Relationship Between Individualist-Collectivist Culture and Entrepreneurial Activity: Evidence From Global Entrepreneurship Monitor Data

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/226786617

Relationship between Individualist–Collectivist Culture and Entrepreneurial


Activity: Evidence from Global Entrepreneurship Monitor Data

Article · January 2011


DOI: 10.1007/s11187-009-9230-6

CITATIONS READS

346 1,911

2 authors:

María-José Pinillos Luisa Eugenia Reyes Recio


King Juan Carlos University King Juan Carlos University
29 PUBLICATIONS 485 CITATIONS 55 PUBLICATIONS 483 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Luisa Eugenia Reyes Recio on 19 May 2020.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Small Bus Econ (2011) 37:23–37
DOI 10.1007/s11187-009-9230-6

Relationship between individualist–collectivist culture


and entrepreneurial activity: evidence from Global
Entrepreneurship Monitor data
Marı́a-José Pinillos Æ Luisa Reyes

Accepted: 15 July 2009 / Published online: 26 August 2009


 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2009

Abstract This paper examines how one dimension 1 Introduction


of national culture (an individualist–collectivist ori-
entation) is related to Total Entrepreneurial Activity, Entrepreneurship is a complex phenomenon that
depending on the level of economic development, involves a great variety of contexts and factors.
measured by GDP per capita. Researchers have Within the analysis of entrepreneurship, the study of
traditionally associated individualism with high rates new firm creation has had an important place,
of firm creation, arguing that an orientation towards particularly due to its importance in economic
achievement and the pursuit of personal objectives development, renewal and employment generation
(dominant aspects in individualist cultures) are deter- (Tödtling and Wanzenböck 2003).
minants of entrepreneurial activity. The current anal- New business start-up activity can be found in all
ysis shows that a country’s culture correlates to countries, but researchers who study entrepreneurship
entrepreneurship, but cannot uphold the idea that across countries find that significant differences exist
higher levels of individualism mean higher rates of in the levels of entrepreneurial activity, and also that
entrepreneurship. Using data from the Global Entre- these differences remain stable over time (Uhlaner
preneurship Monitor on 52 countries, the results show and Thurik 2007; Van Stel et al. 2005).
that a country’s entrepreneurship rate is negatively In the past, most researchers trying to explain the
related to individualism when development is medium different levels of entrepreneurial activity have
or low, and positively related to individualism when carried out comparative analyses of the economic
the level of development is high. Thus, individualism conditions in different countries (Blau 1987; Blanch-
is not related to entrepreneurship in the same way in flower and Oswald 1994; Blanchflower 2000; Evans
countries with differing levels of development. and Leighton 1989; Meager 1992; Acs et al. 1994;
Audretsch et al. 2002; Sternberg and Wennekers
Keywords Culture  Individualism–collectivism  2005). Such studies have provided empirical evi-
Entrepreneurship  Global Entrepreneurship Monitor dence on the existence of a U-form relationship
between the level of economic development and the
JEL Classifications L26  M13  O57 level of national entrepreneurial activity (Carree et al.
2002; Thurik and Wennekers 2004; Sternberg and
Wennekers 2005; Wennekers et al. 2005).
Using data from the Global Entrepreneurship
M.-J. Pinillos (&)  L. Reyes
Rey Juan Carlos University, Madrid, Spain Monitor (GEM), Wennekers et al. (2005) have
e-mail: mariajose.pinillos@urjc.es observed this U-form relationship between nascent

123
24 M.-J. Pinillos, L. Reyes

entrepreneurship and the level of income per capita. femininity. Later, he adds a fifth dimension (Hofstede
The implication of such a U-shape is that, as 1991): long- versus short-term orientation. His cul-
economies develop, the rate of new business start- tural dimensions are useful for identifying key
ups or that of nascent entrepreneurship declines, but aspects of culture related to the potential for entre-
picks up again in highly developed economies. preneurial behaviour (Thomas and Mueller 2000;
However, bearing in mind that the level of Kirkman et al. 2006). Out of the five dimensions
entrepreneurial activity is related to that of economic describing culture, the I–C contrast constitutes the
development, as described above, Van Stel et al. ‘‘profound structure’’ of cultural differences (Triandis
(2005) note that countries such as Belgium, France, and Suh 2002). I–C expresses the cultural tendency to
Japan, Switzerland, Australia, Canada, and the US all place more value on the individual or the group. The
have the same level of development, but that the first present study focuses on the cultural dimension I–C
four have a low level of entrepreneurial activity, and looks at its relationship with entrepreneurial
while the last three have a high level, according to activity, as well as the level of development.
GEM Executive Reports, a difference that is shown to Different theories exist as to why a particular
be persistent. It can thus be concluded that reasons country can have a greater ‘‘entrepreneurial culture’’
may exist, other than solely economic ones, to than another. One of these explanations (Davidsson
explain why countries have similar levels of income 1995; Davidson and Wiklund 1997) implies that in
but a different ratio of entrepreneurial activity, and countries where a greater proportion of the population
these other reasons may be rooted in cultural has entrepreneurial values, there will also be a greater
differences according to Hofstede et al. (2004). prevalence of entrepreneurial behaviour. It can there-
Empirical evidence exists (Noorderhaven et al. fore be assumed that it is precisely people with greater
2004; Wennekers et al. 2007) to support this notion, entrepreneurial spirit who are more likely to create new
and even to suggest that culture, more than economic firms. Individualism is one of the factors related to the
variables, plays a fundamental role in explaining the profile of the entrepreneur. Individualism is associated
differences in entrepreneurial activity in different with the motivation to achieve and the pursuit of
countries, especially in terms of persistence, as personal goals. Some researchers find empirical evi-
cultural aspects are possibly of an even more per- dence supporting the idea that individualism favours
manent nature than economic conditions (Hofstede new firm creation (McGrath et al. 1992a; Shane 1992,
2001; Wennekers et al. 2007). 1993; Mueller and Thomas 2001; Wennekers et al.
Culture, as the underlying value system peculiar to 2002), although other authors have also offered
a specific group or society, shapes the development of empirical evidence to suggest that it is, in fact, a lesser
certain personality traits and motivates individuals in degree of individualism (in other words, collectivism)
a society to engage in behaviour that may not be that is positively related to entrepreneurial activity
evident in other societies. (Hunt and Levie 2003; Baum et al. 1993).
The development of research based on culture These varying results have led us to believe that
began by empirically identifying different types of the I–C relationship and entrepreneurial activity
culture. In the more general field of research of depend on the different levels of development of
culture and management (Sondergaard 1994), and the countries under scrutiny and that the individualist
specifically in culture and entrepreneurship (Hayton culture will have a greater relationship with entre-
et al. 2002), the typology of culture defined by preneurial activity when we refer to countries with a
Hofstede (1980, 2001) has undoubtedly been the most high level of income. Conversely, it is the collectivist
widely used. culture that will have the greatest relationship to
Hofstede’s (1980, 1991, 2001) extensive study of entrepreneurial activity when we consider countries
culture provides a clear articulation of differences with a medium or low level of income. This belief
across countries in values, beliefs, and work roles. In has been backed up via the empirical evidence
his influential first study, Hofstede (1980) finds obtained in this study, whose rationale is linked to
cultural differences across countries along four different motivations that drive entrepreneurs accord-
dimensions: power distance, uncertainty avoidance, ing to their respective cultures, as we will go on to
individualism–collectivism (I–C), and masculinity– demonstrate.

123
Relationship between individualism–collectivism and entrepreneurship 25

Understanding the relationship between cultural An important aspect in the current analysis is to
differences and the level of entrepreneurial activity is consider whether individualism plays a similar stim-
crucial for establishing policy measures designed to ulating role in highly developed economies (rela-
encourage entrepreneurial activity in each country. tively rich countries) and in less developed
Public institutions clearly play a fundamental role economies (relatively poor countries, including both
and, through their policies, can strengthen the devel- transformation economies and developing countries).
opment of productive or unproductive activities Our contrast is based on the statistical analysis of
(Baumol 1996). However, in order to drive entrepre- TEA during the period 1999–2007 for a sample of 52
neurial activity forward, it is important to know countries, and the level of economic development is
which factors are related to entrepreneurial activity, measured by GDP per capita (GDPPC). We also
what is the strength of the relationship and which of analysed the I–C for two groups of countries:
these factors can be influenced by policy measures. developed economies and developing ones.
Prior research finds that the individualist–collec- The rest of this paper is organised as follows.
tivist dimension of culture is a key aspect in entrepre- Section 2 outlines the theoretical foundations justi-
neurial behaviour (e.g., Triandis 1995; Earley and fying the research, and Sect. 3 presents the research
Gibson 1998; Oyserman et al. 2002), and research has hypotheses. Section 4 describes the research meth-
also stressed the importance of the relationship odology, while Sect. 5 reports the results. The study
between the level of economic development and ends with the conclusions and some research
entrepreneurial activity. Recently, authors have tried limitations.
to examine the relationships to be found among
individualism–collectivism, economic development
and entrepreneurial activity (Hunt and Levie 2003; 2 National culture, individualism–collectivism
McGrath et al. 1992b). However, the studies that and entrepreneurship
analyse this threefold relationship are not explicitly
concerned with the questions of (1) whether individ- Culture has been defined in many ways. Building on
ualism–collectivism is related independently to entre- the work of Kluckhohn (1951) and Kroeber and
preneurial activity or (2) whether economic Parsons (1958), Hofstede sees culture as patterned
development moderates the relationship between ways of thinking and feeling that constitute the
individualism–collectivism and entrepreneurial activ- ‘‘mental programming’’, distinguishing members
ity. The current study aims to examine these questions. from one group to another. Such mental program-
Focusing the analysis on individualism–collectiv- ming consists of patterns of ideas and especially their
ism, which is the most representative cultural attached values, which are conserved and passed
dimension (Triandis 1988; Franke et al. 1991; Van- down from generation to generation. Culture is
dello and Cohen 1999; Schimmack et al. 2005), and deeply rooted, operates unconsciously, and is infused
on the basis of the findings on individualism– with the values of political institutions and technical
collectivism (Triandis and Suh 2002), this study systems, all of which simultaneously reinforce values
empirically investigates the relationship between and beliefs. Typical cultural values are formed in the
individualism and entrepreneurial activity at a early years of a person’s life and tend to be
national level. ‘‘programmed’’ in the individual, resulting in behav-
We use material provided by the GEM project. iour patterns that are consistent with the cultural
GEM provides diverse information on participating environment and remain stable over time (Hofstede
countries, including the Total Entrepreneurial Activity 1980; Mueller and Thomas 2001).
(TEA) rate. TEA measures the relative amount of Thus, culture as the underlying system of values
nascent entrepreneurs and business owners of peculiar to a specific group or society shapes the
young firms in a country. This variable is (consis- development of certain personality traits and moti-
tently) measured across a variety of countries and vates individuals in a society to engage in behaviours
appears to be a useful index for measuring rates of that may not be as prevalent in other societies
‘‘entrepreneurship’’. (Mueller and Thomas 2001).

123
26 M.-J. Pinillos, L. Reyes

2.1 The individualist–collectivist cultural hire their own family members, and then relatives of
dimension their employees. Individualist societies, in contrast,
generally consider family relationships to be unde-
Hofstede (2001) puts individualism and collectivism sirable in the workplace since they could lead to
at opposite ends of a continuum, which the majority nepotism or generate conflicts of interest.
of researchers accept (Morris et al. 1994). The Tiessen (1997) summarises the key characteristics
position of each country on that continuum reflects of individualism and collectivism, and stresses that
its individualist or collectivist orientation. Hofstede the objectives people pursue are personal and short-
defines this dimension as follows: ‘‘Individualism term in individualist cultures and group-oriented and
stands for a society in which the ties between long-term in collectivist cultures. We should note that
individuals are loose: Everyone is expected to look in some countries, individualism is seen as a blessing
after him/herself and her/his immediate family only. and a source of well-being, but in others is regarded
Collectivism stands for a society in which people as unacceptable1 (Peterson 1988). Briefly, in the
from birth onwards are integrated into strong, cohe- individualist philosophy, ‘‘I’’ is more important than
sive in-groups that, throughout people’s lifetime, ‘‘we’’, and success is a personal achievement. In the
continue to protect them in exchange for unquestion- collectivist philosophy, in contrast, ‘‘we’’ is more
ing loyalty’’ (Hofstede 2001, p. 225). important than ‘‘I’’, and individuals are willing to
Individualism stresses the individual, self-suffi- make sacrifices in favour of the position, performance
ciency, and self-control. People in individualist and satisfaction of the group. Thus, collectivist
cultures feel proud of their own accomplishments, societies tend to make a greater ‘‘in-group versus
and are motivated by their own interests and the out-group’’ distinction than do individualist cultures
achievement of personal objectives. Thus, Hofstede (Hofstede 1980).
(1980, p. 221) defines individualism as emotional
independence from ‘‘groups, organizations, or other 2.2 Individualism–collectivism and its
collectivities’’. relationship with entrepreneurial activity
Collectivism implies subordinating personal inter-
ests to the interests of the group and is based on It has been said that cultures with a deeply rooted
cooperation and harmony, as well as a concern for the individualism and with low uncertainty avoidance are
well-being of the group. In collectivist cultures, associated with the development of institutional
people feel that they are an indispensable part of the arrangements, and possibly with psychological traits
group and are unconcerned both about their own and/or cognitive processes, which have been found to
benefit and about the possibility that others may be associated with entrepreneurship.
exploit their efforts (Hui and Triandis 1986). Indeed, empirical evidence suggests a positive
The differences between individualism and col- relationship between individualism and entrepreneur-
lectivism are obvious at many levels: the family, ial activity. Thomas and Mueller (2000) see the logic
personality and behaviour, language and group iden- behind this relationship as being related to the fact the
tity, and in school education (Hofstede 2001). For majority of research into entrepreneurship has been
example, Hofstede (2001, p. 226) says ‘‘[m]embers of carried out in the USA and consequently, ‘‘the US
the we-group are distinct from the other people in culture of individualism and achievement has dom-
society who belong to they-groups or out-groups, and inated the world view of entrepreneurship’’ (Thomas
there are many such people and such out-groups. The and Mueller 2000, p. 290). However, ‘‘the cult of
in-group is the major source of one’s identity and the individualism is foreign to, and often unacceptable in,
only secure protection one has against the hardships
of life. Therefore, one owes lifelong loyalty to one’s
1
in-group, and breaking this loyalty is one of the worst An example is the Chinese culture, where individualism is a
things a person can do’’. Loyalty to the group is an manifestation of selfishness, so anti-individualism is strongly
rooted in the culture. But collectivism does not mean denying
essential element in collectivist cultures, where
the well-being or interests of the individual. Instead, safe-
resources are shared. Hofstede (2001) also notes that guarding the welfare of the group is seen as the best guarantee
in collectivist cultures, entrepreneurs preferentially for the individual (Hofstede 2001; Hui and Triandis 1986).

123
Relationship between individualism–collectivism and entrepreneurship 27

many countries round the world. Gradually, it is pre-eminence of higher order needs (Uhlaner and
becoming clear that each country/culture must Thurik 2007).
develop its own brand of entrepreneurship and raise Motivations are, according to Locke and Latham
its own champions to promote entrepreneurial behav- (1990), those factors that cause tension for the
iour that fits the prevailing societal mores’’ (Peterson individual, endow them with vigour, direct and
1988, p. 1). sustain their behaviour and make them act in order
Bearing in mind the argument outlined above, the to try and satisfy their needs. Erez and Earley (1993)
fact that a number of countries with a clear collec- underline the impact of culture in motivation when
tivist orientation currently heads the TEA ranking is they indicate that culture provides a cognitive outline
unsurprising (Bosma and Harding 2007), in stark that endows meaning and values to motivational
contrast to the idea that individualism is more closely variables to adopted decisions and behavioural stan-
associated with entrepreneurial activity. Specifically, dards. Cultural value orientations establish criteria for
out of the 42 countries in GEM 2006, Peru and determining which objectives are desirable and which
Colombia have the strongest collectivist orientation, ones are not.
with I–C indexes of 16 and 13, respectively,2 and Baum et al. (1993) make a detailed examination of
these two countries are first and second in the the needs and motivations of entrepreneurs from
entrepreneurship rankings in 2006, with TEAs of 40.2 differing cultures. Their results provide empirical
and 22.5%, respectively.3 Indeed, a detailed exami- support for the hypothesis of Erez and Earley (1993),
nation of the data from the GEM reports over the and they observe that the motivations of entrepre-
years offers two key observations with regard to the neurs are not always the same, but are different in
analysis of entrepreneurship. Firstly, evidence sug- individualist and collectivist cultures. They point out
gests that levels of entrepreneurship in GEM coun- that national cultural differences may generate dif-
tries are reasonably stable year after year; secondly, ferent motivations among individuals and find that
the relative positions of countries in the TEA ranking entrepreneurs are motivated by the need for auton-
also remain stable. In other words, differences across omy and achievement in both individualist cultures
countries or regions tend to persist over time (Minniti (e.g., the US) and collectivist cultures (e.g., Israel).
et al. 2006; Acs et al. 2005; Reynolds et al. 2002). But the entrepreneurs in Israel’s collectivist culture
For this reason some researchers (Van Stel et al. have a strong need for affiliation, which they can
2005) regard TEA as a structural characteristic of satisfy by creating firms. These authors argue (Baum
each country’s economy. et al. 1993, p. 510) that ‘‘[o]ne explanation for Israeli
From an entrepreneurship standpoint, social psy- entrepreneurs’ higher need for affiliation than their
chology has speculated as to the existence of a human American counterparts is that in a collectivist,
hierarchy of motivations that ranges from ‘‘basic’’ egalitarian, and informal society like Israel’s, success
needs (related to subsistence and physical needs) to in the entrepreneurial role depends to a great extent
the so-called ‘‘higher order needs’’ (which include the on social networks and personal contacts with key
need for achievement, the need for affiliation, the individuals (friends and family) who facilitate com-
need for autonomy and the need for dominance) pany start-ups (e.g., through personal loans). Israelis
(Maslow 1954). The theory of the hierarchy of needs with high needs for affiliation are more likely to
maintains that when ‘‘basic’’ motivations have been develop the necessary support network critical to the
satisfied, attention will then turn to higher order start-up. In contrast, the US is a less intimate society,
needs, a greater level of prosperity will lead to the more dependent on formal social structures. ‘Work-
ing the system’ by following institutional rules and
procedures may be the key to garnering support for
the start-up (e.g., through financial institutions and
2
In order to interpret the size of these scores, recall that the venture capitalists), thus attenuating the need for
I–C index (Hofstede 1980, 2001) can take values between 0
affiliation’’. In sum, in collectivist countries, family
and 100, with values close to 100 meaning individualist
cultures. The country with the highest score—i.e., the most and/or clan loyalties may provide reliable (although
individualist culture—is the US, with a score of 91. informal) investment guarantees or the opportunity to
3
The mean TEA score in 2006 is 9.4%. request investment with greater force. This increases

123
28 M.-J. Pinillos, L. Reyes

the prevalence of informal investment as opposed to industrialisation and a knowledge-based society


individualist countries where such royalties diminish, (Wennekers et al. 2005).
or have been replaced by the rule of law. From this perspective, societies go through three
Along the same lines, Trulsson’s (1997) study of successive stages where economic activity linked to
entrepreneurs in the region of Lagos in Tanzania agriculture dominates, and is then replaced by industry
offers an example that sheds light on the need for and lastly by services and the knowledge-based
affiliation in business behaviour. The author asks why society.
African entrepreneurs seem to behave irrationally to In agricultural societies, the level of development
Western observers. An extreme case of what could be is low, production units are numerous and are
considered ‘‘irrational economic behaviour’’ is one in organised around family groups, and the culture is
which entrepreneurs acquire technology to reduce the collectivist. In industrial societies, the level of devel-
labour force but at the same time needlessly employ a opment increases and the form of production requires
large number of relatives. One of Trulsson’s most large-sized firms, with strong capital and economies
important findings is that a fundamental aspect of the of scale, which determine the fact that firms tend
labour market in this environment is to employ or towards concentration and therefore numbers are
give work to members of the extended family, which reduced, as well as the fact that family ties cease to
coincides with Hofstede’s observation described be as important as they were at the previous stage, as
above. Consequently, entrepreneurs spend a consid- the countryside population moves into the industrial
erable part of their time, energy and financial centres and the individualist spirit grows. However,
resources attempting to balance business and family this does not normally become apparent via the
obligations. The profit motive is subjected to many creation of new firms, but by satisfying the entrepre-
other priorities here, which explains why the per neurial spirit within the large firm through innovation
capita income level of these countries is lower. of new procedures or new products, as stated by Baum
The ideas above indicate that when culture is et al. (1993). In the most advanced stage of economic
collectivist, one of the results is that people identify development, where services and a knowledge econ-
themselves with the group they belong to, and their omy prevail, the possibility of the appearance of the
assessment differs on who should be hired, how entrepreneurial spirit in the form of new firm creation
decisions should be made or how work should be arises once more, as the demands on capital and the
assigned, though in a way that does not diminish the need for economies of scale are no longer as essential
tendency to act entrepreneurially. to their viability. The motivation for achievement and
In conclusion, cultural differences lead to different autonomy that feeds the entrepreneurial spirit moves
behaviour patterns, which are a consequence of the away from large industrial corporations and can be
fact that the motivations that drive individuals’ satisfied through the creation of their own firm.
actions differ according to their culture (Baum et al. That sequence or succession has been described by
1993) and their environment (Stewart and Roth Bond and Smith (1996) through ecological factors,
2007). indicating, for example, that in agriculture, collective
action is often highly valued, and by Inglehart and
Baker (2000) who state that individualism is associ-
3 Level of economic development, individualism– ated with activity in services.
collectivism and entrepreneurship: working The evolution referred to above is undoubtedly not
hypotheses as simple as we have thus far made out. Inglehart and
Welzel (2005) claim that economic development
As we mentioned in the introduction, there is tends to bring about foreseeable changes in people’s
empirical evidence to suggest that entrepreneurial vision of the world; although traditional cultures—
activity is connected to the level of economic derived, for example, from a society that has been
development. This relationship has been explained historically moulded by Protestantism or by Confu-
bearing in mind the different predominant activities cianism—still leave an indelible stamp on a society’s
in the social group, which historically evolve from vision of the world. History is important, and
the primary activity of agriculture, onto prevalent value orientations in a society reflect the

123
Relationship between individualism–collectivism and entrepreneurship 29

interaction between economic forces and the influ- culture. In relatively poor countries a high level of
ence of tradition. collectivism will favour entrepreneurship, since indi-
All of this leads us to highlight the fact that the viduals will be more motivated to create firms to
relationship between culture and entrepreneurial improve their own situation and at the same time
activity must be analysed within the framework of favour the group. In relatively rich countries, in
the level of development. Wennekers et al. (2005) contrast, a high level of individualism will favour
conclude that in the relationship between the level of entrepreneurship. We can therefore propose the
development and entrepreneurial activity there may following the hypotheses:
exist ‘‘interaction effects in the sense that the level of
Hypothesis 1: The country’s economic develop-
economic development influences the effects of
ment level (GDPPC) moderates the relationship
various other determinants’’ (Wennekers et al. 2005,
between the individualist–collectivist (I–C) culture
p. 307). Later on, Wennekers et al. (2007) found
and the entrepreneurial activity rate (TEA).
empirical evidence for the statement that the rela-
tionship between uncertainty avoidance and the level Hypothesis 2: The Total Entrepreneurial Activity
of business ownership depends upon the level of (TEA) rate is negatively associated with individual-
economic development (measured by GDPPC). ism (I–C) in relatively poor countries.
In brief, taking into account all these previous
Hypothesis 3: The Total Entrepreneurial Activity
points, we believe that the relationship between I–C
(TEA) rate is positively associated with individualism
and entrepreneurial activity is moderated by the level
(I–C) in relatively rich countries.
of economic development. In other words, the level
of development and I–C interact on the level of
entrepreneurial activity.
4 Methodology
In line with what we have just described, it might
be expected that, in developing countries with
This section presents the data and the model used in
collectivist cultures, entrepreneurs with a strong need
the analysis.
for achievement and especially affiliation are driven
to create their own business. This is favoured by the
4.1 Sample
existence of an environment of informal relationships
that provides support and at the same time helps
The data used in this study come from three sources
satisfy the need for affiliation. The situation is clearly
of information: the countries’ TEA scores come from
different in individualist cultures, in which the need
the GEM project; the countries’ development levels
for achievement and the pursuit of one’s own benefit
and GDPPC come from the World Bank; the
seem to drive entrepreneurial activity.
countries’ individualism levels come from Hofstede
The possibility that the level of development may
(1980, 2001).
act as a moderating variable has, therefore, important
The GEM project began in 1999 with 10 partic-
implications for understanding the entrepreneurial
ipating countries, and the number of participants has
behaviour of countries,4 since this behaviour will
generally increased year by year to reach 42 countries
clearly be influenced by the country’s development
in 2006 and 2007. Of the 56 countries that have
level. Consequently, the current analysis attempts to
participated in at least one of the GEM editions,
determine whether a country’s individualist–collec-
information about their I–C index is available for 535
tivist culture will affect its entrepreneurship differ-
countries. A country’s TEA varies little from year to
ently depending on its level of development.
year, to the extent that some regard the TEA as a
The majority of people in a country are not aware
structural characteristic of the economy (as previ-
of how their culture influences their values, attitudes,
ously mentioned), and since it is recommendable to
ideas and norms, and most countries have a dominant

4 5
For a detailed analysis of the importance and implications of Individualism–collectivism data are not yet available for the
identifying moderating variables, see Baron and Kenny (1986), Dominican Republic, Latvia, or Uganda, so these countries
and Sharma et al. (1981). cannot be included in the analysis.

123
30 M.-J. Pinillos, L. Reyes

test the hypotheses using the largest possible number the discovering of an opportunity, while TEA_Nec
of countries, this study considers a sample of 526 measures the same one but when the main reason is
countries: all those that have participated in at least necessity. Both TEA_Opp and TEA_Nec are mean
one GEM edition and for which information about values.
their I–C culture according to Hofstede data and their Individualist–collectivist national culture: The I–C
GDPPC is available. We measure the entrepreneurial index takes values between 0 and 100. Higher values
activity by the mean TEA of each of the 52 countries. indicate countries with individualist cultures, while
Appendix I reports the countries included in the lower values indicate more collectivist cultures.
analysis, as well as the group to which each country Hofstede (2001, p. 214) gives the highest values of
belongs given its development level and its corre- this index for the US (91), Australia (90) and the UK
sponding mean TEA. According to the World Bank (89), and the lowest values for Guatemala (6),
classification, 25 of these countries have a medium or Ecuador (8) and Panama (11). The variable INDCOL
low development level (relatively poor countries) and measures Hofstede’s (2001) assessment of the I–C
27 have a high development level (relatively rich orientation of each of the 52 countries.
countries). Gross domestic product per capita at the country
level: The variable GDPPC measures the mean
4.2 Variables GDPPC, expressed in constant 2,000 US dollars, of
each of the 52 countries for the period 1999–2007.
Total national entrepreneurial activity: The GEM These data come from the World Development
project provides an indicator of the country’s entre- Indicators database of the World Bank.
preneurial activity in the shape of the TEA rate. The
TEA is calculated in a survey of the adult population 4.3 Model
of each country, which, among many other things,
registers the percentage of entrepreneurial initiatives In order to contrast our hypotheses, we have taken the
carried out in a 1-year period. The TEA measures the model used by Van Stel et al. (2005), introducing our
percentage of the adult population of a country (18– own variables.
64 years old) that is either actively involved in As mentioned above, we assume that the relation-
starting a new venture or is the owner/manager of a ship between individualism–collectivism and a coun-
business that is less than 42 months old (Reynolds try’s economic development depends on the
et al. 2002). particular stage of its economic development. There
The TEA rate is measured in three different ways. are two ways in which this hypothesis can be tested.
First, the variable TEA measures the mean TEA of The first approach is to include a term of interaction
each of the 52 countries that have participated in at between I–C and per capita income. The estimated
least one of the GEM editions from 1999 to 2007 and model is as follows:
for which information on their level of individualism
TEA ¼ a þ bINDCOL þ cGDPPC
and GDPPC is available. Second, the GEM project þ dINDCOL GDPPC þ e ð1Þ
distinguishes between the motives behind entrepre-
neurial behaviour. People start their own business for Thus, the hypothesis is that the value of d is positive.
two main reasons: because they have perceived and Alternatively, the effect of I–C for different groups
wished to exploit a business opportunity (opportunity of countries (rich versus poor) can be distinguished,
entrepreneurs), or because they have no other work for which a dummy variable (Allison 1977) called
options or their options are unsatisfactory (necessity DEVELOP_LEVEL is introduced. This variable
entrepreneurs). The variable TEA_Opp measures the equals 0 for relatively poor countries and 1 for
TEA when the main reason for starting the business is relatively rich countries.
This study begins with the assumption that there
are differences in the form of the relationship, in
6 other words, in the slope. The entrepreneurial activity
We exclude Taiwan from our analysis because comparable
GDP per capita data are not available for the country in the level differs according to the country’s level of
World Bank’s database. development. It is collectivism that favours TEA in

123
Relationship between individualism–collectivism and entrepreneurship 31

Table 1 Correlationship matrix


Mean 1 2 3 4 5 6

1 TEA 10.27 1
2 TEA_Opp 7.29 0.959* 1
3 TEA_Nec 2.75 0.887* 0.754* 1
4 INDCOL 47.25 -0.533* -0.424* -0.582* 1
5 GDPPC 14,104.88 -0.550* -0.438* -0.614* 0.624* 1
6 DEVELOP_LEVEL 0.52 -0.587* -0.468* -0.656* 0.602* 0.854* 1
* Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level

developing countries (Hypothesis 2) but individual- 5 Results


ism that favours TEA in developed countries
(Hypothesis 3). Table 2 reports the results of the regression. Model 1
The estimated model is as follows: includes INDCOL and GDPPC; Model 2 (Eq. 1)
includes INDCOL, GDPPC, and the interaction term
TEA ¼ a þ bINDCOL þ cDEVELOP LEVEL
between INDCOL and GDPPC; Model 3 (Eq. 2)
þ dINDCOL DEVELOP LEVEL þ e ð2Þ
includes INDCOL, the dummy variable DEVELO-
For relatively poor countries, the variable DEVEL- P_LEVEL, and the interaction term between DEVEL-
OP_LEVEL equals 0. If the second hypothesis is OP_LEVEL and INDCOL. Models 4 and 5 include the
correct, then b must be less than 0, so Eq. 27 can be same variables as Model 3 (i.e., INDCOL, the dummy
written as follows: variable DEVELOP_LEVEL, and the interaction term
between DEVELOP_LEVEL and INDCOL), and the
TEA poor ¼ a  bINDCOL þ e ð3Þ
dependent variables are TEA_Opp and TEA_Nec,
For relatively rich countries, the variable DEVEL- respectively.
OP_LEVEL equals 1, and Eq. 2 can be written as Comparing Model 2 to Model 1, we find that the
follows: addition of the interaction term increases the adjusted
TEA rich ¼ a  bINDCOL þ c 1 R2 considerably, from 0.33 to 0.56 (Hair et al. 1998).
The interaction term has the expected positive effect
þ dINDCOL 1 þ e
and is significant at 1%.8 Hence, the impact of
¼ ða þ cÞ þ ðd  bÞINDCOL þ e ð4Þ individualism increases with per-capita income. The
impact can be written as -0.096 ? 1.44 9 10-5
According to Hypothesis 3, (d - b) is greater than 0.
Table 1 reports the correlationships between the
8
variables used. The correlation between INDCOL and the interaction term
INDCOL*GDPPC was 0.81, which indicates the existence of
multicollinearity problems. Thus we transformed the variables
following Venkatraman’s (1989) procedure. This resulted in a fall
7
It should be pointed out that the model can be specified in in the correlation to only 0.16, suggesting no problems of
different ways (Allison 1977; Southwood 1978). One way multicollinearity. Venkatraman (1989, pp. 426–427) points out
involves carrying out a single regression, with TEA as the that ‘‘[a]lthough statistical estimation problems are posed by
dependent variable and two independent variables in the multicollinearity, it is not problematic for establishing the
equation: one with the INDCOL of the relatively rich countries existence of moderation effects. For interval-level measurements,
and the other with the INDCOL of the relatively poor a simple transformation of the scale of origin reduces the level of
countries. An alternative way of specifying the model is to correlation between the cross-product term, X  Z, and the
carry out two regressions, one for the relatively rich countries original variables (X, Z).[…]any equation [X1,X2,X  3 = X1  X2]
and the other for the relatively poor ones. Following Allison can be transformed into one X10 ; X20 ; X30 ¼ X10  X20 where X10 ¼
(1977), we opted to carry out a single regression using dummy ½X1 þ c and X20 ¼ ½X2 þ k, that is, the two equations express the
variables, because dummy variables permit subsets of the data same surface in the three dimensions [Y,X1,X2], except for the
to have regression functions with different intercepts and shift in the axes of X’’. We transformed the variables as follows
different slopes. In this way, the results for the various datasets (i is country index): INDCOL0i = INDCOLi - mean INDCOL,
can be compared in a stringent way, and statistical inference and GDPPC0i = GDPPCi - mean GDPPC.
becomes more efficient (Ghauri et al. 1995).

123
32 M.-J. Pinillos, L. Reyes

Table 2 Estimation results of Eqs. 1 and 2 (52 observations)


Dependent variable TEA TEA_Opp TEA_Nec
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

Constant 17.497* 16.072* 24.175* 17.262* 7.901*


INDCOL -0.09* -0.096* -0.295* -0.224* -0.094*
GDPPC -2.11 9 10-4* -2.65 9 10-4*
INDCOL*GDPPC 1.44 9 10-5*
DEVELOP_LEVEL -20.969* -15.966* -6.930*
DEVELOP_LEVEL*INDCOL 0.346* 0.286* 0.096*
R 0.60 0.76 0.78 0.73 0.76
R2 0.36 0.58 0.61 0.53 0.58
2
Adjusted R 0.33* 0.56* 0.58* 0.50* 0.56*
F 13.876* 22.412* 24.704* 17.886* 21.441*
* Significant at 0.001 level

GDPPC. This expression equals 0 for a per-capita of individualism, the higher the TEA. In contrast, in
income level of about US$ 6,666. Hence, only beyond developing countries, the slope is negative, in other
this level do increasing individualism levels benefit words the greater the level of individualism, the lower
entrepreneurial activity. For comparison, 28 out of the the TEA. The corresponding p-value shows that the
52 countries in our dataset have a per-capita income difference in the slope is significantly different to 0.
level exceeding US$ 6,666. The same results are obtained when the TEA is
In Model 3, the regression coefficients are all measured taking into account the motivations driving the
significantly different to 0, and the regression is entrepreneurial activity (Models 4 and 5). The adjusted
statistically significant, with an adjusted R2 of 0.58. R2 for Models 4 and 5 gives values of 0.50 and 0.56,
The estimated regression equation is as follows: respectively. In other words, over 50% of the variance in
TEA_Opp and TEA_Nec is explained. Model 4 can be
TEA ¼ 24:175  0:295INDCOL
written for the relatively poor countries as TEA_Opp
 20:969DEVELOP LEVEL
poor = 17.26 - 0.224INDCOL, and for the relatively
þ 0:346DEVELOP LEVEL INDCOL
rich countries as TEA_Opp rich = 1.296 ? 0.062IND-
The multiple regression function has the following COL. Model 5 can be written for the relatively poor
interpretation. The coefficient of the dummy variable countries as TEA_Nec poor = 7.901 - 0.094IND-
DEVELOP_LEVEL estimates the differences in TEA COL, and for the relatively rich countries as TEA_Nec
level between the two groups of countries. The rich = 0.971 ? 0.002INDCOL.
estimated difference is -20.969, and the p-value shows In short, the relationship between individualism
that the difference is significantly different to 0. and entrepreneurial activity (whether the motivation
For the relatively poor countries, the estimated is necessity or opportunity) is statistically significant.
regression equation can be written as follows: The relationship is positive for the relatively rich
TEA poor ¼ 24:175  0:295INDCOL countries and negative for the relatively poor ones.
It can be seen from the analysis of all the results
For the relatively rich countries, the estimated that the I–C predicts the TEA rates. With these results
regression equation can be written as follows: we can accept the three proposed hypotheses.
TEA rich ¼ 24:175  0:295INDCOL
 20:969 1 þ 0:346 1 INDCOL
6 Conclusions and implications
¼ 3:206 þ 0:051INDCOL
In short, and as expected, in the developed countries We have stated that levels of entrepreneurial activity
the slope is positive, in other words the greater the level differ enormously between countries, even between

123
Relationship between individualism–collectivism and entrepreneurship 33

countries with similar levels of economic develop- individualism and argues that both individualism and
ment. The stability of these differences has led us to collectivism contribute to entrepreneurial activity.
propose that such a disparity could not be explained The results obtained here show that neither individ-
only through variables of an economic nature, but ualism nor collectivism necessarily predict the level
that other factors such as culture might be determi- of entrepreneurship, but rather that the relationship is
nants of these differences. moderated by the level of economic development.
Individualism has traditionally been positively Hui and Triandis (1986) argue that collectivism
linked with entrepreneurial activity, arguing that the can be succinctly defined using the word ‘‘concern’’,
search for personal objectives (a dominant aspect in which refers to commitment and ties to others. In
individualist cultures) would be positively associated countries with a collectivist culture and low levels of
with the entrepreneurial spirit, and indeed, in some economic development, such ‘‘concern’’ for others
studies, empirical evidence has been found for this drives forward the search for a business opportunity
relationship. However, in other studies the opposite that allows the group to improve while at the same
relationship has been argued, with some empirical time satisfying the need for affiliation, a characteristic
support, in other words, that there is a positive trait of businesspeople in collectivist cultures, as
relationship between collectivism and entrepreneurial verified by Baum et al. (1993). However, in devel-
activity. oped countries, entrepreneurial activity is associated
Thomas and Mueller (2000) have stated that when with personal achievement, not forgetting the premise
differences exist in culture or in economic systems, that the entrepreneurial spirit can also find a place
conventional theories (mainly aimed at developed among larger firms in developed countries without
countries) could not explain the effects observed and the need to create other new ones, and this fact is
the behaviour particularly when interaction with the consistent with the fact that TEA is less in these
environment needs to be taken into account. This countries.
suggests that both economic and cultural factors The relationship among individualism, level of
should be taken into account simultaneously. Along economic development and new firm creation is a
this line of analysis, Wennekers et al. (2005) state central topic in the field of entrepreneurship. In this
that the level of development could interact with study, we have used moderated regressions in order
other determining factors of the level of entrepre- to explore the moderating effect of the level of
neurial activity. Wennekers et al. (2005) see that the economic development on the relationship between
relationship between the rate of start-up firms and individualism and new firm creation. The results of
that of economic development is not linear, but has a the analysis have shown that the level of economic
U-shape, which indicates that the sign of the development is critical because it establishes the
relationship changes at a certain level of economic context in which to assess the relationships between
development and that, moreover, there may be effects individualism–collectivism and new firm creation.
on interaction in the sense that the level of economic In short, both orientations (individualism and
development influences the effects of other deter- collectivism) can contribute to firm creation. The
mining factors. most important implication in this study, in terms of
Using a broad sample of 52 countries that have adopting policy measures, is that the level of
participated in the GEM study, we have herein been economic development and culture, I–C should not
able to verify that, although the individualist–collec- be regarded independently: both variables interact in
tivist spirit of a country is related to entrepreneurial their relationship with entrepreneurial activity. As
activity, it cannot be stated that a greater level of these factors (level of development and culture) are
individualism results in higher levels of entrepre- of a structural nature (Wennekers et al. 2005), the
neurial activity, but rather that this relationship is differences in the levels of entrepreneurial activity
modified by the level of economic development. tend to remain stable. Consequently, in the short
The results of the current study support Tiessen’s term, the influence of government policies for driving
(1997) work, in which this author breaks with the entrepreneurial activity may be extremely modest. In
initial idea that entrepreneurship is associated with the long term, policies may have a greater impact

123
34 M.-J. Pinillos, L. Reyes

through the gradual evolution of culture and devel- individualist/collectivist dimension of culture consti-
opment. Moreover, in line with the results of our tutes a longlasting cultural value, which is stable over
research, in order to be effective, any policy measure time and is hard to manipulate; Sondergaard (1994),
will have to be different for each country according to in his study of the reviews, citations and replies to the
individual levels of economic development and I–C work of Hofstede, highlights the fact that the
culture, breaking away from the idea that individu- differences foreseen by Hofstede’s dimensions have
alism is always positively correlated to entrepreneur- been widely confirmed, and in particular that of the
ial activity. In countries with a lower average wage, I–C; more recently, Kirkman et al. (2006) concluded
measures should be encouraged that affect the that studies published from the viewpoint of the
satisfaction of the need for affiliation (such as Hofstede (1980) study have upheld and increased
promoting cooperatives), although for more devel- their conclusions. Moreover, differences foreseen
oped countries, the emphasis should lay on the between countries are maintained, and thus ‘‘Hofst-
satisfaction of other needs such as self-realisation and ede’s values are clearly relevant for additional cross-
personal achievement. cultural research’’ (Kirkman et al. 2006, p. 308). In
Our conclusions would complement the recom- addition, Hofstede (2001, p. 34) claims ‘‘that national
mendations made by Wennekers et al. (2005) on cultures are extremely stable over time’’. He argues
concrete measures for economic policy that would be that ‘‘… this stability can be explained from the
more effective in accordance with the level of reinforcement of culture patterns by the institutions
economic development of each country. that themselves are products of the dominant cultural
In short, we believe that the current study is value systems’’. In the long run, ‘‘cultures shift, but
important because it provides empirical evidence they shift in formation, so that the differences
supporting the following conclusions: firstly, the between them remain intact’’ (Hofstede 2001,
country’s level of development moderates the rela- p. 255). In the same sense, Inglehart and Welzel
tionship between culture and entrepreneurship; sec- (2005), from data on the study of values in the
ondly, a country’s individualist–collectivist culture is countries involved from data proceeding from coun-
associated with its level of entrepreneurship; thirdly, tries in several successive waves of data (1981, 1990,
for countries with a medium/low development level, 1995, 1999, and 2000), indicate the fact that society,
the higher the collectivist orientation is, the higher albeit historically Protestant, Orthodox, Islamic or
the level of entrepreneurship (measured as TEA, TEA Confucianist, generates cultures with distinctive
opportunity, and TEA necessity); fourthly, for devel- value systems, which persist even when the effects
oped countries, the higher the individualist orienta- of economic development are controlled. Although in
tion is, the higher the level of entrepreneurship the long term, value systems can evolve, value
(measured as TEA, TEA opportunity and TEA systems of different societies have not converged,
necessity). and cultural differences were empirically as large in
Lastly, it is necessary to consider some of the 2001 as they were 20 years before.
possible limitations of our study. The first is the time Moreover, Chaps. 2 and 5 of Hofstede’s book
gap between the measurements of entrepreneurial present abundant statistical information on the sta-
activity and measuring the level of individualism. bility and reliability of the I–C index. All of this,
Some authors have questioned to what extent Hofst- therefore, leads us to coincide with the ideas of
ede’s cultural measurement (which we have used Wennekers et al. (2007, p. 148) (although these
here) is still valid in the present day (Tang and authors refer to indices of uncertainty avoidance and
Koveos 2008) considering the data were collected by we refer to the I–C index) when they state ‘‘[o]ur best
Hofstede between 1967 and 1969 and again between assessment is that this index can be used for
1971 and 1973. There is no doubt that the stability of explaining national rates of entrepreneurship during
the I–C index is a crucial aspect of our study, and we several decades following the measurement of the
would underline that there is scientific research that index’’.
supports its validity in a more recent context. In this The second limitation concerns the supposed
sense, McGrath et al. (1992b) verify that the excessive simplification of Hofstede’s cultural model

123
Relationship between individualism–collectivism and entrepreneurship 35

(Schepers 2006). However, Hofstede (2006) defends entrepreneurial activity. Following the path marked
his model by arguing that humans have only limited out by Wennekers et al. (2002) and Hunt and Levie
capacity to process information in their minds, so (2003), it would be interesting to find out if individ-
models that are too complex are unlikely to be useful. uals’ perception of well-being also moderates the
The clarity and simplicity of the indicators in I–C–TEA relationship. Such a study, which could use
Hofstede’s model mean that researchers still consider data from the World Values Survey (Inglehart 1997),
them to be particularly useful when analysing cultural would add a perspective that sheds more light on this
differences across countries (Kirkman et al. 2006). important question.
Finally, the current study uses GDPPC (an objec-
tive indicator of a country’s level of economic
development) to analyse the relationship between Appendix I
I–C and TEA. Future research might usefully exam-
ine how individuals’ perception of well-being affects See Table 3.

Table 3 Clusters of countries and mean TEA rate


Developing countries TEA (%) Developed countries TEA (%)

Argentina 12.4 Australia 11.9


Brazil 12.8 Austria 3.8
Colombia 22.6 Belgium 3.4
Croatia 5.3 Canada 8.5
Chile 13.3 Czech Republic 7.9
China 14.0 Denmark 5.3
Ecuador 27.2 Finland 5.3
Hungary 6.2 France 3.9
India 10.9 Germany 5.0
Indonesia 19.3 Greece 6.5
Jamaica 18.7 Hong Kong, China 4.9
Jordan 18.3 Ireland 7.9
Korea, Rep. 14.4 Israel 5.7
Malaysia 11.1 Italy 5.1
Mexico 10.6 Japan 2.6
Peru 35.5 Netherlands 4.9
Philippines 20.4 New Zealand 15.1
Poland 7.7 Norway 8.1
Russian Federation 4.3 Portugal 6.6
Serbia 8.6 Singapore 5.1
South Africa 6.0 Slovenia 4.2
Thailand 20.4 Spain 6.2
Turkey 5.8 Sweden 4.1
Uruguay 12.4 Switzerland 6.7
Venezuela 24.1 United Arab Emirates 6.1
United Kingdom 5.8
United States 10.9
N = 25 countries that have participated in at least one GEM N = 27 countries that have participated in at least one GEM
edition and have I–C culture and GDP per capita data available edition and have I–C culture and GDP per capita data available

123
36 M.-J. Pinillos, L. Reyes

References Franke, R. H., Hofstede, G., & Bon, M. H. (1991). Cultural


roots of economic performance: A research note. Strategic
Acs, Z. J., Audretsch, D. B., & Evans, D. E. (1994). The Management Journal, 12(S1), 165–173.
determinants of variations in self-employment rates across Ghauri, P., Gronhaug, K., & Kristianslund, I. (1995). Research
countries over time. Discussion paper 871. Center for methods in business studies. London: Prentice Hall.
Economic Policy Research, London. Hair, J. F., Anderson, R. E., Tatham, R. L., & Black, W. C.
Acs, Z. J., Arenius, P., Hay, M., & Minniti, M. (2005). GEM, (1998). Multivariate data analysis (5th ed.). Upper Saddle
global entrepreneurship monitor, 2004 executive report. River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Babson Park, MA, USA and London, UK: Babson Col- Hayton, J. C., George, G., & Zahra, S. A. (2002). National
lege and London Business School. culture and entrepreneurship: A review of behavioral
Allison, P. D. (1977). Testing for interaction in multiple regres- research. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 26(4),
sion. American Journal of Sociology, 83(1), 144–153. 33–52.
Audretsch, D. B., Thurik, A. R., Verheul, I., & Wennekers, A. Hofstede, G. (1980). Culture’s consequences: International
R. M. (Eds.). (2002). Entrepreneurship: Determinants and differences in work-related values. Beverly Hills, CA:
policy in a European-US comparison. Boston/Dordrecht: Sage Publications.
Kluwer Academic Publishers. Hofstede, G. (1991). Cultures and organizations: Software of
Baron, R. M., & Kenny, D. A. (1986). The moderator-mediator the mind. London, UK: McGraw Hill.
variable distinction in social psychological research: Con- Hofstede, G. (2001). Culture’s consequences (2nd ed.).
ceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations. Journal of Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.
Personality and Social Psychology, 51(6), 1173–1182. Hofstede, G. (2006). What did GLOBE really measure?
Baum, J. R., Olian, J. D., Erez, M., Schnell, E. R., Smith, K. G., Researchers’ minds versus respondents’ minds. Journal of
Sims, H. P., et al. (1993). Nationality and work role International Business Studies, 37(6), 882–896.
interactions: A cultural contrast of Israeli and U.S. Hofstede, G., Noorderhaven, N. G., Thurik, A. R., Uhlaner, L.
entrepreneurs’ versus managers’ needs. Journal of Busi- M., Wennekers, A. R. M., & Wildeman, R. E. (2004).
ness Venturing, 8(6), 499–512. Culture’s role in entrepreneurship: Self-employment out
Baumol, W. J. (1996). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unpro- of dissatisfaction. In J. Ulijn & T. Brown (Eds.), Inno-
ductive, and destructive. Journal of Business Venturing, vation, entrepreneurship and culture: The interaction
11(1), 3–22. between technology, progress and economic growth
Blanchflower, D. G. (2000). Self-employment in OECD (pp. 162–203). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Countries. Labour Economics, 7(5), 471–505. Hui, C. H., & Triandis, H. C. (1986). Individualism-collecti-
Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (1994). The wage curve. vism: A study of cross-cultural researchers. Journal of
Cambridge, MA: MIT. Cross-Cultural Psychology, 17(2), 225–248.
Blau, D. (1987). A time series analysis of self-employment. Hunt, S., & Levie, J. (2003). Culture as a predictor of entre-
Journal of Political Economy, 95(3), 445–467. preneurial activity. In W. D. Bygrave (Ed.), Frontiers of
Bond, R., & Smith, P. B. (1996). Culture and conformity: A entrepreneurship research 2003 (pp. 171–185). Welles-
meta-analysis of studies using Asch’s (1952b, 1956) line ley, MA: Babson College.
judgment task. Psychological Bulletin, 119(1), 111–137. Inglehart, R. (1997). Modernization and postmodernization.
Bosma, N., & Harding, R. (2007). GEM, global entrepre- Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
neurship monitor, 2006, executive report. Babson Park, Inglehart, R., & Baker, W. E. (2000). Modernization, cultural
MA, USA and London, UK: Babson College and London change, and the persistence of traditional values. American
Business School. Sociological Review, 65(1), 19–51.
Carree, M., Van Stel, A., Thurik, R., & Wennekers, S. (2002). Inglehart, R., & Welzel, C. (2005). Modernization, cultural
Economic development and business ownership: An change and democracy: The human development
analysis using data of 23 OECD countries in the period of sequence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
1976–1996. Small Business Economics, 19(3), 271–290. Kirkman, L. B., Lowe, K. B., & Gibson, C. B. (2006). A
Davidson, P., & Wiklund, J. (1997). Values, beliefs and quarter century of culture’s consequences: A review of
regional variations in new firm formation rates. Journal of empirical research incorporating Hofstede’s cultural val-
Economic Psychology, 18(2–3), 179–199. ues framework. Journal of International Business Studies,
Davidsson, P. (1995). Culture, structure and regional levels of 37, 285–320.
entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship & Regional Devel- Kluckhohn, C. (1951). The study of culture. In D. Lerner & H.
opment, 7, 41–62. D. Lasswell (Eds.), The policy sciences (pp. 86–101).
Earley, P. C., & Gibson, C. B. (1998). Taking stock in our Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
progress on individualism–collectivism: 100 years of Kroeber, A. L., & Parsons, T. (1958). The concepts of culture
solidarity and community. Journal of Management, 24(3), and of social system. American Sociological Review,
265–304. 23(5), 582–590.
Erez, M., & Earley, P. C. (1993). Culture, self-identity and Locke, E. A., & Latham, G. P. (1990). A theory of goal setting
work. New York: Oxford University Press. and task performance. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
Evans, D. S., & Leighton, L. S. (1989). The determinants of Hall.
changes in US self-employment, 1968-1987. Small Busi- Maslow, A. (1954). Motivation and personality. New York:
ness Economics, 1(2), 111–119. Harper.

123
Relationship between individualism–collectivism and entrepreneurship 37

McGrath, R. G., MacMillan, I. C., & Scheinberg, S. (1992a). Stewart, W. H., & Roth, P. L. (2007). A meta-analysis of
Elitists, risk-takers, and rugged individualists? An achievement motivation differences between entrepre-
exploratory analysis of cultural differences between neurs and managers. Journal of Small Business Manage-
entrepreneurs and non-entrepreneurs. Journal of Business ment, 45(4), 401–421.
Venturing, 7(2), 115–135. Tang, L., & Koveos, P. E. (2008). A framework to update
McGrath, R. G., MacMillan, I. C., Yang, E. A., & Tsai, W. Hofstede’s cultural value indices: Economic dynamics
(1992b). Does culture endure, or is it malleable? Journal and institutional stability. Journal of International Busi-
of Business Venturing, 7(6), 441–458. ness Studies, 39(6), 1045–1063.
Meager, N. (1992). Does unemployment lead to self-employ- Thomas, A. S., & Mueller, S. L. (2000). A case for compara-
ment? Small Business Economics, 4(2), 87–103. tive entrepreneurship: Assessing the relevance of culture.
Minniti, M., Bygrave, W. D., & Autio, E. (2006). GEM, global Journal of International Business Studies, 31(2), 287–301.
entrepreneurship monitor, 2005, executive report. Babson Thurik, A. R., & Wennekers, S. (2004). Entrepreneurship,
Park, MA, US and London, UK: Babson College and small business and economic growth. Journal of Small
London Business School. Business and Enterprise Development, 11(1), 140–149.
Morris, M. H., Davis, D. L., & Allene, J. W. (1994). Fostering Tiessen, J. H. (1997). Individualism, collectivism, and entre-
corporate entrepreneurship: Cross-cultural comparisons of preneurship: A framework for international comparative
the importance of individualism versus collectivism. research. Journal of Business Venturing, 12(5), 367–384.
Journal of International Business Studies, 25(1), 65–89. Tödtling, F., & Wanzenböck, H. (2003). Regional differences
Mueller, S. L., & Thomas, A. S. (2001). Culture and entre- in structural characteristics of start-ups. Entrepreneurship
preneurial potential: A nine country study of locus of & Regional Development, 15(4), 351–370.
control and innovativeness. Journal of Business Ventur- Triandis, H. C. (1988). Collectivism vs. individualism: A
ing, 16(1), 51–75. reconceptualization of a basic concept in cross-cultural
Noorderhaven, N., Thurik, R., Wennekers, S., & van Stel, A. social psychology. In G. K. Verma & Y. C. Bagley (Eds.),
(2004). The role of dissatisfaction and per capita income in Cross-cultural studies of personality, attitudes, and cog-
explaining self-employment across 15 European countries. nition (pp. 60–95). London: Macmillan.
Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice, 28, 447–466. Triandis, H. C. (1995). Individualism and collectivism. Boul-
Oyserman, D., Coon, H. M., & Kemmelmeier, M. (2002). der, CO: Westview Press.
Rethinking individualism and collectivism: Evaluation of Triandis, H. C., & Suh, E. M. (2002). Cultural influences on
theoretical assumptions and meta-analyses. Psychological personality. Annual Review of Psychology, 53(1), 133–
Bulletin, 128(1), 3–72. 160.
Peterson, R. (1988). Understanding and encouraging entre- Trulsson, P. (1997). Strategies of entrepreneurship: Under-
preneurship internationally. Journal of Small Business standing industrial entrepreneurship and structural
Management, 26(2), 1–7. change in northwest Tanzania. Linköping, Sweden:
Reynolds, P. D., Bygrave, W. D., Autio, E., Cox, L. W., & Linköping University.
Hay, M. (2002). GEM, global entrepreneurship monitor, Uhlaner, L., & Thurik, R. (2007). Postmaterialism influencing
2002, executive report. Wellesley, MA: Babson College. total entrepreneurial activity across nations. Journal of
Schepers, D. H. (2006). Three proposed perspectives of attitude Evolutionary Economics, 17(2), 161–185.
toward business’ ethical responsibilities and their impli- Van Stel, A., Carree, M., & Thurik, R. (2005). The effect of
cations for cultural comparison. Business and Society entrepreneurial activity on national economic growth.
Review, 111(1), 15–36. Small Business Economics, 24(3), 311–321.
Schimmack, U., Oishi, S., & Diener, E. (2005). Individualism: Vandello, J. A., & Cohen, D. (1999). Patterns of individualism
A valid e important dimension of cultural differences and collectivism across the United States. Journal of
between nations. Personality and Social Psychology Personality and Social Psychology, 77(2), 279–292.
Review, 9(1), 17–31. Venkatraman, N. (1989). The concept of fit in strategy
Shane, S. (1992). Why do some societies invent more than research: Toward verbal and statistical correspondence.
others? Journal of Business Venturing, 7(1), 29–46. Academy of Management Review, 14(3), 423–444.
Shane, S. (1993). Cultural influences on national rates of Wennekers, S., Noorderhaven, N., Hofstede, G., & Thurik, R.
innovation. Journal of Business Venturing, 8(1), 59–73. (2002). Cultural and economic determinants of business
Sharma, S., Durand, R. M., & Gur-Arie, O. (1981). Identifi- ownership across countries. In W. D. Bygrave, E. Autio,
cation and analysis of moderator variables. Journal of C. G. Brush, P. Davidsson, P. G. Greene, P. D. Reynolds,
Marketing Research, 18, 291–300. & H. J. Sapienza (Eds.), Frontiers of entrepreneurship
Sondergaard, M. (1994). Research note: Hofstede’s conse- research 2002 (pp. 179–190). Wellesley, MA: Babson
quences: A study of reviews, citations and replications. College.
Organization Studies, 15(3), 447–456. Wennekers, S., van Stel, A., Thurik, R., & Reynolds, P. (2005).
Southwood, K. E. (1978). Substantive theory and statistical Nascent entrepreneurship and the level of economic
interaction: Five models. The American Journal of Soci- development. Small Business Economics, 24(3), 293–309.
ology, 83(5), 1154–1203. Wennekers, S., Thurik, R., van Stel, A., & Noorderhaven, N.
Sternberg, R., & Wennekers, S. (2005). Determinants and (2007). Uncertainty avoidance and the rate of business
effects of new business creation using global entrepre- ownership across 21 OECD countries, 1976–2004. Jour-
neurship monitor data. Small Business Economics, 24(3), nal of Evolutionary Economics, 17(2), 133–160.
193–203.

123

View publication stats

You might also like