The Impacts of E-Tailer's Private Label On The Sales Mode Selection From The Perspectives of Economic and Environmental Sustainability

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

European Journal of Operational Research


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ejor

Decision Support

The impacts of e-tailer’s private label on the sales mode selection:


From the perspectives of economic and environmental sustainability
Xiuyi Zhang, Wenhua Hou∗
Business School, Nankai University, 94 Weijin Road, Tianjin 300071, PR China

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: In recent years, some e-tailers have introduced private labels to compete with manufacturers’ products
Received 15 October 2020 in end markets. With this in mind, manufacturers who sell products through e-tailers should consider
Accepted 7 April 2021
carefully when choosing the online sales mode. In this paper, we examine two prevalent sales modes
Available online 16 April 2021
and find that the manufacturer should adopt agency selling (reselling) when the percentage fee is low
Keywords: (high). When the percentage fee is moderate, with a high brand advantage, the manufacturer prefers re-
E-commerce selling due to the high effective price. However, the e-tailer prefers agency selling because the percentage
Sales modes fee is more attractive than the decision right of sales quantities. Interestingly, though the manufacturer’s
Private labels and the e-tailer’s preferences over the sales modes seem opposite, they may both prefer agency selling
Environmental sustainability if the percentage fee and the brand advantage are moderate. Besides, we compare the sales modes from
Agency selling the environmental sustainability perspective and identify two influence factors, i.e., total sales quantities
and the manufacturer’s market share. The simultaneous improvement of the manufacturer’s profits, the
e-tailer’s profits and the environmental performance is achievable under agency selling. Moreover, it is
insightful to find that if the manufacturer’s production technology is enough environmentally friendly,
the optimal sales mode in terms of economic sustainability certainly outperforms in environmental sus-
tainability. In the extension, we discuss how asymmetric production and sales costs influence our results.
We find that our main findings still hold and further if the manufacturer’s sales costs are high, the “win-
win-win” situation can be reached under either reselling or agency selling.
© 2021 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction popular private label now (MarketplacePulse, 2020). Kogan.com,


an e-commerce platform in Australia, owned 20 private labels and
In the last decade, firms have increasingly developed their on- sales under these labels accounted for 49.7% of overall gross profit
line channels and turned to online retailing through e-commerce in 2019 (Kogan.com, 2020). Besides, JD.com and Alibaba Group
platforms (also called e-tailers). One indicator of this trend is also started to establish their private labels in 2019.
the growth of global retail e-commerce sales, which have already In practice, manufacturers can sell their products via e-tailers
reached $3.5 trillion in 2019 and even under the pandemic, it under two sales modes: agency selling and reselling. Under agency
was estimated to be $3.914 trillion in 2020 (eMarketer, 2020). selling, the manufacturer sells products directly to consumers and
Amazon, the leading e-tailer in the United States, has achieved shares profits with the e-tailer based on a percentage fee. While
close to $280.5 billion net sales in 2019. The Chinese corporation under reselling, the e-tailer purchases products from the manufac-
Alibaba Group recorded an e-commerce revenue of $47 billion in turer and then resells to consumers. Actually, most e-tailers offer
2020 (statista, 2020a). These prominent e-tailers, giving manu- both agency selling and reselling to manufacturers. For example,
facturers tremendous opportunities to increase their sales, have on Amazon, 53% of paid units were sold under agency selling in
recently developed their private labels. For example, in 2009, the second quarter of 2020 (statista, 2020c). On JD.com, revenue
Amazon introduced its first private label AmazonBasics which from reselling accounted for about 88.5% of the total revenue in
offers household goods and electronics and becomes the most 2019 (statista, 2020d).
Though the sales mode selection problem has already attracted
attention from both firms and scholars, the e-tailers’ private labels

Corresponding author.
may influence manufacturers’ decisions. First, under reselling, the
E-mail addresses: xiuyi.zhang@mail.nankai.edu.cn (X. Zhang), e-tailer may reduce orders from the manufacturer to increase
whhou@nankai.edu.cn (W. Hou). its own private label products’ sales. Second, the private label’s

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2021.04.009
0377-2217/© 2021 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Table 1 quantities and manufacturer’s market share, play important roles.


Percentage of product sales from two sales modes and private labels in Amazon’s
In addition, the manufacturer, the e-tailer and the environment
2019 fiscal year.
can reach the “win-win-win” situation under agency selling.
Category Private labels Agency selling Reselling More interestingly, if the manufacturer’s production technology is
Softlines 2.5% 72% 25.5% enough green, the optimal sales mode with economic sustainabil-
Home and kitchen 1.3% 67% 31.7% ity is certainly the one with environmental sustainability. Fifth, if
Consumer electronics 1.3% 57% 41.7% the sales costs are relatively high, the manufacturer is reluctant to
Consumables 0.8% 59% 40.2%
be in charge of sales under agency selling, thus the above three
parts can also reach the “win-win-win” under reselling.
This study makes several contributions. First, the introduction
and the manufacturer’s products will compete in end markets. of e-tailer’s private labels makes the interactions between the
In practice, many manufacturers have complained that Amazon manufacturer and the e-tailer more complicated. Thus, it is signif-
favored its private labels at the expense of sellers on the platform, icant to take the private labels into consideration when analyzing
especially the agency-selling sellers (YahooFinance, 2021). Further, the sales mode selection problem, which to the best of our knowl-
Amazon’s sales data reveals that the percentage of product sales edge, has not been studied before. Second, we consider both the
from agency selling and reselling are related to private labels manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s preferences over the sales modes
(Amazon, 2021). As shown in Table 1, in the category of softlines, and identify the “win-win” situation. Our findings can not only
the platform’s private labels were relatively popular and agency explain why different sales modes are adopted in practice but
selling represented 72% of total sales. However, in the category also guide e-tailers and manufacturers to develop online retailing
of consumables, private labels had poor performance and agency in the future. Third, e-commerce helps manufacturers increase
selling only represented 59% of total sales. The difference in the product sales but simultaneously enhances the environmental bur-
percentage of sales illustrates that manufacturers’ preferences for den due to production expansion. However, few studies analyze
sales modes may depend on the competitive private labels. e-commerce from the environmental sustainability perspective. In
Thus, in this paper, we investigate the manufacturer’s sales this paper, we compare the environmental performance of two
mode selection problem when the e-tailer introduces the private sales modes and the results are insightful for governments that
label products. Our research questions are as follows: (1) Facing focus on reducing pollution.
the e-tailer’s private label, when should a manufacturer adopt The remainder of the study is organized as follows. We re-
agency selling versus reselling? (2) Given the sale mode, how view the related literature in Section 2. Then we present our main
should the manufacturer decide the wholesale price or sales model in Section 3. In Section 4, we analyze the model and derive
quantities? Also, how should the e-tailer decide the sales/order the results. Section 5 shows the environmental performance of two
quantities? (3) Do there exist incentive alignment opportunities sales modes. Section 6 contains model extensions to confirm the
for both the manufacturer and the e-tailer to prefer one specific robustness of our main results and derive new findings. Finally, we
sales mode? (4) Considering the supply chain sustainability, which conclude the study and provide management insights in Section 7.
sales mode is more environmentally friendly? Can one sales mode
achieve both economic sustainability and environmental sustain- 2. Literature review
ability? (5) How would the results change if the manufacturer and
the e-tailer have asymmetric production or sales costs for online Our study is related to three streams of research: online
retailing? sales modes, private labels and supply chain’s environmental
To answer these questions, we develop a stylized model com- sustainability.
prising a manufacturer and an e-tailer. The manufacturer sells his As online retailing booms, there is a vast literature on two
products via the e-tailer under either agency selling or reselling. prevalent sales modes, i.e., agency selling and reselling. Some
Also, the e-tailer sells private label products which compete with papers studied whether the agency selling mode should be in-
the manufacturer’s in the downstream market. We first analyze the troduced in addition to the reselling mode. Yan, Zhao, and Xing
manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s optimal decisions on sales quan- (2019) found that even the manufacturer has the disadvantages
tities. Then we discuss whether two firms’ preferences over the of sales efficiency and demand information, he may benefit from
sales modes can be reconciled from the economic sustainability the introduction of the agency selling channel. Yan, Zhao, and Liu
perspective and compare the environmental performance of two (2018) demonstrated that the manufacturer and the e-tailer can
sales modes from the environmental sustainability perspective. achieve a Pareto improvement when introducing the agency sell-
Our findings are mainly as follows. ing if the spillover effects of online to offline sales are moderate.
First, the manufacturer’s preference over sales modes depends Mantin, Krishnan, and Dhar (2014) discussed that introducing the
on the percentage fee and his brand advantage. When the percent- agency selling can improve the e-tailer’s bargaining position in
age fee is low, he prefers agency selling because he can reserve the negotiations with the manufacturer under reselling. More similar
right to decide sales quantities and keep most of his profits. When to this paper, some researchers focused on the sales mode selec-
the percentage fee is moderate and the brand advantage is low, he tion and compared the agency selling and reselling considering
also chooses agency selling, where he can obtain relatively high different influence factors, such as data-driven marketing (Liu,
income from unit product. Second, the e-tailer prefers agency sell- Yan, Li, & Wei, 2020), information sharing (Zhang & Zhang, 2020),
ing when the percentage fee is moderate and the brand advantage competing manufacturers (Tian, Vakharia, Tan, & Xu, 2018; Wei, Lu,
is high or when the percentage fee is high. With a high percentage & Zhao, 2020; Zennyo, 2020), logistics services (Qin, Liu, & Tian,
fee, the e-tailer can gain a lot from the manufacturer’s profits. And 2020), product quality (Zhang, Cao, & He, 2019) and cross-channel
with a high brand advantage, the right to decide sales quantities spillovers (Abhishek, Jerath, & John Zhang, 2015). However, dif-
is less valuable, thus the e-tailer is more profitable under agency ferent from the existing works, we compare two sales modes
selling. Third, though the preferences of the manufacturer and the considering the introduction of private label products. When
e-tailer seem opposite, we find that they can achieve incentive offering competing products to end markets simultaneously, the
alignment under agency selling if the percentage fee and the interactions between the manufacturer and the e-tailer become
brand advantage are moderate. Fourth, when considering the sales more complicated and thus their preferences over the sales modes
modes’ environmental impacts, two influence factors, total sales are more strategic, which is worthy of research.

602
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Our work is also closely related to the studies on private Table 2


Summary of literature.
labels. Before the advent of the e-commerce era, some physi-
cal retailers have already launched their private labels. Hence, Representative paper Agency Reselling Private Environmental
based on bricks and mortar retailers, many papers studied the selling label sustainability
competition between national brands and private labels (Bauner, Wei et al. (2020) Yes Yes No No
Jaenicke, Wang, & Wu, 2019; Hökelekli, Lamey, & Verboven, 2017; Zhang and Zhang (2020) Yes Yes No No
Nenycz-Thiel, Sharp, Dawes, & Romaniuk, 2010). Ru, Shi, and Ryan et al. (2012) Yes No Yes No
Zhou et al. (2019) No Yes Yes No
Zhang (2015) showed that the private label can reduce the double
Niu et al. (2020b) No Yes No Yes
marginalization effect and benefit the manufacturer. Similarly, This paper Yes Yes Yes Yes
Zhou, Liu, and Cai (2019) found that with in-store promotion and
its spillover effect, manufacturers can be in favor of the private
label introduction. Zippel, Wilkinson, and Vogler (2013) used a
3. Model
grounded theory approach to examine the private label’s influence
on the cooperation between manufacturers and retail chains.
We consider a stylized model comprising a manufacturer and
Compared to the richness of studies on physical retailers’ private
an e-tailer where the manufacturer sells products M through
labels, e-tailers’ private label introduction, as a relatively novel
the e-tailer and the e-tailer has its own private label products E
phenomenon in practice, has not drawn enough attention from
which will compete with M in the downstream market. For the
academia. The main difference between offline and online retail-
remainder of the study, we use the pronoun “he” to represent the
ers is the sales modes. The former one is mainly based on the
manufacturer and “she” to represent the e-tailer. The manufac-
traditional reselling mode whereas the latter one can be based on
turer can choose one of two sales modes (the superscripts A and
either reselling or agency selling.
R represent these two modes, respectively):
The most relevant paper to ours by Ryan, Sun, and Zhao
Agency selling (A). The e-tailer acts as a two-sided platform
(2012) considered when the manufacturer currently sells prod-
that connects consumers and the manufacturer. The manufacturer
ucts through its own website, whether the e-tailer should offer
sells products based on the e-tailer and shares a certain proportion
the agency selling to him and produce private label products to
of profits with her. The e-tailer also sells her private label products
compete with him. Unlike our paper, they focused on the e-tailer’s
to consumers.
strategies and ignored the reselling mode. However, we research
Reselling (R). The e-tailer, acting as a traditional retailer, buys
the manufacturer’s choice between agency selling and reselling
the products from the manufacturer and sells both M and E to
when facing the e-tailer’s private label products.
end consumers.
Another important element of our study is the supply chain’s
Fig. 1 shows the structures of two sales modes and the se-
environmental sustainability. The issues related to environment
quence of events is illustrated in Fig. 2. At the first stage, the
and green production technology have been increasingly em-
manufacturer chooses the sales mode between agency selling
phasized by governments and environmental groups, and thus
and reselling. If he adopts the agency selling, then the manu-
many scholars in the operation management field have conducted
facturer and the e-tailer decide the sales quantities qm and qe
the studies considering not only firms’ profit maximization but
simultaneously. According to the agency selling agreement, the
also the environmental sustainability. Some papers investigated
manufacturer pays the percentage fee r to the e-tailer when his
the environmental policy tools that can induce a green supply
profits are obtained. In reality, the percentage fee is a long-term
chain. Such tools include environmental taxes (Krass, Nedorezov,
decision and cannot be modified easily. Therefore, we assume that
& Ovchinnikov, 2013; Turken, Carrillo, & Verter, 2020), subsidies
the percentage fee is exogenous, which is consistent with the pre-
(Bian & Zhao, 2020; Xiao, Gaimon, Subramanian, & Biehl, 2019),
vious literature (Liu et al., 2020; Wei et al., 2020). On the opposite,
cap-and-trade mechanisms (Barrieu & Fehr, 2014; Kroes, Subra-
if the manufacturer adopts the reselling mode, he sets the whole-
manian, & Subramanyam, 2012) and so on. Other papers, more
sale price w. Then the e-tailer decides the order quantities (also
closely related to our paper, focused on the environmental perfor-
the final sales quantities) qm and E’s sales quantities qe . Following
mance of different supply chain structures. For example, Niu and
previous studies (Liu et al., 2020; Niu & Mu, 2020; Yan et al.,
Mu (2020) compared two outsourcing structures’ environmental
2018), we assume that the manufacturer and the e-tailer engage
performance and concluded the simultaneous improvement of the
in a Cournot competition in the end market. This assumption is
OEM’s profits, the service provider’s profits and the environmental
based on two reasons: First, two firms compete in their production
performance is achievable when the OEM outsources the bundled
quantities rather than their prices. The Cournot model has been
functions of procurement and logistics. Also, Niu, Xie, Mu, and Ji
(2020) studied how the overseas sourcing and domestic sourcing
affect the supply chain sustainability and identified a “win-win”
situation for both the economic and environmental sustainability.
Örsdemir, Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya, and Parlaktürk (2014) modeled the
environmental impacts of remanufacturing supply chain with and
without third-party independent remanufacturers (IR) and demon-
strated that the IR’s entry can reduce the environmental impacts.
In spite of the common interest in environmental sustainability,
previous works mainly examined the traditional offline supply
chain. However, the large-scale expansion of electronic commerce
increases product sales and meanwhile brings more burden to the
environment. Therefore, different from others, our work compares
the environmental performance of online retailing under agency
selling and reselling, and further concentrates on the coordination
of the economic and environmental sustainability via two sales
modes.
We summarize the most relevant literature in Table 2. Fig. 1. Sales mode structures.

603
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Fig. 2. Sequence of events.

demonstrated to be equivalent to a setting where firms first decide Table 3


Notations and definitions.
production quantities and then set the prices. It is the appropriate
model when production quantities are more difficult than prices Notation Definition
for firms to adjust, which is the case for most manufacturers (Hu, qm , qe Sales quantities of M and E
Mai, & Pekeč, 2020; Niu, Li, Zhang, Cheng, & Tan, 2019). Second, a Market size of the products
two firms decide their production quantities simultaneously. Al- θ Brand advantage of M
though the manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s decision timing can pm , pe Prices of M and E
b Competition intensity degree
be slightly different, during most of the product cycle, M and E
r Percentage fee
coexist in the market, thus the Cournot model is suitable. The π m, π e Profits of the manufacturer and the e-tailer
inverse demand functions of M and E are as follows. A, R Superscripts indicating agency selling and reselling
w Wholesale price of M
pm = a + θ − qm − bqe (1) ep Effective prices
e Unit pollution per quantity of E
γ Environmental advantage of production of M
pe = a − qe − bqm (2) EI Environmental impact index
tm , te Production costs of the manufacturer and the e-tailer
a represents the market size of the products. The manufacturer cm , ce Sales costs of the manufacturer and the e-tailer
is skilled in product design and production and thus product M
owns high brand loyalty. The private labels, however, are thought
of as acceptable alternatives rather than desirable brands to con- Under reselling, the e-tailer purchases M at the wholesale price
sumers according to Gielens et al. (2021) and Commuri (2009). w and sells both M and E to consumers. The profit functions are
Also, Wang, Torelli, and Lalwani (2020) found that though the then:
private label’s quality is almost equal to the national brand’s,
consumers prefer the national brand and are willing to pay a πmR = wqm (5)
higher price. Therefore, similar to Niu et al. (2019) and Hu et al.
(2020), we assume the market potential of M is a + θ , where πeR = ( pm − w )qm + pe qe (6)
θ captures M’s brand advantage over E. One can also see that
Without loss of generality, here we normalize the production
θ measures the price premium of M. We relax this assumption
and sales costs of the manufacturer and the e-tailer to be zero. In
and discuss another type of brand advantage model (Section 6.4)
the extension, we relax this assumption and analyze the situations
and E’s brand advantage (Section 6.5) in the extension. Here we
with positive costs.
require 0 < θ < min[ a(b2(−b−br ) a(2−b−b )2
1+r )
, b
] to rule out the uninter-
esting cases where M’s advantage is too large that the e-tailer no 4. Analysis and results
longer sells her private label products. This condition also ensures
market-clearing prices under two sales modes to be positive. Also, In this section, we solve the equilibrium outcomes and compare
we use b to measure the product competition intensity degree. If the results under agency selling and reselling. Then we analyze the
b = 0, the two products are independent; if b = 1, the two prod- manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s preferences over the sales modes.
ucts are perfectly substituted. Table 3 summarizes the notations
and definitions in our model. Lemma 1. Under agency selling, the equilibrium outcomes are
2
2−b)+2θ a (2−b−br )−b(1+r )θ A = (1−r ) (a (2−b)+2θ ) , and
Then we consider the manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s profits qAm = a4(−b A
2 (1+r ) , qe = 4−b2 (1+r )
, πm 2
(4−b2 (1+r ))

(a2 ( (4 − 4b + b3 r )(1 + r ) + b2 (1 − r − r2 )) + a(8r − 4b(1 + r ) + b3 r (1 + r ) + 2b2 (1 − r2 ))θ + (4r + b2 (1 − r2 ))θ 2 )


πeA = .
(4 − b2 (1 + r ))2

under two sales modes. Under agency selling, the manufacturer Lemma 2. Under reselling, the equilibrium outcomes are
2 )−bθ 2
decides his sales quantities and pays the percentage fee to the a−ab+θ
, qRe = a(2−b−b R = (a−ab+θ ) ,
− ab + θ ), πm
2 (a
1
qRm = 4−4b2 4−4b2
, w = 8(1−b2 )
e-tailer. Thus, the e-tailer generates her profits from private label 2 (5−2b−3b2 )+2a (1−b)θ +θ 2
product sales and the percentage fee. The profit functions are and πeR = a
16(1−b2 )
.
given as:
4.1. Comparison of sales quantities
πmA = (1 − r ) pm qm (3)
First, we compare the sales quantities of M and E under each
πeA = r pm qm + pe qe (4) sales mode.

604
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Lemma 3. (a) Under agency selling, the quantity of M is always b2


4−b2
, a large proportion of increased incomes are shared with the
higher than that of E (i.e., qAm > qAe ). (b) Under reselling, the quantity ∂ epAm ∂ epRm
of M is higher than that of E (i.e., qRm > qRe ) when θ > a(1 − b). e-tailer under agency selling, thus ∂θ < ∂θ .

Lemma 3 illustrates that under agency selling, the manufac- Lemma 6. M’s effective price is higher under agency selling
b2
turer always sets higher sales quantities than his competitor. Such than that under reselling (i.e., epAm > epRm ) when r < 2−b 2 or
b2 2b+b2 −b3 −2ab−ab2 +ab3 +4ar−2abr−ab2 r+ab3 r
behavior is understandable because M has the brand advantage
2−b2
<r< 4−2b−b2 +b3
and θ < b2 −4r+b2 r
.
that brings a larger market. However, under reselling mode, the
right to decide M’s quantities shifts to the e-tailer and at this Lemma 6 presents that the manufacturer can gain more from
time, she decides both M and E’s quantities. On one hand, M has unit sales of M under agency selling when the percentage fee
its brand advantage which can bring more market potential, so the is low, which is understandable. When the percentage fee is
e-tailer will sell more M if its market potential relative to E, repre- moderate, the comparison of the effective prices under two sales
sented by θa , is enough large; on the other hand, considering that modes depends on the brand advantage. As shown in Lemma 5,
the e-tailer has to pay the wholesale price to the manufacturer, though the effective price under either sales mode increases in θ ,
she will sell more M if the wholesale price is low. According to the increase rate is relatively low under agency selling when r is
b2 2b+b2 −b3
2 < r < 4−2b−b2 +b3 , if θ is high, epm < epm ,
large. Hence, given 2−b A R
Lemma 2, the wholesale price decreases in the competition degree
b (i.e., ∂∂wb < 0), which means that when two products are under otherwise epAm > epRm .
intense competition, the manufacturer would set a low wholesale
price. Therefore, if b is large, the e-tailer will order more M from 4.3. Comparison of profits
the manufacturer.

Lemma 4. (a) Under both agency selling and reselling, M’s mar- Proposition 1. The manufacturer prefers agency selling over reselling
∂(
qA
m ) ∂(
qR
m ) (i.e., πm
A > π R ) if r < r or r < r < r and θ < θˆ .
m 1 1 2
qA A
m +qe qR R
m +qe
ket share increases in θ (i.e., ∂θ > 0, ∂θ > 0). (b)
All proofs and values of omitted expressions are provided
M’s market share is larger under agency selling than that un-
b2 b2
in the Appendix. According to Proposition 1, the manufacturer’s
der reselling when r < 2−b 2 and θ < θ1 or r > 2−b2 . Note that preference over sales modes depends on the percentage fee and

θ1 = a(2−2b(1−r )−b (2+r )2)b+(1a−r4) −4b (2+r )+b (8+r ) .
2 2 4 2
the brand advantage. When the percentage fee is low, the man-
ufacturer prefers agency selling, where he can directly sell the
Lemma 4(a) demonstrates that a larger brand advantage brings products to consumers and keep most profits. When the percent-
the manufacturer more market share under both sales modes, age fee is high, the manufacturer chooses the reselling mode to
which is consistent with intuitions. Then Lemma 4(b) shows that avoid the considerate profit sharing. When the percentage fee is
M gains a larger market share under agency selling when the per- moderate, the manufacturer should take his brand advantage into
centage fee is large or the brand advantage is low. Under agency consideration. As mentioned in Lemma 6, when the brand advan-
selling, the manufacturer has to share his profits with the e-tailer. tage is low, M’s effective price is higher under agency selling than
With a large percentage fee, he will increase M’s sales quantities to that under reselling. Thus, when r1 < r < r2 and θ < θˆ , the man-
∂ qA ufacturer prefers agency selling. On the contrary, when r1 < r < r2
maintain his profits (i.e., ∂ rm > 0); on the other side, because the
e-tailer can gain a large proportion of profits from the manufac- and θ > θˆ , the manufacturer prefers reselling. These findings can
turer, she is willing to reduce E’s quantities to keep the prices rel- be supported by empirical evidence. On Amazon, products with
∂ qA high brand advantages are usually sold under reselling, whereas
atively high (i.e., ∂ re < 0). Hence, M occupies a larger market share
other long-tail and niche products are sold under agency sell-
under agency selling if r is large. Under reselling mode, the e-tailer
ing (Jiang, Jerath, & Srinivasan, 2011). In addition, recalling the
has the right to decide M’s sales quantities. As shown in Lemma 3,
statistics on the percentage of sales from private labels, agency
when the brand advantage is low, the e-tailer has no incentive
selling and reselling in Table 1, more sales are generated through
to order large quantities of M. Therefore, M occupies less market
agency selling if the private labels are well received, indicating the
share under reselling than under agency selling when θ is low.
relatively low manufacturers’ brand advantage.
Next, we discuss the e-tailer’s preference over sales modes.
4.2. Comparison of prices
Proposition 2. The e-tailer prefers agency selling over reselling (i.e.,
We first investigate the manufacturer’s incomes from unit sales πeA > πeR ) if r3 < r < r4 and θ > θ˜ or r > r4 .
of M, which we refer to as the effective price of M, represented
For the e-tailer, she can gain the percentage fee under agency
by ep. Under agency selling, M’s effective price is (1 − r ) pAm , while
selling, while has the right to decide M’s sales quantities under
under reselling, that is the wholesale price w.
reselling. If r is high, she prefers agency selling because of the
Lemma 5. (a) The effective prices of M under two sales modes both promising profit sharing. However, if r is low, under agency sell-
∂ epAm ∂ epRm ing, the e-tailer cannot gain much from the manufacturer, which
increase in θ (i.e., ∂θ > 0, ∂θ > 0), and the increase rate under
∂ epA
makes reselling more profitable for her. When the percentage fee
∂ ( ∂θm ) is moderate, given a large brand advantage, the e-tailer would give
agency selling reduces in r (i.e., ∂r < 0). (b) The effective price
under agency selling increases more rapidly than that under reselling up the right and adopt agency selling. The reason behind is that if
∂ epAm ∂ epRm b2 θ is large, M will be more profitable and thus under reselling, the
(i.e., ∂θ > ∂θ ) if r < 4−b2 . e-tailer has to order a lot from the manufacturer. Conversely, if θ
According to Lemma 5(a), if M has a larger brand advantage, no is low, holding the decision right, the e-tailer can set low order
matter which sales mode the manufacturer adopts, the effective quantities of M and thus sell more own products E to consumers
∂ qR ∂ qR
price is always higher. In other words, a larger brand advantage ( ∂θm > 0, ∂θe < 0). Therefore, considering expanding sales of E,
can increase the manufacturer’s incomes from unit M under both a high θ makes the decision right less attractive to the e-tailer,
sales modes. Besides, under agency selling, as r increases, more which inspires her to prefer agency selling.
increased incomes go to the e-tailer and thus to the manufacturer, Intuitively, when the percentage fee is relatively low or the
the increase rate reduces. Lemma 5(b) implies that if r exceeds brand advantage is relatively low, the manufacturer prefers

605
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Following previous studies (Krass et al., 2013; Niu et al., 2020a,


2020b), we adopt the index of environmental impact (EI) to
measure the environmental performance of agency selling and
reselling mode.

E IA = γ eqAm + eqAe (7)

E IR = γ eqRm + eqRe (8)

We use the parameter e to represent unit pollution per unit


production of E. Compared to the e-tailer who is skilled at on-
line sales, the manufacturer often owns more professional and
advanced production technology and has more experience in
clean production (Niu & Mu, 2020). We relax this assumption in
the extension (Section 6.3). Here we assume each M only causes
pollution of γ e, where 0 < γ < 1. γ represents the environmental
advantages of M and a higher γ implies that the production of
M causes almost equal pollution to E, i.e., lower advantages. We
compare the environmental performance under agency selling and
reselling in Proposition 4.

Proposition 4. Agency selling is more sustainable than reselling


mode (i.e., E IA < E IR ) if one of the following conditions occurs: (a)
b2 b2 b2
Fig. 3. The “win-win” zone under the agency selling.
r ≤ 2−b 2 , γ < γ2 and θ < θ2 ; (b) r > 2−b2 and γ < γ1 ; (c) r > 2−b2 ,
γ1 < γ < γ2 and θ < θ2 .

agency selling while the e-tailer prefers reselling. However, To make Proposition 4 more straightforward, we assume
Proposition 3 indicates that there exists a feasible region where that b = 0.5, indicating the moderate competition intensity. This
the manufacturer and the e-tailer can achieve incentive alignment assumption does not influence the structure of our results.
under agency selling. To make it observable, we perform numerical
analysis setting the parameters as b = 0.5 and a = 10 in Fig. 3. Lemma 7. When b = 0.5, agency selling is more environmentally
sustainable than reselling (i.e., E IA < E IR ) if one of the following
Proposition 3. Both the manufacturer and the e-tailer prefer agency 1+10γ a (3+r (19−2γ )−42γ )
conditions occurs: (a) γ ≤ 14
1
, r < 7−2γ and θ < 6+36γ −r (26−4γ ) ;
selling to reselling if one of the following conditions holds: (a) 42γ −3 1+10γ a (3+r (19−2γ )−42γ )
r3 < r < r1 and θ > θ˜ ; (b) r1 < r < r4 and θ˜ < θ < θˆ ; (c) r4 < r < r2 (b) 1
14 <γ < 1
2 , 19−2γ <r< 7−2γ and θ < 6+36γ −r (26−4γ )
; (c)
1+10γ
and θ < θˆ . γ < 12 and r > 7−2γ .

We refer to the regions where both firms prefer one specific Fig. 4 presents three interesting results: First, if r is large,
sales mode as “win-win” zones under that mode. Proposition 3 in- agency selling is more sustainable, otherwise reselling is more
dicates that there exists a “win-win” zone under agency selling. sustainable; Second, a lower brand advantage makes agency selling
From Fig. 3, we can clearly see that when the percentage fee outperform in environmental performance; Third, by comparing
and the brand advantage are moderate, the manufacturer and the Fig. 4(a)–(c), we find that with a higher γ , reselling mode is more
e-tailer both benefit from the agency selling. Besides, the manu- likely to be environmentally friendly, and if γ is very high (i.e.,
facturer and the e-tailer would not prefer reselling simultaneously γ > 12 ), reselling mode is always greener. To understand these re-
and thus there is no “win-win” zone under reselling. Note that, sults, we first identify two factors that influence the environmental
we use the symbol “->” to indicate the preference. For example, performance: total sales quantities and M’s market share. Total
“M->A” means that the manufacturer prefers agency selling. sales quantities mean that under either agency selling or reselling,
This may explain why agency selling has been embraced by the whole sales quantities of M and E. Obviously, larger total
many e-tailers and rapidly developed into a significant sales mode. sales quantities would deteriorate the environmental performance.
On Amazon, agency selling has already contributed above half Besides, M’s market share also affects the sales modes’ EI because
of paid units in 2020 (statista, 2020c). Also, though JD.com was M is more environmentally friendly than E, hence higher market
operated as a reselling platform firstly, agency selling now has share of M can reduce the pollution. Then we analyze how these
become as important as the reselling mode (Yan et al., 2019). two factors vary under agency selling and reselling.

5. Environmental impact of two sales modes Lemma 8. The total sales quantities under agency selling are always
higher than those under reselling (i.e., qAm + qAe > qRm + qRe ).
In addition to the traditional offline sales, e-commerce has
already become a main channel for many manufacturers. In 2019, With a high γ , the environmental advantage of M is not
online retail sales surpassed $3.5 trillion, accounting for 14.1% large, hence the total quantities become a critical factor in the
of all retail sales worldwide and this figure is expected to reach sales modes’ environmental performance. Therefore, as shown in
22% in 2023 (statista, 2020b). Online retailing surely provides Fig. 4(c), reselling mode is always an environmentally-friendly
manufacturers with more opportunities to increase sales, however, option. If γ is relatively moderate or low, M’s market share plays
it aggravates the environmental burden due to the expansion of a vital role. According to Lemma 4(b), M’s market share is larger
production. In Section 4, we compare the two sales modes from under agency selling when θ is low or r is high, so with such
the perspective of economic sustainability, and in this section, we conditions, agency selling induces smaller environmental impacts
analyze the environmental sustainability. (see Fig. 4(a) and (b)).

606
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Fig. 4. Comparison of environmental impacts (a = 10, e = 1, b = 0.5).

Fig. 5. The “win-win-win” zone under agency selling (a = 10, e = 1, b = 0.5).

5.1. Win-win-win situation for the manufacturer, the e-tailer and the the manufacturer’s production is enough green, the “win-win”
environment situation for two firms is definitely the “win-win-win” situation.

Combining Proposition 3 and Proposition 4, we can find there 6. Extensions


exists a “win-win-win” zone under agency selling which coor-
dinates the economic and environmental sustainability. In other 6.1. Positive production costs
words, the manufacturer’s profits, the e-tailer’s profits and the en-
vironment performance can be improved simultaneously. Though In this subsection, we take production costs into consideration.
it is hard to compute the exact expressions of the zone due to the We use tm and te to represent the manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s
sophisticated calculation, we numerically show it in Fig. 5. production costs for unit sales and their profit functions under
According to Fig. 5(a), when M’s production technology is two sales modes are as follows.
far better than E’s, the economic sustainability zone totally co-
ordinates the environmental sustainability. However, as shown
πmA = (1 − r ) pm qm − tm qm (9)
in Fig. 5(b), when M’s production technology advantage is not
very large, only part of the economic sustainability zone coor- πeA = r pm qm + ( pe − te )qe (10)
dinates the environmental sustainability because with a high γ ,
reselling mode is more likely to be the environmentally-friendly
choice. This finding provides valuable management insights for
πmR = (w − tm )qRm (11)
the governments who should implement policies to encourage the
   
manufacturer to improve his clean production technology. Once πeR = pRm − w qm + pRe − te qe (12)

607
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Fig. 8. The impact of production costs on environmental performance (a = 10, b =


Fig. 6. The impact of production costs on the manufacturer’s preference (a = 10,
0.5, γ = 0.8, θ = 3, e = 1).
θ = 3,b = 0.5).

Fig. 7. The impact of production costs on the e-tailer’s preference (a = 10, θ = 3,b =
0.5).

Compared to the e-tailer, the manufacturer owns more profes-


sional production technology and thus he can produce products
with fewer costs. However, the e-tailer with less experience in
Fig. 9. The “win-win-win” zone under agency selling (a = 10, b = 0.5, γ = 0.2, e =
production incurs higher production costs. We set tm < te to 1).
characterize the asymmetry in production costs. To simplify our
model, we normalize tm to zero and let t denote the e-tailer’s
costs of unit sales, which also represents the production cost to the main model, total sales quantities under agency selling
difference between the manufacturer and the e-tailer. Though we are always higher than those under reselling. However, if E’s
can achieve the closed-form equilibrium outcomes as shown in production costs are lower, the e-tailer will produce more E and
the Appendix, the additional analysis becomes intractable. As a order less M under reselling. Because M is more environmentally
result, we conduct the numerical analysis to derive the findings. friendly than E, a low t makes agency selling outperform.
We first focus on the impacts of positive production costs. Then we concentrate on the main results in the basic model,
From Fig. 6, we observe the manufacturer is more likely to prefer which still hold with positive production costs. First, when the
reselling when the e-tailer’s production costs are high. Under re- percentage fee and the brand advantage are low, the manufac-
selling, if the advantage of the manufacturer’s production costs is turer prefers agency selling, while the e-tailer prefers reselling.
large, the e-tailer will order more products from the manufacturer Second, when the percentage fee and the brand advantage are
and reduce the production quantities of private label products, moderate, both firms prefer agency selling. Third, there exists a
which makes reselling more attractive to the manufacturer. On the “win-win-win” situation where agency selling can improve the
opposite, with large production costs, the e-tailer prefers agency manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s profits as well as the environ-
selling as illustrated in Fig. 7. For the e-tailer, even with the mental performance. Fig. 9 intuitively shows the above findings.
decision right of M’s sales quantities under reselling, she cannot
set a low qm due to the disadvantage of E’s production costs and 6.2. Positive sales costs
thus she prefers agency selling in order to gain the promising
percentage fee. The previous analysis proves that positive production costs do
From Fig. 8, we find that when the e-tailer’s production costs not influence our results in the main model. However, when it
are low, agency selling is beneficial for the environment. Similar comes to online sales costs, there exist some additional interesting

608
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

findings. In this subsection, we relax the zero sales cost assump-


tion and explore how the sales costs influence our results. We as-
sume that the manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s sales costs for unit
sales are cm and ce . In reality, akin to the e-tailer’s disadvantage
in production, the manufacturer is often weak in sales efficiency
(Yan et al., 2018) for the following reasons. First, this inefficiency
may stem from the lack of sales experience and information about
customer preferences (Arya, Mittendorf, & Sappington, 2007; Li,
Gilbert, & Lai, 2013). Traditionally, the manufacturer produces
products and gives the sales work to retailers. Compared to the e-
tailer who is actually a professional e-commerce platform operator,
online sales, consisting of online store operation, online consumer
services and online marketing, are obviously not the manufac-
turer’s strength. Second, the manufacturer lacks the economics of
scale (Li, Gilbert, & Lai, 2015). The e-tailer serves many manufac-
turers’ online sales and thus can easily achieve economies of scale.
Take logistics services for example. In 2019, Amazon Logistics
delivered 1.9 billion packages in the US and achieved over $53.7 Fig. 10. The impact of sales costs on the manufacturer’s preference (a = 10, b = 0.5,
θ = 5).
billion in revenue worldwide (Statista, 2021). JD.com built its
large-scale and efficient logistics network, which reduced the
logistics costs (Niu, Xie, Chen, & Xu, 2020). Therefore, we assume
cm > ce and the profit functions are as follows.
πmA = (1 − r ) pm qm − cm qm (13 ) (13)

πeA = r pm qm + ( pe − ce )qe (14)

πmR = wqRm (15)

   
πeR = pRm − w − ce qm + pRe − ce qe (16)
Similar to the production costs, we normalize ce to zero and use
c to describe the sales cost difference between the two firms. This
assumption is common in prior papers (Arya et al., 2007; Li et al.,
2013). We require (1 − r )(a + θ − b(1+
2a
r)
) < c < (1 − r )(a + θ − ab
2 )
to ensure both the manufacturer and the e-tailer produce their
products. Lemma 9 presents the equilibrium outcomes under
Fig. 11. The impact of the brand advantage on the manufacturer’s preference with
agency selling. c = 0.5.

Lemma 9. Under agency selling, the equilibrium outcomes are


)(1−r )−2(c−(1−r )θ ) )+b(1+r )(c−(1−r )θ )
qAm = a(2−b
(4−b2 (1+r ))(1−r )
, qAe = a(1−r )(2(−b−br
4−b2 (1+r ) )(1−r )
,
Observation 1. When the percentage fee is moderate, given low sales
(a(2−b)(1−r )−2(c−(1−r )θ ))2
πmA = 2 , and costs, the manufacturer prefers reselling when θ is high. However,
(1−r )(4−b2 (1+r ))

(a(2 −b(1 −r+ br )) + b(c− (1 −r )θ ))(a(1 −r )(2 −b−br ) + b(1 + r )(c− (1 −r )θ )) + 1−r
r
(a(2−b)(1−r ) −2(c− (1−r )θ ))(a(2−b)(1−r ) −b2 c(1+r ) +2(c+ θ −rθ ))
πeA = .
(1 −r )(4 −b2 (1 + r ))2

given high sales costs, the manufacturer prefers agency selling when
Under reselling, both M and E are sold by the e-tailer, and θ is high.
when assuming her sales costs are zero, the equilibrium outcomes
are the same as Lemma 2. Because the analysis with sales costs With a moderate r, the manufacturer’s choice depends on the
becomes extremely complicated and intractable, we conduct brand advantage. The reason behind Observation 1 is as follows.
numerical analysis to derive the findings. First, we examine the No matter what values the sales costs are, there exists a threshold
manufacturer’s preference over the sales modes. rˆ. Once r > rˆ, the manufacturer begins to take the brand advantage
As Fig. 10 shows, the manufacturer prefers agency selling when into consideration, otherwise, he always adopts the agency selling.
the percentage fee is relatively low, which is consistent with the When the sales costs are high, the manufacturer is reluctant to
main model. When the percentage fee is moderate, we find that pay the costs, so the threshold rˆ is relatively low. According to
the manufacturer prefers agency selling if the sales costs are low, ∂ epAm
∂θ∂( )
otherwise he prefers reselling mode. This observation is intuitive Lemma 5, due to ∂r < 0, when r is low, M’s effective price
because under agency selling, the manufacturer is in charge of under agency selling increases rapidly in θ . Thus, the manufacturer
selling M and has to pay for the sales costs. Then we explore the adopts the agency selling if θ is high. On the contrary, when the
influence of the brand advantage on the manufacturer’s preference. sales costs are low, the manufacturer is willing to adopt agency
In Figs. 11 and 12, when the percentage fee is low, the man- selling, so the threshold rˆ is very high. Hence, at the time that
ufacturer prefers agency selling, and when the percentage fee the brand advantage should be considered, the percentage fee is
is large, he prefers reselling. The most interesting observation so high that M’s effective price increases very slowly in θ under
happens when the percentage fee is moderate. agency selling. Therefore, given low sales costs, the manufacturer

609
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

preference hinges on the brand advantage. If θ is large, the agency


selling is more profitable for the e-tailer. The explanation is the
same as that of Proposition 2.
In the main model, we conclude that the manufacturer and
the e-tailer can achieve incentive alignment under agency selling
when the percentage fee and the brand advantage are moderate.
Next, we investigate how the sales costs affect this result by
numerical analysis. First, we focus on the percentage fee.

Observation 2. When the percentage fee is moderate, with low


sales costs, the manufacturer and the e-tailer can both prefer agency
selling; with high sales costs, they can both prefer agency selling or
reselling depending on the brand advantage.

Fig. 14 illustrates that the manufacturer and the e-tailer have


the same preferences when the percentage fee is moderate, but
unlike the main model, they can both prefer agency selling or
Fig. 12. The impact of the brand advantage on the manufacturer’s preference with reselling depending on the sales costs. In Fig. 14(a), when the
c = 2. sales costs are low, two firms agree on agency selling as the
zero sales cost scenario. However, in Fig. 14(b), with high sales
costs, the manufacturer turns to choose the reselling mode at
a low percentage fee (r=0.35) in accordance with the e-tailer’s
preference. Besides, the brand advantage also influences two firms’
preferences. According to Fig. 15(a), we observe when the sales
costs are low, the preferences of the manufacturer and the e-tailer
are consistent with the main model, that is when the brand
advantage is moderate, they both benefit from the agency selling.
However, when it comes to high sales costs in Fig. 15(b), they
can engage in incentive alignment under agency selling (if θ is
high) and reselling (if θ is low). Note that, the e-tailer owns lower
sales costs and we assume ce =0 in this model. Thus, when the
manufacturer’s sales costs are high, he is more likely to accept the
reselling mode and lets the e-tailer be in charge of sales, which
makes reselling become a possible “win-win” outcome.
In summary, in the basic model, two firms can achieve incen-
tive alignment only under agency selling. However, when the sales
costs of the manufacturer and the e-tailer are asymmetric, they can
Fig. 13. The impact of the brand advantage on the e-tailer’s preference (a = 10, b =
0.5, c = 2). achieve that under agency selling or reselling depending on the
sales costs, percentage fee and brand advantage. In other words,
agency selling is more attractive when the manufacturer’s sales
prefers the reselling mode when θ is high. Next, we discuss the costs are low. This result may explain that many e-tailers did not
e-tailer’s preference. provide agency selling for manufacturers until the online retailing
From Fig. 13, we have two findings that both prove our main became mature. For example, JD.com initially offered only reselling
model’s results still hold. First, the e-tailer prefers agency selling mode and introduced agency selling when the platform was well
when the percentage fee is high, while she prefers reselling when developed (Yan et al., 2019). Also, some e-tailers such as Amazon
the fee is low. Second, when the percentage fee is moderate, her now offer a range of tools and services to help agency-selling

Fig. 14. The manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s preferences over sales modes (a = 10, b = 0.5, θ = 3).

610
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Fig. 15. The “win-win” zones with sales costs (a = 10, b = 0.5).

Fig. 16. The “win-win-win” zones with sales costs (a = 10, b = 0.5, e = 1).

manufacturers reduce sales costs (Amazon, 2021) because based the agency selling. Now we ask the following question: how the
on our findings, manufacturers and e-tailers are more likely to sales costs influence the environmental performance? We analyze
prefer agency selling simultaneously when the sales costs are low. this question and find the “win-win-win” zones with low sales
Recall that when there is no sales cost, the supply chain can costs (c=0.5) and high sales costs (c=2). Fig. 16 illustrates the
reach the economic and the environmental sustainability under results and we gain the following observations.

611
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

6.3. Alternative environmental impacts of M and E

In the main model, we assume that M is more environmentally


friendly than E. In this subsection, we consider the opposite
situation that the e-tailer can achieve cleaner production. The
environmental index functions are identical to those in the main
model (i.e., Eqs. (7) and (8)) with γ > 1.

Proposition 5. Given γ > 1, agency selling is more en-


vironmentally friendly than reselling only when b > 0.89,
 
−4+5b2 3 b3 r
r< b2
, γ > −24b−5+4b2br−2
+b2 r
and θ >θ where θ=
a (−1+b)(b3 (1+r )+b2 (−2+r (−2+γ )−3γ )−4b(r−γ )+4γ )
−4br+3b3 (1+r )+4γ +b2 (−7+r )γ
.

Proposition 5 illustrates that agency selling achieves the en-


vironmental sustainability under very strict conditions if the
production of M leads to higher pollution. Akin to the basic model,
the environmental performance is associated with two factors:
total sales quantities and M’s market share. If γ is low, the impacts
of two products on the environment are similar so the former
Fig. 17. The manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s preferences when θ < 0 (a = 10, b =
factor, which is always higher under agency selling, plays a vital
0.5).
role. Another parameter that influences the strength of the first
factor is b. With a lower b, the difference of total quantities under
two sales modes is higher, making that factor dominate. Further,
Observation 3. The “win-win-win” zone with low sales costs, similar we consider M’s market share. When θ is high and r is low, M’s
to the zero sales cost scenario, only exists under agency selling. Specif- market share is lower under agency selling. Therefore, agency sell-
ically, if γ is low, the “win-win” zone is the “win-win-win” zone; if ing is greener than reselling only when the former factor is very
γ is moderate, the “win-win” zone is partly the “win-win-win” zone; weak (γ and b are both high) and the latter factor is very strong
and if γ is high, there is no “win-win-win” zone. (θ is high and r is low). Note that, though we can prove agency
selling can be the greener sales mode, the conditions require the
Observation 4. The “win-win-win” zone with high sales costs exists extremely intensive competition and large disadvantage of M’s
under both agency selling and reselling. Specifically, if γ is low, the clean production, which are hard to achieve in practice. In other
“win-win” zones under agency selling and reselling can both become words, if the e-tailer owns cleaner production technology, there is
“win-win-win” zones; if γ is moderate or large, the “win-win” zone a strong possibility that reselling is the greener sales mode.
under reselling is the “win-win-win” zone.
6.4. Another type of brand advantage model
Because when the sales costs are low, the results and their
explanations are similar to our main model, here we focus on To verify the robustness of our findings, here we examine our
the high sales costs scenario. As before, two factors, total sales analysis with another typical type of brand advantage model. The
quantities and M’s market share, influence the environmental inverse demand functions are:
performance of two sales modes. Given a low γ , agency selling is
pm = aθ − qm − bqe (17)
more environmentally friendly than reselling if the percentage fee
is moderate and the brand advantage is high because under these
conditions, M has a relatively large market share under agency pe = a − qe − bqm (18)
selling. In addition, as γ increases, the total sales quantities, which
are always higher under agency selling, exert more influence on To capture M’s brand advantage and ensure the positive sales
2
the environmental performance and thus the dominant range quantities of M and E, we assume 1 < θ < min[ b+2br , 2−b
b
]. We de-
of agency selling becomes smaller until it disappears. Therefore, rive the equilibriums and show them in the Appendix. Because all
when γ is moderate or large, the “win-win-win” zone only exists results are consistent with the main model, we omit the analysis
under reselling. and confirm that our findings are robust.

Fig. 18. “Win-win-win” zones when θ < 0 (a = 10, b = 0.5, e = 1).

612
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

6.5. Consumers’ preference for the private label Second, the sales costs highly influence the manufacturer’s
preference and further change two firms’ incentive alignment. Our
In this extension, we study E’s brand advantage which may finding implies that agency selling is more efficient if the sales
stem from the credibility of the online sales platform. We use a + θ costs are relatively low. Considering that many e-tailers are now
to measure M’s market potential following the main model and rapidly developing agency selling, they should make efforts to
assume that consumers are willing to pay a higher price for E by reduce manufacturers’ online sales costs, such as offering sound
setting θ < 0. To ensure that the manufacturer and the e-tailer par- supporting systems. This finding may also explain that some
ticipate in the production, θ > ab − a is required. Note that though e-tailers such as JD.com and Amazon offered only reselling mode
θ is negative here, it still captures M’s brand image. Specifically, a initially, and did not introduce agency selling until the online
higher θ means that consumers are more willing to pay for M. We retailing became relatively mature (Liu et al., 2020).
conduct the same analysis as the main model and prove that our Third, if the manufacturer’s production technology is enough
findings still establish. First, from Fig. 17, if r is low and θ is low, environmentally friendly, the “win-win” situation for the manufac-
the manufacturer prefers agency selling while the e-tailer prefers turer and the e-tailer certainly benefits the environment. Therefore,
reselling. In addition to the “win-win” zone where both firms the governments are suggested to make policies to encourage man-
prefer agency selling as before, there also exists a “win-win” zone ufacturers to improve production technology and reduce pollution.
where they prefer reselling. Second, when considering the environ- There are several limitations in this study, which also offer
mental performance, our results in the main model are also robust. some future research openings. First, we analyze one manufacturer
The “win-win” zone under agency selling is certainly the “win- and one e-tailer in our model. Further studies may be extended
win-win” zone if γ is low (Fig. 18a) and it is partly the “win-win- to consider the competition and interaction between several
win” zone if γ is moderate (Fig. 18b). When γ is high, reselling is manufacturers or e-tailers. Second, compared to manufacturers,
always more environmentally friendly so that the “win-win” zone e-tailers have more market information and history sales data,
under reselling is certainly the “win-win-win” zone (Fig. 18c). which give them advantages in identifying the product potential.
Future research can explore the information sharing strategy when
the market demand is uncertain. Finally, in practice, e-tailers own
7. Conclusion online promotion resources on their platforms, which can be used
to promote the private labels’ and manufacturers’ products. For
This paper studies two common sales modes, agency sell- example, Amazon’s private label advertisements have appeared in
ing and reselling. Under agency selling, the manufacturer sells highly visible areas of the platform, like the top of search results
his products to consumers and shares profits with the e-tailer; or even next to a competitor’s product page (Colabug, 2020). With
while under reselling, the e-tailer, as a traditional retailer, orders this in mind, the allocation of promotion resources and the sales
products from the manufacturer and resells to consumers. We mode selection are worthy of further discussion.
investigate the manufacturer’s and the e-tailer’s preferences over
these two sales modes when the e-tailer owns her private label Declaration of Competing Interest
products. We find that when the percentage fee is high, the
manufacturer prefers reselling, while the e-tailer prefers agency None.
selling. When the percentage fee is moderate, they both take
brand advantage into consideration. With a high brand advantage, Acknowledgments
the manufacturer benefits more from reselling, however, the
e-tailer is more profitable under agency selling. Though their pref- We thank the editors and anonymous reviewers for their in-
erences seem opposite, we prove that they can achieve incentive sightful and constructive comments. This work was supported by
alignment under agency selling when the percentage fee and the the National Social Science Fund of China under Grant 15BGL074
brand advantage are moderate. Further, we compare two sales and 16BGL079.
modes’ environmental performance and identify two influence
Supplementary materials
factors, total sales quantities and manufacturer’s market share.
We find that under agency selling, the manufacturer, the e-tailer
Supplementary material associated with this article can be
and the environment can reach the “win-win-win” situation. In
found, in the online version, at doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2021.04.009.
the extension, we consider the asymmetric production and sales
costs of the manufacturer and the e-tailer. We confirm that the References
main findings in our basic model are robust and conduct some
additional results. In particular, if the sales costs are high, the Abhishek, V., Jerath, K., & John Zhang, Z. (2015). Agency selling or reselling? Channel
“win-win-win” situation can be reached both under agency selling structures in electronic retailing. Management Science, 62(8), 2259–2280. https:
//doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2230.
and reselling. The above findings are insightful for manufacturers Amazon. (2021). Questions for the record for Amazon following the July 29, 2020,
who are developing online channels as well as e-tailers who are Hearing of the Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial, and Administrative
designing the sales contracts for reselling and agency selling. Law, Committee on the Judiciary. Accessed February 28. https://docs.house.gov/
meetings/JU/JU05/20200729/110883/HHRG-116-JU05-20200729-QFR052.pdf.
Besides, our findings, especially those referring to the environ- Arya, A., Mittendorf, B., & Sappington, D. E. M. (2007). The bright side of supplier
mental performance, provide valuable managerial insights for the encroachment.. Marketing Science, 26(5), 651–659. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.
governments. The details are as follows. 1070.0280.
Barrieu, P., & Fehr, M. (2014). Market-consistent modeling for cap-and-trade
First, the manufacturer should consider not only the percentage
schemes and application to option pricing.. Operations Research, 62(2), 234–249.
fee, but also his brand advantage over the e-tailer’s private label https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.2013.1242.
when adopting one sales mode. If the percentage fee is moderate, Bauner, C., Jaenicke, E., Wang, E., & Wu, P.-. C. (2019). Couponing strategies in com-
petition between a national brand and a private label product.. Journal of Retail-
manufacturers with high brand advantages should adopt reselling.
ing, 95(1), 57–66. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretai.2018.11.002.
This finding is consistent with the practice. On Amazon, products Bian, J., & Zhao, X. (2020). Tax or subsidy? An analysis of environmental policies in
that are expected to generate large sales are sold under reselling, supply chains with retail competition. European Journal of Operational Research,
while other long-tail and niche products with low brand advan- 283(3), 901–914. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2019.11.052.
Colabug. (2020). Amazon has quietly removed promotional spots that gave special
tages are sold through manufacturers under agency selling (Jiang treatment to its own product.. Accessed October, 1. https://www.colabug.com/
et al., 2011). 2019/0403/5907420/.

613
X. Zhang and W. Hou European Journal of Operational Research 296 (2022) 601–614

Commuri, S. (2009). The impact of counterfeiting on genuine-item consumers’ Ru, J., Shi, R., & Zhang, J. (2015). Does a store brand always hurt the manufacturer
brand relationships.. Journal of Marketing, 73(3), 86–98. https://doi.org/10.1509/ of a competing national brand? Production and Operations Management, 24(2),
jmkg.73.3.86. 272–286. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12220.
eMarketer. (2020). Global ecommerce 2020. Accessed October 1. https://www. Ryan, J. K., Sun, D., & Zhao, X. (2012). Competition and coordination in online
emarketer.com/content/global- ecommerce- 2020. marketplaces.. Production and Operations Management, 21(6), 997–1014. https:
Gielens, K., Ma, Y., Namin, A., Sethuraman, R., Smith, R. J., Bachtel, R. C., et al. (2021). //doi.org/10.1111/j.1937-5956.2012.01332.x.
The future of private labels: towards a smart private label strategy.. Journal of Statista. (2020a). Share of revenue from product sales of JD.com platform in to-
Retailing doi:. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretai.2020.10.007. tal revenue from 2017 to 2019. Accessed October 1. https://www.statista.com/
Hökelekli, G., Lamey, L., & Verboven, F. (2017). Private label line proliferation and statistics/1011703/china-revenue-share-of-self-operated-business-of-jd/.
private label tier pricing: A new dimension of competition between private la- Statista. (2020b). Percentage of paid units sold by third-party sellers on Amazon
bels and national brands.. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, 36, 39–52. platform as of 2nd quarter 2020. Accessed October 1. https://www.statista.com/
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.12.014. statistics/259782/third- party- seller- share- of- amazon- platform/.
Hu, B., Mai, Y., & Pekeč, S. (2020). Managing innovation spillover in outsourcing.. Statista. (2020c). E-commerce share of total global retail sales from 2015
Production and Operations Management, 29(10), 2252–2267. https://doi.org/10. to 2023. Accessed October 1. https://www.statista.com/statistics/534123/
1111/poms.13222. e- commerce- share- of- retail- sales- worldwide/.
Jiang, B., Jerath, K., & Srinivasan, K. (2011). Firm strategies in the “mid tail” of Statista. (2020). Alibaba group – statistics & facts. Accessed October 1. https://www.
platform-based retailing.. Marketing Science, 30(5), 757–775. https://doi.org/10. statista.com/topics/2187/alibaba-group/.
1287/mksc.1110.0656. Statista. (2021). Revenue of Amazon logistics worldwide from 2017 to
Kogan.com. (2020). Annual Report 2019. Accessed October 1. https://www. 2019. Accessed January 1st. https://www.statista.com/statistics/1179010/
kogancorporate.com/. amazon- logistics- revenue-worldwide/.
Krass, D., Nedorezov, T., & Ovchinnikov, A. (2013). Environmental taxes and the Tian, L., Vakharia, A. J., Tan, Y., & Xu, Y. (2018). Marketplace, reseller, or hybrid:
choice of green technology.. Production and Operations Management, 22(5), strategic analysis of an emerging e-commerce model.. Production and Operations
1035–1055. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12023. Management, 27(8), 1595–1610. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12885.
Kroes, J., Subramanian, R., & Subramanyam, R. (2012). Operational compliance Turken, N., Carrillo, J., & Verter, V. (2020). Strategic supply chain decisions under
levers, environmental performance, and firm performance under cap and trade environmental regulations: When to invest in end-of-pipe and green technol-
regulation.. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 14(2), 186–201. ogy.. European Journal of Operational Research, 283(2), 601–613. https://doi.org/
https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.1110.0357. 10.1016/j.ejor.2019.11.022.
Li, Z., Gilbert, S. M., & Lai, G. (2013). Supplier encroachment under asymmetric in- Wang, J. J., Torelli, C. J., & Lalwani, A. K. (2020). The interactive effect of power
formation.. Management Science, 60(2), 449–462. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc. distance belief and consumers’ status on preference for national (vs. private-
2013.1780. label) brands.. Journal of Business Research, 107, 1–12. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Li, Z., Gilbert, S. M., & Lai, G. (2015). Supplier encroachment as an enhancement or jbusres.2019.10.001.
a hindrance to nonlinear pricing.. Production and Operations Management, 24(1), Wei, J., Lu, J., & Zhao, J. (2020). Interactions of competing manufacturers’ leader-
89–109. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12210. follower relationship and sales format on online platforms.. European Journal of
Liu, W., Yan, X., Li, X., & Wei, W. (2020). The impacts of market size and data-driven Operational Research, 280(2), 508–522. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2019.07.048.
marketing on the sales mode selection in an Internet platform based supply Xiao, W., Gaimon, C., Subramanian, R., & Biehl, M. (2019). Investment in environ-
chain.. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 136, mental process improvement.. Production and Operations Management, 28(2),
Article 101914. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2020.101914. 407–420. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12927.
Mantin, B., Krishnan, H., & Dhar, T. (2014). The Strategic role of third-party market- YahooFinance. (2021). Big tech’s antitrust hearing: what you need
places in retailing.. Production and Operations Management, 23(11), 1937–1949. to know. Accessed February 25. https://finance.yahoo.com/news/
https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12203. big- tech- antitrust- hearing- know- 040100446.html.
MarketplacePulse. (2020). Amazon private label brands. Accessed October 1. https: Yan, Y., Zhao, R., & Liu, Z. (2018). Strategic introduction of the marketplace chan-
//www.marketplacepulse.com/amazon- private- label- brands#search. nel under spillovers from online to offline sales.. European Journal of Operational
Nenycz-Thiel, M., Sharp, B., Dawes, J., & Romaniuk, J. (2010). Competition for mem- Research, 267(1), 65–77. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2017.11.011.
ory retrieval between private label and national brands.. Journal of Business Re- Yan, Y., Zhao, R., & Xing, T. (2019). Strategic introduction of the marketplace chan-
search, 63(11), 1142–1147. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2009.10.010. nel under dual upstream disadvantages in sales efficiency and demand informa-
Niu, B., Li, J., Zhang, J., Cheng, H. K., & Tan, Y. (2019). Strategic analysis of dual sourc- tion.. European Journal of Operational Research, 273(3), 968–982. https://doi.org/
ing and dual channel with an unreliable alternative supplier.. Production and 10.1016/j.ejor.2018.09.022.
Operations Management, 28(3), 570–587. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12938. Zennyo, Y. (2020). Strategic contracting and hybrid use of agency and wholesale
Niu, B., & Mu, Z. (2020). Sustainable efforts, procurement outsourcing, and chan- contracts in e-commerce platforms.. European Journal of Operational Research,
nel co-opetition in emerging markets.. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics 281(1), 231–239. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2019.08.026.
and Transportation Review, 138, Article 101960. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2020. Zhang, J., Cao, Q., & He, X. (2019). Contract and product quality in platform sell-
101960. ing.. European Journal of Operational Research, 272(3), 928–944. https://doi.org/
Niu, B., Xie, F., Chen, L., & Xu, X. (2020). Join logistics sharing alliance or not? Incen- 10.1016/j.ejor.2018.07.023.
tive analysis of competing E-commerce firms with promised-delivery-time.. In- Zhang, S., & Zhang, J. (2020). Agency selling or reselling: E-tailer information shar-
ternational Journal of Production Economics, 224, Article 107553. https://doi.org/ ing with supplier offline entry.. European Journal of Operational Research, 280(1),
10.1016/j.ijpe.2019.107553. 134–151. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2019.07.003.
Niu, B., Xie, F., Mu, Z., & Ji, P. (2020). Multinational firms’ local sourcing strategies Zhou, Y., Liu, T., & Cai, G. (2019). Impact of in-store promotion and spillover effect
considering unreliable supply and environmental sustainability.. Resources, Con- on private label introduction.. Service Science, 11(2), 96–112. https://doi.org/10.
servation and Recycling, 155, Article 104648. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec. 1287/serv.2019.0236.
2019.104648. Zippel, C., Wilkinson, J., & Vogler, T. (2013). The influence of private labels on re-
Örsdemir, A., Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya, E., & Parlaktürk, A. K. (2014). Competitive quality tailer cooperation.. Australasian Marketing Journal (AMJ), 21(4), 271–277. https:
choice and remanufacturing.. Production and Operations Management, 23(1), 48– //doi.org/10.1016/j.ausmj.2013.08.008.
64. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12040.
Qin, X., Liu, Z., & Tian, L. (2020). The optimal combination between selling mode
and logistics service strategy in an e-commerce market.. European Journal of Op-
erational Research. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2020.07.029.

614

You might also like