Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/356607426

Does bank concentration stem from financial inclusion in Africa?

Article in Applied Economics · November 2021


DOI: 10.1080/00036846.2021.2006134

CITATIONS READS

0 95

3 authors:

Désiré Avom Chrysost Bangake


Université de Dschang Université d'Artois
41 PUBLICATIONS 234 CITATIONS 25 PUBLICATIONS 564 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Hermann Ndoya
Université de Dschang
10 PUBLICATIONS 2 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Financial Inclusion and Development in Africa View project

Financial inclusion and development in Africa View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Hermann Ndoya on 29 December 2021.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Applied Economics

ISSN: (Print) (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20

Does bank concentration stem from financial


inclusion in Africa?

Désiré Avom, Chrysost Bangake & Hermann Ndoya

To cite this article: Désiré Avom, Chrysost Bangake & Hermann Ndoya (2021): Does
bank concentration stem from financial inclusion in Africa?, Applied Economics, DOI:
10.1080/00036846.2021.2006134

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2021.2006134

Published online: 28 Nov 2021.

Submit your article to this journal

View related articles

View Crossmark data

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=raec20
APPLIED ECONOMICS
https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2021.2006134

Does bank concentration stem from financial inclusion in Africa?


Désiré Avoma, Chrysost Bangakeb and Hermann Ndoyac
a
Lille Economie Management (LEM) UMR 9221, University of Artois, Arras, France; bCentre d’Etudes et de Recherche en Economie et Gestion
(CEREG), University of Yaounde II-Soa, Yaoundé, Cameroon; cLaboratoire de Recherche en Economie Fondamentale et Appliquée (LAREFA),
University of Dschang, Cameroon, Dschang

ABSTRACT KEYWORDS
This paper provides original econometric evidence on whether banking concentration stems from Financial Inclusion; Bank
financial inclusion in African countries. In applying a system generalized methods of moments Concentration; Nonlinear
(SGMM) and the panel threshold regression method to a sample of 30 African countries for 2004– Relationship; Threshold
2017, we find two main results. First, bank concentration negatively and significantly affects Regression
financial inclusion in Africa. Second, as far as the nonlinear relationship is concerned, we find JEL
two extreme regimes with a smooth shift characterizing the bank concentration–financial inclusion G21; K20; O16
nexus, with respect to conditional variables; bank concentration effects are negative and signifi­
cant under the first regime and positive and significant under the second. Furthermore, our
findings show that the nonlinear relationship between bank concentration and financial inclusion
depends on the levels of financial freedom, mobile phones penetration, protection of property
rights, control of corruption and regulatory quality. The results are robust to alternative measures
of banking market structure, such as Lerner index and Boone indicator and to the panel smooth
transition regression (PSTR).

I. Introduction
Africa is the world’s second fastest-growing region, financial inclusion measures the ability of the
experiencing an average annual GDP growth of financial system to provide the financial services
4.6% from 2000 to 2016. For the current five-year to the poorest by alleviating their vulnerability
period to 2022, Africa’s real GDP is projected to (Eggoh and Bangaké 2021).
grow 3.9% annually (IMF 2021). However, as From this perspective, financial inclusion has
Africa’s growth rates continue to be sustained, become a subject of considerable interest among
and the region increasingly is sought after by for­ policy makers, researchers, and other stakeholders.
eign investors, the World Bank (2013) notes that This heightened interest reflects a better under­
poverty and inequality remain at an ‘unacceptable’ standing of the importance of financial inclusion
level and that progress made in reducing them to economic and social development. This trend
remains slow. Growth must be inclusive, and one indicates a growing recognition that access to
of the components of inclusive development is financial services has a critical role in reducing
financial inclusion, in which Africa still lags far extreme poverty, boosting shared prosperity, and
behind the rest of the world (Triki and Faye supporting inclusive and sustainable development.
2013). Although this is often confusing, financial However, the achievement of financial inclusion
inclusion is not the same as financial depth. first requires the establishment of a well-developed
Financial depth might be high and financial inclu­ financial system (Beck and Cull 2014). Among a
sion be low if large amount of credits are assigned diverse group of financial service providers, com­
to few household. Furthermore, it is possible to mercial banks certainly provide the most basic
have financial development without financial financial services across developing economies
inclusion since the former refers to the aggregate (Sarma and Pais 2011). Elsewhere, most developing
level of credit or deposit money bank. Thus, countries have concentrated banking markets,

CONTACT Chrysost Bangake chrysost.bangake@univ-artois.fr Centre d’Etudes et de Recherche en Economie et Gestion (CEREG), University of Yaounde
II-Soa institution
© 2021 Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group
2 D. AVOM ET AL.

which has given rise to the natural question as to Previous studies pay less attention to this aspect.
ask whether banking concentration harms financial This relationship may be contingent on bank con­
inclusion in these countries, as advocated by centration, where the variable promotes financial
Chauvet and Jacolin (2017). Our study is part of inclusion below or above a given threshold.1 This
this tradition insofar as it analyses the impact of conjecture requires the use of a more flexible mod­
banking concentration on financial inclusion in eling strategy that can accommodate various bank
African countries. concentration-financial inclusion interactions. To
Existing theories provide ambiguous predictions this end, we applied the dynamic panel threshold
regarding the impact of banking concentration on model to analyze the nonlinear relationship
financial inclusion. The conventional market between bank concentration and financial inclu­
power hypothesis argues that concentration in the sion. As a third novelty, for robustness checks, we
banking system reduces financial inclusion. In con­ rely on the panel smooth transition regression
trast, the information hypothesis argues that in the (PSTR) model proposed by González, Teräsvirta,
presence of information asymmetries, bank con­ and Van Dijk (2005), which authorized a smooth
centration can increase access to credit. transition for a weak number of thresholds over a
Empirically, previous works that exploring the continuum of regimes. The PSTR model allows
effects of banking concentration on financial inclu­ individuals to move between groups over time
sion finds mixed results. For example, Pham, depending on changes in threshold variables.
Nguyen, and Nguyen (2019), Lu, Wu, and Liu Most of the empirical literature indirectly assumes
(2020), and Wang, Han, and Huang (2020) show a constant impact of banking concentration along
that higher concentration is associated with greater the entire span and homogeneity among sample
credit availability, whereas Chauvet and Jacolin countries. In this regard, such studies identify exo­
(2017) find the reverse. geneous or endogenous break thresholds using a
These conflicting results show that this relation­ rolling Chow test. This test imposes discontinuity
ship is likely nonlinear, where the effect of banking in the relationship between banking concentration
concentration on financial inclusion may vary by and financial inclusion. This is not the case for our
stage and level of economic development. Indeed, PSTR model, which captures, on a continuous
countries with the same level of banking concen­ basis, the effect of bank concentration on financial
tration may record different levels of financial inclusion. To the best of our knowledge, this model
inclusion. The existence of such a nonlinear pattern has not been applied before on the considered
has been confirmed by other authors, such as Owen topic, although it seems to be highly relevant.
and Pereira (2018), who found that greater banking The rest of this article is organized as follows.
industry concentration is associated with more Section II presents a summary of the main studies
access to deposit accounts and loans, provided on bank concentration and financial inclusion.
that the market power of banks is limited. Section III lays out the empirical strategy adopted.
Our main contribution to the existing literature Section IV describes the data and variables used,
is threefold. The first novelty of the paper is that we and the results are discussed in Section V. Finally,
construct a multidimensional financial inclusion Section VI highlights the main conclusions drawn
index to circumvent the criticisms often leveled at and policy implications for African countries.
individual measures. The weights assigned to the
three dimensions (usage, penetration and availabil­
II. Related literature
ity) are determined endogenously by using a two-
stage principal component analysis (PCA). As a Existing theories provide ambiguous predictions
second novelty, we explore whether there a thresh­ regarding the impact of banking concentration on
old of bank concentration in the financial inclu­ financial inclusion. Two opposing theoretical
sion-bank concentration relationship exists. approaches are proposed. The first hypothesis,

1
In addition, we explore other channels through which bank concentration may affect financial inclusion (financial freedom, bank stability, corruption, and
property rights). We test these transmission channels.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 3

related to the conventional structure-conduct-per­ bank concentration, financial inclusion, and firm
formance (SCP) hypothesis, suggests that banking performance. Applying a fixed effect model to a
concentration increases the cost of finance and sample of 79 developing countries over the period
lowers the efficiency of banking institutions 2006–2014, the authors find that less concentration
(Vatiero 2010; Berger et al. 2004). Therefore, in a and more competition in the banking market posi­
concentrated banking market, banks negatively use tively impact financial inclusion and firm perfor­
their market power by taking excessive risks to mance. Bank concentration therefore has a
increase their profits. The second theory based on negative effect on financial inclusion. However,
the information hypothesis argues that in the pre­ this result can be mitigated if certain aspects,
sence of information asymmetries between banks related to the legal and institutional framework
and their borrowers, the former has incentives to and economic development are taken into account.
invest in monitoring and private information As far as Africa is concerned, there is a few
acquisition. Then, in concentrated markets, banks studies that tackle the impact of bank concentra­
with more market power have more incentives to tion on financial inclusion. For example, as a sup­
invest in information acquisition and to build long- port of the market power theory, Bara, Mugano,
term relationships with borrowers. Indeed, such and Le Roux (2017) have studied the relationship
banks can better internalize the costs of these activ­ between Bank concentration, country income and
ities and then face lower risks of borrowers leaving financial development in SADC countries for
for another bank (Petersen and Rajan 1995). 1985–2014. They have applied a fixed and random
While SCP and information hypotheses are effect model and found that bank concentration
based on conflicting points of view, a potential constrains development of the financial sectors in
reconciliation could arise from several mechan­ all SADC countries. Mengistu and Saiz (2018) have
isms. Contestable market theory developed by analyzed how competition and financial soundness
Baumol, Panzar, and Willig (1983) shows that a affect financial inclusion in Sub-Saharan Africa, by
concentrated market can remain efficient and per­ using structural and non-structural measures of
formant, if competition exists between actors of competition over 2011 and 2014 period. They
this market (Vives 2011). Furthermore, a strong applied a probit model regression and found that
legal and institutional framework, and fewer more competition tends to increase the probability
restrictions on banking activities can mitigate the of access to financial products. Ajide (2019),
monopolistic market power of banks and improve employed the autoregressive distributed lag
financial inclusion (Fernandez de Guevara, (ARDL) bound test approach to reappraise the
Maudos, and Perez 2005; Gonzalez 2009). relationship between remittances, bank concentra­
Previous empirical studies on the effects of bank tion and credit availability in Nigeria for the period
concentration on financial inclusion, provide 1986–2015. The author found that bank concentra­
mixed results. Earlier studies find that bank con­ tion constrains the development of financial sector
centration promotes financial inclusion (Petersen in Nigeria. Finally, Moyo and Sibindi (2020) used
and Rajan 1995), while others conclude that bank probit model to assess bank concentration and
concentration is negatively related to financial credit access nexus on a sample of 14 Sub-
inclusion (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic Saharan African countries. They found a negative
2004). This first stream of literature mainly uses and significant effect of bank concentration on
cross-sectional, panel and probit models. For access to credit.
example, Shi and Mao (2014) use data from 71 Conversely, work by Ayalew and Xianzhi (2019)
developing countries for 2004–2013, and a probit on a sample of 27 African countries suggests that
model to assess the impact of bank concentration bank competition worsens credit/financing con­
on firms’ access to finance. The authors find that straints. Finally, Chinoda and Mashamba (2021)
firms face fewer financing constraints when the have examined the relationship between financial
banking market is more concentrated. Chauvet inclusion, bank competition and economic growth
and Jacolin (2017) assess the relationships between for a sample of 20 African countries over the period
4 D. AVOM ET AL.

2004–2018. They found that in the long-run bank negative. This finding suggests that there is a
competition reduces financial inclusion, which is in threshold that countries must reach that, eventually
line with the information hypothesis. However, in renders the effects of bank concentration minimal.
the short run the effect is significantly positive, In summary, although the nonlinearity of the
consistent with the market power hypothesis. relationship between bank concentration and
However, the cross-sectional methodology has financial inclusion seems to be widely accepted,
many drawbacks. Quah (1993) formally shows a controversy remains on the sensitivity of this rela­
lack of balanced paths across a country, which tionship due to the frequency of data, the consid­
violates the hypothesis of averaging and pooling ered framework, and the methodology used. Past
cross-country. Evans (1995) also identifies the het­ attempts made to take these nonlinearities into
erogeneity of slope coefficients across countries as account have either exogenously determined the
the main limitation of cross-sectional analysis. threshold level or involved improper treatment of
Furthermore, the methodology used by most pre­ the endogenous threshold. To address this pro­
vious studies does not fully account for endogene­ blem, in addition to the dynamic panel threshold
ity. Correcting for the endogeneity of bank regression, we use the PSTR model to investigate
concentration remains the primary challenge for the nonlinearity of the relationship between bank
researchers focused on the effects of bank concen­ concentration and financial inclusion in African
tration on financial inclusion. A failure to correct countries.
for reverse causality and other sources of endo­
geneity in bank concentration may lead to mislead­
III. Empirical strategy
ing conclusions regarding the causal relationship
between the two variables. Our strategy relies on three methods. The Principal
To address endogeneity issues, Pham, Nguyen, Component Analysis (PCA), the dynamic panel
and Nguyen (2019) applied a system GMM method model regression, and the Panel Smooth Transition
to a sample of 93 countries for 2000–2014 to deter­ Regression (PSTR). The PCA helps us to build an
mine whether competition and bank concentration aggregate index of financial inclusion. The dynamic
promote financial inclusion. The authors find a panel model regression allows us to estimate the
positive effect of bank concentration on financial linear and nonlinear relationships between bank
inclusion. concentration and financial inclusion, while the
As one limitation of the previous studies, they do PSTR estimator highlights the different transitions
not take into account the potential nonlinearity of of bank concentration and the financial inclusion
this relationship. It has been advanced that the nexus with respect to threshold variables.
relationship between bank concentration and
financial inclusion, far from being linear, may be
Index of financial inclusion
influenced by bank concentration or other vari­
ables such as financial freedom, regulatory quality, In computing our index of financial inclusion, we
corruption, and property rights. In other words, combine the approaches of Sarma and Pais (2011)
the marginal effect of financial inclusion may be and Camara and Tuesta (2014). We closely follow the
stronger in some countries than others. Indeed, in approach developed by Nagar and Basu (2002) who
investigating the nonlinearity between bank con­ used PCA to weight socioeconomic indicators from
centration and financial inclusion, Owen and the latent variable. This methodology has recently
Pereira (2018) put forward the existence of thresh­ been used by Nguyen (2020) and Avom, Bangaké,
olds above and below which the effects of bank and Ndoya (2021). The main advantage of this
concentration on financial inclusion differ. More method is that it considers all information contained
precisely, the authors use a system Generalized in each variable used in the construction of the index.
Methods of Moments (SGMM) model to control Following OECD (2008), we start by normalizing
for endogeneity and find a positive impact of bank all indicators, using Min-Max method to reduce the
concentration on financial inclusion. When the influence of outliers. Therefore, any indicator xtqc of
interaction is considered, the relationship becomes country c at the date t is transformed in:
APPLIED ECONOMICS 5

t
xqc minc ðxtqc Þ effect, μt is a time-specific effect and εit is the
Itqc ¼ (1) error term. Our main interest variable is Conc,
maxc ðxtqc Þ minc ðxtqc Þ
which measures bank concentration and is cap­
t t
where minc ðxqc Þ and maxc ðxqc Þ respectively indi­ tured by the assets held by three or five large
cate minimum and maximum values of xtqc between banks.
countries c at the date t. Then, the normalized The GMM estimator is useful for several rea­
indicators Itqc have a value between 0 and 1, where sons. First, the estimator has been widely used to
0 indicates the lowest score and 1 the highest. address the endogeneity problem that appears in
The first step involves applying PCA to estimate panel data estimation (Arellano and Bover 1995;
each of the three dimensions (penetration, avail­ Blundell and Bond 1998). Second, the GMM esti­
ability, and mator also considers the biases that appear due to
P usage) and is P
given by:
country-specific effects. Third, GMM also avoids
Di ¼ dj; k ¼ 1λdj dki
d
dj ¼ 1λdj (2)
where Dk ¼ Xλj . λj represents the variance of the simultaneity or reverse causality problems. Two
kth principal components (weights), X the indica­ versions of the GMM technique have been devel­
tors and Di the index of dimensions. Weights are oped: ‘difference GMM’ and ‘system GMM’. For
assigned to each indicator included in the con­ the difference GMM estimator, the lagged levels of
struction of the dimension indices according to the endogenous variables are used as instruments
their respective contributions. (for exogenous variables, their first differences
The second stage involves conducting a PCA serve as their own instruments). The system
again to compute the overall financial inclusion GMM estimator simultaneously employs the equa­
index by applying a similar procedure to that tion in differences and the equation in levels by
used in the first stage, as follow: using lagged levels of the variables as instruments
X X in the differenced equation and lagged differences
FIIi ¼ Dj; k ¼ 1λj Dki Dj ¼ 1λj (2) of the variables as instruments in the level equa­
tion. Given sample bias concerns associated with
where FIIi is the financial inclusion index of the difference GMM estimator, Bond, Hoeffler, and
country i. The FII obtained is multiplied by 100 Temple (2001) noted that the system GMM esti­
and lies between 0 and 100, with a value close of 0 mator can dramatically improve efficiency and
reflecting a low level of financial inclusion and a avoid the weak instrument problem of the first-
value close of 100 reflecting a high level of financial difference GMM estimator. The consistency of the
inclusion. GMM estimator depends on two factors: the valid­
ity of the assumption that the error term does not
System generalized method of moments (SGMM) exhibit serial correlation (AR (2)) and the validity
of the instruments used (Hansen test).
To properly test the hypothesis that bank concen­
tration can stem from financial inclusion, we use
SGMM as developed by Arellano and Bover (1995), Dynamic panel threshold model
and Blundell and Bond (1998), to estimate our To test for the existence of threshold level of bank
model. The baseline regression of our GMM spe­ concentration in the bank concentration-financial
cification is as follows.. inclusion nexus, we apply the dynamic panel thresh­
FIIit ¼ β0 þ β1 FIIi;t þ β2 Concit þ β3 Xit þ λi þ μt old model of Seo and Shin (2016). This method
1
þ εit extends the original model by Hansen (1999) and
Caner and Hansen (2004) to allow for endogenous
(3) regressors in a panel framework and is practicable by
where FII represents the financial inclusion the work of Seo, Kim, and Kim (2019). Built on the
index, X represents a vector of control vari­ principles of GMM, the method addresses the inher­
ables, λ i is an unobserved country-specific ent endogeneity and simultaneity which cannot be
6 D. AVOM ET AL.

ruled out in the nexus between bank concentration The measure also allows us to address problems of
and financial inclusion. At the same time, the financial inclusion measurement often discussed in
method further reports the threshold level between the literature. Then, we compare the effects of bank
bank concentration and financial inclusion. concentration on financial inclusion to each of the
The model takes the following form: three dimensions mentioned above. The index of
financial inclusion and the dimensions range from
FIIit ¼ μi þ β1 Concit δ1 Iðqit � γÞ 0 to 100; with a value of close to 0 indicating the
þ β2 Concit Iðqit > γÞ þ φXit þ εit (4) worst performance and a value close of 100 indicat­
where qit is the threshold variable, γis the thresh­ ing the best performance. The main exogenous
old level, and the error term isεit . I (·) is an indi­ variable is bank concentration (C3/C5) as, mea­
cator function taking a value of 1 if the argument in sured by the total assets held by the three or five
the indicator function holds, and 0 otherwise. The largest banks in a country. Following empirical
threshold variable, qit divides the sample into works on the determinants of financial inclusion,
regimes with different regression slope parameters we use a set of control variables, to assess the
β1 andβ2 . We use bank concentration, financial strength of an independent link between bank con­
freedom, protection of property rights, mobile centration and financial inclusion. We use GDP per
phones penetration, control of corruption and reg­ capita (GDPPC) and domestic credit to the private
ulatory quality as the threshold variable. Xit is a sector to appraise financial development (Findev);
vector of explanatory variables which may include Allen et al. (2014), Evans (2015) and Li and Wong
lagged dependent variable. (2018) have shown that economic and financial
To allow for differences in the regime intercept, development are lever of financial inclusion. We
we follow Osei and Kim (2020) and include a also control for human capital, measured by mean
threshold interceptδ. Including regime intercept years of schooling. As mentioned by Guerineau
helps minimize any potential bias in the threshold and Jacolin (2014), education is a key driver of
and the marginal effect estimates.2 financial inclusion. Following Pham, Nguyen, and
Nguyen (2019), we also control for bank ineffi­
ciency and systemic stability. We use bank over­
IV. Data and variable description head costs to total assets to proxy bank inefficiency
The present study covers the period of 2004 to 2017 (Inefficiency), while systemic stability is proxied by
and focuses on data for a sample of 30 African non-performing loan (NPL).
countries,3 on the basis of the quality and availabil­ To analyze the nonlinear relationship and to
ity of data. Data are taken from different sources: check for the main channels through which bank
the World Development Indicators (WDI), Global concentration affects financial inclusion, we use
Financial Development Database (GFDD) and bank concentration, financial freedom, property
Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) from rights protection, mobile phone penetration, con­
the World Bank, and IMF’s Financial Access trol of corruption and regulatory quality as thresh­
Survey (FAS). old variables. Table 1 provides the descriptive
Our endogenous variable is the financial inclu­ statistics and it shows that from 2004–2017, the
sion index (FII) as measured by a composite index average level of financial inclusion in our sample
based on three dimensions (penetration,4 is 16.29%, with average value of 15.99, 18.30 and
availability5 and usage6). Using an aggregated mea­ 18.92% found for penetration, availability and
sure of financial inclusion allows us to take into usage, respectively. The level of financial inclusion
account the maximum amount of information is relatively low, with limited penetration of finan­
related to access to and use of financial services. cial products and services. However, the average
2
Further details of the method can be found in Seo and Shin (2016) and Seo, Kim, and Kim (2019).
3
Algeria, Botswana, Burundi, Cameroon, Central Africa Republic, Chad, Congo, Egypt, Equatorial Guinea, Eswatini, Gabon, Ghana, Guinea, Kenya, Madagascar,
Malawi, Mauritius, Morocco, Mozambique, Namibia, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Senegal, Seychelles, South Africa, Tanzania, Tunisia, Uganda, Zambia.
4
Penetration refers to the percentage of the adult population with financial accounts to total population and life and nonlife insurance policies per 1000 adults.
5
Availability includes the number of commercial bank branches and of ATMs per 1000 km2 and per 100,000 adults.
6
Usage is measured as the share of the adult population who borrowed and saved from a financial institution.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 7

Table 1. Descriptive statistics.


Variable Unit Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
FII Index 420 16.289 16.581 0.789 75.998
Penetration Index 420 10.805 15.986 0.5 84.327
Availability Index 420 17.731 18.303 2.334 78.891
Usage Index 420 20.258 18.923 0.368 0.869
C3 Percentage 392 73.359 21.143 32.062 100
C5 Percentage 336 84.897 16.311 48.653 100
Boone Index 406 −0.075 0.198 −2.540 0.321
Lerner Index 308 0.285 0.136 −0.282 0.648
NPL Ratio 406 9.301 8.307 −26.035 41.508
Inefficiency Ratio 420 5.797 6.695 −3.44 90.339
Findev Percentage 420 27.019 29.722 2.097 160.125
GDPPC USD 420 3297.772 3865.53 213.405 20333.94
Human capital No of years 420 5.457 2.147 1.3 10.1
Financial freedom Index 420 45 12.130 20 70
Property rights Index 420 38.160 14.586 10 75
Control of corruption Index 420 −0.527 0.620 −1.825 1.159
Regulatory quality Index 420 −0.479 0.543 −1.480 1.127
Mobile phones Percentage 420 60.428 42.050 1.263 91.496
Source: Author’s calculations.

level of bank concentration is 73.35% for the three


largest banks and 84.90% for the five largest banks. Table 2. Direct effect of bank concentration on financial inclu­
Thus, bank concentration is high in our sample sion and sensitivity analysis (C3 indicator).
(1) (2) (3) (4)
and, higher than the global average. FII Penetration Availability Usage
C3 −0.041*** −0.027** −0.032** −0.053***
(0.014) (0.013) (0.015) (0.018)
V. Results and discussion NPL −0.047** −0.050* −0.039 0.021
(0.023) (0.029) (0.061) (0.047)
Inefficiency 0.131* 0.043 0.129 0.053
Results of the linear nexus between bank (0.070) (0.070) (0.146) (0.288)
concentration and financial inclusion Findev 0.031 −0.003 0.024** 0.050*
(0.019) (0.011) (0.011) (0.027)
As an initial exercise, we analyze the direct impact of GDPPC 0.001*** 0.001** 0.001*** 0.001***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
bank concentration on financial inclusion. To test Hum Cap −0.221 −0.269 −0.563 −0.497*
(0.175) (0.227) (0.472) (0.257)
the sensitivity of the results, we compare the effect of L.FII 0.908***
bank concentration (C3 and C5) to the different (0.039)
L.Penetration 0.949***
dimensions of the financial inclusion index. (0.043)
Although this linear specification is not our pre­ L.Availability 0.976***
(0.054)
ferred model for this work, it allows us to appraise L.Usage 0.923***
the standalone effect of bank concentration and the (0.058)
Constant 3.582 3.049 4.287 5.265***
other control variables on financial inclusion. The (2.169) (1.807) (3.431) (1.894)
results obtained from the first set of regressions of Observations 351 351 352 351
Countries 27 27 27 27
SGMM method are reported in Tables 2 and 3, Instruments 25 25 24 24
AR (1) 0.000 0.012 0.003 0.002
respectively for C3 and C5 indicators. AR (2) 0.904 0.681 0.610 0.218
To lessen concerns about endogeneity, we lagged Hansen 0.891 0.632 0.680 0.867
all regressors one period. In all regressions shown in Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are
shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and
Tables 2 and 3, we control for non-performing loans, the rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively.
bank inefficiency, financial development, GDP per C3 indicates bank concentration for the three largest banks, FII is the
financial inclusion index and L denotes to lag variables.
capita, and human capital. The regressions satisfy all
of the specification tests (AR (1), AR (2) and Hansen
test). There is no evidence of a second-order serial Across all estimations, we find that bank con­
correlation, but there is evidence of a first-order serial centration is negatively and significantly related to
correlation. Moreover, the regressions pass the financial inclusion regardless of the measure of
Hansen test and confirm the validity of the bank concentration used. This finding supports
instruments. the view that bank concentration stems from
8 D. AVOM ET AL.

Table 3. Direct effect of bank concentration on financial inclu­ Let us consider a general finding relating to the
sion and sensitivity analysis (C5 indicator). other control variables. The positive coefficients of
(1) (2) (3) (4)
FII Penetration Availability Usage GDP per capita and financial development are sig­
C5 −0.056** −0.028** −0.063*** −0.087*** nificant determinants of financial inclusion. As
(0.021) (0.011) (0.022) (0.030) shown by Adeola and Evans (2017) and Li and
NPL −0.063* −0.086 −0.094** 0.002
(0.035) (0.063) (0.040) (0.095) Wong (2018), finance is easier to access in high-
Inefficiency 0.063 −0.042 0.495*** 0.415*
(0.131) (0.141) (0.170) (0.235)
income and developed financial system countries.
Findev 0.101* 0.024* 0.079** 0.081* However, the previous linear specification
(0.056) (0.012) (0.034) (0.042)
GDPPC 0.000** 0.001* 0.000* 0.000** assumes the homogeneity of the nexus between
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) bank concentration and financial inclusion; this
Hum Cap −0.207 −0.383* 0.019 −0.411
(0.230) (0.196) (0.247) (0.345) can be misleading. Indeed, countries that have the
L.FII 0.851*** same level of bank concentration record different
(0.080)
L.Penetration 0.892*** levels of financial inclusion. These divergences can
(0.055) lead to a nonlinear relationship between the two
L.Availability 0.907***
(0.050) variables.
L.Usage 0.944***
(0.053)
Constant 5.512** 4.617** 2.788 5.840
(2.081) (1.723) (1.678) (3.933) Results of the nonlinear nexus between bank
Observations 276 276 276 276
Countries 23 23 23 23 concentration and financial inclusion
Instruments 20 20 19 20
AR (1) 0.005 0.048 0.002 0.004 In this section, we explore whether there is a non­
AR (2) 0.843 0.880 0.287 0.152
Hansen 0.629 0.732 0.705 0.690
linear nexus between bank concentration and
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are financial inclusion. We first test the threshold effect
shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and by using bank concentration as the threshold vari­
the rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively.
C5 indicates bank concentration for the five largest banks, FII is the able (model (1)) and we further run the threshold
financial inclusion index and L denotes to lag variables. regression by using other thresholds variables such
as financial freedom, protection of property rights,
financial inclusion in developing countries, parti­ mobile phone penetration, control of corruption
cularly in African countries. This finding corrobo­ and regulatory quality. In this regard, we develop
rates the results of Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and a nonlinear specification, using dynamic panel
Maksimovic (2004), Love and Martínez pería threshold regression.
(2015) and Chauvet and Jacolin (2017), who find We first run a dynamic threshold model, and we
a negative impact of bank concentration on finan­ test for the existence of a threshold level of bank
cial inclusion. With regard to different dimensions concentration in the bank concentration-financial
of financial inclusion, we find similar results as for inclusion relationship. The results of our dynamic
the financial inclusion index: a negative and sig­ panel threshold model are presented in Tables 4
nificant effect of bank concentration on each and 5. The first column of Tables 4 and 5 shows the
dimension. results with bank concentration as threshold vari­
These findings support the theoretical view of able. They imply that there is a threshold relation­
the market power hypothesis, which predicts a ship in the nexus level of bank concentration for
negative effect of bank concentration on access to achieving financial inclusion in Africa.
finance. Countries with concentrated banking sec­ Furthermore, the threshold relationship is vali­
tors exhibit low financial product and service pene­ dated by the linearity test. The test is based on the
tration and availability, especially in poor countries bootstrap algorithm robust to the nonparametric
with less developed financial systems. Moreover, iid under the null hypothesis of no threshold. The
banks in such countries take advantage of their results of the linearity test confirm that the models
reduced values on the market and their market are not linear because the indicators are significant
power to increase the cost of credit, which ulti­ at 1%. The point estimate of the threshold values is
mately negatively affects financial inclusion. 59.63 and 76.94, respectively for C3 and C5 which
APPLIED ECONOMICS 9

Table 4. Dynamic panel threshold estimation of the effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion (C3 indicator).
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES C3 Financial freedom Property rights Mobile phones Control of corruption Regulatory quality
First regime (C3) −0.485*** −0.107* −0.202* −0.191*** −0.580*** −0.408**
(0.175) (0.051) (0.109) (0.072) (0.200) (0.189)
Second regime (C3) 0.517*** 0.345*** 0.297** 0.303** 0.533** 0.364**
(0.189) (0.106) (0.126) (0.118) (0.225) (0.152)
NPL 0.189 0.440* 0.138 1.557*** −0.932 −0.279*
(0.340) (0.256) (0.406) (0.397) (0.743) (0.163)
Inefficiency −0.296 2.373*** −1.149 −0.247 0.593 0.136
(0.578) (0.792) (0.786) (1.050) (0.948) (0.413)
Findev −0.175** 0.033 −0.257* 0.144** 0.249** 0.270**
(0.078) (0.038) (0.139) (0.073) (0.105) (0.129)
GDPPC −0.001 0.004*** 0.002 −0.003* −0.005 −0.001
(0.002) (0.001) (0.004) (0.002) (0.003) (0.001)
Hum Cap 3.316* −2.128** −4.381 3.129 6.821* −2.544
(1.741) (1.061) (4.348) (2.482) (4.056) (3.546)
L.FII 0.542** 1.123*** 0.829** 0.400* 0.939*** 0.324***
(0.216) (0.183) (0.407) (0.229) (0.299) (0.090)
Constant −42.977*** −27.835*** 0.842 −39.211* −47.093* −15.801
(10.287) (8.954) (28.526) (20.063) (27.640) (22.680)
Threshold 59.632*** 50*** 44.141*** 83.746*** 0.512*** 0.343***
CI [56.81–64.46] [49.35–50.65] [37.88–50.40] [79.87–87.52] [0.46–0.57] [0.33–0.35]
No. Countries 27 27 27 27 27 27
No. Instruments 19 23 13 18 19 19
Linearity test (prob.) 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000***
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicates statistical significance and the
rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. C3 indicate bank concentration for the three largest banks, FII is the financial inclusion
index and L denotes to lag variables. CI indicates the confidence intervals at 95%.

Table 5. Dynamic panel threshold estimation of the effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion (C5 indicator).
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Threshold variables C5 Financial freedom Property rights Mobile phones Control of corruption Regulatory quality
First regime (C5) −0.784** −1.076*** −0.233* −0.689*** −0.603*** −1.067**
(0.352) (0.311) (0.139) (0.242) (0.215) (0.485)
Second regime (C5) 1.344*** 0.752* 0.702* 0.715* 0.884** 1.249**
(0.404) (0.447) (0.369) (0.565) (0.409) (0.595)
NPL −3.175* 1.363 −2.789** −0.493 −3.037 −0.906
(1.840) (1.015) (1.139) (1.821) (2.119) (0.703)
Inefficiency 0.224 −0.377 1.315* 1.181 1.924 −2.116**
(0.618) (0.536) (0.755) (1.338) (1.644) (0.996)
Findev −0.029 0.016 −0.292** −0.184* −0.133 −0.138
(0.207) (0.123) (0.146) (0.101) (0.106) (0.296)
GDPPC 0.012* −0.000 0.001 −0.010*** −0.006 −0.006
(0.007) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.006) (0.005)
Hum Cap −2.158 1.197 −3.389 9.156** −1.618 −4.084
(5.087) (4.776) (5.895) (4.434) (3.700) (10.473)
L.FII 2.671*** 1.047*** 0.754 0.642 1.315* 0.791
(0.798) (0.398) (0.595) (1.392) (0.703) (0.940)
Constant −73.591* −65.766 −53.531 −85.606 −66.822 −37.056
(38.347) (51.969) (33.963) (69.981) (42.776) (66.092)
Threshold 76.937*** 40*** 49.630*** 86.465 0.600*** 0.268***
CI [74.52–79.35] [38.46–41.54] [49.51–49.75] [80.12–87.35] [0.39–0.81] [0.21–0.32]
No. Countries 23 23 23 23 23 23
No. Instruments 21 20 13 15 19 21
Linearity test (prob.) 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000***
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and the
rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. C5 indicates bank concentration for the five largest banks, FII is the financial inclusion
index and L denotes to lag variables. CI indicates the confidence intervals at 95%.

are equivalent to 59.63% and 76.94% of the assets threshold, however, the effect of bank concentra­
held by the three and five largest banks respectively. tion is positive and significant at 1% level for the
With respect to the regime-dependent marginal both indicators. This second wave of results is
effects, bank concentration appears to have a sig­ consistent with the information efficiency hypoth­
nificantly negative effect on financial inclusion at esis, which predicts a positive effect of bank con­
1% and 5% level, respectively for C3 and C5 if bank centration on financial inclusion, and opposes the
concentration is less than the threshold. Above the market power hypothesis.
10 D. AVOM ET AL.

In the other models, i.e. when using the other ratios used above. The second robustness analysis
threshold variables, the linearity tests are signifi­ consists of using an alternative estimation strategy
cant at 1% and confirm the nonlinear relationship to assess the nonlinearity between bank concentra­
between bank concentration and financial inclu­ tion and financial inclusion.
sion, whatever the threshold variable used. Our baseline analysis adopted the concentra­
For example, using financial freedom as the tion ratios (C3/C5) to measure bank concentra­
threshold variable, the study finds a threshold tion. There are more involved measures which
level of 50% and 40% respectively for C3 and C5. are commonly used to assess the degree of
The results imply that under these thresholds, bank effective banking concentration (Carbó et al.
concentration decreases financial inclusion in 2009; Claessens 2009). We then use two
African countries and beyond these thresholds the involved indicators to ascertain the robustness
relationship between bank concentration and of our findings. The first indicator is the Lerner
financial inclusion become positive. Thus, fewer index, which is defined as the difference
constraints on banking activities lead to a positive between output prices and marginal costs (rela­
effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion tive to prices) and is equal to the inverse of the
(Fernandez de Guevara, Maudos, and Perez 2005; elasticity of demand for the case of a perfect
Gonzalez 2009). monopoly and equal to zero for a perfect com­
Moreover, regarding the estimation results of petitive market. Therefore, higher values of the
mobile phone as threshold variable, the point esti­ Lerner Index indicate high bank concentration
mate of the threshold values is 83.75% and 86.47%, and less competition (Clerides, Delis, and
respectively for C3 and C5. The results imply that Kokas 2015). The second indicator is the
bank concentration negatively affects financial Boone Indicator (Boone 2008), which reflects
inclusion in countries with low mobile phones the effect of efficiency on profits, calculated as
penetration (threshold of mobile phones lower the elasticity of profits to marginal costs. The
than 83.75 and 86.47), and the effect of bank con­ indicator mainly measures that more efficient
centration on financial inclusion become positive banks achieve higher profits. Therefore, the
when the penetration of mobile phones is high more negative the Boone indicator, the lower
(threshold of mobile phones greater than 83.75 level of banking concentration and the more
and 86.47). Mobile phone penetration can there­ positive the Boone indicator, the higher level
fore be an alternative for individuals to access of bank concentration.
financial services when the banking market is As in the previous analysis we first perform a
concentrated. linear regression, assessing the direct effect of
Turning to the regulatory quality as threshold Lerner and Boone indicators on financial inclusion,
variable, the results show that the threshold level of using SGMM. We also analyze the sensitivity of the
regulatory quality is 0.34 and 0.27 for C3 and C5, results by estimating the effect of both Lerner index
respectively. This finding corroborates the views of and Boone indicator on the different dimensions of
Claessens and Laeven (2005), Delis (2012), financial inclusion (penetration, availability and
Anginer, Demirguc-Kunt, and Zhu (2014) and usage).
Owen and Pereira (2018), who showed that the The results are reported in Tables 6 and 7 for
negative effect of bank concentration on financial Lerner index, respectively. In all regressions shown
inclusion can be mitigated by a strong regulatory in Tables 6 and 7, we also control for non-perform­
quality framework. ing loans, bank inefficiency, financial development,
GDP per capita, and human capital. The regres­
sions satisfy all of the specification tests (AR (1),
Robustness checks
AR (2) and Hansen test). There is no evidence of a
In this section, we perform two main robustness second-order serial correlation, but there is evi­
analyses. The first is to use alternative indicators to dence of a first-order serial correlation. Moreover,
measure the structure of the banking market, given the regressions pass the Hansen test and confirm
the criticisms generally leveled to the concentration the validity of the instruments.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 11

Table 6. Robustness checks on the direct effect of bank con­ Table 7. Robustness checks on the direct effect of bank con­
centration on financial inclusion, by using Lerner index. centration on financial inclusion, by using Boone indicator.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (1) (2) (3) (4)
FII Penetration Availability Usage VARIABLES FII Penetration Availability Usage
Lerner −4.443*** −2.540* −4.975** −3.870** Boone −1.493*** −1.472*** −1.360** −3.289***
(1.423) (1.460) (2.237) (1.653) (0.508) (0.492) (0.658) (0.825)
NPL −0.462* −0.208 0.069 −0.479 NPL −0.121** −0.332* 0.069** 0.055
(0.255) (0.156) (0.229) (0.428) (0.051) (0.172) (0.026) (0.097)
Inefficiency −0.125** −0.107* −0.220*** 0.022 Inefficiency −0.089** −0.155*** −0.067** −0.118**
(0.056) (0.054) (0.074) (0.177) (0.035) (0.046) (0.029) (0.051)
Findev 0.105*** −0.003 0.065** 0.132*** Findev −0.008 −0.011 0.016 −0.019
(0.037) (0.026) (0.027) (0.036) (0.023) (0.038) (0.019) (0.027)
GDPPC 0.001 0.001* 0.001* 0.000 GDPPC 0.000*** 0.001** 0.000** 0.000*
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Hum Cap 0.197 −0.187 −0.543 0.318 Hum Cap −0.290 −0.418 −0.333 −0.457
(0.402) (0.477) (0.715) (0.388) (0.190) (0.453) (0.375) (0.444)
L.FII 0.732*** L.FII 0.964***
(0.050) (0.033)
L.Penetration 0.840*** L.Penetration 0.959***
(0.069) (0.040)
L.Availability 0.774*** L.Availability 0.996***
(0.079) (0.038)
L.Usage 0.801*** L.Usage 1.058***
(0.098) (0.031)
Constant 4.454 3.745* 5.669* 2.695 Constant 3.338*** 5.351* 1.381 2.575
(3.428) (2.116) (3.189) (2.086) (1.151) (3.049) (1.302) (1.636)
Observations 273 252 252 273 Observations 308 364 364 364
Countries 21 21 21 21 Countries 28 28 28 28
Instruments 17 17 17 17 Instruments 25 25 25 25
AR (1) 0.026 0.013 0.014 0.005 AR (1) 0.000 0.016 0.005 0.003
AR (2) 0.549 0.726 0.513 0.384 AR (2) 0.902 0.552 0.578 0.294
Hansen 0.802 0.821 0.485 0.771 Hansen 0.464 0.343 0.756 0.492
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are
shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and
the rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. the rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively.
FII is the financial inclusion index and L denotes to lagged variables. FII is the financial inclusion index and L denotes to lag variables.

Table 8. Robustness checks on the dynamic panel threshold regression of the effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion, by
using Lerner index.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Threshold variable Lerner Financial freedom Property rights Mobile phones Control of corruption Regulatory quality
First regime (Lerner) −2.521 −1.496* −4.750** −5.507** −5.103** −5.466*
(23.164) (16.648) (23.921) (30.557) (51.209) (31.976)
Second regime (Lerner) 3.681* 1.084 3.899** 4.966* 3.204** 3.052
(20.417) (16.062) (18.224) (43.900) (50.155) (24.467)
NPL −0.427* −0.812 0.485 0.278 −0.042 1.057
(0.253) (1.270) (1.062) (1.033) (1.221) (0.818)
Inefficiency −1.196 −1.645 −0.145 −0.887 −4.208 −0.617
(1.151) (2.700) (1.138) (3.434) (4.011) (2.083)
Findev 0.075 0.002 −0.333 −0.401 0.534 −0.244
(0.204) (0.057) (0.415) (0.486) (0.774) (0.183)
GDPPC −0.000 −0.005 0.011 −0.005 0.018 0.017
(0.005) (0.007) (0.013) (0.005) (0.030) (0.012)
Hum Cap −4.241 15.457* −2.361 5.888 −18.814 −3.039
(3.762) (9.071) (9.699) (6.839) (35.701) (6.753)
L.FII 8.412 −68.705 4.585 −24.344 137.663 −32.481
(19.808) (43.370) (51.901) (37.843) (203.608) (24.987)
Constant 0.958* 0.553 1.238 0.699 4.436 0.437
(0.511) (0.893) (1.261) (0.721) (5.553) (1.682)
Threshold 0.211*** 60.000*** 39.495*** 61.283*** 0.379*** 0.466***
CI [0.17–0.26] [59.56–60.44] [36.99–42.03] [44.32–78.29] [0.35–0.41] [0.44–0.49]
No. Countries 21 21 21 21 21 21
No. Instruments 20 18 19 13 18 14
Linearity test (prob.) 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000***
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and the
rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. FII is the financial inclusion index and L denotes to lag variables. CI indicates the
confidence intervals at 95%.
12 D. AVOM ET AL.

Overall, the results show a negative and signifi­ and Boone indicator, and financial inclusion.
cant effect of both Lerner index and Boone indica­ Specifically, for Lerner index for example, the
tor on financial inclusion. These results confirm results in Table 8 show that the threshold relation­
those obtained with concentration ratio measures ship is validated by the linearity test. The results of
(C3 and C5) and corroborate the market power the linearity test confirm that the models are not
hypothesis, which states that bank concentration linear because the indicators are significant at 1%.
stems from financial inclusion. Moreover, with The point estimate of the threshold values is 0.21.
regard to different dimensions of financial inclu­ With respect to the regime-dependent marginal
sion, we find similar results as for the financial effects, Lerner index appears to have a negative
inclusion index: a negative and significant effect but insignificant effect on financial inclusion
of bank concentration on each dimension. Our below the threshold and a positive and significant
results using alternative measures remain robust. effect on financial inclusion at 10% level beyond the
Further, as in baseline analysis, we run a non­ threshold. In the same vein for Boone indicator, the
linear regression with the Lerner index and the results of the linearity test are also significant at 1%
Boone indicator, using the dynamic panel thresh­ level, confirming that the models are not linear.
old regression method. We first investigated a The estimated threshold of the Boone indicator is
threshold effect of the Lerner index and the −0.36. Therefore, under the first regime, the Boone
Boone indicator in the nexus with financial inclu­ indicator is negative and significant at 10% level
sion, and we further analyze other threshold and the effect become positive and significant at 5%
variables. level under the second regime.
The results of the dynamic panel threshold Let us consider a general comment relating to
model are reported in Tables 8 and 9, respectively the other threshold variables. All the other thresh­
for Lerner index and Boone indicator. The first old variables confirm a nonlinear relationship and
model of each specification assesses the threshold threshold effect in the nexus between both Lerner
effect. In sum, the results in Tables 8 and 9 also index and Boone indicator on financial inclusion.
confirm the robustness of our baseline findings, a The results show a negative effect of Lerner index
nonlinear relationship between both Lerner index and Boone indicator under the first regime (below

Table 9. Robustness checks on the dynamic panel threshold regression of the effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion, by
using Boone indicator.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Threshold variables Boone Financial freedom Property rights Mobile phones Control of corruption Regulatory quality
First regime (Boone) −3.941* −1.680* −2.788* −4.113** −2.514* −4.702***
(2.644) (0.969) (1.175) (1.164) (0.886) (2.373)
Second regime (Boone) 2.283* 17.071** 1.575*** 3.691** 2.484 4.324***
(1.794) (8.608) (0.699) (0.603) (21.373) (2.392)
NPL 0.001 −0.025 0.763** 1.260** 0.458 −0.459*
(0.108) (0.165) (0.351) (0.541) (0.332) (0.278)
Inefficiency 0.362 0.492 −0.583 2.015 0.750 0.045
(0.767) (0.585) (0.515) (1.953) (0.846) (0.628)
Findev −0.070** 0.017 −0.113 −2.301*** 0.285 0.234
(0.033) (0.046) (0.111) (0.721) (0.263) (0.302)
GDPPC −0.002*** 0.001 0.002* 0.003 −0.002 0.004
(0.000) (0.002) (0.001) (0.010) (0.003) (0.003)
Hum Cap 3.820** −1.379 −5.375** −0.786 11.348** −6.586**
(1.933) (1.994) (2.240) (4.312) (5.655) (3.119)
L.FII 0.884*** 1.053*** 0.940*** 5.940** 1.679*** 1.085**
(0.160) (0.094) (0.209) (2.635) (0.643) (0.474)
Constant −18.155* 3.533 4.537 −22.179 −23.571 30.534**
(10.047) (6.987) (12.990) (22.207) (19.179) (12.343)
Threshold −0.36*** 50*** 45.152*** 27.095*** 0.491*** 0.228***
CI [−0.06–0.012] [46.30–53.57] [44.46–54.84] [22.13–32.06] [0.46–0.50] [0.22–0.23]
No. Countries 28 28 28 28 28 28
No. Instruments 21 24 13 13 18 16
Linearity test (prob.) 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000***
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and the
rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. FII is the financial inclusion index and L denotes to lag variables. CI indicates the
confidence intervals at 95%.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 13

the indicated threshold) and a positive a significant and Terasvirta et al. (1993) and González,
effect under the second regime (above the indicated Teräsvirta, and Van Dijk (2005), we consider the
threshold), whatever the threshold variable used. following logistic transition function:
Our findings of the dynamic panel threshold
regression, using alternative measures of bank con­ Γðqit ; γ; cÞ ¼ ½1 þ expð γðqit cÞÞ� 1 ; γ�0
centration remain robust. (6)
As mentioned above our second robustness For a high value of γ, the transition becomes
check addressed the concern with alternative strat­ rougher, and transition function Γ(qit ; γ; c) tends
egy to assess the nonlinear relationship between toward indicator function Γ(qit ; c). Hence, when γ
bank concentration and financial inclusion. We tends to infinity, the PSTR model
therefore check for the robustness of this nonli­ reduces to Hansen’s (Hansen 1999) two-regime
nearity by using a PSTR estimator, proposed by panel threshold regression (PTR) model. In the
González, Teräsvirta, and Van Dijk (2005). The opposite case, when γ is close to 0, transition func­
main advantage of the PSTR model is that it allows tion Γ(qit ; γ; c) is constant, and the PSTR estima­
the bank concentration–financial inclusion coeffi­ tion becomes a panel with fixed-effects. Last, low
cients to vary with respect to time and country. and high values of qit correspond to the two
Hence, the coefficients can take different values, extremes. For instance, if transition variable qit is
depending on the value of another observable vari­ different from the bank concentration variable, the
able, which in our case is bank concentration, bank sensitivity of financial inclusion to the bank con­
stability, financial freedom or the control of cor­ centration level for the ith country at time t is
ruption. The PSTR model allows individuals to defined as follows:
move between groups and over time depending
on changes in the threshold variables. The PSTR @FIIit
#it ¼ ¼ β0 þ β1 Γðqit ; γ; cÞ (7)
model also provides a parametric approach to @Concit
cross-country heterogeneity, and to the time where β0 and β0 + β1 are the regression coeffi­
instability of the bank concentration–financial cients and Γ(qit; γ; c) is the transition function. #it is
inclusion coefficient, smoothing the alterations of defined as a weighted average of parameters β0 and
these coefficients with respect to the threshold β1 located at two extreme regimes of the PSTR
variables. model. β0 indicates the first regime (i.e. when the
The simplest case of a PSTR with two extreme transition function tends toward 0) and β0 + β1
regimes and a single transition function is written indicates the second regime (i.e. when the transi­
as follows: tion function tends toward 1).
FIIit ¼ μi þ β0 Conci;t þ β1 Conci;t 1 Γðqit ; γ; cÞ For estimating a PSTR model, González,
1
þ δ0 0 Xit þ εit Teräsvirta, and Van Dijk (2005) propose the fol­
lowing procedure: (a) test the linearity against the
(5)
PSTR model, and (b) determine the number r of
for i = 1, . . . , N and t = 1, . . . , T, where N and T transition functions. The test of linearity using the
denote the cross-sectional and time dimensions PSTR model applies the following:
of the panel, respectively. FII is the financial H0 : γ ¼ 0orH0 : β2 ¼ 0. However, under the
inclusion index, Conc the bank concentration and null hypothesis, the test is nonstandard in both
Xit is a vector of control variables. µi represents cases, and the PSTR model contains unidentified
individual fixed-effects, and εit is the error term. nuisance parameters. A possible solution is to
Transition function Γ is continuous and depends replace transition function Γ(qit; γ; c) with its
on threshold variable qit and on c, which is location first-order Taylor expression around γ = 0 and to
the parameter. Last, parameter γ determines the test an equivalent hypothesis in an auxiliary regres­
slope of the transition function. Based on Granger sion. We then obtain the following..
14 D. AVOM ET AL.

FIIit ¼ αi þ θ0 Concit þ θ1 Conct � qit þ δ0 Xit þ ε�it thresholds of bank concentration are 55.01% and
(8) 73%, for C3 and C5, respectively. Indeed, under the
first regime (below the threshold), all else being
Because θi parameters are proportional to the equal, bank concentration stems from financial
slope parameter of transition function γ, testing inclusion, and the effect becomes positive under
the linearity of the bank concentration-financial the second regime (above the threshold).
inclusion model against PSTR involves testing the In the same vein, as in previous results, the non­
following: . linear relationship is confirmed when using the
Let SSR0 be the panel sum of squared residuals other threshold variable. Turning to financial free­
under H0, and let SSR1 be the PSTR model with dom as threshold variable for example, the PSTR
m regimes. The corresponding F-statistic is then results exhibit two regimes, where the bank con­
defined as follows: centration effect is negative and significant under
LMF ðSSR0 SSR1 Þ=mk the first regime and positive and significant under
,F ðmk; TN N mkÞ the second one. The estimated thresholds for finan­
SSR0 ðTN N mkÞ
cial freedom are 50.95% and 56.09% for C3 and C5,
(9) respectively.
where T, N and K denote the number of years, Overall, these nonlinear results confirm previous
the number of countries and the number of exo­ findings obtained with the dynamic threshold
genous variables, respectively. regression. For all specifications, the value of the
The results of the PSTR estimation are reported slope parameter is low, characterizing a smooth
in Tables 10 and 11 and they confirm the results change of the transition function.
previously obtained when estimating the panel Finally, as for dynamic panel regression, we also
threshold regression, i.e. a nonlinear relationship perform a PSTR regression with the Lerner index
between bank concentration and financial inclu­ and the Boone indicator. The results are reported
sion. Hence, bank concentration exhibits two in Tables 12 and 13 for the Lerner index and the
extreme regimes with a smooth shift characterizing Boone indicator, respectively and remain robust
the bank concentration-financial inclusion nexus, whatever the model or the specification. The
where the bank concentration effect is negative and PSTR results exhibit two extreme regimes with a
significant under the first regime and positive and smooth shift characterizing the Lerner index-finan­
significant under the second. The estimated cial inclusion nexus, and the Boone indicator-

Table 10. PSTR estimation of the effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion (C3 indicator).
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Threshold variables C3 Financial freedom Property rights Mobile phones Control of corruption Regulatory quality
First regime (C3) −0.274** −0.095*** −0.068** −0.069*** −0.233* −0.376***
(0.133) (0.028) (0.027) (0.020) (0.156) (0.170)
Second regime (C3) 0.709** 0.062*** 0.041 0.160*** 0.606*** 0.920*
(0.276) (0.023) (0.035) (0.027) (0.194) (0.639)
NPL 0.156** −0.081 −0.066 −0.302* −0.283** −0.196***
(0.043) (0.078) (0.062) (0.170) (0.115) (0.043)
Inefficiency −0.365 −0.523** −0.034 0.742*** 0.928*** −0.413
(0.321) (0.246) (0.313) (0.281) (0.482) (0.176)
Findev −0.168*** 0.114*** 0.098*** 0.027** 1.757 0.452***
(0.050) (0.034) (0.037) (0.013) (1.304) (0.043)
GDPPC 0.375 −0.002*** 0.001 −0.001* 0.001 0.083
(0.687) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.031)
Hum Cap 0.658 0.426 −0.604 −0.802** 3.446*** 0.890***
(0.592) (0.277) (0.574) (0.373) (0.968) (0.456)
Threshold 55.01 50.95 32.11 97.43 0.42 0.62
γ 1.080 2.675 20.681 5.313 10.760 3.266
LMF 5.687 3.467 4.152 5.697 3.803 3.355
(0.000) (0.002) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000)
r 1 1 1 1 1 1
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and the
rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. C3 indicates bank concentration for the three largest banks, FII is the financial inclusion
index and r indicates the number of transition function.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 15

Table 11. PSTR estimation of the effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion (C5 indicator).
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Threshold variable C5 Financial freedomProperty rightsMobile phonesControl of corruption Regulatory quality


First regime (C5) −0.149** −0.042 −0.063*** −0.426* −0.426** −0.036*
(0.063) (0.030) (0.024) (0.228) (0.240) (0.021)
Second regime (C5) 0.232*** 0.078*** 0.244*** 0.838*** 0.069* 0.095**
(0.068) (0.022) (0.178) (0.220) (0.041) (0.043)
NPL −0.178* −0.022** −0.877* −0.620*** −0.690** 0.114
(0.110) (0.095) (0.619) (0.210) (0.279) (0.121)
Inefficiency 0.724 −1.024*** 0.476*** −0.043** −0.301 −1.482**
(0.443) (0.232) (0.149) (0.079) (0.446) (0.645)
Findev −0.433 0.151*** −0.131 1.157** −0.136*** 0.096**
(0.049) (0.047) (0.207) (0.491) (0.051) (0.044)
GDPPC −0.004*** −0.005*** −0.006*** −0.001* 0.001 −0.007***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Hum Cap 0.948* 1.348*** 0.486*** −0.161*** 0.522 1.801***
(0.537) (0.400) (0.285) (0.473) (0.679) (0.266)
Threshold 73 56.09 54.59 93.22 0.71 0.53
γ 0.184 0.280 2.122 0.394 260.83 144.01
LMF 3.343 3.483 11.354 3.560 2.085 6.580
(0.000) (0.002) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000)
r 1 1 1 1 1 1
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and the
rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. C5 indicates bank concentration for the five largest banks, FII is the financial inclusion
index r indicates the number of transition function.

financial inclusion nexus. The effects of both financial freedom channel, there is a threshold
Lerner index and Boone indicator on financial beyond which bank stability has a positive e ect
inclusion are negative and significant under the on financial inclusion. The threshold level is 50%
first regime and positive and significant under the for C3 indicator and 40% for C5 indicator. The
second one. direct effect is negative whereas the indirect effect
The estimated threshold of Lerner index and is negative. These results suggest that reducing
Boone indicator, given by the PSTR regression are banking constraints led banks to be more efficient
respectively 0.46 and −0.27. Concerning the other and thus promotes financial inclusion.
threshold variables, the results are qualitatively the Turning to the control of corruption channel,
same. the value of the threshold is 0.51 for C3 and 0.60 for
the C5 indicator. Once this threshold has been
reached, the negative ect of bank concentration
VI. Conclusion and policy implications
on financial inclusion tends to change and gradu­
The aim of this study is to provide new evidence of ally becomes positive. This result implies that the
the nonlinearity of the bank concentration-finan­ negative effect of bank concentration on financial
cial inclusion nexus. Applying the SGMM and the inclusion is mitigated when corruption is con­
dynamic panel threshold regression method to a trolled in the financial sector.
sample of 30 African countries for 2004–2017, we Furthermore, we run two main robustness
show strong evidence that bank concentration may checks on our results. First, we use alternative
stem from financial inclusion. More precisely, our measures of banking market, capturing the con­
findings exhibit a U-shaped relationship between testability of banking sector and the market
bank concentration and financial inclusion, where power of banks. We therefore use Lerner index
the bank concentration effect is first negative and and Boone indicator and replicate our regres­
then positive. However, five channels through sions. The results remain robust. Second, we use
which bank concentration may have an indirect an alternative estimation strategy to our
ect on financial inclusion have been identified: dynamic panel regression to assess the nonli­
financial freedom, mobile phone penetration, pro­ nearity of bank concentration on financial inclu­
tection of property rights, control of corruption sion. The results found are qualitatively identical
and regulatory quality. Concerning, the bank to those previously obtained.
16 D. AVOM ET AL.

Table 12. Robustness checks on the PSTR regression of the effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion, by using Lerner
indicator.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Threshold variable Lerner Financial freedom Property rights Mobile phones Control of corruption Regulatory quality
First regime (Lerner) −0.167** −0.108* −0.119* −2.586** −0.054* −0.158*
(0.090) (0.077) (0.038) (1.942) (0.185) (0.145)
Second regime (Lerner) 0.789** 0.430** 0.127* 1.101*** 0.277*** 0.204***
(0.342) (0.219) (0.358) (0.293) (0.064) (0.077)
NPL 0.120** −0.112 −0.032 −0.306*** 0.057 −0.911***
(0.052) (0.072) (0.069) 0.196) (0.267) (0.306)
Inefficiency −0.152*** −0.524** −0.319** 1.265*** −0.518 0.363
(0.021) (0.246) (0.205) (0.058) (0.421) (0.039)
Findev 0.083*** 0.046 0.112 0.116*** −0.293 0.012
(0.021) (0.033) (0.031) (0.023) (0.050) (0.016)
GDPPC −0.003*** 0.009 0.001** 0.001 0.001** −0.013**
(0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001)
Hum Cap 1.508*** 0.943 −0.350 −1.074** −0.509 1.188***
(0.430) (0.247) (0.474) (0.434) (0.301) (0.163)
Threshold 0.46 50.13 35.29 74.41 0.71 0.70
γ 101.23 3.377 1.033 0.101 155.72 70.32
LMF 1.589 2.301 1.371 5.540 3.242 3.490
(0.010) (0.000) (0.41) (0.000) (0.058) (0.004)
r 1 1 1 1 1 1
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and the
rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. FII is the financial inclusion index and r indicates the number of transition function.

Table 13. Robustness checks on the PSTR regression of the effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion, by using Lerner
indicator.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Threshold variable Boone Financial freedom Property rights Mobile phones Control of corruption Regulatory quality
First regime (Boone) −0.146** −0.646 −1.251** −2.702** −1.164* −2.326*
(0.060) (0.640) (0.569) (1.191) (0.888) (1.112)
Second regime (Boone) 0.292** 0.701*** 0.127 3.003* 4.238** 1.545*
(0.055) (0.233) (4.706) (2.808) (2.464) (0.976)
NPL 0.395 −0.063* −0.014 −0.189* −0.730*** −0.652**
(0.546) (0.037) (0.059) (0.067) (0.255) (0.261)
Inefficiency −0.732 0.263* −0.310 0.589* −0.049 −0.481
(0.107) (0.151) (0.294) (0.179) (0.046) (0.707)
Findev −0.201 0.011 0.126*** 0.116* −0.083** −0.091
(0.137) (0.037) (0.033) (0.031) (0.040) (0.084)
GDPPC 0.004** −0.001** 0.011* 0.001 −0.001** −0.006**
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Hum Cap 0.208 0.090 −0.360 −0.177 0.342*** 0.528***
(0.147) (0.275) (0.648) (0.276) (0.101) (0.134)
Threshold −0.27 45.63 35.58 60.90 0.71 0.76
γ 7.209 8.303 1.139 0.066 37.174 4.481
LMF 4.748 7.580 5.351 5.690 2.042 3.372
(0.043) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.046) (0.000)
r 1 1 1 1 1 1
Note: The sample period runs from 2004 to 2017. Robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. (***, **, and *) indicate statistical significance and the
rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. FII is the financial inclusion index and r indicates the number of transition function.

This study implies taking into account the References


relaxation of regulations in the banking sector, in
Adeola, O. and O. Evans. 2017. “Financial Inclusion, Financial
particular the opening of the banking market, to Development, and Economic Diversification in Nigeria.”
facilitate competition in the market and promote a Journal of Developing Areas 51 (3): 1–15. doi:10.1353/
greater supply and distribution of financial pro­ jda.2017.0057.
ducts and services. AFI. 2013. “Measuring Financial Inclusion Core Set of Financial
Inclusion Indicators.” Financial Inclusion Data Working
Group (FIDWG), Alliance for financial inclusion. FIDWG
Disclosure statement Ajide, F. M. 2019. “Remittances, Bank Concentration and Credit
Availability in Nigeria.” Journal of Development Policy and
No potential conflict of interest was reportedby the authors. Practice 4 (1): 66–88. doi:10.1177/2455133318811727.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 17

Allen, F. E. Carletti, R. Cull, J. Q. Qian, L. Senbet, and P. Chauvet, L., and L. Jacolin. 2017. “Financial Inclusion, Bank
Valenzuela. 2014. “The African Financial Development and Concentration, and Firm Performance.” World
Financial Inclusion Gaps.” Journal of African Economies 23 Development 97: 1–13. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2017.03.018.
(5): 614–642. doi:10.1093/jae/eju015. Chinoda, T. and T. Mashamba. 2021. “Financial Inclusion,
Anginer, D. A. Demirguc-Kunt, and M. Zhu. 2014. “How Does Bank Competition and Economic Growth in Africa.”
Competition Affect Bank Systemic Risk?.” Journal of Financial Journal of Economic and Financial Sciences 14 (1): 9.
Intermediation 23 (1): 1–26. doi:10.1016/j.jfi.2013.11.001. doi:10.4102/jef.v14i1.649.
Arellano, M. and O. Bover. 1995. “Another Look at the Claessens, S. (2009). Competition in the financial sector:
Instrumental Variable Estimation of Error-Components Overview of competition policies. The World Bank
Models.” Journal of Econometrics 68 (1): 29–51. Research Observer, 24(1), 83–118.
doi:10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D. Claessens, S. and L. Laeven. 2005. “Financial Dependence,
Avom, D. C. Bangaké, and H. Ndoya. 2021. “Measuring Banking Sector Competition, and Economic Growth.”
Financial Inclusion in African Countries.” Economics Journal of the European Economic Association 3 (1): 179–
Bulletin 41 (3): 867–881. 207. doi:10.1162/1542476053295322.
Ayalew, M. M. and Z. Xianzhi. 2019. “Bank Competition and Clerides, S., M. D. Delis, and S. Kokas. 2015. “A New Data Set
Access to Finance: Evidence from African Countries.” on Competition in National Banking Markets.” Financial
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 19 (1): 155– Markets, Institutions & Instruments 24 (2–3): 267–311.
184. doi:10.1007/s10842-018-0283-6. doi:10.1111/fmii.12030.
Bara, A. G. Mugano, and P. Le Roux. 2017. “Bank Delis, M. D. 2012. “Bank Competition, Financial Reform, and
Concentration, Country Income and Financial Institutions: The Importance of Being Developed.” Journal
Development in SADC.” Southern African Business of Development Economics 97 (2): 450–465. doi:10.1016/j.
Review 21 (1): 150–176. jdeveco.2011.05.012.
Baumol, W. J. J. C. Panzar, and R. D. Willig. 1983. Eggoh, J., and C. Bangaké. 2021. “Remittances and Financial
“Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Inclusion: Does Financial Development Matter?.”
Industry Structure: Reply.” The American Economic Economics Bulletin 41 (2): 374–386.
Review 73 (3): 491–496. Evans, O. 2015. “The Effects of Economic and Financial
Beck, T. A. Demirgüç-Kunt, and V. Maksimovic. 2004. “Bank Development on Financial Inclusion in Africa.” Review of
Competition and Access to Finance: International Economics and Development Studies 1 (1): 21–32.
Evidence.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 36 (3b): doi:10.26710/reads.v1i1.113.
627–648. doi:10.1353/mcb.2004.0039. Evans, P. 1995. How to Estimate Growth Equations
Beck, T. and R. Cull. 2014. “SME Finance in Africa.” Journal of Consistently. Memo Ohio State University.
African Economies 23 (5): 583–613. doi:10.1093/jae/eju016. Fernandez de Guevara, J. J. Maudos, and F. Perez. 2005.
Berger, A. N. A. Demirgüç-Kunt, R. Levine, and J. G. “Market Power in European Banking Sectors.” Journal of
Haubrich. 2004. “Bank Concentration and Competition: Financial Services Research 27 (2): 109–137. doi:10.1007/
An Evolution in the Making.” Journal of Money, Credit, s10693-005-6665-z.
and Banking 36 (3b): 433–451. doi:10.1353/mcb.2004.0040. González, A. T. Teräsvirta, and D. Van Dijk. 2005. Panel
Blundell, R. and S. Bond. 1998. “Initial Conditions and Smooth Transition Model and an Application to
Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models.” Investment Under Credit Constraints. Technical report,
Journal of Econometrics 87 (1): 115–143. doi:10.1016/ Working Paper, Stockholm School of Economics.
S0304-4076(98)00009-8. Gonzalez, F. 2009. “Determinants of Bank-Market Structure:
Bond, S. R., A. Hoeffler, and J. R. Temple. 2001. “GMM Efficiency and Political Economy Variables.” Journal of
Estimation of Empirical Growth Models, CEPR Discussion Money, Credit, and Banking 41 (4): 735–754. doi:10.1111/
Papers/Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Papers.” j.1538-4616.2009.00229.x.
Boone, J. 2008. “A New Way to Measure Competition.” The Granger, C. W. and T. Terasvirta, et al. 1993. “Modelling Non-
Economic Journal 118 (531): 1245–1261. doi:10.1111/ Linear Economic Relationships.” OUP Catalogue.
j.1468-0297.2008.02168.x. Guérineau, S., & Jacolin, L. (2014). L'inclusion financière en
Camara, N. and D. Tuesta. 2014. “Measuring Financial Inclusion: Afrique subsaharienne: faits stylisés et déterminants. Revue
A Muldimensional Index.” BBVA Research Paper, (14/26). d'économie financière, (4), 57–80.
Caner, M., and B. Hansen. 2004. “Instrumental Variable Hansen, B. E. 1999. “Threshold Effects in Non-Dynamic
Estimation of a Threshold Model.” Econometric Theory 20 Panels: Estimation, Testing, and Inference.” Journal of
(5): 813–843. doi:10.1017/S0266466604205011. Econometrics 93 (2): 345–368. doi:10.1016/S0304-4076(99)
Carbó, S. D. Humphrey, J. Maudos, and P. Molyneux. 2009. 00025-1.
“Cross-Country Comparisons of Competition and Pricing IMF. 2021. Regional Economic Outlook. Sub-Saharan Africa.
Power in European Banking.” Journal of International Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Money and Finance 28 (1): 115–134. doi:10.1016/j. Li, C., and J. Wong. 2018. Financial Development and Inclusion in the
jimonfin.2008.06.005. Caribbean. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
18 D. AVOM ET AL.

Love, I. and M. S. Martínez pería. 2015. “How Bank Competition Pham, T. T. T. T. V. H. Nguyen, and K. Nguyen. 2019. “Does
Affects Firms' Access to Finance.” The World Bank Economic Bank Competition Promote Financial Inclusion? A Cross-
Review 29 (3): 413–448. doi:10.1093/wber/lhu003. Country Evidence.” Applied Economics Letters 26 (13):
Lu, Z. J. Wu, and J. Liu. 2020. “Bank Concentration and SME 1133–1137. doi:10.1080/13504851.2018.1540833.
Financing Availability: The Impact of Promotion of Financial Quah, D. 1993. “Galton's Fallacy and Tests of the Convergence
Inclusion in China.” International Journal of Bank Marketing Hypothesis.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 95 (4):
38 (6): 1329–1349. doi:10.1108/IJBM-01-2020-0007. 427–443. doi:10.2307/3440905.
Mengistu, A., and H. P. Saiz 2018. Financial Inclusion and Sarma, M. and J. Pais. 2011. “Financial Inclusion and
Bank Competition in Sub-Saharan Africa. Washington, DC: Development.” Journal of International developmentJournal
International Monetary Fund. of International developmentJournal of International
Moyo, B. and A. B. Sibindi. 2020. “Does Bank Competition Development 23 (5): 613–628. doi:10.1002/jid.1698.
Affect Credit Access in Sub-Saharan Africa? Evidence from Seo, M. H. S. Kim, and Y.-J. Kim. 2019. “Estimation of
World Bank Informal Firms Surveys.” Journal of African Dynamic Panel Threshold Model Using Stata.” The Stata
Business 1–19. doi:10.1080/15228916.2020.1826857. Journal: Promoting communications on statistics and Stata
Nagar, A. L. and S. R. Basu. 2002. “Weighting Socioeconomic 19 (3): 685–697. doi:10.1177/1536867X19874243.
Indicators of Human Development: A Latent Variable Seo, M. and Y. Shin. 2016. “Dynamic Panels with Threshold
Approach.” In Handbook of Applied Econometrics and Effect and Endogeneity.” Journal of Econometrics 195 (2):
Statistical Inference, 631–664. CRC Press. 169–186. doi:10.1016/j.jeconom.2016.03.005.
Nguyen, T. T. H. 2020. “Measuring Financial Inclusion: A Shi, J. and X. Mao. 2014. “Bank Concentration and Financing
Composite FI Index for the Developing Countries.” Obstacle: Evidence from Developing and Emerging
Journal of Economics and Development, 23(1): 77-99 . Markets.”
OECD. 2008. Handbook on Constructing Composite Indicators. Triki, T., and I. Faye 2013. Financial Inclusion in Africa.
Methodology and User Guide. Paris: OECD Publications. 15, avenue du Ghana: African Development Bank.
Osei, M. J. and J. Kim. 2020. “Foreign Direct Investment and Vatiero, M. 2010. “The Ordoliberal Notion of Market
Economic Growth: Is More Financial Development Better?.” Power: An Institutionalist Reassessment.” European
Economic Modelling 93: 154–161. doi:10.1016/j. Competition Journal 6 (3): 689–707. doi:10.5235/ecj.
econmod.2020.07.009. v6n3.689.
Owen, A. L. and J. M. Pereira. 2018. “Bank Concentration, Vives, X. 2011. “Competition Policy in Banking.” Oxford Review
Competition, and Financial Inclusion.” Review of of Economic Policy 27 (3): 479–497. doi:10.1093/oxrep/grr021.
Development Finance 8 (1): 1–17. doi:10.1016/j. Wang, X. L. Han, and X. Huang. 2020. “Bank Competition,
rdf.2018.05.001. Concentration and EU SME Cost of Debt.” International
Petersen, M. A. and R. G. Rajan. 1995. “The Effect of Credit Review of Financial Analysis 71: 101534. doi:10.1016/j.
Market Competition on Lending Relationships.” The irfa.2020.101534.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (2): 407–443. World Bank. 2013. “Global Financial Development Report
doi:10.2307/2118445. 2014.” Financial Inclusion 2.

View publication stats

You might also like