Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 55

Complications with Global SEP Enforcement:

Adjudicated FRAND Royalty and Extraterritorial


Approach to Parallel Patent Litigations in
“Telecom Combat” Context

by Zhen Liu

Berlin, January 31, 2023


Email: morisawa256@gmail.com

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


Bibliography

Article

Andre Schevciw, The Unwilling Licensee in the Context of Standards Essential Patent Licensing
Negotiations, AIPLA Q J. 2019, 369-400

Anusha Pirani, The Unitary Patent Court - Caution Ahead, Ct Uncourt. 2018, 5-8

Claire Guo, Intersection of Antitrust Laws with Evolving Frand Terms in Standard Essential Patent
Disputes, J Marshall Rev IP L. 2019, [i]-284

Christopher S. Storm, Standard Essential Patents versus the World: How the Internet of Things Will
Change Patent Licensing Forever, Tex Intell Prop LJ. 2022, 259-314

Cody M. Akins, Overdeclaration of Standard-Essential Patents, Tex L Rev. 2020, 579-599

Damien Geradin, The Meaning of Fair and Reasonable in the Context of Third-Party Determination
of Frand Terms, Geo Mason L Rev. 2014, 919-956

Daniel F. Spulber, Antitrust Policy toward Patent Licensing: Why Negotiation Matters, Minn JL Sci
& Tech. 2020, 83-162

Daniel F. Spulber, Finding Reasonable Royalty Damages: A Contract Approach to Patent Infringement,
U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615-700

Daniel F. Spulber, Patent Licensing and Bargaining with Innovative Complements and Substitutes,
Res. Econ. 2016, 693-713

Daniel F. Spulber, Licensing Standard Essential Patents with FRAND Commitments: Preparing for
5G Mobile Telecommunications, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79-160

Daniel G. Swanson, William J. Baumol, Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory (RAND) Royalties,


Standards Selection, and Control of Market Power, Antitrust LJ. 2005, 1-58

David J. Teece, Patent Counting and the “Top-down” Approach to Patent Valuations: An Economic
and Public Policy Appraisal of Reasonable Royalties, Criterion J on Innovation. 2020, 157-191

Erik Hovenkamp & Herbert J. Hovenkamp, Patent Pools and Related Technology Sharing, Penn Carey
Law. 2017, 1-18

Fei Deng, Gregory K. Leonard & Mario A. Lopez, Comparative Analysis of Court-Determined
FRAND Royalty Rates, ANTITRUST. 2018, 47-53

Felix K. Hess, US anti-suit injunctions and German anti-anti-suit injunctions in SEP disputes, J World
Intell Prop. 2022, 536-555

Florian Schmidt-Bogatzky & Clemens Heusch, Requirements in SEP License Negotiations - Sustaining
a FRAND Offer - The Relation between Confidentiality Issues and Providing Evidence for Its Own
I

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


Fair and Reasonable Position, Int’l In-House Counsel J. 2018, 1-6

Haris Tsilikas, Huawei v. ZTE in Context—EU Competition Policy and Collaborative Standardization
in Wireless Telecommunications, IIC-Int’L Rev. Intell. Prop. & Comp L. 2017, 151-178

Haris Tsilikas, Comparable Agreements and the “Top-Down” Approach to FRAND Royalties
Determination, CPI IP Column. 2020, 1-10

Jason R. Bartlett & Jorge L. Contreras, Rationalizing FRAND Royalties: Can Interpleader Save the
Internet of Things, Rev Litig. 2017, 285-334

John C. Jarosz & Michael J. Chapman, The Hypothetical Negotiation and Reasonable Royalty
Damages: The Tail Wagging the Dog, Stan Tech L Rev. 2013, 769-832

Jorge L. Contreras, Aggregated Royalties for Top-down FRAND Determinations: Revisiting Joint
Negotiation, Antitrust Bulletin. 2017, 690-709

Jorge L. Contreras, Anti-Suit Injunctions and Jurisdictional Competition in Global FRAND Litigation:
The Case for Judicial Restraint, NYU JIPEL. 2020, 171-184

Jorge L. Contreras, Fixing Frand: A Pseudo-Pool Approach to Standards-Based Patent Licensing,


Antitrust LJ. 2013, 47-97

Jorge L. Contreras, Global Rate Setting: A Solution for Standards-Essential Patents, Wash L Rev. 2019,
701-758

Jorge L. Contreras, It’s Anti-Suit Injunctions All the Way Down—The Strange New Realities of
International Litigation Over Standards-Essential Patents, IP Litigator. 2020, 1-7

Jorge L. Contreras, The New Extraterritoriality: FRAND Royalties, Anti-Suit Injunctions and the
Global Race to the Bottom in Disputes over Standards-Essential Patents, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2019,
251-290

J. Gregory Sidak, Misconceptions concerning the Use of Hedonic Prices to Determine FRAND or
RAND Royalties for Standard-Essential Patents, Criterion J on Innovation. 2019, 501-532

J. Gregory Sidak, Negotiating FRAND Licenses in Good Faith, Criterion J on Innovation. 2020, 1-28

J. Gregory Sidak, Is Patent Holdup a Hoax, Criterion J on Innovation. 2018, 401-554

Jyh-An Lee, Implementing the FRAND Standard in China, Vand J Ent & Tech L. 2016, 37-86

Kassandra Maldonado, Breaching RAND and Reaching for Reasonable: Microsoft v. Motorola and
Standard-Essential Patent Litigation, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2014, 419-464

Kelce Wilson, Designing a Standard Essential Patent (SEP) Program, les Nouvelles. 2018, 202-209

King Fung Tsang & Jyh-An Lee, The Ping-Pong Olympics of Antisuit Injunction in FRAND Litigation,
Mich Tech L Rev. 2022, 305-384

Mario Mariniello, Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory (FRAND) Terms: A Challenge for

II

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


Competition Authorities, J. Comp. L. & Econ. 2011, 523-541

Mark A. Lemley, Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organizations, Calif L. Rev. 2002,
1889-1980

Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking, Tex. L. Rev. 2007, 1991-2050

Matthieu Dhenne, Calculation of FRAND Royalties: An Overview of Practices Around the World,
European Intell Prop Rev. 2019, 754-764

Michael Renaud, James Wordarwski, & Sandra Badin, Efficient Infringement and the Undervaluation
of Standard-Essential Patents, INTELL. ASSET MGMT. 2016, 59-62

Michelle Emeterio, Antitrust Deterrence of Patent Holdup: Refocusing on Competition as a Driver of


Technological Innovation, UC Irvine L Rev. 2022, 1091-1134

Peter E. Herzog, Brussels and Lugano, Should You Race to the Courthouse or Race for a Judgment,
Am J Comp L. 1995, 379-400

Peter K. Yu, Jorge L. Contreras & Yu Yang, Transplanting Anti-Suit Injunctions, Am U L Rev. 2022,
1537-1618

Raghavendra R. Murthy, Why Can’t We Be FRANDs?: Anti-Suit Injunctions, International Comity,


and International Commercial Arbitration in Standard-Essential Patent Litigation, Vand L Rev. 2022,
1609-[ii]

Richard A. Epstein & Kayvan B. Noroozi, Why Incentives for Patent Holdout Threaten to Dismantle
FRAND, and Why It Matters, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2017, 1381-1432

Roya Ghafele, Global Licensing on FRAND Terms in Light of Unwired Planet v. Huawei, UCLA JL
& Tech. 2020, i-21

Samuel Howard, FRAND, RAND, & the Problem at Hand: Increasing Certainty in Infringement
Damages for Standard-Essential Patents, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2021, 204-236

Stanley M. Besen, Why Royalties for Standard Essential Patents Should Not Be Set by the Courts,
Chicago-Kent J. Intell Prop. 2016, 19-48

Theodore Eisenberg & Geoffrey P. Miller, The Flight to New York: An Empirical Study of Choice of
Law and Choice of Forum Clauses in Publicly-Held Companies’ Contracts, Cardozo L Rev. 2009,
1475-1512

Thomas F. Cotter, Patent Damages Heuristics, Tex Intell Prop LJ. 2018, 159-214

Thomas F. Cotter, Erik Hovenkamp & Norman Siebrasse, Demystifying Patent Holdup, Wash & Lee
L Rev. 2019, 1501-1566

Tim Pohlmann, Who Is Leading the 5G Patent Race for Edge Computing, Managing Intell Prop. 2021,
38-42

Yang Yu & Jorge L. Contreras, Will China’s New Anti-Suit Injunctions Shift the Balance of Global
III

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


FRAND Litigation, Patently-O. 2020, No. 403, 1-5

Zelin Yang, Damaging Royalties: An Overview of Reasonable Royalty Damages, Berkeley Tech LJ.
2014, 647-680

Handbook

Jorge L. Contreras, Cambridge Handbook of Technical Standardization Law—Competition, Antitrust,


and Patents, Cambridge University Press, 2017

Oliver E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational


Contracting, New York, 1985

Richard F. Cauley, Winning the Patent Damages Case: A Litigator’s Guide to Economic Models and
Other Damage Strategies, 2nd edition, Oxford University Press, USA, 2011

Thomas F. Cotter, Comparative Patent Remedies: A Legal and Economic Analysis, Illustrated edition,
Oxford University Press, 2013

Yann Ménière, Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory (FRAND) Licensing Terms—Research


Analysis of a Controversial Concept, Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, 2015

Institutional Document

ANSI Essential Requirements 2022, https://www.ansi.org/american-national-standards/ans-


introduction/essential-requirements (accessed on 17.11.2022)

ETSI, IPR Licensing Declaration forms, https://www.etsi.org/images/files/ipr/etsi-ipr-policy.pdf


(accessed on 09.11.2022)

European Commission Communication on Setting out the EU approach to Standard Essential Patents,
https://ec.europa.eu/docsroom/documents/26583 (accessed on 17.12.2022)

European Commission, Request for Consultations by the European Union, Geneva, 18.02.2022,
https://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2022/february/tradoc_160051.pdf (accessed on 12.01.2023)

Federal Trade Commission, The Evolving IP Marketplace: Aligning Patent Notice and Remedies
with Competition, https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/reports/evolving-ip-
marketplace-aligning-patent-notice-and-remedies-competition-report-federal-
trade/110307patentreport.pdf (accessed on 12.12.2022)

IEEE, Letter of Assurance for Essential Patent Claims,


https://mentor.ieee.org/myproject/public/mytools/mob/loa.pdf (accessed on 09.11.2022)

WIPO, Mediation for Intellectual Property and Technology Disputes Pending Before Courts in
China, https://www.wipo.int/amc/en/center/specific-sectors/ipoffices/national-courts/china/spc.html
(accessed on 18.01.2023)
IV

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


WIPO, PCT FAQs, https://www.wipo.int/pct/en/faqs/faqs.html (accessed on 19.01.2023)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


List of Abbreviations
Abbreviation Definition
ADR Alternative Dispute Resolution
ASI Anti-Suit Injunction
AASI Anti-ASI
AAASI Anti-AASI
AAAASI Anti-AAASI
CJEU Court of Justice of the European Union
ECHR European Convention on Human Rights
EMVR Entire Market Value Rule
ETSI European Telecommunications Standards Institute
EU European Union
FRAND Fair, Reasonable, and Non-discriminatory
G-P Georgia-Pacific
IEEE Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers
IP Intellectual Property
IPR Intellectual Property Right
IPRP International Preliminary Report on Patentability
ITU International Telecommunication Union
LOA Letter of Assurance
LTE-A Long Term Evolution-Advanced
NPE Non-Practicing Entity
NR New Radio
PCT Patent Cooperation Treaty
RC Regional Court
TFEU Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union
TRIPS The Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights
SEP Standard-Essential Patent
SSO Standard Setting Organization
SSPPU Smallest Salable Patent-Practicing Unit
UE User Equipment
UMTS Universal Mobile Telecommunications System
UPC Unified Patent Court
U.S.C. United States Code
Wi-Fi Wireless Fidelity
WIPO World Intellectual Property Organization
WTO World Trade Organization
3G 3rd Generation
3GPP 3rd Generation Partnership Project

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


4G 4th Generation
5G 5th Generation

II

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


Table of Contents
A. Introduction ....................................................................................................................................... 1

B. Disputes over the global enforcement of SEP ................................................................................... 2

I. SEP proprietary in augmented monopolistic nature ....................................................................... 3

1. Essentiality of SEP ..................................................................................................................... 3

2. SEP holdup hypothesis ............................................................................................................... 4

3. Royalty stacking hypothesis ....................................................................................................... 5

II. Disputes over the enforcement mechanism of FRAND commitment ........................................... 6

1. The contractual essence of FRAND commitment ...................................................................... 6

2. Antitrust implications from FRAND commitment ..................................................................... 8

3. Patent holdout: Exception to FRAND defense ........................................................................... 9

C. Judicial harmonization on FRAND royalty .................................................................................... 10

I. Complications with judicial approaches to FRAND royalty ........................................................ 11

1. Hypothetical negotiation & Georgia-Pacific framework ......................................................... 11

a. Overview .................................................................................................................. 11

b. Applicability of hypothetical negotiation to SEP infringement ............................... 12

c. Applicability of the Georgia-Pacific factors to SEP royalty disputes...................... 14

2. Comparable license methodology ............................................................................................ 17

a. Adoption by courts worldwide ................................................................................. 17

b. Merits of using comparable licenses ........................................................................ 18

c. Drawbacks of using comparable licenses ................................................................ 20

3. “Bottom-up” & “Top-down” methodologies ........................................................................... 21

a. Overview .................................................................................................................. 21

b. Drawbacks................................................................................................................ 22

4. Transnational Intervention: Adjudication of global FRAND royalty ...................................... 24

II. Reflections & Proposals: Settlements on FRAND disputes ........................................................ 27

1. Reflections: Court of Justice as the instrument for FRAND royalty settlement ...................... 28

2. Proposal: “Informed contract” framework ............................................................................... 30

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


D. Anti-suit injunction: extraterritorial approach to SEP parallel litigations ...................................... 33

I. ASI in international parallel FRAND litigations .......................................................................... 33

1. The United States...................................................................................................................... 34

a. Procedural requirements for issuance of ASI ........................................................... 34

b. ASI in the US FRAND litigations............................................................................ 35

2. Europe ....................................................................................................................................... 36

3. China......................................................................................................................................... 37

II. Complications with ASI: Why courts should refrain from availing extraterritoriality?.............. 39

1. EU’s complaint at WTO of Chinese ASIs against TRIPS Agreement ..................................... 40

2. Incompatibility of ASI with Art. 6(1) ECHR ........................................................................... 41

III. Proposed countermeasures for the extraterritoriality disarray ................................................... 42

E. Conclusion ....................................................................................................................................... 44

II

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


A. Introduction

Standard Essential Patents (SEPs) proliferate as an integral part of global telecom protocols, such

as 3GPP 4G LTE-A or 5G NR, extensively implemented by the manufacturers of User Equipment (UE),

like smartphone, laptop, tablet computer, etc., due to the interoperability benefits of standard-compliant

UEs appealing to the consumers.1 By virtue of its “global essentiality”, SEP confers an augmented

monopoly upon the patentee in the telecom market, arousing anticompetition concerns.2

To supervise the SEP monopoly and the well-functioning of telecom marketplace, Standard Setting

Organizations (SSOs) like IEEE, ETSI, etc., enact IP policy—the mandate of Fair, Reasonable and

Non-discriminatory (FRAND) commitment by SEP holders, along with requiring disclosure of all the

associated patents.3 However, complications alarmingly arise with globally enforced telecom-relevant

SEPs. Rather than bilateral licensing negotiation, the vague interpretation of FRAND commitment

inevitably triggered the implementers and SEP proprietors’ fallback to litigations.

On the one hand, FRAND royalty determination is historically a major crux in almost every in-

court settlement, as court has limited ability to valuate an SEP technology.4 A diversity of the existing,

debatable approaches to FRAND royalty calculation, e.g., Georgia-Pacific framework, top-down,

bottom-up, comparable license methodologies trigger the controversy as to whether court is an

adequate regulator of FRAND rate in the telecom market.

In Unwired Planet v. Huawei, the UK court even adjudicated a globally binding FRAND royalty

rate, extending its jurisdiction beyond the subjects complained of. 5 The global harmonization of

FRAND royalty worsens the complications, as it not only encroached foreign authorities’ judicial

power but also disrespect the oversea economy, market rules and conditions, particularly if the global

royalty is not precisely FRAND owing to the flawed calculation methods.

On the other hand, the Unwired Planet judgement triggered a secondary complication, i.e., another

1
Tim Pohlmann, Managing Intell Prop. 2021, 38(39)
2
Mark A. Lemley, Cali L Rev. 2002, 1889(1947)
3
IEEE, Letter of Assurance for Essential Patent Claims; ETSI, IPR Licensing Declaration forms
4
J. Gregory Sidak, Criterion J on Innovation. 2019, 501(504)
5
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶23

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


transcontinental hassle by anti-suit injunction (ASI) in international parallel SEP litigations. The

national courts in the US and China indulge in granting ASIs to prohibit the litigants from filing

lawsuits in another country. In TCL v. Ericsson, the US court granted an ASI to obstruct Ericsson from

maintaining patent infringement actions in other jurisdictions.6 Confronted with the ASIs, German

courts have issued AASIs in five cases until January, 2022, to safeguard against external authoritarian

offense.7

Those transnational approaches prima facie interfere with the authorities enforcing their own

domestic IP laws. They disregard the specific circumstances of parallel SEP actions and the

compatibility with the legal frameworks of different jurisdictions. Consequently, the global telecom

combat incurs complications that go outrageously beyond the boundary of FRAND commitment.

Overall, in this paper, multi-jurisdictional analysis is conducted, encompassing the European, the

US, Chinese approaches and rulings in major or landmark SEP proceedings. Chapter B exposes the

current common issues worldwide brought about by global enforcement of SEP and FRAND

commitment. Chapter C principally evaluates the inherent flaws, and complications thereby, of the

existing judicial methodologies for FRAND royalty determination, and advocates a preferred solution.

Chapter D analyzes the recent ASI-related parallel litigations and the legitimacy of ASI against TRIPS

Agreement and Art. 6(1) ECHR. Meanwhile, a viable strategy is proposed to eliminate the hazard from

extraterritoriality disorder. Lastly, I outline the conclusions for the subject analysis.

B. Disputes over the global enforcement of SEP

The first section of this chapter depicts the most typical issues on the augmented SEP monopoly

per se, ranging from the over-declaration, patent holdup to royalty stacking theories. The second

section focuses on in-court practices for settling FRAND disputes based on, e.g., the contractual

obligation in FRAND commitment, and antitrust implications in conjunction with case laws like

Huawei v. ZTE. The discussion aims to set up a foundation for later assessment of the judicial

approaches to global FRAND litigations, and clearly illustrate how the telecom combat has been going

6
TCL v. Ericsson, No. SACV 14-341 JVS(DFMx) (C.D. Cal. 2018)
7
Felix K. Hess, J World Intell Prop. 2022, 536(544)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


from the outset of FRAND enforcement, finally towards international disharmony.

I. SEP proprietary in augmented monopolistic nature

As noted, the global essentiality, if not challenged, will confer an augmented monopoly such that

the patentee’s exercise of the exclusive SEP right could engage in patent holdup and royalty stacking,

which render implementers at stake. Those issues were repeatedly highlighted by tribunals in FRAND

royalty determination for a pile of SEP cases, like Microsoft v. Motorola,8 and Innovatio.9 Thus, the

insight about the monopolistic nature of SEP is a prerequisite for figuring out the court’s adjudications

in FRAND disputes.

1. Essentiality of SEP

SEP is elected through a standard selection procedure undertaken by SSOs for interoperability and

sustainability purpose.10 During the course of selection, SSO members make self-declarations to tout

their proprietary technologies for incorporation into a standard.11 Nonetheless, SSOs incorporate a

declared patent into a standard without independently verifying its essentiality.12 This has aroused

debates over the standard setting mechanism with the global application of 4G and 5G protocols.

In practice, some so-called SEPs were overvalued for lack of in-depth scrutiny on the essentiality,

which scrutiny is regarded rather costly and time-consuming.13 Jorge Contreras has noted that patent

pools that collect SEPs to facilitate licensing transactions, spend between $10,000 and $15,000 per

patent to verify essentiality. 14 SSO members are inspired to make over-declaration in contest for

qualification of each owned technology as SEP. SEP monopolies granted by deceptive means are not

achieved through competition on the merits.15 Once a patented technology is integrated into a global

8
Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc., No. C10-cv-1823JLR (W.D. Wash. 2013)
9
In re Innovatio IP Ventures, LLC Patent Litig, MDL2303 (N.D. Ill. 2013)
10
Daniel G. Swanson, William J. Baumol, Antitrust LJ. 2005, 1(6)
11
Mark A. Lemley, Cali L Rev. 2002, 1889(1933)
12
Jorge L. Contreras, Antitrust LJ. 2013, 47(60)
13
Cody M. Akins, Tex L Rev. 2020, 579(587)
14
Jorge L. Contreras, Antitrust LJ. 2013, 47(77)
15
Michelle Emeterio, UC Irvine L Rev. 2022, 1091(1098)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


telecom standard, the industry will be too entrenched to retrograde at unaffordable switching costs.16

Meanwhile, over-declaration will artificially inflate the price of non-essential patents in licensing

negotiations and skew judicial analysis on FRAND rate.17 This calls to mind the “top-down” approach

in the US case Innovatio where the shares of an aggregate rate for all SEPs in a standard are apportioned

amongst SEP holders.18 If the apportionment does not take actual essentiality into account, putatively

essential patents would be also allocated a share of the total royalty.19 Hence, the absence of the proof

for essentiality of SEPs may cause legal uncertainty and judicial inefficiency.

2. SEP holdup hypothesis

A classic assumption about patent enforcement over decades is patent holdup, or a figurative

jargon “patent ambush” in case of SEP monopoly.20 Patent holdup is a hypothesis stemming from

Williamson’s economic theory.21 SEP holdup conjecture posits when an unlicensed implementer has

made a sunk investment in implementing a standard and thus becomes “locked in” to it, an SEP holder

comes into play ex post and tries to recoup from the infringer inordinately high royalty exceeding the

ex-ante value of the SEP in the standard.22

Some scholars recognize that patent holdup is no more than a fallacy. Gregory Sidak contends that

“the patent-holdup conjecture is an expedient hoax” by presenting counterevidence that patentees’

disclosure of SEPs mandated by SSOs already gives adequate notice to implementers and therefore,

there is supposed to be little chance that implementers are surprised by SEP claims.23

Conversely, the proponents of holdup theory like Michelle Emeterio demonstrate a high frequency

of evidentiary holdup by referring to the empirical SEP litigations where the adjudicated royalty

typically shows that the proprietor demanded far beyond what is legitimately FRAND, amounting to

16
Michelle Emeterio, UC Irvine L Rev. 2022, 1091(1118)
17
Cody M. Akins, Tex L Rev. 2020, 579(588)
18
Innovatio, MDL2303
19
Jason R. Bartlett & Jorge L. Contreras, Rev Litig. 2017, 285(309)
20
Thomas F. Cotter, et al, Wash & Lee L Rev. 2019, 1501(1541)
21
Oliver E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, 52-54
22
Thomas F. Cotter, et al, Wash & Lee L Rev. 2019, 1501(1544)
23
J. Gregory Sidak, Criterion J on Innovation. 2018, 401(418)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


holdup.24 This indicates global SEP litigations must have been triggered at a certain point, such as

SEP holdup.

Irrespective of the scholarly controversy, personally, this hypothesis serves as an ex-ante alert for

SEP owners. It does not necessarily need substantiation with a real-life instance because the

hypothetical phenomenon has certain legal implications for legislator or judge. Judicial weighting of

holdup in FRAND valuation can at least deter SEP holder from overpricing its technology in the

marketplace.

3. Royalty stacking hypothesis

Royalty stacking is another hypothetical concern that may compound the issue of patent holdup.25

Royalty stacking is a particular embodiment of “Cournot Effect” of complementary SEP techniques

under various ownerships, which posits that: a patented technology with lower price would be “over-

supplied” in the market, boosting the customer’s demand for its complements with higher price, and

eventually, each of the SEP owners barely has incentive to charge lower licensing fees than the others.26

This theory is termed as royalty stacking.

In telecom context, UE as the end-product integrating 3GPP standards corresponding to a vast of

SEPs, may constitute such a product that more than one patentees can independently claim cumulative,

i.e., “stacking” royalty from a UE manufacturer. The conjecture predicts that the sum of all

independently demanded royalties might impose exorbitant royalty on the licensee.27 Royalty stacking,

as a matter of simple arithmetic, will multiply patent holdup if numerous SEPs read on the same one

product.28

A stack of unfair royalties will jeopardize the practicing entities against transforming SEPs into

marketable products, which truly help to monetize the SEPs for patentees. Realistically, it is not

complex to appreciate that a claimant, if as a Non-Practicing Entity (NPE), would refrain from

24
Michelle Emeterio, UC Irvine L Rev. 2022, 1091(1101)
25
Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Tex. L. Rev. 2007, 1991(1993)
26
Jorge L. Contreras, Antitrust Bull. 2017, 690(691)
27
J. Gregory Sidak, Criterion J on Innovation. 2018, 401(455)
28
J. Gregory Sidak, Criterion J on Innovation. 2018, 401(456)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


claiming excessive fees or diligently invoking exclusion orders against SEP recoupment. No

implementation, no SEP revenues.

Yet, comparable to patent holdup hypothesis, royalty stacking theory is still instructive from

jurisprudential perspective. As comparatively analyzed later, the “top-down” approach to royalty

determination remarkably outshines the “bottom up” approach in deterring royalty stacking.

II. Disputes over the enforcement mechanism of FRAND commitment

For fear of the above hypothesis, SSOs undertake the duty to mandate FRAND commitment with

each proprietor during standardization process. FRAND aims to strike a fair balance between upstream

proprietors and the downstream innovators by depriving SEP holder of the undue leverage of its

augmented monopolistic privilege and prohibiting any abuse of dominant power in the marketplace,29

and ultimately foster innovative ecosystem. However, the vagueness and non-transparency of FRAND

terms in early times resulted in a mixed or even synchronized enforcement in different legal contexts.30

SSOs barely elaborate or harmonize the definition of “FRAND,”31 leaving it interpretated mutatis

mutandis amongst global judiciaries.

1. The contractual essence of FRAND commitment

Prior to the official inclusion of a patent into a standard, SSOs request a Letter of Assurance (LOA)

in case of IEEE and ITU32, or IPR licensing declarations in case of ETSI, from the SEP holder to

declare its intention either not to enforce its patent, to license on FRAND terms, or to decline

incorporation into the standard.33 Mainstream international legislations admit the SEP holder has the

contractual obligation of licensing SEPs on FRAND basis. In Microsoft v. Motorola, the Ninth Circuit

affirms that if an SEP holder’s signed LOA states acceptance of FRAND terms, it would constitute a

binding contract with SSO.34 Such FRAND mandate pertains to SSOs’ IPR policy rather than statutory

29
Richard A. Epstein & Kayvan B. Noroozi, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2017, 1381
30
Claire Guo, J Marshall Rev IP L. 2019, [i](269)
31
Mario Mariniello, J. Comp. L. & Econ. 2011, 523(532)
32
IEEE, Letter of Assurance for Essential Patent Claims
33
ETSI, IPR Licensing Declaration forms
34
Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc., 696 F.3d 872, 885 (9th Cir. 2012)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


provision but is enforceable as a contract with SEP holders.35 Regarding the contractual content of

FRAND, e.g., American National Standards Institute (ANSI)’s 2022 FRAND policy defines that SEP

holder must license to similarly situated licensees under the reasonable terms and conditions that are

demonstrably free of unfair discrimination.36

As such, the “FRAND contract” identifies the standard implementer as a third-party beneficiary

and thus entitled to demand performance of the contractual obligation in the ambit of US contract

law. 37 In Microsoft v. Motorola, Judge Robart recognizes that the implementer as a third-party

beneficiary can accuse the patentee of a breach of FRAND contract.38 China also followed suit by

approval of the implementer to sue upon FRAND contract in Huawei v. Interdigital.39 Even though

IEEE or ITU does not supervise SEP holder’s FRAND performance, contract law is still a viable

enforcement mechanism due to jurisprudential essence of FRAND being contractual.

In greater detail, the performance of contract dictates the principle of good faith under the national

contract law of China (Art. 509 of Chinese Civil Code) and the United States (known as an implied

duty). Thus, the obligor, i.e., SEP owner must redeem its FRAND commitment in good faith. In

Huawei v. Interdigital, the Shenzhen Court examined the proprietor’s FRAND behavior against the

principles of good faith and fair dealing to draw a baseline for FRAND breach. 40 SEP holder’s

willingness to negotiation or responsiveness to an offer reflects its good faith. On the contrary, the

proprietor’s inactivity upon receipt of a willing licensee’s offer departs from good faith. Inappropriate

enforcement of its SEP, like seeking for injunctive relief without negotiation, immediately fails good

faith.

Further, if SEP holder is explicitly unwilling to lower its non-FRAND rate, in China and US, the

implementer may also lodge an action on the ground of anticipatory breach,41 such as under Art. 578

35
Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc., 696 F.3d 872, 885
36
ANSI Essential Requirements 2022, Art. 3.1.1
37
Mark A. Lemley, Calif L. Rev. 2002, 1889(1909)
38
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR
39
Huawei v. Interdigital, (华为诉交互数字技术公司滥用市场支地位及标准必要专利许可费纠纷案) Yue Gao Fa Min Zhong Zi, No.
306 (Guangdong Higher People’s Ct. 2013)
40
Huawei v. Interdigital, Yue Gao Fa Min Zhong Zi, No. 306
41
Kassandra Maldonado, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2014, 419(456)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


Chinese Civil Code, by proving the obligor’s positive statement of non-performance.42 Thus, in the

US and China, the fulfilment of FRAND commitment is overseen under multiple statutes in the sole

ambit of contract law.

However, in Germany, the implementer cannot invoke contractual remedy to SEP holder’s non-

FRAND demands. In IPCom v. Deutsche Telekom and Vodafone, German SEP infringement courts

have construed FRAND commitment as mere declaration of an obligation submitted to ETSI to

conclude a contract that already exists under German competition law. 43 The wording of “non-

discriminatory” element of FRAND also seems to signify some overlap with antitrust policy.

Competition law is then practically the only legal framework for FRAND disputes in Germany.44

2. Antitrust implications from FRAND commitment

In Huawei v ZTE, CJEU authorizes antitrust scrutiny on breaches of FRAND if there is a sign of

abuse of market dominance.45 CJEU sets out the landmark criteria for courts to assess if or not Art.

102 TFEU intrusions are present when injunction is sought for by the patentee, particularly, a

negotiation protocol extending to both the two parties.46 The protocol requires 1) the SEP owner to

provide notice of infringement and initial offers on FRAND terms, and 2) the SEP implementers to

respond diligently and provide counter-offers recognized by industry practice without engaging in

delaying tactics 47 . Therefore, in EU, antitrust implications will rest upon a series of interactions

between the two stakeholders in FRAND context. For instance, right holder’s initial offer of

unreasonable royalty does not indicate the licensee has a meritorious cause of action for

anticompetitive conduct.48

Post-Huawei v. ZTE, rulings in lower courts in Germany have assumed that in order to avoid a

finding of abuse of dominance, SEP holder must make an initial FRAND offer to a potential licensee.49

42
Microsoft v. Motorola, 864 F. Supp. 2d 1023, 1036 (W.D. Wash. 2012)
43
LG Düsseldorf Urt. v. 24.4.2012 - 4b O 274/10
44
Haris Tsilikas, IIC-Int’L Rev. Intell. Prop. & Comp L. 2017, 151(165)
45
Case C-170/13 Huawei v ZTE [2015] ECR 477
46
Claire Guo, J Marshall Rev IP L. 2019, [i](273)
47
Case C-170/13 Huawei v ZTE [2015] ECR 477 ¶71
48
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶153
49
Claire Guo, J Marshall Rev IP L. 2019, [i](274)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


It follows that to comply with Art. 102 TFEU, and not to lose the last resort to injunction, SEP holder

may need to delineate a certain level of royalty within the meaning of “FRAND offer”. However,

CJEU does not illuminate the extent to which a non-FRAND license can infringe Art. 102 TFEU.

Afterwards, in Unwired Planet v. Huawei, the UK court enlightens the interlink between FRAND

and antitrust violations. The UK court sets forth that FRAND terms have weakened SEP owner’s

market dominance but the boundaries of FRAND and competition law are not the same. 50 A rate

offered above FRAND rate in the first instance may be not definitely contrary to competition law.51 If

any deviation from the court-determined rate is antitrust breach, the SEP owners would be overly

burdened to make initial offers.52 This may not yet legitimize the intention to place the implementer

at the mercy of SEP holder by sticking to exorbitant royalty. Like Huawei v. ZTE, nonetheless, the UK

court does not lay down the specific threshold for such an exorbitant royalty that it brings about

antitrust suspicion.

3. Patent holdout: Exception to FRAND defense

“Patent holdout”, also named “reverse holdup” or “efficient infringement”, refers to SEP

implementers’ refusal to negotiate in good faith53. Implementers’ holdout mischief strategically forces

the innovator to either undertake significant litigation costs and time delays to extract a licensing

payment through a court order54. Incentives for patent holdout could originate from the implementer’s

expectation that the patent would be devaluated by challenging the essentiality to standard, and that

the patent holders will not assert their patents before court owing to the uncertainty and costs of

litigation, or that a request of counterclaim may succeed in nullifying an SEP before patent office.55

The history proceedings in the US, such as Microsoft v. Motorola and Apple v. Motorola, exhibit

that the US courts and policymakers were agonized by the illusory patent holdup in favor of the SEP

50
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶757
51 Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶757
52
Claire Guo, J Marshall Rev IP L. 2019, [i](274)
53
Michael Renaud, INTELL. ASSET MGMT. 2016, 59
54
Richard A. Epstein & Kayvan B. Noroozi, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2017, 1381(1384)
55
Yann Ménière, Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory (FRAND) Licensing Terms—Research Analysis of a
Controversial Concept, 15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


implementer, whereas they largely overlooked the factual severity of patent holdout, and even

exacerbated it through a series of missteps in the past. 56 Arguably, judicial decisions prone to

penalizing SEP holders from injunction would help nurture holdout practice by dishonest implementers.

In Huawei v. ZTE, CJEU outlaws unwilling licensee’s holdout by ruling that the alleged infringer

should actively engage in FRAND negotiation. 57 CJEU conditionally legitimizes SEP holder’s

attempt to injunction on SEP holdout despite FRAND constraints whereas patent holdout is statutorily

treated as an exception to FRAND defense.

On some occasions, the implementer can justify its “holdout” or unwillingness in relation to non-

discriminatory prong of FRAND. Where similarly situated implementers have signed FRAND

agreement with SEP holders, the licensee’s reluctance to pay commensurate amount of fee is normally

deemed as holdout, unless he is able to justify his objection to the offered rate under specific unsettled

discords. In Sisvel v. Haier, German Federal Court of Justice adjudges that for “non-discriminatory”

purpose, according to the market dynamics, it is not obligatory for the SEP holder to apply a ‘standard

tariff’ to all licensees with identical pricing, whereas patent holders must establish a justification

behind an unequal treatment of licensees and the infringer also has the duty to clarify why the offer is

discriminatory.58

C. Judicial harmonization on FRAND royalty

Ever since Huawei v. ZTE, the stakeholders are supposed to refrain from speculative mischiefs

like patent holdup or holdout infringement. Instead, bilateral negotiation is encouraged by CJEU, as

the binding negotiation code consists of all the necessary steps towards the FRAND license without

the need of any judicial intervention.59

When out-of-court negotiation sinks into impasse, each party could not but bank on legal

instruments. As the global SEP litigations reveal so far, the issues ultimately narrow down to the kink

56
Richard A. Epstein & Kayvan B. Noroozi, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2017, 1381(1384)
57
Case C-170/13 Huawei v ZTE [2015] ECR 477 ¶71
58
BGH Urt. v. 5.5.2020 - KZR 36/17 BGHZ 225, 269
59
Andre Schevciw, AIPLA Q J. 2019, 369(397)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


of FRAND royalty resolution. However, the courts generally lack a distinct vision of FRAND

negotiation, technological details, and market conditions. With limited competence, the courts are

adopting rudimentary and defective approaches to FRAND royalty, e.g., the top-down and bottom-up

methodologies as noted earlier. The following firstly elucidates the complications with the judicial

practices in harmonizing FRAND royalty, and secondly, based on the exposed issues, proposes a

preferable solution.

I. Complications with judicial approaches to FRAND royalty

This section debates about the tribunal approaches to FRAND royalty, including Georgia-Pacific

(G-P) framework, comparable license methodologies, followed by a comparative analysis of top-down

vs. bottom-up approaches, and finally, the approach of transnational harmonization by national court

on a global FRAND royalty. This can be viewed as a signpost of how to reform the legal mechanism

for addressing FRAND disputes in the future.

1. Hypothetical negotiation & Georgia-Pacific framework

To begin with, hypothetical negotiation & G-P framework is thoroughly studied for ease of

investigation on its derivative methods of FRAND royalty calculation in specific SEP cases, as well

as exploring new feasible approach.

a. Overview

A milestone ruling for reasonable royalty damages arose from the Georgia-Pacific case in 1970,

where a 15-factor Georgia-Pacific framework serves as the agenda for a “hypothetical negotiation”.60

This framework is a long-lasting foundation for contemporary analysis of reasonable royalty damages,

well-accepted by the US courts.61 The Federal Circuit has defined it as the “willing licensor-willing

licensee” approach to ascertaining the royalty upon which the parties would have agreed had they

successfully negotiated a license just before the infringement began. 62 Namely, the fundamental

60
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. United States Plywood Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970).
61
Richard F. Cauley, Winning the Patent Damages Case, 7
62
Lucent Techs., Inc. v. Gateway, Inc., 580 F.3d 1301, 1324 (Fed Cir. 2009)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


rationale behind it is to deter ex-post patent holdup whereas it does not address patent holdout.

This approach came into FRAND picture as early as Microsoft v. Motorola in which Judge Robart

adaptively modified the Georgia-Pacific factors to reconstruct a FRAND-compliant hypothetical

negotiation.63 The Microsoft factors prioritize the contribution of the SEPs at issue to the standard,

and the importance of the standard and the SEPs to the infringing products, as in Microsoft factors 6,

8, 10, 11, and 13.64 Judge Robart also highlighted the purpose to mitigate patent holdup and royalty

stacking by neglecting the value associated with incorporation into the standard.65

b. Applicability of hypothetical negotiation to SEP infringement

Foremost, hypothetical negotiation frames patent infringement as a contractual issue with an

analogy to real-world negotiation aimed at royalty rate.66 35 U.S.C. § 284 provides that an injured

party is entitled to “damages adequate to compensate for the infringement, but in no event less than a

reasonable royalty for the use made of the invention by the infringer.” This statute does not demand a

negotiation for compensation, but specifies the damages are assessed against the factual infringing

conduct. 67 It is conceptually obscure to view the damages compensation for the tort of SEP

infringement as amounting to an ex-ante agreed royalty from a retroactive negotiation.68 Conversely,

damages ought to be commensurate with the actual consequences of the infringing activity, including

the patentee’s lost profits and lost licensing opportunities.69 But hypothetical negotiation is likely to

be inconsistent with the ex-post evidence including, among other things, the infringer’s earned profits,

as the litigants acted in the absence of an agreement.70

The fiction will pretend at least a part of facts after the date of the hypothetical negotiation, such

as the market price of or the revenue made from the infringing products, are unavailable.71 It thus

63
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR *41
64
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR *37
65
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR*38
66
John C. Jarosz & Michael J. Chapman, Stan Tech L Rev. 2013, 769(785)
67
John C. Jarosz & Michael J. Chapman, Stan Tech L Rev. 2013, 769(784)
68
John C. Jarosz & Michael J. Chapman, Stan Tech L Rev. 2013, 769(786)
69
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(656)
70
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(672)
71
Federal Trade Commission, The Evolving IP Marketplace, 166-167

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


instigates unproductive debates over the timing of such negotiation.72 The debates are compounded in

case of the asserted portfolio of SEPs with multiple dates of “first infringement,”73 which unduly

amplifies the judicial complexity of yielding an equitable result.

Another consideration is that the uncertainties and motivations that drive real-world negotiations

do not exist in a hypothetical negotiation. 74 Admittedly, on certain conditions (e.g., an upfront

payment), ex ante signed agreement lawfully hampers the patentee from ex post claiming licensing

fees otherwise when the implementer’s ex post revenue amazingly goes beyond the ex-ante bilateral

expectations. However, it is impossible for the court to ascertain the ex-ante intangible knowledge,

beliefs and expectations of the patent holder and infringer had they entered a negotiation before the

infringement began.75

The construct must be premised upon a valid, enforceable, and infringed patent, and the

essentiality of SEP.76 In reality, the implementer might rather anticipate holdout by lodging annulment

actions. But the judicial branch is not in a position to reckon those scenarios.

The unrealistic assumption of willingness, which gives priority to holdup avoidance, would

contravene the notion of Huawei v. ZTE which further seeks to address SEP holdout. In Microsoft v.

Motorola, Microsoft responded to Motorola’s opening offer by immediately filing a lawsuit—an

approach the district court and Ninth Circuit embraced and rewarded.77 But settling FRAND disputes

through the delusion of good-faith negotiators is counterproductive in the event of unwilling licensee’s

stalling tactics. The implementer-favorable construct is thus disproportionate and obsolete as per

Huawei v. ZTE.

As is unveiled later the proposed “informed contract” approach offsets all the aforesaid flaws of

hypothetical negotiation.

72
John C. Jarosz & Michael J. Chapman, Stan Tech L Rev. 2013, 769(805)
73
John C. Jarosz & Michael J. Chapman, Stan Tech L Rev. 2013, 769(805)
74
Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Tex. L. Rev. 2007, 1991(2019)
75
Fujifilm Corp. v. Benun, 605 F.3d 1366, 1372 (Fed. Cir. 2010)
76
John C. Jarosz & Michael J. Chapman, Stan Tech L Rev. 2013, 769(796)
77
Richard A. Epstein & Kayvan B. Noroozi, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2017, 1381(1417)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


c. Applicability of the Georgia-Pacific factors to SEP royalty disputes

The Microsoft court altered a majority of the G-P factors to lessen the bargaining disparity on

account of SEP status.78 In Ericsson v. D-Link, the court observes that at least five of the G-P factors

are opposed to FRAND-encumbered patents. 79 Comparative analysis on the applicability of G-P

factors to SEP disputes is made below according to the two cases.

• Factor 1: Existence of an established royalty. A prerequisite is that the patentee’s lease must be

FRAND encumbered. 80 Licensing of the same patent but outside the status as an SEP does not

mandatorily trigger FRAND implications,81 in which case an SEP may be lawfully renumerated at a

higher rate than FRAND. Ignorance of this may lead to non-FRAND judgement in favor of SEP

holders. The Microsoft court altered this factor: “licensing royalties for a given patent(s) must be

comparable to [F/RAND] licensing circumstances.”82 The Ericsson court was silent on Factor 1.83

• Factor 2: Rates paid by licensee for comparable patents. Factor 2 indicates the essentiality of an

SEP may be undermined by any available alternative.84 Otherwise, Factor 2 produces a paradox of

recognizing both the “essential” and the “alternative”. Patented technologies tend not to have 1:1

alternative to their specific use and function, except for similarly functioning devices in mechanical

field. 85 Licensing fees for superficially comparable alternative may not properly approximate the

value of an SEP to the standard and thus Factor 2 would confound the judicial analysis.86 But neither

of the courts altered Factor 2.

• Factor 3: Nature and scope of the license. This factor is inherent to a license but will not skew

the royalty determining process. FRAND commitment only encumbers the license by default to be

non-exclusive in nature and scope, because courts would readily find violation of the “non-

78
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR
79
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1201(Fed. Cir. 2014)
80 Apple v. Motorola, 869 F. Supp. 2d 901, 911(N.D. Ill. 2012)
81
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR *196
82
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR *58
83
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1201, 1230-32
84 Samuel Howard, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2021, 204(218)
85
Innovatio, No. 11 C 9308, *161
86
Samuel Howard, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2021, 204(218)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


discriminatory” prong, otherwise.87

• Factor 4: Licensor’s established licensing policy to maintain a monopoly. Both courts eliminated

Factor 4 since the FRAND commitment has invalidated the private monopolistic policy.88

• Factor 5: Commercial relationship between licensor and licensee. It may concern whether the

commercial relationship (e.g., competitors) will affect the right holder’s willingness to license.89 For

FRAND purpose, Factor 5 was disregarded by both courts.

• Factor 6: Effect of selling patented specialty and existing value of the invention as a generator

of sales for other non-patented items. As noted, the Microsoft factors emphasize the contribution of an

SEP to the standard instead of assessing the licensee’s revenue harvested from the standard,90 which

is the case for applying Factor 6. This bright-line rule likely averts inflating SEP’s value, but may fail

to consider the intent of an SSO when incorporating a patent into a standard.91

• Factor 7: The duration of the patent and the term of the license. The term of a license for a

FRAND-encumbered patent is usually the duration of the patent. 92 Hence, Factor 7 does not

dramatically affect the justice of adjudged royalty.

• Factor 8: Established profitability, commercial success, and current popularity. Both courts

suggested adjusting Factor 8 out of similar considerations as Factor 6.

• Factor 9: Comparative utility and advantages of the patent property over the old modes or

devices. Factor 9 is associated with the incremental value of the SEP over another technology. Akin to

Factor 2, such substitution of technology ignores the realities of complex standards, and assuming

superiority may unfairly reward an SEP-holder.93 The Microsoft court backing Factor 9 alleged that

parties would consider alternatives instead of the SEP prior to standardization.94 The Ericsson court

87
Samuel Howard, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2021, 204(218)
88
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1230-32
89
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1231
90
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR, *59-60
91
Samuel Howard, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2021, 204(219)
92
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR, *60-61
93
Samuel Howard, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2021, 204(221)
94
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR, *60-61

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


cautioned against Factor 9, as SEP technology does not necessarily indicate an incremental value.95

• Factor 10: Nature and benefits of the patented invention. In connection with Factors 6 and 8,

the courts frustrate the justification for overpricing an SEP by its special status. The US courts

unanimously rebutted using product’s market performance to calculate damages, e.g., in Garretson v.

Clark and Uniloc v. Microsoft.96 The Ericsson court did not retain Factor 10 or 11,97 whereas the

Microsoft court combined it with Factor 11 as both factors are “relevant to the capability of the

standard and contribution of the standard to the implementer.”98

• Factor 11: Extent of the licensee’s use of the patent and the value thereof. See Factor 10.

• Factor 12: The customary portion of the profit or selling price paid as licensing royalty. Factor

12 is directed to comparable licenses and a markdown of the infringer’s profit.99 The Microsoft court

limited it to the investigation of “customary practices of businesses licensing RAND-committed

patents”.100 The Microsoft court averaged the royalty rate in Via 802.11 patent pool, the price of

Marvell Wi-Fi chip, and InteCap Analysis as the benchmark rate of Motorola’s SEPs relating to 802.11

standard101. Having regard to the Marvell chip price is to obey the doctrine of smallest salable patent-

practicing unit (SSPPU) in LaserDynamics v. Quanta Computer.102 But the reference to the de facto

tariff in patent pool as benchmark rate is controversial due to the numerical proportionality, which

presumes equal royalty for every SEP independent of its strength (e.g., essentiality and validity), thus

boosting inflation of the number of patents in the pool.103

• Factor 13: Portion of profit creditable to patented invention. Both courts treated Factor 13 in the

same manner as they do for Factors 10 and 11, in which the Microsoft court highlights that “… the

value of the patent as the result of its incorporation into the standard … would improperly reward the

95
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1231
96
Garretson v. Clark, 111 U.S. 120, 121(1884); Uniloc. v. Microsoft, 632 F.3d 1292, 1318 (Fed. Cir. 2011)
97
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1231
98
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR, *60-61
99
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(683)
100
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR, *261
101
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR, *296-97
102
LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Computer, Inc., 694 F.3d 51, 67(Fed. Cir. 2012)
103
Damien Geradin, Geo Mason L Rev. 2014, 919(953)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


SEP-owner for the value for the standard itself.”104

• Factor 14: The testimony of qualified experts. Factor 14 was not modified by the two courts, as

it will not be distorting. Exceptionally, in Ericsson v. D-Link, the defendant opposed the testimony of

Ericsson’s expert Mr. Bone. 105 The argument is Mr. Bone breached the entire market value rule

(EMVR) due to the failure to apportion his royalty base between the accused and non-accused features

of the downstream product in light of SSPPU, and further, no evidence proved Ericsson’s SEPs drove

market demand for the defendants’ entire products.106 Chief Judge Davis rejected by stating Mr. Bone

based the calculation on Ericsson’s revenue, which was not attributable to the end products, but rather

to the value of Ericsson’s patents essential to the Wi-Fi standard.107

• Factor 15: Ex-ante hypothetical negotiation. Refer to the hypothetical negotiation as detailed in

the foregoing.

Except the impractical Factor 15, the other factors still deserve refinement and exploitation. G-P

factors are comprehensive but also complex to implement. The courts have been struggling to optimize

the technique for FRAND royalty calculation by virtue of the G-P framework. The subsequent

approaches hereinafter are judicial mutations of G-P framework for analytical simplicity.

2. Comparable license methodology

Comparable license methodology, which integrates G-P Factors 1, 2 and 12, begins with

identifying the sufficiently comparable licenses with similarly situated parties for analogous set of

patents.108 It has been endorsed by numerous jurisdictions including the US, China, Germany, the UK,

etc., as summarized below.

a. Adoption by courts worldwide

As noted, Judge Robart derived a royalty relying on patent pool licensing arrangements (G-P

104
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR, *62
105
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1201, 1225
106
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1201, 1225-29
107
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1201, 1236
108
TCL v. Ericsson, No. SACV 14-341 JVS(DFMx) *54

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


Factor 12) in Microsoft v. Motorola.109 In HTC v. Ericsson, the district court held that comparable

licenses are “highly probative, given the sophistication of the market and the amount of resources and

time that the industry devotes to negotiations.”110 The Federal Circuit confirmed in Apple v. Motorola

that “using sufficiently comparable licenses is a generally reliable method of estimating the value of a

patent.”111

Likewise, in assessing compliance with Huawei v. ZTE, inter alia, non-discrimination prong of

FRAND, German court attached significance to comparable licenses such as in Saint Lawrence v.

Vodafone, and Tagivan (MPEG-LA) v. Huawei.112 Düsseldorf court held that the higher the number of

concluded licensing agreements on similar conditions, the stronger the presumption that such terms

are indeed FRAND.113

The UK High Court, in Unwired Planet v. Huawei, directly set a global FRAND rate for plaintiff’s

SEP portfolio through comparable licenses.114 The judge submitted that FRAND obligations constrain

both parties in their conduct during licensing negotiations, and accordingly, the real-life comparable

licenses offer pertinent evidence of FRAND terms concurred by parties.115

In Huawei v. Interdigital, Shenzhen court investigated Interdigital’s comparable licenses with

Samsung, Apple, and others to examine whether the royalty rates Interdigital offered to Huawei were

discriminatory, and to calculate the appropriate FRAND rate.116

b. Merits of using comparable licenses

Aside from the courts’ endorsements, comparable licenses have further substantial merits.

Foremost, comparable licenses intuitively unfold the prospect of FRAND royalty for similar

transactions in the marketplace. Negotiated SEP licensing agreements characterize the meaning of

109
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR, *62
110
HTC v. Ericsson, No. 6:18-CV-00243-JRG (E.D. Tex. 2019) 10
111
Apple v. Motorola, No. 2012-1548 (Fed. Cir. Apr. 25, 2014) 60
112
LG Düsseldorf Urt. v. 31.3.2016 - 4a O 73/14
113
LG Düsseldorf Urt. v. 15.11.2018 - 4a O 17/17, ¶225
114
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat)
115
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶160
116
Huawei v. Interdigital, Yue Gao Fa Min Zhong Zi, No. 306

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


FRAND in industry-specific sense as well as how the good-faith negotiators perceive it.117 Unlike the

hypothetical negotiation, those achieved contracts expose the real expectation and knowledge of each

party and thus, the willing participants’ jointly chosen clauses of the contracts including royalties

implicitly define what is meant by “FRAND”.118

In line with the LOA mechanism, parties are well-informed, in a competitive market environment,

about the publicly available standards and the involved SEPs to accomplish a bilateral transaction.119

The finalized contracts have thus ruled out the patent holdup and holdout hazards, enabling the courts

to have a clear-cut recognition of FRAND embodiments in the market by exploring the comparable

provisions.

The reality-oriented approach also functions in concert with the objective of SSOs’ IP policies. As

introduced earlier, SSOs incentivize competition among upstream market players (e.g., NPEs), and

promote fair market transactions between SEP holders and implementers with a view to high

performance standards.120 Although voluntary parties’ negotiations are routine and commonplace121,

they can realize FRAND provisions and thus, are meritorious in light of SSOs’ IP policies. As such,

courts should consider these customary practices so as not to intervene SSOs’ IP regulation and the

competition in the upstream industry.

Comparable licenses also enable courts to benefit from the resources and expertise invested by

private parties in collecting information necessary for a proper valuation of SEP portfolio.122 They can

alleviate the information asymmetry between the industry and courts,123 in such a way that the court

will not make blind speculations as will do via hypothetical negotiation. Recourse to real-life

transactions can simulate market outcomes and elevate the accuracy of setting FRAND rates that

reflect actual supply-and-demand conditions in the market.124 Thereby, market price signals, based on

117
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(117)
118
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(117)
119
J. Gregory Sidak, Criterion J on Innovation. 2018, 401(418)
120
European Commission Communication on Setting out the EU approach to Standard Essential Patents, 2
121
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(117)
122
Haris Tsilikas, CPI IP Column. 2020, 1(5)
123
Haris Tsilikas, CPI IP Column. 2020, 1(8)
124
Haris Tsilikas, CPI IP Column. 2020, 1(5)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


which private parties make investment decisions, may not be interfered with.125

In doing so, the court is exempted from reproducing the overly complex analysis of G-P factors

or recurrently adjusting them mutatis mutandis on case-by-case basis. It can thus bolster the judicial

impartiality and efficiency insofar as relevant comparison to the specific disputes is made. The later

proposed “informed contract approach” is infused with the above properties of comparable licenses.

c. Drawbacks of using comparable licenses

For the contentions below, this methodology is not flawless or 100% reliable when put into

practice, albeit commended by courts as the optimal FRAND metrics.

The plausibility of this method is contingent on precise factual elements that allow associating the

previous license royalties with the particular case. 126 Thus, one source of challenge is the

comparability, e.g., as to which parties are similarly situated, and whether the royalty is eligible as a

benchmark rate, etc.127 Judicial divergence empirically occurred on this matter. Recalling G-P Factor

12, Judge Robart remarked patent pool as a good comparable indicator of FRAND royalty128, whereas

in Innovatio, Judge Holderman concluded otherwise by recognizing the unfairness of numerical

proportionality.129 Meanwhile, recalling G-P Factor 1, in the event that the only available licenses for

the same SEP are made outside the FRAND scope, then no comparable one exists. Recalling G-P

Factor 2, the price of so-called “alternative” comparable technology is not recommended as a valid

FRAND indicator unless it can overrule the essentiality of the SEP.

In Realtek v. LSI, Judge Whyte set out a comparability criteria regarding the licenses in 802.11

standard. 130 However, the challenge remains in identifying how comparable the parties in those

licenses are with the case at hand, noting that enterprises differ in lots of aspects, such as their size,

bargaining power, the scale and scope of operations, IP ownerships, and their resources for and

125
Haris Tsilikas, CPI IP Column. 2020, 1(5)
126
Apple v. Motorola, No. 2012-1549, 11
127
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶382
128
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR, *62
129
Innovatio, 921 F. Supp. 2d 903 (N.D. Ill. 2013)
130
Realtek Semiconductor Corp v. LSI Corp, 946 F. Supp. 2d 998 (N.D. Cal. 2013)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


expertise in negotiating licensing deals.131

Comparable licenses under the Realtek criteria may be opaque to the court. One reason is license

agreements usually have a confidentiality regime in place as the parties have an interest to keep the

conditions secret from competitors.132 In Sisvel v. ZTE, the German court required the SEP holder to

disclose all relevant licenses of the patents in suit, in order to constitute an appropriate basis for

comparison and to evaluate the “non-discriminatory” prong.133 However, this order would give parties

a litigation access to competitors’ agreements, leading to unfair commercial advantage.134 Even if the

licensor shares this information, it is hard to verify the authenticity, like whether the shared materials

are cherry-picked or whether the past deals represent the up-to-date value of the licensed SEPs.135

3. “Bottom-up” & “Top-down” methodologies

Next, a comparative analysis of bottom-up and top-down approaches will be given to demonstrate

that the courts, in absence of the in-depth perception of the market situation, derive inaccurate royalty

estimates for FRAND disputes.

a. Overview

The bottom-up method, or proportional contribution approach, starts with the price of the final

infringing product and bases the maximum royalty rate per product on the cost for implementing

alternative technologies to the SEP at issue.136 It largely evolves from Microsoft factors with regard

to the “contribution” of individual SEPs to the infringing products at issue, but regardless of the

valuation of the remaining SEPs in the identical standard. 137 The aggregate royalty for the entire

standard is simply a summation of all bottom-up royalties, each independently determined by separate

courts without coordination with one another.138 As noted, it risks royalty stacking in that the sum of

131
Haris Tsilikas, CPI IP Column. 2020, 1(4)
132
Florian Schmidt-Bogatzky & Clemens Heusch, Int’l In-House Counsel J. 2018, 1(3)
133
LG Düsseldorf Urt. v. 13.7.2017 - 4a O 154/15
134
Florian Schmidt-Bogatzky & Clemens Heusch, Int’l In-House Counsel J. 2018, 1(3)
135
Christopher S. Storm, Tex Intell Prop LJ. 2022, 259(276)
136
Matthieu Dhenne, European Intell Prop Rev. 2019, 754(759)
137
Innovatio, MDL2303
138
Jorge L. Contreras, Wash L Rev. 2019, 701(715)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


the individually adjudicated royalties may not intimately correspond to the FRAND value of a

standard.139

The contrasting top-down approach determines in the first place an aggregate royalty for all SEPs

of a standard, and then allocates a portion to individual SEPs according to certain apportionment

methodology.140 In confining a royalty cap for an entire standard that is payable by the implementers,

top-down approach suppresses the fear for royalty stacking. As such, top-down approach can remedy

the risk of an overstated total of the discrete bottom-up values for a single standard. As the trial judge

in Innovatio put it, a “top-down approach best approximates the RAND rate that the parties to a

hypothetical ex-ante negotiation…”141 Likewise, in Samsung v. Apple Japan, the Japanese court also

allocated a fraction of aggregate royalty to Samsung’s asserted SEP based on the total number of 3G

UMTS-essential patents.142

b. Drawbacks

The bottom-up methodology potentially incurs significant discrepancy from the top-down

aggregate and inconsistency of rates among the isolated judicial branches for the same standard.143

According to Jorge L. Contreras, Table 1 below illustrates the inconsistent royalties adjudicated by the

US courts for 802.11 Wi-Fi standard in different SEP litigations.

Table 1 The US FRAND Royalty Adjudications for 802.11 SEPs144

Case Court (Year) Royalty


Microsoft v. Motorola W.D. Wash. (2013) $0.035 per unit
Innovatio N.D. Ill. (2013) $0.0956 per unit
Ericsson v. D-Link E.D. Tex. (2013) $0.15 per unit
Realtek v. LSI N.D. Cal. (2014) 12% of net sales
CSIRO v. Cisco E.D. Tex. (2014) Up to $1.90 per unit

Were such royalties to be calculated by global courts in a similarly uncoordinated, bottom-up

139
Jorge L. Contreras, Antitrust Bull. 2017, 690(694)
140
Jason R. Bartlett & Jorge L. Contreras, Rev Litig. 2017, 285(306)
141
Innovatio, MDL2303 *163
142
Apple Japan v. Samsung, IP High Court of Japan, 2014, 10043, 132
143
Jason R. Bartlett & Jorge L. Contreras, Rev Litig. 2017, 285(295)
144
Jason R. Bartlett & Jorge L. Contreras, Rev Litig. 2017, 285(296)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


manner, the aggregate patent royalty on a Wi-Fi router could easily surpass the product’s retail price

by at least an order of magnitude.145 This is a prime example of how the bottom-up approach leads to

royalty stacking.146 Further, the profits from implementing the alternative technology is not readily

observable, recalling the analysis of G-P Factor 2 and 9. Unless the essentiality is defeated after a

lengthy process, SEPs in complex standards like 802.11 are unlikely to have a functionally identical

alternative147, rendering bottom-up solution less practical.

Though top-down approach can mitigate some of the bottom-up concerns, systematically

dependable methods of determining the aggregate royalty burden on a particular standard have yet to

be developed.148 Like comparable license methodology, a principal reason is the lack of transparency

in FRAND transactions, compelling the court to adopt less trustworthy information.149 Data for a

sufficiently precise top-down calculation could only be gathered at a prohibitive cost in resources and

time. 150 The maximum cumulative royalties historically chosen or proposed have been selected

largely out of thin air, with little or no compelling economic justification.151

In Innovatio, the US court started with the average price of a Wi-Fi chip, followed by calculating

the profit of the chip to determine the income available with which the chipmaker can pay SEP

royalties.152 A separate expert witness in the Innovatio case warned that widespread infringement may

allow manufacturers to set such low prices that SEP-holders’ recovery for damages is severely

limited.153 In TCL v. Ericsson, the court relied on Ericsson’s former public pronouncements on its own

subjective estimations of the aggregate rate. 154


Such pronouncement, made ahead of the

commercialization of a standard and before its value can be inferred from consumers’ willingness to

pay, can hardly establish a tenable pillar for FRAND estimation, as recognized by Birss J. in Unwired

Planet.155 Briss J. also cited a combination of eight different press releases and public statements by

145
Jorge L. Contreras, Antitrust Bull. 2017, 690(693)
146
Jorge L. Contreras, Wash L Rev. 2019, 701(715)
147
Samuel Howard, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2021, 204(233)
148
Jorge L. Contreras, Antitrust Bull. 2017, 690(694)
149
Jorge L. Contreras, Wash L Rev. 2019, 701(717)
150
Kelce Wilson, les Nouvelles. 2018, 202(203)
151
David J. Teece, Criterion J on Innovation. 2020, 157(163)
152
Innovatio, MDL2303 *163
153
Innovatio, MDL2303 *166
154
TCL v. Ericsson, No. SACV 14-341 JVS(DFMx) 20-26
155
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶269-272

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


industry participants to determine the aggregate royalty for ETSI’s 3G and 4G standards.156 However,

due to the limited probative strength of the evidences, Briss J. solely used the top-down rate as a cross-

check against the one calculated from comparable licenses.157

Another unjustified practice is the misuse of apportionment according to numerical proportionality.

In TCL v. Ericsson, Judge Selna bypassed the task of precisely calculating a relative value of claimant’s

SEPs through simplistic patent-counting.158 Likewise, as noted, the Japanese court picked analogous

scheme in Samsung v. Apple Japan. Arguably, the apportionment should rest on an objective and

integrative rating of the SEPs in a standard. Arbitrarily basing damages on headcount waters down the

contribution of technically crucial patents, leading to incomplete compensation for the SEP holders.159

Arbitrary apportionment systems are unsound without economic reasoning. 160 A judicial uniform

valuation for every SEP without essentiality assessment nurtures SSO members’ routine to make

speculative and commission-free over-declarations.161 The apportionment may exacerbate the risks of

skewing judicial analysis and inflating the value of patents which are not authentically essential, as

noted earlier.

4. Transnational Intervention: Adjudication of global FRAND royalty

The above exposed hassles of judicial approaches to FRAND royalty are far from the only knot to

be disentangled. National courts have begun to use disputes over domestic SEPs as autocratic vehicles

for shaping the global business arrangements of private parties, as is the case in Unwired Planet.162

Although national courts rationalized their transnational interventions based on multi-dimensional

justifications, the highlighted truth herein is the national courts are incapable of precisely computing a

FRAND royalty via those deficient methods. Thus, more severe complications arise from global SEP

enforcement.

156
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶264
157
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶476
158
TCL v. Ericsson, No. SACV 14-341 JVS(DFMx) 26
159
Jason R. Bartlett & Jorge L. Contreras, Rev Litig. 2017, 285(300)
160
Thomas F. Cotter, Tex Intell Prop LJ. 2018, 159(197)
161
David J. Teece, Criterion J on Innovation. 2020, 157(171)
162
Jorge L. Contreras, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2019, 251

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


In Unwired Planet, the plaintiff petitioned that the court should mandate a global FRAND license

between the parties, and if Huawei failed performance, issue an injunction against Huawei’s sale of

infringing products in the UK.163 Birss J. responded favorably that the ETSI standards in question are

intended for use worldwide; and the comparable licenses introduced at trial were also granted on a

worldwide basis, whereby only a global license is FRAND.164 Briss J overrode his former ruling in

Vringo v. ZTE where the request for global license terms was denied by himself.165 The Court of

Appeal in favor of Briss J. reasoned that licensing negotiation per country is inefficient; it may be

prohibitively expensive in case of global litigations; and also, FRAND commitment must have an

international effect.166 Huawei criticized the ruling on the ground that Birss J. sought to usurp alien

court’s authority of settling FRAND disputes, but eventually, was rejected by court’s stance that

disobedience of the ruling would only lead to an internal injunction on Huawei’s products in the UK,

rather than external jurisdiction.167

In TCL v. Ericsson, TCL voluntarily negotiated with Ericsson for a global portfolio license, unlike

Unwired Planet.168 The TCL court took as a starting point the need to calculate a global FRAND

royalty and was particularly sensitive to regional variations in patent value.169 Judge Selna made the

practical observation that courts are not equipped to “resolve disputes involving the technical nuances

of patent law in dozens of jurisdictions.” Ultimately, Judge Selna prudently considered extensive expert

testimony and adjusted the FRAND royalty per region (including US, Europe, China) per standard

according to Ericsson’s portfolio strength.170 Global rate was also determined by the US court, but

this global adjudication is attentive and tailormade to national variations in SEP strength and

coverage.171

While both courts relied on comparable license methodology, the Unwired Planet court arrived at

163
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat)
164
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat)
165
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶561
166
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶543
167
Unwired Planet II [2018] EWCA Civ 2344 ¶81
168
TCL v. Ericsson, No. 8:14-cv-00341 (C.D. Cal., 2017)
169
TCL v. Ericsson, No. 8:14-cv-00341 *44-46
170
TCL v. Ericsson, No. 8:14-cv-00341 *45
171
Jorge L. Contreras, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2019, 251(264)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


a global rate (0.8 percent for a “major market”) for Ericsson’s LTE portfolio that is almost twice greater

than the TCL court’s counterpart (0.45 percent).172 As such, the two adjudicated rates, that are to be

applied globally to the license terms of Ericsson’s LTE patent portfolio, are misaligned. The TCL

decision discussed a 2015 Ericsson license with Apple, which was not considered by Unwired Planet

court.173 Further, both courts had to unpack the license at a sophisticated level to derive a one-way

rate, since most of the license agreements involving Ericsson were cross-licenses, which means the

payments are net of any cross-licensing value the paying party receives.174 In both cases, Ericsson’s

one-way rates were unpacked using various measures of the relative SEP portfolio strengths of the

parties to the respective licenses.175 Although both decisions redacted many of the details, the two

analysis likely differed in the operation of unpacking.176 Because the TCL court considered the sales

forecast estimates from Ericsson’s internal projections whereas the Unwired Planet court did not.177

However, it is unclear which of the two inconsistent global rates shall prevail so that they will not

intrude the “non-discriminatory” constraint or unfairly impact the market participants outside the

disputes.

Following the global harmonization by the UK and US judiciaries of FRAND royalty, Conversant,

a patent assertion entity which claims to own SEPs essential to ETSI standards in 40 countries,

requested the English court to declare FRAND its global license offers to Huawei and ZTE.178 In

reaction, Huawei brought action in China requesting declarations of non-infringement for Conversant’s

three SEPs and if it did infringe, adjudication of FRAND royalty for only Chinese SEPs.179 In Xiaomi

v. Interdigital in China, Xiaomi sued Interdigital before the Wuhan Court by following the footstep of

requesting global FRAND terms.180

The harmonizing effects of the adjudicated multinational FRAND royalty are far-reaching for

172
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat); TCL v. Ericsson, No. SACV 14-341 JVS(DFMx)
173
TCL v. Ericsson, No. SACV 14-341 JVS(DFMx)
174
Fei Deng, et al., ANTITRUST. 2018, 47(49)
175
Fei Deng, et al., ANTITRUST. 2018, 47(49)
176
Fei Deng, et al., ANTITRUST. 2018, 47(50)
177
TCL v. Ericsson, No. SACV 14-341 JVS(DFMx)
178
Huawei Techs. Co. v. Conversant Wireless Licensing, S.A.R.L. [2019] EWCA Civ 38
179
Huawei v. Conversant (华为技术有限公司与康文森无线许可有限公司确认不侵害专利权纠纷案) 2019 Zui Gao Fa Zhi Min Zhong
No. 732, 733, 734 (Sup. People’s Ct. Aug. 28, 2020)
180
Xiaomi v. Interdigital (小米行为保全申请民事裁定书), [Decision on Xiaomi’s Application for Behavior Preservation] E 01
Zhi Min Chu 169 (I) (Wuhan Interm People’s Ct. 2020)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


future strategy of FRAND negotiations around the world. Forum shopping is likely to be inflamed

upon globalizing a national ruling. The courts’ tendency to determine high global FRAND rates or

otherwise to favor the positions of NPEs characterizes the national courts as an attractive litigation

venue for SEP owners upon struggling to conclude license.181 By the same token, jurisdictions that

establish reputations for setting low global FRAND rates, or which are otherwise hostile to patentees’

claims, may entice manufacturers to challenge the offered rates.182 Apparently, the Unwired Planet

court is partial to the SEP holder for being driven by the desire to curb holdout irrespective of the

previous ruling or the defendant’s plea.183 Thus, a party is likely to initiate litigation, as promptly as

possible, in the most favorable jurisdiction to foreclose a later suit in a less favorable one, which is

termed as “race to the courthouse”.184

Meanwhile, those post-Unwired Planet SEP litigations also signal that the extraterritorial decision

risks triggering a rivalry amongst nations for international judicial ambit. The competing national

courts may attempt to divest foreign authorities of FRAND judgement, likely touting that their legal

frameworks are superior in terms of fairness, efficiency or competency.185 This distorts the processes

and edifications of judicial and administrative rulemaking—substituting national desires to attract

business for just and evenhanded application of the law.186 When jurisdictions deliberately adapt their

rules and procedures, justice of legal system is progressively diluted and deteriorated in an effort to

artificially shape the “impartial image” of attracting litigation. 187 The Unwired Planet court best

illustrates such effort in its conspicuous reversal of Vringo v. ZTE in an opportune fashion.

II. Reflections & Proposals: Settlements on FRAND disputes

The second section reflects on the complications with global SEP enforcement by answering

whether the court is eligible as an instrument for FRAND negotiation, whether the above judicial

approaches to FRAND royalty are adversely influential, whether the court should act as a regulatory

181
Jorge L. Contreras, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2019, 251(282)
182
Jorge L. Contreras, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2019, 251(282)
183
Roya Ghafele, UCLA JL & Tech. 2020, i(3)
184
Peter E. Herzog, Am J Comp L. 1995, 379
185
Theodore Eisenberg & Geoffrey P. Miller, Cardozo L Rev. 2009, 1475(1480)
186
Jorge L. Contreras, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2019, 251(286)
187
Jorge L. Contreras, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2019, 251(282)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


agency for telecom market, and subsequently, whether there is better solution to FRAND royalty

adjudication.

1. Reflections: Court of Justice as the instrument for FRAND royalty settlement

In decades’ telecom combat, the courts are deployed by the stakeholders as an instrument for

royalty settlement, like Microsoft v. Motorola. Carlton and Shampine observe that “the licensee has

the option and a strong incentive to go to court rather than accept unreasonable terms . . . if the cost

of litigation is small relative to the overall value to be paid under the license.”188

Given the arduous process of setting FRAND royalty, and given the insufficient information that

was available to the courts, it is difficult to criticize the courts’ efforts.189 Unfortunately, there is a risk

that the provisions of SEP licenses could be regulated more by judicial branches than by negotiation

in competitive market.190 In Huawei v. ZTE, CJEU’s limited guidance on FRAND royalty threshold is

thus comprehensible with the controversy whether the onus of defining FRAND should fall on the

court. Foremost, SSO policies, intended for incentivizing competition and negotiation, do not

contemplate that courts engage in tuning FRAND terms.191

In FTC v. Qualcomm, the US court established a permanent injunction that Qualcomm should

submit, as necessary, to arbitral or judicial resolution of FRAND terms.192 In pursuit of “regulatory

decrees”, the courts seeks to supplant the function of SSOs and market negotiation of SEP licenses,

and become regulators of the telecom market.193 Nevertheless, SSOs and market participants typically

have more expertise and precise information than courts about technology and market conditions.194

Thus, it is ill-advised for the courts to function as regulatory agencies for telecom IP market by

extending the regulatory control beyond coordinated SSO FRAND commitments and negotiated

FRAND agreements,195 let alone beyond national frontier. Courts risk applying judicial regulation that

188
Stanley M. Besen, Chicago-Kent J. Intell Prop. 2016, 19(43)
189
Stanley M. Besen, Chicago-Kent J. Intell Prop. 2016, 19(43)
190
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79
191
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(147)
192
Federal Trade Comm’n v. Qualcomm Inc., 411 F. Supp. 3d 658 (N.D. Cal. 2019)
193
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(148)
194
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(148)
195
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


would diminish the benefits of standardization, and induce inefficiency of the IP market.196 Hence,

the courts should further avoid regulatory approaches that would spread the application of their

decisions to industry participants external to particular SEP disputes,197 or even to global jurisdictions.

It remains highly ambiguous as to whether the Unwired Planet global rate should be also legally

binding for the other extraneous implementers than Huawei, of the same SEP portfolio involved in the

adjudication. If affirmative, a chaos would be incited throughout the global market in telecom sector,

as the bilaterally negotiated FRAND royalty must be uniformly redefined as Unwired-Planet-

compliant irrespective of the ex-ante existence of enforceable contracts.

Meantime, putting aside the inherent defects, adverse consequences could also arise from those

calculation approaches. In particular, the courts should evade using the top-down aggregate price caps

and bottom-up (or G-P framework’s) incremental contributions to impose one-size-fits-all regulatory

formulas.198

Again, adjudication of royalty caps will indirectly characterize the courts as market regulatory

divisions, which would overstep the judicial authority of settling the SEP disputes at hand. 199

Implementers may interpret the court-imposed aggregates as the compulsory constraints on royalty of

a standard, which will restrict future FRAND negotiations over the use of SEPs not involved in the

settled disputes.200

Courts reliant on bottom-up approach seek to remove the effects of standardization from the

market value of SEPs, but the result is more likely to remove the value that SEPs add to the

standardized technology.201 This would eclipse the equilibrium between the interests of SEP holders

and implementers sought by SSO FRAND policies.202 Because the courts overlooked that the total

incremental contributions of individual SEPs are greater than the total contributions of the standard if

the SEPs are “innovative complements” in a standard. 203 Vice versa, the total incremental

196
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(139)
197
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(149)
198
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(147)
199
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(152)
200
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(153)
201
Daniel F. Spulber, Colo Tech LJ. 2020, 79(157)
202
Unwired Planet v. Huawei (2017) EWHC 711 (Pat) ¶18
203
Daniel F. Spulber, Res. Econ. 2016, 693(694)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


contributions of individual SEPs are less than the total contributions of the standard if the SEPs are

“innovative substitutes”.204

Undoubtedly, FRAND determinations are lengthy, costly, and cumbersome for courts due to the

incredible amount of resources the courts must invoke.205 It is too idealistic for courts to be swamped

with pleadings for FRAND royalty, either sincerely or as a negotiation instrument.206 For illustrative

purposes, Judge Robart’s calculation spanned 208 pages and Judge Holderman’s calculation, which

simplified Judge Robart’s method, was still 89 pages.207 The arduous procedure does not appear to

yield a superior judicial efficiency or shrink the transaction costs compared to bilateral negotiations.

The race to the courthouse, as mentioned, will not mitigate the courts’ burden of processing the

overwhelming pleas for royalty calculation.

2. Proposal: “Informed contract” framework

In practice, almost all patent license agreements form through market negotiation, except for

licenses offered by patent pools. 208 CJEU propels the parties to observe good-faith negotiation

etiquette instead of relying on judicial procedures. However, litigation is still indispensable in case of

a standoff during negotiation. Inasmuch as the analyzed complications exist, the judicial approaches

to FRAND royalty calculation require upgrading by finer calibrations.

Daniel F. Spulber proposes an “informed contract” framework to improve estimation of SEP

damages by means of the ex-post evidence and information, including patent validity, technology

standards, market outcomes, patentee’s lost profits, and the extent of the infringement, as revealed

from a patent case, like SEP litigation or infringing activities.209 By the time of the patent case, the

actions of the infringer and the SEP owner have filled in much of the “informed contract” for the court

to discover and interpret a range of elements of such contract in the course of resolving SEP disputes.210

The G-P factors can be adapted in the context of an “informed contract” so that the flaws of a

204
Daniel F. Spulber, Res. Econ. 2016, 693
205
Kassandra Maldonado, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2014, 419(455)
206
Kassandra Maldonado, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2014, 419(455)
207
Microsoft v. Motorola, No. C10-cv-1823JLR; Innovatio, MDL2303
208
Daniel F. Spulber, Minn JL Sci & Tech. 2020, 83(86)
209
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(623)
210
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(653)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


hypothetical negotiation are remedied.211 For instance, an informed licensing contract of SEP may

encompass at least the provisions in Table 2 below.

Table 2 Exemplary formulation of an “informed contract” for SEP license212

Terms of the licensing contract Specific definitions

The patent case discloses the date that infringement


Start date, and duration of the began, which is the start date of the forgone contract.
agreement The same applies to the duration of contract, i.e., the
duration of infringement (G-P Factor 7).

Litigants and the courts devote efforts to selecting what


SEPs and what claims of SEPs can be validly invoked in
Definition of the IP the patent case. The efforts may refer to claim
construction by court, and adjudication of nullity
proceedings. Thereby, the IP rights at issue are
pinpointed.

The infringer’s exploitations, including manufacturing,


Grant of rights using, selling, importing of SEP-based products or the
(IP limits, field of use, territory, SEP processes, determine the scope of the license. In
degree of exclusivity) FRAND context, the “informed contract” must be non-
exclusive. The infringer’s business activities determine
various restrictions in the contract, such as the industry
and territory in which the implementer operates (G-P
Factor 3).

Firstly, royalty base is selected from comparable


licenses or estimated market value of SEP (G-P Factors
1-2). Secondly, the economic parameters, such as the
Compensation number of units sold, prices received, sales revenues,
costs, and profits, from an infringer’s business
operations constitute the basis for refining other aspects
of royalty payments (G-P Factors 11-13). Thus, the
final estimates take into consideration the informative
and comprehensive facts to approximate “FRAND.”

Based on Table 2, it follows that the “informed contract” framework is thoroughly evidence-

oriented. Using the information obtained from the patent case, like the infringer’s actual profits, vastly

improves the estimate of damages, as it accounts for the economic effects of infringement.213 When

the patent holder’s lost profits and opportunity costs from technology transfer are not available, the

profits of the infringer and other events during the period of infringement offer a good foundation for

211
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(637)
212
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(653-655)
213
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(656)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


calculating damages, in contrast to the court’s unrealistic conjectures on the expectations of the two

parties.214 Market conditions, such as the market prices of products, never lie, but the hypothetical

negotiation probably does. Ruling out the philosophical problem of the hypothetical negotiation, the

“informed contract” simplifies damage estimation by submitting it to economic analysis.215

As already noted, EMVR restricts the application of final price of an infringing product to FRAND

royalty calculation.216 If a market exists for a la carte components containing the patented inventions,

the respective market prices are probative.217 Otherwise, SSPPU royalty base would not accurately

reflect a patent’s contribution to the market value of a product, thus deriving inadequate compensation

for damages. 218 In reality, for many comparable FRAND contracts, and patent pools, however,

royalties or royalty rates are based on final product sales.219 In case of identifying comparable licenses

with similar provisions, certain adjustments suggested by the “informed contract” can apply to the

comparable royalty bases.220 Else, the market price of SEPs, such as the transactions costs of patent

transfer, could also be referenced.221

The “informed contract” framework is favorable to judicial determination of FRAND royalty as

it not only blends in the noted merits of court-endorsed comparable license methodology but also

remedies its deficiencies. It is flexibly compatible with a majority of G-P factors, and comparable

licenses. The “informed contract” streamlines the tribunal adjudication by eliminating undue

assumption of FRAND commitment, and making it utterly evidence-based and conform to the

economics without substantial intervention on the competitive SEP market. “Informed contract” can

mitigate the legal uncertainties from top-down royalty capping, apportionment, and incremental value

estimation. The reality-driven framework respects the realized economy and market on which the

infringer already imposed effects.

214
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(656)
215
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(656)
216
Zelin Yang, Berkeley Tech LJ. 2014, 647(654)
217
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(695)
218
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(695)
219
Erik Hovenkamp & Herbert J. Hovenkamp, Penn Carey Law. 2017, 1(2)
220
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(670)
221
Daniel F. Spulber, U Ill L Rev. 2019, 615(656)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


D. Anti-suit injunction: extraterritorial approach to SEP parallel litigations

Following the Unwired Planet transnational intrusion, national courts became keener on autocratic

expedience to expand their jurisdictional impact worldwide. Namely, an accompanying extraterritorial

practice that emerged in global parallel FRAND litigations, as early as in Microsoft v. Motorola, is the

issuance of ASI. ASI is an interlocutory remedy in one jurisdiction, which prohibits a party from

litigation in foreign jurisdictions. 222 Foreign courts may accordingly retaliate by granting a

counteractive anti-ASI (AASI) prohibiting the party from applying for or enforcing an ASI. 223

Admittedly, ASIs contain litigation costs and reduce the likelihood of inconsistent results by ensuring

FRAND disputes are resolved in one jurisdiction before they are litigated elsewhere. 224 The

inconsistency concern is thus the court’s vital justification for such transnational interference.

I do not deny the purported upsides of the cross-border injunction. As a double-edged sword,

however, ASI globally spurred jurisdictional chaos, as seen below. In this chapter, I contend that the

domestic tribunals, ignorant of foreign legislation and economy, should not avail ASIs to facilitate the

ex-parte regulation of a uniform global FRAND rate at the expense of intruding TRIPS Agreement

and human rights. Next, the complications with ASI will be firstly set forth upon review of the recent

ASI cases.

I. ASI in international parallel FRAND litigations

In telecom combat, the extraterritoriality sprouted since the issuance of ASI in Microsoft, and

soared after the global royalty adjudication in Unwired Planet. The ping-pong-like reciprocation by

AASI and AAAASI across continent has dramatically put on a “farce in the global IP arena.” Table 3

below summarizes the occurrence of ASIs in major global SEP litigations since 2012.

Table 3 ASIs in Major SEP Litigations 2012-2021225

Case Year 1st Juris. Foreign Juris. ASI Granted AASI Issued

222
Raghavendra R. Murthy, Vand L Rev. 2022, 1609(1622)
223
Jorge L. Contreras, IP Litigator. 2020, 1
224
Jorge L. Contreras, Cambridge Handbook of Technical Standardization Law, 451
225
Peter K. Yu, et al., Am U L Rev. 2022, 1537(1588)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


Microsoft v. Motorola 2012 US DE Yes N/A
Vringo v. ZTE 2015 US CN No N/A
TCL v. Ericsson 2015 US FR,BR,RU,UK,DE,AR Yes N/A
Apple v. Qualcomm 2017 US UK, JP, CN, TW No N/A
Conversant v. Huawei & ZTE 2018 UK CN Yes N/A
Optis v. Huawei 2018 US CN No N/A
Huawei v. Samsung 2018 US CN Yes N/A
Continental v. Avanci 2019 US DE N/A DE
IPCom v. Lenovo 2019 US UK, FR N/A UK, FR
Conversant v. Huawei 2020 CN DE Yes N/A
Interdigital v. Xiaomi 2020 CN IN, DE Yes IN, DE
Oppo v. Sharp 2020 CN JP, DE, TW Yes DE
Ericsson v. Samsung 2020 CN US Yes US
IPBridge v. Huawei 2021 CN DE N/A DE
Philips, GE, Mitsubishi v. Xiaomi 2021 CN DE N/A DE
Ericsson v. Apple 2021 US NL N/A No

Next, the issuance of ASIs in the US, Europe and China will be discussed by studying the selected

parallel SEP litigations from Table 3.

1. The United States

The US court is the initiator of granting ASI in FRAND disputes, mostly relying on liberal

approach. Thus, the analysis starts with the existing criteria set out by the US for granting ASI,

followed by an overview of ASI cases in the US.

a. Procedural requirements for issuance of ASI

Depending on the US circuits, three approaches, commonly referred to as the liberal, the

conservative, the middle-ground approach, are adopted to decide granting an ASI or not.226 All begin

with two common criteria: (a) whether the parties are the same; and (b) whether a resolution of the US

action is dispositive of the foreign action.227 Next, the approaches diverge in the criteria to be satisfied

as to whether a non-US proceeding (1) frustrates a US policy; (2) is vexatious; (3) threatens the ASI

issuing court’s in rem or quasi in rem jurisdiction; (4) whether the proceedings prejudice other

equitable considerations;228 and (5) would result in delay, inconvenience, expense, inconsistency, or a

race to judgment.229

226
Raghavendra R. Murthy, Vand L Rev. 2022, 1609(1631)
227
China Trade & Dev. Corp. v. M.V. Choong Yong, 837 F.2d 33, 35(2d Cir. 1987)
228
In re Unterweser Reederei GmbH, 428 F.2d 888, 890(5th Cir. 1970)
229
China Trade, 837 F.2d 33, 35

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


Liberal approach permits granting ASI if any one of Unterweser factors (1)-(4) is satisfied.230

Circuits using conservative approach emphasize that “comity dictates that foreign anti-suit injunctions

be issued sparingly and only in the rarest of cases”, and thus exclusively examine (1) and (3).231 The

middle-ground approach acknowledges a rebuttable presumption against issuing ASI due to comity,

that can be rebutted by weighing (1)-(5) against the conflicting comity concerns.232 Finally, under all

the three tests, if all the factors favor issuance of ASI, the court may consider whether comity violation

is tolerable.233

b. ASI in the US FRAND litigations

The first ASI in FRAND litigations was issued by the US district court in Microsoft v. Motorola.

This ASI prohibited Motorola from enforcing the German injunction in which the Mannheim Court

enjoined Microsoft from selling the infringing products in Germany.234 Applying the liberal approach,

the court determined that the threshold criteria (a), (b) and at least the factors (2) and (5) favored

granting the ASI.235 Further, the court found comity intrusion tolerable as the ASI only intended to

suspend the enforcement of German judgement rather than interfere with the proceedings of German

court.236 The Ninth Circuit also affirmed the district court’s discretion of issuing such ASI by alleging

that Motorola’s contractual commitment is incompatible with seeking injunction banning sales

abroad.237

In TCL v. Ericsson, the district court in California approved of TCL’s request for ASI based on the

liberal approach, noting that “bilateral preliminary anti-suit injunction is warranted based on the

parties’ mutual agreement.”238 The court acknowledged that the parties were the same in both the

California breach-of-contract action and the foreign actions, and that the parties both indicated the

anticipation that the US action should be dispositive of a global resolution of the SEP licensing and

230
Unterweser, 428 F.2d 888, 890
231
Goss Int’l Corp. v. Man Roland Druckmaschinen Aktiengesellschaft, 491 F.3d 355, 359(8th Cir. 2007)
232
Quaak v. Klynveld Peat Marwick Goerdeler Bedrijfsrevisoren, 361 F3d 11, 18(1st Cir. 2004)
233
E.&J. Gallo Winery v. Andina Licores S.A., 446 F.3d 984, 991(9th Cir. 2006)
234
Microsoft v. Motorola, 696 F.3d 872, 884(9th Cir. 2012)
235
Microsoft v. Motorola, 696 F.3d 872, 1093
236
Microsoft v. Motorola, 696 F.3d 872, 1093
237
Microsoft v. Motorola, 696 F.3d 872, 884
238
ORDER re Motions, TCL v. Ericsson, 11(C.D. Cal. 2015)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


damages claims.239

In Apple v. Qualcomm, the court rejected Qualcomm’s request for ASI banning Apple from pursuit

of alien lawsuits, since they involved different subjects of Apple’s challenges, i.e., validity and

exhaustion of Qualcomm’s foreign patents and antitrust implications from Qualcomm’s licensing

practices, unlike the breach of contractual obligation in Microsoft v. Motorola. 240 Thus, US

proceedings setting a worldwide FRAND rate will not be dispositive of the oversea counterclaim or

antitrust actions brought by Apple, which, as the implementer, is not the obligor of FRAND

commitment to the SEPs at disputes.241

In Huawei v. Samsung, following the Microsoft analysis, the court granted ASI to enjoin Huawei

from enforcing the Chinese injunction against Samsung.242 The court held that its adjudication of the

global FRAND disputes would dispose of Chinese action, and there was frustration with the forum’s

policy, as chances are that inconsistent judgments could occur if the ASI was not granted.243 The court

regarded the ASI’s impact on comity as negligible, since the Chinese injunction was just temporarily

restrained by the ASI, while it remained possible for Huawei to seek damages.244

It can be concluded that regarding ASI in the US: (i) the liberal test might be adopted if there is a

jurisdictional conflict between a US suit on a global FRAND license and a foreign patent infringement

suit; (ii) if the US suit involves global FRAND license and a foreign suit involves patent invalidity or

antitrust action lodged by the implementer, the US courts will be reluctant to grant an ASI.245

2. Europe

European judicatures maintain averse to ASI regime intervening foreign proceedings but struggle

to safeguard their own jurisdictions against foreign ASIs by iteratively granting AASI and AAAASI.246

239
ORDER re Motions, TCL v. Ericsson, 11
240
Apple v. Qualcomm, No. 3:17-cv-00108-GPC-MDD, 17-18 (S.D. Cal. 2017)
241
Apple v. Qualcomm, No. 3:17-cv-00108-GPC-MDD, 19
242
Order Granting Samsung’s Motion for Antisuit Injunction, 1, Huawei v. Samsung, No 3:16-cv-02787-WHO (N.D.
Cal. 2018)
243
Order Granting Samsung’s Motion for Antisuit Injunction, 3-5, Huawei v. Samsung
244
Order Granting Samsung’s Motion for Antisuit Injunction, 20, Huawei v. Samsung
245
King Fung Tsang & Jyh-An Lee, Mich Tech L Rev. 2022, 305(337)
246
Jorge L. Contreras, NYU JIPEL. 2020, 171(179)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


The UK and French courts in the respective IPCom v. Lenovo cases issued AASIs barring Lenovo

from seeking an ASI from a US court.247 The UK court noted that it would be vexatious and oppressive

to IPCom had it been deprived entirely of its right to litigate infringement and validity of its SEPs.248

The Court of Paris held that the US ASI would infringe on IPCom’s fundamental rights, such as the

rights to property (Art. 17 Charter), and to a fair trial (Art. 6(1) ECHR).249 In Nokia v. Continental in

Germany, the Regional Court (RC) Munich issued AASI and reasoned that the ASI sought for from

the US court by Continental is an unlawful interference with a Nokia’s IP rights.250 RC Munich views

AASI as the only defensive measure available against a foreign ASI, and a lawful exercise of the right

to self-defense.251

The German opposition to foreign ASIs was reinforced by the proactive order of AAAASI in

Interdigital v. Xiaomi, a case that corresponds with the worldwide ASI issued by the Wuhan Court in

Xiaomi, with the aim to preempt that a foreign court may issue an AAASI that prohibits SEP owner

from enforcing AASI.252 This should be a powerful deterrent against ASIs directed at German suits.253

In tune with French practice, German judiciaries have endeavored to dodge and rein in extraterritorial

interruption on domestic proceedings. The FRAND ping-pong ball was eventually rebounded to the

court of China.254

3. China

Amid this international jockeying that frequently targets China as the battlefield, China is activated

as another major jurisdiction banking on ASI with at least 4 issuances in 2020 alone (see Table 3).255

The President of the Beijing IP Court advanced a series of proposals to strengthen China’s judicial

procedures, including the expansion of the “behavior preservation” measure with ASI-like regime

247
IPCom v. Lenovo [2019] EWHC 3030 (Pat); IPCom v. Lenovo, Court of Appeal of Paris, RG 19/21426 (3 March
2020).
248
IPCom v. Lenovo [2019] EWHC 3030 (Pat) ¶52
249
IPCom v. Lenovo, RG 19/21426 ¶4
250
OLG München Urt. v. 12.12.2019 - 6 U 5042/19
251
OLG München Urt. v. 12.12.2019 - 6 U 5042/19
252
Xiaomi v. Interdigital, E 01 Zhi Min Chu No. 431 (Wuhan Interm. People’s Ct. Sep. 23, 2020) (China)
253
King Fung Tsang & Jyh-An Lee, Mich Tech L Rev. 2022, 305(364)
254
King Fung Tsang & Jyh-An Lee, Mich Tech L Rev. 2022, 305(363)
255
Yu Yang & Jorge L. Contreras, Patently-O. 2020, No. 403, 1

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


under Chinese Civil Procedure Law.256 Despite the hostility of countermeasures by foreign courts,

China has been more aggressive than the US in issuing ASIs.257

In Huawei v. Conversant, SPC laid down the following factors for granting ASI, which resemble

Microsoft: (i) the effect of enforcing the foreign ruling on Chinese litigation; (ii) necessity of taking

behavior preservation measures; (iii) the reasonable balance of the interests of the applicant and the

respondent; (iv) whether the behavior preservation measures harm the public interest; and (v)

compliance with international comity.258

Accordingly, SPC held that Conversant’s enforcement of the German injunction would interfere

with the Chinese action, because Huawei would risk either withdrawing from the German market or

accepting the license offered by Conversant in Germany, which offer claimed a global royalty more

than 18 times higher than the rate set by the Nanjing court.259 SPC also found that the issuance of ASI

would not materially prejudice Conversant’s rights in Germany with respect to any merits decision of

the German court, and the ASI would not harm the public interest or disobey international comity.260

Upon entry of the ASI, the SPC adjudicated a penalty of one million RMB (above US $140,000) per

day for any violation by Conversant.261

In the final dramatic Chinese ASI case of 2020, a gripping race to the courthouse—Samsung v.

Ericsson, Samsung requested ASI, on December 14, to enjoin Ericsson from seeking injunctive relief

in the US or elsewhere pending the Wuhan action.262 The Wuhan court expeditiously issued an order

on December 25 that included an ASI of global scope along with an AAASI, the latter prohibiting

Ericsson from taking actions to negate the ASI while imposing a penalty of one million RMB per day

in case of Ericsson’s rebellion.263 Procedurally, the ASIs issued by the Chinese courts were generally

made on an ex-parte basis.264 In the judgment, the court simply justified the AAASI by claiming that

256
Peter K. Yu, et al., Am U L Rev. 2022, 1537(1578)
257
King Fung Tsang & Jyh-An Lee, Mich Tech L Rev. 2022, 305(339)
258
Huawei v. Conversant 2019 Zui Gao Fa Zhi Min Zhong No. 732, 733, 734
259
Huawei v. Conversant, 2019 Zui Gao Fa Zhi Min Zhong No. 732, 733, 734
260
Huawei v. Conversant, 2019 Zui Gao Fa Zhi Min Zhong No. 732, 733, 734
261
Huawei v. Conversant, 2019 Zui Gao Fa Zhi Min Zhong No. 732, 733, 734
262 Samsung v. Ericsson (三星电子株式会社与爱立信公司标准必要专利许可费纠纷案) E 01 Zhi Min Chu No. 743 (Wuhan Interm.

People’s Ct. Dec. 25, 2020)


263
Samsung v. Ericsson, E 01 Zhi Min Chu No. 743
264
King Fung Tsang & Jyh-An Lee, Mich Tech L Rev. 2022, 305(344)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


an AASI issued by a foreign court would interfere with the Chinese proceedings, but without

addressing the potential added damage to comity by the AAASI.265 On December 28, the US court

granted Ericsson’s request for temporary restraining order (effectively, AASI) against Samsung’s

enforcement of the Chinese ASI.266 In addition, the US court’s AASI required Samsung to indemnify

Ericsson against any penalties levied on Ericsson for breach of the Chinese ASI.267 Few months later,

the two parties ended up with reconciliation on FRAND rate.

Samsung v. Ericsson represents an important variant in the evolution of global FRAND disputes.268

The parties, headquartered in Korea and Sweden, selected jurisdictions for SEP litigation by virtue of

procedural and substantive advantages, independent of any “home court advantage.” 269 The

remarkably rapid actions and counteractions in this case exemplify the worst features of the race to the

courthouse.270 For example, Chinese courts have earned a reputation for setting substantially lower

FRAND royalty rates than courts in other jurisdictions—a feature attractive to product manufacturers

but unattractive to SEP holders. 271 In contrast, the bifurcated German framework for patent cases

nearly automated the issuance of permanent injunctions after a finding of infringement and prior to

conclusion of patent validity, making Germany an attractive venue for SEP holders.272

II. Complications with ASI: Why courts should refrain from availing

extraterritoriality?

In the above US, Europe and China ASI cases, the ASIs were issued to avoid inconsistency with

foreign FRAND royalty adjudications. “Inconsistency” concern is not a legitimate or convincing

justification for offense to foreign autonomy, policy, and economy. Despite the established principles

for issuing ASI, the courts have not countered forum shopping and extraterritoriality disarray in those

265
Samsung v. Ericsson, E 01 Zhi Min Chu No. 743
266
Ericsson v. Samsung, No. 20-CV-00380 (E.D.Tex. 2021)
267
Ericsson v. Samsung, No. 20-CV-00380
268
Peter K. Yu, et al., Am U L Rev. 2022, 1537(1585)
269
Peter K. Yu, et al., Am U L Rev. 2022, 1537(1585)
270
Peter K. Yu, et al., Am U L Rev. 2022, 1537(1587)
271
Jyh-An Lee, Vand J Ent & Tech L. 2016, 37(78)
272
Thomas F. Cotter, Comparative Patent Remedies: A Legal and Economic Analysis, 245-46

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


cases.

It is manifested that FRAND royalty disagreements are always the root cause for SEP

complications, which, with the invocation of ASIs, degenerate into inter-jurisdictional disorder. Even

if national tribunals may have the legal authority to regulate global FRAND rates as incidental to

contractual commitments (like in Unwired Planet), doing so may not only contradict the interests of

the parties or the market,273 but also incur global jurisprudential absurdity, and show disrespect of

TRIPS Agreement and ECHR.

Accordingly, this section argues that courts should refrain from availing extraterritoriality in light

of TRIPS Agreement and Art. 6(1) ECHR, to which the ASI-issuing courts have not earnestly given

priority. Finally, some proposals are presented for tackling the extraterritorial complications from the

ASI issuance and global royalty adjudication.

1. EU’s complaint at WTO of Chinese ASIs against TRIPS Agreement

The fermenting ASI interferences ultimately provoked EU’s complaint at the WTO, requesting

consultation with Chinese authority in respect of the issuance of ASIs and the failed transparency

obligation of making judicial ruling publicly available, which breach Arts. 1.1, 41.1, 44.1, and 63.1

TRIPS Agreement. 274 Emphatically, EU denounced Chinese courts of failure to enact safeguards

against the abuse of ASI under Art. 41.1 TRIPS.275 The EU criticism at WTO conveys its long-held

objection to ASI.

As noted above, in dismissing Huawei’s petition against global FRAND royalty, the Unwired

Planet court opined in a chop logic that its injunction was only specific to Huawei’s products in the

UK domestic market, and as such, the UK adjudicated royalty was not truly globally binding in the

sense that it is at Huawei’s discretion whether to abide. Accordingly, without disparate or non-

reciprocal standards than the UK, Chinese WTO delegates could lawfully invoke equating

justifications that punishments for breach of ASIs are exclusively enforced in China rather than

273
Jorge L. Contreras, NYU JIPEL. 2020, 171(182)
274
Request for Consultations by the European Union, 18.02.2022, 1
275
Request for Consultations by the European Union, 18.02.2022, 7

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


elsewhere, thus placing no restrictions on the SEP owner’s exertion of IP rights in alien jurisdictions,

compliant with Arts. 1.1, 41.1, 44.1 TRIPS.

However, the worldwide courts’ justifications for extraterritoriality consistently lack stringency in

view of the TRIPS obligations. Pursuant to Art. 41.1 TRIPS, members must ensure that their judicial

authorities are able to provide remedies for patent infringement and permit effective action such as

injunctive relief under Art. 44.1 TRIPS.276 For TRIPS remedies to be available, the courts must not be

bound by foreign ASI, which entails granting AASI. 277 The grant of ASI betrays a state’s TRIPS

commitment and tarnishes justice if court is willfully adjusting legislation with the desire to expand its

sovereignty. EU’s complaint is applicable to any country like America, which, by granting ASI in lax

approach, aims to deprive litigant of the legal protection under TRIPS Agreement.

2. Incompatibility of ASI with Art. 6(1) ECHR

As noted, in IPCom v. Lenovo, the French court declared inadmissible the US-granted ASI

violating IPCom’s right to fair trial under Art. 6(1) ECHR. It is thus worth probing into how the foreign

ASI could be governed by ECHR regime covering a broader territory than EU.

It was not until Strasbourg court’s ruling in Pellegrini v. Italy that Art. 6(1) ECHR extended to the

enforcement of a non-contracting state’s judgement. In Pellegrini v. Italy, the Italian court declared

enforceable the judgment by the ecclesiastical court in Vatican (Vatican did not ratify ECHR) annulling

the appellant—Mrs. Pellegrini’s marriage without informing her of the possibility of defense and the

assistance of a lawyer, etc., and consequently, Mrs. Pellegrini’s guarantees of fair hearing were

deprived. 278 Strasbourg court noted that the enforcement per se, of the judgment by foreign

jurisdiction was the infraction of Art. 6(1) ECHR committed by Italian court.279

If Pellegrini v. Italy is translated into the context of ASI from non-contracting state of ECHR,

theoretically, the ASI should be denied as it prohibits a litigant based in ECHR’ jurisdiction from

accessing the court for a fair trial. However, exceptions were set out in In Zone Brands International

276
Arts. 41.1 and 44.1 TRIPS
277
Felix K. Hess, J World Intell Prop. 2022, 536(548)
278
Pellegrini v. Italy, no.30882/96, ECHR 2001
279
Pellegrini v. Italy, no.30882/96, ECHR 2001

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


by Cour de cassation. 280 The dispute arose out of a contract between a French and an American

company, that included a choice-of-law clause providing that Georgian laws and the jurisdiction of

Georgian courts shall prevail.281 Thus, the court declared that the American ASIs are not contrary to

French policy, insofar as they only aim at enforcing a pre-existing contractual obligation, and no treaty

or European regulation applies.282 Briefly, the claims of the two parties fall outside the jurisdictional

boundary of France, as bilaterally agreed in their contract.

The above exceptions to Pellegrini v. Italy may be rarely applicable to the ASIs in the telecom

combat context. The reason is, SEP owners have mostly made FRAND commitment with global SSOs,

including the France-based ETSI. Article 12 of the ETSI IPR Policy provides that FRAND

commitment is governed by French legislation,283 and accordingly, European regulation. Further, if

the alleged SEP claims are valid within ECHR territory, the right holder is entitled to fair trial for SEP

infringement. Likewise, it also applies to the implementer filing antitrust complaints, if not recognized

as third-party beneficiary of FRAND commitment by European courts. Where the exceptions cannot

apply, the foreign ASIs in SEP disputes are incompatible with Strasbourg case laws, contravening Art.

6(1) ECHR. The proposition of ECHR conformity can articulate the French court’s backlash of the

external ASI through AASI in FRAND disputes.

III. Proposed countermeasures for the extraterritoriality disarray

China demonstrates that if one jurisdiction issues ASI, others are inspired to echo with a

comparable level of protection. 284 EU’s objection to Chinese ASI might be a trigger and kickoff

advocacy to annul the global ASI regime before WTO. As noted, extraterritorial complications arise

from FRAND royalty disagreements. As such, the most effective remedy for such jurisdictional

disharmony would be the enactment of a unitary, global SEP enforcement system dedicated to global

FRAND royalty settlement on a comprehensive basis.285

280
Beverage international SA v. In Zone Brands International Inc., no. 08-16.369, Cour de cassation 2009
281
In Zone Brands International, no. 08-16.369
282
In Zone Brands International, no. 08-16.369
283
ETSI, IPR Licensing Declaration forms, 48
284
Raghavendra R. Murthy, Vand L Rev. 2022, 1609(1643)
285
Jorge L. Contreras, BU J Sci & Tech L. 2019, 251(289)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


As an example, a shift to a new horizon of patent system is underway in Europe, namely, the

unified patent court (UPC).286 UPC, with a new judicial execution framework, will enable centralized

mechanism for counterclaim and infringement proceedings for patents in member states, notably

unlike the conventional bifurcation system. 287 UPC may set a role model for future design of

international mechanism, though it seems to be only adequate to set a community-wide FRAND

royalty.

For a broader scope of territory, WIPO is likely equipped with the competence of setting global

FRAND royalty as its International Bureau has been doing pioneering work for global patent

application.288 In drawing up the IPRP for a PCT application, the bureau may have gathered some

preliminary information on validity and essentiality.289 This may facilitate the WIPO Arbitration and

Meditation center to implement its cost-efficient ADR (Alternative Dispute Resolution) for a global

FRAND royalty. Thus, SEP holder’s over-declaration and antitrust behaviors may be further restrained

on a global basis. Further, extraterritorial complications would unlikely occur when an international

body harmonizes the global FRAND terms. For the sake of supervising the unlawful extraterritorial

measures by WTO signatories, WIPO is supposed to take the lead to ease the international tension in

telecom combat.

In 2020, Shanghai court defused international IP disputes by ADR in coordination with WIPO.290

This receptivity and collaboration with WIPO indicate that China might be less concerned about

unfavorable arbitral awards by a neutral WIPO tribunal than by a foreign court, like the Unwired Planet

court, that issued decisions hostile toward Chinese implementers.291 This signals that WIPO ADR

option is a practicable strategy given the surged grant of ASIs in China, since it has found approval

and support in this country under the neutrality, clarity and transparency guaranteed by internationally

recognized WIPO.292

286
Anusha Pirani, Ct Uncourt. 2018, 5(7)
287
Anusha Pirani, Ct Uncourt. 2018, 5(6)
288
WIPO, PCT FAQs
289
Roya Ghafele, UCLA JL & Tech. 2020, i(20)
290
WIPO, Mediation for Intellectual Property and Technology Disputes Pending Before Courts in China
291
Raghavendra R. Murthy, Vand L Rev. 2022, 1609(1639)
292
Raghavendra R. Murthy, Vand L Rev. 2022, 1609(1646)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


E. Conclusion

Complications with telecom-relevant SEPs come up in each of the phases from SSOs’

standardization procedure, and FRAND negotiation, until the judicial instruments in SEP suits. To

mitigate the legal uncertainty of interpreting FRAND, CJEU bans both patent holdup and holdout and

boosts bilateral negotiation for FRAND licensing terms. The Huawei v. ZTE protocol strikes a fair

balance between each party’s entitlements to secure a competitive telecom market.

In contrast, an array of approaches to FRAND royalty have been developed by the US courts, and

soon emulated by English and Asian courts. Herein, both the intrinsic defects and the resultant

ramifications of those judicial methods are analyzed with reference to disproportionate adjudications

in SEP cases e.g., in Microsoft v. Motorola, TCL v. Ericsson, etc. Specifically, the hypothetical

negotiation & G-P framework is antiquated in view of Huawei v. ZTE. The comparative analysis of

top-down vs. bottom-up approaches accounts for courts’ inadequate capacity of estimating an exact

royalty cap and fair apportionment, recalling the inconsistent rulings for 802.11 standard.

G-P factors are still a legally constructive prototype of later mutations for FRAND royalty

calculation. As an example, the proposed “informed contract” framework is a promising and judicious

solution, as it exploits the merits of the court-honored comparable license method and G-P factors

while offsetting the shortcomings therein. Emphatically, adjudication by “informed contract” will not

interfere with the fair competition in the telecom sector.

At any rate, with less expertise than market participants, court is not the optimal instrument for

FRAND negotiation. Court will instead act as a market regulatory agency to impede competition with

the chilling effects from, e.g., adjudicated royalty caps. Despite the Huawei’s justifiable plea, the

English court desperately overturned Vringo v. ZTE in a persistent effort to shape the worldwide

telecom market, only to derive a divergent global royalty from TCL v. Ericsson for the same SEP

portfolio. Complications like forum shopping and race to the courthouse thus globally burst, as initially

seen from Conversant v. Huawei and ZTE, and Xiaomi vs. Interdigital and ultimately, the ASI petitions

of parallel SEP disputes spreading in the US, Europe and China.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940


Herein, in resonance with EU’s opposition before WTO, it is argued that ASIs were dictatorially

granted through untenable justifications in breach of TRIPS Agreement. In Europe, ASI also blatantly

infringes Art. 6(1) ECHR as per Strasbourg case law Pellegrini v. Italy. At least those legal basis should

govern the issuance of ASIs to stifle the growth of extraterritoriality disarray.

Due to the global nature of telecom combat, an international, UPC-like mechanism may be

invented, or alternatively, the ADR procedure before WIPO is recommended as well. Nations and

multinational private enterprises are supposed to have sufficient and firm faith in WIPO. WIPO may

most likely preclude the ASI disorder, terminate the odyssey, and consolidate the neutrality of

construing what is “fair, reasonable, and non-discriminatory.”

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4351940

You might also like