Product Variety and Channel Structure Strategy For A Retailer-Stackelberg Supply Chain

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

European Journal of Operational Research


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ejor

Production, Manufacturing and Logistics

Product variety and channel structure strategy for a retailer-Stackelberg


supply chain
Tiaojun Xiao a, Tsan-Ming Choi b,⇑, T.C.E. Cheng a,c
a
School of Management Science and Engineering, Nanjing University, Nanjing 210093, China
b
Business Division, Institute of Textiles and Clothing, The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hung Hom, Kowloon, Hong Kong
c
Department of Logistics and Maritime Studies, The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hung Hom, Kowloon, Hong Kong

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Motivated by the observations that the direct sales channel is increasingly used for customized products
Received 25 January 2013 and that retailers wield leadership, we develop in this paper a retailer-Stackelberg pricing model to inves-
Accepted 27 August 2013 tigate the product variety and channel structure strategies of manufacturer in a circular spatial market.
Available online 5 September 2013
To avoid channel conflict, we consider the commonly observed case where the indirect channel sells stan-
dard products whereas the direct channel offers custom products. Our analytical results indicate that if
Keywords: the reservation price in the indirect channel is sufficiently low, adding the direct channel raises the unit
Supply chain management
wholesale price and retail price in the indirect channel due to customization in the direct channel.
Product variety
Customization
Despite the fact that dual channels for the retailer may dominate the single indirect channel, we find that
Dual channels the motivation for the manufacturer to use dual channels decreases with the unit production cost, while
Game theory increases with (i) the marginal cost of variety, (ii) the retailer’s marginal selling cost, and (iii) the cus-
tomer’s fit cost. Interestingly, our equilibrium analysis demonstrates that it is more likely for the manu-
facturer to use dual channels under the retailer Stackelberg channel leadership scenario than under the
manufacturer Stackelberg scenario if offering a greater variety is very expensive. When offering a greater
variety is inexpensive, the decentralization of the indirect channel may invert the manufacturer’s channel
structure decision. Furthermore, endogenization of product variety will also invert the channel structure
decision if the standard product’s reservation price is sufficiently low.
Ó 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction product attributes. It is well known that there exists channel conflict
between the indirect channel and the direct channel because both
With the development of e-commerce and Internet technologies, channels compete for customers.1 Hence, the manufacturer must
increasing numbers of manufacturers that previously sold their cautiously avoid channel conflict and make a careful trade-off be-
products indirectly through third-party retailers have established tween product variety and customization. In fact, incorporating this
sales channels to sell to customers directly. Some well-known trade-off to address whether and when the manufacturer has an
examples are Compaq, Hewlett–Packard, IBM, Eastman Kodak, Nike, incentive to use dual channels is a main objective of this paper.
Mattel, and Apple, among others (Mukhopadhyay et al., 2008; Tsay Consider the sales channel of Nike, an international brand for
and Agrawal, 2004; Wilder, 1999). The U.S. Department of Com- footwear and apparel, in Hong Kong. Since Hong Kong is a market
merce reported that total U.S. e-commerce sales jumped by 14.8% in which retail brands mainly rely on bricks-and-mortars stores to
in 2010 to about US$165.4 billion (Brohan, 2011). To cater for a sell their products, Nike’s standard products are only available in
broader (more heterogeneous) mix of consumer groups, supply physical retail stores. At the same time, Nike launches its
chains are increasingly providing a higher product variety to attract renowned NIKEiD mass customization programme online.
customers (Dekimpe et al., 2011). Product variety here refers to the Consumers in Hong Kong can select and buy a pair of customized
number of variants within a specific product group. Customization shoes with their names printed via this online sales channel.
is an important value-adding service of the direct channel (which Obviously, Nike’s dual channel strategy is one designed to avoid
is more effective compared with the indirect channel) because it channel conflict, which is the exact business model that we
can better satisfy the heterogeneous demands of customers for examine in this paper.

⇑ Corresponding author. Tel.: +852 2766 6450. 1


A classic example of channel conflict is Levi’s case (Laudon and Laudon, 2002, p.
E-mail addresses: xiaotj@nju.edu.cn (T. Xiao), jason.choi@polyu.edu.hk 130), in which Levi’s had to give up its online direct sales channel because of a fierce
(T.-M. Choi), Edwin.Cheng@polyu.edu.hk (T.C.E. Cheng). channel conflict with its indirect channel.

0377-2217/$ - see front matter Ó 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2013.08.038
T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124 115

Dual channels, as a part of the popular concept of multi-channel paper. The channel leadership structure (sequence of decisions)
retailing, are usually associated with the Internet direct sales chan- affects the equilibrium outcome (Choi and Fredj, 2013), which
nel. The recent literature has explored dual channels from various further influences the channel structure strategy of the manufac-
perspectives. Perspective one assumes that the dual channel struc- turer. Some works are made in the effect of channel leadership
ture of a manufacturer is given and explores the corresponding structure. For example, Pan et al. (2010) discussed different con-
operational issues. There is no consideration of the strategic action tract strategies under both manufacturer-Stackelberg (MS) and
of adding the direct channel in the pure indirect channel strategy RS supply chains and identified the conditions under which the
(e.g., Cattani et al., 2006;Mukhopadhyay et al., 2008). Perspective leader is better off using a revenue-sharing contract. Edirisinghe
two considers the strategic choice as to whether there are incen- et al. (2011) studied the implications of channel power (capability
tives for manufacturers to add a direct channel (e.g., Bernstein of being a leader) on supply chain stability for a two-supplier and
et al., 2008). For both perspectives, customer acceptance and pref- one-retailer supply chain. Choi et al. (2013) examined the closed
erence for the direct channel relative to traditional stores (the indi- loop supply chain with different channel leadership. To the best
rect channel) undoubtedly influences the success of dual channels of our knowledge, the effect of channel leadership structure on
(see, e.g., Chiang et al., 2003 for some more arguments and exam- the channel structure decision of the manufacturer is still under-
ples). Moreover, the difference in marginal cost between the two explored. We try to fill this important research gap by comparing
channels plays an important role in determining the existence the RS model with the MS model.
and configuration of dual channels. For instance, Tsay and Agrawal Increasing product variety is an effective business strategy be-
(2004) pointed out that in the personal computer industry, direct cause it can raise market demand. When a new product emerges,
selling facilitates the ‘‘assemble-to-order’’ strategy that typically firms often produce many variants. For example, in the automobile
entails less inventory risk than the ‘‘make-to-stock’’ approach of industry, manufacturers differentiate their products according to
retail distribution. Dumrongsiri et al. (2008) found that the manu- interior color, power specifications, and seat materials (Fisher
facturer is likely to be better off using dual channels than using the and Ittner, 1999). In the bicycle industry, manufacturers offer
single channel when the retailer’s marginal cost is high, and the different products according to frame material, frame size, frame
wholesale price, customer valuation, and demand variability are color, and components (Randall and Ulrich, 2001). In the literature,
low. Hendrikse and Jiang (2011) studied dual distributions in fran- product variety is well-regarded as an important factor that
chising based on incomplete contract. In this paper we follow per- influences customers’ buying decisions (Gaur and Honhon, 2006;
spective two in the above reviewed literature on dual channels and Hoffman and Novak, 1996; Xia and Rajagopalan, 2012). For
examine the strategic challenge from adding the direct sales chan- instance, Xia and Rajagopalan (2009) studied the standardization
nel. We consider the case where the two channels sell different and customization decisions of two firms in a competitive setting
products (the indirect channel sells a standard product while the and found interestingly that increasing product variety will not
direct channel sells a custom product) and customers have differ- intensify price competition if firm differentiation is sufficiently
ent reservation prices for the products in different channels. high. Gaur and Honhon (2006) developed a location-choice model
Chiang et al. (2003) argued that reducing double marginalization to study an assortment planning and inventory management prob-
effect is a main incentive for adding the direct channel. However, lem for a retailer under stochastic demand. However, increasing
as we shall show in later sections, we find that adding the direct product variety is not without drawbacks (Matsubayashi et al.,
channel may strengthen double marginalization effect, which has 2009). For example, it is well known that having a greater product
a negative effect on the indirect channel’s profitability and weak- variety within a supply chain tends to increase the corresponding
ens the motivation to use dual channels. operational costs (see, e.g., Randall and Ulrich, 2001 for more dis-
Using dual channels for the business model as adopted by Nike cussions). Furthermore, product variety alone (without proper cus-
Hong Kong, the manufacturer has two revenue sources, which tomization) may not well satisfy the heterogeneous demands of
would increase the manufacturer’s profit. However, the presence customers. As a result, some firms offer customization service, such
of the reservation price disadvantages of the direct channel over as the popular mass customization service, to address this issue.
the indirect channel and probable channel conflict between the For instance, apparel brands adopting mass customization allow
two channels together reduce the manufacturer’s profit. In partic- consumers to select various customizable attributes such as color,
ular, when the retailer (i.e., the indirect channel) is a Stackelberg rise, front pocket style, leg, waist, inseam, and seat shape of their
leader of the supply chain channel, the counter-force for the devel- pants (Mendelson and Parlaktürk, 2008). With the concepts of
opment of the direct channel and channel conflict can be large. As a mass customization and dual channels in mind, Dewan et al.
consequence, it is unclear whether the manufacturer in a retailer- (2003) found that the simultaneous adoption of customization in
Stackelberg (RS) supply chain should use the dual channel strategy. a duopoly game reduces differentiation between the players’
In the literature, in view of the emergence of retail giants such as standard products but does not intensify price competition. In this
Wal-Mart and Hudson’s Bay, there is a growing body of studies paper we consider product variety, mass customization, and dual
on exploring the effect of downstream power shifting in supply channels simultaneously. These factors affect the double marginal-
chains (see, e.g., Geylani et al., 2007). To be specific Geylani et al. ization effect and market demand in the indirect channel, which in
(2007) studied how a manufacturer strategically reacts to a domi- turn influences the channel structure decision. Our scenario is sup-
nant retailer to decide the unit wholesale price for the weak retai- ported by real-world cases (e.g., Nike) and obviously helps reduce
ler and advertising investment, where the bargaining power is the pressure of channel conflict. In the literature, Randall and
described by the (exogenous) unit wholesale price for the domi- Ulrich (2001) investigated the interaction between product variety
nant retailer. Since the effect of adding a direct channel on the unit and supply chain structure by examining U.S. bicycle industry,
wholesale price plays an important role in making the channel where supply chain structure is characterized by production effi-
structure decision, unlike Geylani et al. (2007), we consider the ciency and facility location. Unlike Randall and Ulrich (2001), we
endogenous wholesale price case. Notice that recently a number study whether the manufacturer has an incentive to add a direct
of studies have examined the RS supply chain (Choi and Fredj, channel to the indirect channel. Thonemann and Bradley (2002)
2013; Gerchak and Wang, 2004; Pan et al., 2010;Wang and Liu, studied how product variety affects the expected leadtime and
2007). Based on the observed industrial trend and the literature expected cost at the retailers. However, we explore how product
on RS supply chain management, we focus on examining the variety affects channel structure strategy. In addition, it is interest-
probable existence of dual channels in a RS supply chain in this ing to study how the channel structure strategy affects product
116 T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124

variety decision through influencing the pricing and demand for may invert the channel structure strategy of the manufacturer. To
the indirect channel. In short, our objective is to understand how the best of our knowledge, our model and analysis are novel and dif-
product variety and customization affect the double marginaliza- ferent from the extant dual channel literature in two important ways:
tion effect, and the interaction between the product variety deci- (i) we examine how dual channel strategy relates to product variety
sion and the channel structure decision.2 To the best of our strategy, and channel leadership structure (RS and MS), and (ii) we
knowledge, these issues are still not addressed in the literature employ a consumer-utility driven ‘‘circular spatial market’’ model.
and hence this paper attempts to address them. In particular, we fo- To enhance presentation, we put some technical propositions in
cus on how the exogenization of product variety affects the channel Appendix A and use Theorems and Corollaries to summarize the main
structure strategy. We find that this effect is essential because the insights. Detailed proofs are relegated to an online supplementary
interaction between product variety and pricing is absent. document.
As a remark, our model in this paper is also related to the circu-
lar spatial market model (Balasubramanian, 1998; Dewan et al., 2. The basic model
2003; Salop, 1979). Essentially, Salop (1979) pioneered and intro-
duced a variant of the traditional Hotelling (1929) model, known Consider a supply chain consisting of one manufacturer and one
as the circular spatial market model, where the consumers are bricks-and-mortar retail store (‘‘retailer’’ in short). The manufac-
modeled to be uniformly distributed on a circle and all the firms turer sells the standard product through the retailer (indirect chan-
are located evenly on the circle. Salop’s circular spatial market nel). Now, the manufacturer has an opportunity to consider
model is influential and has been employed in many studies whether to add a direct (online) channel to supplement the indi-
(Soberman and Parker, 2006). For instance, Balasubramanian rect channel, where the direct channel sells a fully customized
(1998) considered the competition between a direct marketer product to satisfy consumer requirements (custom product). If
and conventional retailers in price with the behaviors of the sup- deemed beneficial to add the online channel, the manufacturer
pliers being ignored. Dewan et al. (2003) developed a duopoly would use dual channels with both indirect and direct channels
model where each firm first chooses a customization scope and as the channel structure strategy; otherwise, it only uses the single
then optimally determines the conventional market price. Since indirect channel. In other words, we consider in this paper the case
in the context of RS supply chain management, a consumer-utility where the manufacturer needs to select either the ‘‘single indirect
driven demand model can better capture the different demand pat- channel’’ or the ‘‘dual channels’’ strategy.
terns of dual channels, we employ the circular spatial market in We construct the basic model based on the commonly adopted
developing our model. circular spatial market in the literature (Balasubramanian, 1998;
In this paper, in order to address the research issues raised Salop, 1979; Soberman and Parker, 2006). In the circular spatial
above, we first develop a formal analytical RS supply chain model market, the preferences of consumers are uniformly distributed
in a circular spatial consumer market. In this ‘‘basic model’’, the re- on a circle of unit circumference (the locations represent their ideal
tailer is the Stackelberg pricing leader and the manufacturer is the products) and n types of a standard product are evenly distributed
follower. In the indirect channel, the manufacturer sells a standard- on the circle, i.e., the manufacturer evenly divides the unit circular
ized (standard) product with variety through the retailer; in the di- market into n segments such that the arc length of each segment is
rect channel, the manufacturer sells a mass customized (custom)3 1/n (see Fig. 1). Each consumer has a unitary demand in each per-
product directly to consumers (cf: Nike). As a benchmark, we first iod and the unit reservation price of the standard product is r. A
consider the dual channel strategy of a vertically integrated firm. standard product at an arc distance y units away from the con-
We find that when the product variety investment is very expensive, sumer generates a gross utility of r  ty, where t is called the fit cost
the integrated firm inclines to use dual channels. We then study the per unit distance and reflects the attribute differentiation of the
equilibrium decisions of the decentralized supply chain, with a focus standard product (Dewan et al., 2003). Gaur and Honhon (2006)
on the dual channel strategy of the manufacturer. We obtain the considered a location-choice model for a retailer under the uncer-
closed-form conditions under which it is optimal for the manufac- tain environment. To focus on the channel competition and the
turer to use dual channels. We find that the decentralization of the channel structure decision, we assume that the market environ-
supply chain may invert the effect of channel structure on the equi- ment excluding consumers’ locations is deterministic. As a remark,
librium product variety. Unlike the extant literature on dual channels we adopt the circular spatial market because it can well describe
(Chiang et al., 2003), we show that adding the direct channel raises the effects of product variety and heterogeneity of consumers on
the prices in the indirect channel if the (consumer) reservation price market demand for dual channels.
of the standard product is sufficiently low, i.e., intensifying the dou- The retailer orders the standard product from the manufacturer.
ble marginalization effect, which weakens the motivation of using In the basic model, we consider the supply chain as a RS channel
dual channels. We analytically reveal why the manufacturer would where the retailer is the pricing leader that first determines the
prefer and use dual channels even though adding the direct channel profit margin m and then the manufacturer determines the unit
intensifies the double marginalization effect. To examine the effect of wholesale price w for the standard product.4
the channel leadership on the manufacturer’s decisions and the retai- Owing to symmetry of the locations of the different types of the
ler’s profit, we also develop an MS model and compare its results with standard product, the equilibrium retail prices are identical, i.e.,
those of the RS model. We show that whether the retailer has an the manufacturer should charge the retailer the same unit
incentive to act as a Stackelberg leader depends on whether the mar- wholesale price such that the retailer offers the same retail price
ket is fully covered. In addition, we examine how product variety and p(= w + m) for all types of the standard product (Xia and
exogenization of product variety affect the implementation of the Rajagopalan, 2009). Thus, the (net) utility of the consumer that
dual channel strategy. We find that endogenizing product variety buys a unit of the standard product from the retailer is
r  ty  (w + m), y 6 1/(2n).
Denote the reservation price of the consumer that buys the
2
As a remark, both adding the direct channel and increasing product variety can custom product from the direct channel as rd and the (direct) retail
raise the total market demand. To a certain extent, the two approaches substitute
each other. However, both approaches incur different costs.
3 4
In this paper we follow the literature (Xia and Rajagopalan, 2009) to use ‘‘custom Notice that the case in which the retailer determines the profit margin is very
product’’ and ‘‘standard product’’ for the terms ‘‘customized product’’ and ‘‘standard- common in the literature and practice (see, e.g., Kadiyali et al., 1999; Sudhir, 2001;
ized product’’, respectively. Trivedi, 1998).
T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124 117

Rn From r  ty  (w + m) P 0 and y 6 1/(2n), we see that when the


Direct
channel’s manufacturer only uses the indirect channel, the market demand is
share 
2nðr  w  mÞ=t; if w > r  m  t=ð2nÞ
x1 ¼ ; ð1Þ
pd 1; if w 6 r  m  t=ð2nÞ
which means that the market is not fully covered if the retail price
R1 D p R Retailer’s is sufficiently high (w > r  m  t/(2n)). Furthermore, the manufac-
share turer’s profit function is

pM11 ; if w > r  m  t=ð2nÞ
pM1 ¼ ; ð2Þ
pM12 ; if w 6 r  m  t=ð2nÞ
where pM11 = (w  c)  2n(r  w  m)/t  gn2/2  nf and pM12 =
R2 (w  c) 1  gn2/2  nf. The retailer’s profit function is pR1 =
x1  (m  cr). The second number suffix j(= 1, 2) represents branch j.
Fig. 1. Circular spatial market. Unlike Dewan et al. (2003), we consider the case that the man-
ufacturer sells the standard product through the indirect channel
price of the custom product as pd. rd may be different from r due to
and the custom product through the direct channel that can cus-
a virtual inspection and a lead time (i.e., waiting time). The (net)
tomize the whole circle. We consider the market demand (x) for
utility of the consumer that buys the custom product from the di-
the standard product. In dual channels, since the direct channel
rect channel is rd  pd. Here a consumer can save fit cost by buying
can customize the product to meet consumers’ specifications, no
custom product to satisfy its requirements. However, buying stan-
fit cost is incurred to consumers and each consumer obtains a sur-
dard product incurs a fit cost because this standard product may be
plus rd  pd. If pd > rd, the manufacturer achieves a higher profit un-
different from its preference. To prevent the retailer from buying
der the single indirect channel than under dual channels because
from the direct channel (the retailer’s arbitrage behavior), the
the dual channels strategy is degenerated to be a single indirect
manufacturer charges the retailer a unit wholesale price lower
channel and incurs a positive fixed cost of adding direct channel.
than the direct channel’s retail price, i.e., w 6 pd (Chiang et al.,
Thus, the manufacturer should offer a direct retail price pd less than
2003). Let the unit production cost of the manufacturer be c. The
the reservation price rd in dual channels such that a consumer that
retailer incurs a marginal selling cost of the standard product cr;
buys the custom product will obtain a nonnegative surplus
the direct channel incurs a marginal selling cost of the custom
rd  pd P 0. Furthermore, the market is fully covered and each
product cd.5 Note that the retail prices in the two channels are higher
consumer buys from either channel in dual channels. Since the
than the total marginal costs, i.e., w + m P c + cr and pd P c + cd. To
effect of the fixed cost from adding direct channel to the channel
avoid the trivial cases, we assume throughout this paper that (i)
structure decision is well understood, we ignore it, which does
the total surplus of each channel is positive, i.e., r  c  cr > 0 and
not impact our main results.
rd  c  cd > 0 (otherwise, the channel with a non-positive value will
When the manufacturer uses dual channels and there is a posi-
withdraw from the market because the manufacturer cannot make a
tive demand for the custom product, the manufacturer’s profit
profit from the channel), and (ii) the indirect channel has a higher
function is
total surplus than the direct channel (otherwise, the manufacturer
will sell all the products through the direct channel despite having pM2 ¼ 2nðr  w  mÞðw  cÞ=t þ ½1  2nðr  w  mÞ=t
dual channels), i.e., r  cr P rd  cd. For a notational purpose, denote ðpd  c  cd Þ  gn2 =2  nf ; ð3Þ
(i) the total surplus of the indirect channel as A1 = r  c  cr(>0),
(ii) the total surplus difference between the two channels as where the first term is the manufacturer’s gross profit coming from
A2 = cd  cr + r  rd > 0. Since rd  c  cd > 0, we have A1 > A2. the indirect channel and the second term is the manufacturer’s
Increasing product variety incurs costs to the manufacturer profit coming from the direct channel. In dual channels, the retai-
(Xia and Rajagopalan, 2009). A higher variety level often raises ler’s profit function is
the difficulty of increasing variety such that a higher marginal vari- pR2 ¼ 2nðr  w  mÞðm  cr Þ=t: ð4Þ
ety cost is incurred. Thus, we extend the linear cost structure (nf) in
Xia and Rajagopalan (2009) to the case where product variety n in- The retailer should take the manufacturer’s wholesale price reac-
curs a cost gn2/2 + nf, including the product development cost and tion into consideration in order to maximize its profit function.
the labor learning cost, and f, g > 0.6 This quadratic cost structure The sequence of decisions in the game in our basic model (the
means that the marginal cost of product variety increases with the RS model) is given as follows:
variety level, which is consistent with that in the literature on inno-
vation (e.g., Gupta, 2008). A similar cost structure with a quadratic (i) The manufacturer chooses the single indirect channel (the
term is used by Dewan et al. (2003) who study product customiza- standard product) or dual channels (standard and custom
tion. We call g the variable marginal cost coefficient (VC) and f the products), and then determines product variety n for the
constant marginal cost of product variety. standard product;
For the sake of convenience, in the basic model, we use the first (ii) The retailer determines the (profit) margin m of the standard
number suffix 1 to represent the case of using the single indirect product;
channel and 2 to represent the case of using dual channels. (iii) If the manufacturer uses dual channels, it determines the
unit wholesale price w of the standard product in the indi-
rect channel and the retail price pd of the custom product
5
cr includes costs like stocking, labor, and facility maintenance costs; cd includes in the direct channel; otherwise, it determines the unit
the costs of maintaining the website, the distribution system, and extra unit wholesale price w.
production cost due to customization.
6
Notice that even though equilibrium analysis is still feasible for a more general
product variety cost function, in order to obtain closed-form analytical results, we
In the above RS game, we can derive the Subgame Perfect Nash
follow the literature by assuming that the product variety cost function is a quadratic Equilibrium (SPNE) using the standard backward induction tech-
function. nique. This game does not result in a holdup issue because the unit
118 T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124

wholesale price affects the retail price as well as market demand. Proposition 1. The integrated firm uses dual channels if the variety
In addition, we also develop an MS model to explore the effect of  2
cost satisfies g > g ^ I1 or (g ^ I1 and A22  2ft =ð8t2 gÞ
^ I2 < g 6 g
channel leadership structure on the equilibrium channel structure    2 
strategy. A2 þ t= 2nI1 þ g nI1 =2 þ fnI1 > 0); otherwise, the integrated firm
uses only the indirect channel.
3. Equilibrium analysis

To understand the economic force for dual channels, we Proofs of all the propositions are given in the online supplemen-
first consider in this section the channel structure strategy of tary document. Proposition 1 is intuitive, for the integrated firm,
an integrated firm, and then consider the channel structure when the variety cost (f, g) is sufficiently high, the integrated firm
strategy of a manufacturer that sells the standard product has an incentive to add the direct channel to the indirect channel to
through an independent retailer (i.e., a decentralized supply save the variety cost; and when it is sufficiently low, the integrated
chain). firm has no incentive to add the direct channel because the inte-
grated firm can always meet customers’ demand through the indi-
3.1. The optimal decisions of the integrated firm rect channel and dual channels cannot improve its profit. As a
result, we find that with the addition of the direct channel, the
In this subsection the indirect channel is operated by an manufacturer should take the variety cost into consideration in
integrated firm. When the integrated firm only uses the indirect determining whether adding the direct channel decreases product
channel, it decides the retail price and variety to maximize variety depends on the variety cost. Moreover, the variety cost plays
pind (= pM1 + pR1); and when the integrated firm chooses dual an important role in determining the channel structure strategy for
channels, it decides the retail prices and variety to maximize the integrated firm.
pI (= pind + pd = pM2 + pR2). Similar to Balasubramanian (1998) and
Xia and Rajagopalan (2009), we relax the integrality of variety n 3.2. Equilibrium outcome in a decentralized supply chain
to ease the exposition. Since the market is fully covered, the man-
ufacturer would like to raise the retail prices of the standard and In a decentralized supply chain, the players make their deci-
custom products to extract the consumer’s surplus until the sions independently. We first consider the setting in which the
marginal consumer obtains zero surplus.7 Thus, the manufacturer manufacturer only uses the indirect channel; then we consider
always offers the retail price rd of the custom product if the the dual channels setting; finally, we explore the channel structure
manufacturer wants to sell the custom product, i.e., pdI ¼ r d . strategy of the manufacturer by comparing the two settings. Prop-
osition A.1 (Appendix A) summarizes the equilibrium outcome in
Table 1 summarizes the optimal decisions and profits,
    the single indirect channel.
where g ^ I1 ¼ A1 A21  2ft =ð2t 2 Þ; g
^ I2 ¼ A2 A22  2ft =ð2t 2 Þ < g
^ I1 , and
Under the single indirect channel, we have the following find-
nI1 is the unique positive root of 2gn3  2fn2 + t = 0. Here the suffix ings (i) When the variety cost (f, g) is sufficiently low (g 6 g ^ 1 Þ,
I indicates the integrated setting. the manufacturer would like to offer a great product variety to cov-
From Table 1, A1 > A2 > 0 and rd  cd  c > 0, we derive Corollary er the market; otherwise, the manufacturer would only meet part
1. of the demand due to a high cost of variety. (ii) If the market is fully
covered, when the total surplus A1 increases, the retailer raises the
Corollary 1. (i) When the variety cost is sufficiently large ðg > g ^ I1 Þ, margin to share the benefit such that the manufacturer reduces
 
the integrated firm offers a higher retail price, provides a smaller product variety n1 to save the variety cost because the market
product variety, and produces a smaller quantity of the standard has been covered. (iii) However, if the market is not fully covered,
product in dual channels than in the single indirect channel; and (ii) the manufacturer no longer decreases product variety. It is now the
when the variety cost is sufficiently small ðg < g
^ I2 Þ, the integrated firm case where the manufacturer increases product variety. This
offers a higher retail price and provides a greater product variety in happens because the manufacturer can strategically raise price to
dual channels than that in the single indirect channel. attain a higher unit profit and provide a greater variety to attract
consumers when the market is not fully covered. The manufacturer
shares the benefit of the increased total surplus in the indirect
Corollary 1 is intuitive. When the market is not fully covered by channel with the retailer. Thus, they have full incentives to cooper-
the standard product ðg > g ^ I1 Þ, adding the direct channel, the inte- atively raise the total surplus in the indirect channel by decreasing
grated firm can better extract the consumer’s surplus by raising the costs or raising the consumer’s reservation price. (iv) When the fit
retail price, providing less product variety to save the variety cost, cost (t) increases, the profits of the two players decrease because
and attracting some consumers from the indirect channel to the di- this discourages consumers if the market is not covered; if the
rect channel, which decreases the demand for the standard prod- market is covered, the manufacturer’s profit decreases because
uct. Adding the direct channel raises the total market demand, the manufacturer must invest more in variety to cover the whole
i.e., product customization acts as a substitution for variety for market while the retailer’s profit is unchanged.
attracting consumers. However, when the market is fully covered Define A3 = r  cr  rd. Throughout this paper, we shall assume
by the standard product ðg < g ^ I2 Þ, adding the direct channel raises A3 > 0 to ensure that the equilibrium outcome exists. From rd > c,
the product variety in dual channels relative to that in the single we have A1 > A3. For a convenience’s sake, we denote the case where
indirect channel because this increases the difficulty of attracting r < 2cd + cr + rd or where 2cd + cr + rd 6 r < 3cd + cr + rd and
consumers to the indirect channel. pffiffiffi 
cd P 2  1 A3 as Case I, and the case where r P 3cd + cr + rd or
Proposition 1 summarizes the optimal channel structure strat- pffiffiffi 
egy of the integrated firm. where 2cd + cr + rd 6 r < 3cd + cr + rd and cd < 2  1 A3 as Case
II. Observe that Case I refers to the scenario in which the reservation
7
When the manufacturer offers a second-degree discriminatory pricing scheme—a price r is sufficiently low and the marginal selling cost in the direct
scheme under which the manufacturer sets prices for its products, and among all the
product-price pairs, each consumer picks the one that maximizes its surplus (Dewan
channel cd is sufficiently high, whereas Case II refers to the case where
et al., 2003), we find that the retail price of the custom product is also the reservation the reservation price r is sufficiently high and the marginal selling cost
price rd. in the direct channel cd is sufficiently low.
T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124 119

Table 1
The optimal decisions and profits of the vertically integrated firm.

Single indirect channel Dual channels


Cases g > g^ I1 g 6 g^ I1 g > g^ I2 g 6 g^ I2
   
pI 1
2 ðc þ c r þ rÞ
r  t= 2nI1 r  A2/2 r  t= 2nI2
   
nI A21  2ft =ð2t
gÞ nI1 ¼ maxft=A1 ; nI1 g A22  2ft =ð2t gÞ nI2 ¼ maxft=A2 ; nI1 g
   
xI A1 A21  2ft =ð2t2 gÞ 1 A2 A22  2ft =ð2t2 gÞ 1
 2  
pind 2
gðnI1 Þ A22  2ft ð4A1 A2
2
gðnI2 Þ
A21  2ft =ð8t2 gÞ A1  2nt   2 

fnI1 A1  2nt   2

 fnI2
I1 I2
3A22  2ftÞ=ð8t 2 gÞ
pd n/a d  c  cd Þ½1  A2
ðr 0
 A22  2ft =ð2t2 gÞ
pI  2 2  2 2
gðnI1 Þ gðnI2 Þ
A21  2ft =ð8t2 gÞ A1  2nt   2  fnI1

A22  2ft =ð8t 2 gÞ A1  2nt   2

 fnI2
I1 I2
c  cd þ r d
Feasible range f < A21 =ð2tÞ f < A22 =ð2tÞ

Proposition A.2 (Appendix A) summarizes the equilibrium out- Corollary 3. In Case II, if the reservation price r is sufficiently high
comes of these two cases in using dual channels. From Propositions (r > cr  3c + 4rd), the manufacturer charges the retailer a lower unit
A.1 and A.2, we know that, in Case I, when the variety cost is suffi- wholesale price in using dual channels than using the single indirect
ciently high, the retailer offers a lower margin and obtains a lower de- channel; otherwise, it charges a higher unit wholesale price.
mand while the manufacturer charges a higher unit wholesale price
and provides a smaller product variety in using dual channels than Corollary 3 means whether adding the direct channel decreases
using the single indirect channel. Furthermore, we have Corollary 2. the unit wholesale price directly depends on the reservation price.
By adding the direct channel, the manufacturer can decrease prod-
Corollary 2. In Case I: (i) if the reservation price r is sufficiently low uct variety to save the variety cost. On the other hand, when the
and the variety cost is sufficiently high, the effects of the channel marginal selling cost of the custom product cd increases, the man-
structure on the manufacturer’s decisions are similar to those in the ufacturer increases product variety to stimulate the demand for
centralized setting (see Corollary 1); and adding the direct channel the standard product. In Case II, the manufacturer provides a greater
decreases the retailer’s profitability. (ii) Since the manufacturer can product variety in using dual channels than using the single indirect
serve part of consumers through the direct channel, the manufacturer channel if the marginal selling cost of the custom product (cd) is
decreases product variety to reduce the variety cost if VC is sufficiently sufficiently high regardless of VC, which is inconsistent with the
high. (iii) Adding the direct channel raises the unit wholesale price and centralized setting (see Corollary 1). Thus, we can see that the
retail price in the indirect channel if the reservation price r is decentralization of the supply chain may invert the effect of channel
sufficiently low, i.e., enhancing the double marginalization effect. structure on product variety.
The custom product can substitute for the standard product
such that adding the direct channel negatively influences the de-
Notice that the finding of Corollary 2(iii) is different from that in mand for the standard product in the indirect channel. On the
Chiang et al. (2003), who claimed that the wholesale and retail other hand, the market demand for the standard product positively
prices are always lower when the manufacturer uses dual channels depends on product variety. Moreover, adding the direct channel
than when it relies only on retail distribution. Specifically, in Case I, may decrease the unit wholesale price and the retailer’s margin
the arbitrage constraint w 6 pd is nonbinding such that the nega- of the standard product, which increases the market demand due
tive effect of this constraint on the unit wholesale price does not to a lower retail price. As a result, when the variety cost is suffi-
exist. Note that the retailer extracts most of the total surplus of ciently high ðg > maxfg ^1; g
^ 22 gÞ, adding the direct channel raises
the indirect channel, and the reservation price for the direct chan- the demand for the standard product if the marginal selling cost
nel relative to the indirect channel is not too low. Moreover, the of the custom product is very high ðcd > ^cd1 Þ. From Proposition
customization avoids the consumer’s fit cost (trip cost), which in- A.2 and Table 1, it is clear that in using dual channels, the inte-
creases market demand for the direct channel and decreases that grated firm offers a lower retail price and produces a larger quan-
for the retailer. As a result, the manufacturer transfers some con- tity of the standard product than in the decentralized supply chain;
sumers from the indirect channel to the direct channel through and the product variety of the integrated firm is greater than that
raising the unit wholesale price. in the decentralized supply chain. That is, decentralization raises
In Case II, when the variety cost is sufficiently high, although the retail price of the standard product due to the double margin-
adding the direct channel decreases the retailer’s margin, the re- alization effect and decreases product variety because the manu-
sults on the unit wholesale price, product variety, and market de- facturer only reaps part of the benefit from increasing product
mand depend on the values of the parameters as summarized in variety, which decreases the demand for the standard product.
Proposition A.3 (Appendix A). Notice that in Case II, on one hand, Proposition 2 summarizes the conditions under which the man-
adding the direct channel can raise the control of the manufac- ufacturer uses dual channels.
turer over the unit wholesale price due to product customization
in the direct channel. On the other hand, the relative profitability Proposition 2. (i) In Case I, the manufacturer uses dual channels if
of the indirect channel to the direct channel is high and the unit g > g^ 1 ; and (ii) in Case II, the manufacturer uses dual channels if
wholesale price constraint w 6 rd in dual channels is binding such 2rd + cr  c < r < 4rd  3c + cr and g 6 minfg
^1 ; g
^ 22 g.
that the manufacturer leaves more profit to the retailer to prevent
the retailer from switching purchases to the direct channel. The From Propositions 1 and 2, we know that the results on the
higher the reservation price r is, the higher the relative profitabil- channel structure strategy in the decentralized setting may be
ity of the indirect channel will be. As a consequence, we have different from those in the integrated setting. Specifically, the man-
Corollary 3. ufacturer may have an incentive to use dual channels even when
120 T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124

the variety cost is sufficiently low ðg 6 minfg


^1; g
^ 22 gÞ, which differs M
from the findings in Proposition 1 because the manufacturer can 4.4
reduce the retailer’s profit margin by adding the direct channel.
Proposition 2(ii) implies that dual channels for the manufac-
M1
turer may be better than the single indirect channel even when 4.2
there is no demand for the direct channel because adding the direct
channel decreases the retailer’s profit margin. This finding is con-
sistent with that in Chiang et al. (2003). 4.0
M2

Proposition 3. A higher unit production cost c or marginal selling


cost cd decreases the manufacturer’s motivation to use dual channels. 3.8

From Proposition 3, we know that when the unit production


cr
cost increases, the manufacturer has a weaker incentive to use dual 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0
channels. Specifically, when the unit production cost c increases,
the manufacturer’s profit decreases regardless of the channel Fig. 2. Manufacturer’s profit versus marginal selling cost for the standard product.
structure strategy. However, the negative effect of the higher unit
production cost on the manufacturer’s profit in using the single
M
indirect channel is smaller than that in using dual channels be- 4.5
cause the total demand in dual channels is higher than that in
the single indirect channel. This explains why the manufacturer 4.0
has a higher incentive to use dual channels when th unit produc- M2

tion cost decreases. When the marginal selling cost cd increases, 3.5
the demand for the standard product increases, which raises the
3.0
manufacturer’s profitability; on the other hand, the demand for
the custom product decreases and the variety cost increases due 2.5 M1
to a greater product variety, which decreases the manufacturer’s
profitability. Moreover, if the marginal selling cost of the custom 2.0
product cd increases, the manufacturer’s profitability in using the
1.5
direct channel will decrease. As a consequence, the manufacturer’s
profit in using dual channels decreases with the marginal selling r
cost cd because its negative effect outweighs its positive effect, 28 30 32 34
which further decreases the manufacturer’s motivation to use dual
channels. Theorem 1 below summarizes the core insights from the Fig. 3. Manufacturer’s profit versus reservation price for the standard product.

above discussions.
M
Theorem 1. (a) The effect of channel structure on product variety
may be inverted by the supply chain decentralization. (b) When the
5.5
variety cost is sufficiently low: the decentralization of indirect channel M1

may invert the manufacturer’s equilibrium channel structure strategy,


5.0
i.e., decentralization raises the motivation of using dual channels. (c) It
is more likely for the manufacturer with either a low unit production
4.5
cost or low marginal selling cost for the direct channel to use dual
channels. M2
4.0
Figs. 2–4 illustrate how the manufacturer’s profit depends on
some of the key parameters, the default values of which are as 3.5
follows:
t
c ¼ 5; cd ¼ 2; cr ¼ 3; f ¼ 0:1; r ¼ 34; r d ¼ 10; t ¼ 20; 12 14 16 18 20 22 24
and g ¼ 2:
Fig. 4. Manufacturer’s profit versus the fit cost.
In Figs. 2–4, the fine curve represents the manufacturer’s profit in
 
using the single indirect channel pM1 and the thick curve
  repre-
sents the manufacturer’s profit in using dual channels pM2 . to use dual channels decreases with the reservation price of
From Fig. 2, we know that a higher marginal selling cost of the standard product.
the standard product cr raises the incentive for the manufacturer Fig. 4 implies that a higher fit cost t strengthens the manufac-
to use dual channels due to a lower unit wholesale price in turer’s motivation to use dual channels. Specifically, if the market
using the single indirect channel. Fig. 3 indicates that a higher is fully covered by the standard product, the manufacturer in-
reservation price r weakens the manufacturer’s motivation to use creases product variety to cover the market as fit cost t increases;
dual channels. To be specific, when the reservation price r in- otherwise, the manufacturer reduces product variety to save the
creases, the manufacturer increases product variety to stimulate variety cost because it is more difficult to stimulate demand by
the demand for the standard product in using dual channels. increasing product variety. If the market is fully covered by the
However, in using the single indirect channel, the manufacturer standard product, the manufacturer offers a greater product vari-
can raise the unit wholesale price to extract the consumer’s sur- ety to react to the increased fit cost in using the single indirect
plus, which further induces a greater product variety to stimu- channel than using dual channels because adding the direct chan-
late demand. As a consequence, the manufacturer’s motivation nel decreases the retail price of the standard product, which means
T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124 121

that using dual channels reduces the increased variety cost. If the When the market is partially covered, the effects of the
market is not fully covered by the standard product, the demand parameters on the equilibrium outcomes and profits are similar
advantage of using the single indirect channel over dual channels to those under the RS model. When the market is fully covered
decreases with the fit cost due to a smaller variety difference. As and n32 > 2t/A1, we find that product variety decreases with the
a consequence, the manufacturer has a stronger incentive to use variety cost factors (g, f) and is independent of the total surplus
dual channels as the fit cost increases. In other words, it is more of the indirect channel (r  c  cr), which differs from the RS mod-
likely for a manufacturer to use dual channels when consumers are el. If n32 6 2t/A1, the product varieties under the two models are
very sensitive to product differentiation. identical when the market is fully covered. Furthermore, from
Proposition 4 addresses the issue of whether adding the direct Proposition A.1 and Table 2, we see that the manufacturer charges
channel harms the retailer. a higher unit wholesale price and achieves a higher profit under
the MS model than under the RS model. When the market is fully
Proposition 4. (i) In Case I, adding the direct channel is detrimental covered, the retailer makes a smaller profit under the MS model
to the retailer; (ii) in Case II, adding the direct channel is not than under the RS model. That is, there exists a first-mover advan-
detrimental to the retailer if and only if (a) g
^1 < g 6 g
^ 22 and r d < ^rd1 tage for the retailer (Choi and Fredj, 2013). However, when the
or (b) g > maxfg ^1 ; g
^ 22 g and cd P ^cd2 , where ^r d1 ¼ r  cr  market is partially covered, the first-mover advantage no longer
     
A21 A21  8ft =ð16t 2 gÞ and ^cd2 ¼ A21 A21  8ft = 16A33 þ ft=A3 ; (iii) exists for the retailer. It is now the case where the retailer can
counter-intuitively gain a higher profit due to a higher demand un-
In Case II, the Pareto range over which the two players are better off der the MS model than under the RS model. We summarize the
using dual channels is non-empty. core insights in Theorem 2.
Proposition 4 states that adding the direct channel may reduce
the equilibrium profit of the retailer due to reduced demand for the Theorem 2. (a) In the single indirect channel setting, channel
standard product or a lower profit margin. However, under some leadership plays an important role in determining product variety if
conditions, adding the direct channel is beneficial to the retailer be- the variety cost is sufficiently low; otherwise, the effect of channel
cause the retailer can secure a higher profit margin or obtain a leadership on product variety is small. (b) Whether the retailer has an
higher demand. Thus, the retailer may encourage the manufacturer incentive to act as a leader depends on whether the market is fully
to add the direct channel because this action raises the retailer’s covered in the single indirect channel setting.
profit. This argument is consistent with Tsay and Agrawal (2004),
who found that given the retail price, the addition of a direct chan- When the manufacturer uses dual channels, the marginal con-
nel alongside an indirect (reseller) channel is not necessarily detri- sumer is indifferent between the standard and custom products,
mental to the reseller. Proposition 4(iii) means that the dual i.e., r  p  tx/(2n) = rd  pd P 0. Thus, in using dual channels, the
channel structure for the two players may Pareto dominate the sin- demand for the standard product is x4 = 2n(pd  p + r  rd)/t. Fur-
gle indirect channel in Case II. Thus, they may have an incentive to thermore, the retailer’s profit is
collaborate with each other to add the direct channel. pR4 ¼ 2nðpd  p þ r  rd Þðp  w  cr Þ=t
4. Robustness of the channel structure strategy and the manufacturer’s profit is
pM4 ¼ 2nðpd  p þ r  rd Þðw  cÞ=t þ ½1  2nðpd  p þ r  rd Þ=t
In this section, based on the basic model, we develop two alter-
 ðpd  c  cd Þ  gn2 =2  nf :
native models to examine the robustness of the channel structure
strategy to channel leadership and exogenization of product vari- Solving the first-order condition @ pR4/@p = 0 for p, we have
ety by comparing them with the basic model. Alternative model p4 = (cr + pd + r  rd + w)/2. Substituting p4 into x4, we have
1 assumes that the manufacturer acts as the Stackelberg pricing x4(w) = n(r  cr + pd  rd  w)/t. When the constraint x4(w) 6 1 is
leader and the retailer is the follower, and alternative model 2 satisfied, inserting p4 into pM4, we obtain the manufacturer’s profit
assumes that the product variety level is exogenously set. pM4(n, pd, w). Differentiating pM4(n, pd, w) with respect to w yields
the first-order condition
4.1. Channel leadership
Solving it for w, we have w(pd) = pd + (r  cd  cr  rd)/2. If
r < cd + cr + rd, we have w(pd) < pd, so the unit wholesale price reac-
We have considered the RS model where the retailer is the pricing
tion is w4(pd) = w(pd). If r P cd + cr + rd, the constraint w(pd) 6 pd is
leader and the manufacturer is the follower. How does the channel
binding such that the unit wholesale price reaction is w4(pd) = pd.
leadership structure (i.e., sequence of decisions) affect the manufac-
Considering the unit wholesale price of the standard product in
turer’s equilibrium channel structure strategy? To address this issue,
using the indirect channel, the manufacturer determines (n, pd) to
we consider an MS model in which the manufacturer is the Stackel-
maximize pM4(n, pd, w4 (pd)). We can show that pM4(n, pd, w4(pd))
berg leader. Specifically, in the first stage, the manufacturer first de-
cides whether to engage in direct sales, and then determines the
Table 2
product variety n, unit wholesale price w of the standard product, Equilibrium outcomes and profits when only using the indirect channel.
and price pd of the custom product (if the manufacturer opens the di-
rect channel). In the second stage, the retailer determines the retail g > g^ 3 (Partially covered, g 6 g^ 3 (Fully covered, j = 2)
j = 1)
price p of the standard product.
For the sake of convenience, in this subsection we use the first n3j ðA21  4ftÞ=ð4t gÞ n32 ¼ maxfn32 ; 2t=A1 g
w3j (c + r  cr)/2 r  cr  t=n32
number suffix 3 to represent the case of using the single indirect  
p3j (c + cr + 3r)/4 r  t= 2n32
channel and 4 to represent the case of using dual channels. We first  
x3j A1 A21  4ft =ð8t 2 gÞ 1
consider the case where the manufacturer only uses the indirect
pM3j  2  2
channel. The market demand is given by Eq. (1). The retailer’s A21  4ft =ð32t2 gÞ A1  t=n32  g n32 =2  n32 f
profit is pR3 = x1  (p  w  cr) and the manufacturer’s profit is pR3j
    
A21 A21  4ft =ð32t2 gÞ t= 2n32
pM3 = (w  c)x1  gn2/2  nf. Table 2 summarizes the equilibrium
outcomes and profits, where n32 is the unique positive root of Feasible f < A21 =ð4tÞ
  range
t  gn3  fn2 = 0, and g^ 3 ¼ A1 A21  4ft =ð8t 2 Þ.
122 T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124

is an increasing function of pd and a concave function of n. Similar the main incentives for the manufacturer to use dual channels is to
to the RS model, the manufacturer has no incentive to use dual strengthen its bargaining power in the indirect channel. When the
channels if pd > rd. Thus, the manufacturer will offer the direct manufacturer is the leader, the incentive of the manufacturer to
channel price pd4 ¼ r d in using dual channels. Table 3 summarizes strengthen its bargaining power via adding the direct channel is
 
the equilibrium outcomes and profits, where g ^ 41 ¼ A2 A22  4ft = weaker. That is, the channel leadership advantage of the retailer gives
the manufacturer a stronger incentive to use dual channels.
ð8t 2 Þ < g ^ 42 ¼ A3 ðcd A3  ftÞ=t 2 ¼ g
^ 3 and g ^ 22 .
From Proposition A.2 and Table 3, we observe that in using dual 4.2. Exogenization of product variety
channels, the effects of the parameters on the equilibrium outcomes
and profits are similar to those under the RS model. However, the We have considered the endogenous variety setting and we
range over which the unit wholesale price is lower than the direct now investigate how the exogenization of product variety affects
channel price is smaller than that under the RS model. If the reserva- the optimal channel structure strategy. From Proposition A.1 and
tion price r of the standard product is sufficiently large, the equilib- A.2, we derive Proposition A.4 (Appendix A). We find that if the res-
rium outcomes are identical under both the RS and MS models. If the ervation price r is sufficiently low, the manufacturer prefers dual
reservation price of the standard product is sufficiently low (r < cd + - channels to the single indirect channel because adding the direct
cr + rd), the unit wholesale price and retail price in using dual chan- channel can attract more consumers or reduce the retailer’s profit
nels are higher than using the single indirect channel. This result is margin, regardless of product variety. However, in the endogenous
different from Chiang et al. (2003). However, it is consistent with variety setting, if the variety cost (g) is sufficiently low, this result
that under the RS model. Hence, we argue that the channel leadership is no longer valid. Now, the manufacturer has no incentive to use
is not one of the major factors that account for this difference (in the ef- dual channels. Here, the insight is summarized in Theorem 3:
fect of channel structure on prices) but customization in using the direct
channel is the major factor. Theorem 3. (i) The endogenization of product variety inverts the
Similar to Propositions 1 and 2, we derive the following. manufacturer’s channel structure strategy if the reservation price of
the standard product and the variety cost are sufficiently low. (ii) If the
Proposition 5. Under the MS model, we have: (i) when r < cd + cr + rd, reservation price r is sufficiently low, the retailer may object to the
the manufacturer chooses dual channels if and only if g > g ^3, addition of the direct channel because adding the direct channel harms
 2
or g^ 41 < g 6 g
^ 3 and A22  4ft =ð32t2 gÞ  A2 þ t=n32 þ n32 f þ the retailer through reducing the retailer’s profit margin or demand.
  2 In the exogenous variety setting, if the reservation price r is suffi-
g n32 =2 > 0; and (ii) when r P cd + cr + rd, the manufacturer ciently high, the manufacturer’s motivation to use dual channels de-
chooses dual channels if g 6 minfg ^3 ; g
^ 42 g; A1 < 2A3 , and n32 < t/A3. pends on product variety, i.e., product variety plays an important
role in making the channel structure decision. Specifically, if product
Comparing Propositions 1, 2, and 5, we find that the qualitative variety is sufficiently high (n P max{t/A3, 2t/A1}), a higher product
results on the channel structure strategy are robust to the relative variety will increase the manufacturer’s motivation to use dual
channel leadership of the players. Similar to Proposition 3, we can channels due to a lower unit wholesale price in using the
show that a higher marginal selling cost cd decreases the manufac- single indirect channel. However, if product variety satisfies
turer’s motivation to use dual channels. t/A3 6 n < 2t/A1, a greater product variety weakens the manufac-
From Propositions 2 and 5, we see that if g > g ^ 3 ð> g
^ 1 Þ and turer’s motivation to use dual channels due to a higher gross profit
r < cd + cr + rd, the manufacturer uses dual channels under both excluding the variety cost in using the single indirect channel. If
the RS and MS models; and if g > maxfg ^3 ; g
^ 42 gðP maxfg ^1; g^ 22 gÞ product variety is sufficiently small (n < t/A3), the manufacturer
2 2 chooses dual channels only if the marginal selling cost in using
and r P 3cd + cr + rd, we can show ½ðcd A3  ftÞ  ðA21  8ftÞ =64
2 2 the direct channel cd is sufficiently low due to a high profitability
=ð2t 2 gÞ > ½ðcd A3  ftÞ  ðA21  4ftÞ =16=ð2t2 gÞ, which implies Cor- for the direct channel. Here, we have Theorem 4.
ollary 4.
Theorem 4. The monotonicity of the manufacturer’s motivation to
Corollary 4. The manufacturer has a stronger incentive to use dual using dual channels in product variety depends on product variety,
channels under the RS model than the MS model if the variety cost is and the reservation price or costs in the direct channel.
sufficiently large.
5. Conclusions
We can explain Corollary 4 as follows: when the retailer is the
leader, the retailer extracts most of the profit in the indirect chan- With the emergence of e-commerce, the dual channel distribu-
nel, which decreases the manufacturer’s profitability. Thus, one of tion structure is becoming an important channel structure strategy
Table 3
Equilibrium outcomes and profits when using dual channels.

r < cd + cr + rd (j = 1) r P cd + cr + rd (j = 2)

g > g^ 41 g 6 g^ 41 g > g^ 42 g 6 g^ 42
 
n4j A22  4ft =ð4tgÞ n41 ¼ maxfn32 ; 2t=A2 g (cdA3  ft)/(tg) n42 ¼ maxfn32 ; t=A3 g

w4j (r  cr + rd  cd)/2 r cr  t=n41 rd r  cr  t=n42


 
p4j r  A2/4 r t=ð2n41 Þ (cr + r + rd)/2 r  t= 2n42
 
x4j A2 A22  4ft =ð8t 2 gÞ 1 A3(cdA3  ft)/(t2g) 1

p  2  2 2  
M4j ðA22  4ftÞ t g n41 ðcd A3  ftÞ t g n42 2
 c  cd þ r d A1    n41 f  c  cd þ r d A1    n42 f
32t2 g n41 2 2t 2 g n 2
      42
pR4j 2 2
A2 A2  4ft =ð32t2 gÞ t= 2n41 A23 ðcd A3  ftÞ=ð2t 2 gÞ t= 2n42

Feasible range f < A22 =ð4tÞ f < cdA3/t


T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124 123

for manufacturers. Owing to the development of economy and Acknowledgements


technology, consumer’s needs for product variety and customiza-
tion increase such that product variety and customization are We would like to thank the two anonymous referees for their
becoming important competing dimensions. We develop an RS helpful suggestions and insightful comments, which have signifi-
model of a one-manufacturer and one-retailer two-echelon supply cantly improved the presentation of this paper. Tiaojun Xiao’s re-
chain to investigate the interactions between product variety and search was supported in part by the National Natural Science
channel structure strategy for a manufacturer in the case where Foundation of China under Grants 71371093, 70971060 and
the manufacturer sells a custom product via the direct channel. 71071073. Tsan-Ming Choi’s research was supported partially by
We also develop two alternative models to examine the robustness the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong, under Grant No. PolyU
of the channel structure strategy to channel leadership and exoge- 5424/11H.
nization of product variety.
In the basic model, namely the RS model, the retailer is the Appendix A. Technical notes
pricing leader and the manufacturer is the pricing follower. We
give the equilibrium outcomes and profits in the single indirect
and dual channel settings, and find that when the variety cost Proposition A.1. Assume f < A21 =ð8tÞ. When the manufacturer only
is sufficiently large, the integrated firm provides a smaller prod- uses the indirect channel, the unique SPNE and the respective decisions
uct variety in dual channels than in the single indirect channel; are given as follows: (i) the SPNE market demand is
otherwise, the integrated firm provides a greater product variety ( 
A1 A21  8ft ; Þ=ð16t 2 gÞ; if g > g^1
in dual channels. The decentralization of the supply chain may in- x1 ¼ (ii) the SPNE variety is
vert the effect of channel structure on product variety. Unlike 1; if g 6 g
^1
( 
Chiang et al. (2003), adding the direct channel enhances the dou- A21  8ft =ð8t gÞ; if g > g ^1
n1 ¼ ; the SPNE margin is
ble marginalization effect due to customization in using the direct 2t=A1 ; if g 6 g
^1
channel if the reservation price r is sufficiently low. When the  
m1 ¼ cr þ A1 =2, and the SPNE unit wholesale price is w1 ¼ c þ A1 =4;
variety cost is sufficiently high and the reservation price of the and (iii) the SPNE profits of the two players are
standard product is sufficiently low, the manufacturer would like 8 2
to use dual channels. In addition, we find that the manufacturer’s >
< A21  8ft =ð128t 2 gÞ; if g > g
^1
motivation to use dual channels decreases with the unit produc- pM1 ¼ and
tion cost, the reservation price of the standard product, and the >
: A1  2ft  2t22g ; if g 6 g
^1
4 A1 A1
marginal selling cost in using the direct channel, while increases ( 2 2 
with the marginal selling cost of the retailer and the fit cost. The A1 A1  8ft =ð32t 2 gÞ; if g > g
^1
pR1 ¼ ;
decentralization of the indirect channel may invert the channel A1 =2; if g 6 g
^1
structure strategy for the manufacturer if the variety cost is suf-
ficiently low. We give the conditions under which the dual chan-  
nels structure for the retailer dominates the single indirect where g^ 1 ¼ A1 A21  8ft =ð16t 2 Þ. P.S.: The assumption f < A21 =ð8tÞ en-
channel structure. sures that the equilibrium outcome is feasible.
Comparing the MS model with the RS model, we find that in the
n o
single indirect channel setting, channel leadership (and hence se-
Proposition A.2. Assume f < min A22 =ð8tÞ; cd A3 =t . In using dual
quence of decisions in the supply chain) plays an important role channels, we have pd2 ¼ r d and:
in determining product variety if and only if the variety cost is suf-
ficiently low; and whether the retailer has an incentive to act as a (i) For Case I, the SPNE decisions are: m2 ¼ cr þ A2 =2;
pricing leader depends on whether the market is fully covered. The
w2 ¼ ½r  cr þ 3ðr d  cd Þ=4, and
manufacturer has a stronger incentive to use dual channels under ( 
the RS model than the MS model if the variety cost is sufficiently A22  8ft =ð8tgÞ; if g > g ^ 21
n2 ¼ ; the SPNE demand for
large because adding the direct channel serves as a means for the 2t=A2 ; if g 6 g
^ 21
manufacturer to strengthen its power over the retailer. In the exog- the standard product is
(  
enous variety model, we give the variety range over which the 2
A2 A2  8ft =ð16t2 gÞ; if g > g^ 21 ; and the SPNE profits are
x2 ¼
manufacturer would like to use dual channels and find that 1; if g 6 g
^ 21
whether a greater product variety weakens the manufacturer’s 8 2
< A2  8ft =ð128gt 2 Þ  c  cd þ r d ; if g > g^ 21
motivation to use dual channels depends on the product variety pM2 ¼
2
and
: A2  2ft  2t2 g  c  cd þ r d ; if g 6 g^ 21
and reservation price of the standard product. Product variety 4 A2 A22
influences the channel structure strategy and the retailer prefers (  
A22 A22  8ft =ð32t 2 gÞ; if g > g^ 21 ;
collaborating with the manufacturer in adding the direct channel pR2 ¼ where g^ 21 ¼
A2 =2; if g 6 g^ 21
only when the reservation price of the standard product is suffi-  
ciently high. We find that endogenizing product variety inverts A2 A22  8ft =ð16t2 Þ;
the channel structure strategy of the manufacturer if the reserva- (ii) For Case II, the SPNE decisions are: m2 ¼ ðcr þ r  r d Þ=2;

tion price of the standard product and the variety cost are suffi- ðcd A3  ftÞ=ðtgÞ; if g > g ^ 22
w2 ¼ rd , and n2 ¼ ; the SPNE
ciently low. t=A3 ; if g 6 g
^ 22
In this paper we assume that the direct channel can customize demand for the standard product is

the whole circular spatial market. In reality, the manufacturer may  A3 ðcd A3  ftÞ=ðt 2 gÞ; if g > g ^ 22
x2 ¼ ; and the SPNE profits
only customize a part of the market. Thus, considering the custom- 1; if g 6 g ^ 22
(
ization range is an interesting topic for future research (Dewan 2
ðcd A3  ftÞ =ð2t2 gÞ c  cd þ rd ; if g > g ^ 22
et al., 2003). We assume that the variety cost is independent of are pM2 ¼ 2 2 and
r d  c  tf =A3  t g= 2A3 ; if g 6 g ^ 22
the demand for the standard product. Future research may relax  2
2
this assumption to examine the robustness of the channel struc- pR2 ¼ A3 ðcd A3  ftÞ=ð2t gÞ; if g > g^^22 , where g^ 22 ¼
ture strategy to cost structure by making use of information A3 =2; if g 6 g22
technology. A3 ðcd A3  ftÞ=t2 .
124 T. Xiao et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 233 (2014) 114–124

Proposition A.3. Assume f < minfA22 =ð8tÞ; cd A3 =tg. In Case II, adding Dewan, R., Jing, B., & Seidmann, A. (2003). Product customization and price
competition on the internet. Management Science, 49(8), 1055–1070.
the direct channel: (i) decreases the unit wholesale price if and only if
Dumrongsiri, A., Fan, M., Jain, A., & Moinzadeh, K. (2008). A supply chain model with
r > cr  3c + 4rd; (ii) when g > maxfg ^1; g
^ 22 g, increases the product direct and retail channels. European Journal of Operational Research, 187(3),
variety of the standard product if cd > A21 =ð8A3 Þ and increases the 691–718.
Edirisinghe, N. C. P., Bichescu, B., & Shi, X. (2011). Equilibrium analysis of supply
market demand for the standard product if cd > ^cd1 ¼ chain structures under power imbalance. European Journal of Operational
 
Research, 214, 568–578.
A1 ðA21  8ftÞ= 16A23 þ ft=A3 ; (iii) when g 6 minfg ^1; g
^ 22 g or
Fisher, M. L., & Ittner, C. D. (1999). The impact of product variety on automobile
g^ 1 < g 6 g^ 22 , increases the product variety of the standard product assembly operations: Empirical evidence and simulation analysis. Management
Science, 45(6), 771–786.
if cd > A3; and (iv) when g ^ 22 < g 6 g
^ 1 , increases the product variety
Gaur, V., & Honhon, D. (2006). Assortment planning and inventory decisions under a
of the standard product if cd > ft/A3 + 2t2g/(A1A3). locational choice model. Management Science, 52(10), 1528–1543.
Gerchak, Y., & Wang, Y. (2004). Revenue-sharing vs. wholesale-price contracts in
assembly systems with random demand. Production and Operations
Proposition A.4. In the exogenous product variety setting, we have: Management, 13(1), 23–33.
Geylani, T., Dukes, A. J., & Srinivasan, K. (2007). Strategic manufacturer response to a
dominant retailer. Marketing Science, 26(2), 164–178.
(i) In Case I, the manufacturer would like to use dual channels and Gupta, S. (2008). Channel structure with knowledge spillovers. Marketing Science,
adding the direct channel reduces the retailer’s benefit, regard- 27(2), 247–261.
less of product variety; Hendrikse, G., & Jiang, T. (2011). An incomplete contracting model of dual
distribution in franchising. Journal of Retailing, 87(3), 332–344.
(ii) In Case II, (a) the manufacturer uses dual channels if (n P max Hoffman, D. L., & Novak, T. P. (1996). Marketing in hypermedia computer-mediated
{t/A3, 2t/A1} and n > t/[2(rd  c)]), (n < min {t/A3), (2t/A1} and environments: Conceptual foundations. Journal of Marketing, 60(3), 50–68.
cd < ^cd3 ), (2t=A1 6 n < t=A3 and cd < ^cd4 ) or (t/A3 6 n < 2t/A1 Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. Economic Journal, 39(153),
41–57.
and r d > c þ nA21 =ð8tÞ); and (b) adding the direct channel does Kadiyali, V., Vilcassim, N., & Chintagunta, P. (1999). Product line extensions and
not reduce the retailer’s benefit if and only if (c > ^c1 and competitive market interactions: An empirical analysis. Journal of Econometrics,
n < min {t/A3, 2t/A1}) or (t/A3 6 n < 2t/A1 and n < 2tA3 =A21 Þ, 89(March/April), 339–364.
Laudon, K. C., & Laudon, J. P. (2002). Management information systems – Managing the
where ^cd3 ¼ ½r d  c  nA21 =ð8tÞ  ffiffiffinA3 =tÞ; ^cd4 ¼ ½rd  c  t=
pffiffiffi =ð1 p digital firm (7th ed.). Prentice Hall (pp. 130).
ð2nÞ=ð1 nA3 =tÞ and ^c1 ¼ 2r d  ð 2  1Þ ðr  cr Þ. Matsubayashi, N., Ishii, Y., Watanabe, K., & Yamada, Y. (2009). Full-line or
specialization strategy? The negative effect of product variety on product line
strategy. European Journal of Operational Research, 196(2), 795–807.
Appendix B. Supplementary material Mendelson, H., & Parlaktürk, A. K. (2008). Competitive customization.
Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 10(3), 377–390.
Mukhopadhyay, S. K., Zhu, X., & Yue, X. (2008). Optimal contract design for mixed
Supplementary data associated with this article can be found, in channels under information asymmetry. Production and Operations
the online version, at http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2013.08.038. Management, 17(6), 641–650.
Pan, K. W., Lai, K. K., Leung, S. C. H., & Xiao, D. (2010). Revenue-sharing versus
wholesale price mechanisms under different channel power structures.
References European Journal of Operational Research, 203, 532–538.
Randall, T., & Ulrich, K. (2001). Product variety, supply chain structure, and firm
Balasubramanian, S. (1998). Mail versus mall: A strategic analysis of competition performance: Analysis of the U.S. bicycle industry. Management Science, 47(12),
between direct marketers and conventional retailers. Marketing Science, 17(3), 1588–1604.
181–195. Salop, S. C. (1979). Monopolistic competition with outside goods. The Bell Journal of
Bernstein, F., Song, J. S., & Zheng, X. (2008). Bricks-and-mortar’’ vs. ‘‘clicks and Economics, 10(1), 141–156.
mortar’’ an equilibrium analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, Soberman, D. A., & Parker, P. M. (2006). The economics of quality-equivalent store
187(3), 671–690. brands. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 23(2), 125–139.
Brohan, M. (2011). What this year’s top 500 numbers really mean. Internet Retailer Sudhir, K. (2001). Structural analysis of manufacturer pricing in the presence of a
May 3. strategic retailer. Marketing Science, 20(3), 244–264.
Cattani, K., Gilland, W., Heese, H. S., & Swaminathan, J. (2006). Boiling frogs: Pricing Thonemann, U. W., & Bradley, J. R. (2002). The effect of product variety on supply-
strategies for a manufacturer adding a direct channel that competes with the chain performance. European Journal of Operational Research, 143, 548–569.
traditional channel. Production and Operations Management, 15(1), 40–56. Trivedi, M. (1998). Distribution channels: An extension of exclusive retailership.
Chiang, W. K., Chhajed, D., & Hess, J. D. (2003). Direct marketing, indirect profits: A Management Science, 44(7), 896–909.
strategic analysis of dual-channel supply-chain design. Management Science, Tsay, A. A., & Agrawal, N. (2004). Channel conflict and coordination in the e-
49(1), 1–20. commerce age. Production and Operations Management, 13(1), 93–110.
Choi, T. M., Li, Y., Xu, L. (2013). Channel leadership, performance and coordination in Wang, X., & Liu, L. (2007). Coordination in a retailer-led supply chain through option
closed loop supply chains. International Journal of Production Economics. doi: contract. International Journal of Production Economics, 110(1–2), 115–127.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2013.08.002 (published online). Wilder, C. (1999). HP’s online push. Information Week, May 31.
Choi, S., & Fredj, K. (2013). Price competition and store competition: Store brand vs. Xia, N., & Rajagopalan, S. (2009). Standard vs. custom products: Variety, leadtime,
national brand. European Journal of Operational Research, 225, 166–178. and price competition. Marketing Science, 28(5), 887–900.
Dekimpe, M. G., Gielens, K., Raju, J., & Thomas, J. S. (2011). Strategic assortment Xia, N., & Rajagopalan, S. (2012). Product variety, pricing and differentiation in a
decisions in information-intensive and turbulent environments. Journal of supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 217(1), 84–93.
Retailing, 87(Supplement 1), S17–S28.

You might also like