Economic Incentives Ideas & The End of Cold WR

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 24

Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War:

Gorbachev and German Unification

Tuomas Forsberg

Journal of Cold War Studies, Volume 7, Number 2, Spring 2005, pp.


142-164 (Article)

Published by The MIT Press

For additional information about this article


https://muse.jhu.edu/article/181900

For content related to this article


https://muse.jhu.edu/related_content?type=article&id=181900
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War
Forsberg

Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the


Cold War: Gorbachev and German Uniªcation

A
mong various explanations of the end of the Cold War, Soviet
economic weakness relative to the West has been the factor most often cited.1
It is widely assumed that Mikhail Gorbachev had to yield in negotiations with
the West because the Soviet economy was bankrupt. Often repeated is the
view that Gorbachev “sold” East Germany to West Germany or, alternatively,
that Helmut Kohl “bought” German uniªcation from Gorbachev. In other
words, the “price” for Gorbachev’s acceptance of German uniªcation and
Germany’s membership in the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO)
was the food aid and loans that Kohl provided to Gorbachev in 1990.2
At ªrst glance, German economic aid to the Soviet Union seems to ªt a
materialist liberal explanation that runs against realist assertions of the impor-
tance of military power and against the constructivists’ emphasis on new
ideas, learning, and identity change. Yet, both realists and constructivists can
incorporate the role of German economic aid into their theoretical frame-
works. Realists can claim that the efªcacy of the economic incentives de-

1. See especially Stephen Brooks and William C. Wohlforth, “Power, Globalization and the End of the
Cold War,” International Security, Vol. 25, No. 3 (Winter 2000/2001), pp. 5–53; and Celeste
Wallander, “Western Policy and the Demise of the Soviet Union,” Journal of Cold War Studies, Vol. 5,
No. 4 (Fall 2003), pp. 137–177. For related debate, see Robert English, “Power, Ideas and New Evi-
dence on the Cold War’s End: A Reply to Brooks and Wohlforth,” International Security, Vol. 26,
No. 4 (Spring 2002), pp. 70–92; Stephen Brooks and William C. Wohlforth, “From Old Thinking to
New Thinking in Qualitative Research,” International Security, Vol. 26, No. 4 (Spring 2002), pp. 93–
111; Margarita Petrova, “The End of the Cold War: A Battle or Bridging Ground between Rationalist
and Ideational Approaches in International Relations,” European Journal of International Relations,
Vol. 9, No. 1 (March 2003), pp. 115–163; and Jeremi Suri, “Explaining the End of the Cold War: A
New Historical Consensus,” Journal of Cold War Studies, Vol. 4, No. 4 (Fall 2002), pp. 60–92.
2. See, for example, Hélène Seppain, “European Integration, German Uniªcation and the Economics
of Ostpolitik,” in Heinz Kurz, ed., United Germany and the New Europe (Aldershot, UK: Edward
Elgar, 1993), pp. 113–127; Randall Newnham, “The Price of German Unity: The Role of Economic
Aid in the German-Soviet Negotiations,” German Studies Review, Vol. 22, No. 3 (October 1999),
pp. 421–446; and Randall E. Newnham, “More Flies with Honey: Positive Economic Linkage in Ger-
man Ostpolitik from Bismarck to Kohl,” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 44, No. 1 (March 2000),
pp. 73–96.
Journal of Cold War Studies
Vol. 7, No. 2, Spring 2005, pp. 142–164
© 2005 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute
of Technology

142
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

pended on the underlying power structure, deªned primarily in military


terms, and constructivists can argue that the economic aid was a means to
communicate changing identities. In other words, to see the economic aid
merely as a “purchase” is to take a narrow view of the possible role of eco-
nomic incentives.
In this article, I will elaborate on the constructivist perspective. By focus-
ing on the role of economic incentives, I will demonstrate the crucial role of
ideas in shaping the “power” of material factors. My aim in this article is not
to assert that German economic aid alone was a key to German uniªcation
and consequently to the end of the Cold War,3 but that it was important
enough to merit special attention. Soviet acceptance of German uniªcation
and of German membership in NATO can be seen as the culmination of the
rapprochement leading to the end of the Cold War. To assess the relative im-
portance of different factors contributing to the end of the Cold War, it is
necessary to analyze concrete decisions. It is one thing to acknowledge that
material constraints “forced” the Soviet Union to change the basic course of
its foreign policy, but it is quite another to explain crucial decisions. Regard-
ing German uniªcation and, in particular, the acceptance of uniªed Ger-
many’s membership in NATO, Gorbachev had a choice: he could have acted
otherwise. At the time, both German and U.S. decision-makers were unsure
about what would happen if Gorbachev agreed to uniªcation only on the
condition of neutrality.4 After all, explanatory puzzles remain in the main-
stream realist account of the solution to the German question. If Soviet de-
cline drove Gorbachev’s foreign policy concessions, why did the Germans of-
fer Moscow so many expensive economic incentives?
Although the role of economic incentives is often downplayed by the key
decision-makers of the time—not least by Gorbachev himself—other former
ofªcials stress that “money” is what forced the Soviet Union to abandon East
Germany.5 Most scholars who have studied the case in greater detail accord
some importance to the economic dimension.6 Even though it was not neces-

3. Kevin Clements, “Carrots Were More Important than Sticks in Ending the Cold War,” in Ralph
Summy and Michael E. Salla, eds., Why the Cold War Ended: A Range of Interpretations (Westport, CT:
Greenwood Press, 1995), ch. 16. On the effectiveness of positive inºuence methods see, for example,
David Baldwin, Paradoxes of Power (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1989); and Eileen Crumm, “The Value
of Economic Incentives in International Politics,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 32, No. 3 (August
1995), pp. 313–330.
4. See, for example, Jack F. Matlock Jr., Autopsy on an Empire: The American Ambassador’s Account of
the Collapse of the Soviet Union (New York: Random House, 1995), p. 387; and William C.
Wohlforth, ed., Cold War Endgame: Oral History, Analysis, Debates (University Park, PA: Pennsylvania
States University Press, 2003), ch. 2.
5. This includes the former Soviet Foreign Ministry ofªcial Sergei Tarasenko. See Wohlforth, ed., Cold
War Endgame, p. 70.
6. Philip Zelikow and Condoleezza Rice name thirteen variables that were part of the diplomatic pro-

143
Forsberg

sarily the overriding factor, it is seen as an essential part of the causal chain
that led to the end of the Cold War. Yet, as William Wohlforth and Nina
Tannenwald stress in the introduction to this special issue of the journal, his-
torical research showing that something was “important” does not, as such,
refute or conªrm any theory.7 The crucial question is what the role of eco-
nomic incentives was in the end of the Cold War. Even if we agree that eco-
nomic aid mattered, the second and more fundamental question is, how did it
matter? This question has so far been given only scant attention in the theo-
retical literature.
The constructivist emphasis on the importance of ideas does not dimin-
ish even if the claim about the relationship between economic incentives and
identity change is shown to be wrong. Ideas matter in the typical realist and
liberal interpretations because the role of economic aid depends on its mean-
ing in a wider interpretive framework. Brute material forces explain relatively
little in the social world. A simple act such as a “purchase” involves normative

cess leading to Gorbachev’s acceptance of German uniªcation and its membership in NATO. Limited
ªnancial aid from Germany and promises to develop ties with and deliver assistance to Russia are
among them. Philip Zelikow and Condoleezza Rice, Germany Uniªed and Europe Transformed: A
Study in Statecraft, 2nd ed. (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1997), p. viii. Rafael
Biermann, in turn, lists seven motives for Gorbachev’s concession. One of them is the foundation of a
new German Russian partnership, and in Biermann’s view the German “Jumbo-Credit” in May 1990
and the payment of billions toward the withdrawal of the troops showed that the Germans were pre-
pared to help Gorbachev. Rafael Biermann, Zwischen Kreml und Kanzleramt: Wie Moskau mit der
deutschen Einheit rang (Paderborn, Germany: Schöningh, 1997), p. 781. In the view of Stephan
Bierling, “uniªcation would not have been achievable without the large economic concessions of the
Federal Republic government.” See Stephan Bierling, Wirtschaftshilfe für Moskau: Motive und
Strategien der Bundesrepublik Deutschland und der USA 1990–1996 (Paderborn, Germany: Schöningh,
1998), p. 327. Angela Stent contends that “economic factors, though not decisive, certainly
inºuenced Gorbachev and Shevardnadze.” Angela Stent, Russia and Germany Reborn: Uniªcation, the
Soviet Collapse and the New Europe (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1999), p. 146. James
Davis and William Wohlforth discuss material incentives, ideas, domestic politics, and leadership as
four generic ways of explaining German uniªcation. They argue that at the time of crucial negotia-
tions both East Berlin and Moscow were seeking increased ªnancial favors from Bonn and that this re-
duced their bargaining leverage. James W. Davis and William C. Wohlforth “German Uniªcation,” in
Richard K. Herrmann and Richard Ned Lebow, eds., Ending the Cold War: Interpretations, Causation,
and the Study of International Relations (New York: Palgrave MacMillan, 2004), p. 137. On the diplo-
macy of German uniªcation, see also Alexander von Plato, Die Vereinigung Deutschlands—Ein
weltpolitisches Machtspiel: Bush, Kohl Gorbatschow und die geheimen Moskauer Protokolle (Berlin: Ch.
Links, 2002); Werner Weidenfeld, Aussenpolitik für die deutsche Einheit: Die Entscheidungsjahre 1989/
90 (Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt, 1998); Hans-Hermann Hertle, Der Fall der Mauer: Die
unbeabsichtigte Selbstauºösung des SED-Staates, 2nd ed. (Opladen, Germany: Westdeutscher Verlag,
1999); and Charles S. Maier, Dissolution: The Crisis of Communism and the End of East Germany
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997).
7. See also Colin Elman and Miriam Fendius Elman, eds., Bridges and Boundaries: Historians, Political
Scientists and the Study of International Relations (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2001); William C.
Wohlforth, “Reality Check: Revising Theories of International Politics in Response to the End of the
Cold War,” World Politics, Vol. 50, No. 4 (July 1998), pp. 650–680; and Caroline Kennedy-Pipe, “In-
ternational History and International Relations Theory: A Dialogue beyond the Cold War,” Interna-
tional Affairs, Vol. 76, No.4 (October 2000), pp. 741–754.

144
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

and interpretative conceptualization. In other words, what are seen as power


resources and how these resources are converted into actual inºuence depend
partly on ideational structures: power and interests are not idea-free baselines.
Constructivist theorizing not only reinterprets the realist and liberal explana-
tions by showing their dependence on ideational constructions; it also adds
a separate explanation of the events that differs from the realist and liberal
explanations by enlarging the framework of possible interpretations.8
In bringing the constructivist position to bear, one must show the differ-
ence ideas make. A constructivist analysis of the economic incentives
Germany provided to the Soviet Union is important for three reasons. First,
the economic incentives were signiªcant as trust-building measures. This in-
terpretation gives only partial support to the theses of “the West won the Cold
War” and the “rational exchange of quid pro quo.” Neither Soviet weakness
nor the existence of mutual beneªts alone can account for the deal. The par-
ties needed to establish a shared understanding of a future partnership for the
economic incentives to work.
Second, the analysis will contribute to the application of constructivist
theory as it has developed within the ªeld of international relations (IR). The
question of achieving political change through changes in identities lies at the
core of the constructivist theory. For many constructivists the end of the
Cold War is a primary example of such an interaction process. But
constructivist explanations of the end of the Cold War have not attributed
much importance to economic aid even though gifts and rewarding can be
seen as basic means through which social relationships are formed and trans-
formed.9

8. Alexander Wendt, Social Theory of International Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press,
1999). See also Wendt’s reply to his critics, Alexander Wendt, “On the Via Media: A Response to the
Critics,” Review of International Studies, Vol. 26, No. 1 (January 2000), pp. 165–180. On the
constructivist view of the role of ideas, see also Ronald Jepperson, Peter Katzenstein, and Alexander
Wendt, “Norms, Identity and Culture in National Security,” in Peter Katzenstein, ed., The Culture of
National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics (New York: Columbia University Press, 1996),
ch. 2; Emanuel Adler, “Seizing the Middle Ground: Constructivism in World Politics,” European Jour-
nal of International Relations, Vol. 3, No. 3 (September 1997), pp. 319–363; Jeffrey Checkel, “The
Constructivist Turn in International Relations Theory,” World Politics, Vol. 50, No. 2 (January 1998),
pp. 324–348; Ted Hopf, “The Promise of Constructivism in International Relations Theory,” Interna-
tional Security, Vol. 23, No. 1 (Summer 1998), pp. 171–200; and Stefano Guzzini, “A Reconstruction
of Constructivism in International Relations,” European Journal of International Relations, Vol. 6,
No. 2 (June 2000), pp. 147–182.
9. For example, Thomas Risse, who defends constructivist theory and emphasizes the role of commu-
nication, argues that “there is no evidence that the German loan guarantee was crucial in the Soviet de-
cision to accept rapid uniªcation in NATO.” Yet, he conceptualizes the economic incentives as “ex-
change for cash” or “bribery” and not from the perspective of constructivist theory. Thomas Risse,
“The Cold War’s Endgame and German Uniªcation,” International Security, Vol. 21, No. 4 (Spring
1997), pp. 159–185. Andrew Bennett, who emphatically but critically reviews Risse’s account of trust

145
Forsberg

Third, and more generally, the theoretical framework developed here will
offer a broader understanding of the mechanisms of change in international
relations and help to reªne our understanding of economic aid policies. It will
show how the inºuence of economic power depends on the underlying and
attached ideational constructions, and how the practices themselves shape
these constructions. To gain a more comprehensive understanding of reward-
ing practices in international politics, we need to go beyond exchange theories
based on rational choice.
I will justify my claims about the importance of ideas in three steps: ªrst,
by making them theoretically plausible; second, by analyzing the views of par-
ticipants and their behavior; and third, by testing them on the basis of a
counterfactual analysis.10 Accordingly, in the ªrst section below I distinguish
between economic incentives as face-savers, payments, and signals and show
in theoretical terms why, on matters dealing with national security between
potential enemies, economic incentives are likely to be the most effective
mechanism for communicating signals about changing interests and identi-
ties. The second section examines the evidence on the case itself, showing how
the power of economic incentives in the negotiations over German uniªcat-
ion depended less on their material value than on their symbolic value. The
evidence suggests that the ability of economic incentives to assure Gorbachev
that there was a prospect of true partnership with Germany in particular and
the West in general was more important than their direct economic utility.
The third section presents a counterfactual comparative analysis of Japan’s un-
successful attempts to link economic aid to the return of the four disputed
Kurile Islands. The case is crucial because any analysis that tries to explain
why the Cold War ended in Europe should be able to account why the stale-
mate continued in East Asia. With due regard for the important differences
between the two cases, the comparison effectively illustrates the critical role of
ideas in determining the effect of economic incentives on behavior and thus
on the disparate outcomes.

building with the help of cognitive theories, accepts his view that the economic incentives were mere
sweeteners. Andrew O. Bennett, “Trust Bursting Out All Over: The Soviet Side of German Uniªca-
tion,” in Wohlforth, ed., Cold War Endgame, p. 187. For constructivist explanations of the end of the
Cold War, see also Brian Federking, “Resolving Security Dilemmas: A Constructivist Explanation of
the Cold War,” International Politics, Vol. 35, No. 2 (June 1998), pp. 207–232. On the symbolic as-
pects of rewarding and gift giving, see Helmuth Berking, Sociology of Giving (London: Sage, 1999).
10. For methodological discussion of ideas-as-causes, see Albert Yee, “The Causal Effects of Ideas in
Policies,” International Organization, Vol. 50, No. 1 (Winter 1996), pp. 69–108; Jeffrey Checkel and
Andrew Moravcsik, “A Constructivist Research Program in EU Studies?” European Union Politics,
Vol. 2, No. 2 (June 2001), pp. 219–249; and Craig Parsons, “Showing Ideas as Causes: The Origins of
the European Union,” International Organization, Vol. 56, No. 1 (Winter 2002), pp. 47–84.

146
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

How Ideas Construct Economic Incentives

Economic power depends on ideas—not only conceptions of what is valuable


but also rules and norms that tell how items of value can be exchanged. For
example, the inºuence of economic aid on donors and recipients depends on
whether they view the aid as a face-saver, a payment, or a signal. In the ªrst
conception (i.e., aid as a face-saver), economic aid is effective only if enough
military power supports it; in the second, economic aid is itself the key vehi-
cle; and in the third, economic aid helps because it establishes trust and a sense
of partnership between the parties. Although each of these conceptions is pri-
marily associated with a major school of IR theory, each can also be understood
from multiple perspectives. The ªrst two conceptions converge in generating
the expectation that, on national security issues involving potential enemies,
economic aid is not a perfect face-saver, and the possibilities of using eco-
nomic aid as a form of payment are severely restricted. Delivering economic
aid is, by contrast, one means that an adversary may use to signal partnership,
though whether it actually transforms a relationship is always questionable.

Economic Incentives as Face-Savers


From the realist perspective the general efªcacy of coercive methods does not
mean that positive means of inºuence are futile. They may play an important
role when combined with coercive methods. For example, Arnold Wolfers ar-
gued that rewarding methods can be useful in some situations but are not
generally as effective as coercive power. The situations that favor positive in-
ducements, he claimed, are rare and are related to questions of minor impor-
tance. In Wolfers’s view, changes are especially difªcult to achieve on ques-
tions related to territory and national security. Wolfers conceded, however,
that in cooperative contexts, especially when demands are made between
friendly countries, non-coercive inºuence can outstrip coercive power.11 Simi-
larly, when addressing the potential role of economic incentives vis-à-vis the
Soviet Union, William Kaufmann was skeptical of their efªcacy but con-
cluded that we are mistaken if we assume that concessions are not worth mak-
ing at all. “In conjunction with our other weapons,” he argued, “they can give
us reasonably powerful means of inºuencing the opponent’s calculations of
cost and risk.”12

11. Arnold Wolfers, “Power and Inºuence: The Means of Foreign Policy,” in Arnold Wolfers, Discord
and Collaboration: Essays on International Politics (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1962), p. 107–108.
12. William Kaufmann, “The Requirements of Deterrence,” in William Kaufmann, ed., Military Pol-
icy and National Security (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1956), p. 32.

147
Forsberg

Other realists also assume that rewarding modes of inºuence do not work
in crisis situations where some important issues are at stake. Glenn Snyder
and Paul Diesing maintain that a distinctive feature of crisis bargaining is the
prominence of coercion. This is so, they argue, because crises usually develop
around issues that have a redistributive character, and the resister is likely to
stand ªrm because he has something to lose.13 In those cases, exchange is im-
possible and economic incentives can work only if they are backed by military
power. As E. H. Carr wrote, “if dollars were a humanitarian substitute for bul-
lets, they could and would be reinforced by bullets in the case of political
need.”14
What is the purpose of economic rewards from a realist perspective? The
importance of positive sanctions, in the realist conception, depends on their
use as face-saving gestures.15 Face-savers are needed because the country that
backs down needs to show its resolve. Face-savers are not primary causes in
the achievement of the resolution but are important in facilitating agreement
under coercion.16 According to Snyder and Diesing, the winner provides face-
savers to the loser “not so much because he has to, to gain the ªnal victory, but
to avoid unnecessary embitterment of future relations with the adversary.”17
In situations in which a solution is likely to be achieved anyway, positive sanc-
tions may smooth the way for an honorable retreat. In a situation in which
the outcome would otherwise be seen as a relationship of superior power,
face-savers transmit an image of a more balanced relationship. Although
the overwhelming power of the opponent would be a rational reason to
yield, face-savers are needed to uphold the reputation of the other party.
The upshot is that face-savers are special kinds of rewards because of their
symbolic value.
In sum, for realists, economic incentives can be effective when they are
backed by coercive force. Under the rationalist version of realism, economic
promises and rewards give an additional reason to yield. Under the con-
structivist version of realism, these rewards help to overcome the problems as-
sociated with the norm requiring states to be resolute.

13. Glenn Snyder and Paul Diesing, Conºict among Nations: Bargaining, Decision Making, and System
Structure in International Crises (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1977), p. 26.
14. E. H. Carr, Twenty Years’ Crisis, 1919–1939 (London: MacMillan, 1964), p. 126.
15. On face-saving, see Bert Brown, “Face-Saving and Face-Restoration in Negotiation,” in Daniel
Druckmann, ed., Negotiations: Social-Psychological Perspectives (London: Sage 1977), pp. 275–299.
16. Roger Fisher, William Ury, and Bruce Patton, Getting to Yes: Negotiating an Agreement without
Giving In, 2nd ed. (London: Business Books, 1991), p. 29.
17. Snyder and Diesing, Conºict among Nations, p. 256.

148
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

Economic Incentives as Payments


The second possibility is to see economic incentives simply as payments or,
more broadly, as elements of a reciprocal exchange. No coercion is needed in
this case because exchange is based on mutual beneªt. According to liberal
logic, rewarding should be effective if the offers are more attractive than the
alternatives. Although the degree to which cooperation is “voluntary” depends
on the range of alternatives, liberals argue that the best way to inºuence the
other side is to increase the number of alternatives rather than restrict them.
Thus, from the liberal perspective, anything can be exchanged when there is a
mutuality of interests, and the greatest problem liberals see is how to adjust
the values associated with the objects to be exchanged so that the offers will be
credible. Klaus Knorr writes: “Whether or not a reward will be offered and
accepted depends on each party’s estimate of whether the exchange is advanta-
geous and also on the actor’s estimate of whether the expected beneªt will
actually be forthcoming.”18 Gerald Sorokin concurs: “States are more likely to
accept rewards when the rewards are valuable and the demands are small.”19
No doubt, many exchanges between states are characterized in these
terms. According to Robert Keohane, for example, speciªc reciprocity, which
refers to situations in which certain partners exchange items of equivalent
value speciªed in terms of the rights and duties of particular actors, plays an
important role in world politics.20 Yet, the international system is not a mar-
ket in which political issues can be traded the way equities are on the stock ex-
change. As Keohane notes, the problem for speciªc reciprocity is that the
measurement of equivalence is often impossible to carry out without market
prices that would show whether an exchange involves equivalent values.
Therefore, speciªc reciprocity is not a sure-ªre recipe for promoting coopera-
tion.21 This limitation decreases the scope of exchange despite the existence of
mutual beneªt.
To remedy this problem, liberals tend to stress diffuse reciprocity, which
means that the exchange does not have to be as rigorously framed as in the
case of speciªc reciprocity.22 Diffuse reciprocity makes multilateral arrange-

18. Klaus Knorr, Power and Wealth: The Political Economy of International Power (New York: Basic
Books, 1971), p. 21.
19. Gerald Sorokin, “The Role of Rewards in Conºictual International Interactions,” Journal of
Conºict Resolution, Vol. 40, No. 4 (December 1996), p. 676.
20. Robert Keohane, “Reciprocity in International Relations,” in Robert Keohane, International Insti-
tutions and State Power (Boulder: Westview Press, 1988), p. 137.
21. Ibid.
22. Ibid. Keohane draws on the difference between economic and social exchange as outlined in Peter
Blau, Exchange and Power in Social Life (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1964).

149
Forsberg

ments viable, and it allows for a time lag in the reciprocation. Overall, the
idea of diffuse reciprocity is that people do not keep track of the inputs of oth-
ers. But there is no claim that such reciprocal relationships necessarily evoke a
desire to increase others’ welfare.
Diffuse reciprocity becomes possible if people are following the rule of
reciprocity.23 The parties are not calculating whether it is better to reward or
coerce; it is a matter of obligation rather than rational choice. Reciprocity fos-
ters cooperation because it diminishes the need to show resolve.24 Yet, people
do not mechanically reciprocate conciliation and defection. Their decision is
mediated by their analysis of what the other side did and why it did it. As
Deborah Larson has contended, perceived motives are critical in determining
whether states reciprocate concessions.25 The players may not agree on
whether an act is positive or negative or on how to match the acts of others.26
Although reciprocity can be seen as a powerful norm that is recognized almost
universally, its mere existence does not necessarily lead to cooperation if the
relationship is perceived as competitive.27
In short, reciprocal exchange can in many circumstances work as a strat-
egy for achieving objectives in world politics. Normally the logic of exchange
is strong enough to spark substantial cooperation, but a hostile environment
can cause immense problems for any substantial deals; it is especially unlikely
that adversaries would be able to exchange issues that are closely linked to
national security.

Economic Incentives as Communication


Economic incentives can also be seen as forms of communication in a rela-
tionship that itself can be reproduced and transformed by strategic moves,
such as giving economic aid or threatening the use of force. Noel Kaplowitz
stresses the importance of taking into account “not only the inºuence of an
actor’s strategy upon the adversary’s tangible costs and beneªts, but also upon
his self-images and enemy perceptions, all of which feed back into and deter-

23. Deborah Welch Larson, “The Psychology of Reciprocity in International Relations,” Negotiation
Journal, Vol. 4, No. 3 (July 1988), pp. 281–301.
24. Robert Jervis, “Security Regimes,” in Stephen Krasner, ed., International Regimes (Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1983), pp. 182–183.
25. Larson, “The Psychology of Reciprocity in International Relations,” p. 282.
26. Robert Jervis, “Realism, Game Theory, and Cooperation,” World Politics, Vol. 40, No. 3 (April
1988), pp. 317–349.
27. See, for example, Juan Carlos Martinez Coll and Jack Hirshleifer, “The Limits of Reciprocity: So-
lution Concepts and Reactive Strategies in Evolutionary Equilibrium Models,” Rationality and Society,
Vol. 3, No. 1 (January 1991), pp. 35–64.

150
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

mine his strategy.”28 In Han Dorussen’s words, “the value of incentives is their
ability to alter the preferences and perceptions of the recipients as well as the
sender. These psychological beneªts go beyond the speciªc bargain or quid
pro quo but are often the real objectives of the states involved.”29 Similarly,
James Davis concludes that “through the iterative process of signaling—of
threatening and promising—actors’ goals and interests are formed and trans-
formed.”30
Because relationships are formed by interaction, the parties’ interests can
be crucially shaped by it. Constructivists like Alexander Wendt have sug-
gested that practices of rewarding can reduce the competitive dimension of
identities, allowing for greater cooperation.31 Wendt’s idea is often likened to
Charles Osgood’s strategy of Graduated Reciprocation in Tension-Reduction
(GRIT),32 which, as Osgood put it, amounts to “the application of the
Golden rule on an international scale.”33 Through positive unilateral acts, this
approach tries to reduce international tension and foster an atmosphere of
mutual trust that will facilitate negotiations on critical political and military
issues. The basic point is that the unilateral initiatives must be continued over
a considerable period, regardless of the lack of immediate reciprocation or the
occurrence of adverse events, in order to achieve the assumed ends.34
It follows that the efªcacy of economic incentives as a form of communi-
cation differs from their efªcacy as a face-saver or a payment. In particular, the
amount of the inducements as such is not as important as their quality. Be-
cause fast responses show best the sincerity of the actor, they make coopera-
tion more likely. Unconditional rewards are better because otherwise the sig-
nals are interpreted as part of an offensive posture. The rewards must be
unambiguous—big enough to be substantial but perhaps not so big that the
opponent would become suspicious. As C. R. Mitchell has remarked, “the

28. Noel Kaplowitz, “Psychopolitical Dimensions of International Relations: The Reciprocal Effects
of Conºict Strategies,” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 28, No. 3 (December 1984), pp. 373–406.
29. Han Dorussen, “Mixing Carrots with Sticks: Evaluating the Effectiveness of Positive Incentives,”
Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 38, No. 2 (May 2001), pp. 251–262.
30. James Davis Jr., Threats and Promises: The Pursuit of International Inºuence (Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 2000), p. 159.
31. Alexander Wendt, “Anarchy Is What States Make of It,” International Organization, Vol. 46, No. 2
(Spring 1992), p. 422. See also Friedrich Kratochwil, International Order and Foreign Policy: A Theo-
retical Sketch of Post-War Politics (Boulder: Westview Press, 1978), pp. 116–117.
32. Wendt himself regards his position as a constructivist reading of Axelrod’s tit-for-tat theory. See
Wendt, “Identity and Structural Change in International Politics,” in Yosef Lapid and Friedrich
Kratochwil, eds., The Return of Culture and Identity in IR Theory (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 1996),
p. 57.
33. Charles Osgood, An Alternative to War or Surrender (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1962).
34. Ibid., p. 103.

151
Forsberg

more an action renders an initiator obviously vulnerable, or places him in a


risky situation vis-à-vis the target, the more likely that action will be seen as
genuinely conciliatory by the target.”35
When used as signals, economic incentives may help change not only the
interests but also the identities of the other side. They can develop trust and
goodwill between the actors so that the interests of the other are taken into ac-
count. Economic incentives can thus break the interpretative framework of
mutual hostility and establish a cooperative relationship through empathy
and mutual role-taking.
These different conceptualizations of economic aid are not mutually ex-
clusive. Although the most relevant actors deªning the nature of the aid are
the ones directly involved in the process as decision-makers, other partici-
pants, observers, and domestic audiences may challenge and resist the original
interpretations. Even the decision-makers themselves can have overlapping
and almost contradictory views of the process. Hence, looking at the verbal
narratives and assessments of the process is not enough. A solid interpretation
must be sustained by evidence of corresponding behavior. If the economic in-
centives serve as face-savers, coercion should take place; if they are payments,
bargaining should follow; and if they are signals of a closer partnership, dis-
cussion about the changing nature of the relationship should occur. In the
case of German uniªcation the empirical question is whether Germany’s eco-
nomic incentives to the Soviet Union were face-savers in circumstances in
which the outcome was already a fait accompli, payments for a balanced deal,
or signals that helped amalgamate understandings toward partnership.

Economic Incentives in German Unification

During the eleven months from the opening of the Berlin wall in November
1989 to the signing of the two-plus-four agreement in September 1990, West
Germany used economic incentives several times in its relations with the
Soviet Union. From the beginning Kohl assured Gorbachev that he was will-
ing to support the economic reforms of the Soviet Union. In February 1990,
Bonn quickly decided to grant food aid worth 220 million Deutschmarks
(DM) to relieve the shortage in the Soviet Union. In ªnancial negotiations
between Bonn and Moscow in the spring of 1990, the West Germans pledged
to guarantee that the Soviet Union would not lose anything because of uni-
ªcation. A payment of 1.25 billion DM was agreed to cover the costs of

35. C. R. Mitchell, “A Willingness to Talk: Conciliatory Gestures and De-escalation,” Negotiation


Journal, Vol. 7, No. 4 (October 1991), pp. 405–429.

152
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

Soviet troops in the German Democratic Republic (GDR). In May 1990,


Shevardnadze secretly asked whether the West German government would
provide guarantees for a commercial loan of 20 billion DM. The German
government reacted immediately, and West German banks granted the Soviet
Union a loan of 5 billion DM, which was delivered in July. In September
1990, Gorbachev presented a bill of 35 billion DM to the Germans and de-
manded economic assistance. Kohl was reluctant to contribute the amount
Gorbachev proposed, but he agreed to a compromise that would oblige
Germany to pay 12 billion DM plus an interest-free credit of 3 billion DM. A
smaller part of that assistance was used as compensation to the Soviet Union
for its troops stationed in the GDR, as well as for their transportation and vo-
cational rehabilitation. The German government allocated 8 billion DM for a
civilian housing program in the Soviet Union.36
If Germany was able to inºuence the Soviet Union by means of economic
incentives, how did this really happen? For realists, the signiªcance of eco-
nomic incentives lies not in their ultimate power in ensuring the success of
negotiations but in their role as face-savers. Some observers interpreted Kohl’s
economic promises and rewards to Gorbachev in this vein. James Goldgeier
has argued that “despite the West’s overwhelming victory in the negotiations
over Germany’s future, the United States and Germany did see the need to of-
fer Gorbachev a face-saver for the capitulation.” German economic assistance,
according to Goldgeier, served this function.37
Yet, the case of German uniªcation revealed a paradox in the use of eco-
nomic rewards for face-saving purposes. Receiving economic beneªts instead
of military concessions is seen as dishonorable. For Gorbachev the core prob-
lem was that he not be regarded as selling anything, because such a perception
would badly damage his domestic reputation and make the Soviet Union
appear weak.
This paradox aside, realist claims about the importance of face-savers are,
in principle, accurate. Although Gorbachev was not forced to yield, he needed
to justify to his domestic critics the “concessions” in his policy toward Ger-
many. An agreement on the reduction of German military power fulªlled that
purpose. Because Gorbachev had to avoid the impression that money played
any role in the deal, economic incentives could not serve as face-savers that
would pave the way for an “honorable retreat.” Gorbachev realized that he
would need to defend himself against allegations that he sold out the USSR’s
“victory” in World War II, and therefore no reference to the economic aid was

36. See, for example, Horst Teltschik, 329 Tage: Innenansichten der Vereinigung (Berlin: Siedler, 1991),
pp 28, 100, 226; Bierling, Wirtschaftshilfe für Moskau; and Newnham, “The Price of German Unity.”
37. James Goldgeier, Leadership Style and Soviet Foreign Policy: Stalin, Khrushchev, Brezhnev, Gorbachev
(Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994), p. 110.

153
Forsberg

included in the press release of the Caucasus meeting.38 Gorbachev also does
not mention the role of economic assistance in his memoirs and instead em-
phasizes that he was able to insist on a signiªcant reduction of German armed
forces.39
Because the need to obtain economic assistance was nevertheless crucial
to Gorbachev, the view that the agreement between the Soviet Union and
Germany was an exchange based on mutual beneªt has some obvious merit.
As Stephan Bierling argues, Gorbachev wanted to receive the maximal
ªnancial compensation for his cooperative stance on the issue.40 Exchange
theorists can also easily explain why the deal was lucrative to both. According
to the theory of marginal utility, the relative value of the economic resources
that were transferred was higher for the poorer side and lower for the richer.
Germany was in a stronger position and could negotiate a deal that reºected
its interests, but the deal was still mutually beneªcial.
The problem with this exchange argument is that the amount of eco-
nomic incentives was hardly the key to the settlement. In 1988 Gorbachev
had already received a much bigger offer from German industrial circles.
They promised to deliver 500 billion DM to the Soviet Union in various
forms of commodities if Gorbachev acquiesced in German uniªcation.41 The
reason this offer did not have any inºuence is not that Gorbachev feared do-
mestic opposition or that the sum was too small but that it simply did not
seem serious at the time. The amount of the economic assistance Gorbachev
ultimately accepted was less signiªcant than the interpretative context within
which things were exchanged.
The view that German economic aid was merely a payment is also belied
by the dearth of evidence of direct bargaining between Kohl and Gorbachev.
Although the Soviet Union tried to receive a substantial amount of German
assistance, this was not the main issue in the crucial phase of negotiations. As
Hannes Adomeit has pointed out, the economic and ªnancial aspects of Ger-
man uniªcation were treated in a rather vague and haphazard fashion, almost
as if economics did not play an important role in Gorbachev’s consent to
uniªcation.42 When Gorbachev and Kohl met in Stavropol (Gorbachev’s
home town in southern Russia) in July 1990 to set the terms of German
uniªcation, the ªnancial arrangements were left to the two sides’ ªnance min-

38. von Plato, Die Vereinigung Deutschlands, p. 393.


39. Mikhail Gorbachev, Memoirs (London: Doubleday, 1996).
40. Bierling, Wirtschaftshilfe für Moskau, p. 318.
41. Ekkehard Kuhn, Gorbatschow und die deutsche Einheit: Aussagen der wichtigsten russischen und
deutschen Beteiligten (Bonn: Bouvier, 1993), p. 45.
42. Hannes Adomeit, “Gorbachev, German Uniªcation, and the Collapse of Empire,” Post-Soviet Af-
fairs, Vol. 10, No. 3 (July/September 1994), pp. 197–230.

154
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

isters. The two principals—Kohl and Gorbachev—focused on their mutual


partnership and the general terms of their future cooperation. During the
three-day meeting, speciªc ªgures for the amount of aid rarely came up. Real
bargaining on the sum of the German aid took place only after the two sides
reached agreement in Stavropol. When Kohl received the request for 36 bil-
lion DM in September, he responded with an offer of 8 billion and then
agreed to provide 12 billion plus 3 billion of credit. This compromise
was achieved through tough negotiations that Adomeit called “two of the
most expensive telephone conversations in recent Russian German history.”43
The notion of a pure exchange is therefore insufªcient to explain the na-
ture of the link between German economic aid to the Soviet Union and
Gorbachev’s acceptance of German uniªcation and Germany’s membership
in NATO. To understand how the German economic assistance was con-
nected to the agreement, we need to examine the promises of future coopera-
tion. Gorbachev explained ten years after the fall of the Berlin Wall that in the
political circumstances of 1990 he did not present (and could not have pre-
sented) Germany with uniªcation. Rather than depicting the agreement as a
mere business deal, he stressed that the most important element was the pro-
vision for extensive future cooperation.44 From this perspective, economic in-
centives were largely a form of diffuse reciprocity. What was exchanged was
not deªned clearly, but the idea of common future cooperation loomed large
and Gorbachev was able to count on long-term beneªts. Gorbachev’s aide
Anatoly Chernyaev believes that “economic support for perestroika would not
have been limited to ‘moments of German gratitude’ but would have become
a mutually advantageous collaboration on a broad scale.”45 Although
Gorbachev had to fulªll his obligation to reciprocate, he did not believe that
his acceptance of German uniªcation and its membership in NATO was any
direct reciprocation. Gorbachev’s way of handling this issue at the Stavropol
meeting demonstrates the point. According to Adomeit, “Kohl reiterated the
theme that that to him economic and ªnancial assistance was an integral part
of the total package. Gorbachev spoke about the great economic opportuni-
ties that existed for the Federal Republic in the Soviet Union and said that the
USSR was not concerned about (economic) dependency on Germany.”46
Gorbachev still fully believed that the Soviet Union was a powerful country

43. Adomeit, “Gorbachev, German Uniªcation, and the Collapse of Empire,” p. 225.
44. “Gipfelgespräch: Wie es wirklich war,” interview with George H. W. Bush, Mikhail Gorbachev,
and Helmut Kohl, Welt am Sonntag (Berlin), 14 November 1999, p. 3.
45. Anatoly Chernyaev, “The Uniªcation of Germany: Political Mechanisms and Psychological Ste-
reotypes,” Russian Politics and Law, Vol. 36, No. 4 (July/August 1998), p. 24.
46. Hannes Adomeit, Imperial Overstretch: Germany in Soviet Policy from Stalin to Gorbachev (Baden-
Baden: Nomos, 1998), p. 548.

155
Forsberg

that would be able to modernize its economy and pay back its debt to Ger-
many after a period of necessary restructuring. Gorbachev claimed he would
never have accepted political dependence in return for economic credits: “If
we take something, we will pay for it.”47
Because exchange that rests on ideas of future cooperation requires a con-
siderable amount of trust, the economic rewards and promises can also be
seen as signals that help to forge a bond of common interest. Gorbachev him-
self claimed that a frank atmosphere and mutual understanding on a variety
of issues were essential in resolving the German question. The delivery of aid
without strings attached strengthened the idea of a communal relationship
and increased the feeling of trust. This is how Kohl and his aides conceived
the effects of the economic assistance. Kohl later wrote: “The good relation-
ship we had established in Bonn in 1989 proved to be watertight because I
subsequently had several occasions in which I was able to redeem promises.
[Gorbachev] knew that I was somebody who keeps his word and on whom he
could rely in difªcult situations.”48
Kohl and his chief foreign policy adviser, Horst Teltschik, regarded the
Soviet request for aid as a good sign because it showed that Gorbachev was
not seeking conºict. They wanted to reciprocate and use the economic aid
consciously to improve the atmosphere. However, the German leaders did not
want to exploit the situation in a blatant manner, which they believed would
be counterproductive.49 Instead, they tried to make their expectations of re-
ciprocal gestures from Moscow as explicit as they could without proposing a
direct deal. This was especially the case when Horst Teltschik negotiated over
the conditions of the German credit to the Soviet Union. Teltschik later re-
called that Soviet acceptance of Germany’s NATO membership was clearly
part of the package:

At the discussion with Gorbachev my task was to make clear that the chancellor
was ready to give the credit. But we wanted to get something in return for it.
(Laughter.) And I could not say this openly. I mean, the most difªcult aspect of
this discussion was to let the partner know that we regarded the credit as a part
of the entire solution without causing annoyance that we said it and without
causing bad feelings. That was my task.50

47. von Plato, Die Vereinigung Deutschlands, p. 339. All translations here are by the author.
48. Helmut Kohl, Ich wollte Deutschlands Einheit (Berlin: Propyläen, 1996), p. 280.
49. This view was also shared by Foreign Minister Hans-Dietrich Genscher. See Hans-Dietrich
Genscher, Erinnerungen (Berlin: Siedler, 1995), pp. 829–830.
50. Cited in von Plato, Die Vereinigung Deutschlands, p. 338. See also Horst Teltschik, 329 Tage,
p. 221.

156
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

It is not clear whether Gorbachev himself understood the message exactly this
way. The protocols of the meeting do not provide a clue. Gorbachev has re-
peatedly denied that there was any direct linkage between the credit and the
political agreement on German uniªcation. But, as we have seen before, he
subscribes to the view that the German economic assistance was important in
building mutual conªdence, which was crucial for the political solution. In-
deed, his defense was somewhat open-ended: “Some people insinuate that we
sold the victory that was achieved with so many sacriªces [in World War II]
for the Deutschmark. One must not simplify the connection, but we have to
see the reality.”51
This account suggests that explanations of the end of the Cold War
depicting Gorbachev as having simply upheld his own principles when he
accepted Germany’s membership in NATO are not sufªcient either.52
Gorbachev had introduced new thinking in foreign policy, but Soviet iden-
tity—and, with it, Soviet interests—continued to change during the process.
They did not transform in a vacuum but as a result of interaction. When
Gorbachev was looking for feedback on his vision of a common European
home, German economic rewards reinforced his beliefs.
Timothy Garton Ash, among others, has hinted at the importance of
German aid from this perspective:
[I]t would of course be quite absurd to suggest that German unity was bought
for 52,000 tonnes of beef. But this was an important and very speciªc signal that
the prospect of Germany being Gorbachev’s greatest helper in his embattled at-
tempt to modernize the Soviet Union was made not less but more real by the
possibility of German uniªcation.53

The clue to success was that Gorbachev was able to interpret Kohl’s promises
and rewards as genuine signs of a changing style of policymaking in Europe
based on the idea of shared responsibility. The German promises and rewards
were interpreted in this way because of the communicative processes that un-
derlay them, but the economic incentives themselves were part of the com-
municative process. The promises and rewards seemed to offer a totally differ-
ent way of understanding of how great-power politics was to be conducted in
the future. The trust that was established was important because it allowed
Gorbachev to separate political from economic issues. Because he assumed

51. Mikhail Gorbachev, Gipfelgespräche: Geheime Protokolle aus meiner Amtszeit (Berlin: Rowohlt,
1993), p. 171.
52. See, for example, Risse, “The Cold War’s Endgame and German Uniªcation.”
53. Timothy Garton Ash, In Europe’s Name: Germany and the Divided Continent (New York: Random
House 1992), p. 350.

157
Forsberg

that assistance and mutually beneªcial cooperation would be forthcoming, he


did not need to ask for “money” directly for his acceptance of German mem-
bership in NATO.
Gorbachev found economic assistance from Germany valuable because
the Soviet Union was facing increasing ªnancial problems. This is hardly a
contentious point. But the clue to the success of the German economic incen-
tives was not that Gorbachev saw the credits as a direct payment for a political
deal but that he was able to interpret Kohl’s promises and rewards as genuine
signs of a changing style of policymaking in Europe and the beginning of a
new partnership between the countries. To gauge the difference that this
ideational factor made, it helps to examine a contrasting case in which it was
absent.

Economic Incentives in the Kuriles Dispute

The Japanese also tried to inºuence Gorbachev with economic incentives at


the end of the Cold War. In particular, they tried to use their economic power
to resolve the dispute over the four Kurile Islands that had been under Soviet
control since the end of World War II. The Japanese linked large-scale aid to
progress in peace treaty negotiations over the territorial question. Although
the linkage was mainly negative (i.e., Japan was withholding large-scale eco-
nomic assistance), Japan also tried to use promises of economic aid in a more
positive manner.54
Because the purpose of this analysis may be misconceived, let me clarify
its validity before moving forward. Some people may object to the compari-
son because they feel that the cases were entirely different. This is true to a de-
gree, but real-world counterfactuals in open systems are always different in
various respects. Historically speaking, however, it was by no means clear in
1989–1990 that it would be easier for the Soviet Union to accept German
uniªcation than to return the disputed islands to Japan. Moreover, I do not
explain the different outcomes solely by referring to the economic aid. Rather
I try to demonstrate that the reason the dynamics were different in the two
cases is that the parties attached different meanings to the economic aid.55

54. This narrative is based mainly on Tsuyoshi Hasegawa, The Northern Territories Dispute and Russo-
Japanese Relations, Vol. 2, Neither War nor Peace, 1985–1998 (Berkeley: University of California Press,
1998); and Hiroshi Kimura, Distant Neighbours, Vol. 2, Japanese-Russian Relations under Gorbachev
and Yeltsin (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 2000), esp. pp. 239–255. See also William Nimmo, Japan
and Russia: A Reevaluation in the Post-Soviet Era (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1994); and Joachim
Glaubitz, Between Tokyo and Moscow: The History of an Uneasy Relationship, 1972 to the 1990s (Lon-
don: Hurst & Co., 1995).
55. Randall Newnham makes a parallel point in comparing German and Japanese policies toward the

158
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

German economic aid and promises of future assistance paved the way
for Gorbachev’s acceptance of German uniªcation and membership in
NATO. By contrast, Japanese attempts to use economic statecraft to settle the
long-standing territorial dispute with the Soviet Union were futile and even
counterproductive. If the Germans were able to inºuence the Soviet Union
with economic aid, why were the Japanese unable to? Or, even more striking,
why did the promises of Japanese aid seem to complicate rather than facilitate
the solution?
Materialist notions of power and self-interest do not seem to offer any
clear keys to this puzzle. In terms of military power or economic compatibil-
ity, one should not expect any major difference between the German and Jap-
anese cases. In materialist terms, the relevant factors are the total amount of
the promised aid, the need for assistance, and the credibility of the promises.
For ideationalists, by contrast, the relevant factors are how the aid was con-
ceived between the parties and how its delivery would (re)deªne the relation-
ship between the parties. In the cases of German uniªcation and the dispute
over the Kurile Islands, there was a clear difference in the role of economic aid
in the bilateral relationships and how this role was perceived.
The most striking example of Japan’s use of economic statecraft occurred
in March 1991, just before Gorbachev’s scheduled visit to Tokyo, when Ichiro
Ozawa, the head of the then-ruling Liberal Democratic Party, went to Mos-
cow to discuss the territorial issue personally with Gorbachev. He suggested
that $26 billion of Japanese aid would be forthcoming if the Soviet Union
promised to return the islands, but the attempt failed badly.56 Later the link-
age between economic aid and the territorial question was more subtle but
still rather overt. In October 1991 the Japanese government declared that, as a
special gesture, Moscow would receive $2.5 billion worth of emergency aid,
but the decision was only partly implemented.57 The Japanese told Russian
leaders that they would provide this “unconditional aid” only after a peace
treaty had been concluded.58 In the early 1990s Japanese aid lagged behind
Western assistance. Food aid worth some $155,000 was delivered separately
to residents of the contested islands. In 1992 only fairly modest direct aid was
provided, including $25 million to upgrade safety standards at nuclear power
plants, $20 million to help provide a decent wage to nuclear weapons scien-
Soviet Union. Randall Newnham, “A Comparison of German and Japanese Economic Linkage Pol-
icies,” in Iliana Zloch-Christy, ed., Eastern Europe and the World Economy: Challenges of Transition and
Globalization (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 1998), pp. 244–261.
56. Another politician who suggested a purchase of the islands was Shin Kanemaru. See Nimmo, Ja-
pan and Russia, p. 79; and Glaubitz, Between Tokyo and Moscow, p. 208.
57. See, for example, Leszek Buszyñski, “Russia and Japan: The Unmaking of a Territorial Settle-
ment,” The World Today, Vol. 49, No. 3 (March 1993), pp. 50–54.
58. Nimmo, Japan and Russia, p. 116.

159
Forsberg

tists in Russia and Ukraine (who might otherwise have been tempted to seek
work abroad), and tons of humanitarian aid worth $150 million to Russia’s
Far East regions.59 Private Japanese investments were also minimal, in part be-
cause Japanese business executives did not want to be seen as proªting while
the islands remained in Russian hands.60
Ozawa’s offer in 1991, however, was large by any measure. The Soviet
Union was in desperate need of economic assistance, and Soviet diplomats
had hinted to the Japanese that they would like to develop cooperation
schemes. Yet, Gorbachev angrily rejected the offer because he regarded a deal
over the disputed islands to be impossible. He insisted that Ozawa’s proposal
was an affront to the Soviet state.61 If Gorbachev had agreed to the Japanese
proposal, he would have been accused of selling the islands. Rumors of con-
spiracy circulating in the Soviet press provided a strong interpretative frame-
work for any deal involving economic issues. Consequently, Gorbachev was
in a no-win situation. The Soviet press accused the Japanese of believing “that
the USSR will inevitably capitulate on the territorial question in exchange for
Japanese foreign assistance.”62 Moreover, ofªcials in Moscow believed that the
economic promises came not from reliable people but from “political ªgures
or Foreign Ministry ofªcials who do not actually have economic power or
corresponding material resources.”63
The opposition to territorial concessions became more vocal in 1992
after the Soviet Union had collapsed. Russian leaders and parliamentarians
argued that the territorial question should never have been raised at all. For
reasons of national pride, hardline commentators were viscerally opposed to
the idea of trading what they called Russia’s “sacred land” for promises of in-
creased Japanese aid.64 The Russians stressed that they would not begin their
existence as an independent state by abandoning some of their territory. An
inºuential Russian industrialist accused Japan of treating Russia “like some
kind of Zimbabwe” by trying to coerce it to give up the islands for promises of
massive economic aid.65 According to another commentator, “when [Soviet

59. “Japan’s Basic Policy on Relations with the Russian Federation,” Japanese Ministry of Foreign Af-
fairs, Tokyo, 13 April 1993.
60. Gerald Segal, Normalizing Soviet-Japanese Relations, RIIA Special Paper (London: Royal Institute
of International Affairs, 1991).
61. Hasegawa, The Northern Territories Dispute, Vol. 2, p. 384.
62. Vsevolod Ovchinnikov, “Poishchem reshenie vmeste,” Pravda (Moscow), 10 October 1991, p. 5.
63. S. Agafonov, “Kto popadet v spiski,” Izvestiya (Moscow), 1 November 1991, p. 5.
64. See, for example, Falkenheim Meyer, “Moscow’s Relations with Tokyo: Domestic Obstacles to a
Territorial Agreement,” Asian Survey, Vol. 33, No. 10 (October 1993), p. 958.
65. Nimmo, Japan and Russia, p. 150.

160
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

leaders] learned that the Japanese wanted back at least four islands of the
Kurile chain, they started hating the Japanese.”66 Another Russian view was
that “we should not deceive ourselves into thinking that anyone in Japan will
take this as a show of goodwill; instead it is purely a sign of weakness, a con-
cession by a military superpower to an economic superpower, a gesture aimed
in the pitiful hope of [gaining] aid in return.”67 Other Russian commentators
concurred, describing the Japanese promises of aid as hostile acts that were an
insult to Russia.68 In the view of a prominent Japanese specialist, Tsuyoshi
Hasegawa, the offers of economic aid in exchange for the islands diminished
any prospect of early compromise: “The Japanese government’s change in po-
sition was not perceived by the Soviet side as good intentions but rather as a
crude maneuver for the sale of the territory.”69
Thus, the Japanese proposals failed not because Japan lacked military
capacity in comparison to Germany or because the ªnancial offers were
smaller or because Japan’s economy was not strong enough. Nor did Soviet
and Russian leaders believe that Japan’s offers stemmed from weakness and
that there was no need for Moscow to budge. On the contrary, Soviet and
Russian leaders regarded the proposals as threats and concluded that they
must not budge. Russian President Boris Yeltsin indicated that Japan should
loosen the link between economic assistance and the territorial question.
Moreover, he claimed that Japan had been “putting pressure on Russia eco-
nomically, politically and psychologically” and thus making it more difªcult
to solve the dispute: “The idea of putting pressure on me is no good. More
pressure makes it more difªcult to solve problems. That’s the way Russians
think.”70 Twice Yeltsin decided to cancel a planned visit to Tokyo because he
feared that the Japanese wanted to pressure him. Moscow’s weakness, not its
strength, is what prevented the deal.
Although it is true that Japan’s economic promises were not entirely cred-
ible from Moscow’s standpoint, the lack of credibility cannot be explained
by Japan’s objective capabilities. The reason the Japanese rewards lacked
credibility in Moscow is that the Japanese evinced a sense of mistrust. The
Japanese limited their economic incentives to a direct exchange because they
did not expect that cooperation with Moscow would be beneªcial. Soviet

66. Leo Mlechin, “Japanophobia,” Moscow News (Moscow), No. 44 (October 1991), pp. 22–23.
67. Feodor Ivanov and Alexandr Anichin, Izvestiya (Moscow), 28 March 1991, quoted in Rozman, Ja-
pan and Russia, p. 86.
68. See Alexei Arbatov and Boris Makeyev, “The Kuril Barrier,” New Times, No. 42 (1992), pp. 24–
26.
69. Hasegawa, The Northern Territories Dispute, Vol. 2, p. 387.
70. Nimmo, Japan and Russia, p. 147.

161
Forsberg

and Russian leaders, in turn, regarded the Japanese promises as an affront.


Neither Gorbachev nor Yeltsin could escape the image that by returning the
islands they would be acting in a “non-statesmanlike manner.” Holding ªrm
on the territorial issue boosted Yeltsin’s support in conservative circles. That
support was more important to Yeltsin than the promised economic beneªts.
The Japanese offers not only failed to alter existing identities but actually
fortiªed them, pushing Yeltsin to defend past Soviet actions. Because the rela-
tionship was seen as competitive rather than cooperative, the Russians re-
garded the Japanese promises of future economic aid not as a carrot but as a
stick.
The problem was that the Japanese economic promises did not signal a
desire to strengthen common bonds. Rather, they suggested that Moscow
could not yet be treated as a real partner. When Soviet and Russian leaders ex-
pected aid anyway, Japan’s conditional promises were understood not as a pos-
itive inducement but as a negative deferral of any large-scale aid. Yeltsin
seemed to take for granted that it was the moral obligation of other countries
to assist Russia.71 In short, the determination that helped Germany to achieve
its objectives did not work in the Japanese case. On the contrary, Soviet and
Russian leaders were irritated by the rigidity of the Japanese position. Some
also suspected that the four disputed Kurile Islands were not what the Japa-
nese genuinely wanted and that they would extend their claims to Sakhalin
and to the entire chain of the Kurile Islands. As a result, Russia became
increasingly averse to Japanese aid. Although Japan increased its economic as-
sistance after 1992, it did not have the effect of promoting friendship. Psycho-
logically, the Russians had to deny that the Japanese were helping them and
had to strip the aid of its obligations. The normative commitments that gift
giving can produce in international relations did not obtain in this case. Real-
izing that aid and the islands question were tacitly linked, Russia did not want
to establish any reciprocal relationship.72
The success of Germany’s rewarding strategy and the failure of Japan’s can
be explained not by the amount of the promised aid but by the way the re-
wards were delivered and conceived. The German rewards were based on the
idea of diffuse reciprocity, and they signaled changing identities and interests.
The Japanese rewards were based on the idea of speciªc reciprocity, which did
not entail changes in identities and interests.

71. Hasegawa, The Northern Territories Dispute, Vol. 2, p. 445.


72. In May 1995, an earthquake occurred north of Sakhalin, killing nearly 2,000 people in the
Neftegorsk area. The Japanese offered aid to the town, but the Russian government turned down the
offer. “Yeltsin said that Russia did not want Japanese aid because Japan might then say ‘Give us back
the islands.’” “Geo-Political Earthquake,” The Economist, 3 June 1995, p. 45.

162
Economic Incentives, Ideas, and the End of the Cold War

Conclusions

In this article I have tried to show how seemingly materialist factors (Soviet
economic weakness and the USSR’s need to receive economic assistance) that
are often cited as reasons for the end of the Cold War and for Moscow’s ac-
commodation with Western positions in foreign policy were in a crucial way
constituted by ideational elements. How economic incentives work depends
on the way they are constructed by the parties involved. In this sense, material
forces cannot be separated from ideas. When looking at the assumed link be-
tween German economic assistance and Gorbachev’s acceptance of German
membership in NATO, the depiction of German aid as a payment for
Gorbachev’s concession is only one possible construction of the nature of the
aid. Far from expediting a solution, the idea of a “purchase” actually limited
Gorbachev’s actions.
The role of German economic statecraft, in the pledges and delivery of
economic assistance to the Soviet Union, was not a supplementary compo-
nent of coercive power. German economic assistance cannot be adequately
described as a face-saver that was needed to rescue Gorbachev from complete
humiliation, nor can it be seen as simply a payment or “bribe” paid to
Gorbachev for his concessions. Rather, it was a signal of future cooperation
and partnership between Germany and the Soviet Union that facilitated
Gorbachev’s decision to accept German membership in NATO.
If we want to explain why economic incentives were important in the
German case and failed in the Japanese case, the constructivist argument is
that the different role of economic incentives depended on their meanings.
What was remarkable in these two cases was how differently the economic aid
was seen from the Soviet/Russian perspective. This difference in signiªcation
was partly due to the nature of the proposed aid and partly to the context of
the relationship in which the economic rewards and offers of further aid were
embedded. German aid was important not only because it matched Soviet in-
terests but because it bolstered Gorbachev’s belief that Soviet relations with
Germany could be—and were being—fundamentally transformed.
Japanese aid, by contrast, did not help to redeªne Soviet interests, be-
cause it was mainly conditional. Soviet and Russian leaders were irritated by
the rigidity of the Japanese position. There was no larger framework of prom-
ises of future cooperation within which the offers of economic aid could have
been interpreted. The Japanese government believed it had no speciªc obliga-
tions to help the Soviet Union because it did not share the same cultural
space. The conditionality of Japan’s offers of economic assistance did not
establish trust between Soviet/Russian and Japanese leaders. Even though

163
Forsberg

the economic situation in the Soviet Union and Russia was worsening,
Gorbachev’s and then Yeltsin’s willingness to bargain over the conditions of
economic assistance declined.
In sum, when explaining the role of economic incentives at the end of the
Cold War, ideas mattered in several ways. An exchange of material items is
not an idea-free process; it rests on notions of what can be exchanged and
when. Liberal ideas construct a wide range of space for exchange, especially
when tied to the norm of reciprocity, but it is not guaranteed that government
leaders adopt these ideas. In particular, realist notions of what is honorable to
be exchanged hampered the use of economic incentives. In the case of Ger-
man uniªcation, Gorbachev was able to adopt ideas of diffuse reciprocity and
shared responsibility. Although normative structures tend to reproduce them-
selves, the end of the Cold War shows that they are not immutable. Many
things enabled Gorbachev to adopt new rules and ideas: he wanted to ªnd so-
lutions to economic problems, but he also wanted to establish a radically dif-
ferent partnership with Germany. In this context, Germany’s economic incen-
tives played a crucial role in conªrming Gorbachev’s belief that the rules of
international politics and of relationships in Europe could be fundamentally
transformed.

164

You might also like