% and 0.65%) per

month between the High- and Low-LIQU portfolios and significant at the 1% level based on the Newey-

West t-statistics. These positive and significant return and alpha spreads, together with the long-run

predictive regression results shown in Table 9, confirm that the predictive power of liquidity shocks

goes beyond the next month and is unlikely to be driven by short term microstructure effects.

In Section 3.3, we investigate one-month ahead predictive power of liquidity shocks after control-

ling for volume and volatility shocks using double sorted portfolios. We now test whether liquidity

shocks can continue to predict two-month ahead returns after controlling for volume and volatility

shocks, again with double sorted portfolios.

32

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Panel B of Table 10 shows that after controlling for VOLDU, two-month ahead return (t + 2 return)

on LIQU portfolios averaged across the VOLDU quintiles increases from 0.99% to 1.49% per month,

with an average return difference of 50 basis points per month between Low and High LIQU portfolios,

and highly significant with a t-statistic of 5.01. The corresponding alpha is also 0.50% per month with

a t-statistic of 5.34. After controlling for IVOLU, t + 2 return on LIQU portfolios averaged across

the IVOLU quintiles increases monotonically from 0.91% to 1.53% per month, with an average return

difference of 62 basis points per month (t-statistic = 5.25). The corresponding alpha is 0.69% per

month, and highly significant with a t-statistic of 6.11. As shown in Table A12 of the online appendix,

similar results are obtained when we replicate Panel B of Table 10 by replacing LIQU with alternative

measures of liquidity shocks (SPRDU and LIQCU). These results suggest that the longer term return

predictability of liquidity shocks are robust with respect to volume shocks or volatility shocks.

To address the issue of bid-ask bounce more directly, we measure stock returns using the quoted

bid-ask midpoints and then replicate our main findings for the period of 1993-2010. The monthly stock

returns are calculated based on the quote midpoint, which is the average of the monthly closing national

best bid and offer (NBBO) and adjusted for dividends and stock splits.

In Table A13 of the online appendix, we report the equal- and value-weighted average one-month

ahead quote midpoint returns for decile portfolios formed on liquidity shocks. Panel A shows that

the average return differences between High and Low liquidity shock deciles and the corresponding

Fama-French alphas are positive and highly significant for all measures of liquidity shocks (LIQU,

SPRDU, and LIQCU). More importantly, both the economic and statistical significance of the return

and alpha spreads in Table A13 are very similar to those reported in Table 3. In addition to the portfolio

results in Panel A, we present stock-level cross-sectional regressions from midquote returns in Panel

B of Table A13. Panel B reports the average slope coefficients of liquidity shocks from the Fama-

MacBeth regressions of one-month ahead quote midpoint returns on liquidity shocks and all other

control variables. A notable point in Panel B is that both the magnitude and statistical significance

of the average slopes from quote midpoint returns are similar to those reported in Table 6. Overall,

33

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


these results indicate that the economically and statistically significant link between liquidity shocks

and future returns is not driven or magnified by microstructure effects.

We further account for the possibility that market microstructure effects can bias the Fama-MacBeth

regression coefficients using the technique of Asparouhova, Bessembinder, and Kalcheva (2010). Specif-

ically, we run monthly weighted least squares (WLS) regressions, where each observed return is

weighted by the gross return on the same stock in the prior month. For our key variable, liquidity

shocks, the coefficient estimates and t-statistics are slightly lower than our original results after cor-

recting for microstructure biases, but they all remain positive and significant at the 5% level or better.

The results are presented in Table A14 of the online appendix. It shows that the predictive power of

liquidity shocks is robust to potential microstructure-related biases.

5.2. Screen on stock exchanges

In this section, we provide evidence that our main findings are not driven by the inclusion of Amex and

Nasdaq stocks, and the results hold for big and liquid stocks in the S&P 500 sample.

We apply three types of screens by using stocks listed only on (i) NYSE/Amex, (ii) NYSE, and

(iii) S&P 500 index. Table 11 reports the one-month ahead returns of the univariate portfolios sorted

on LIQU for the three stock samples. The results show that the predictive ability of liquidity shocks

remains strong. The NYSE/Amex sample and the NYSE sample results are very similar to the full

CRSP sample result documented in Table 3, with the long-short portfolio raw return differential ranging

from 104 to 115 basis points per month for raw returns and 94 to 117 basis points per month for

three-factor adjusted returns, all highly significant. Even for the S&P 500 sample, the return and

alpha spreads from equal- and value-weighted portfolios remain economically large and statistically

significant, ranging from 61 to 68 basis points per month, suggesting that underreaction to liquidity

shocks is not restricted to small and illiquid stocks.

34

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


5.3. Recessionary vs. expansionary periods

In Table 12, we examine whether our findings are sensitive to the state of the economy by examining

the one-month ahead returns on the long-short portfolio sorted on LIQU for different subsample peri-

ods. The first two columns of Panel A exclude the most recent financial crisis period (July 2007 to June

2009). For this sample, the long-short portfolio generates a return of 121 basis points per month, com-

parable to the full sample results presented in Table 3. The next four columns present results for NBER

expansionary and recessionary periods, respectively. The raw returns from the long-short portfolio are

stable across the business cycles, with a magnitude of 116 basis points for the expansionary periods

and 130 basis points for the recessionary periods and statistically significant. The results suggest that

the predictive power of liquidity shocks are robust to different states of the economy.

5.4. Subsample analysis

In this section, we provide a thorough subsample analysis by dividing our full sample into five decades:

August 1963-July 1973, August 1973-July 1983, August 1983-July 1993, August 1993-July 2003, and

August 2003-December 2010.

Panel B of Table 12 shows that the average return differences and their alphas between the High and

Low LIQU portfolios are positive and highly significant for all decades. Specifically, the average raw

return differences are, respectively, 1.41%, 1.09%, 0.96%, 1.75%, and 0.55% per month for the afore-

mentioned decades, and are significant at the 5% level or better; the corresponding alpha differences

are, respectively, 1.32%, 0.95%, 0.96%, 1.88%, and 0.67% per month, and are all highly significant as

well. These results show that the strong positive link between liquidity shocks and future returns are

robust across different sample periods.

35

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


6. Discussions of Alternative Mechanisms

We have shown that the positive relation between liquidity shocks and future returns are robust after

controlling for a long list of alternative explanations, including the level and the variability of illiquidity,

the exposure to systematic liquidity risk, microstructure effects, and high volume return premium. In

this section, we discuss whether our findings can be explained by other mechanisms.

Hvidkjaer (2006, 2008) find that stocks with high level of sell-initiated small-trade volume tend to

outperform those with a high level of buy-initiated small-trade volume, suggesting that stocks favored

by retail investors experience overshooting in the short term which result in subsequent reversals. One

possibility is that stocks’ increased liquidity is driven by increased selling by retail investors, which

is followed by high returns in the subsequent months as the sells reverse out. This explanation is,

however, unlikely as the Hvidkjaer mechanism leads to return reversals (price overshooting), while we

observe return continuations (underreaction). To account for the effect of small trade order flows, we

follow Hvidkjaer (2008) and construct the signed small-trade turnover (SSTT) variable that is defined

as the small-trade buy-initiated turnover minus the small-trade sell-initiated turnover, measured over

the past one through 24 months.34 It turns out that the Hvidkjaer variables have a very low correlation

coefficient with our liquidity shock measures, ranging from -0.1% to -3.5%. We formally control for the

Hvidkjaer variables using bivariate portfolio sorts and by including them as additional control variables

in Fama-MacBeth regressions.

For month t, we sort common stocks into quintiles based on SSTTJ (J=1, 3, 6, 12 and 24); then

within each STTTJ quintile, we further sort stocks into quintile portfolios of liquidity shock.. Panel

A of Table 13 reports the one-month ahead returns and return differentials, averaged across the five

control groups for the same liquidity shock quintile. Panels A1, A2 and A3 correspond to liquidity

shock measures LIQU, SPRDU, and LIQCU, respectively. Our results show that, regardless of the

horizon used to measure SSTT, controlling for SSTT does not affect the economic magnitude or the
34 We provide a detailed description of the SSTT variables in the Appendix.

36

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


statistical significance of liquidity shocks’ predictive power for future returns. The return differences

between High and Low liquidity shock portfolios and their corresponding Fama-French alphas are in

the range of 77 and 129 basis points per month, and they are all significant at the 1% level.

We further run Fama-MacBeth predictive regressions of one-month ahead returns on liquidity shock

and SSTTJ , including all the other control variables listed in Table 6. Specifications (1) and (2) control

for the GKM dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ) and the abnormal dollar trading volume (VOLDU),

respectively. Panel B of Table 13 reports the average slope coefficients of liquidity shock and SSTT.35

The results indicate that the average slope coefficients of liquidity shock remain positive and highly

significant, and are similar in magnitude to those reported in Table 6. Consistent with Hvidkjaer (2008),

the average slope coefficients of SSTT are always negative and are mostly significant for aggregate

turnover over 3- to 12-month periods. Overall, the results of conditional bivariate sorts and Fama-

MacBeth cross-sectional regressions confirm that the predictive ability of liquidity shock is not driven

by the effect of the signed small-trade turnover.

One might argue that a liquidity shock can lead to a “flight to liquidity”, i.e., investors rush to dump

their illiquid stocks and shift their funds into the liquid ones. In this case, the assets with a negative

liquidity shock can be oversold and we should expect their prices to come back in the future. This

story can not explain why, on the contrary, we find that the prices of those that experienced a negative

liquidity shock continue to go down for an extended period of time in the future. Furthermore, “flight to

liquidity” usually occurs during a systematic market-wide liquidity crisis, while our findings are strong

and robust for all periods including busts and booms. Hence, our results cannot be explained by “flight

to liquidity”, although the evidence of return continuation after a liquidity shock do lend support to

investors’ motive to dump their less liquid assets and move to more liquid assets.

Some may argue that the story can go the other way: in a liquidity crisis, rather than flight to liquid-

ity, investors may choose to sell off liquid assets to meet margin constraints or capital requirements and

hold on to illiquid assets as they can only be sold at fire sale prices. As a result, stocks that are subject
35 For brevity, we suppress the average slope coefficients of the other control variables. They are available upon request.

37

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


to a positive liquidity shock (increases in liquidity) are oversold, and future returns should be positive

as they rebound. On the other hand, stocks that are subject to a negative liquidity shock (decreases in

liquidity) are not sold enough, and future returns should be negative as the prices of these assets come

down later. This story can produce a positive link between liquidity shocks and future stock returns

during crisis periods. However, it is not clear whether the effect should be there during normal peri-

ods. Given that our finding of a positive relation between liquidity shocks and future stock returns are

equally strong for non-crisis periods as well as recessionary and expansionary periods, it seems that the

proposed story cannot fully explain our findings.

Can the positive relation between liquidity shocks and future returns be driven by positively auto-

correlated liquidity shocks? That is, when negative liquidity shocks are followed by negative liquidity

shocks in the future, would this lead to lower future returns? The answer is no if the market is effi-

cient. If the market rationally and immediately reacts to liquidity shocks, it should have anticipated the

correlated nature of the shocks and should have factored it into prices, leaving no return predictability.

Thus, correlated liquidity shocks should not be able to predict future returns.

Generally speaking, if markets are rational and react to information promptly, these other value-

relevant shocks (information releases and company events) should have been incorporated into prices

already and any of their predictability should have been captured by the predictability of past returns.

Our results remain significant after controlling for past returns and past earnings surprises, suggesting

that these other factors alone can not explain our findings. For future work, it might be interesting to

focus on concrete cases of liquidity shocks and study market’s reactions to these particular episodes in

an event study setting. One example of such events is stock splits. Muscarella and Vetsuypens (1996),

Schultz (2000) and Lin, Singh, and Yu (2009) find that there has been considerable increases in trading

volume and reduction in liquidity risk subsequent to stock splits. This suggests that stock splits increase

the liquidity of the stocks and should lead to a reduction in risk premia. The implication is that, in a

fully efficient market in which investors react immediately and rationally to split announcements, share

prices should rise instantaneously and future returns should be low. However, this is inconsistent with

38

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


the findings in Ikenberry, Rankine, and Stice (1996) and Desai and Jain (1997), who document that

prices continue to drift upwards up to one year following split announcements. Investigating stock

market’s underreaction to stock splits and the associated liquidity changes can potentially explain these

findings.

Another interesting question for future analysis is what is the exact propagation mechanism of

the securities markets’ underreaction to liquidity shocks. Given that securities dealers (or designated

market makers) are liquidity providers, why wouldn’t they be able to react promptly to liquidity shocks

by changing their quotes? The reasons can be the following.

First, dealers face incomplete information and rely on information extracted from order flows,

which aggregates information from the marginal investor of a stock. A large body of empirical evidence

shows that investor inattention has significant pricing impacts, suggesting that attention constraint is

binding for the marginal investors of a considerable number of stocks. If the marginal investor can not

fully process all available information (including information about changes in future liquidity and its

impact on prices), the amount of information the dealer can learn from order flows will be limited. As

a result, the prices that the dealer sets would not fully reflect information on liquidity shocks.

Second, there are empirical evidence that even dealer themselves are subject to limited attention.

Corwin and Coughenour (2008) show that NYSE specialists’ attention constraints affect execution

quality in terms of price improvement and transaction costs for securities for which they are market

makers, and as a result, stocks that receives less specialist attention exhibit less frequent price improve-

ments. Boulatov et al. (2009) find that the speed of quote adjustment is faster for stocks with greater

attention from NYSE specialists. Chakrabarty and Moulton (2012) find that attention constraints for

NYSE specialists have an effect on the liquidity of the stocks they handle. These articles suggest that

one potential propagation mechanism of markets’ underreaction to liquidity shocks is because securi-

ties dealers suffer from limited attention.

39

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


For future work, it would be interesting to explore how order flow and dealers’ quoting behavior

respond to liquidity shocks and how dealers’ attention allocation across stocks in their portfolio affect

the speed of quote adjustments in response to liquidity shocks.

7. Conclusion

The liquidity of a stock refers to the degree to which a significant quantity can be traded in a short period

without incurring a large transaction cost or adverse price impact. Given that the level of individual

stock illiquidity is positively priced in the cross-section of expected returns and that liquidity shocks

have persistent effects, one would expect that negative liquidity shocks lead to higher future returns if

stock market reacts immediately and to the full extent to the increased risk premium.

On the contrary, we find a surprising positive relation between stock level liquidity shocks and

future returns: decile portfolios that long stocks with positive liquidity shocks and short stocks with

negative liquidity shocks generate a raw and risk-adjusted return of 0.70% to 1.20% per month. This

relation is economically and statistically significant and robust across alternative measures of liquid-

ity shocks and after controlling for various risk factors and stock characteristics such as beta, size,

book-to-market, momentum, short-term reversal, co-skewness, idiosyncratic volatility, maximum daily

return, analyst dispersion, level and volatility of illiquidity, exposures to systematic liquidity factors,

unexpected earnings, abnormal dollar trading volume, and signed small-trade turnover. The strong

predictive power of liquidity shocks remains intact for various subsample periods, as well as across

recessionary and expansionary periods.

We show that negative liquidity shocks not only lead to lower contemporaneous returns, but they

also continue to predict negative returns for up to seven months in the future. This evidence suggests

that the stock market underreacts to stock level liquidity shocks.

We explore two potential driving forces of this underreaction: investor inattention and illiquidity.

We find that the predictive power of liquidity shocks for future returns is stronger among stocks that

40

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


receive less investor attention (small stocks and stocks with low analyst coverage and institutional

holdings) as well as among less liquid stocks. While both mechanisms are significant in explaining

one-month ahead return predictability of liquidity shocks, investor inattention mechanism is stronger

in predicting two- to four-month ahead returns.

Our study contributes to the empirical literature on the effects of investor inattention on stock price

dynamics by introducing a new liquidity dimension. Our findings also contribute to the literature on

liquidity and stock returns by focusing on time series variations in liquidity and by providing the first

piece of evidence on the stock market’s underreaction to stock level liquidity shocks.

41

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


References
Acharya, V., and L. H. Pedersen, 2005, “Asset Pricing with Liquidity Risk,” Journal of Financial
Economics, 77, 375–410.
Akbas, F., W. J. Armstrong, and R. Petkova, 2010, “The Volatility of Liquidity and Expected Stock
Returns,” Working Paper.
Amihud, Y., 2002, “Illiquidity and Stock Returns: Cross-section and Time-Series Effects,” Journal of
Financial Markets, 5, 31–56.
Amihud, Y., and H. Mendelson, 1986, “Asset Pricing and the bid-ask spread,” Journal of Financial
Economics, 17, 223–249.
, 1989, “The Effects of Beta, Bid-Ask Spread, Residual Risk and Size on Stock Returns,”
Journal of Finance, 44, 479–486.
An, B.-J., A. Ang, T. G. Bali, and N. Cakici, 2013, “The Joint Cross Section of Stocks and Options,”
Journal of Finance, forthcoming.
Ang, A., R. Hodrick, Y. Xing, and X. Zhang, 2006, “The cross-section of volatility and expected
returns,” Journal of Finance, 61, 259–299.
, 2009, “High idiosyncratic volatility and low returns: International and further U.S. evidence,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 91, 1–23.
Asparouhova, E. N., H. Bessembinder, and I. Kalcheva, 2010, “Liquidity Biases in Asset Pricing Tests,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 96, 215–237.
Bali, T. G., N. Cakici, and R. Whitelaw, 2011, “Maxing out: Stocks as lotteries and the cross-section
of expected returns,” Journal of Financial Economics, 99, 427–446.
Bali, T. G., A. Scherbina, and Y. Tang, 2009, “Unusual News Events and the Cross-Section of Stock
Returns,” Working Paper.
Ball, R., and P. Brown, 1968, “An empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers,” Journal of
Accounting Research, 6, 159–178.
Barber, B., and T. Odean, 2008, “All that glitters: The effect of attention on the buying behavior of
individual and institutional investors,” Review of Financial Studies, 21, 785–818.
Bekaert, G., and G. Wu, 2000, “Asymmetric Volatility and Risk in Equity Markets,” Review of Financial
Studies, 13, 1–42.
Bernard, V. L., and J. K. Thomas, 1989, “Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: Delayed Price Response
or Risk Premium,” Journal of Accounting Research, 27, 1–36.
, 1990, “Evidence that stock prices do not fully reflect the implications of current earnings for
future earnings,” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 13, 305–340.
Bessembinder, H., and K. Venkataraman, 2010, “Bid-Ask Spreads: Measuring Trade Execution Costs
in Financial Markets,” Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance.
Black, F., 1976, “The pricing of commodity contracts,” Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 167–179.
Bollerslev, T., J. Litvinova, and G. Tauchen, 2006, “Leverage and Volatility Feedback Effects in High-
Frequency Data,” Journal of Financial Econometrics, 4, 353–384.

42

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Boulatov, A., S. A. Johnson, B. C. Hatch, and Y. C. Lei, 2009, “Dealer attention, the speed of quote
adjustments to information, and net dealer revenue,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 33, 1531–
1542.
Brennan, M. J., T. Chordia, and A. Subrahmanyam, 1998, “Alternative Factor Specifications, Security
Characteristics, adn the Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns,” Journal of Financial Economics,
49, 345–373.
Brennan, M. J., N. Jegadeesh, and B. Swaminathan, 1993, “Investment Analysis and the Adjustment of
Stock Prices to Common Information,” Review of Financial Studies, 6, 799–824.
Brennan, M. J., and A. Subrahmanyam, 1996, “Market microstructure and asset pricing: On the com-
pensation for illiquidity in stock returns,” Journal of Financial Economics, 41, 441–464.
Campbell, J. Y., and L. Hentschel, 1992, “No news is good news: An asymmetric model of changing
volatility in stock returns,” Journal of Financial Economics, 31, 281–318.
Chakrabarty, B., and P. C. Moulton, 2012, “Earnings announcement and attention constraints: The role
of market design,” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 53, 612–634.
Chordia, T., S. Huh, and A. Subrahmanyam, 2009, “Theory-based Illiquidity and Asset Pricing,” Re-
view of Financial Studies, 22, 3629–2668.
Chordia, T., R. Roll, and A. Subrahmanyam, 2000, “Commonality in liquidity,” Journal of Financial
Economics, 56, 3–28.
, 2001, “Market Liquidity and Trading Activity,” Journal of Finance, 56, 501–530.
Chordia, T., A. Subrahmanyam, and V. R. Anshuman, 2001, “Trading Activity and Expected Stock
Returns,” Journal of Financial Economics, 59, 3–32.
Christie, A. A., 1982, “The stochastic behavior of common stock variances: Value, leverage and interest
rate effects,” Journal of Financial Economics, 10, 407–432.
Cohen, L., and A. Frazzini, 2008, “Economic Links and Predictable Returns,” Journal of Finance, 63,
1977–2011.
Constantinides, G., 1986, “Capital Market Equilibrium with Transaction Costs,” Journal of Political
Economy, 94, 842–862.
Corwin, S. A., and J. F. Coughenour, 2008, “Limited attention and the allocation of effort in securities
trading,” Journal of Finance, 63, 3031–3067.
Cremers, M., and V. Nair, 2005, “Governance Mechanisms and Equity Prices,” Journal of Finance, 60,
2859–2894.
Datar, V. S., N. Y. Naik, and R. Radcliffe, 1998, “Liquidity and Asset Returns: An Alternative Test,”
Journal of Financial Markets, 1, 203–219.
DellaVigna, S., and J. Pollett, 2007, “Demographics and Industry Returns,” American Economic Re-
view, 97, 1167–1702.
, 2009, “Investor Inattention and Friday Earnings Announcements,” Journal of Finance, 64,
709–749.
Desai, H., and P. Jain, 1997, “Long-run Common Stock Returns Following Stock Splits and Reverse
Splits,” Journal of Business, 70, 409–433.

43

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Diether, K., C. Malloy, and A. Scherbina, 2002, “Differences of opinion and the cross-section of stock
returns,” Journal of Finance, 57, 2113–2141.
Duffie, D., N. Garleanu, and L. H. Pedersen, 2002, “Securities Lending, Shorting, and Pricing,” Journal
of Financial Economics, 66, 307–339.
, 2005, “Over-the-Counter Markets,” Econometrica, 73, 1815–1847.
Eleswarapu, V. R., 1997, “Cost of Transacting and Expected Returns in the Nasdaq Market,” Journal
of Finance, 52, 2113–2117.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1992, “The cross-section of expected stock returns,” Journal of Finance,
46, 427–466.
, 1993, “Common risk factors in the returns of stocks and bonds,” Journal of Financial Eco-
nomics, 33, 3–56.
, 2000, “Characteristics, covariances, and average returns: 1929-1997,” Journal of Finance, 55,
389–406.
Fama, E. F., and J. MacBeth, 1973, “Risk, return and equilibrium: Empirical tests,” Journal of Political
Economy, 51, 55–84.
French, K. R., G. W. Schwert, and R. F. Stambaugh, 1987, “Expected stock returns and volatility,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 19, 3–29.
Gao, X., and J. R. Ritter, 2010, “The Marketing of Seasoned Equity Offerings,” Journal of Financial
Economics, 97, 33–52.
Garleanu, N., and L. H. Pedersen, 2004, “Adverse Selection and the Required Return,” Review of
Financial Studies, 17, 643–665.
Gervais, S., R. Kaniel, and D. Mingelgrin, 2001, “The high-volume return premium,” Journal of Fi-
nance, 56, 877–919.
Harvey, C. R., and A. Siddique, 2000, “Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests,” Journal of Finance,
55, 1263–1295.
Hasbrouck, J., 2009, “Trading Costs and Returns for US Equity,” Journal of Finance, 63, 1445–1477.
Hasbrouck, J., and D. J. Seppi, 2001, “Common factors in prices, order flows, and liquidity,” Journal
of Financial Economics, 59, 383–411.
Heaton, J., and D. J. Lucas, 1996, “Evaluating the Effects of Incomplete Markets on Risk Sharing and
Asset Pricing,” Journal of Political Economy, 104, 443–487.
Hirshleifer, D., K. Hou, S. H. Teoh, and Y. Zhang, 2004, “Do Investors Overvalue Firms with Bloated
Balance Sheets,” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 38, 297–331.
Hirshleifer, D., P.-H. Hsu, and D. Li, 2012, “Innovative Efficiency and Stock Returns,” Journal of
Financial Economics, forthcoming.
Hirshleifer, D., S. Lim, and S. H. Teoh, 2009, “Driven to Distraction: Extraneous Events and Underre-
action to Earnings News,” Journal of Finance, 64, 2289–2325.
Hirshleifer, D., and S. H. Teoh, 2003, “Limited Attention, Information Disclosure, and Financial Re-
porting,” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 36, 337–386.

44

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Hodrick, R., 1992, “Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns: Alternative Procedures for Inference
and Measurement,” Review of Financial Studies, 5, 357–386.
Hong, H., T. Lim, and J. Stein, 2000, “Bad news travels slowly: Size, analyst coverage, and the prof-
itability of momentum strategies,” Journal of Finance, 55, 265–295.
Hong, H., W. Torous, and R. Valkanov, 2007, “Do Industries Lead the Stock Market?,” Journal of
Financial Economics, 83, 367–396.
Hou, K., 2007, “Industry Information Diffusion and the Lead-Lag Effect in Stock Returns,” Review of
Financial Studies, 20, 1113–1138.
Hou, K., and T. Moskowitz, 2005, “Market Frictions, Price Delay, and the Cross-Section of Expected
Returns,” Review of Financial Studies, 18, 981–1020.
Huang, M., 2003, “Liquidity Shocks and Equilibrium Liquidity Premia,” Journal of Economic Theory,
109, 104–129.
Huberman, G., and D. Halka, 2001, “Systematic Liquidity,” Journal of Financial Research, 2, 161–178.
Huberman, G., and T. Regev, 2001, “Contagious Speculation and a Cure for Cancer: A Non-Event
That Made Stock Prices Soar,” Journal of Finance, 56, 387–396.
Hvidkjaer, S., 2006, “A Trade-based Analysis of Momentum,” Review of Financial Studies, 19, 457–
491.
, 2008, “Small trades and the cross-section of stock returns,” Review of Financial Studies, 21,
1123–1151.
Ikenberry, D. L., G. Rankine, and E. K. Stice, 1996, “What Do Stock Splits Really Signal?,” Journal
of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 31, 357–375.
Jegadeesh, N., 1990, “Evidence of predictable behavior of security returns,” Journal of Finance, 45,
881–898.
Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1993, “Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for
stock market efficiency,” Journal of Finance, 48, 65–91.
Jones, C. M., 2002, “A Century of Stock Market Liquidity and Trading Costs,” Working Paper,
Columbia University.
Kahneman, N., 1973, Attention and effort. Prentice Hall, New Jersey.
Kyle, A. S., 1985, “Continuous auctions and insider trading,” Econometrica, 53, 1315–1335.
Lee, C. M. C., and M. J. Ready, 1991, “Inferring trade direction from intraday data,” Journal of Fi-
nance, 46, 733–746.
Lin, J.-C., A. K. Singh, and W. Yu, 2009, “Stock Splits, Trading Continuity, and the Cost of Equity
Capital,” Journal of Financial Economics, 93, 474–489.
Lo, A. W., H. Mamaysky, and J. Wang, 2004, “Asset Prices and Trading Volume Under Fixed Transac-
tions,” Journal of Political Economy, 112, 1054–1090.
Mashruwala, C., S. Rajgopal, and T. Shevlin, 2006, “Why Is the Accrual Anomaly Not Arbitraged
Away? The Role of Idiosyncratic Risk and Transaction Costs,” Journal of Accounting and Eco-
nomics, 42, 3–33.

45

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Muscarella, C. J., and M. R. Vetsuypens, 1996, “Stock splits: Signaling or liquidity? The case of ADR
’solo-splits’,” Journal of Financial Economics, 42, 3–26.
Nelson, D. B., 1991, “Conditional heteriskedasticity in asset returns: A new approach,” Econometrica,
59, 347–370.
Newey, W. K., and K. D. West, 1987, “A simple, positive-definite, heteroscedasticity and autocorrela-
tion consistent covariance matrix,” Econometrica, 55, 703–708.
Pashler, H., and J. Johnston, 1998, “Attentional Limitations in Dual-task performance,” in Attention,
ed. by H. Pashler. Psychology Press, pp. 155–189.
Pastor, L., and R. F. Stambaugh, 2003, “Liquidity Risk and Expected Stock Returns,” Journal of Polit-
ical Economy, 111, 642–685.
Peng, L., 2005, “Learning with Information Capacity Constraints,” Journal of Financial Quantitative
Analysis, 40, 307–329.
Peng, L., and W. Xiong, 2006, “Investor Attention, Overconfidence and Category Learning,” Journal
of Financial Economics, 80, 563–602.
Pereira, J. P., and H. H. Zhang, 2010, “Stock Returns and the Volatility of Liquidity,” Journal of Finan-
cial Quantitative Analysis, 45, 1077–1110.
Sadka, R., 2006, “Momentum and post-earnings-announcement drift anomalies: The role of liquidity
risk,” Journal of Financial Economics, 80, 309–349.
Schultz, P., 2000, “Stock Splits, Tick Size, and Sponsorship,” Journal of Finance, 55, 429–450.
Shumway, T., 1997, “The delisting bias in CRSP data,” Journal of Finance, 52, 327–340.
Vayanos, D., 1998, “Transaction Costs and Asset Prices: A Dynamic Equilibrium Model,” Review of
Financial Studies, 11, 1–58.

Appendix

This appendix provides detailed descriptions on how we construct our control variables. Unless other-
wise stated, we measure all variables at the end of portfolio formation month (i.e., month t) and require
a minimum of 15 daily observations for all variables computed monthly from daily data.
Following Fama and French (1992), market beta of an individual stock is estimated by running a
time-series regression based on the monthly return observations over the prior 60 months if available
(minimum of 24 months):

Ri,t − R f ,t = αi + β1i (Rm,t − R f ,t ) + β2i (Rm,t−1 − R f ,t−1 ) + εi,t , (1)

where Ri , R f , and Rm are the monthly returns on stock i, the one-month Treasury bills, and the CRSP
value-weighted index, respectively. The stock’s market beta is the sum of the slope coefficients of the
current and lagged excess market returns (i.e. BETA= βb1i + βb2i ).
The stock’s size (LNME) is the natural logarithm of the product of the price per share and the
number of shares outstanding (in million dollars). Following Fama and French (1992, 1993, and 2000),
the natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio at the end of June of year t, denoted LNBM,

46

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


is computed as the book value of stockholders’ equity, plus deferred taxes and investment tax credit
(if available), minus the book value of preferred stock for the last fiscal year end in t − 1, scaled by
the market value of equity at end of December of t − 1. Depending on availability, the redemption,
liquidation, or par value (in that order) is used as the book value of preferred stock.
Following Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), momentum (MOM) is the cumulative return of a stock
over a period of 11 months ending one month prior to the portfolio formation month. Following Je-
gadeesh (1990), short-term reversal (REV) is defined as the stock return over the prior month.
Following Harvey and Siddique (2000), the stock’s monthly co-skewness (COSKEW) is defined
as the estimate of γi in the regression using the monthly return observations over the prior 60 months
(minimum of 24 months):

Ri,t − R f ,t = αi + βi (Rm,t − R f ,t ) + γi (Rm,t − R f ,t )2 + εi,t , (2)


where Ri , R f , and Rm are the monthly returns on stock i, the one-month Treasury bills, and the CRSP
value-weighted index, respectively.
Following Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006), the monthly idiosyncratic volatility of stock i
(IVOL) is computed as the standard deviation of the residuals from the regression:

Ri,d − R f ,d = αi + βi Rm,d − R f ,d + γi SMBd + ϕi HMLd + εi,d , (3)
where Ri,d , R f ,d , and Rm,d are, respectively, the daily returns on stock i, the one-month Treasury bills,
and the CRSP value-weighted index. SMBd and HMLd are the daily size and book-to-market factors
of Fama and French (1993).
Following Bali, Cakici, and Whitelaw (2011), the stock’s extreme positive return (MAX) is defined
as its maximum daily return in each month.
Following Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002), analyst earnings forecast dispersion (DISP) is the
standard deviation of annual earnings-per-share forecasts scaled by the absolute value of the average
outstanding forecast.
Stocks that experience positive (negative) liquidity shocks may coincide with positive (negative)
earnings shocks and it is well known that earnings shocks are followed by a post announcement drift.
To control for this effect, we follow Ball and Brown (1968) and Bernard and Thomas (1989, 1990) and
define stock i’s unexpected EPS (UE) in calendar quarter q of earnings announcement as:

UEi,q = EPSi,q − EPSi,q−4 , (4)


where EPSi,q and EPSi,q−4 are the stock’s basic EPS excluding extraordinary items in quarters q and
q − 4, respectively. The stock’s standardized unexpected earnings in quarter q (SUEq ) is UEq scaled by
its standard deviation over the past eight quarters (with a minimum of four UE observations available).
Since a stock’s liquidity and trading volume are highly related, we also examine whether the pricing
effect of liquidity shocks is driven by the high volume return premium documented by Gervais, Kaniel,
and Mingelgrin (2001). Following Gervais et al. (2001), stocks are first sorted into low, normal, and
high volume portfolios based on the dollar trading volume on the last but second trading day in the
portfolio formation month relative to daily dollar trading volume over the prior 49 trading days. We
then create two volume premium dummy variables: the high-volume dummy variable (GKMH ) is 1
if a stock belongs to the high volume group and zero otherwise; the low-volume dummy variable
(GKML ) equal to 1 if a stock resides in the low volume portfolio and zero otherwise. Hence, stock i
in month t belongs to one the three groups: GKMH , GKML , and GKMM indicating that the stock does
not experience abnormally high or low dollar volume. We further construct a continuous variable for

47

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


abnormal dollar volume (VOLDU) in the same fashion as we define the liquidity shock. That is, we
subtract monthly dollar volume by its past 12-month average.
We also control for a variety of liquidity-based variables. Following Chordia, Subrahmanyam, and
Anshuman (2001), the trading activity (SDTURN) is computed as the standard deviation of monthly
turnover (TURN) over the past 12 months. Following Akbas, Armstrong, and Petkova (2010), the
coefficient of variation in the Amihud illiquidity (CVILLIQ) is computed as the standard deviation of
the daily Amihud’s illiquidity measure in a month scaled by the monthly Amihud’s illiquidity measure.
Following Pastor and Stambaugh (2003), the stock’s liquidity exposure (PS) is the OLS estimate of
βLi in the regression, estimated using all data available over the past 60 months (if at least 24 months
are available):
Ri,t − R f ,t = αi + βLi Lt + βM S H
i MKTt + βi SMBt + βi HMLt + εi,t , (5)
where Ri and R f are the monthly returns on stock i and the one-month Treasury bills, respectively. L
is the innovation in aggregate liquidity factor, and MKT , SMB, and HML are the three factors of Fama
and French (1993).
Following Acharya and Pedersen (2005) at the end of year k − 1, we sort common stocks listed
on NYSE, Amex and Nasdaq into 25 groups based on the average daily Amihud’s (2002) illiquidity
ratio in year k − 1 (with at least 100 daily ratios available) using the NYSE illiquidity breakpoints. We
estimate the four betas proposed in Acharya and Pedersen (2005) that capture different aspects of a
security’s systematic risk in a world where trading costs vary randomly over time:
Cov (r p,t , rm,t )
β1p = , (6)
Var (rm,t − cum,t )
Cov (cu p,t , cum,t )
β2p = , (7)
Var (rm,t − cum,t )
Cov (r p,t , cum,t )
β3p = , (8)
Var (rm,t − cum,t )
Cov (cu p,t , rmm,t )
β4p = , (9)
Var (rm,t − cum,t )

where r p and rm are, respectively, the monthly excess returns for portfolio p and the market portfolio
proxied by the CRSP equal-weighted index; cu p and cum are the monthly innovations in illiquidity for
portfolio p and the market, respectively. For each month t, we normalize the monthly Amihud’s (2002)
illiquidity measures in months t to t − 2 for stock i (denoted ci,t , ci,t−1|t and ci,t−2|t , respectively) by

ci,t = min (0.25 + 0.3ILLIQi,t Pm,t−1 , 30) , (10)


ci,t−1 = min (0.25 + 0.3ILLIQi,t−1 Pm,t−1 , 30) , (11)
ci,t−2 = min (0.25 + 0.3ILLIQi,t−2 Pm,t−1 , 30) , (12)

where Pm,t−1 is the ratio of the capitalization of the market portfolio at the end of month t − 1 to that
as of the end of July 1962. We then calculate the illiquidity measures in months t to t − 2 for each

48

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


illiquidity portfolio (denoted c p,t , c p,t−1|t and c p,t−2|t , respectively) by averaging the corresponding
normalized illiquidity measures for each stock in the portfolio:

1 T
c p,t = ∑ ci,t , (13)
N t=1
1 T
c p,t−1|t = ∑ ci,t−1|t , (14)
N t=1
1 T
c p,t−2|t = ∑ ci,t−2|t . (15)
N t=1

The illiquidity measures in months t to t − 2 for the market (denoted cm,t , cm,t−1|t and cm,t−2|t , re-
spectively) are calculated similarly by averaging the corresponding normalized illiquidity measures for
NYSE/Amex common stocks.
The liquidity innovations in month t for portfolio p (cu p,t ) and the market (cm p,t ) are defined as
the residuals of the AR(2) model estimated based on a 60-month rolling sample with a minimum of 24
observations and updated on a monthly basis:

c p/m,t = a0 + a1 c p/m,t−1|t + a2 c p/m,t−2|t + ε p/m,t , (16)


cu p/m,t ≡ ε p/m,t . (17)

For each month t, the four factor loadings of stock i (denoted β1i,t , β2i,t , β3i,t and β4i,t ) are, respectively, set
to β1p,t , β2p,t , β3p,t and β4p,t of the illiquidity portfolio to which the stock belongs in the month.
We further control for the pricing effects of the illiquidity risk factor of Sadka (2006). We download
from Ronnie Sadka’s webpage the time series of the monthly fixed and variable components of the
illiquidity factor covering the period from April 1984 to December 2010. For each month, a stock’s
illiquidity risk loadings on the fixed and the variable components (denoted SADKAF and SADKAV,
respectively) are estimated using monthly return data over the prior 60 months with a minimum of
24 monthly observations available after controlling for the monthly market, size and book-to-market
factors of Fama and French (1993):

Ri,t − R f ,t = αi + λ1 FIXt + λ2VARt + βi (Rm,t − R f ,t ) + γi SMBt + ϕi HMLt + εi,t , (18)


where FIX and VAR are the fixed and variable components of Sadka’s liquidity factor.
In Section 4, we investigate the pricing effect associated with liquidity shocks in conjunction with
alternative measures of investor attention. Following the literature, we use several measures to capture
the degree of investor attention: (i) stock size (LNME); (ii) analyst coverage (CVRG), computed as
the natural logarithm of the number of analysts covering the stock in the portfolio formation month;
and (iii) institutional holdings (INST), defined as quarterly institutional ownership as of the portfolio
formation month.
In Section 6, to ensure that our liquidity shock measures are not picking up the effect of small
trade order flows, we control for the variables originally introduced by Hvidkjaer (2008). Each trade
from the TAQ database covering the period of 1993 - 2010 is identified as buy- or sell-initiated using
the procedure described in Lee and Ready (1991). We sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on the
NYSE/Amex size breakpoints. The small-trade cutoff for each size quintile is calculated as the ratio of
a dollar cutoff to the share price at the end of the prior month rounded up to the nearest hundred round-
lot, where the dollar cutoffs are, respectively, $4,800, $7,300, $10,300 and $16,400 for the smallest to
the largest size portfolios. The monthly small-trade buy-initiated turnover is calculated as the ratio of

49

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


the small-trade buy-volume in a month to the number of shares outstanding. The monthly small-trade
sell-initiated turnover is calculated similarly. At the end of each portfolio formation month (i.e., month
t), the small-trade buy- and sell-initiated turnover are then summed over the prior J months, where
J=1, 3, 6, 12, and 24. For each J, the signed small-trade turnover (SSTTJ ) is the difference between
the corresponding summed small-trade buy-initiated turnover and the summed small-trade sell-initiated
turnover.

50

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Figure 1. Monthly return differences between the highest and lowest LIQU deciles for 1 to 12
months after portfolio formation. This figure depicts the monthly return differences between the
highest and lowest LIQU deciles for 1 to 12 months after portfolio formation. LIQU is the liquidity
shock, defined as the negative Amihud’s (2002) illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), demeaned using the past
12-month ILLIQ as the mean. The dashed lines indicate the 95% confidence bands based on the
Newey-West robust standard errors.

51

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 1
Descriptive statistics

Panel A reports the time-series averages of the cross-sectional mean, median, and standard deviation
of each variable used in this paper. All the variables, except for RET, the return in month t + 1, are
computed for individual stocks at the end of the portfolio formation month (month t). LIQU denotes
the liquidity shock, defined as the negative Amihud’s (2002) illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), demeaned
using the past 12-month ILLIQ as the mean. SPRDU is the shock to the monthly volume-weighted
effective relative spread (SPRD), calculated in the same fashion as LIQU. LIQCU denotes the condi-
tional measure of liquidity shock, defined as the negative of the difference between the realized ILLIQ
and the conditional mean of ILLIQ in the month estimated under the assumption that the conditional
mean of ILLIQ follows an ARMA(1,1) process. BETA, LNME, and LNBM denote the market beta,
the natural logarithm of the market capitalization, and the natural logarithm of the book-to-market eq-
uity ratio, respectively. MOM is the momentum return. REV is the short-term reversal. COSKEW
and IVOL are the co-skewness and idiosyncratic volatility, respectively. MAX denotes the maximum
daily return in a month. DISP measures the analyst earnings forecast dispersion. SUE is the stan-
dardized unexpected earnings. GKMH and GKML denote the high- and low-volume dummy variables.
VOLDU is the dollar trading volume shock, calculated in the same fashion as LIQU and SPRDU. SD-
TURN denotes the standard deviation of the monthly turnover over the past 12 months. CVILLIQ is
the coefficient of variation in the Amihud’s illiquidity measure. PS is Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003)
liquidity beta. BETA1–BETA4 are Acharya and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas. SADKAF and
SADKAV are the loadings on the fixed and the variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity fac-
tor. CVRG denotes the natural logarithm of the number of analysts covering the stock. INST is the
quarterly institutional ownership. Panel B reports time-series average of the monthly cross-sectional
correlations (multiplied by 100) between the variables in our sample. The full sample covers the period
from August 1963 to December 2010.

52

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 1 – continued
Panel A. Summary statistics
Variable Mean Median Std. dev.
RET 1.12 0.51 11.08
ILLIQ 0.81 0.15 2.94
SPRD 0.99 0.70 0.98
LIQU 0.17 0.01 1.39
SPRDU 0.27 0.07 1.02
LIQCU 0.26 0.01 3.07
BETA 1.32 1.21 0.79
LNME 5.34 5.17 1.63
LNBM -0.50 -0.41 0.74
MOM 20.18 10.92 53.19
REV 1.77 0.79 11.74
COSKEW -0.01 -0.01 0.08
IVOL 2.12 1.85 1.25
MAX 5.73 4.66 4.50
DISP 0.13 0.02 0.90
SUE -0.02 -0.01 1.04
GKMH 0.11 0.03 0.27
GKML 0.08 0.00 0.27
VOLDU 0.43 -0.08 3.03
CVILLIQ 1.14 1.03 0.44
SDTURN 0.42 0.24 0.73
PS -1.20 -0.82 36.10
BETA1 0.93 0.83 1.62
BETA2 0.01 0.00 0.14
BETA3 -0.03 -0.03 0.89
BETA4 -0.02 0.00 0.28
SADKAF 2.44 0.71 35.61
SADKAV -0.25 -0.15 6.16
CVRG 1.89 1.89 0.77
INST 0.43 0.44 0.24

53

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 1 – continued
Panel B: Correlations
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (17) (18) (19) (20) (21) (22) (23) (24) (25) (26) (27) (28) (29)
RET (1)
ILLIQ (2) 0.2
SPRD (3) 0.1 53.4
LIQU (4) 2.4 -19.3 15.4
SPRDU (5) 2.0 -6.4 -15.9 42.8
LIQCU (6) 1.7 -15.3 10.0 52.8 21.4
BETA (7) -0.9 4.0 3.9 3.4 7.5 6.6
LNME (8) -0.6 -40.8 -65.3 -12.6 -11.6 -12.5 -22.1
LNBM (9) 2.6 13.4 14.2 3.5 -1.4 -0.9 -13.0 -22.5
MOM (10) 3.5 -7.8 -6.2 22.5 27.0 13.8 5.1 2.5 -14.1
REV (11) -3.0 -0.5 2.1 12.6 11.9 9.9 1.7 0.1 2.0 0.4
COSKEW (12) -0.2 -4.1 -10.3 -1.7 -2.2 -2.4 3.7 10.2 4.2 -1.1 0.2
IVOL (13) -3.7 25.3 39.9 9.8 6.5 12.1 34.2 -41.0 -6.0 1.8 21.2 -4.2
MAX (14) -3.6 16.2 26.6 11.6 8.3 12.2 28.8 -28.8 -4.8 1.2 42.0 -2.8 85.8

54
DISP (15) -1.0 -2.7 -0.1 -2.1 -1.1 -1.7 4.0 1.3 3.3 -5.3 -0.8 0.7 3.8 3.1
SUE (16) 3.8 -1.1 -2.4 6.8 7.6 1.8 -0.5 3.0 -0.6 23.1 8.5 0.3 -1.3 1.3 -2.3
GKMH (17) 0.5 2.6 5.6 -7.3 -11.0 -3.5 -0.3 -5.0 1.1 -20.7 -28.2 -0.2 4.7 -4.6 2.9 -12.8
GKML (18) 0.2 -0.8 -1.3 2.7 3.1 0.8 -0.8 1.3 -0.7 8.7 -1.1 0.2 -2.7 -2.1 -0.9 3.6 -8.8
VOLDU (19) 1.3 -4.8 -1.7 18.9 16.5 11.4 -1.5 1.6 -0.4 14.6 38.8 -0.1 27.0 32.3 -1.6 9.0 -8.4 -0.9
CVILLIQ (20) 0.9 29.6 48.1 2.2 5.0 1.9 -4.5 -36.8 13.2 -5.6 3.7 -4.7 4.1 3.1 -3.1 -1.0 0.5 -0.1 5.3
SDTURN (21) -2.2 -4.3 -1.0 6.7 12.8 7.0 27.7 -15.8 -11.1 20.4 3.8 -0.6 32.1 27.6 3.1 -1.3 -0.6 0.3 8.3 -7.8
PS (22) 0.4 -0.5 0.8 0.1 0.5 -0.8 -4.6 1.5 2.0 0.0 0.7 -21.0 -3.6 -2.7 -0.5 0.5 0.2 -0.2 0.6 1.9 -4.1
BETA1 (23) -1.4 5.6 5.9 4.1 7.7 7.9 76.8 -24.5 -10.4 5.0 1.7 3.4 33.5 27.8 3.3 -0.6 -1.1 -0.3 -1.5 -3.2 26.9 -10.0
BETA2 (24) -0.1 26.9 32.4 13.8 10.2 19.6 16.5 -33.2 4.0 7.4 3.7 -3.6 20.9 15.6 -2.4 0.4 -1.5 0.6 2.6 16.2 5.3 -2.7 16.6
BETA3 (25) 0.8 -2.6 -5.5 -3.1 -4.4 -4.9 -50.4 12.8 8.7 -3.3 0.0 2.7 -17.5 -14.3 -1.7 0.8 -0.3 0.3 1.1 1.0 -13.8 -2.6 -39.9 -15.8
BETA4 (26) 0.1 -17.4 -20.3 -8.6 -7.6 -12.4 -14.5 24.7 -2.0 -5.5 -2.2 1.3 -14.8 -11.1 1.7 0.0 1.0 -0.4 -1.5 -10.3 -5.2 2.3 -16.6 -44.3 11.1
SADKAF (27) 0.4 3.6 6.5 3.7 3.7 2.8 26.2 -6.4 2.1 4.5 1.5 7.1 6.8 5.4 -0.3 0.5 -0.6 0.0 1.2 3.2 3.4 5.9 7.8 5.1 -8.4 -3.8
SADKAV (28) 0.4 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.9 -0.3 -3.1 -0.5 1.3 -0.4 1.1 -13.7 -1.3 -1.0 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.1 0.6 2.0 -1.7 18.0 -7.8 0.9 -6.1 -0.4 -22.1

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


CVRG (29) -0.9 -26.4 -52.3 -8.1 -11.9 -11.6 -12.1 76.5 -12.6 -6.4 -2.9 14.4 -24.9 -17.3 -3.7 0.4 0.5 0.0 -1.0 -33.8 -5.7 -1.3 -14.9 -25.4 10.3 19.2 -3.6 -1.2
INST (30) 0.6 -23.7 -49.9 -14.0 -11.7 -11.4 2.9 53.5 -5.5 -3.3 -4.1 13.6 -21.0 -14.8 2.5 1.5 -0.7 0.0 -2.4 -30.1 1.7 0.0 -1.0 -22.2 -0.4 15.9 -5.6 0.2 43.6
Table 2
Contemporaneous returns for portfolios formed on LIQU

For month t, NYSE, Amex and Nasdaq stocks are sorted into ten decile portfolios based on their
liquidity shock (LIQU) using the NYSE breakpoints. LIQU is defined as the negative Amihud’s (2002)
illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), demeaned using the past 12-month ILLIQ as the mean. This table reports
the equal- and value-weighted monthly contemporaneous returns (month t) and the alpha with respect
to the Fama-French (1993) factors for each LIQU portfolio. Columns “Avg. LIQU” and “Avg. ILLIQ”
report the average LIQU and ILLIQ values for each decile portfolio. The last column shows the average
market share of each portfolio. The last row shows the differences in monthly returns between High
and Low LIQU decile portfolios and the alphas. Average returns and alphas are defined in monthly
percentage terms. Newey-West t-statistics are given in parentheses. The sample covers the period from
August 1963 to December 2010.

Equal-weighted Value-weighted
Decile Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. LIQU Avg. ILLIQ Mkt. shr.
1 (Low) -0.39 -1.61 0.04 -1.10 -0.8970 2.6533 4.73%
(-1.61) (-12.18) (0.17) (-8.20)
2 -0.25 -1.40 0.30 -0.78 -0.0803 0.2963 10.55%
(-1.00) (-12.73) (1.25) (-6.87)
3 0.22 -0.92 0.69 -0.39 -0.0335 0.1479 16.59%
(0.88) (-8.93) (2.85) (-3.55)
4 0.61 -0.51 1.12 0.07 -0.0132 0.0881 16.68%
(2.42) (-5.17) (4.51) (0.64)
5 0.96 -0.13 1.60 0.60 -0.0006 0.0704 15.22%
(4.01) (-1.58) (6.89) (8.01)
6 1.36 0.29 2.12 1.14 0.0111 0.0716 12.56%
(5.73) (4.17) (8.86) (13.49)
7 1.74 0.67 2.64 1.66 0.0270 0.0927 9.28%
(7.27) (10.14) (10.38) (14.34)
8 2.08 0.99 3.15 2.14 0.0551 0.1415 6.91%
(8.92) (13.52) (12.22) (16.59)
9 2.61 1.48 3.80 2.76 0.1209 0.2463 4.66%
(10.43) (18.00) (13.81) (18.55)
10 (High) 4.51 3.29 5.27 4.11 1.3128 0.9851 2.84%
(15.05) (25.93) (15.94) (22.67)
High-Low 4.90 4.89 5.23 5.20
(28.88) (28.92) (22.15) (21.67)

55

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 3
One-month ahead returns for portfolios formed on liquidity shocks
For month t, NYSE, Amex and Nasdaq stocks are sorted into ten decile portfolios based on one of the three liquidity shock measures (LIQU, SPRDU and
LIQCU) using the NYSE breakpoints. LIQU denotes the liquidity shock, defined as the negative Amihud’s (2002) illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), demeaned
using the past 12-month ILLIQ as the mean. SPRDU is the shock to the monthly volume-weighted effective relative spread (SPRD), calculated in the same
fashion as LIQU. LIQCU denotes the conditional measure of liquidity shock, defined as the negative of the difference between the realized ILLIQ and the
conditional mean of ILLIQ in the month estimated under the assumption that the conditional mean of ILLIQ follows an ARMA(1,1) process. This table
reports the equal- and value-weighted one-month ahead returns (month t + 1) and the alpha with respect to the Fama-French (1993) factors for each liquidity
shock decile portfolio. The last row shows the differences in monthly returns between High and Low liquidity shock decile portfolios and the corresponding
alphas. Average returns and alphas are defined in monthly percentage terms. Newey-West t-statistics are given in parentheses. The sample period for the
results based on LIQU and LIQCU is from August 1963 to December 2010. The results for SPRDU are based on the sample period from January 1993 to
December 2010.
LIQU SPRDU LIQCU
Equal-weighted Value-weighted Equal-weighted Value-weighted Equal-weighted Value-weighted
Decile Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha
1 (Low) 0.51 -0.75 0.43 -0.73 0.50 -0.55 0.56 -0.54 0.77 -0.49 0.60 -0.55

56
(1.84) (-8.75) (1.68) (-7.45) (1.42) (-4.18) (1.43) (-2.86) (2.87) (-6.84) (2.43) (-7.19)
2 0.72 -0.45 0.65 -0.42 0.97 -0.17 0.72 -0.32 0.76 -0.41 0.63 -0.41
(2.75) (-5.14) (2.71) (-4.53) (2.71) (-1.30) (1.80) (-2.06) (3.09) (-5.59) (2.79) (-6.13)
3 0.94 -0.17 0.84 -0.17 1.02 -0.06 0.83 -0.10 1.00 -0.10 0.98 -0.01
(3.81) (-1.88) (3.68) (-1.94) (3.00) (-0.53) (2.55) (-0.72) (4.34) (-1.27) (4.67) (-0.09)
4 1.04 -0.06 1.01 -0.01 0.92 -0.17 0.83 -0.11 1.05 -0.01 0.98 0.03
(4.41) (-0.79) (4.56) (-0.12) (2.76) (-2.08) (2.65) (-1.09) (4.75) (-0.20) (4.64) (0.60)
5 1.08 -0.02 0.99 -0.01 0.94 -0.11 0.82 -0.11 1.08 0.02 0.95 -0.01
(4.47) (-0.28) (4.36) (-0.21) (3.09) (-1.30) (2.81) (-1.59) (4.78) (0.35) (4.42) (-0.12)
6 1.07 -0.02 1.04 0.04 1.04 -0.02 0.88 0.00 1.19 0.09 1.14 0.15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


(4.53) (-0.39) (4.84) (0.82) (3.37) (-0.21) (3.04) (0.00) (5.16) (1.37) (5.28) (2.75)
7 1.19 0.10 1.21 0.23 0.98 -0.05 0.87 -0.03 1.23 0.11 1.08 0.10
(5.17) (1.74) (5.45) (3.63) (3.27) (-0.67) (2.94) (-0.37) (5.13) (1.73) (4.71) (1.60)
8 1.23 0.10 1.16 0.15 1.01 -0.02 1.12 0.23 1.30 0.12 1.22 0.17
(5.04) (1.71) (4.97) (1.96) (3.35) (-0.20) (3.66) (1.68) (5.13) (2.24) (5.01) (2.76)
9 1.34 0.18 1.29 0.24 1.19 0.14 1.18 0.23 1.41 0.22 1.30 0.23
(5.27) (2.89) (5.32) (3.49) (3.76) (1.77) (3.49) (1.74) (5.51) (3.94) (5.24) (3.49)
10 (High) 1.69 0.48 1.60 0.45 1.42 0.43 1.23 0.25 1.52 0.27 1.40 0.22
(6.02) (6.88) (6.01) (6.01) (4.25) (4.21) (3.39) (1.75) (5.25) (4.38) (4.97) (3.83)
High-Low 1.18 1.23 1.17 1.17 0.92 0.98 0.67 0.79 0.75 0.76 0.80 0.78
(10.18) (10.13) (8.01) (7.64) (5.08) (5.94) (2.26) (2.90) (7.76) (8.93) (5.73) (6.81)
Table 4
Bivariate portfolio sorts
This table reports the equal-weighted returns and return differences in month t + 1 between High and Low liquidity shock (LIQU) quintile
portfolios and the Fama-French (1993) alphas after controlling for a given stock characteristic. LIQU is computed as the negative Amihud’s
(2002) illiquidity measure, demeaned using the past 12-month illiquidity as the mean. BETA, LNME, and LNBM denote the market beta,
the natural logarithm of the market capitalization, and the natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio, respectively. MOM is the
momentum return. REV is the short-term reversal. COSKEW and IVOL are the co-skewness and idiosyncratic volatility, respectively. MAX
denotes the maximum daily return in a month. DISP measures the analyst earnings forecast dispersion. SUE is the standardized unexpected
earnings. CVILLIQ is the coefficient of variation in the Amihud’s illiquidity measure. SDTURN denotes the standard deviation of the monthly
turnover over the past 12 months. PS is thePastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta. BETA1–BETA4 are Acharya and Pedersen’s (2005)
four liquidity betas. SADKAF and SADKAV are the loadings on the fixed and the variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor.
GKM divides the sample into the high, median, and low dollar trading volume groups. VOLDU measures the abnormal dollar trading volume.
Newey-West t-statistics are reported in parentheses.
Quintile BETA SIZE BM MOM REV COSKEW IVOL MAX DISP SUE ILLIQ
1 (Low) 0.63 0.68 0.50 0.73 0.45 0.57 0.74 0.73 0.68 0.87 0.69
2 0.97 0.93 0.98 0.89 0.92 0.93 0.93 0.91 1.02 1.23 0.95

57
3 1.14 1.19 1.15 1.07 1.10 1.10 1.12 1.12 1.16 1.32 1.16
4 1.38 1.32 1.40 1.34 1.39 1.41 1.40 1.39 1.37 1.54 1.30
5 (High) 1.74 1.43 1.71 1.64 1.79 1.72 1.76 1.84 1.69 1.84 1.51
High - Low 1.12 0.75 1.21 0.91 1.35 1.16 1.02 1.11 1.01 0.96 0.82
(7.46) (5.89) (7.84) (7.38) (7.65) (7.46) (7.89) (7.50) (7.04) (6.61) (5.37)
Alpha 1.15 0.85 1.24 0.88 1.36 1.19 1.03 1.13 1.02 0.99 0.85
(7.09) (6.38) (7.72) (7.96) (7.77) (7.55) (7.06) (7.15) (7.59) (6.84) (5.43)

Quintile CVILLIQ SDTURN PS BETA1 BETA2 BETA3 BETA4 SADKAF SADKAV GKM VOLDU

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


1 (Low) 0.46 0.60 0.56 0.51 0.58 0.45 0.57 0.34 0.35 0.62 0.62
2 0.97 0.96 0.92 0.92 0.89 0.89 0.85 0.92 0.95 0.99 0.87
3 1.12 1.11 1.09 1.04 1.08 1.04 1.04 1.04 1.04 1.10 1.09
4 1.30 1.39 1.32 1.28 1.23 1.30 1.26 1.22 1.21 1.21 1.37
5 (High) 1.66 1.74 1.69 1.61 1.35 1.63 1.40 1.51 1.54 1.66 1.67
High - Low 1.20 1.14 1.13 1.11 0.76 1.18 0.82 1.18 1.19 1.03 1.05
(7.40) (7.93) (7.29) (7.63) (6.58) (7.89) (6.74) (7.63) (7.54) (7.60) (7.94)
Alpha 1.22 1.17 1.18 1.18 0.88 1.25 0.91 1.33 1.34 0.99 0.99
(7.39) (7.58) (7.45) (7.43) (7.87) (7.11) (7.35) (7.60) (7.22) (7.42) (7.20)
Table 5
Bivariate sorts controlling for volume shocks and idosyncratic volatility shocks

This table reports the average returns in month t + 1 for each portfolio obtained from conditional bivari-
ate sorts by volume shocks (VOLDU) and LIQU (Panel A), and idosyncratic volatility shocks (IVOLU)
and LIQU (Panel B). The last column in each panel reports the average returns for each LIQU port-
folio across the five control variable quintiles (VOLDU in Panel A, and IVOLU in Panel B). The last
two rows in each panel present the return differences between the highest and the lowest LIQU portfo-
lios within each control quintile and the corresponding alphas with respect to the Fama-French (1993)
factors. Newey-West t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

Panel A. Control for VOLDU


LIQU VOLDU (Low) VOLDU 2 VOLDU 3 VOLDU 4 VOLDU (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.45 0.35 0.61 0.72 0.97 0.62
2 0.42 0.81 0.91 1.03 1.16 0.87
3 0.88 0.94 1.05 1.19 1.39 1.09
4 1.03 1.21 1.36 1.52 1.74 1.37
5 (High) 1.27 1.63 1.66 1.78 1.99 1.67
High - Low 0.82 1.28 1.05 1.07 1.02 1.05
(8.10) (10.74) (7.81) (7.02) (5.64) (7.94)
Alpha 0.93 1.28 0.98 0.90 0.87 0.99
(9.72) (10.82) (7.76) (7.09) (6.01) (7.20)

Panel B. Control for IVOLU


LIQU IVOLU (Low) IVOLU 2 IVOLU 3 IVOLU 4 IVOLU (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.65 0.70 0.84 0.69 -0.02 0.57
2 1.04 0.94 0.98 0.99 0.49 0.89
3 1.14 1.15 1.11 1.14 0.82 1.07
4 1.64 1.36 1.30 1.38 1.20 1.38
5 (High) 1.96 1.96 1.79 1.76 1.43 1.78
High - Low 1.31 1.26 0.95 1.06 1.45 1.21
(7.46) (8.02) (5.09) (5.94) (6.24) (7.91)
Alpha 1.33 1.27 0.96 1.08 1.49 1.23
(7.52) (7.60) (5.08) (5.81) (6.97) (8.09)

58

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 6
Stock-level cross-sectional regressions

Monthly excess stock returns are regressed on a set of lagged predictive variables using the Fama and
MacBeth (1973) methodology. This table reports the average slope coefficients and Newey-West t-
statistics in parentheses. LIQU denotes the liquidity shock, defined as the negative Amihud’s (2002)
illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), demeaned using the past 12-month ILLIQ as the mean. SPRDU is the
shock to the monthly volume-weighted effective relative spread (SPRD), calculated in the same fashion
as LIQU. LIQCU denotes the conditional measure of liquidity shock, defined as the negative of the
difference between the realized ILLIQ and the conditional mean of ILLIQ in the month estimated under
the assumption that the conditional mean of ILLIQ follows an ARMA(1,1) process. BETA, LNME,
and LNBM denote the market beta, the natural logarithm of the market capitalization, and the natural
logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio, respectively. MOM is the momentum return. REV is the
short-term reversal. COSKEW and IVOL are the co-skewness and idiosyncratic volatility, respectively.
MAX denotes the maximum daily return in a month. DISP measures the analyst earnings forecast
dispersion. SUE is the standardized unexpected earnings. CVILLIQ is the coefficient of variation in
the Amihud’s illiquidity measure. SDTURN denotes the standard deviation of the monthly turnover
over the past 12 months. PS is Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta. BETA1–BETA4 are
Acharya and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas. SADKAF and SADKAV are the loadings on the
fixed and the variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor. GKMH and GKML denote the
high- and low-volume dummy variables. VOLDU measures the abnormal dollar trading volume.

59

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 6 – continued
Variable LIQU SPRDU LIQCU
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQ-Shock 0.201 0.175 0.632 0.554 0.179 0.146
(5.00) (4.36) (7.41) (6.80) (5.12) (3.59)
BETA 0.156 0.171 0.264 0.278 0.175 0.188
(1.41) (1.56) (2.19) (2.32) (1.57) (1.69)
LNME -0.066 -0.096 -0.065 -0.081 -0.044 -0.085
(-2.03) (-2.94) (-1.58) (-1.99) (-1.35) (-2.59)
LNBM 0.140 0.125 0.101 0.091 0.148 0.126
(1.82) (1.65) (1.20) (1.09) (1.95) (1.68)
MOM 0.005 0.003 0.004 0.002 0.005 0.003
(3.33) (2.04) (2.04) (1.18) (3.20) (2.05)
REV -0.033 -0.048 -0.028 -0.041 -0.034 -0.048
(-6.13) (-8.84) (-5.20) (-7.77) (-6.18) (-8.64)
COSKEW 0.119 0.105 0.731 0.689 0.280 0.252
(0.15) (0.13) (0.87) (0.83) (0.36) (0.33)
IVOL -0.307 -0.383 -0.247 -0.334 -0.279 -0.356
(-6.47) (-7.89) (-4.24) (-5.49) (-5.62) (-7.17)
MAX -0.012 -0.002 -0.018 -0.011 -0.009 0.000
(-1.25) (-0.21) (-1.58) (-0.96) (-0.90) (-0.01)
DISP -0.070 -0.064 -0.09 -0.08 -0.079 -0.074
(-2.27) (-2.07) (-2.32) (-2.17) (-2.51) (-2.37)
SPRD 0.059 0.102
(0.88) (1.50)
ILLIQ 0.051 0.032 0.176 0.154 0.068 0.052
(1.95) (1.32) (4.55) (4.09) (2.63) (2.08)
CVILLIQ 0.098 0.034 0.102 0.032 0.112 0.045
(1.66) (0.58) (1.51) (0.47) (1.81) (0.74)
SDTURN -0.271 -0.226 -0.233 -0.176 -0.263 -0.215
(-2.94) (-2.51) (-2.43) (-1.86) (-2.83) (-2.36)
PS 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.002
(1.28) (1.18) (0.96) (0.89) (1.44) (1.34)
BETA1 0.180 0.181 0.210 0.215 0.136 0.138
(0.95) (0.97) (0.97) (1.01) (0.68) (0.70)
BETA2 -4.367 -3.606 2.963 2.869 -5.019 -3.544
(-1.14) (-0.96) (0.82) (0.81) (-1.15) (-0.83)
BETA3 1.638 1.541 3.977 3.874 2.020 1.871
(1.27) (1.21) (3.28) (3.22) (1.43) (1.34)
BETA4 -0.325 -0.334 -0.098 -0.091 -0.570 -0.571
(-0.98) (-1.02) (-0.28) (-0.27) (-1.38) (-1.40)
SADKAF -0.004 -0.004 0.000 0.000 -0.004 -0.003
(-1.12) (-1.16) (-0.03) (0.01) (-1.11) (-1.10)
SADKAV -0.016 -0.016 -0.011 -0.010 -0.016 -0.015
(-1.82) (-1.80) (-1.07) (-0.99) (-1.76) (-1.70)
SUE 0.303 0.283 0.276 0.254 0.303 0.283
(13.77) (12.99) (11.13) (10.42) (13.82) (13.07)
GKMH 0.547 0.523 0.537
(5.64) (4.76) (5.22)
GKML -0.071 -0.136 -0.079
(-1.10) (-1.85) (-1.17)
VOLDU 0.210 0.186 0.200
(9.77) (7.84) (9.35)
60

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 7
Bivariate sorts controlling for attention and liquidity

Stocks are sorted into quintile portfolios based on an investor attention variable or the Amihud’s illiq-
uidity measure (ILLIQ) and then into quintile portfolios of liquidity shock (LIQU) within each control
quintile using NYSE breakpoints. The investor attention variables are the natural logarithm of mar-
ket capitalization (LNME), the number of analysts covering the stocks (CVRG), and the quarterly
aggregate institutional holdings (INST). This table reports the average returns for each of the 5 × 5
portfolios, the return differences between High and Low LIQU quintile portfolios within each control
variable quintile portfolio and the Fama-French (1993) alphas. The last column presents the 5 − 1 av-
erage return differences for each control variable within each LIQU quintile portfolio. Newey-West
t-statistics are given in parentheses.
Panel A. Control for LNME
LIQU LNME (Low) LNME 2 LNME 3 LNME 4 LNME (High) High - Low
1 (Low) 0.41 0.76 0.74 0.82 0.64 0.22
2 0.77 1.00 1.02 0.98 0.89 0.11
3 1.33 1.23 1.26 1.13 0.98 -0.35
4 1.72 1.45 1.33 1.19 0.89 -0.84
5 (High) 1.87 1.58 1.39 1.23 1.07 -0.80
High - Low 1.45 0.82 0.66 0.40 0.43 -1.02
(10.96) (5.27) (4.16) (2.66) (2.98) (-7.54)
Alpha 1.50 0.95 0.75 0.54 0.52 -0.98
(11.51) (5.80) (4.33) (3.32) (3.51) (-7.16)

Panel B. Control for CVRG


LIQU CVRG (Low) CVRG 2 CVRG 3 CVRG 4 CVRG (High) High - Low
1 (Low) 0.61 0.78 0.95 1.02 0.78 0.17
2 0.89 1.09 1.11 1.05 1.02 0.13
3 1.26 1.19 1.23 1.02 1.05 -0.21
4 1.62 1.32 1.18 1.18 1.03 -0.59
5 (High) 1.89 1.70 1.52 1.35 1.27 -0.62
High - Low 1.28 0.92 0.57 0.33 0.49 -0.79
(8.14) (5.01) (2.70) (1.71) (2.11) (-3.90)
Alpha 1.32 1.00 0.62 0.42 0.51 -0.81
(8.40) (5.89) (3.07) (2.11) (2.24) (-3.89)

61

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 7 – continued
Panel C. Control for INST
LIQU INST (Low) INST 2 INST 3 INST 4 INST (High) High - Low
1 (Low) 0.23 0.50 0.74 0.75 0.72 0.49
2 0.54 0.98 1.22 1.15 1.09 0.55
3 1.04 1.03 1.26 1.20 1.11 0.07
4 1.55 1.36 1.22 1.20 1.13 -0.42
5 (High) 1.70 1.84 1.57 1.55 1.33 -0.37
High - Low 1.47 1.34 0.82 0.79 0.61 -0.86
(9.18) (7.34) (4.32) (4.15) (3.16) (-4.71)
Alpha 1.56 1.46 1.01 0.98 0.82 -0.74
(10.80) (8.82) (5.58) (5.53) (4.59) (-4.33)

Panel D. Control for ILLIQ


LIQU ILLIQ (Low) ILLIQ 2 ILLIQ 3 ILLIQ 4 ILLIQ (High) High - Low
1 (Low) 0.73 0.82 0.79 0.67 0.45 -0.29
2 0.94 0.98 1.03 1.03 0.78 -0.15
3 0.99 1.18 1.24 1.19 1.18 0.19
4 0.98 1.17 1.31 1.39 1.65 0.68
5 (High) 1.26 1.30 1.45 1.75 1.81 0.55
High - Low 0.52 0.47 0.66 1.08 1.36 0.84
(3.44) (2.60) (3.24) (5.34) (10.56) (6.00)
Alpha 0.49 0.58 0.69 1.12 1.38 0.89
(3.03) (3.23) (3.24) (5.25) (10.99) (6.07)

62

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 8
Monthly Fama-MacBeth regressions with interaction terms

One-month ahead excess returns are regressed on the Amihud’s illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), one investor atten-
tion variable, the liquidity shock (LIQ-Shock), and the interactions between ILLIQ and LIQ-Shock and between
the attention variable and LIQ-Shock using the Fama-MacBeth (1973) methodology. LIQ-Shock is measured
by LIQU in Panel A, SPRDU in Panel B and LIQCU in Panel C. The investor attention variables are the nat-
ural logarithm of market capitalization (LNME), the number of analysts covering the stocks (CVRG), and the
quarterly aggregate institutional holdings (INST). We simultaneously control for a large set of cross-sectional
predictors: the investor attention variable (controlled for one at a time), the market beta (BETA), LNME, the
natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio (LNBM), the momentum return (MOM), the short-term re-
versal (REV), the co-skewness (COSKEW), the idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), the maximum daily return in a
month (MAX), the analyst earnings forecast dispersion (DISP), the standardized unexpected earnings (SUE), the
high- and low-volume dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ), the dollar trading volume shock (VOLDU), the
standard deviation of the monthly turnover over the past 12 months (SDTURN), the coefficient of variation in
the Amihud’s illiquidity measure (CVILLIQ), Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta (PS), Acharya and
Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas (BETA1–BETA4), and the loadings on the fixed and the variable com-
ponents of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor (SADKAF and SADKAV). Specifications (1) and (2) control for the
GKM dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ) and the abnormal dollar trading volume (VOLDU), respectively.
For brevity, we suppress the average slope coefficients of the control variables, which are available in Table A10
of the online appendix. Newey-West t-statistics are given in parentheses.

Panel A. Liquidity shock measured by LIQU


LNME CVRG INST
Variable (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQU 0.908 0.979 0.603 0.572 0.403 0.320
(4.68) (4.80) (6.82) (6.54) (6.79) (5.76)
LIQU×ILLIQ 0.100 0.086 0.100 0.055 0.027 0.003
(1.93) (1.66) (1.07) (0.60) (0.54) (0.06)
LIQU×ATTENTION -0.111 -0.148 -0.180 -0.234 -0.234 -0.304
(-3.34) (-4.12) (-3.11) (-3.94) (-2.01) (-2.56)

Panel B. Liquidity shock measured by SPRDU


LNME CVRG INST
Variable (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
SPRDU 1.721 1.650 0.825 0.753 0.788 0.679
(7.37) (7.06) (5.71) (5.26) (6.56) (5.85)
SPRDU×ILLIQ 0.322 0.272 0.019 0.043 0.116 0.057
(3.36) (2.87) (0.09) (0.20) (1.14) (0.55)
SPRDU×ATTENTION -0.228 -0.237 -0.313 -0.335 -0.815 -0.836
(-5.71) (-5.82) (-3.76) (-3.99) (-4.17) (-4.26)

Panel C. Liquidity shock measured by LIQCU


LNME CVRG INST
Variable (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQCU 0.329 0.353 0.230 0.216 0.241 0.197
(3.39) (3.62) (3.78) (3.51) (3.87) (3.38)
LIQCU×ILLIQ 0.088 0.081 0.111 0.082 0.092 0.073
(2.45) (2.28) (1.27) (0.93) (2.42) (2.04)
LIQCU×ATTENTION -0.032 -0.046 -0.050 -0.073 -0.237 -0.261
(-1.87) (-2.67) (-1.53) (-2.15) (-1.90) (-2.04)
63

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 9
Predicting long-term stock returns
Excess cumulative returns in two to six months into the future are regressed on a set of predictive variables measured in
month t using the Fama and MacBeth (1973) methodology. This table reports the average slope coefficients of LIQU (in
Panel A), and LIQU and the interactions between ILLIQ and LIQU and between LIQU and an attention variable – LNME in
Panel B, CVRG in Panel C and INST in Panel D. Specifications (1) and (2) control for the GKM dummy variables (GKMH
and GKML ) and the abnormal dollar trading volume (VOLDU), respectively. We simultaneously control for the market beta
(BETA), LNME, the natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio (LNBM), the momentum return (MOM), the short-
term reversal (REV), the co-skewness (COSKEW), the idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), the maximum daily return in a month
(MAX), the analyst earnings forecast dispersion (DISP), the standardized unexpected earnings (SUE), the high- and low-
volume dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ), the abnormal dollar volume (VOLDU), the standard deviation of the monthly
turnover over the past 12 months (SDTURN), the coefficient of variation in the Amihud’s illiquidity measure (CVILLIQ),
Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta (PS), Acharya and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas (BETA1–BETA4),
and the loadings on the fixed and the variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor (SADKAF and SADKAV). We
suppress the average coefficients of the control variables, which are available upon request.The t-statistics (in parentheses)
are based on Hodrick (1992) robust standard errors.

Panel A. Without interaction terms


Variable 2-Month 3-Month 4-Month 5-Month 6-Month
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQU 0.320 0.294 0.401 0.378 0.502 0.481 0.577 0.557 0.654 0.632
(5.34) (4.76) (4.56) (4.25) (3.81) (3.69) (3.44) (3.32) (3.24) (3.14)

Panel B. Interacting with ILLIQ and LNME


Variable 2-Month 3-Month 4-Month 5-Month 6-Month
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQU 1.454 1.507 1.938 1.991 2.428 2.478 2.727 2.767 3.054 3.097
(3.96) (4.03) (4.39) (4.42) (4.14) (4.14) (3.65) (3.62) (3.66) (3.67)
LIQU×ILLIQ 0.133 0.125 0.194 0.189 0.214 0.218 0.221 0.223 0.222 0.232
(1.35) (1.31) (1.71) (1.70) (1.30) (1.38) (1.05) (1.07) (0.93) (1.01)
LIQU×LNME -0.198 -0.228 -0.284 -0.315 -0.375 -0.402 -0.420 -0.444 -0.471 -0.496
(-3.02) (-3.36) (-3.53) (-3.79) (-3.59) (-3.73) (-3.16) (-3.21) (-3.22) (-3.32)

Panel C. Interacting with ILLIQ and CVRG


Variable 2-Month 3-Month 4-Month 5-Month 6-Month
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQU 0.999 0.956 1.097 1.052 1.235 1.186 1.222 1.169 1.315 1.264
(5.99) (5.70) (4.52) (4.30) (3.84) (3.68) (3.04) (2.90) (2.75) (2.62)
LIQU×ILLIQ 0.199 0.147 0.089 0.024 0.057 0.020 0.115 0.192 0.232 0.323
(1.23) (0.90) (0.34) (0.09) (0.17) (0.06) (0.27) (0.43) (0.41) (0.54)
LIQU×CVRG -0.393 -0.448 -0.468 -0.523 -0.567 -0.614 -0.543 -0.579 -0.566 -0.599
(-3.49) (-3.91) (-2.94) (-3.26) (-2.72) (-2.89) (-2.04) (-2.13) (-1.82) (-1.91)

Panel D. Interacting with ILLIQ and INST


Variable 2-Month 3-Month 4-Month 5-Month 6-Month
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQU 0.613 0.541 0.690 0.617 0.770 0.709 0.820 0.764 0.862 0.810
(6.04) (5.22) (4.70) (4.18) (3.70) (3.38) (3.17) (2.94) (2.78) (2.57)
LIQU×ILLIQ 0.035 0.016 0.058 0.039 0.050 0.041 0.012 0.003 0.035 0.036
(0.51) (0.24) (0.59) (0.41) (0.32) (0.28) (0.06) (0.02) (0.15) (0.16)
LIQU×INST -0.552 -0.607 -0.673 -0.723 -0.816 -0.851 -0.835 -0.865 -0.809 -0.838
(-2.07) (-2.20) (-1.86) (-1.92) (-1.56) (-1.81) (-1.54) (-1.58) (-1.26) (-1.30)

64

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 10
Two-month ahead return predictability
Panel A of this table reports the equal- and value-weighted two-month ahead returns (month t + 2)
and the alphas with respect to the Fama-French (1993) factors for each decile portfolio formed on the
liquidity shock measured by the negative Amihud’s illiquidity measure, demeaned using the past 12
months as the mean. The last row shows the monthly return differences between High and Low LIQU
decile portfolios and the alphas. Panel B reports average returns and return differences in month t + 2
between High and Low LIQU quintile portfolios and the alphas after controlling for the abnormal dollar
trading volume (VOLDU) and the idiosyncratic volatility shock (IVOLU). Newey-West t-statistics are
given in parentheses.

Panel A. Univariate portfolio sorts


Equal-weighted Value-weighted
Decile Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha
1 (Low) 0.90 -0.40 0.88 -0.34
(3.19) (-5.05) (3.40) (-3.81)
2 0.99 -0.20 0.95 -0.13
(3.75) (-2.21) (4.01) (-1.51)
3 1.01 -0.11 0.96 -0.05
(4.16) (-1.34) (4.33) (-0.61)
4 1.05 -0.06 1.00 -0.04
(4.38) (-0.80) (4.53) (-0.57)
5 1.05 -0.05 0.94 -0.07
(4.45) (-0.77) (4.17) (-1.08)
6 1.00 -0.10 1.06 0.05
(4.36) (-1.57) (5.00) (0.82)
7 1.08 -0.01 1.10 0.13
(4.57) (-0.13) (5.08) (1.96)
8 1.06 -0.04 1.09 0.11
(4.35) (-0.73) (4.67) (1.47)
9 1.24 0.09 1.23 0.17
(4.83) (1.69) (5.05) (2.64)
10 (High) 1.51 0.31 1.46 0.31
(5.30) (4.38) (5.39) (4.33)
High-Low 0.60 0.70 0.58 0.65
(5.56) (6.59) (4.20) (4.67)

65

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Panel B. Bivariate portfolio sorts
Quintile Controlling for VOLDU Controlling for IVOLU
1 (Low) 0.99 0.91
2 0.96 1.01
3 1.04 1.01
4 1.22 1.19
5 (High) 1.49 1.53
High - Low 0.50 0.62
(5.01) (5.25)
Alpha 0.50 0.69
(5.34) (6.11)

66

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 11
Predicting one-month ahead returns based on the NYSE/Amex, NYSE and S&P 500 samples

Columns “NYSE/Amex”, “NYSE” and “S&P 500” report the equal- and value-weighted monthly returns in month t + 1 and the alphas with re-
spect to the Fama-French (1993) factors for decile portfolios formed based on the liquidity shock (LIQU) in month t. The last row presents the
differences in monthly returns between High and Low LIQU decile portfolios and the alphas. Newey-West t-statistics are given in parentheses.

NYSE/Amex NYSE S&P 500


Equal-weighted Value-weighted Equal-weighted Value-weighted Equal-weighted Value-weighted
Decile Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha
1 (Low) 0.58 -0.73 0.46 -0.75 0.89 -0.60 0.75 -0.63 0.83 -0.42 0.73 -0.41
(2.06) (-7.60) (1.77) (-6.86) (3.76) (-5.22) (3.34) (-4.83) (3.12) (-3.57) (2.83) (-3.30)
2 0.75 -0.49 0.67 -0.47 1.02 -0.41 0.95 -0.34 0.98 -0.14 0.90 -0.12
(2.85) (-5.08) (2.75) (-4.50) (4.69) (-3.50) (4.77) (-2.68) (3.97) (-1.29) (3.85) (-1.15)
3 0.95 -0.21 0.86 -0.20 1.15 -0.20 1.04 -0.18 0.95 -0.10 0.85 -0.12
(3.82) (-2.11) (3.74) (-2.03) (5.82) (-1.83) (5.81) (-1.70) (4.10) (-1.16) (3.79) (-1.41)

67
4 1.09 -0.05 1.06 0.02 1.28 -0.07 1.23 -0.01 1.04 0.03 0.95 0.02
(4.63) (-0.52) (4.86) (0.25) (6.77) (-0.77) (6.95) (-0.08) (4.71) (0.41) (4.22) (0.20)
5 1.08 -0.04 0.99 -0.04 1.31 -0.03 1.20 -0.03 1.07 0.08 1.00 0.07
(4.52) (-0.51) (4.43) (-0.52) (6.91) (-0.39) (6.79) (-0.33) (5.10) (1.39) (4.87) (1.05)
6 1.10 -0.02 1.04 0.01 1.34 -0.02 1.25 0.00 1.06 0.07 1.08 0.17
(4.70) (-0.30) (4.91) (0.19) (7.06) (-0.34) (7.25) (-0.04) (5.06) (0.96) (5.51) (2.60)
7 1.25 0.13 1.23 0.21 1.50 0.09 1.47 0.19 1.07 0.05 0.99 0.07
(5.51) (1.89) (5.73) (3.31) (7.69) (1.33) (8.07) (2.58) (5.04) (0.68) (4.92) (0.92)
8 1.29 0.11 1.18 0.10 1.54 0.06 1.43 0.04 1.22 0.20 1.14 0.19
(5.39) (1.45) (5.30) (1.35) (7.54) (0.88) (7.70) (0.59) (5.56) (2.63) (5.39) (2.43)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


9 1.41 0.20 1.37 0.24 1.68 0.14 1.62 0.16 1.23 0.14 1.17 0.18
(5.67) (2.23) (5.88) (3.04) (7.75) (1.82) (8.12) (2.15) (5.33) (2.00) (5.40) (2.33)
10 (High) 1.72 0.44 1.61 0.40 1.96 0.34 1.79 0.21 1.46 0.26 1.34 0.23
(6.22) (5.33) (6.22) (4.87) (8.14) (3.66) (7.82) (2.23) (5.87) (3.11) (5.53) (2.76)
High-Low 1.14 1.17 1.15 1.14 1.07 0.94 1.04 0.84 0.63 0.68 0.61 0.65
(10.43) (10.51) (8.48) (8.24) (9.60) (6.90) (7.25) (5.23) (4.32) (4.71) (3.76) (3.98)
Table 12
Subperiod analysis

Each month, stocks are sorted into ten decile portfolios based on liquidity shock (LIQU), defined as
the negative Amihud’s (2002) illiquidity measure, demeaned using the past 12-month illiquidity as
the mean. This table reports the average monthly returns in month t + 1 and the Fama-French (1993)
alphas for each LIQU portfolio. The last row shows the differences in monthly returns between High
and Low LIQU decile portfolios and the alphas. In Panel A, column “Non-crisis period” covers the
period from August 1963 to December 2010 and excludes the financial crisis period, July 2007 − June
2009; the “expansionary” and “recessionary” periods are based on the NBER business cycle periods.
Panel B reports the results for five decades in our sample: August 1963 − July 1973, August 1973 −
July 1983, August 1983 − July 1993, August 1993 − July 2003, and August 2003 − December 2010.
Newey-West t-statistics are given in parentheses.

Panel A. Returns on the liquidity shock portfolios in expansionary vs. recessionary periods
Non-crisis periods Expansionary periods Recessionary periods
Decile Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha
1 (Low) 0.64 -0.74 0.77 -0.70 -0.87 -0.86
(2.41) (-7.71) (3.09) (-7.07) (-0.86) (-4.78)
2 0.81 -0.47 0.94 -0.46 -0.49 -0.26
(3.25) (-4.85) (4.14) (-4.60) (-0.49) (-1.21)
3 1.05 -0.18 1.13 -0.21 -0.09 0.15
(4.55) (-1.75) (5.55) (-2.11) (-0.09) (0.64)
4 1.14 -0.09 1.23 -0.10 0.01 0.26
(5.13) (-1.08) (6.43) (-1.18) (0.01) (1.39)
5 1.21 -0.02 1.29 -0.05 -0.03 0.25
(5.47) (-0.24) (6.52) (-0.63) (-0.03) (1.45)
6 1.18 -0.04 1.29 -0.06 -0.09 0.21
(5.42) (-0.58) (6.59) (-0.89) (-0.10) (1.34)
7 1.30 0.07 1.39 0.00 0.13 0.41
(6.00) (1.25) (6.85) (0.06) (0.16) (2.78)
8 1.35 0.06 1.46 0.02 0.01 0.25
(5.73) (1.07) (6.66) (0.32) (0.02) (1.26)
9 1.45 0.13 1.56 0.09 0.16 0.41
(5.79) (2.17) (6.65) (1.59) (0.18) (1.71)
10 (High) 1.85 0.47 1.93 0.41 0.43 0.50
(6.72) (6.61) (7.31) (5.78) (0.46) (1.96)
High-Low 1.21 1.22 1.16 1.11 1.30 1.36
(10.42) (8.96) (9.37) (7.89) (4.02) (4.32)

68

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table 12 – continued
Panel B. Returns on the liquidity shock portfolios for five decades in 1963-2010
08/1963−07/1973 08/1973−07/1983 08/1983−07/1993 08/1993−07/2003 08/2003−12/2010
Decile Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha
1 (Low) 0.23 -0.78 1.39 -0.54 0.38 -0.57 0.14 -1.04 0.39 -0.59
(0.34) (-6.19) (2.27) (-3.08) (0.73) (-7.01) (0.28) (-4.66) (0.53) (-3.65)
2 0.22 -0.66 1.32 -0.27 0.77 -0.32 0.45 -0.81 0.87 -0.08
(0.39) (-5.43) (2.35) (-1.53) (1.50) (-2.86) (0.81) (-3.35) (1.23) (-0.51)
3 0.36 -0.46 1.46 0.04 1.20 -0.04 0.87 -0.26 0.76 -0.14
(0.63) (-3.27) (2.76) (0.27) (2.55) (-0.26) (1.89) (-0.97) (1.09) (-1.01)
4 0.53 -0.30 1.27 -0.13 1.36 0.16 1.01 -0.08 1.01 0.12
(0.94) (-2.47) (2.39) (-1.26) (3.17) (1.11) (2.52) (-0.38) (1.51) (0.99)
5 0.88 0.06 1.36 -0.02 1.21 0.07 1.02 -0.04 0.86 -0.05

69
(1.68) (0.77) (2.42) (-0.23) (2.81) (0.46) (2.48) (-0.26) (1.15) (-0.34)
6 0.70 -0.14 1.49 0.08 1.18 0.10 0.97 -0.11 0.98 0.07
(1.35) (-1.95) (2.66) (0.66) (2.86) (1.11) (2.43) (-0.78) (1.37) (0.64)
7 1.08 0.20 1.75 0.33 1.19 0.11 1.00 -0.10 0.84 -0.01
(2.17) (2.22) (3.16) (2.17) (2.71) (1.32) (2.39) (-0.70) (1.30) (-0.08)
8 1.07 0.13 1.88 0.28 1.15 0.17 1.02 -0.11 0.96 0.06
(2.10) (1.31) (3.12) (1.80) (2.48) (1.63) (2.14) (-0.74) (1.46) (0.56)
9 1.16 0.21 2.22 0.46 1.01 0.08 1.23 0.06 0.98 0.09
(1.97) (1.64) (3.55) (2.67) (2.08) (0.92) (2.52) (0.56) (1.60) (0.74)
10 (High) 1.64 0.54 2.48 0.41 1.34 0.40 1.89 0.84 0.94 0.08

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


(2.23) (3.78) (3.77) (2.22) (2.56) (4.77) (3.80) (5.31) (1.47) (0.52)
High-Low 1.41 1.32 1.09 0.95 0.96 0.96 1.75 1.88 0.55 0.67
(6.30) (6.09) (4.58) (2.87) (8.21) (8.55) (4.96) (6.21) (2.06) (2.94)
Table 13
Controlling for the signed small-trade turnover

Panel A of this table reports one-month ahead average returns and return differences between High
and Low liquidity shock quintile portfolios and the Fama-French (1993) alphas after controlling for the
signed small-trade turnover (SSTT). Panel B reports the average slope coefficients of liquidity shock
and SSTT from the Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions of one-month ahead excess stock returns
on liquidity shock and SSTT, including all the other control variables listed in Table 6. Specifications
(1) and (2) control for the GKM dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ) and the abnormal dollar trading
volume (VOLDU), respectively. SSTT is defined as the small-trade buy-initiated turnover minus the
small-trade sell-initiated turnover, measured over the past one through 24 months. Liquidity shock is
measured by LIQU in Panels A1 and B1, SPRDU in Panels A2 and B2 and LIQCU in Panels A3 and
B3. Newey-West t-statistics are reported in parentheses.
Panel A. Conditional bivariate sorts
Panel A1. Liquidity shock measured by LIQU
Quintile 1-month SSTT 3-month SSTT 6-month SSTT 12-month SSTT 24-month SSTT
1 (Low) 0.34 0.33 0.31 0.26 0.46
2 0.88 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.97
3 0.98 0.99 1.01 1.01 1.13
4 1.24 1.24 1.25 1.20 1.29
5 (High) 1.49 1.49 1.46 1.36 1.48
High - Low 1.15 1.15 1.14 1.10 1.02
(4.25) (4.08) (4.30) (4.23) (3.48)
Alpha 1.29 1.28 1.26 1.23 1.17
(5.67) (5.33) (5.62) (5.51) (4.83)

Panel A2. Liquidity shock measured by SPRDU


Quintile 1-month SSTT 3-month SSTT 6-month SSTT 12-month SSTT 24-month SSTT
1 (Low) 0.43 0.46 0.44 0.41 0.48
2 0.74 0.73 0.74 0.72 0.83
3 0.96 0.95 0.95 0.98 1.10
4 1.12 1.10 1.09 1.09 1.14
5 (High) 1.37 1.35 1.32 1.18 1.32
High - Low 0.94 0.89 0.88 0.77 0.84
(4.29) (4.21) (4.34) (4.00) (4.17)
Alpha 0.93 0.95 0.94 0.85 0.96
(5.09) (4.72) (4.99) (4.58) (4.94)

Panel A3. Liquidity shock measured by LIQCU


Quintile 1-month SSTT 3-month SSTT 6-month SSTT 12-month SSTT 24-month SSTT
1 (Low) 0.43 0.42 0.42 0.39 0.42
2 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.81
3 1.04 1.09 1.10 1.09 1.19
4 1.23 1.23 1.21 1.10 1.18
5 (High) 1.26 1.25 1.23 1.17 1.29
High - Low 0.83 0.83 0.81 0.78 0.87
(4.68) (4.10) (4.01) (3.95) (3.70)
Alpha 1.12 0.98 0.95 0.95 1.04
(5.31) (4.43) (4.21) (4.28) (4.06)
70

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Panel B. Monthly Fama-MacBeth regressions
Panel B1. Liquidity shock measured by LIQU
1-month SSTT 3-month SSTT 6-month SSTT 12-month SSTT 24-month SSTT
Variable (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQU 0.227 0.206 0.220 0.199 0.267 0.244 0.276 0.247 0.232 0.205
(3.76) (3.41) (3.92) (3.55) (4.01) (3.62) (3.44) (3.07) (3.69) (3.27)
SSTT -14.635 -17.713 -12.217 -13.110 -7.355 -7.355 -3.458 -3.254 -2.500 -2.334
(-1.76) (-2.07) (-3.47) (-3.63) (-3.20) (-3.19) (-2.39) (-2.24) (-2.08) (-1.95)

Panel B2. Liquidity shock measured by SPRDU


1-month SSTT 3-month SSTT 6-month SSTT 12-month SSTT 24-month SSTT
Variable (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)

71
SPRDU 0.655 0.565 0.618 0.527 0.672 0.570 0.556 0.451 0.623 0.536
(5.98) (5.16) (5.33) (4.59) (5.48) (4.68) (4.45) (3.58) (4.93) (4.25)
SSTT -10.087 -12.231 -10.787 -11.692 -6.990 -7.029 -4.424 -4.267 -2.318 -2.187
(-0.91) (-1.11) (-2.46) (-2.60) (-2.88) (-2.87) (-2.71) (-2.62) (-2.00) (-1.89)

Panel B3. Liquidity shock measured by LIQCU


1-month SSTT 3-month SSTT 6-month SSTT 12-month SSTT 24-month SSTT
Variable (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQCU 0.156 0.127 0.163 0.136 0.159 0.131 0.142 0.112 0.165 0.140
(4.32) (3.11) (4.42) (3.21) (4.53) (3.27) (3.99) (2.75) (4.28) (3.23)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


SSTT -14.972 -17.581 -12.648 -13.418 -7.610 -7.539 -3.536 -3.318 -2.531 -2.361
(-1.75) (-2.02) (-3.48) (-3.63) (-3.26) (-3.24) (-2.43) (-2.27) (-2.13) (-1.99)
Liquidity Shocks and Stock Market Reactions

Online Appendix

To save space in the paper, we present some of our findings in the Online Appendix. Table A1 presents
the monthly contemporaneous returns (month t) and the alphas for the decile portfolios constructed
based on the shock to effective spread (SPRDU) in Panel A and the conditional measure of shock
to Amihud’s illiquidity measure (LIQCU) in Panel B. Table A2 reports 5 × 5 portfolio results from
the conditional bivariate sorts of liquidity shocks (measured by the changes in Amihud’s illiquidity)
and the control variables. Table A3 provides bivariate portfolio results from the conditional sorts of
liquidity shocks (measured by SPRDU in Panel A and LIQCU in Panel B) and the control variables.
Table A4 presents bivariate portfolio results from the conditional sorts by liquidity shocks (LIQU,
SPRDU and LIQCU) after controlling for VOLDU and IVOLU. Table A5 investigates the orthogonal
components of SPRDU for predicting future stock returns. Table A6 shows stock-level cross-sectional
regression results after controlling for IVOLU and all other return predictors. Table A7 presents results
from the Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions of one-month ahead returns on the liquidity shock
measures and the control variables. Panels A and B of Table A8, respectively, present the results
of the univariate portfolio sorts and stock-level Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions based on
the shock to equal-weighted quoted spread (QSPRDU). Table A9 reports the 5 × 5 portfolio results
from conditional bivariate sorts of liquidity shocks (measured by SPRDU in Panel A and LIQCU in
Panel B) with control for the Amihud’s illiquidity measure and the attention variables. Table A10
reports results from the Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions with interaction terms (interactions
between liquidity shocks and level of liquidity, and between liquidity shocks and attention proxies).
Table A11 shows the results from the Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions of two- to six-month
ahead cumulative returns against liquidity shocks (measured by SPRDU in Panel A and LIQCU in
Panel B) with and without interaction terms. Table A12 shows two-month ahead returns for bivariate
portfolios of liquidity shocks & VOLDU and IVOLU. Table A13 reports the portfolio results (Panel A)
and the stock-level Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions (Panel B) from quote midpoint returns.
Table A14 presents stock-level cross-sectional regressions results after accounting for microstructure
biases.

This Version: August 23, 2013

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A1
Liquidity shocks and contemporaneous stock returns

For month t, NYSE, Amex and Nasdaq stocks are sorted into ten decile portfolios based on SPRDU in
Panel A and LIQCU in Panel B using the NYSE breakpoints. SPRDU is defined as the negative volume-
weighted relative effective spread (SPRD), demeaned using the past 12-month SPRD as the mean.
LIQCU denotes the conditional measure of liquidity shock, defined as the negative of the difference
between the realized ILLIQ and the conditional mean of ILLIQ in the month estimated under the
assumption that the conditional mean of ILLIQ follows an ARMA(1,1) process. This table reports the
equal- and value-weighted monthly contemporaneous returns (month t) and the alpha with respect to
the Fama-French (1993) factors for each LIQU portfolio. In Panel A, columns “Avg. SPRDU” and
“Avg. SPRD” report average SPRDU and SPRD values for each SPRDU decile portfolio. In Panel B,
columns “Avg. LIQCU” and “Avg. ILLIQ” report average LIQCU and ILLIQ values for each LIQCU
decile portfolio. In each panel, the last column shows the average market share of each portfolio, and
the last row presents the differences in monthly returns between High and Low LIQU decile portfolios
and the corresponding alphas. Average returns and alphas are defined in monthly percentage terms.
Newey-West t-statistics are given in parentheses. The samples for Panels A and B cover the periods
from January 1993 to December 2010 and August 1963 to December 2010, respectively.
Panel A: Portfolio sorts based on SPRDU
Equal-weighted Value-weighted
Decile Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. SPRDU Avg. SPRD Mkt. shr.
1 (Low) -0.12 -1.16 -0.32 -1.41 -0.5934 2.2936 6.03%
(-0.32) (-5.21) (-0.71) (-5.02)
2 0.09 -1.05 -0.05 -1.15 -0.0648 0.8118 8.85%
(0.26) (-5.92) (-0.14) (-5.48)
3 0.53 -0.55 0.59 -0.39 -0.0170 0.5996 13.10%
(1.60) (-3.45) (1.82) (-2.36)
4 0.80 -0.25 1.05 0.13 0.0097 0.5031 15.99%
(2.54) (-2.07) (3.53) (1.03)
5 1.10 0.06 1.44 0.54 0.0301 0.4720 15.42%
(3.59) (0.48) (5.19) (4.46)
6 1.37 0.37 2.04 1.14 0.0502 0.4840 12.93%
(4.76) (3.50) (7.40) (10.09)
7 1.77 0.76 2.45 1.54 0.0740 0.5300 9.88%
(6.12) (7.27) (8.82) (11.34)
8 2.05 1.05 2.92 2.02 0.1082 0.6121 7.39%
(7.26) (10.08) (8.83) (9.32)
9 2.51 1.49 3.74 2.81 0.1730 0.7818 5.24%
(7.90) (11.74) (8.92) (9.51)
10 (High) 4.42 3.45 4.95 3.94 1.0497 1.4349 5.17%
(10.83) (15.25) (9.16) (10.01)
High-Low 4.54 4.61 5.26 5.36
(13.06) (13.14) (8.87) (9.45)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A1 – continued
Panel B: Portfolio sorts based on LIQCU
Equal-weighted Value-weighted
Decile Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha Avg. LIQCU Avg. ILLIQ Mkt. shr.
1 (Low) -0.26 -1.49 0.15 -0.99 -0.8663 2.3145 2.55%
(-1.09) (-14.67) (0.63) (-9.44)
2 -0.31 -1.47 0.11 -0.93 -0.0456 0.2681 11.67%
(-1.30) (-16.51) (0.50) (-11.16)
3 0.14 -0.99 0.66 -0.35 -0.0155 0.1239 22.17%
(0.60) (-11.54) (2.88) (-4.37)
4 0.65 -0.44 1.23 0.23 -0.0041 0.0710 20.84%
(2.72) (-5.57) (5.23) (3.29)
5 1.12 0.05 1.79 0.81 0.0029 0.0603 15.52%
(4.84) (0.74) (7.93) (10.97)
6 1.57 0.50 2.42 1.44 0.0108 0.0699 10.53%
(6.76) (6.97) (10.32) (16.97)
7 1.89 0.82 2.78 1.83 0.0235 0.1004 7.51%
(8.01) (10.54) (11.51) (16.28)
8 2.20 1.08 3.24 2.21 0.0484 0.1655 4.34%
(9.09) (12.74) (12.66) (16.57)
9 2.61 1.45 3.72 2.64 0.1103 0.2929 2.57%
(10.22) (15.77) (13.21) (17.58)
10 (High) 4.16 2.90 4.84 3.68 1.4877 1.0427 2.29%
(12.93) (23.24) (14.84) (23.24)
High-Low 4.42 4.39 4.69 4.67
(25.95) (29.21) (22.13) (24.90)

ii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A2
5 × 5 bivariate sorts with liquidity shocks measured by LIQU

This table reports the average returns in month t + 1 for each portfolio obtained from conditional bi-
variate sorts with liquidity shocks measured by LIQU. LIQU is computed as the negative difference
between the Amihud’s (2002) illiquidity measure and its past 12-month mean. The last column in each
panel reports the average returns for each LIQU portfolio across the five control variable groups. The
last two rows in each panel present the return differences between the highest and the lowest LIQU
portfolios within each control group and the corresponding alphas with respect to the Fama-French
(1993) factors. BETA, LNME and LNBM denote the market beta, the natural logarithm of the market
capitalization and the natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio, respectively. MOM is the
momentum return. REV is the short-term reversal. COSKEW and IVOL are the co-skewness and id-
iosyncratic volatility, respectively. MAX denotes the maximum daily return in a month. DISP measures
the analyst earnings forecast dispersion. SUE is the standardized unexpected earnings. CVILLIQ is the
coefficient of variation in the Amihud’s illiquidity measure. SDTURN denotes the standard deviation
of the monthly turnover over the past 12 months. PS is Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta.
BETA1–BETA4 are Acharya and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas. SADKAF and SADKAV are
the loadings on the fixed and the variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor. GKM di-
vides the sample into the high, median, and low dollar trading volume groups. VOLDU measures the
abnormal dollar trading volume. Newey-West t-statistics are reported in parentheses.
Panel A. Control for BETA
LIQU BETA (Low) BETA 2 BETA 3 BETA 4 BETA (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.51 0.81 0.76 0.70 0.36 0.63
2 0.85 0.94 1.11 0.97 0.97 0.97
3 1.02 1.23 1.13 1.18 1.15 1.14
4 1.11 1.38 1.44 1.48 1.50 1.38
5 (High) 1.46 1.63 1.84 1.90 1.87 1.74
High - Low 0.95 0.83 1.08 1.20 1.51 1.12
(6.60) (7.41) (6.48) (8.46) (6.95) (7.46)
Alpha 0.94 0.85 1.07 1.27 1.64 1.15
(6.55) (7.83) (6.31) (9.47) (7.75) (7.09)

Panel B. Control for LNME


LIQU LNME (Low) LNME 2 LNME 3 LNME 4 LNME (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.41 0.76 0.74 0.82 0.64 0.68
2 0.77 1.00 1.02 0.98 0.89 0.93
3 1.33 1.23 1.26 1.13 0.98 1.19
4 1.72 1.45 1.33 1.19 0.89 1.32
5 (High) 1.87 1.58 1.39 1.23 1.07 1.43
High - Low 1.45 0.82 0.66 0.40 0.43 0.75
(10.96) (5.27) (4.16) (2.66) (2.98) (5.89)
Alpha 1.50 0.95 0.75 0.54 0.52 0.85
(11.51) (5.80) (4.33) (3.32) (3.51) (6.38)

iii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A2 – continued
Panel C. Control for BM
LIQU BM (Low) BM 2 BM 3 BM 4 BM (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.00 0.37 0.55 0.76 0.80 0.50
2 0.78 0.85 0.96 1.14 1.19 0.98
3 0.91 0.96 1.07 1.25 1.54 1.15
4 1.07 1.23 1.34 1.53 1.81 1.40
5 (High) 1.31 1.65 1.76 1.76 2.05 1.71
High - Low 1.32 1.27 1.22 1.00 1.25 1.21
(7.38) (7.72) (8.96) (7.41) (9.30) (7.84)
Alpha 1.35 1.30 1.28 1.02 1.25 1.24
(7.14) (7.94) (8.70) (7.34) (9.08) (7.72)

Panel D. Control for MOM


LIQU MOM (Low) MOM 2 MOM 3 MOM 4 MOM (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) -0.13 0.67 0.78 1.06 1.25 0.73
2 0.18 0.79 0.95 1.11 1.43 0.89
3 0.61 0.98 0.98 1.18 1.61 1.07
4 0.82 1.18 1.28 1.48 1.96 1.34
5 (High) 0.98 1.47 1.75 1.84 2.16 1.64
High - Low 1.12 0.80 0.97 0.78 0.91 0.91
(9.24) (7.63) (8.43) (5.99) (5.44) (7.38)
Alpha 1.12 0.80 0.90 0.75 0.83 0.88
(9.12) (7.49) (7.65) (6.09) (5.57) (7.96)

Panel E. Control for REV


LIQU REV (Low) REV 2 REV 3 REV 4 REV (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 1.18 0.71 0.66 0.24 -0.56 0.45
2 1.25 1.19 0.92 0.79 0.43 0.92
3 1.41 1.24 1.13 0.98 0.76 1.10
4 1.69 1.53 1.37 1.20 1.16 1.39
5 (High) 2.25 1.92 1.74 1.61 1.45 1.79
High - Low 1.07 1.21 1.08 1.37 2.01 1.35
(6.95) (7.40) (7.86) (8.81) (9.51) (7.65)
Alpha 1.12 1.18 1.11 1.36 2.01 1.36
(7.75) (7.37) (7.79) (8.55) (9.46) (7.77)

Panel F. Control for COSKEW


LIQU COSKEW (Low) COSKEW 2 COSKEW 3 COSKEW 4 COSKEW (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.55 0.66 0.69 0.58 0.36 0.57
2 0.90 0.94 0.95 0.92 0.94 0.93
3 1.13 1.19 1.11 1.06 0.99 1.10
4 1.63 1.50 1.36 1.29 1.29 1.41
5 (High) 1.84 1.70 1.67 1.65 1.75 1.72
High - Low 1.29 1.04 0.98 1.07 1.39 1.16
(8.81) (8.05) (6.76) (9.00) (8.02) (7.46)
Alpha 1.33 1.08 0.98 1.12 1.44 1.19
(9.16) (8.14) (6.62) (8.99) (7.93) (7.55)

iv

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A2 – continued
Panel G. Control for IVOL
LIQU IVOL (Low) IVOL 2 IVOL 3 IVOL 4 IVOL (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.85 0.97 0.98 0.88 0.03 0.74
2 0.96 1.11 1.11 1.15 0.32 0.93
3 1.10 1.18 1.23 1.23 0.85 1.12
4 1.13 1.43 1.46 1.60 1.37 1.40
5 (High) 1.25 1.81 1.94 2.08 1.70 1.76
High - Low 0.40 0.84 0.96 1.20 1.67 1.02
(4.71) (7.13) (6.29) (7.73) (7.87) (7.89)
Alpha 0.39 0.83 0.97 1.22 1.75 1.03
(5.01) (7.81) (6.97) (8.66) (7.27) (7.06)

Panel H. Control for MAX


LIQU MAX (Low) MAX 2 MAX 3 MAX 4 MAX (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 1.01 1.09 1.06 0.74 -0.25 0.73
2 1.06 1.11 1.06 1.02 0.29 0.91
3 1.23 1.18 1.19 1.18 0.79 1.12
4 1.35 1.40 1.40 1.48 1.30 1.39
5 (High) 1.64 2.01 1.98 2.02 1.53 1.84
High - Low 0.63 0.92 0.91 1.28 1.78 1.11
(6.41) (7.38) (7.78) (8.47) (7.40) (7.50)
Alpha 0.64 0.94 0.90 1.31 1.85 1.13
(6.78) (8.27) (8.36) (9.11) (7.08) (7.15)

Panel I. Control for DISP


LIQU DISP (Low) DISP 2 DISP 3 DISP 4 DISP (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.58 1.06 0.91 0.68 0.16 0.68
2 0.95 1.18 1.20 1.01 0.78 1.02
3 1.27 1.23 1.20 1.15 0.96 1.16
4 1.77 1.35 1.25 1.37 1.10 1.37
5 (High) 1.77 1.64 1.75 1.70 1.59 1.69
High - Low 1.19 0.58 0.84 1.01 1.43 1.01
(7.58) (3.52) (5.60) (5.59) (7.19) (7.04)
Alpha 1.18 0.61 0.83 1.01 1.51 1.02
(7.71) (3.94) (5.75) (5.72) (7.90) (7.59)

Panel J. Control for SUE


LIQU SUE (Low) SUE 2 SUE 3 SUE 4 SUE (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.22 0.72 0.90 1.15 1.38 0.87
2 0.86 1.12 1.33 1.36 1.49 1.23
3 1.06 1.13 1.28 1.41 1.74 1.32
4 0.93 1.27 1.57 1.72 2.20 1.54
5 (High) 0.91 1.53 1.91 2.10 2.74 1.84
High - Low 0.69 0.81 1.02 0.95 1.35 0.96
(4.34) (5.32) (6.17) (4.91) (8.14) (6.61)
Alpha 0.80 0.85 1.04 0.96 1.32 0.99
(5.07) (5.48) (6.52) (4.98) (8.22) (6.84)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A2 – continued
Panel K. Control for ILLIQ
LIQU ILLIQ (Low) ILLIQ 2 ILLIQ 3 ILLIQ 4 ILLIQ (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.73 0.82 0.79 0.67 0.45 0.69
2 0.94 0.98 1.03 1.03 0.78 0.95
3 0.99 1.18 1.24 1.19 1.18 1.16
4 0.98 1.17 1.31 1.39 1.65 1.30
5 (High) 1.26 1.30 1.45 1.75 1.81 1.51
High - Low 0.52 0.47 0.66 1.08 1.36 0.82
(3.44) (2.60) (3.24) (5.34) (8.56) (5.37)
Alpha 0.49 0.58 0.69 1.12 1.38 0.85
(3.03) (3.23) (3.24) (5.25) (8.99) (5.43)

Panel L. Control for CVILLIQ


LIQU CVILLIQ (Low) CVILLIQ 2 CVILLIQ 3 CVILLIQ 4 CVILLIQ (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.34 0.41 0.43 0.53 0.60 0.46
2 0.97 0.93 0.98 1.05 0.94 0.97
3 1.00 1.06 1.12 1.17 1.26 1.12
4 0.99 1.16 1.27 1.49 1.61 1.30
5 (High) 1.36 1.55 1.73 1.84 1.81 1.66
High - Low 1.02 1.14 1.31 1.32 1.21 1.20
(5.39) (6.86) (7.34) (8.27) (8.86) (7.40)
Alpha 1.04 1.16 1.32 1.32 1.25 1.22
(5.60) (6.76) (7.34) (7.99) (9.03) (7.39)

Panel M. Control for SDTURN


LIQU SDTURN (Low) SDTURN 2 SDTURN 3 SDTURN 4 SDTURN (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.74 0.72 0.71 0.65 0.20 0.60
2 0.93 0.97 1.06 1.08 0.76 0.96
3 1.09 1.09 1.21 1.22 0.96 1.11
4 1.32 1.39 1.45 1.49 1.30 1.39
5 (High) 1.61 1.83 1.82 1.89 1.56 1.74
High - Low 0.87 1.12 1.11 1.23 1.36 1.14
(9.59) (8.74) (8.96) (8.63) (7.52) (7.93)
Alpha 0.88 1.11 1.13 1.26 1.47 1.17
(9.54) (9.22) (9.47) (9.23) (7.75) (7.58)

Panel N. Control for PS


LIQU PS (Low) PS 2 PS 3 PS 4 PS (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.39 0.64 0.64 0.64 0.47 0.56
2 0.86 0.92 0.94 1.00 0.87 0.92
3 1.00 1.12 1.11 1.08 1.12 1.09
4 1.32 1.23 1.26 1.32 1.45 1.32
5 (High) 1.69 1.78 1.67 1.59 1.71 1.69
High - Low 1.30 1.13 1.03 0.94 1.24 1.13
(7.17) (8.81) (7.86) (6.42) (6.43) (7.29)
Alpha 1.39 1.17 1.07 0.99 1.30 1.18
(7.19) (8.63) (7.69) (6.91) (6.73) (7.45)

vi

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A2 – continued
Panel O. Control for BETA1
LIQU BETA1 (Low) BETA1 2 BETA1 3 BETA1 4 BETA1 (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.38 0.61 0.69 0.64 0.20 0.51
2 0.88 1.01 1.04 0.98 0.71 0.92
3 0.97 1.07 1.13 1.06 0.99 1.04
4 1.03 1.33 1.32 1.42 1.31 1.28
5 (High) 1.34 1.62 1.63 1.83 1.63 1.61
High - Low 0.97 1.01 0.94 1.19 1.43 1.11
(9.07) (8.96) (9.02) (8.59) (7.59) (7.63)
Alpha 0.98 1.09 0.96 1.26 1.59 1.18
(8.51) (9.89) (9.62) (9.16) (8.38) (7.43)

Panel P. Control for BETA2


LIQU BETA2 (Low) BETA2 2 BETA2 3 BETA2 4 BETA2 (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.38 0.83 0.75 0.70 0.26 0.58
2 0.77 1.01 0.97 1.01 0.69 0.89
3 1.03 1.01 1.10 1.10 1.14 1.08
4 0.94 1.14 1.21 1.34 1.53 1.23
5 (High) 1.17 1.10 1.30 1.50 1.66 1.35
High - Low 0.79 0.27 0.56 0.81 1.40 0.76
(6.15) (1.90) (3.44) (5.64) (9.90) (6.58)
Alpha 0.91 0.39 0.70 0.93 1.50 0.88
(7.63) (2.90) (4.67) (6.38) (10.19) (7.87)

Panel Q. Control for BETA3


LIQU BETA3 (Low) BETA3 2 BETA3 3 BETA3 4 BETA3 (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.31 0.50 0.63 0.61 0.22 0.45
2 0.68 0.99 1.00 0.97 0.82 0.89
3 0.91 1.05 1.11 1.10 1.00 1.04
4 1.27 1.44 1.34 1.27 1.18 1.30
5 (High) 1.57 1.66 1.77 1.56 1.61 1.63
High - Low 1.26 1.17 1.14 0.95 1.39 1.18
(6.01) (6.72) (7.61) (7.71) (6.98) (7.89)
Alpha 1.43 1.22 1.20 1.00 1.40 1.25
(6.55) (6.96) (7.25) (7.80) (6.41) (7.11)

Panel R. Control for BETA4


LIQU BETA4 (Low) BETA4 2 BETA4 3 BETA4 4 BETA4 (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.35 0.62 0.62 0.81 0.47 0.57
2 0.67 0.91 0.90 0.92 0.86 0.85
3 1.15 1.06 1.08 0.95 0.96 1.04
4 1.54 1.34 1.19 1.09 1.16 1.26
5 (High) 1.69 1.50 1.23 1.21 1.35 1.40
High - Low 1.34 0.88 0.62 0.40 0.88 0.82
(8.90) (5.74) (3.92) (2.60) (6.70) (6.74)
Alpha 1.45 0.98 0.74 0.51 0.88 0.91
(9.06) (6.17) (4.84) (3.45) (6.72) (7.35)

vii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A2 – continued
Panel S. Control for SADKAF
LIQU SADKAF (Low) SADKAF 2 SADKAF 3 SADKAF 4 SADKAF (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.11 0.44 0.62 0.51 0.02 0.34
2 0.73 0.99 1.13 0.94 0.83 0.92
3 0.83 1.01 1.08 1.16 1.11 1.04
4 1.00 1.14 1.13 1.39 1.46 1.22
5 (High) 1.47 1.54 1.44 1.56 1.53 1.51
High - Low 1.36 1.10 0.82 1.05 1.51 1.18
(6.49) (7.25) (5.22) (6.77) (6.83) (7.63)
Alpha 1.51 1.25 0.95 1.18 1.73 1.33
(7.19) (8.63) (6.60) (8.39) (8.94) (7.60)

Panel T. Control for SADKAV


LIQU SADKAV (Low) SADKAV 2 SADKAV 3 SADKAV 4 SADKAV (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.00 0.56 0.47 0.56 0.17 0.35
2 0.72 1.04 1.06 1.15 0.79 0.95
3 0.88 0.98 1.15 1.21 0.98 1.04
4 1.30 1.11 1.28 1.20 1.19 1.21
5 (High) 1.49 1.56 1.52 1.56 1.55 1.54
High - Low 1.49 0.99 1.05 1.00 1.38 1.19
(6.70) (5.90) (6.78) (5.92) (7.51) (7.54)
Alpha 1.67 1.16 1.18 1.14 1.51 1.34
(8.03) (7.19) (7.79) (6.95) (8.94) (7.22)

Panel U. Control for GKM


LIQU GKM (Low) GKM 2 GKM (High) Avg. RET – –
1 (Low) 0.71 0.45 0.70 0.62 – –
2 0.96 0.92 1.11 0.99 – –
3 1.01 1.05 1.24 1.10 – –
4 1.23 1.15 1.26 1.21 – –
5 (High) 1.41 1.57 2.00 1.66 – –
High - Low 0.71 1.12 1.27 1.03 – –
(4.66) (9.63) (6.00) (7.42) – –
Alpha 0.56 1.15 1.28 0.99 – –
(4.11) (9.74) (6.34) (7.60) – –

Panel V. Control for VOLDU


LIQU VOLDU (Low) VOLDU 2 VOLDU 3 VOLDU 4 VOLDU (High) Avg. RET
1 (Low) 0.45 0.35 0.61 0.72 0.97 0.62
2 0.42 0.81 0.91 1.03 1.16 0.87
3 0.88 0.94 1.05 1.19 1.39 1.09
4 1.03 1.21 1.36 1.52 1.74 1.37
5 (High) 1.27 1.63 1.66 1.78 1.99 1.67
High - Low 0.82 1.28 1.05 1.07 1.02 1.05
(8.10) (10.74) (7.81) (7.02) (5.64) (7.94)
Alpha 0.93 1.28 0.98 0.90 0.87 0.99
(9.72) (10.82) (7.76) (7.09) (6.01) (7.20)

viii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A3
Bivariate portfolio sorts - liquidity shock measured by SPRDU and LIQCU
This table reports the equal-weighted returns and return differences in month t + 1 between High and Low liquidity shock (SPRDU in Panel A or LIQCU in
Panel B) quintile portfolios and the three-factor alphas after controlling for a given stock characteristic. SPRDU is computed as the negative of the volume-
weighted relative effective spread (SPRD), demeaned using the past 12-month SPRD as the mean. LIQCU denotes the conditional measure of liquidity
shock, defined as the negative of the difference between the realized ILLIQ and the conditional mean of ILLIQ in the month estimated under the assumption
that the conditional mean of ILLIQ follows an ARMA(1,1) process. BETA, LNME, and LNBM denote the market beta, the natural logarithm of the market
capitalization, and the natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio, respectively. MOM is the momentum return. REV is the short-term reversal.
COSKEW and IVOL are the co-skewness and idiosyncratic volatility, respectively. MAX denotes the maximum daily return in a month. DISP measures
the analyst earnings forecast dispersion. SUE is the standardized unexpected earnings. CVILLIQ is the coefficient of variation in the Amihud’s illiquidity
measure. SDTURN denotes the standard deviation of the monthly turnover over the past 12 months. PS is Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta.
BETA1–BETA4 are Acharya and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas. SADKAF and SADKAV are the loadings on the fixed and the variable components
of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor. GKM divides the sample into the high, median, and low dollar trading volume groups. VOLDU measures the abnormal
dollar trading volume. IVOLU denotes the idiosyncratic volatility shock. Newey-West t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

Panel A. Liquidity shock measured by SPRDU


Quintile BETA SIZE BM MOM REV COSKEW IVOL MAX DISP SUE SPRD ILLIQ

ix
1 (Low) 0.64 0.96 0.59 0.73 0.55 0.64 0.82 0.81 0.64 0.70 0.68 0.78
2 1.02 1.17 1.05 0.97 0.98 1.00 1.00 1.01 1.02 1.05 0.92 1.18
3 1.09 1.32 1.09 1.11 1.07 1.06 1.07 1.06 1.03 1.09 1.06 1.28
4 1.22 1.40 1.23 1.18 1.25 1.23 1.22 1.24 1.16 1.21 1.12 1.33
5 (High) 1.55 1.56 1.43 1.38 1.46 1.48 1.45 1.49 1.44 1.50 1.23 1.73
High - Low 0.91 0.54 0.83 0.65 0.91 0.84 0.63 0.68 0.80 0.80 0.55 0.76
(5.73) (3.86) (4.72) (5.15) (5.44) (4.59) (5.14) (5.15) (3.86) (4.23) (3.46) (4.41)
Alpha 0.99 0.56 0.89 0.63 0.96 0.92 0.67 0.70 0.86 0.86 0.63 0.81
(7.17) (4.05) (5.48) (5.39) (6.40) (5.47) (5.99) (5.61) (4.66) (4.94) (3.79) (4.24)

Quintile CVILLIQ SDTURN PS BETA1 BETA2 BETA3 BETA4 SADKAF SADKAV GKM VOLDU IVOLU

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


1 (Low) 0.59 0.69 0.67 0.62 0.75 0.58 0.70 0.59 0.59 0.66 0.65 0.70
2 0.98 1.05 1.01 1.02 0.96 0.99 0.97 1.00 1.01 1.08 0.95 0.95
3 1.04 1.06 1.05 1.12 1.06 1.07 1.04 1.06 1.05 1.01 1.08 1.00
4 1.09 1.25 1.26 1.21 1.15 1.22 1.16 1.20 1.22 1.07 1.22 1.22
5 (High) 1.40 1.49 1.52 1.53 1.31 1.57 1.32 1.44 1.45 1.21 1.36 1.49
High - Low 0.81 0.81 0.85 0.91 0.56 0.99 0.62 0.85 0.86 0.55 0.71 0.79
(3.12) (4.78) (4.94) (5.53) (2.74) (5.08) (2.98) (4.75) (4.64) (4.19) (5.30) (5.32)
Alpha 0.89 0.91 0.91 0.99 0.69 1.07 0.73 0.92 0.93 0.58 0.71 0.85
(3.83) (6.46) (5.61) (6.83) (3.58) (6.21) (3.69) (5.58) (5.35) (4.80) (5.44) (6.09)
Table A3 – continued
Panel B. Liquidity shock measured by LIQCU
Quintile BETA SIZE BM MOM REV COSKEW IVOL MAX DISP SUE ILLIQ
1 (Low) 0.77 0.84 0.70 0.85 0.68 0.71 0.84 0.87 0.89 0.98 0.84
2 1.03 1.06 1.04 0.98 0.97 1.00 1.00 0.96 1.09 1.24 1.04
3 1.20 1.23 1.20 1.20 1.18 1.20 1.16 1.17 1.27 1.37 1.21
4 1.39 1.28 1.42 1.38 1.43 1.40 1.43 1.43 1.39 1.64 1.33
5 (High) 1.59 1.26 1.52 1.49 1.62 1.53 1.63 1.72 1.51 1.66 1.30
High - Low 0.82 0.42 0.82 0.64 0.94 0.82 0.79 0.85 0.63 0.68 0.46
(9.16) (3.97) (8.14) (7.45) (8.81) (7.92) (9.62) (10.07) (5.66) (5.86) (3.58)
Alpha 0.82 0.51 0.80 0.60 0.90 0.82 0.78 0.84 0.63 0.69 0.50
(10.91) (5.51) (9.38) (8.83) (10.59) (9.22) (12.04) (12.30) (7.43) (6.99) (4.67)

x
Quintile CVILLIQ SDTURN PS BETA1 BETA2 BETA3 BETA4 SADKAF SADKAV GKM VOLDU IVOLU
1 (Low) 0.71 0.78 0.72 0.69 0.76 0.67 0.74 0.61 0.60 0.82 0.82 0.76
2 1.02 0.98 0.98 0.98 0.98 0.97 0.97 1.04 1.08 0.95 0.95 0.96
3 1.21 1.21 1.15 1.15 1.13 1.09 1.10 1.15 1.13 1.20 1.17 1.19
4 1.36 1.42 1.37 1.30 1.22 1.36 1.23 1.24 1.26 1.26 1.42 1.38
5 (High) 1.46 1.60 1.49 1.42 1.24 1.42 1.29 1.27 1.31 1.58 1.50 1.61
High - Low 0.75 0.81 0.77 0.72 0.48 0.76 0.54 0.68 0.72 0.75 0.68 0.85
(5.85) (9.54) (7.71) (9.08) (5.35) (7.97) (5.89) (5.12) (5.28) (8.00) (6.80) (7.03)
Alpha 0.74 0.81 0.79 0.75 0.57 0.79 0.60 0.83 0.86 0.72 0.61 0.83

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


(7.12) (11.13) (8.99) (10.48) (6.79) (9.21) (6.92) (7.50) (7.32) (8.65) (8.43) (8.37)
Table A4
Bivariate portfolio sorts by liquidity shocks after controlling for VOLDU and IVOLU

This table reports the equal-weighted returns and return differences in month t + 1 between High and Low
liquidity shock (LIQU, SPRDU and LIQCU) quintile portfolios and the three-factor alphas after controlling
for the abnormal dollar trading volume (VOLDU) and the idiosyncratic volatility shock (IVOLU). Newey-West
t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

Controlling for VOLDU Controlling for IVOLU


LIQU SPRDU LIQCU LIQU SPRDU LIQCU
1 (Low) 0.62 0.65 0.82 0.57 0.70 0.76
2 0.87 0.95 0.95 0.89 0.95 0.96
3 1.09 1.08 1.17 1.07 1.00 1.19
4 1.37 1.22 1.42 1.38 1.22 1.38
5 (High) 1.67 1.36 1.50 1.78 1.49 1.61
High - Low 1.05 0.71 0.68 1.21 0.79 0.85
(7.94) (5.30) (6.80) (7.91) (5.32) (7.03)
Alpha 0.99 0.71 0.61 1.23 0.85 0.83
(7.20) (5.44) (8.43) (8.09) (6.09) (8.37)

xi

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A5
Investigating the orthogonal components of SPRDU for predicting future stock returns

In Panel A, for month t, NYSE, Amex and Nasdaq stocks are sorted into ten decile portfolios based
on the orthogonal component of SPRDU obtained by estimating monthly cross-sectional regressions of
SPRDU separately against contemporaneous idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL) and idiosyncratic volatility
shock (IVOLU). SPRDU is defined as the negative volume-weighted relative effective spread (SPRD),
demeaned using the past 12-month SPRD as the mean. Panel A reports the average one-month ahead
returns (month t + 1) and the alpha with respect to the Fama-French (1993) factors for each liquidity
shock decile portfolio. The last row shows the differences in monthly returns between High and Low
liquidity shock decile portfolios and the corresponding alphas. Average returns and alphas are defined
in monthly percentage terms. In Panel B, monthly excess stock returns are regressed on a set of lagged
predictive variables using the Fama and MacBeth (1973) methodology. Panel B reports the average
slope coefficients. SPRDU-RESD denotes the orthogonal component of SPRDU. BETA, LNME, and
LNBM denote the market beta, the natural logarithm of the market capitalization, and the natural
logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio, respectively. MOM is the momentum return. REV is the
short-term reversal. COSKEW and IVOL are the co-skewness and idiosyncratic volatility, respectively.
MAX denotes the maximum daily return in a month. DISP measures the analyst earnings forecast
dispersion. SUE is the standardized unexpected earnings. CVILLIQ is the coefficient of variation in the
Amihud’s illiquidity measure. SDTURN denotes the standard deviation of the monthly turnover over
the past 12 months. PS is Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta. BETA1–BETA4 are Acharya
and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas. SADKAF and SADKAV are the loadings on the fixed and
the variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor. GKMH and GKML denote the high- and
low-volume dummy variables. VOLDU measures the abnormal dollar trading volume. IVOLU is the
idiosyncratic volatility shock. Newey-West t-statistics are given in parentheses.
Panel A. Univariate portfolio sorts
SPRDU orthogonal to IVOL SPRDU orthogonal to IVOLU
Decile Avg. RET Alpha Avg. RET Alpha
1 (Low) 0.44 -0.56 0.61 -0.44
(1.35) (-4.23) (1.72) (-3.71)
2 1.01 -0.05 1.01 -0.10
(3.13) (-0.40) (2.98) (-0.98)
3 0.96 -0.08 0.94 -0.12
(3.19) (-0.74) (2.95) (-1.37)
4 1.00 -0.06 1.02 -0.02
(3.15) (-0.76) (3.39) (-0.23)
5 1.03 -0.03 1.00 -0.03
(3.24) (-0.40) (3.34) (-0.30)
6 1.05 0.00 1.00 0.00
(3.48) (0.05) (3.42) (-0.02)
7 1.06 -0.02 0.99 -0.05
(3.34) (-0.19) (3.32) (-0.56)
8 1.07 0.00 1.04 -0.02
(3.27) (0.06) (3.33) (-0.21)
9 1.09 -0.02 1.13 0.02
(3.05) (-0.18) (3.27) (0.25)
10 (High) 1.46 0.38 1.37 0.33
(4.07) (3.49) (3.97) (3.18)
High-Low 1.02 0.94 0.76 0.77
(5.91) (5.17) (4.51) (4.57)

xii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Panel B. Monthly Fama-MacBeth regressions
Variable SPRDU orthogonal to IVOL SPRDU orthogonal to IVOLU
(1) (2) (1) (2)
SPRDU-RESD 0.631 0.550 0.621 0.472
(6.99) (6.38) (6.75) (4.93)
BETA 0.255 0.269 0.258 0.263
(2.05) (2.17) (2.07) (2.11)
LNME -0.068 -0.083 -0.080 -0.093
(-1.64) (-2.04) (-1.91) (-2.23)
LNBM 0.096 0.089 0.095 0.099
(1.16) (1.08) (1.18) (1.26)
MOM 0.004 0.002 0.004 0.002
(2.06) (1.18) (2.09) (1.20)
REV -0.027 -0.040 -0.027 -0.040
(-5.00) (-7.58) (-4.97) (-7.50)
COSKEW 0.700 0.657 0.707 0.668
(0.83) (0.79) (0.85) (0.81)
IVOL -0.247 -0.336 -0.248 -0.254
(-4.01) (-5.26) (-1.94) (-2.00)
MAX -0.015 -0.008 -0.017 -0.012
(-1.30) (-0.69) (-1.49) (-0.99)
DISP -0.086 -0.079 -0.085 -0.083
(-2.33) (-2.18) (-2.51) (-2.46)
SPRD 0.046 0.093 0.018 0.011
(0.67) (1.32) (0.20) (0.12)
ILLIQ 0.097 0.083 0.089 0.072
(3.29) (2.95) (3.02) (2.55)
CVILLIQ 0.085 0.017 0.079 0.024
(1.31) (0.26) (1.38) (0.41)
SDTURN -0.234 -0.177 -0.259 -0.253
(-2.42) (-1.86) (-2.56) (-2.52)
PS 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
(1.01) (0.96) (1.00) (0.96)
BETA1 0.231 0.237 0.203 0.174
(1.05) (1.09) (1.08) (0.95)
BETA2 0.198 0.055 -0.226 -0.446
(0.05) (0.01) (-0.06) (-0.12)
BETA3 3.947 3.843 3.904 3.771
(3.23) (3.17) (3.24) (3.17)
BETA4 -0.344 -0.340 -0.397 -0.401
(-0.81) (-0.82) (-0.94) (-0.97)
SADKAF 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
(-0.02) (0.01) (-0.08) (-0.02)
SADKAV -0.010 -0.010 -0.011 -0.011
(-1.01) (-0.96) (-1.09) (-1.06)
SUE 0.248 0.228 0.250 0.231
(10.26) (9.51) (10.44) (9.84)
GKMH 0.503 0.501
(4.62) (4.46)
GKML -0.140 -0.143
(-1.84) (-1.89)
VOLDU 0.168 0.170
(6.78) (6.53)
IVOLU -0.092 -0.178
(-0.84) (-1.58)

xiii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A6
Stock-level cross-sectional regressions with control for IVOLU

Monthly excess stock returns are regressed on a set of lagged predictive variables using the Fama and
MacBeth (1973) methodology. This table reports the average slope coefficients and Newey-West t-
statistics in parentheses. LIQU denotes the liquidity shock, defined as the negative Amihud’s (2002)
illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), demeaned using the past 12-month ILLIQ as the mean. SPRDU is the
shock to the monthly volume-weighted effective relative spread (SPRD), calculated in the same fashion
as LIQU. LIQCU denotes the conditional measure of liquidity shock, defined as the negative of the
difference between the realized ILLIQ and the conditional mean of ILLIQ in the month estimated
under the assumption that the conditional mean of ILLIQ follows an ARMA(1,1) process. BETA,
LNME, and LNBM denote the market beta, the natural logarithm of the market capitalization, and
the natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio, respectively. MOM is the momentum return.
REV is the short-term reversal. COSKEW and IVOL are the co-skewness and idiosyncratic volatility,
respectively. MAX denotes the maximum daily return in a month. DISP measures the analyst earnings
forecast dispersion. SUE is the standardized unexpected earnings. CVILLIQ is the coefficient of
variation in the Amihud’s illiquidity measure. SDTURN denotes the standard deviation of the monthly
turnover over the past 12 months. PS is Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta. BETA1–BETA4
are Acharya and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas. SADKAF and SADKAV are the loadings on
the fixed and the variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor. GKMH and GKML denote
the high- and low-volume dummy variables. VOLDU measures the abnormal dollar trading volume.
IVOLU is the idiosyncratic volatility shock.

xiv

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A6 – continued
Variable LIQU SPRDU LIQCU
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQ-Shock 0.200 0.156 0.621 0.472 0.179 0.000
(4.80) (3.70) (6.75) (4.93) (5.00) (4.01)
BETA 0.179 0.185 0.258 0.263 0.179 0.189
(1.65) (1.71) (2.07) (2.11) (1.63) (1.72)
LNME -0.073 -0.089 -0.080 -0.093 -0.048 -0.078
(-2.17) (-2.69) (-1.91) (-2.23) (-1.39) (-2.31)
LNBM 0.138 0.135 0.095 0.099 0.149 0.137
(1.86) (1.87) (1.18) (1.26) (2.02) (1.87)
MOM 0.005 0.003 0.004 0.002 0.005 0.003
(3.27) (1.98) (2.09) (1.20) (3.14) (1.97)
REV -0.033 -0.048 -0.027 -0.040 -0.033 -0.048
(-6.20) (-9.04) (-4.97) (-7.50) (-6.31) (-8.93)
COSKEW 0.039 0.042 0.707 0.668 0.245 0.225
(0.05) (0.05) (0.85) (0.81) (0.31) (0.29)
IVOL -0.366 -0.371 -0.248 -0.254 -0.315 -0.331
(-3.57) (-3.67) (-1.94) (-2.00) (-3.10) (-3.32)
MAX -0.014 -0.006 -0.017 -0.012 -0.012 -0.005
(-1.50) (-0.65) (-1.49) (-0.99) (-1.22) (-0.48)
DISP -0.072 -0.069 -0.085 -0.083 -0.083 -0.081
(-2.54) (-2.46) (-2.51) (-2.46) (-2.83) (-2.78)
SPRD 0.018 0.011
(0.20) (0.12)
ILLIQ 0.046 0.035 0.089 0.072 0.067 0.056
(1.62) (1.32) (3.02) (2.55) (2.52) (2.18)
CVILLIQ 0.091 0.028 0.079 0.024 0.110 0.042
(1.54) (0.47) (1.38) (0.41) (1.78) (0.69)
SDTURN -0.233 -0.231 -0.259 -0.253 -0.247 -0.233
(-2.75) (-2.77) (-2.56) (-2.52) (-2.74) (-2.64)
PS 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
(1.13) (1.07) (1.00) (0.96) (1.29) (1.21)
BETA1 0.152 0.118 0.203 0.174 0.118 0.085
(0.94) (0.77) (1.08) (0.95) (0.69) (0.51)
BETA2 -3.715 -3.311 -0.226 -0.446 -3.432 -2.737
(-0.96) (-0.86) (-0.06) (-0.12) (-0.77) (-0.62)
BETA3 1.721 1.601 3.904 3.771 2.053 1.892
(1.36) (1.29) (3.24) (3.17) (1.50) (1.40)
BETA4 -0.366 -0.385 -0.397 -0.401 -0.549 -0.570
(-1.10) (-1.16) (-0.94) (-0.97) (-1.36) (-1.42)
SADKAF -0.003 -0.003 0.000 0.000 -0.003 -0.003
(-1.06) (-1.11) (-0.08) (-0.02) (-1.00) (-1.02)
SADKAV -0.016 -0.016 -0.011 -0.011 -0.015 -0.015
(-1.84) (-1.85) (-1.09) (-1.06) (-1.76) (-1.72)
SUE 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
(12.02) (12.34) (9.44) (9.84) (12.18) (11.48)
GKMH 0.554 0.501 0.551
(5.58) (4.46) (5.22)
GKML -0.083 -0.143 -0.091
(-1.29) (-1.89) (-1.35)
VOLDU 0.000 0.000 0.000
(8.33) (6.53) (7.98)
IVOLU -0.061 -0.037 0.000 -0.105 -0.024 -0.063
(-0.62) (-0.38) (0.00) (-0.89) (-0.25) (-0.65)

xv

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A7
Stock-level cross-sectional regressions

Monthly excess stock returns are regressed on a set of lagged predictive variables using the Fama and
MacBeth (1973) methodology. This table reports the average slope coefficients and Newey-West t-
statistics in parentheses. LIQU denotes the liquidity shock, defined as the negative Amihud’s (2002)
illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), demeaned using the past 12-month ILLIQ as the mean. SPRDU is the
shock to the monthly volume-weighted effective relative spread (SPRD), calculated in the same fashion
as LIQU. LIQCU denotes the conditional measure of liquidity shock, defined as the negative of the
difference between the realized ILLIQ and the conditional mean of ILLIQ in the month estimated under
the assumption that the conditional mean of ILLIQ follows an ARMA(1,1) process. BETA, LNME,
and LNBM denote the market beta, the natural logarithm of the market capitalization, and the natural
logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio, respectively. MOM is the momentum return. REV is the
short-term reversal. COSKEW and IVOL are the co-skewness and idiosyncratic volatility, respectively.
MAX denotes the maximum daily return in a month. DISP measures the analyst earnings forecast
dispersion. SUE is the standardized unexpected earnings. CVILLIQ is the coefficient of variation in
the Amihud’s illiquidity measure. SDTURN denotes the standard deviation of the monthly turnover
over the past 12 months. PS is Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta. BETA1–BETA4 are
Acharya and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas. SADKAF and SADKAV are the loadings on the
fixed and the variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor. GKMH and GKML denote the
high- and low-volume dummy variables. VOLDU measures the abnormal dollar trading volume.

xvi

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A7 – continued
Panel A. Liquidity shock measured by LIQU
Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
LIQU 0.267 0.195 0.205 0.201 0.206 0.176 0.201 0.175 0.331 0.295
(8.17) (6.22) (5.16) (4.99) (5.18) (4.52) (5.00) (4.36) (6.96) (6.05)
BETA 0.064 0.189 0.166 0.158 0.164 0.180 0.156 0.171 0.254 0.272
(0.60) (1.70) (1.63) (1.42) (1.61) (1.80) (1.41) (1.56) (2.35) (2.50)
LNME -0.052 -0.117 -0.058 -0.068 -0.057 -0.091 -0.066 -0.096 -0.115 -0.125
(-1.58) (-3.59) (-1.79) (-2.08) (-1.75) (-2.78) (-2.03) (-2.94) (-2.92) (-3.18)
LNBM 0.207 0.205 0.181 0.141 0.179 0.165 0.140 0.125 0.093 0.085
(2.72) (2.69) (2.32) (1.83) (2.30) (2.15) (1.82) (1.65) (1.42) (1.29)
MOM 0.007 0.006 0.005 0.006 0.004 0.005 0.003 0.004 0.003
(5.10) (3.61) (2.83) (4.07) (2.81) (3.33) (2.04) (2.85) (1.92)
REV -0.039 -0.036 -0.038 -0.031 -0.047 -0.033 -0.048 -0.026 -0.036
(-7.96) (-6.39) (-6.94) (-5.78) (-8.44) (-6.13) (-8.84) (-4.56) (-6.35)
COSKEW -0.054 0.270 0.131 0.264 0.240 0.119 0.105 0.732 0.705
(-0.10) (0.36) (0.16) (0.35) (0.32) (0.15) (0.13) (0.92) (0.89)
IVOL -0.427 -0.319 -0.285 -0.337 -0.423 -0.307 -0.383 -0.222 -0.274
(-8.59) (-6.35) (-6.00) (-6.69) (-8.18) (-6.47) (-7.89) (-4.15) (-4.94)
MAX -0.013 -0.013 -0.006 -0.018 -0.009 -0.012 -0.002 -0.013 0.000
(-1.43) (-1.37) (-0.59) (-1.92) (-0.95) (-1.25) (-0.21) (-1.05) (-0.02)
DISP -0.20 -0.07 -0.07 -0.07 -0.07 -0.07 -0.06 -0.08 -0.08
(-2.05) (-2.37) (-2.25) (-2.38) (-2.16) (-2.27) (-2.07) (-2.31) (-2.11)
SPRD -0.120 -0.091
(-1.47) (-1.21)
ILLIQ 0.030 0.044 0.054 0.042 0.025 0.051 0.032 0.005 0.007
(1.55) (1.97) (2.05) (1.88) (1.22) (1.95) (1.32) (0.14) (0.19)
CVILLIQ 0.076 0.097 0.078 0.009 0.098 0.034 0.178 0.111
(1.30) (1.64) (1.32) (0.15) (1.66) (0.58) (2.58) (1.66)
SDTURN -0.345 -0.267 -0.345 -0.305 -0.271 -0.226 -0.176 -0.164
(-3.69) (-2.93) (-3.70) (-3.28) (-2.94) (-2.51) (-2.14) (-1.98)
PS 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
(1.13) (1.32) (1.09) (0.99) (1.28) (1.18) (1.04) (1.06)
BETA1 0.164 0.163 0.177 0.183 0.180 0.181 0.246 0.246
(0.93) (0.87) (0.99) (1.05) (0.95) (0.97) (1.31) (1.33)
BETA2 -1.890 -4.292 -1.996 -1.344 -4.367 -3.606 0.368 0.561
(-0.80) (-1.13) (-0.84) (-0.58) (-1.14) (-0.96) (0.10) (0.16)
BETA3 1.855 1.604 1.880 1.814 1.638 1.541 3.760 3.716
(1.81) (1.24) (1.82) (1.79) (1.27) (1.21) (2.98) (2.94)
BETA4 -0.045 -0.321 -0.049 -0.052 -0.325 -0.334 -0.337 -0.319
(-0.19) (-0.98) (-0.21) (-0.22) (-0.98) (-1.02) (-1.06) (-1.01)
SADKAF -0.003 -0.004 -0.003 -0.003 -0.004 -0.004 0.000 0.000
(-1.03) (-1.17) (-1.00) (-1.04) (-1.12) (-1.16) (0.05) (-0.01)
SADKAV -0.010 -0.016 -0.010 -0.010 -0.016 -0.016 -0.010 -0.010
(-1.23) (-1.85) (-1.22) (-1.22) (-1.82) (-1.80) (-1.06) (-1.04)
SUE 0.296 0.303 0.283 0.279 0.262
(13.32) (13.77) (12.99) (12.74) (11.94)
GKMH 0.415 0.547 0.469
(4.07) (5.64) (4.57)
GKML -0.101 -0.071 -0.132
(-1.66) (-1.10) (-1.91)
VOLDU 0.230 0.210 0.210 0.120
(10.89) (9.77) (9.77) (8.93)
xvii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A7 – continued
Panel B. Liquidity shock measured by SPRDU
Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
SPRDU 0.421 0.328 0.532 0.576 0.615 0.592 0.512 0.632 0.554
(6.72) (5.38) (6.29) (6.68) (7.29) (6.84) (6.17) (7.41) (6.80)
BETA 0.170 0.210 0.207 0.236 0.266 0.235 0.249 0.264 0.278
(1.05) (1.47) (1.46) (1.96) (2.20) (1.97) (2.10) (2.19) (2.32)
LNME 0.015 -0.048 -0.057 -0.066 -0.069 -0.062 -0.080 -0.065 -0.081
(0.43) (-1.31) (-1.53) (-1.64) (-1.68) (-1.54) (-2.01) (-1.58) (-1.99)
LNBM 0.171 0.178 0.177 0.137 0.103 0.134 0.124 0.101 0.091
(1.59) (1.87) (1.81) (1.56) (1.22) (1.54) (1.44) (1.20) (1.09)
MOM 0.005 0.004 0.004 0.003 0.005 0.003 0.004 0.002
(2.80) (2.40) (2.29) (1.70) (2.60) (1.75) (2.04) (1.18)
REV -0.028 -0.028 -0.029 -0.033 -0.025 -0.038 -0.028 -0.041
(-5.16) (-5.11) (-5.22) (-5.97) (-4.61) (-7.04) (-5.20) (-7.77)
COSKEW 0.495 0.497 0.887 0.727 0.910 0.849 0.731 0.689
(0.69) (0.67) (1.01) (0.86) (1.04) (0.98) (0.87) (0.83)
IVOL -0.249 -0.307 -0.234 -0.224 -0.254 -0.350 -0.247 -0.334
(-3.67) (-4.51) (-3.95) (-3.80) (-4.33) (-5.67) (-4.24) (-5.49)
MAX -0.006 -0.014 -0.014 -0.012 -0.019 -0.013 -0.018 -0.011
(-0.47) (-1.12) (-1.14) (-1.01) (-1.62) (-1.10) (-1.58) (-0.96)
DISP -0.09 -0.09 -0.08 -0.08 -0.09 -0.08 -0.09 -0.08
(-2.40) (-2.44) (-2.35) (-2.31) (-2.35) (-2.18) (-2.32) (-2.17)
SPRD 0.014 0.092 0.040 0.049 0.049 0.092 0.059 0.102
(0.25) (1.45) (0.63) (0.74) (0.76) (1.41) (0.88) (1.50)
ILLIQ 0.134 0.169 0.180 0.166 0.141 0.176 0.154
(3.37) (4.47) (4.68) (4.36) (3.81) (4.55) (4.09)
CVILLIQ 0.097 0.103 0.097 0.021 0.102 0.032
(1.43) (1.53) (1.43) (0.30) (1.51) (0.47)
SDTURN -0.306 -0.234 -0.306 -0.244 -0.233 -0.176
(-3.25) (-2.43) (-3.27) (-2.66) (-2.43) (-1.86)
PS 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
(0.75) (0.98) (0.73) (0.66) (0.96) (0.89)
BETA1 0.215 0.192 0.225 0.238 0.210 0.215
(1.05) (0.90) (1.09) (1.18) (0.97) (1.01)
BETA2 2.823 3.054 2.700 2.680 2.963 2.869
(0.90) (0.85) (0.85) (0.86) (0.82) (0.81)
BETA3 3.240 3.989 3.226 3.116 3.977 3.874
(2.86) (3.30) (2.82) (2.76) (3.28) (3.22)
BETA4 0.125 -0.086 0.122 0.117 -0.098 -0.091
(0.44) (-0.25) (0.42) (0.41) (-0.28) (-0.27)
SADKAF 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
(-0.01) (0.01) (-0.03) (-0.05) (-0.03) (0.01)
SADKAV -0.009 -0.011 -0.009 -0.009 -0.011 -0.010
(-0.86) (-1.02) (-0.89) (-0.84) (-1.07) (-0.99)
SUE 0.268 0.276 0.254
(10.69) (11.13) (10.42)
GKMH 0.423 0.523
(3.75) (4.76)
GKML -0.145 -0.136
(-2.05) (-1.85)
VOLDU 0.204 0.186
(8.40) (7.84)
xviii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A7 – continued
Panel C. Liquidity shock measured by LIQCU
Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
LIQCU 0.198 0.180 0.177 0.168 0.177 0.157 0.169 0.148 0.135 0.116
(7.84) (6.86) (5.39) (5.07) (5.46) (3.63) (5.12) (3.59) (5.87) (4.12)
BETA 0.044 0.163 0.160 0.178 0.158 0.170 0.175 0.188 0.286 0.304
(0.41) (1.42) (1.53) (1.59) (1.51) (1.64) (1.57) (1.69) (2.65) (2.78)
LNME -0.032 -0.098 -0.039 -0.046 -0.038 -0.084 -0.044 -0.085 -0.088 -0.108
(-0.96) (-3.06) (-1.21) (-1.40) (-1.16) (-2.54) (-1.35) (-2.59) (-2.27) (-2.77)
LNBM 0.215 0.219 0.184 0.149 0.183 0.160 0.148 0.126 0.118 0.103
(2.90) (2.90) (2.36) (1.96) (2.35) (2.08) (1.95) (1.68) (1.85) (1.61)
MOM 0.007 0.006 0.004 0.006 0.004 0.005 0.003 0.005 0.003
(4.80) (3.45) (2.71) (3.91) (2.78) (3.20) (2.05) (3.08) (2.20)
REV -0.040 -0.036 -0.039 -0.031 -0.046 -0.034 -0.048 -0.027 -0.037
(-7.97) (-6.36) (-6.95) (-5.75) (-8.17) (-6.18) (-8.64) (-4.69) (-6.44)
COSKEW -0.092 0.373 0.287 0.375 0.334 0.280 0.252 0.821 0.773
(-0.17) (0.49) (0.37) (0.49) (0.44) (0.36) (0.33) (1.03) (0.97)
IVOL -0.407 -0.291 -0.257 -0.308 -0.397 -0.279 -0.356 -0.217 -0.269
(-8.23) (-5.88) (-5.18) (-6.22) (-7.86) (-5.62) (-7.17) (-4.08) (-4.87)
MAX -0.011 -0.009 -0.003 -0.014 -0.006 -0.009 0.000 -0.015 -0.004
(-1.15) (-0.90) (-0.27) (-1.41) (-0.60) (-0.90) (-0.01) (-1.29) (-0.30)
DISP -0.20 -0.08 -0.08 -0.08 -0.08 -0.08 -0.07 -0.08 -0.08
(-2.06) (-2.63) (-2.51) (-2.64) (-2.47) (-2.51) (-2.37) (-2.34) (-2.15)
SPRD -0.082 -0.056
(-1.35) (-1.29)
ILLIQ 0.032 0.063 0.070 0.062 0.048 0.068 0.052 0.104 0.107
(1.51) (2.67) (2.73) (2.58) (2.06) (2.63) (2.08) (2.65) (2.77)
CVILLIQ 0.103 0.113 0.103 0.030 0.112 0.045 0.191 0.122
(1.70) (1.82) (1.69) (0.50) (1.81) (0.74) (2.75) (1.79)
SDTURN -0.316 -0.258 -0.320 -0.272 -0.263 -0.215 -0.183 -0.172
(-3.54) (-2.80) (-3.56) (-3.07) (-2.83) (-2.36) (-2.25) (-2.10)
PS 0.001 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.001
(1.23) (1.47) (1.20) (1.10) (1.44) (1.34) (1.03) (1.03)
BETA1 0.125 0.117 0.138 0.149 0.136 0.138 0.173 0.174
(0.67) (0.59) (0.73) (0.80) (0.68) (0.70) (0.91) (0.93)
BETA2 -4.567 -4.868 -4.728 -3.069 -5.019 -3.544 5.547 5.733
(-1.23) (-1.13) (-1.25) (-0.86) (-1.15) (-0.83) (1.66) (1.73)
BETA3 1.714 1.978 1.753 1.639 2.020 1.871 4.015 3.959
(1.39) (1.40) (1.41) (1.34) (1.43) (1.34) (3.00) (2.95)
BETA4 -0.364 -0.555 -0.376 -0.383 -0.570 -0.571 -0.008 -0.020
(-0.98) (-1.36) (-1.00) (-1.03) (-1.38) (-1.40) (-0.02) (-0.06)
SADKAF -0.003 -0.004 -0.003 -0.003 -0.004 -0.003 0.000 0.000
(-1.16) (-1.15) (-1.12) (-1.13) (-1.11) (-1.10) (-0.08) (-0.10)
SADKAV -0.010 -0.016 -0.009 -0.009 -0.016 -0.015 -0.011 -0.010
(-1.14) (-1.77) (-1.13) (-1.09) (-1.76) (-1.70) (-1.17) (-1.09)
SUE 0.296 0.303 0.283 0.281 0.264
(13.39) (13.82) (13.07) (12.86) (12.01)
GKMH 0.406 0.537 0.489
(3.88) (5.22) (4.73)
GKML -0.082 -0.079 -0.136
(-1.24) (-1.17) (-1.98)
VOLDU 0.218 0.200 0.200 0.120
(10.08) (9.35) (9.35) (8.75)
xix

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A8
Results based on equal-weighted quoted spread shock

QSPRDU is the negative equal-weighted quoted spread (QSPRD), demeaned using the past 12-month QSPRD as the mean. Panel A presents
the equal- and value-weighted one-month ahead returns for decile portfolios formed on QSPRDU, the return differentials between High and
Low QSPRDU deciles and the corresponding Fama-French (1993) alphas. Panel B reports the average slope coefficients of QSPRDU from the
monthly Fama-MacBeth regressions of one-month ahead returns on QSPRDU and all the other control variables listed in Table 6. Specifications
(1) and (2) control for the GKM dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ) and the abnormal dollar trading volume (VOLDU), respectively. For
brevity, we suppress the average coefficients of the control variables, which are available upon request. Newey-West t-statistics are reported in
parentheses.
Panel A. One-month ahead returns for portfolios formed on QSPRDU
Decile Equal-weighted Value-weighted
1 (Low) 0.48 0.56
2 0.95 0.84
3 0.95 0.89

xx
4 0.87 0.87
5 0.94 0.86
6 1.04 0.99
7 1.03 1.00
8 0.96 1.01
9 1.18 1.27
10 (High) 1.50 1.33
High-Low 1.02 0.77
(5.47) (2.88)
Alpha 1.09 0.85

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


(6.33) (3.30)

Panel B. Monthly Fama-MacBeth regressions


(1) (2)
0.557 0.481
(8.26) (7.24)
Table A9
Bivariate sorts with control for attention and liquidity

Stocks are sorted into quintile portfolios based on an investor attention variable or the Amihud’s illiq-
uidity measure (ILLIQ) and then into quintile portfolios of liquidity shock (SPRDU in Panel A and
LIQCU in Panel B) within each control quintile using NYSE breakpoints. The investor attention vari-
ables are the natural logarithm of market capitalization (LNME), the number of analysts covering the
stocks (CVRG), and the quarterly aggregate institutional holdings (INST). This table reports the aver-
age returns for each of the 5 × 5 portfolios, the return differences between High and Low LIQU quintile
portfolios within each control variable quintile portfolio and the Fama-French (1993) alphas. The last
column presents the 5−1 average return differences for each control variable within each LIQU quintile
portfolio. Newey-West t-statistics are given in parentheses.
Panel A. Liquidity shock measured by SPRDU
Panel A1. Control for LNME
SPRDU LNME (Low) LNME 2 LNME 3 LNME 4 LNME (High) High-Low
1 (Low) 1.04 0.96 0.93 0.92 0.93 -0.11
2 1.16 1.30 1.09 1.11 1.04 -0.12
3 1.39 1.38 1.13 1.37 1.10 -0.29
4 1.74 1.33 1.21 1.30 1.09 -0.65
5 (High) 1.86 1.67 1.41 1.29 1.24 -0.62
High - Low 0.82 0.71 0.48 0.37 0.31 -0.51
(5.20) (3.64) (3.02) (2.25) (1.84) (-2.99)
Alpha 0.89 0.75 0.42 0.40 0.33 -0.56
(5.60) (4.56) (3.24) (2.45) (2.01) (-3.03)

Panel A2. Control for CVRG


SPRDU CVRG (Low) CVRG 2 CVRG 3 CVRG 4 CVRG (High) High-Low
1 (Low) 0.74 0.88 0.96 0.91 0.96 0.22
2 1.19 1.23 1.40 1.14 1.08 -0.12
3 1.28 1.41 1.37 1.16 1.17 -0.11
4 1.55 1.51 1.52 1.21 1.28 -0.28
5 (High) 1.77 1.80 1.62 1.49 1.42 -0.35
High - Low 1.03 0.92 0.65 0.58 0.46 -0.58
(4.80) (4.01) (2.72) (2.53) (1.98) (-3.57)
Alpha 1.05 0.97 0.67 0.59 0.49 -0.57
(5.23) (4.32) (2.75) (2.54) (2.17) (-3.49)

xxi

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A9 – continued
Panel A3. Control for INST
SPRDU INST (Low) INST 2 INST 3 INST 4 INST (High) High-Low
1 (Low) 0.29 0.67 0.91 0.83 0.99 0.70
2 0.80 1.10 1.14 0.95 1.08 0.28
3 0.99 1.00 1.13 0.93 0.99 0.00
4 1.36 1.14 1.17 1.07 1.03 -0.33
5 (High) 1.46 1.52 1.49 1.37 1.33 -0.13
High - Low 1.17 0.85 0.58 0.54 0.35 -0.83
(5.77) (3.39) (2.24) (2.08) (1.94) (-4.12)
Alpha 1.16 0.96 0.75 0.53 0.45 -0.64
(5.99) (4.55) (3.41) (2.67) (2.02) (-3.30)

Panel A4. Control for ILLIQ


SPRDU ILLIQ (Low) ILLIQ 2 ILLIQ 3 ILLIQ 4 ILLIQ (High) High-Low
1 (Low) 0.92 0.97 1.13 1.02 0.82 -0.15
2 1.09 1.12 1.19 1.22 1.28 0.16
3 1.28 1.11 1.38 1.30 1.34 0.22
4 1.25 1.11 1.30 1.38 1.60 0.50
5 (High) 1.41 1.58 1.87 1.90 1.88 0.30
High - Low 0.49 0.61 0.74 0.88 1.06 0.45
(2.22) (2.74) (3.36) (5.85) (6.71) (3.34)
Alpha 0.52 0.62 0.80 1.04 1.05 0.43
(2.06) (2.44) (3.61) (5.65) (6.64) (2.78)

xxii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A9 – continued
Panel B. Liquidity shock measured by LIQCU
Panel B1. Control for LNME
LIQCU LNME (Low) LNME 2 LNME 3 LNME 4 LNME (High) High-Low
1 (Low) 0.79 0.91 0.89 0.86 0.74 -0.05
2 1.00 1.14 1.11 1.13 0.92 -0.08
3 1.49 1.32 1.31 1.13 0.93 -0.56
4 1.59 1.41 1.29 1.19 0.93 -0.65
5 (High) 1.59 1.35 1.25 1.08 1.02 -0.57
High - Low 0.80 0.44 0.36 0.22 0.27 -0.52
(6.73) (3.44) (2.72) (1.44) (2.51) (-4.47)
Alpha 0.82 0.53 0.48 0.36 0.36 -0.46
(7.80) (4.56) (3.64) (2.69) (3.33) (-3.84)

Panel B2. Control for CVRG


LIQCU CVRG (Low) CVRG 2 CVRG 3 CVRG 4 CVRG (High) High-Low
1 (Low) 0.86 1.00 1.04 1.07 0.90 0.04
2 1.05 1.15 1.23 1.09 1.05 0.00
3 1.40 1.38 1.27 1.13 1.03 -0.37
4 1.54 1.34 1.19 1.22 1.16 -0.39
5 (High) 1.60 1.49 1.39 1.36 1.13 -0.47
High - Low 0.74 0.49 0.36 0.29 0.23 -0.51
(6.36) (3.47) (2.29) (1.97) (1.37) (-3.28)
Alpha 0.78 0.54 0.46 0.39 0.34 -0.44
(7.15) (4.45) (3.29) (3.07) (2.24) (-2.76)

Panel B3. Control for INST


LIQCU INST (Low) INST 2 INST 3 INST 4 INST (High) High-Low
1 (Low) 0.61 0.77 0.91 0.94 0.83 0.23
2 0.79 1.03 1.23 1.23 1.13 0.34
3 1.33 1.18 1.28 1.18 1.15 -0.18
4 1.42 1.44 1.34 1.44 1.16 -0.26
5 (High) 1.41 1.54 1.41 1.21 1.16 -0.24
High - Low 0.80 0.78 0.49 0.27 0.33 -0.47
(5.43) (5.11) (3.03) (1.53) (2.10) (-3.06)
Alpha 0.91 0.91 0.65 0.43 0.52 -0.38
(8.34) (6.67) (4.22) (2.80) (3.87) (-2.60)

Panel B4. Control for ILLIQ


LIQCU ILLIQ (Low) ILLIQ 2 ILLIQ 3 ILLIQ 4 ILLIQ (High) High-Low
1 (Low) 0.81 0.92 0.91 0.83 0.74 -0.07
2 0.97 1.06 1.11 1.08 0.98 0.01
3 0.99 1.15 1.26 1.29 1.34 0.34
4 1.01 1.25 1.39 1.49 1.52 0.51
5 (High) 1.14 1.21 1.18 1.47 1.50 0.36
High - Low 0.33 0.29 0.27 0.64 0.76 0.43
(2.85) (1.75) (1.60) (3.59) (6.53) (3.64)
Alpha 0.32 0.41 0.33 0.67 0.76 0.43
(2.87) (2.94) (2.17) (4.17) (7.34) (3.48)

xxiii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A10
Stock-level cross-sectional regressions with interaction terms

One-month ahead excess returns are regressed on the Amihud’s illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), one
investor attention variable, the liquidity shock (LIQ-Shock), and the interactions between ILLIQ
and LIQ-Shock and between the attention variable and LIQ-Shock using the Fama-MacBeth (1973)
methodology. LIQ-Shock is measured by LIQU in Panel A, SPRDU in Panel B and LIQCU in Panel C.
The investor attention variables are the natural logarithm of market capitalization (LNME), the number
of analysts covering the stocks (CVRG), and the quarterly aggregate institutional holdings (INST). We
control for a large set of cross-sectional predictors: the investor attention variable (controlled for one
at a time), the market beta (BETA), LNME, the natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio
(LNBM), the momentum return (MOM), the short-term reversal (REV), the co-skewness (COSKEW),
the idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), the maximum daily return in a month (MAX), the analyst earnings
forecast dispersion (DISP), the standardized unexpected earnings (SUE), the high- and low-volume
dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ), the dollar trading volume shock (VOLDU), the standard devi-
ation of the monthly turnover over the past 12 months (SDTURN), the coefficient of variation in the
Amihud’s illiquidity measure (CVILLIQ), Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta (PS), Acharya
and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas (BETA1–BETA4), and the loadings on the fixed and the
variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor (SADKAF and SADKAV). Specifications (1)
and (2) control for the GKM dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ) and the abnormal dollar trading
volume (VOLDU), respectively. Newey-West t-statistics are given in parentheses.

xxiv

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A10 – continued
Panel A. Liquidity shock measured by LIQU
Variable Attention measured by LNME Attention measured by CVRG Attention measured by INST
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQU 0.908 0.979 0.603 0.572 0.403 0.320
(4.68) (4.80) (6.82) (6.54) (6.79) (5.76)
LIQU×ILLIQ 0.100 0.086 0.100 0.055 0.027 0.003
(1.93) (1.66) (1.07) (0.60) (0.54) (0.06)
LIQU×ATTENTION -0.111 -0.148 -0.180 -0.234 -0.234 -0.304
(-3.34) (-4.12) (-3.11) (-3.94) (-2.01) (-2.56)
BETA 0.154 0.169 0.219 0.229 0.148 0.162
(1.42) (1.58) (1.83) (1.91) (1.38) (1.51)
LNME -0.129 -0.177 -0.062 -0.105
(-2.72) (-3.72) (-1.85) (-3.10)
LNBM 0.143 0.125 0.080 0.063 0.152 0.137
(1.89) (1.67) (0.96) (0.76) (2.04) (1.87)
MOM 0.004 0.003 0.004 0.002 0.004 0.003
(2.71) (1.87) (2.06) (1.41) (2.67) (1.86)
REV -0.035 -0.048 -0.039 -0.050 -0.036 -0.049
(-6.51) (-8.79) (-6.82) (-8.47) (-6.74) (-8.93)
COSKEW 0.199 0.178 -0.012 -0.039 0.260 0.250
(0.25) (0.22) (-0.01) (-0.05) (0.32) (0.32)
IVOL -0.293 -0.371 -0.306 -0.371 -0.289 -0.358
(-6.09) (-7.54) (-5.79) (-6.67) (-6.04) (-7.26)
MAX -0.010 -0.001 -0.027 -0.019 -0.009 -0.001
(-1.03) (-0.12) (-2.43) (-1.75) (-0.99) (-0.09)
DISP -0.06 -0.06 -0.07 -0.07 -0.07 -0.06
(-2.10) (-1.92) (-2.28) (-2.19) (-2.21) (-2.07)
ILLIQ 0.080 0.065 0.301 0.265 0.069 0.050
(3.37) (2.75) (2.62) (2.35) (2.92) (2.15)
CVILLIQ 0.105 0.037 0.207 0.149 0.113 0.053
(1.77) (0.63) (2.81) (2.02) (1.99) (0.93)
SDTURN -0.282 -0.246 -0.266 -0.241 -0.280 -0.244
(-3.04) (-2.72) (-2.87) (-2.64) (-2.99) (-2.68)
PS 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
(1.22) (1.14) (1.10) (1.06) (1.18) (1.11)
BETA1 0.194 0.196 0.072 0.074 0.194 0.189
(1.02) (1.05) (0.36) (0.37) (1.03) (1.02)
BETA2 -4.399 -3.892 0.809 2.335 -3.350 -2.589
(-1.25) (-1.14) (0.10) (0.28) (-0.97) (-0.76)
BETA3 1.639 1.515 2.440 2.396 1.750 1.632
(1.28) (1.20) (1.62) (1.60) (1.36) (1.28)
BETA4 -0.304 -0.304 0.547 0.534 -0.309 -0.316
(-0.95) (-0.95) (0.92) (0.90) (-0.97) (-1.00)
SADKAF -0.004 -0.004 -0.003 -0.004 -0.003 -0.003
(-1.19) (-1.24) (-0.98) (-1.00) (-1.00) (-1.03)
SADAKV -0.015 -0.015 -0.009 -0.009 -0.015 -0.015
(-1.79) (-1.78) (-0.99) (-0.95) (-1.82) (-1.79)
SUE 0.296 0.281 0.216 0.207 0.295 0.281
(13.92) (13.20) (9.49) (9.04) (13.85) (13.15)
GKMH 0.571 0.514 0.577
(5.92) (4.92) (6.08)
GKML -0.088 -0.092 -0.092
(-1.35) (-1.31) (-1.37)
VOLDU 0.196 0.145 0.176
(9.31) (6.83) (8.67)
ATTENTION -0.071 -0.125 0.145 0.148 0.187 0.163
(-2.23) (-3.90) xxv(2.46) (2.53) (1.00) (0.88)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A10 – continued
Panel B. Liquidity shock measured by SPRDU
Variable Attention measured by LNME Attention measured by CVRG Attention measured by INST
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
SPRDU 1.721 1.650 0.825 0.753 0.788 0.679
(7.37) (7.06) (5.71) (5.26) (6.56) (5.85)
SPRDU×ILLIQ 0.322 0.272 0.019 0.043 0.116 0.057
(3.36) (2.87) (0.09) (0.20) (1.14) (0.55)
SPRDU×ATTENTION -0.228 -0.237 -0.313 -0.335 -0.815 -0.836
(-5.71) (-5.82) (-3.76) (-3.99) (-4.17) (-4.26)
BETA 0.263 0.279 0.345 0.354 0.258 0.272
(2.21) (2.36) (2.47) (2.54) (2.19) (2.32)
LNME -0.084 -0.106 -0.160 -0.183 -0.078 -0.099
(-2.10) (-2.68) (-2.90) (-3.36) (-1.86) (-2.37)
LNBM 0.101 0.089 0.056 0.043 0.107 0.095
(1.23) (1.10) (0.63) (0.49) (1.32) (1.18)
MOM 0.004 0.002 0.004 0.003 0.004 0.002
(2.14) (1.35) (2.00) (1.39) (2.14) (1.36)
REV -0.028 -0.041 -0.030 -0.041 -0.029 -0.041
(-5.37) (-7.86) (-5.25) (-7.07) (-5.53) (-7.99)
COSKEW 0.746 0.718 0.364 0.302 0.777 0.751
(0.89) (0.86) (0.44) (0.37) (0.91) (0.89)
IVOL -0.234 -0.322 -0.243 -0.324 -0.239 -0.325
(-4.12) (-5.50) (-4.05) (-5.03) (-4.19) (-5.50)
MAX -0.017 -0.010 -0.029 -0.023 -0.018 -0.011
(-1.49) (-0.90) (-2.23) (-1.77) (-1.56) (-0.98)
DISP -0.082 -0.075 -0.09 -0.08 -0.08 -0.08
(-2.27) (-2.10) (-2.27) (-2.21) (-2.33) (-2.18)
SPRD -0.019 0.018 -0.124 -0.080 -0.003 0.035
(-0.30) (0.26) (-1.18) (-0.74) (-0.05) (0.54)
ILLIQ 0.183 0.159 0.486 0.433 0.185 0.162
(4.32) (3.94) (2.99) (2.69) (4.48) (4.08)
CVILLIQ 0.124 0.057 0.227 0.156 0.125 0.061
(1.75) (0.80) (2.39) (1.64) (1.78) (0.85)
SDTURN -0.250 -0.192 -0.250 -0.202 -0.233 -0.177
(-2.57) (-2.01) (-2.43) (-2.00) (-2.43) (-1.87)
PS 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
(0.93) (0.86) (1.00) (0.95) (0.97) (0.91)
BETA1 0.207 0.219 0.117 0.138 0.205 0.216
(0.97) (1.04) (0.50) (0.59) (0.97) (1.04)
BETA2 3.313 3.241 -5.548 -5.362 3.805 3.786
(0.91) (0.90) (-0.78) (-0.76) (1.04) (1.05)
BETA3 3.954 3.885 5.332 5.320 4.066 3.999
(3.33) (3.30) (3.58) (3.59) (3.35) (3.32)
BETA4 -0.132 -0.123 0.516 0.601 -0.164 -0.152
(-0.39) (-0.37) (0.74) (0.86) (-0.49) (-0.47)
SADKAF 0.000 0.000 -0.001 -0.001 0.001 0.001
(0.10) (0.13) (-0.21) (-0.18) (0.17) (0.21)
SADAKV -0.010 -0.010 -0.009 -0.008 -0.010 -0.010
(-1.00) (-0.93) (-0.84) (-0.75) (-1.01) (-0.94)
SUE 0.272 0.251 0.183 0.169 0.272 0.252
(11.39) (10.60) (7.41) (6.87) (11.27) (10.51)
GKMH 0.548 0.513 0.552
(4.99) (4.25) (5.03)
GKML -0.146 -0.157 -0.146
(-2.03) (-1.90) (-1.95)
VOLDU 0.186 0.154 0.179
(8.36) xxvi (6.29) (8.38)
ATTENTION 0.168 0.188 0.134 0.144
(2.72) (3.01) (0.65) (0.71)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A10 – continued
Panel C. Liquidity shock measured by LIQCU
Variable Attention measured by LNME Attention measured by CVRG Attention measured by INST
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQCU 0.329 0.353 0.230 0.216 0.241 0.197
(3.39) (3.62) (3.78) (3.51) (3.87) (3.38)
LIQCU×ILLIQ 0.088 0.081 0.111 0.082 0.092 0.073
(2.45) (2.28) (1.27) (0.93) (2.42) (2.04)
LIQCU×ATTENTION -0.032 -0.046 -0.050 -0.073 -0.237 -0.261
(-1.87) (-2.67) (-1.53) (-2.15) (-1.90) (-2.04)
BETA 0.172 0.188 0.192 0.201 0.167 0.181
(1.55) (1.70) (1.49) (1.57) (1.51) (1.65)
LNME -0.127 -0.173 -0.051 -0.093
(-2.59) (-3.51) (-1.49) (-2.70)
LNBM 0.146 0.120 0.086 0.062 0.154 0.132
(1.93) (1.60) (1.03) (0.75) (2.08) (1.79)
MOM 0.005 0.003 0.005 0.003 0.005 0.003
(3.18) (2.05) (2.61) (1.67) (3.09) (2.00)
REV -0.033 -0.047 -0.037 -0.049 -0.034 -0.048
(-6.08) (-8.54) (-6.27) (-8.23) (-6.29) (-8.70)
COSKEW 0.264 0.232 -0.115 -0.149 0.356 0.330
(0.33) (0.30) (-0.14) (-0.18) (0.46) (0.43)
IVOL -0.279 -0.360 -0.293 -0.366 -0.279 -0.355
(-5.60) (-7.22) (-5.44) (-6.61) (-5.56) (-7.05)
MAX -0.009 0.000 -0.025 -0.017 -0.009 0.000
(-0.91) (-0.02) (-2.24) (-1.50) (-0.89) (-0.01)
DISP -0.08 -0.07 -0.09 -0.08 -0.08 -0.07
(-2.43) (-2.26) (-2.51) (-2.44) (-2.43) (-2.28)
ILLIQ 0.104 0.083 0.262 0.213 0.096 0.074
(3.83) (3.20) (2.49) (2.10) (3.54) (2.84)
CVILLIQ 0.108 0.039 0.241 0.169 0.105 0.040
(1.72) (0.64) (3.14) (2.23) (1.74) (0.67)
SDTURN -0.271 -0.219 -0.250 -0.206 -0.265 -0.212
(-2.90) (-2.40) (-2.71) (-2.27) (-2.83) (-2.33)
PS 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
(1.32) (1.22) (0.99) (0.92) (1.33) (1.24)
BETA1 0.140 0.144 0.045 0.054 0.131 0.132
(0.69) (0.72) (0.20) (0.25) (0.65) (0.67)
BETA2 -4.907 -4.348 -9.425 -7.990 -3.904 -2.969
(-1.14) (-1.01) (-0.66) (-0.56) (-0.94) (-0.72)
BETA3 2.035 1.855 1.323 1.259 2.154 1.989
(1.46) (1.34) (0.71) (0.68) (1.53) (1.42)
BETA4 -0.559 -0.558 0.501 0.429 -0.588 -0.601
(-1.33) (-1.34) (0.56) (0.48) (-1.40) (-1.44)
SADKAF -0.003 -0.004 -0.002 -0.002 -0.003 -0.003
(-1.10) (-1.13) (-0.56) (-0.57) (-0.87) (-0.88)
SADAKV -0.016 -0.015 -0.012 -0.011 -0.016 -0.015
(-1.77) (-1.70) (-1.13) (-1.05) (-1.78) (-1.71)
SUE 0.304 0.284 0.226 0.212 0.304 0.284
(13.87) (13.12) (9.88) (9.32) (13.92) (13.17)
GKMH 0.533 0.498 0.534
(5.20) (4.54) (5.25)
GKML -0.081 -0.084 -0.082
(-1.20) (-1.19) (-1.19)
VOLDU 0.203 0.170 0.196
(9.27) (7.71) (9.34)
ATTENTION -0.067 -0.117 0.129 0.140 0.147 0.128
(-2.00) (-3.49) xxvii(2.23) (2.43) (0.77) (0.68)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A11
Predicting cumulative stock returns
Each month, cumulative excess returns in two to six months into the future are regressed on a set of
predictive variables measured in month t using the Fama and MacBeth (1973) methodology. This table
reports the average slope coefficients of the liquidity shock (SPRDU in Panel A and LIQCU in Panel B)
without interaction terms and with interactions between liquidity shock and ILLIQ and between liquid-
ity shock and an attention variable. The control variables include the market beta (BETA), the natural
logarithm of market capitalization (LNME), the natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity ratio
(LNBM), the momentum return (MOM), the short-term reversal (REV), the co-skewness (COSKEW),
the idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), the maximum daily return in a month (MAX), the analyst earnings
forecast dispersion (DISP), the standardized unexpected earnings (SUE), the high- and low-volume
dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ), the dollar trading volume shock (VOLDU), the standard devi-
ation of the monthly turnover over the past 12 months (SDTURN), the coefficient of variation in the
Amihud’s illiquidity measure (CVILLIQ), Pastor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta (PS), Acharya
and Pedersen’s (2005) four liquidity betas (BETA1–BETA4), and the loadings on the fixed and the
variable components of Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor (SADKAF and SADKAV). Specifications (1)
and (2) control for the GKM dummy variables (GKMH and GKML ) and the abnormal dollar trading
volume (VOLDU), respectively. For brevity, we suppress the average coefficients of the control vari-
ables, which are available upon request. The t-statistics (in parentheses) are based on Hodrick (1992)
robust standard errors.

xxviii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A11 – continued
Panel A. Liquidity shock measured by SPRDU
Panel A1. Without interaction terms
Variable Month 2 Month 3 Month 4 Month 5 Month 6
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
SPRU 0.952 0.868 1.242 1.164 1.514 1.449 1.658 1.599 1.829 1.775
(6.33) (5.77) (5.52) (5.17) (4.82) (4.59) (4.07) (3.90) (3.70) (3.55)

Panel A2. Interacting with ILLIQ and LNME


Variable Month 2 Month 3 Month 4 Month 5 Month 6
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
SPRU 2.798 2.707 3.669 3.573 4.415 4.319 4.819 4.722 5.214 5.119
(6.72) (6.48) (5.69) (5.51) (5.18) (5.05) (4.44) (4.34) (4.02) (3.93)
SPRU×ILLIQ 0.337 0.290 0.428 0.383 0.468 0.431 0.424 0.392 0.434 0.403
(1.82) (1.57) (1.46) (1.30) (1.31) (1.20) (0.92) (0.84) (0.86) (0.79)
SPRU×LNME -0.382 -0.385 -0.499 -0.501 -0.605 -0.603 -0.659 -0.654 -0.718 -0.713
(-5.32) (-5.29) (-4.42) (-4.37) (-4.13) (-4.05) (-3.55) (-3.47) (-3.29) (-3.22)

Panel A3. Interacting with ILLIQ and CVRG


Variable Month 2 Month 3 Month 4 Month 5 Month 6
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
SPRU 1.307 1.214 1.636 1.532 1.817 1.724 1.770 1.673 1.879 1.787
(5.31) (4.92) (4.29) (4.02) (3.64) (3.47) (2.92) (2.76) (2.58) (2.42)
SPRU×ILLIQ 0.127 0.202 0.166 0.256 0.559 0.601 0.721 0.770 0.776 0.831
(0.34) (0.54) (0.30) (0.46) (0.73) (0.81) (0.77) (0.83) (0.64) (0.71)
SPRU×CVRG -0.486 -0.502 -0.561 -0.568 -0.589 -0.586 -0.530 -0.521 -0.561 -0.554
(-3.35) (-3.43) (-2.49) (-2.50) (-1.93) (-1.90) (-1.39) (-1.36) (-1.25) (-1.22)

Panel A4. Interacting with ILLIQ and INST


Variable Month 2 Month 3 Month 4 Month 5 Month 6
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
SPRU 1.136 1.030 1.298 1.199 1.396 1.306 1.459 1.377 1.420 1.342
(5.65) (5.05) (4.42) (4.01) (3.60) (3.30) (2.98) (2.79) (2.42) (2.26)
SPRU×ILLIQ 0.024 0.076 0.130 0.180 0.283 0.329 0.434 0.475 0.537 0.577
(0.13) (0.41) (0.47) (0.64) (0.81) (0.93) (0.96) (1.04) (1.08) (1.13)
SPRU×INST -1.128 -1.127 -1.088 -1.087 -1.068 -1.053 -0.980 -0.947 -0.728 -0.704
(-3.13) (-3.08) (-2.04) (-2.01) (-1.53) (-1.50) (-1.04) (-1.00) (-0.65) (-0.63)

xxix

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A11 – continued
Panel B. Liquidity shock measured by LIQCU
Panel B1. Without interaction terms
Variable Month 2 Month 3 Month 4 Month 5 Month 6
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQCU 0.222 0.159 0.226 0.168 0.200 0.145 0.226 0.170 0.225 0.165
(6.01) (4.14) (3.47) (2.48) (2.24) (1.58) (1.95) (1.44) (1.56) (1.11)

Panel B2. Interacting with ILLIQ and LNME


Variable Month 2 Month 3 Month 4 Month 5 Month 6
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQCU 0.320 0.337 0.331 0.345 0.485 0.499 0.478 0.500 0.582 0.605
(2.68) (2.79) (1.95) (2.02) (2.07) (2.13) (1.68) (1.73) (1.58) (1.65)
LIQCU×ILLIQ 0.046 0.040 0.010 0.003 0.029 0.021 0.020 0.013 0.062 0.056
(0.93) (0.80) (0.14) (0.05) (0.34) (0.25) (0.19) (0.13) (0.44) (0.40)
LIQCU×LNME -0.037 -0.047 -0.042 -0.051 -0.074 -0.083 -0.069 -0.080 -0.085 -0.097
(-1.65) (-2.07) (-1.68) (-1.89) (-1.31) (-1.59) (-1.31) (-1.50) (-1.23) (-1.40)

Panel B3. Interacting with ILLIQ and CVRG


Variable Month 2 Month 3 Month 4 Month 5 Month 6
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQCU 0.278 0.267 0.270 0.263 0.325 0.315 0.274 0.270 0.314 0.308
(3.55) (3.42) (2.06) (2.01) (1.90) (1.85) (1.30) (1.29) (1.25) (1.23)
LIQCU×ILLIQ 0.179 0.154 0.166 0.146 0.158 0.135 0.142 0.120 0.251 0.224
(1.35) (1.17) (0.82) (0.72) (0.70) (0.60) (0.42) (0.36) (0.62) (0.55)
LIQCU×CVRG -0.094 -0.109 -0.103 -0.119 -0.148 -0.164 -0.115 -0.134 -0.123 -0.144
(-2.23) (-2.55) (-1.49) (-1.72) (-1.63) (-1.79) (-1.00) (-1.17) (-0.84) (-0.98)

Panel B4. Interacting with ILLIQ and INST


Variable Month 2 Month 3 Month 4 Month 5 Month 6
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQCU 0.230 0.202 0.192 0.165 0.208 0.181 0.220 0.191 0.204 0.174
(3.68) (3.26) (2.37) (2.03) (1.93) (1.70) (1.39) (1.22) (1.12) (0.97)
LIQCU×ILLIQ 0.056 0.042 0.013 0.000 0.012 0.002 0.006 0.009 0.018 0.004
(1.12) (0.84) (0.20) (0.00) (0.14) (0.02) (0.06) (0.08) (0.13) (0.03)
LIQCU×INST -0.331 -0.348 -0.254 -0.265 -0.329 -0.338 -0.329 -0.338 -0.234 -0.247
(-2.09) (-2.19) (-1.22) (-1.26) (-1.28) (-1.33) (-0.87) (-0.89) (-0.54) (-0.58)

xxx

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A12
Bivariate Portfolios of Liquidity Shocks controlling for IVOLU and VOLDU: Two-month ahead
predictability

This table reports the equal-weighted returns and return differences in month t + 2 between High and
Low liquidity shock (SPRDU or LIQCU) quintile portfolios and the alphas after controlling for the
abnormal dollar trading volume (VOLDU) and the idiosyncratic volatility shock (IVOLU). Newey-
West t-statistics are given in parentheses.

Controlling for VOLDU Controlling for IVOLU


Quintile SPRDU LIQCU SPRDU LIQCU
1 (Low) 0.81 0.94 0.74 0.90
2 0.90 1.04 0.95 1.07
3 1.05 1.08 1.04 1.06
4 1.13 1.26 1.10 1.24
5 (High) 1.30 1.45 1.26 1.41
High - Low 0.49 0.51 0.52 0.51
(3.48) (4.22) (3.13) (4.19)
Alpha 0.50 0.44 0.57 0.54
(4.14) (4.81) (4.06) (5.21)

xxxi

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A13
Results based on quote midpoint returns

Monthly stock returns are calculated based on the quote midpoint, which is the average of the monthly closing national best bid and offer
(NBBO) and adjusted for dividends and stock splits. NBBO data is from the TAQ database. Panel A of this table reports the equal- and value-
weighted one-month ahead quote midpoint returns for decile portfolios formed on liquidity shocks (LIQU, SPRDU, and LIQCU), the return
differentials between High and Low liquidity shock deciles and the corresponding Fama-French (1993) alphas. Panel B reports the average
slope coefficients of liquidity shocks (Liq-shock) from the monthly Fama-MacBeth regressions of one-month ahead excess quote midpoint
returns on liquidity shock and all the other control variables listed in Table 6. Specifications (1) and (2) control for the GKM dummy variables
(GKMH and GKML ) and the abnormal dollar trading volume (VOLDU), respectively. For brevity, we suppress the average coefficients of the
control variables, which are available upon request. Newey-West t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

Panel A. One-month ahead returns for portfolios formed on liquidity shocks


LIQU portfolios SPRDU portfolios LIQCU portfolios
Decile Equal-weighted Value-weighted Equal-weighted Value-weighted Equal-weighted Value-weighted
1 (Low) 0.36 0.20 0.47 0.47 0.53 0.49

xxxii
2 0.68 0.61 0.91 0.56 0.80 0.56
3 0.87 0.74 0.90 0.70 1.02 1.00
4 1.05 1.01 0.82 0.71 1.05 0.93
5 0.99 0.90 0.86 0.72 1.00 0.83
6 0.99 0.99 0.97 0.74 1.06 1.04
7 0.98 1.11 0.90 0.74 1.02 0.88
8 1.12 1.17 0.91 1.03 1.06 0.95
9 1.27 1.12 1.12 1.12 1.11 0.98
10 (High) 1.63 1.43 1.34 1.19 1.37 1.13

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


High-Low 1.27 1.23 0.87 0.72 0.84 0.64
(5.29) (3.82) (3.92) (2.11) (4.40) (2.33)
Alpha 1.39 1.30 0.91 0.80 0.97 0.79
(6.32) (4.60) (4.64) (2.69) (6.30) (3.84)

Panel B. Monthly Fama-MacBeth regressions


Liquidity shock measured by LIQU Liquidity shock measured by SPRDU Liquidity shock measured by LIQCU
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQ-shock 0.287 0.274 0.674 0.593 0.161 0.131
(5.47) (5.07) (7.45) (6.49) (5.16) (4.57)
Table A14
Stock-level cross-sectional regressions after correcting for microstructure biases

This table performs modified Fama-MacBeth regressions following Asparouhova, Bessembinder, and
Kalcheva (2010). We estimate monthly weighted least squares (WLS) regressions, where each ob-
served return is weighted by the gross return on the same stock in the prior month. This table reports
the average slope coefficients and Newey-West t-statistics in parentheses. LIQU denotes the liquid-
ity shock, defined as the negative Amihud’s (2002) illiquidity measure (ILLIQ), demeaned using the
past 12-month ILLIQ as the mean. SPRDU is the shock to the monthly volume-weighted effective
relative spread (SPRD), calculated in the same fashion as LIQU. LIQCU denotes the conditional mea-
sure of liquidity shock, defined as the negative of the difference between the realized ILLIQ and the
conditional mean of ILLIQ in the month estimated under the assumption that the conditional mean
of ILLIQ follows an ARMA(1,1) process. BETA, LNME, and LNBM denote the market beta, the
natural logarithm of the market capitalization, and the natural logarithm of the book-to-market equity
ratio, respectively. MOM is the momentum return. REV is the short-term reversal. COSKEW and
IVOL are the co-skewness and idiosyncratic volatility, respectively. MAX denotes the maximum daily
return in a month. DISP measures the analyst earnings forecast dispersion. SUE is the standardized
unexpected earnings. CVILLIQ is the coefficient of variation in the Amihud’s illiquidity measure.
SDTURN denotes the standard deviation of the monthly turnover over the past 12 months. PS is Pas-
tor and Stambaugh’s (2003) liquidity beta. BETA1–BETA4 are Acharya and Pedersen’s (2005) four
liquidity betas. SADKAF and SADKAV are the loadings on the fixed and the variable components of
Sadka’s (2006) liquidity factor. GKMH and GKML denote the high- and low-volume dummy variables.
VOLDU measures the abnormal dollar trading volume.

xxxiii

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472


Table A14 – continued
Variable LIQU SPRDU LIQCU
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
LIQ-Shock 0.212 0.181 0.672 0.583 0.184 0.148
(4.59) (4.00) (7.12) (6.63) (5.31) (3.51)
BETA 0.169 0.189 0.265 0.283 0.187 0.204
(1.52) (1.70) (2.11) (2.26) (1.67) (1.83)
LNME -0.060 -0.091 -0.069 -0.085 -0.038 -0.083
(-1.82) (-2.74) (-1.65) (-2.05) (-1.17) (-2.49)
LNBM 0.150 0.134 0.104 0.096 0.158 0.136
(1.90) (1.74) (1.22) (1.13) (2.05) (1.77)
MOM 0.006 0.003 0.004 0.002 0.005 0.003
(3.57) (2.25) (2.20) (1.30) (3.45) (2.25)
REV -0.032 -0.049 -0.027 -0.041 -0.033 -0.048
(-6.25) (-9.35) (-5.15) (-8.02) (-6.27) (-9.11)
COSKEW 0.100 0.097 0.748 0.719 0.263 0.247
(0.12) (0.12) (0.87) (0.85) (0.33) (0.31)
IVOL -0.287 -0.363 -0.210 -0.301 -0.258 -0.337
(-5.74) (-7.11) (-3.38) (-4.63) (-4.93) (-6.43)
MAX -0.016 -0.004 -0.016 -0.008 -0.012 -0.002
(-1.62) (-0.40) (-1.36) (-0.66) (-1.19) (-0.16)
DISP -0.072 -0.065 -0.088 -0.082 -0.082 -0.076
(-2.26) (-2.04) (-2.32) (-2.17) (-2.53) (-2.36)
SPRD 0.013 0.064
(0.18) (0.91)
ILLIQ 0.060 0.039 0.104 0.089 0.080 0.062
(2.21) (1.56) (3.39) (3.05) (3.04) (2.47)
CVILLIQ 0.106 0.036 0.095 0.021 0.121 0.046
(1.74) (0.59) (1.40) (0.30) (1.89) (0.72)
SDTURN -0.252 -0.204 -0.233 -0.170 -0.242 -0.189
(-2.83) (-2.33) (-2.52) (-1.86) (-2.68) (-2.14)
PS 0.002 0.001 0.002 0.001 0.002 0.002
(1.37) (1.25) (1.12) (1.03) (1.53) (1.40)
BETA1 0.142 0.139 0.185 0.187 0.100 0.098
(0.77) (0.77) (0.87) (0.89) (0.51) (0.51)
BETA2 -4.852 -4.048 0.131 -0.081 -5.281 -3.756
(-1.26) (-1.07) (0.03) (-0.02) (-1.20) (-0.88)
BETA3 1.494 1.394 3.764 3.633 1.913 1.745
(1.13) (1.07) (3.02) (2.95) (1.34) (1.23)
BETA4 -0.378 -0.391 -0.392 -0.393 -0.637 -0.640
(-1.10) (-1.14) (-0.89) (-0.91) (-1.52) (-1.54)
SADKAF -0.003 -0.003 0.001 0.001 -0.003 -0.003
(-0.86) (-0.91) (0.26) (0.26) (-0.84) (-0.85)
SADKAV -0.015 -0.015 -0.010 -0.009 -0.015 -0.014
(-1.70) (-1.69) (-0.97) (-0.92) (-1.60) (-1.55)
SUE 0.279 0.259 0.255 0.233 0.280 0.260
(12.70) (11.85) (10.31) (9.48) (12.80) (11.99)
GKMH 0.556 0.516 0.550
(5.78) (4.75) (5.39)
GKML -0.086 -0.156 -0.095
(-1.34) (-2.05) (-1.39)
VOLDU 0.201 0.181 0.195
(9.10) (7.10) (8.72)
xxxiv

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2055472

You might also like