Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 7

Competition, Policy Burdens, and State-Owned Enterprise Reform

Author(s): Justin Yifu Lin, Fang Cai and Zhou Li


Source: The American Economic Review , May, 1998, Vol. 88, No. 2, Papers and
Proceedings of the Hundred and Tenth Annual Meeting of the American Economic
Association (May, 1998), pp. 422-427
Published by: American Economic Association

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/116960

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic
Review

This content downloaded from


138.51.86.105 on Mon, 13 Feb 2023 19:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CHINA'S ECONOMIC REFORMS: SOME UNFINISHED BUSINESSt

Competition, Policy Burdens,


and State-Owned Enterprise Reform

By JUSTIN YIFU LIN, FANG CAI, AND ZHOU Li *

One of the most important remaining issues Io Competition and the Performance of Large
in China's transition to a market economy Corporation in a Market Economy
is the reform of state-owned enterprises
(SOE's). When reforms started in late 1978, Although, by definition, the state owns the
SOE's dominated China's industrial sectors in SOE's, the state cannot operate them by itself
every aspect. After 18 years of gradual tran- and needs to delegate their control to the en-
sition, the SOE share in China's total industrial terprises' managers. The separation of own-
output has declined from 77.6 percent in 1978 ership and control is a common feature of any
to 28.8 percent in 1996. However, in 1996 large modem corporation. Due to this separa-
SOE's still employed 57.4 percent of urban tion, the issues of incentive incompatibility
workers and possessed 52.2 percent of total and information asymmetry often arise be-
investment in industrial fixed assets. Improv- tween the managers and the owners. Agency
ing SOE performance is crucial for social problems, such as the moral hazard and man-
stability and sustained growth in China. How- agerial slacks and discretion, may surface. The
ever, over 40 percent of SOE's are losing success of any large modem corporate insti-
money. In this paper, we will argue that the tution depends on its ability to overcome these
root of the SOE problem is the separation of problems. Intuitively, one possible way out for
ownership and control and that the often- the owners is to oversee the managers' actions
criticized soft-budget constraints arise from directly and to reward the managers according
various state-imposed policy burdens, which to their managerial efforts (Armen A. Alchian
make the state accountable for the poor per- and Harrod Demsetz, 1972). In practice, total
fornance of SOE's. The key for a successful observation of managerial actions in a large
SOE reform is to remove the policy burdens modern corporation is either impossible or
and to create a level playing field so that mar- prohibitively costly. Moreover, the owners of
ket competition can provide sufficient infor- a large modem corporation are numerous. Due
mation for the managerial performance of the to the free-rider problem, any individual
SOE's and make the managers' incentives owner of a firm will not have the incentive to
compatible with those of the state)' oversee the detailed activities of the firm. The
large modem corporation does not have own-
ers in the same sense as in the property-rights
t Discussants: Bary Naughton, University of California-
literature.2
San Diego; Loren L. Brandt, Jr., University of Toronto.
The prevalence of large modem corpora-
* Lin: China Center for Economic Research, Peking
tions in the market economy indicates that
University, Beijing, 100871, China, and Department of
Economics, Hong Kong University of Science and Tech- some institutional arrangements to mitigate the
nology, Hong Kong; Fang Cai and Zhou Li: Chinese agency problems must exist. The recent liter-
Academy of Social Sciences, Beijing 100732. China.
' In this paper we limit our discussions to the reform
of large-scale SOE's, which consisted of 5.6 percent of
SOE's in terms of number of enterprises in 1996 but con- 2 An institutional investor may own a large share of a
tributed to 63.3 percent of the gross output value of SOE's firm. However, the institutional investor is also an agent
in the same year. For the medium- and small-scale SOE's, who may not have the right incentives to monitor the man-
lease, privatization, or bankruptcy are appropriate reform agers. The owners of the institution's funds may not have
programs. incentives to monitor the institutional investor either.

422

This content downloaded from


138.51.86.105 on Mon, 13 Feb 2023 19:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL 88 NO. 2 CHINA'S ECONOMIC REFORMS 423

ature suggests that market competition is such ported from developed countries; and (iii)
an arrangement. Some summary indicators in each project required a large lump-sum in-
a competitive market, such as relative profits vestment. However, the Soviet-type econo-
of firms in the market, provide a sufficient- mies were built in low-income agrarian
statistic condition for evaluating managers' countries which also had three characteristics:
performance (Bengt Holmstrom, 1982). With (i) capital was scarce and the market-
the sufficient statistic, incentive compatibility determined interest was high; (ii) exportable
between the owners and the managers can be goods were limited, and the market-
achieved in two ways: directly, the owners can determined price for foreign exchange was
design a managerial-compensation scheme expensive; and (iii) funds for large projects
that is based on the comparison of the firm's were hard to mobilize because economic sur-
performance with the industrial average or on plus was small and scattered. For the purpose
the rank of the firm's performance in the in- of reducing the costs and mobilizing funds for
dustry (Holmstrom, 1982); indirectly, a firm's the heavy-industry projects, the Soviet-type
performance in a competitive market provides economy formed a distorted macroeconomic-
a signal to the managerial labor market about policy environment in which interest rates,
the manager's talent and behavior, and the sig- foreign-exchange rates, wage rates, and prices
nal determines the manager's future wages for raw materials and other products were ar-
(Eugene F. Fama, 1980).3 tificially suppressed (Lin et al., 1996).
The above macroeconomic-policy distor-
II. Endogeneity of the SOE Management tions induced a total imbalance in the supply
Institution in a Soviet-Type Economy and demand for credits, foreign exchanges,
raw materials, and other products. Because
A salient feature of traditional SOE's in the nonpriority sectors were competing with pri-
Chinese economy and other Soviet-type econ- ority sectors for the low-priced resources, the
omies was their lack of autonomy. The state state needed to have a plan that indicated pri-
provided all inputs to SOE's for their produc- orities for each project and then used admin-
tion according to central plans and covered all istrative measures to allocate the resources
their costs. In turn, the SOE's delivered to the accordingly to guarantee that the scarce re-
state all outputs and revenues. The state set the sources would be allocated according to the
wage rates of the SOE workers and managers. state's strategic goal. In that way, market com-
All activities of the SOE's required the state's petition was suppressed.
approvals. Such a seemingly irrational ar- Under such a macroeconomic-policy envi-
rangement in effect was an endogenous re- ronment and resource-allocation system,
sponse to the agency problems in a traditional agency problems would be a serious threat to
Soviet-type economy. the state's goal of maximally mobilizing re-
The Soviet-type economy is known for its sources for its priority projects. The replace-
maximal mobilization of resources for the es- ment of market competition by planned
tablishment of capital-intensive heavy indus- allocation removed the possibility for the state
tries. These heavy-industry projects had three to rely on the observation of relative perform-
characteristics: (i) they required a long ges- ances to evaluate the SOE managers. Further-
tation; (ii) for a less-developed country, most more, because of the distortions in the
equipment for the projects needed to be im- macroeconomic-policy environment, the prof-
itability of an SOE was determined mostly by
its output and input prices. The influence of
3 If only the firm's performance itself (but not the per- managers' actions on the profitability of an
formance of other firms in the market) is observable, com- SOE was only secondary. Therefore, it was
petition may also mitigate the agency problems by the also impossible for the state to discipline the
threat of liquidation (Klaus M. Schmidt, 1997) and re-
managers by simply observing the firm's profit
duction in the firm's profits which reduce the room for
managerial discretion (Oliver D. Hart, 1983), although
level alone. Moreover, an incentive contract
the optimal-contracting literature suggests that these ef- based on the comparison between current and
fects are not very robust. past performances would not solve the agency

This content downloaded from


138.51.86.105 on Mon, 13 Feb 2023 19:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
424 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1998

problems because of the ratchet effect (Martin management systems led the reforms in the
L. Weitzman, 1980) and also because the state resource-allocation systems, which in turn led
often failed to deliver materials on time or in the reforms in the macroeconomic-policy en-
the quantity and quality required, so that man- vironment. Specifically, the Chinese govern-
agers could blame the state for their failures. ment first allowed the SOE's to share part of
Furthermore, it was impossible or prohibi- the performance improvement by a profit-
tively costly for the state to oversee the retention program, which initially gave 12 per-
managers' actions directly. Under such a cir- cent of the increased profits or reduced losses
cumstance, if the state had granted business to the enterprises. The SOE's could use the
autonomy to the managers, the managers of a retained income for paying bonuses to work-
policy-determined profitable SOE could have ers, supporting welfare programs, and invest-
a lot of shirking and on-the-job consumption ing in capacity expansions. The managerial
because the state could observe neither their autonomy was gradually deepened through the
wrongdoings directly nor the firm's ought-to- replacement of the profit-retention system by
be profits indirectly. For a policy-determined a contract-responsibility system in which
loss-making SOE, similar agency problems the SOE's agreed to deliver predetermined
would arise because the state could observe amounts of revenue to the state and retained
neither the managers' discretion nor the firm's the residuals, and later the replacement of the
ought-to-be losses. One of the purposes of in- contract-responsibility system by the modem
stituting price distortions in the Soviet-type corporate system in which the state was enti-
economy was to maximally mobilize resources tled to the dividend on its shares in the SOE
for priority projects. To prevent the policy- assets. Parallel to the SOE managerial reform
created economic surplus from being dis- was the decollectivization of agriculture,
sipated by managerial discretion, it was which replaced the production-team system
imperative for the state to deprive managers of with the household-responsibility system.
their autonomy and to make the SOE's like Meanwhile, a dual-track system was intro-
puppets in the economic system. The fact that, duced to reform the resource-allocation sys-
before the recent reforms, the state always had tem. After fulfilling the compulsory delivery
to recentralize the management in order to obligations, the SOE's were allowed to sell
control walloping increases in wages after their above-quota outputs to the markets at
each of the state's attempts to increase the au- market-determined prices. The enterprises
tonomy of SOE's in China and other Soviet- were also permitted to purchase inputs from
type economies testifies to the above analysis. the markets to increase production or to ex-
pand production capacity.
III. The Effects of SOE Reform in China An unexpected effect of the above reforms
was the entry and rapid growth of nonstate en-
The Soviet-type economy was very good at terprises, especially the township and village
mobilizing resources for building a few pri- enterprises (TVE's). Rural industry already
ority sectors. However, the economy was very existed before the reform as a result of the gov-
inefficient due to two reasons: (i) low alloca- ernment's 1971 policy to develop rural pro-
tive efficiency because of the deviation of the cessing industries in order to finance the
industrial structure from the pattern dictated agricultural mechanization program. How-
by the comparative advantages of the econ- ever, being outside the state plans, the growth
omy; and (ii) low technical efficiency because of TVE's was severely constrained by their
the managers had no means to motivate the lack of access to capital, raw materials, equip-
workers and no incentives to improve their op- ment, and markets. The reforms created two
erations (Lin et al., 1996). favorable conditions for the rapid expansion
To improve economic efficiency, the Chi- of TVE's: (i) a new stream of surpluses
nese government initiated a series of in- were brought about by the household-
cremental, gradual reforms in 1979 that responsibility-system reform and were re-
eventually resulted in a transition to a market tained in rural areas, providing a resource base
economy. In the process, the reforms in the for new investinent initiatives (Lin, 1992);

This content downloaded from


138.51.86.105 on Mon, 13 Feb 2023 19:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 88 NO. 2 CHINA'S ECONOMIC REFORMS 425

(ii) the dual-track system provided nonstate at least mitigated these agency problems.
enterprises with access to key raw materials, However, agency problems in SOE's have
equipment, and markets. In 1978, the output worsened after the reforms in spite of the in-
of TVE's accounted for 7.2 percent of the total tensification of competition. What are the
value of industrial output in China. The output reasons?
share of TVE's increased to 31.1 percent in From the literature, we know that the ob-
1996. servation of some summary indicators, such as
Being outsiders to the traditional system, relative profits, will be a sufficient statistic of
nonstate enterprises had to obtain credits and managers' actions if firms face only common
inputs from competitive markets, and in turn, uncertainties (i.e., do not have any idiosyn-
their products were sold to markets. They cratic shocks in input costs, output prices, or
faced hard budget constraints, and they would production process) (Holmstrom, 1982).
not survive if their performances were poor. However, this condition does not hold for the
SOE's in China and other transitional econo-
The dynamism of nonstate enterprises exerted
a heavy pressure on the SOE's and triggered mies. As legacies of prereform policies, the
the state's policy of deepening the SOE man- SOE's encounter a number of idiosyncratic
agerial reforms. Firm-level studies show that burdens, including the following:
the increase in managerial autonomy and the
intensification of competition have signifi- (i) The capital intensity of many large
cantly improved the managerial incentives and SOE's is too high, judging from the
total factor productivity of SOE's (Wei Li, capital-scarcity nature of the Chinese
1997). economy. They cannot survive if they
When the reform started in 1979, most have to pay market-determined interest
SOE's were profitable. Taxes and revenues rates and face market competition, es-
from SOE's were the government's main pecially competition from the capital-
sources of fiscal income. However, in spite of abundant economies. Before the reforms,
the significant increase in productivity, the both their investments and working cap-
profitability of the SOE's has declined sub- ital came from interest-free fiscal appro-
stantially since the reforms started. Currently, priations. They were also shielded from
evidence shows that more than 40 percent of international competition. After the re-
SOE's are operating at losses in spite of large form, the government replaced the fiscal
amounts of implicit subsidies from low- appropriations with interest-bearing
interest loans and other policy protections. The loans, and the protections were also grad-
decline of the profitability of SOE's is partly ually eliminated. In a capital-scarce
attributable to the dissipation of their monop- economy, the capital-intensive enter-
oly rent. However, the walloping increases in prises industries are not competitive by
wages and other fringe benefits are other im- nature. However, the state views the
portant reasons. The average annual growth capital-intensive industries as strategi-
rate of the SOE wage fund in the state sector cally important and the SOE' s are
was 16 percent during 1978-1996, while the instructed to operate in those industries.
average annual growth rate of output in the (ii) The SOE's bear a heavy burden from re-
same period was 7.6 percent. tirement pensions, other social-welfare
costs, and redundant workers. Before
IV. Policy Burdens and Soft-Budget Constraints the reforms, the state adopted a low-
nominal-wage policy. The wage was
Before the reforms, except for shirking, only enough to cover an employee' s cur-
agency problems such as on-the-job consump- rent consumption. The SOE's were re-
tion, looting, and other wrongdoings were not sponsible for their ernployees' retirement
serious in SOE's because of the absence of pensions, housing, medical cares, and
managerial autonomy. The analysis in Section other needs. Before the reform, this pol-
II suggests that the increase of competition in icy did not pose any extra burden on the
a market economy should have eliminated or SOE's, because the state covered all the

This content downloaded from


138.51.86.105 on Mon, 13 Feb 2023 19:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
426 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1998

SOE expenditures by fiscal appropria- of SOE's. The managers of SOE's will ascribe
tion. However, after the managerial all their losses to the state's policies, no matter
reform, the SOE's have had to be re- whether the losses are due to the policy burdens
sponsible for the wages and social or due to their own managerial discretion. Con-
welfare of not only the incumbent em- sequently, in most cases, the state in practice
ployees, but also their retired workers. has to be responsible for all the SOE losses. As
The older an SOE is, the more retired such, the budget constraints of SOE's become
workers it has, and the heavier the bur- soft. The soft budget constraints in turn worsen
den from retired workers' pensions and the moral hazard, managerial slacks, on-the-job
social-welfare expenditures it carries. In consumption, and other agency problems. To
a similar vein, the heavy-industry- constrain the agency problems, the state will
oriented development strategy before the have to intervene directly into the operations of
reforms did not create enough job op- SOE's. Then there will arise a vicious cycle of
portunities for urban residents. SOE's policy burdens, subsidies, agency problems,
were thus forced to employ many redun- and political interventions in the SOE manage-
dant workers. In the interest of social sta- ment systeM .4
bility, the SOE's are not allowed to lay
off the redundant workers. V. Fair Competition and SOE Reform
(iii) Some SOE output prices are still dis-
torted. Before the reforms, the prices of The failures of 18 years of managerial re-
energy, raw materials, and other products forms to harden the budget constraints of
or services, which were considered as in- SOE's and to improve their performance have
puts to the heavy-industry projects, were made privatization an attractive alternative to
artificially suppressed. After 18 years of some economists. However, as long as the pol-
reform, most prices have been liberal- icy burdens remain, even if the SOE's are pri-
ized. However, the prices of energy, vatized, the state cannot excuse itself from the
transportation, and a few other pro- policy-induced losses, and the soft budget con-
ducts are still kept below the market- straints will persist. The evidence after the pri-
equilibrium level. These prices often vatization in Eastern Europe and the former
cannot cover production costs. Soviet Union supports the above statement
(World Bank, 1996 p. 45). Therefore, for the
The above policy-determined burdens put SOE reform to be effective, it is necessary to
the SOE's in a disadvantaged position in. com- remove the policy burdens of SOE's and to
peting with nonstate enterprises. Because each provide them with a level playing field first.
SOE was established at a different time, has Some Pareto-improvement measures can be
somewhat different technology and capital in- introduced to deal with each of the above pol-
tensity, and has a different number of retired icy burdens (Lin et al., 1998). Without policy
as well as redundant workers, the impact of burdens, the state is no longer accountable for
the above policy burdens on the competitive- failures of SOE's and can thus impose hard
ness of SOE's is idiosyncratic. Therefore, budget constraints on them. Without the state's
competition among the SOE's or between the subsidies, the SOE managers in turn can resist
SOE's and nonstate enterprises cannot serve unnecessary political interventions in their
as a device to extract information optimally.
Under this circumstance, the expansion of the
managerial autonomy of SOE's will worsen
4 The agency literature suggests that, without compe-
the agency problems. tition, it is still possible to design a second-best incentive
In theory, the state should be responsible contract to minimize the principal's problem. However,
only for the SOE losses that arise from the the literature assumes that the shocks, no matter common
or idiosyncratic, are exogenous and that the contract is
policy burdens. However, because of the
enforceable. In the case of policy burdens, the state has to
information-asymmetry problem, it is very hard be accountable for the burdens. As such, incentive con-
for the state to distinguish between the policy- tracts between the state and SOE's are not enforceable and
induced losses and the own operational losses will not mitigate the principal's problem.

This content downloaded from


138.51.86.105 on Mon, 13 Feb 2023 19:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL 88 NO. 2 CHINA'S ECONOMIC REFORMS 427

operations. Certainly, a level playing field Holmstrom, Bengt. "Moral Hazard in Teams."
does not guarantee that SOE performances Bell Journal of Economics, Autunm 1982,
will necessary be good. If an SOE fails to per- 13(2), pp. 324-40.
form well, other enterprises, including those Li, Wei. "The Impact of Economic Reform on
privately owned, will have incentives to take the Performance of Chinese State Enter-
over, replace its managers, improve the effi- prises, 1980-1989." Journal of Political
ciency, and make profits from the takeover be- Economy, October 1997, 105(5), pp.
cause, without policy burdens, an SOE should 1081-1106.
be able to make a normal profit with a normal Lin, Justin Yifu. "Rural Reforms and Agricul-
management. However, whether privatization tural Growth in China." American Economic
is a necessary condition for improving the ef- Review, March 1992, 82(1), pp. 34-51.
ficiency of the SOE's cannot be determined a Lin, Justin Yifu; Cai, Fang and Li, Zhou. The
priori. Fundamentally, for any large modern China miracle: Development strategy and
corporation, as pointed out by Fama (1980), economic reform. Hong Kong: Chinese
there are no owners in any meaningful sense. University Press, 1996.
_-. Sufficient information and state-
REFERENCES owned enterprise reforn. Hong Kong: Chi-
nese University Press, 1998 (forthcoming).
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold. "Pro- Schmidt, Klaus M. "Managerial Incentives and
duction, Information Costs, and Economic Product Market Competition." Review of
Organization." American Economic Re- Economic Studies, April 1997, 64(2), pp.
view, December 1972, 62(5), pp. 777-95. 191-213.
Fama, Eugene F. "Agency Problems and the Weitzman, Martin L. "The 'Ratchet Principle'
Theory of the Firm." Journal of Political and Performance Incentives." Bell Journal
Economy, April 1980,88(2), pp. 288-307. of Economics, Spring 1980, 11 (1), pp.
Hart, Oliver D. "The Market Mechanism as 302-8.
an Incentive Scheme." Bell Journal of World Bank. World development report 1996:
Economics, Autumn 1983, 14(2), pp. From plan to market. New York: Oxford
366-82. University Press, 1996.

This content downloaded from


138.51.86.105 on Mon, 13 Feb 2023 19:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like