Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 17

CPA Switches and Associated Market Reactions

Author(s): Dov Fried and Allen Schiff


Source: The Accounting Review, Vol. 56, No. 2 (Apr., 1981), pp. 326-341
Published by: American Accounting Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/245816
Accessed: 26-01-2016 03:55 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Accounting Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Accounting
Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW
Vol. LVI, No. 2
April 1981

CPA Switches and Associated


Market Reactions
Dov Friedand Allen Schiff

ABSTRACT: In 1978, the Securities and Exchange Commission issued its final require-
ments concerning the disclosure requirements of companies that change their auditors.
Along with a filing requirement for an auditor change, companies were also required to
enumerate and describe disagreements they may have had with their CPAs on accounting
and auditing issues in the 18 months prior to the change. To provide evidence on the
existence and degree of market impact of these disclosure requirements, the behavior of
stock prices of a sample of companies that switched auditors and a matched pair of
control companies that did not were analyzed. Results of the study appear to be in-
consistent with the SEC requirement for companies to enumerate and describe disagree-
ments with their auditors. For the general event of auditor changes, there seems to be
negative market reaction around the time of the switch; however, there is some difficulty
in interpreting the motivation for this reaction.

IN 1971, the Securities and Exchange whether the auditor change was recom-
Commission (SEC) initiated its re- mended or approved by their audit com-
quirement that publicly held com- mittees and their boards. However, the
panies file 8-K reports within 15 days SEC rejected a proposed rule that would
following a change in the registrant's have required a company to state its
certifying accountant [Coopers & Ly- reason for switching to new auditors
brand, 1979]. The requirement was beyond disagreements on accounting
viewed as another step in disclosing the issues [SEC ASR No. 247, 1978]. Instead,
relationship between a company and its the SEC simply urged disclosure of non-
auditor. This perceived need was articu- accounting information beyond the mini-
lated by John C. Burton, the SEC's mum requirement.
chief accountant at that time, as a step In the period 1971-1976, a large num-
"in the development of more complete ber of companies switched auditors, and
disclosure of the auditor-client relation-
The authors would like to acknowledge the helpful
ship." ["The SEC Bears Down Harder comments of Joel Owen, Joshua Livnat, Michael Schiff,
on Disclosure," 1974, pp. 33-37]. Along George Sorter, and the anonymous reviewers. Also,
with the filing requirement for a switch thanks are due to Janet Landis and Linda Volkert for
from one CPA firm to another, a com- their technical assistance.
pany was also required to enumerate and Dov Fried is Assistant Professor of
describe disagreements it may have had Accounting, New York University, and
with its auditor on accounting and audit- Allen Schiff is Associate Professor of
ing issues in the 18 months before the Accounting, Fordham University.
change.
In addition, under an amendment to Manuscript received September 1978.
the SEC's accounting rules, effective July Revisions received November 1979 and March 1980.
31, 1978, registrants also had to disclose Accepted June 1980.

326

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Fried and Schiff 327

a number of reasons have been given for more flexibleinterpretationand applica-


these changes: tion of accountingstandards,one would
have to identify which of the Big Eight
1. CPA firms assumed a more con- CPA firms,for example,are more or less
servative posture in interpreting and inclined to flexibility. Gosman [1973]
applying accounting standards as a attemptedto classifythe Big Eight firms
reaction to an increased number of
by identifyingthe frequencywith which
lawsuits.
they issued consistencyqualificationsin
2. The SEC increased disclosure re-
annual reports.He could not prove that
quirements. the frequencyof occurrenceof suchquali-
3. Economic conditions in the 1970s
ficationswas a function of one or more
deteriorated and corporate manage- identifiablefirms.A morerecentstudyby
ments were hard-pressed to produce
Eggleton et al. [1976] attempted to
constantly increasing earnings per
associate CPA firms with a particular
share in their annual reports
policy regarding a specific accounting
["Companies vs. Auditors," 1974, change. If proved, this could be a cause
pp. 33, 35]. for a shift by clientsfavoringa particular
Other suggested reasons for auditor accountingpolicy. Theirresultswerenot
switches include management change, conclusive.
changes in auditor fee structure, need for Because of the lack of statistically
additional services, regular rotation meaningfulresults in previous attempts
policy, and new financing (the switch to identifyparticularaccountingcharac-
made in response to a suggestion by a teristicswith particularCPA firms as a
lender or as a result of management's general motivation for switching and
impression that a larger CPA would lend becauseof associateddisclosurerequire-
more prestige to the security offering) ments, we have looked at this problem
[Bedingfieldand Loeb, 1974]. froma differentviewpoint.Ourapproach
As one SEC staff member commented, was to examinethe moregeneralquestion
"Auditors and companies are disagreeing of whetherCPA switcheswereassociated
more these days because the companies with significantmarketreactions.At the
want to do what the auditors taught them sametime,we wereinterestedin isolating
in the late Sixties, and now the auditors, and observingto what extent the SEC
afraid of expensive lawsuits, are saying disclosurerequirement,as it relatedto the
no" ["Companies vs. Auditors," 1974, reporting of conflict, was "justifiable."
pp. 33, 35]. It should be noted that the This, of course,includesthe possibilityof
reasons listed above are interrelated, for the synergisticeffects discussed above,
if, indeed, accountants had become more i.e., economic conditions causing a dis-
conservative some switches in outside agreement over accounting principles.
auditors would have occurred. However, Thus, a CPA switch may be viewed by
when one adds the elements of relatively the market as an informationsignal of
depressed economic conditions and more changing economic conditions for the
extensive disclosure requirements, the companies. Independentof the motiva-
result is likely to be synergistic, thus, tion for the auditorchange, a disclosure
substantially increasing the probable inci- requirementwould not be inconsistent
dence of external auditor changes. with an environmentof marketreaction
If one assumes that the motivation for aroundthe time of a CPA switch. If, on
switching auditors would be to secure the other hand, no reaction occurred,

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
328 The AccountingReview,April 1981

TABLE I
OF SAMPLEBY REASONOF AUDITOR CHANGEAND TYPE OF PRACTICE
CLASSIFICATION

Big Eight To Non-Big Eight Big Eight To Non-Big Eight To


Reason Big Eight To Big Eight Non-Big Eight Non-Big Eight Total

StatedNo Conflict 16 6 2 1 25
Rotation 2 2
AuditCommittee 2 2
Lawsuit I I
Conformto Subsidiary I I
No Referenceto Reason 5 1 1 7
Disagreement-Conflict 6 6
Disagreement-Conflict 4 4
Not Resolved
Total 37 7 2 2 48

then the disclosure of the switch would be Return tape of the Center for Research
viewed as a "nonevent" by the market. on Security Prices (CRSP) prior to the
The market would have already dis- announcement date were included in our
counted for any economic events (if any sample. In addition, we eliminated those
had ever existed) causing the switch, companies that were subsequently taken
thereby making the disclosure super- off the CRSP tape (and/or were delisted
fluous. by the New York Stock Exchange) after
The remainder of this study is divided the disclosure date. This was done to
into four sections. The first section is remove from our sample those compan-
devoted to a discussion of our sample ies that changed auditors as a result of
selection procedures. The second section mergers or were placed under receiver-
states our hypothesis, and the following ship.'
section focuses on research design. The Daily returns (adjusted for stock splits)
last section describes our results and were then obtained from the CRSP Daily
conclusions. Returns tape (December 1976 version)
for each of the companies in the sample.
PROCEDURES
SAMPLESELECTION These daily returns were then converted
The names of the companies that to weekly returns and then annualized by
switched their auditors in the four years the procedure outlined in Kaplan and
1972 through 1975 were obtained from Roll [1972]. Daily returns for the market
CorporateProfiles and Index of Corporate as a whole were also obtained from the
Events [Disclosure, Inc., 1975]. The CRSP tape and converted to a weekly
Index provides a chronological record of basis in the same fashion. These proce-
reports and filings of New York Stock dures resulted in a sample of 48 com-
Exchange, American Stock Exchange, panies.
and Over The Counter companies. From Table 1, derived from the 8-K reports
this Index, we also obtained dates of the of our sample companies, describes the
8-K filings to be used as our announce- I This sample procedure may result in a bias of
ment dates. Out of the total number of "survivorship" in our sample. However, it was felt that
companies that switched CPA firms in for companies which went into receivership and/or
merged, the likelihood was that any market response
the years 1972-1975, only those com- would be due to other events (of which the auditor switch
panies that were included on the Daily was only a by-product) rather than the switch itself.

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Fried and Schiff 329

nature of the change in auditors in our STATEMENT OF HYPOTHESES


sample in terms of type of practiceand As stated above, our overall objective
reason for the change. By "type of prac- was to examinewhethera changein audi-
tice,"we meanthe directionof the change tors is associatedwith significantmarket
in CPA firms,i.e., a Big Eight CPA firm reaction.In addition,we were interested
to or from a non-BigEight firm.As may in examining whether the SEC's dis-
be observed from Table 1, most of the closure requirementas it related to the
switches were toward large CPA firms. reportingof conflictsbetweenCPAs and
The reasonfor this directionseems to be clients was justifiable.
that our sampleis composedof relatively Morespecifically,ourgeneralhypothe-
largecompanieswhich are morelikely to sis (Hypothesis I) may be stated as:
use national CPA firms (see Schiff and Users view all switches with suspicion,
Fried [1976]). i.e., negatively.Statingthis formally,we
Table 1 also indicates the reported have:
reasons for an auditor switch. It can be
seen that 25 companies reported that (I) Ho: d (all companies)? 0
therewas no disagreementwith the previ- versusthe alternativehypothesis:
ous accountanton any accounting,dis-
closure, or auditing issue, and they did H1: d (all companies)< 0
not volunteer any other reasons for the whered (*) representsthe marketreaction
change. Ten companies reported dis- to the changein auditors.2
agreementswith their CPAs, and, in six The potential for negative reactions
of thesecases,the conflictwas resolvedto comes about becausea changein auditor
the satisfactionof both the client and the may weakenthe investors'notion of the
auditor. In cases where these conflicts independencebetweenthe companyand
were not resolved, the results were a the auditor [SEC ASR 165, 1974]. A
"qualified" audit opinion, dismissal of weakeningin independence,in the words
the CPA, and/or a reluctantacceptance of the SEC, could result in a loss of
by the client of the CPA's recommenda- "confidencein financialstatements"[SEC
tion. Among the issues of disagreement ASR 247, 1978].The companywould be
were: asset valuation, the timing of perceivedas wantingto change auditors
revenuerecognition,and the scope of the to obtain what the SEC refers to as
audit. Reasonsgiven by othercompanies "more favorableaccountingtreatment"
for changing auditorswere: audit com- on the financial statements [SEC ASR
mittee recommendation,a desire to ro- 165, 1974]. Underlying Hypothesis I is
tate auditors,a preferencefor one auditor the implicit assumptionthat the skepti-
of all subsidiaries,and a future lawsuit. cism with respectto financialstatements
Seven companies made no referenceat might ariseif it were felt that companies
all to any disagreementor to any other wanted to suppress information that
reason. could produce a negative impact on
The distributionof the typesof reasons investors'perceptionsof futureexpected
and, specifically,the percentageof com- earnings.
paniesthat reporteda clear-cutdisagree- Testing for the "justifiability"of the
ment with their formerfirmof CPAs are
similarto the findingsof otherdescriptive 2
For this hypothesis and the other two to follow,
studies (e.g., Bedingfield and Loeb rejection of the null would be consistent with the motiva-
[1974]; AICPA [1976]). tion which led to the particular test.

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
330 The Accounting Review, April 1981

SEC disclosure requirement for conflicts TABLE2

implies that a lack of user reliance occurs SAMPLEPARTITIONS


primarilywhen a conflict between auditor
and client is present. That is, the argu- Group Description # in Group
ments presented previously for Hypothe- A Companies that switched to "same 31
sis I would prevail when the market is size" CPA firm and did not report
informed that a conflict has indeed a conflict with their auditors.*
occurred, since the reported conflict B Companies that switched to the 10
would then reflectmanagement's pressure same size" CPA firm and did report
on the auditor to give a clean opinion on a conflict with their auditors.
financial statements that, at a minimum, C Companies that switched to a Big 7
should be qualified and, at a maximum, Eight CPA firm and did not report
fraudulently mislead the public.3 a conflict.
Hypothesis II may be stated as: users * Included in Group A were two companies that
view "with suspicion" only those switches switched from a Big Eight CPA firm to a smaller firm
where the company states that it has been and did not report a conflict with their auditors. The
omission or inclusion of these companies did not alter
in conflict with its auditor. More for- our results.
mally, we have:
vidually introduces a problem of multiple
(II) Ho: d("conflict" companies) ? 0 hypothesis-testing. This problem mani-
versus the alternative hypothesis fests itself in two ways. First, testing on
an individual basis can lead to an under-
H1: d ("conflict" companies) < 0 stating of the a level (probability of Type
It can be argued, however, that a nega- I error) when viewed from the perspective
tive reaction by users would occur only if of all companies that switched CPA
they were to find no other motivation to firms. That is, testing a sequence of
explain the change in auditor. Thus, those hypotheses can result in one of the hy-
companies that switched from non-Big potheses being rejected by mere chance.
Eight CPA firms to Big Eight CPA firms Secondly, we face a possible jointness
may be perceived as obtaining improved problem in that Hypothesis II, for exam-
auditing service and generating more ple, could be considered as our test to see
reliable financial statements, and conse- whether the SEC requirement, as it
quently one might expect to observe a related to reporting conflicts, was justi-
nonnegative reaction associated with this fiable. Suppose, now, we were to find
type of CPA switch. This latter argument significant results by testing Hypothesis
may also be stated more formally as II. This does not mean that we could
Hypothesis III: necessarily conclude that a conflict results
in "bad" news. The reason for this result
(III) Ho: d (companies that change to is that if the null for Hypothesis I were
Big Eight firms)< 0
also rejected (i.e., all CPA switches have
versus H1: d (companies that change to
bad news associated with them), there
Big Eight firms) > 0 might be no justification for the special
These hypotheses imply a partitioning SEC requirement relating to reporting a
of our sample (based on the categories in conflict, unless it can be shown that a
Table 1) into the groups presented in I For further discussion on the motivation to disclose
Table 2. conflict on accounting issues, see Barlev and Benston
However, testing each hypothesis indi- [1974].

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Fried and Schiff 331

change with conflict is "worse" news than (significance level) probability of a Type I
a change without conflict. This potential error for all possible weightings (hy-
problem then implies a need for a proce- potheses).
dure to test for differences between reac- From a "theoretical" point of view, it
tions to Group A and Group B. Similar is necessary for the multivariate T2 tests
arguments can be made with respect to to show significance before testing the
Hypothesis III. univariate t-scores on an EB level. This
To overcome these problems, we need arises because the multivariate T2
turned to a multivariate test-the Hotel- test finds the weighting that maximizes
ling T2 statistic. This test examines the t-test result, whereas the individual
simultaneously all possible linear combi- t-tests are constrained to a specific
nations of the market reactions of Groups weighting.
A, B, and C. More specifically, the Controlling for the a level, by setting a
Hotelling T2 statistic tests the null high critical level, however, increases the
hypothesis: probability of committing a Type II
error for an individual hypothesis (i.e.,
Ho: aAd(A)+ aBd(B)+ acd(C) 0 (1) accepting the null when it is indeed false).8
against the alternative: For this reason, we present results for the
IB approach as well. The IB level ensures
H1: aAd(A)+ aBd(B)+ acd(C) O (2)
an a probability of Type I error for each
whereaA, aBand ac are weightings4of the weighting (hypothesis) individually. This
market reactions d(A), d(B), and d(C). level may show significance even if the
Setting aA= aB= ac = 1/3, for example, multivariate T2 does not, since lower
would be equivalent to testing Hy- critical levels are needed. These uni-
pothesis I. Similarly, if aA= aB= O and variate results, however, should be inter-
ac=1, or if aA=ac=O and aB=l, we preted with caution, since, as noted, on a
would be testing Hypotheses III and II, theoretical level, they may be biased.
respectively.5'6 That is, they may be due to chance as a
Rejection of the null hypothesis for the result of having tested sequentially a
T2 test does not, however, indicate which series of individual hypotheses.
of the weighting schemes contributed to
RESEARCH DESIGN
its rejection. In order to gain insight into
this issue, one must examine the univari- This section of the paper will describe
ate t-scores calculated for the pre-speci- the procedures undertaken to test our
fied weightings of interest consistent with
Hypotheses 1-111. These t-scores can be 4 The T2 statistic is invariant; i.e., it is unaffected by a
change in scale of the weightings (see Morrison [1967, p.
employed on two levels: an experiment- 119]). In our discussion, we have "normalized" the
wide basis (EB) and an individual basis weighting by imposing the constraint that they sum to
(IB). The t-scores calculated for both the one.
5 Other weightings, which would also be tested for,
EB and IB approaches are identical. The could be constructed that would test for differing re-
difference lies in the "theoretical" t-value sponses between partitions.
needed before any statement about rejec- 6 Ideally, a directional test would be more appropriate
to test our hypotheses, since they are one-sided. The T2
tion could be made. The EB approach test, however, is nondirectional.
which is "consistent" with the multi- 7 A discussion of the determination of the critical
variate T2 test requires a higher critical levels is presented in the Appendix.
8 That is, a null hypothesis which may indeed be false
level than the IB approach.7 That is to may get "lost" in the context of being viewed with the
say, the EB approach ensures an a other hypotheses.

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
332 The AccountingReview,April 1981

hypotheses. The issues addressed here are nouncement date.' Weekly returns were
selection of a control group, development then obtained for these candidates in the
of an operational definition for the mar- same manner as had been done for the
ket reaction to a switch (d(*)), fl-stability, sample firms. Betas were then generated
and the formulation of the statistical tests by the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS)
used. method for the sample and candidate
companies by using the following formu-
Selection of Control Group lation of the Capital Asset Pricing Model:
The procedure used in our study is
Rit = Rft + 13i(Rmt-Rft) + ej, (3)
based upon methods carried out by
Gonedes [19751 and Harrison [19771. where
The first step was to select a control group
of 48 companies which did not switch Rit= rate of return of the ith company
in period t, i.e., price change plus
auditors. Previous evidence, (e.g., King dividends for week t divided by
[1966]) indicated that general market price at beginning of week t.
conditions and, to a lesser degree, indus- Rft = "risk free" rate of return as
try-wide factors have an impact on a measured by the one-week yield
security's returns; thus, a control group on treasury bills
of companies was constructed which
matched each company in the sample and
with the following characteristics: Rmi= weekly market portfolio rate of
(1) the company's fi, which measures returns calculated from the daily
market returns provided on the
the co-movement of the firm's re-
CRSP tapes.
turns with the general market
return, and, The need for the Plsto be calculated on a
(2) where possible, the industry classi- weekly basis was motivated by the fact
fication of the company. that the statistical tests used in the study
were based upon weekly observations.
Industry classifications were based on The estimates of 1#were obtained by
the SIC classification code. The four- running the OLS regression on weekly
digit code was examined first. If no suit- observations spanning (approximately)
able match was found on this level (the the five-year period (249 weeks) around
absolute value of the difference in /3 is the announcement date, but omitting 24
greater than .5), we went to the three- weeks on either side of the announce-
digit and finally to the two-digit code. In ments. Notationally, if we set the week of
most cases-39 companies-we were the announcement as t = 0, the regression
able to obtain matches on at least the was run using 200 observations from the
two-digit level (25 of which were matched
period t= -124 to t= -25 and t=25 to
at the four-digit level). The remaining
nine companies were matched solely on IThese monthly betas were obtained from two
the basis of /. sources. The first source was a colleague (Joshua Livnat,
now at Hebrew University) who provided monthly
The companies placed in the control betas calculated (as in Equation (3)) every six months
group were selected from a group of (i.e., June and December) over the period 1970-1975
candidates whose monthly fs had already using the previous 60 months' observations. The second
source was the monthly issues of Merrill Lynch, Pierce,
been matched to our sample companies' Fenner & Smith's Security Risk Evaluation. In both cases,
monthly P3sby the use of data covering the candidates were selected based on the period preced-
the five-year period preceding the an- ing the announcement date.

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Fried and Schiff 333

TABLE 3 free security with Wiand 1- Wi acting as


FREQUENCY DISTRIBUTIONOF ABSOLUTE DIFFERENCES the respective weightings. The JJof any
BETWEENPREADJUSTEDfIS OF SAMPLECOMPANIES (weighted) portfolio is equal to the
AND CONTROLGROUP
(weighted) average of the fls of the in-
dividual securities which make up the
Deciles 0-.1 .J-.2 .2-.3 .3-.4 .4-S.5
portfolio. Thus, since the 1#of the risk-
# of Companies 23 8 9 5 3 free asset by definition equals zero, the
, of the newly generated "combined"
control security was exactly equal to that
t= 124.10 The 49 weeks closest to the of the corresponding sample company
announcement date were not included in (i.e., WjBc = B).
the regression so as to avoid possible
Measuring the Market's Response to a
distortion in the estimation of ft which
Switch
may result from "unusual" market activ-
ity around the time of the switch. The fls Using our sample and control "com-
calculated in this fashion were then panies," we were then able to generate an
screened to find the most suitable match empirical measure of the market's re-
for our sample companies. The frequency sponse to a switch that is equal to the dif-
distribution of the absolute difference ference between the returns of the sample
between the /3of our sample of companies company (Rjt(S))and control "company"
and the control group obtained in this (Rit(C )):
manner is presented in Table 3. The aver-
age , for our sample was 1.06 as com- dt(i) = Rit(S) - Rit(C) (5)
pared to 1.03 for the control companies. This measure would reflect the mar-
For partitions A, B, and C, the relevant ket's reaction to a CPA switch, because
figures were 1.03 and .97; .95 and .98; and the procedures used in selecting the con-
1.38 and 1.34, respectively. trol group ensure that the overall market
Because, for certain companies the dif- (and industry) factors affecting returns
ferences in 1#were relatively large, a final would be common to both the sample and
refinement was undertaken to ensure 1#- control companies. This difference-or
equivalence."1 Rather than using the abnormal return-therefore "reflects"
actual returns of the control securities, the market reaction to the CPA switch.
we combined the rate of return of the con- This latter statement holds true so long
trol securities (RI) with that of the risk- as the betas are stable over time. If the fls,
free asset (Rft) into a new combined asset however, do shift over time, then the dO(i)
Rit(C) defined as: measure would also capture the differing
reactions of the sample and control com-
Rit(C) = WiRc + (1 - Wi)Rft (4)
panies to overall market conditions and
where not only to the CPA switch itself. Thus,
14 = sc before statistical tests can be undertaken,
the issue of fl-stability must be addressed.
and f3sand fl, are the fls computed previ-
lOFor some firms whose announcement dates were
ously for the sample and control com- close to December 1976, we did not have the full 100 ob-
panies, respectively. The above "trans- servations in the post-switch period.
formation" was, in effect, the formation of 'l In our statistical tests, some of the observations
examined did not include every member of the group. We
a weighted portfolio consisting of the therefore could not expect the effect of the differences in
original control security and the risk- # to be "averaged away."

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
334 The Accounting Review, April 1981

Beta Stability alreadyeliminatedany reactionto overall


The selection of the time period and the market conditions.Thus, so long as the
use of data from both sides of the an- sample and "control" companies' fls
nouncement date were motivated by a werestableor movedin tandemwe would
desire to avoid potential biases resulting expect that d,(i) would not be sensitive
from unstable fls. Previous empirical to general market returns. Hence, we
evidence (e.g., Blume [1975]) has indi- would expect bi to equal zero for each
cated that although fls tend to be un- subperiod.
stable over time, generally speaking they A t-statisticwas calculatedto test the
were found to be relatively stable over null hypothesis that bi was not sig-
shorter time periods, such as five years. nificantlydifferentfromzero.An inability
Therefore, a time interval of five years to rejectthe null hypothesiswould indi-
was used in this study to estimate sample cate that fl-instabilitywas not a problem,
and control betas (see Gonedes [1973]). since the sample and "control" com-
Furthermore, by estimating our fls panies eitherwere stable or were shifting
using data from both sides of the switch together.We found that at the .05 level
period, any shifting that did occur over of significance,rejectionof the nullwould
the five years would tend to be "aver- have occurredfor only one company in
aged" out when focusing on the middle the pre-switchperiod and for only two
of the time period. In our case, this mid- companiesin the post-switchperiod. At
point represents the switch period itself. the .10 level of significance,the figures
Finally, a test was run to observe whether were one and three companies, respec-
beta instability was indeed a problem. tively. For a sampleof 48 companies,we
In our framework, it should be noted would expectthat at levels of significance
that shifts in beta are a problem only if of .05 and .10 just by chance alone the
the sample and control betas do not move null hypothesis would be rejected for
in the same direction. If the betas do move (.05x 48) 2.4 and (.10x 48) 4.8 companies,
together, then, once again, the d,(i) respectively. As the results found are
measure only reflects market reaction to below whatwouldbe expectedby chance,
a switch, since the "new beta" capturing we felt assured'2in proceedingwith this
co-movement with general market condi- sampleof controlcompanies.
tions is common for both the sample and StatisticalDesign
control companies. Therefore, in order In this study,we look for abnormalbe-
that fl-instability not be a problem, we havior around the time of the switch in
need only establish that the difference in the returnsof the companiesthat changed
sample and control betas is zero for both auditors.As definedin Equation(5), the
the pre-switch and post-switch periods. returndifference,d,(i),measuresthis ab-
This end was achieved by regressing the normalreturnor marketresponseto the
values d,(i) against the (excess) market switchfor companyi in week t. The aver-
return (Rmt- Rft) for the pre-switch pe-
age marketresponsefor a given partition
riod (t = -124 to t = -25), and then (group)in week t can thus be calculated
separately for the post-switch period as:
(t=25 to t= 124). For each of the 48
12
companies, for each sub-period, we have: Interestingly enough, two of the three companies
for which the null had been rejected during the post-
switch period were companies for which we did not have
dt(i) = a, + bi(Rmt- Rft) (6) the full 100 weeks of observation in this period (see foot.
note 10). This point further strengthens the argument
By our definition, the d,(i) measure has that these results may be attributable to chance.

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Fried and Schiff 335

Note that both do(P) and d1(P) con-


dt(P) = E dt(i) (7) tain an observation from the same cal-
endar week F2. In the case of t = 0, the
where observation would be firm y's abnormal
return in calendar week F2, (do=F2(Y)).
P= the particular partition (A, B, or
For t= 1, the observation would be firm
C) of firms being examined and
x's abnormal return in calendar week F2,
MP = the number of firms in the parti-
tion. (dl =F2(X))-
Empirical evidence [King, 1966] sug-
If we define t = 0 as the week in which gests that these cross-sectional abnormal
the 8-K report is filed, the average (ab- returns would not be uncorrelated. In
normal) return due to the switch over a general, then, since the companies in our
given time period (-L to + L) can be sample do have filing dates within N
defined as: weeks of each other, d,(P) cannot be
L considered to be independent across t.
d(P) = E dt(P) (8) Consequently, an estimate of the stan-
Nt= -L dard deviation of d,(P) (which would be
where N =the length of the time period needed for a univariate t test or multi-
being examined: N = 2L + 1. variate T2 test), calculated by
An approach to testing our hypotheses
would be to examine whether these aver- /L

age abnormal returns (d(P)) are statisti- S(P)= d (dt(P) -d(P))2


t= -L I1('l
cally different from zero. Applying a
univariate t test or multivariate T2 test to
the average return differences as calcu- would not be unbiased.
lated above, however, is not a straight- To overcome this problem, an ap-
forward proposition. To be able to carry proach based on Jaffe [1974a and b]14
out these tests one must assume that the and extended to the multivariate case
observations taken for a given partition, was used. The approach is designed to
dt(P), are independent over time. Such an enable one to carry out tests of signifi-
assumption, however, is untenable as cance on the average return differences
long as the companies in our sample have calculated in Equation (8) without run-
filing dates within N weeks of each other. ning into the problem caused by over-
This point can be illustrated by the use of lapping time periods. Essentially, what
the following example.'3 Suppose that the approach does is to form "port-
we have a sample of two firms x and y folios" (not to be confused with the parti-
whose filing dates correspond to the tions we have formed in Table 2) on a
first (Fl) and second (F2) weeks of calendar-week basis of all companies
February, respectively. As the return dif- whose announcement dates were within a
ferences are summed over a period rela- number of weeks (L) of the calendar week
tive to a given firm's filing date and not in question. Referring to our previous
to a chronological or calendar frame- example and introducing the notation
work, we would have for t = 0: d(P)t to denote formulation of a port-
do(P) = Rdo=F,(x) + do=F2y)); (9) 13 For illustrative
purposes, in our example, we
assume that we are interested only in examining the
Similarly for t= 1 we would have: behavior of return differences over the period 0 to 1.
14 Variations of this procedure have been used by
d,(P) = !(d, =F2(X) + d, =F3(Y)) (10) Patell [1976] and Hong et al. [1978].

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
336 The AccountingReview,April 1981

folio on a calendar-week basis, we would (N= 49) and at a shorter period of ten
now have: weeks on both sides of the filing date
d(P)tFl =d(X)t=Fl (12) (N= 21).
RESULTS AND CONCLUSIONS
d(P)t = F2=-ddt= F2(X)+ dt= F2(Y)); and (13) Results
d(P)t=F3=dt=F3(Y) (14)
Results for the full 49- and 21-week
Note that the observations of d(P)t(t= Ft, periods are presented in Tables 4 and 5,
F2, F3) contain no individual return dif- respectively. For the longer period of
ferences from the same calendar week. time, we found no statistically significant
Proceeding in this manner ensures in- results for any of the partitions either on
dependence of the observations under an an lB or EB level. That is, to say, if there
assumption that weekly returns are in- is any market reaction to a change in
dependent. Tests can thus be carried out auditors, it does not seem to be the result
on these observations after an inter- of long-term economic phenomena as-
mediate "standardization" step. This sociated with the companies in our
latter step is needed because, as the port- sample.
folio composition of d(P)t differs from Examining the statistics in Table 5 for
week to week, one would not expect the period closer to the filing date, we
different observations of d(P)t to have found that the hypotheses associated with
identical distributions. The net effect of the multivariate T2 test would be rejected
these steps is that the abnormal return only at a 0.23 a level, which is not very
"observations" used in our study can be significant. That is, on an overall basis,
considered to be independent of each no abnormal market reaction was de-
other as well as identically distributed. tected for the partitions we examined.
The details of the tests and portfolio Consistent with this result is, of course,
formulation steps are presented in the the finding that none of the EB univariate
Appendix. t-tests would be rejected at a .1 a level.
Finally, looking for market reactions However, when the hypotheses were
to a particular event under investigation examined individually, a different picture
involves a question of selecting the length emerged. The TBresults suggests that the
of the time period to be examined. In the interpretation of the results obtained
introduction to this paper, it was pointed from the EB tests are not unequivocal
out that CPA switches may be associated and that our results may be due to the
with other developments in the firm. fact that our partitioning scheme did not
Hence, the switch could be one of many capture the motivation for the switches.
signals emanating from the firm at this Specifically, when we examined all the
time. As such, it was stated that any firms together as one group, the results
results could not necessarily be attributa- suggested that there is "bad news"
ble to the switch itself. associated with an auditor switch. The
One way of gaining insight into this t-test for Hypothesis I, indicated that the
issue is to vary the number of weeks null hypothesis of no reaction to a CPA
around the announcement date over switch [for the total (nonpartitioned)
which return differences are averaged. sample] should be rejected at a .03 level
Thus, in the next section, we present of significance. However, dividing the
results looking at a period covering 24 sample into partitions A, B and C to see
weeks on both sides of the filing date if there were differing reactions along

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Fried and Schiff 337

TABLE4
TESTSFORN=49
RESULTSOF UNIVARIATEAND MULTIVARIATE

One-TailSignificance
Meanof Level*
Differencex 102
Hypothesis Partition d(P) t-Score EB IB
I All Companies (AuBuC) -.08 - .61
II "Conflict" Companies (B) -.33 -1.07
III "Size Companies (C) -.26 - .46
Multivariate T2 Test Score= 1.40 Upper Tail** =.80

* Significance only stated if greater than .10 level of Significance.


** Based on Chi-Square Distribution with three degrees of freedom.

TABLE5
RESULTSOF UNIVARIATEAND MULTIVAmATETESTSFORN=21

One-TailSignificance
Meanof Level*
Differencex 102
Hypothesis Partition d(P) t-Score EB IB
I All Companies (AuBuC) -.21 -1.88 .0 3
II "Conflict" Companies (B) -.41 -1.28
III "Size" Companies (C) -.60 -1.58
Multivariate 72 Test Score=4.64 Upper Tail** =.23
* Significance only stated if greater than .10 level of Significance.
** Based on Chi-Square Distribution with three degrees of freedom.

the dimensions of "size" and conflict did result, although it barely misses our .10
not prove to be fruitful. The results were cut-off point (one-tail significance is
not sufficiently significant to reject the .1003), is nevertheless considerably
null for Hypotheses II and III even on an weaker than the significance found for
TB level. With respect to group C, for the total non-partitioned sample. This
companies that switched to large CPA finding is, of course, inconsistent with the
firms, we found negative market reaction SEC disclosure requirement regarding
rather than the expected nonnegative the reporting of conflicts.
reaction that motivated this particular The fact that the results for Hypothesis
partition. Hence, "upgrading the quality" I show significance, whereas the results
of CPA firms in a switch-our size di- for the conflict grouping do not, suggests,
mension-did not reflect any particular as we have noted, that if there is "bad
''good news" to investors. news" associated with switches, there is
Similarly, the lack of statistical results some other motivation for it that has not
for companies that changed their auditors been accounted for in our partitioning
and reported conflicts (partition B) does scheme.
not support the contention15 that there
15 Given the number of companies, ten, reporting
is informational benefit to the investor
conflict in our sample, we are not willing to state the lack
from having companies and their CPAs of statistical support for informational benefits to the
disclose any disagreement. The t-test investor in any stronger terms.

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
338 The AccountingReview,April 1981

In order to gain further insight into group, was composed of all high /3 firms
the factors which may have accounted (average /3= 1.3).
for the results, we examined the A parti- Although stronger evidence is needed,
tion by itself. This partition consisted of these results might suggest that audit
those firms which did not report a conflict switches may be a consequence of con-
and switched to the same "size" CPA flicts (not disclosed) over accounting
firm. Had we been able to find negative issues that are most directly related to
reactions for this partition, it would have economy-wide events (e.g., uncertainty
strengthened the impression that the related to financing and future liabilities).
reporting of a conflict (or changing We have not structured this analysis in
"size") was not necessarily a factor the framework of a formal hypothesis
associated with the "bad news" found because we feel stronger theoretical un-
for the total sample. However, we found derpinnings are still needed. However,
no statistically significant reaction at all we do feel that a risk factor may be an
(t-statistic = -.62). 16 This finding sug- interesting focal point for future research
gests that the conflict partition (B) and/or in the area of disclosure requirements
"size" partition (C) contributed to the generally and specifically in the area of
rejection of Hypothesis 1.17 However, as filings for companies that change
mentioned, these partitions on their own auditors.
show no significance, and in the case of
Conclusion
the "size" partition, the direction of the
results is counter-intuitive. The general conclusion reached by our
Findings in a paper by Shank and study is that our results would seem to be
Murdock [1978] may shed some light on inconsistent with the SEC requirement
the ambiguity of our results. Their for a company to enumerate and describe
analysis found an increased incidence of disagreements with its auditors on ac-
qualified opinions for companies which counting and auditing issues.
had high fls. They hypothesized that the For the general event of auditor
reason for their finding was that a large switches, there is some evidence (on an
number of qualifications dealt with ac- lB level) which indicates that there is
counting disputes over events (such as negative market reaction around the time
asset valuation) that are closely related to of the announcement of the switch. The
economy-wide effects. Thus, high 11firms 16 Focusing on other variations of our partitioning

would tend to have a greater likelihood scheme, such as comparing just the (A) and (B) port-
of receiving a qualified opinion on their folios or (AuC) and (B) which isolated the conflict vs.
nonconflict situations given different assumptions about
financial statements. the "size" effect, did not affect our results. They still
It is interesting to note that, with re- showed no significance.
17 Consistent with the above results, it should be
spect to our sample, it was the companies
noted that the particular weighting scheme which
with the relatively high fis that reflected "maximized" the T2 statistic was aA =.26; aB=.40; and
most of the negative market reaction. ac=.34. These weightings do not deviate in a dramatic
Specifically, dividing our sample into fashion from the ones implied by Hypothesis I (aA=aB
= ac= 1/3), although there is some suggestion that parti-
high/low betas, we found significant tions B and C have a greater "impact" relative to parti-
results18 for the high /1firms but none for tion A.
18 The univariate t-test would have been rejected at a
the low /3 firms. Group C, which had, .10 level of significance for the high /3 portfolio with the
relatively speaking, the strongest statisti- multivariate T2 statistic falling in the upper I -percent
cal results in the negative direction by portion of the curve.

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Fried and Schiff 339

difficulty in interpreting this result is that Equation (5); and


it is not clear what motivates this reac- Mtj= number of firms in portfolio tj.
tion. The dimension of size and conflict
(3) A measure of variability V(tj) of the
examined in this study did not yield a
performance of portfolio tj and a measure
conclusive explanation, since a partition-
ing along these lines resulted in no signifi- of covariability C(tjk) of the performance
cance being indicated. of portfolio tj with the performance of
portfolio tk were then computed, using
This result suggests that further re-
the data of the previous 50 weeks;
search into the motivation for auditor
switches and the type of disclosure re- 1 50
V(tj) = 4 h (d(tj)th - (
quired at the time of the switch needs to 49h= 1
be undertaken. Given our results, we
1 50
could not find support for the assump-
C(tjk) = d(tj)t-h
tions implicit in the present SEC 49h= 1
disclosure requirement. - - d(tk))
d(tj))(d(tk)A-h
APPENDIX
where
OFTESTINGPROCEDURE
DESCRIPTION
1 so
(1) For any calendar week t, P19 d(tj) = 150 d(tj)th
portfolios of -companies that switched h= 1

CPAs in the period t - L to t + L were It should be noted that only for those
formed. A company was placed in port- weeks where both portfolios tj and tkcon-
folio tj (j= 1, P) depending on the type of tained at least one security each was
switch applicable to it. Note that t in this there a need to calculate C(tjk).
case is to be interpretedon a calendar week (4) The next step was to standardize
basis, rather than in terms of the number the performance difference for each port-
of weeks before or after the announcement folio tj and find the average standardized
date. performance difference across all t.
In addition, corresponding portfolios The standardized difference for port-
consisting of the beta-matched securities folio tj is calculated as:
were formed for the week. If no firm for a
given classification j had switched in the -
Sd(tj)t d_(')'
period t + L, then the portfolio tj con- V1V(tj)
tained no securities and was ignored in
the statistical tests. The average standardized performance
(2) The performance difference of port- difference is defined as:
folio tj during the week t, defined as:
Sdj =-EI Sd(tj)tD(tj)
nj.
d(tj)t = M E dt(i)
Mtj ze-t1 where D(tj) = 1 when there is at least one
was then calculated, where
19 The description that follows is presented for the

d(tj)t= average return difference of more general multivariate case. In that case, P is 3 and
portfolio tj in week t; the portfolio corresponds to the A-C groupings of Table
2. For each of the univariate cases, P is 1 and corresponds
dt(i)= the week t return difference of to the particular hypothesis being tested (i.e., all com-
the ith firm; as defined by panies, B grouping and C grouping).

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
340 The Accounting Review, April 1981

security in portfolio tj and 0 otherwise; elements and S is the P x P covariance


and matrix containing SJ along its diagonal
and Sij elsewhere.
nj= D(tj) Testing the univariate null hypotheses
t
is carried out by forming the following
(5) Under an assumption that the re- t-statistic:
turns of the individual securities (or, more
precisely, the differences) are normally Sd
distributed, then each of the standardized Tj= (A2)
1/\/fnj
differences will have a t-distribution with
49 df. The average standardized residuals Since the degrees of freedom 49 nj are
will then also be t-distributed with de- large for all j(> 2000), we can use a chi-
grees of freedom approximately equal to square distribution with P= 3 degrees of
49 nj. The variance of -STwill be equal to: freedom (x2,3) to test T2 as calculated by
Equation (Al). For the t-statistic calcu-
I lated by Equation (A2) on the EB level,
V(tj)~ =
n2 12EV(tj) 'j a significance would be determined by
comparing ,j to Vx2,3,whereX2,3 denotes
and the covariance between Sd1 and Sdk
the upper lOOapercentage point of the
will equal:
chi-square distribution with 3 degrees of
freedom (see Morrison [1967, pp. 120-
.. .. C(tjk)
122]).
a}njnk t V V(tj) V(tk)
For the IB level, the t-statistic can be
(6) The overall null hypotheses can tested by use of the normal distribution.
then be tested in the multivariate cases by Since the percentage points of a normal
forming the following T2 statistic: distribution are equivalent to the square
root of a chi-square distribution with
T2 = SdS-I1Sd (Al) degrees of freedom equal to 1(1,7), it is
clear that the EB critical level will always
Where Sd is the P x l vector with Sdj as its be greater than the IB level.

REFERENCES
American Institute of Certified Public Accountants (AICPA), The CPA Letter (November 22, 1976).
Barlev, B., and G. Benston, "Change of Auditors: An Analysis of the SEC's Reporting Requirement,"
Hebrew University Working Paper, 1974.
Bedingfield, J. and S. Loeb, "Auditor Changes-An Examination," Journal of Accountancy (March
1974), pp. 66-69.
Blume, M., "Betas and Their Regression Tendencies," Journal of Finance (June 1975), pp. 785-795.
"Companies vs. Auditors," Dun's Review (July 1974), pp. 33-37.
Coopers & Lybrand, The C&L SEC Manual (November 1979).
DisclosureInc., CorporateProfiles and Index of CorporateEvents (1975).
Eggleton, I., S. Penman, and J. Twombly, "Accounting Changes and Stock Prices: An Examination of
Selected Uncontrolled Variables," Journal ofAccounting Research (Spring 1976), pp. 66-88.
Gonedes, N. J., "Evidence on the Information Content of Accounting Numbers: Accounting-Based and
Market-Based Estimates of Systematic Risk," Journal of Finance and QuantitativeAnalysis (June 1973),
pp. 407-443.
,"Risk, Information, and the Effects of Special Accounting Items on Capital Market Equilibrium,"
Journal of Accounting Research (Autumn1975),pp. 220-256.
Gosman, M., "Characteristics of Firms Making Accounting Changes," THEACCOUNTING REVIEW (Jan-
uary 1973), pp. 1-11.

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Fried and Schiff 341

Harrison, T., "Different Market Reactions to Discretionary and Non-discretionary Accounting Changes,"
Journal of Accounting Research (Spring 1977), pp. 84-107.
Hong, H., R. Kaplan, and G. Mandelker, "Pooling vs. Purchase: The Effects of Accounting for Mergers
on Stock Prices," THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW(January 1978), pp. 31-47.
Jaffe, J. F., "The Effect on Regulation Changes on Insider Trading," The Bell Journal of Economics and
Management Science (Spring 1974a), pp. 93-121.
Jaffe, J. F., "Special Information and Insider Trading," Journal of Business (July 1974b), pp. 410-428.
Kaplan, R. and R. Roll, "Investor Evaluation of Accounting Information: Some Empirical Evidence,"
Journal of Business (April 1972), pp. 225-57.
King, B. F., "Market and Industry Factors in Stock Price Behavior," Journal of Business (January 1966),
pp. 139-190.
Morrison, D. F., Multivariate Statistical Methods (McGraw-Hill, 1967).
Patell, J. M., "Corporate Forecasts of Earnings per Share and Stock Price Behavior: Empirical Tests,"
Journal of Accounting Research (Autumn 1976), pp. 246-276.
Schiff, A., and H. D. Fried, "Large Companies and the Big Eight: An Overview," Abacus (December
1976), pp. 116-124.
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), Accounting Series Release No. 165, Notice of Amendments
to Require Increased Disclosure of Relationships Between Registrants and Their IndependentPublic Ac-
countants (1974).
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), Accounting Series Release No. 247, Auditor Changes Final
Rules (1978).
Shank, J. and R. Murdock, "Comparability in the Application of Reporting Standards: Some Further
Evidence," THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW (October 1978), pp. 824-835.
"The SEC Bears Down Harder on Disclosure," Business Week (October 19, 1974), pp. 33-37.

This content downloaded from 132.234.251.230 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 03:55:57 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like