Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 12

Int. J.

Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Int. J. Production Economics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ijpe

Price and service competition between new and remanufactured products


in a two-echelon supply chain
Cheng-Han Wu *
Department of Industrial Engineering and Management, National Yunlin University of Science and Technology, Yunlin 64002, Taiwan, ROC

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: In this paper, we consider a supply chain consisting of two manufacturers and a retailer. The first
Received 4 July 2011 manufacturer is a traditional manufacturer that produces the new product, while the second
Accepted 27 June 2012 manufacturer operates a reverse channel producing remanufactured products from used cores. Both
Available online 5 July 2012
manufacturers bundle their products with services, including warranty and advertisement, and they
Keywords: sell through the same retailer, which independently determines the sales prices. We assume that the
Game theory second manufacturer invests extra effort in facilitating the remanufacturing process. In this study, we
Pricing identify the equilibrium characteristics with respect to the remanufacturer’s effort and price and
Remanufacturing service decisions for all members of the supply chain. We also investigate the profits of chain members
Service
by considering different interactions between prices and service. Based on the theoretical and
Supply chain management
numerical analyses, we derive economic and managerial insights for chain members.
& 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction performing well and can substitute new products at lower prices, and
it also provides warranty and service for the remanufactured pro-
Remanufacturing is the process whereby some components of ducts. Thus far, not all HP’s competitors have followed suit, and
used products are disassembled, cleaned, reprocessed, inspected, therefore, the consumers must choose between remanufactured and
and then reassembled to be used again. Consumer awareness, new products based on product information of prices and service
oversight from non-governmental organizations, and legislative offerings. In the context of this business model, a comparative
pressures have encouraged manufacturers to produce green and investigation of price and service for new versus remanufactured
eco-friendly products, and thus, more and more manufacturers now products is useful for manufacturers as well as retailers, as it should
build reverse channels to recycle used products for remanufacturing. provide valuable insights into the interactions between price and
However, rather than environmental concerns, the economic bene- service, sales decisions, and performance.
fits that accompany remanufacturing is the main consideration for To the best of our knowledge, all the previous studies examin-
manufacturers. Because of decrements in the costs associated with ing remanufacturing are models that only consider the remanu-
raw material production, a remanufacturing system provides an factured product while ignoring the competition, or they are
opportunity to reduce not only the environmental burden but also competitive models with a single price attribute. In this study,
production costs. According to a recent report by Global Industry we incorporate the competitive nature of products and service
Analysts (2010), global automotive manufacturing is growing, and into our supply chain model of a common retailer and two
by 2015, it is forecasted to reach US$104.8 billion. Such a strong manufacturers. One manufacturer produces the new product,
growth in remanufacturing is also present in other industries, such and the other produces the remanufactured product under the
as toner and inkjet cartridges, electrical equipments, consumer framework of product competition. In our model, we analyze the
electronics, and furniture (Hauser and Lund, 2008). effects of competition, and thus, we consider four competitive
In practice, it is important for manufacturers to adjust their sales interactions: the presence of price and service competition, price
strategies in response to the introduction of remanufacturing. For competition only, and service competition only as well as the
instance, the large personal computer manufacturer, HP Inc., has absence of both price and service competition. Note that the
adopted a remanufacturing program called ‘‘HP Renew Program’’ for interaction with both price and service competition can be
recycling and selling the remanufactured or refurbished products. Its viewed as a general model such that the demand functions, chain
remanufacturing program certifies that the remanufactured products members’ profit functions, and equilibrium decisions for other
interactions can be obtained from this competitive model.
Our analyses reveal that when remanufacturing leads to more
*
Tel.: þ 886 5 5342601; fax: þ 886 5 5312073. cost-savings, the remanufacturer will provide a higher service level
E-mail address: wuchan@yuntech.edu.tw to the customers than the traditional manufacturer. Moreover,

0925-5273/$ - see front matter & 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2012.06.034
C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507 497

production cost always has negative effects on the chain members’ chain in the absence of service interactions, and often analyzed
decisions; however, the effects of the costs of recycling and service the recycling effort or profitability associated with remanufactur-
investment on equilibrium decisions depend on the intensities of ing (Atasu et al., 2008; Debo et al., 2005; Ferrer and Swaminathan,
price and service competition, especially in determining the new- 2006; Guide and Van Wassenhove, 2009; Hsueh, 2011; Liang
product manufacturer’s equilibrium decisions. Comparing the dif- et al., 2009; Mitra and Webster, 2008; Pokharel and Liang, 2012;
ferent interactions, we find that in the presence of competition, the Robotis et al., 2005; Robotis et al., in press; Savaskan et al., 2004;
manufacturer has an incentive to remanufacture, yet the opposite is Savaskan and Van Wassenhove, 2006; Vadde et al., 2011).
the case in the absence of competition. Moreover, for the retailer, Savaskan et al. (2004), for instance, studied price decisions and
price competition generally enhances profits from the remanufac- collection effort in a supply chain with three types of reverse
tured product, and thus benefits the remanufacturer. Meanwhile, channels for remanufacturing in comparison with a centralized
service competition is profitable for the retailer yet detrimental to system; the study examined the incentives provided to the
both manufacturers. However, the remanufacturer is likely to customer in order to improve the collection of used items in the
engage in service competition when cost-savings from remanufac- absence of the competition. Savaskan and Van Wassenhove
turing are significant or recycling costs are low. Moreover, remanu- (2006) further extended the previous closed-loop supply chain
facturing is an effective strategy in a highly price-sensitive market, models by considering a duopolistic competition with a retailer; it
even in the absence of price competition. also discussed the interactions surrounding price decisions with
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 respect to forward and reverse channels. Atasu et al. (2008)
surveys the related literature while emphasizing the contribution examined remanufacturing as a marketing strategy by consider-
of our work. In Section 3, we formalize price- and service- ing several factors, including cost savings, green-market segment,
sensitive market demands and chain members’ profit functions, competition with new products, and product life cycle. The study
and we derive their best response functions. Then, we solve for found that a remanufactured product is more profitable under
the member equilibrium decisions under the four competitive monopolistic competition, even in the absence of a green market
interactions. Section 4 presents analytical analyses of chain segment. Moreover, the study also pointed out that smart price
members’ equilibrium decisions with respect to the cost para- decision-making is important as the manufacturer cannibalizes
meters, and then it describes numerical studies that examine the used products. A few recent studies including Atasu et al. (2008),
effects of cost- and demand-related parameters on chain mem- Debo et al. (2005), Ferrer and Swaminathan (2006), Majumder
bers’ equilibrium profits. The final section concludes with a brief and Groenevelt (2001), Mitra and Webster (2008), and Savaskan
summary, including suggestions for future research. and Van Wassenhove (2006) have shed light on competition in
closed-loop supply chains with remanufacturing, but they all
focus exclusively on price competition.
This paper differs from the aforementioned studies in two
2. Literature review aspects. First, we assume that manufacturers compete in a duopoly,
and second, we incorporate service competition between manufac-
This study relates to two streams of literature: one examines turers. As discussed in Atasu et al. (2008), remanufactured products
the dynamics of chain members’ service decisions in the face of usually have lower customer valuations, and thus, manufacturers
service incentive demand, and the other explores supply chains with remanufacturing (e.g. HP Inc.) may provide service (e.g.,
with remanufacturing. Previous studies in the first stream of product information, after-sales maintenance, etc.) for customers
literature have concentrated on service interactions in supply to stimulate sales. Moreover, the remanufactured versus new
chains under game theoretical models (Bernstein and Federgruen, products possess different characteristics in terms of cost structures
2007; Cohen and Whang, 1997; De Borger and Van Dender, 2006; and interactive effects such that remanufactured products directly
Desiraju and Moorthy, 1997; Ray, 2005; Tsay and Agrawal, 2000; relate to the amount a manufacturer invests in remanufacturing.
Winter, 1993; Xia and Gilbert, 2007; Xiao and Yang, 2008; Zhen, Thus, a study of the interactions between price and service decisions
2012). Cohen and Whang (1997) used a product life cycle model to and an analysis of profitability of these two products should provide
study the sales prices and service qualities in a supply chain with a useful insights to supply chain members.
manufacturer and a service shop. In this model, the manufacturer
sells the product as well as provides the after-sales service, while
the service shop only provides service. They adopted a time-
dependent utility function to construct market demand, and then 3. The model
sequentially analyzed the price and service decisions of members.
Tsay and Agrawal (2000) studied a supply chain with two compet- Consider a supply chain comprised a manufacturer that produces
ing retailers with a common manufacturer in which both the new products from raw materials, a remanufacturer1 that produces
retailers provide products as well as service to customers. Thus, remanufactured products from used items directly collected from
retailers sell the same products and compete along price and customers (Savaskan et al., 2004; Savaskan and Van Wassenhove,
service. Xia and Gilbert (2007) focused on a supply chain model 2006), and a common retailer that sells the products of these two
with two substitutable products in which the product service manufacturers on the market. The two products are functionally the
levels are provided by a manufacturer, and the prices are deter- same. However, the customers treat them differently as new and
mined by a dealer (i.e., a retailer). This setting is applicable to remanufactured products. The retailer independently determines the
consumer electronics, computer devices and automobiles, which sales prices of the two products. Each manufacturer produces only
widely adopt remanufacturing. Many models have also addressed one product, and each has the opportunity to enhance demand
service competition, such as Ba et al. (2008), Bernstein and by bundling the product with service, such as sales effort (e.g.,
Federgruen (2007), De Borger and Van Dender (2006), Darian advertisement, product information) (Tsay and Agrawal, 2000) or
et al. (2005), Dan et al. (2012), and Kurata and Nam (2010);
however, only forward channels are examined in these studies. 1
In many instances, we use ‘‘remanufacturer’’ specifically to refer to the
More recently, studies have begun to take into account manufacturer producing the remanufactured products. In other instances, we refer
remanufacturing as a part of production. However, these studies to both the manufacturer and the remanufacturer as the ‘‘two manufacturers.’’
have focused on price interaction within a closed-loop supply Moreover, we refer to the retailer as female and the manufacturers as males.
498 C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507

after-sales service (e.g., maintenance and warranty repair agree- where aj , bp , bs 4 0, and gp , gs Z0, j ¼ fr,ng, and k ¼ fr,ng\j. aj
ments) (Cohen and Whang, 1997; Xia and Gilbert, 2007). However, describes the market base parameterizing the potential market size
to facilitate the remanufacturing process, the remanufacturer has to for product j when both prices at zero and no service is offered. bp
decide its recovering effort, which may lead to additional costs and and bs represent the price and service elasticities, respectively, on
savings. We discuss costs and savings later in the model. All chain market demand. dj is downward sloping along its price pj yet
members’ decisions must be made prior to the selling season. The upward sloping along its service sj; i.e., the higher the price (service)
sequence of events is as follows. Let the subscript j take the values of r is, the lower (higher) is the demand. gp and gs measure the price and
and n, denoting the remanufactured and new products, respectively. service competition, respectively, between the new and remanufac-
Because the production plan should be made before the sale tured products, and a higher gp (gs ) magnifies the influence of price
decisions, the remanufacturer first determines its remanufacturing (service) competitively. As discussed in Tsay and Agrawal (2000),
effort t, 0 r t r1, where t can be considered the portion of recovered lowering pj by one unit will attract bp þ gp ð@dj =@pj ¼ bp þ gp Þ more
materials used to produce a unit product by the remanufacturer. customers with demand (dj), if all else parameters are held equal;
Then, both manufacturers choose their service package levels that is, bp is the additional customers induced from a decrease in
sj. Finally, given the wholesale prices wj of manufacturer j, the product j’s price, and gp ð@dj =@pk ¼ gp Þ is additional customers
retailer chooses the sales prices pj for these two products, and diverted due to an increase in the other product’s price. Therefore,
orders the required quantities from the two manufacturers. the higher gp leads to severe price competition between the
Before the start of the selling season, the price and service products, and gs has similar implications in service competition.
information for the products is announced to the market. This (Refer to Tsay and Agrawal, 2000, for more details about the demand
scenario is common in real life, for instance, the remanufactured functions with competition.)
and new toner cartridges are usually sold through a common Given market demand dj, we can formulate the members’
retailer (e.g., Amazon.com) in a market. In this example, the profit functions. The new product manufacturer carries the
cartridge manufacturers provide the service for their products, production cost and service cost. The total production cost is
and Amazon.com decides the sales prices. All product and service cdj , and the service cost is ðms2j Þ=2, where c is the unit production
information is communicated to the customers. cost and m is the ultimate cost of service as in Tsay and Agrawal
We assume that the manufacturers have ample capacity to (2000). Therefore, the manufacturer’s profit function is
meet the retailer’s order quantity (Ferrer and Ketzenberg, 2004;
ms2n
Savaskan et al., 2004; Savaskan and Van Wassenhove, 2006). This PM
n ¼ ðwn cÞdn  : ð2Þ
2
assumption is plausible to the reality when the recovered materi-
als are common modules, which can be collected from different The remanufacturer must account for collection cost, production
types of products (e.g., aftermarket automotive parts) or from cost, and service cost. Following Debo et al. (2005) and Savaskan
different brands (e.g., computer parts), and when the source of and Van Wassenhove (2006), we assume that the recycling
recovered materials is from popular or long-life products, for process incurs a total collection cost of ðbt2 Þ=2 for the remanu-
example, XPS Inc., a remanufacturer of toner cartridges, has facturer, where b is a recycling cost. Note that the quadratic cost
sufficient capacity of remanufactured cartridges for some popular functions of service and collection imply the increasing marginal
printers (www.xps-lasercartridge.com). The manufacturers are costs, that is, the subsequent improvements of unit service and
able to deliver the order quantities to the retailer before the collection are progressively more difficult (for example, the
selling season. The retailer is the monopolist in the considered manufacturer bears the higher cost to enhance the service level
market area, and other products in this market area or different from 0.8 to 0.9 than does from 0.1 to 0.2.). This means that the
market areas under consideration, while the other products in chain members will target the ‘‘lowest-hanging fruit’’ (Tsay and
this market area or different market have no effect on the demand Agrawal, 2000) in determining service and remanufacturing
of these two products. This assumption allows us to investigate levels. Let cr be the complete remanufacturing cost, and let
competition between the new and remanufactured products. d  ccr 4 0 be the cost-savings from the remanufacturing
We also consider the chain members to be independent, (Atasu et al., 2008; Ferrer and Swaminathan, 2006; Savaskan
risk-neutral, and profit-maximizing. Moreover, the chain mem- et al., 2004; Savaskan and Van Wassenhove, 2006). In practice,
bers choose their decisions sequentially in a manufacturer-Stack- cost reduction is a main reason for many manufacturers (e.g.,
elberg game (Lau and Lau, 2002; Savaskan et al., 2004; Savaskan Caterpillar, HP, Xerox) to engage in remanufacturing, which
and Van Wassenhove, 2006; Trivedi, 1998) under a level playing provides 30–70% cost savings in comparison to the usage of
field, and they have complete information about the other members new cores (Gray and Charter, 2007). Then, the unit remanufactur-
(Cachon and Lariviere, 1999; Choi, 1991, 1996; Goyal and Netessine, ing cost with returned items can be expressed as
2007; Lee and Staelin, 1997; Trivedi, 1998). The notation used cð1tÞ þcr t ¼ cdt. Similar cost structure is also adopted in the
throughout this paper is summarized in Appendix A. literature (Gupta and Loulou, 1998; Savaskan et al., 2004;
Savaskan and Van Wassenhove, 2006) in the formulation of fixed
costs and cost differences.
The remanufacturer’s profit function can be described by the
3.1. Demand and profit functions following:

ms2r bt2
Let dj denote the market demand for product j A fr,ng. We PM
r ¼ ðwr c þ dtÞdr   : ð3Þ
2 2
consider demand dj to be a linear function of prices and service
levels, which is commonly adopted in the literature on price Assume both manufacturers’ prices to the retailer wr and wn
competition (Choi, 1991, 1996; Lee and Staelin, 1997; McGuire are predetermined (Hsieh and Wu, 2009; Lee et al., 2000; Tsay
and Staelin, 1983; Trivedi, 1998) and price and service competi- and Agrawal, 2000). Then, the retailer’s profit function PR is the
tion (Tsay and Agrawal, 2000; Xia and Gilbert, 2007). We define sum of the profits PRr and PRn from the remanufactured and new
the general demand function that captures both product and products, respectively:
service competition as follows:

dj ¼ aj bp pj þ gp ðpk pj Þ þ bs sj gs ðsk sj Þ, ð1Þ PR ¼ PRr þ PRn ¼ ðpr wr Þdr þ ðpn wn Þdn : ð4Þ
C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507 499

3.2. Strategic interactions results in the following:


ðwr c þ dtÞLs ðwn cÞLs
We now examine chain members’ decisions by maximizing s[r ¼ and s[n ¼ : ð6Þ
2m 2m
their profits in (2)–(4). Because the remanufacturing effort is
related to the remanufacturer’s production plan, we consider that In (6), we find that s[n is independent of t; i.e., s*n ¼ s[n . Yet, s[r is
the remanufacturer chooses the remanufacturing effort prior to increasing in t, meaning that the higher the remanufacturing
sale decisions. Afterwards, both the manufacturers determine effort is, the higher is the service level provided by the remanu-
their service levels, and the retailer determines the prices for facturer. Moreover, if dt 4 wn wr , then s[r 4 s[n . This indicates that
the remanufactured and new products, depending on their service the remanufacturer would provide a better service level for his
levels. Note that the proofs of the propositions presented product than that offered with the new product when remanu-
throughout this paper are included in Appendix A. facturing strategy leads to higher cost-savings.
The following proposition characterizes chain members’ profit Finally, with the best response functions for prices in (5) and
functions with respect to their decisions. service levels in (6), the remanufacturer’s best response in terms
of his remanufacturing effort can be obtained by solving t* A
Proposition 1. (i) The remanufacturer’s profit function PM r is arg maxt PM
r ðt9sr ,sn ,pr ,pn Þ, which yields the equilibrium remanu-
[ [ [ [

concave with respect to its remanufacturing effort t and service level facturing effort t* :
sr. (ii) The manufacturer’s profit function PM n is concave with respect
to its service level sn. (iii) The retailer’s profit function PR is concave dð2mðar þwn gp Þ þ Ls ðcbs þwn gs Þ þwr ð2mLp L2s ÞÞ
t* ¼ 2
: ð7Þ
with respect to sales prices pr and pn. 4bm þ d L2s

Proposition 1 shows that each chain member has an optimal With t* in (7), we can derive all equilibrium service levels and
choice to maximize heir profits, and this also implies that each prices s*r , p*r , and p*n in different scenarios (i.e., gs , gp a0 presents
member has the optimal strategies in response to the decisions of the presence of price and service competition, gs ¼ 0 no service
other chain members in competition. In pursuit of equilibrium competition, gp ¼ 0 no price competition, and gs , gp ¼ 0 no price
decisions, we use backward induction; that is, each chain member
and service competition), as shown in Table 1.
formulates its best reactions, denoted by the superscript ‘‘[’’, as a
function of the decisions of the prior movers. Let the superscript
‘‘*’’ denote the equilibrium value. Up to the remanufacturer’s 4. Analysis
equilibrium decision of t* is obtained, and all chain members’
equilibrium decisions are revealed by taking the remanufacturer’s We now perform further analyses of the equilibrium results.
equilibrium decision into the best response functions for the We focus on the effects of cost- and demand-related parameters
service levels and prices. on equilibrium decisions, and then we explore their influences on
First let us derive the last mover’s strategy, i.e., the best both manufacturers’ equilibrium profits. However, due to analy-
response functions of the retailer’s prices p[r ,p[n A arg maxpr ,pn PR tical intractability of chain members’ equilibrium profits, we use a
ðpr ,pn 9t,sr ,sn Þ. By solving the first conditions @PR =@pr ¼ 0 and numerical approach for providing more insights.
@PR =@pn ¼ 0, we obtain
4.1. Effects of costs on equilibrium decisions
ar Lp þ an gp þðsr sn Þbp gs þ wr bp ðgp þ Lp Þ þ bs ðsn gp þ sr Lp Þ
p[r ¼ ,
2bp ðgp þ Lp Þ Based on Table 1, we analyze the equilibrium decisions of the
ð5Þ remanufacturing effort, service levels, and sales prices with
respect to costs.
an Lp þ ar gp þ ðsn sr Þbp gs þwn bp ðgp þ Lp Þ þ bs ðsr gp þ sn Lp Þ Proposition 2. All the equilibrium decisions t* ,s*r ,s*n ,p*r , and p*n are
p[n ¼ :
2bp ðgp þ Lp Þ decreasing in c.

Note that Lp  bp þ gp is the overall effect of the product’s price on Proposition 2 shows that greater unit production cost leads to
its demand. Focusing on the impact of service levels on the lower equilibrium decisions. From the proof shown in Appendix,
retailers’ best response functions, we derive the first differential we observe that product cost has a direct effect on the equili-
of p[j with respect to the service levels, i.e., @p[j =@sj ¼ ðbs gp þ brium service levels, yet it has an indirect effect on equilibrium
prices and remanufacturing effort. When production cost is
bp Ls Þ=ð2bp ðbp þ Lp ÞÞ 4 0 and @p[j =@sk ¼ ðbs gp bp gs Þ= ð2b2p þ 4bp gp Þ, higher, the manufacturers will provide less service to lower costs,
where Ls  bs þ gs represents the overall effect of service on and decreasing service levels decreases equilibrium prices and the
demand, k aj, and j ¼ fr,ng. The higher the service level of product remanufacturing effort.
j is, the higher is the sales price of product j charged by the
retailer. However, the influence of the competitor’s service level Proposition 3. (i) t* is decreasing in b but increasing in d. (ii) s*r is
on the sales price depends on the competition intensities gj decreasing in b but increasing in d, but s*n is independent of b and d.
(iii) p*r is decreasing in b but increasing in d. Whenever bs gp Z bp gs ,
(j ¼ r,n). If bs gp 4 bp gs , then @p[j =@sk 40. This indicates that if the
p*n is decreasing in b but increasing in d; otherwise, p*n is increasing in
price competition is severer (i.e., gp is greater) or service competi-
b but decreasing in d.
tion is milder (i.e., gs is smaller), then the higherservice level of
product k increases the sales price of product j; otherwise, the Proposition 3 shows that the equilibrium decision trends
result is reversed. behave more complexly with respect to remanufacturing-related
Each manufacturer’s best response functions for service costs b and d than unit cost c. We observe that the remanufacturer
level s[j includes the retailer’s best reaction in (5); that is, invests a lower remanufacturing effort in production while bear-
ing the higher cost in remanufacturing, leading to the lower
s[j A arg maxsj PM
j ðsj ,sk 9t,pr ,pn Þ,k a j and j ¼ fr,ng. Thus, solving
[ [ [
service levels provided by the remanufacturer (recall that sr is
the first conditions, @ðPM [ [ M
r 9pr ,pn Þ=@sr ¼ 0 and @ðPn 9pr ,pn Þ=@sn ¼ 0,
[ [
positively related to t, as discussed before). Intuitively, the
of both manufacturers’ profits with respect to their service levels retailer charges a lower price, as the remanufactured product
500 C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507

Table 1
Equilibrium decisions under the different competition scenarios.

Scenarios Equilibrium decisions

gs , gp a 0 dð2mðar þ wn gp Þ þ Ls ðcbs þ wn gs Þþ wr ð2mLp L2s ÞÞ


tn ¼ 2
4bm þ d L2s

Ls ð4bcm þ wr ð4bm2md2 Lp Þþ d2 ð2mðar þ wn gp Þ þ ðcwn Þgs Ls ÞÞ


snr ¼ 2
2mð4bmd L2s Þ

ðwn cÞLs
snn ¼
2m

2 2
pnr ¼ ½8bm ðan gp þ ar Lp þ wr ðg2p þ L2p ÞÞ þ 2mgs ðgp ð2bc þ 2bwr þ d ðar þ wn gp ÞÞ
2 2 2
ð2bc2bwn þ d wr gp ÞLp ÞLs þ ð2md wr 2p þ 4mLp ðbc þ wr ðb þ d Lp ÞÞ
g
2 2
þ gp ð4bcm þ d ð2man þ cg2s Þwn ð4bm þ d ðg2s þ 2mLp ÞÞÞÞL2s
2 2
þ d ðc þ wn Þgp L4s =½4mðg2p L2p Þð4bmd L2s Þ

2 2 2
pnn ¼ ½8bm ðar gp þ an Lp þ wn ðg2p þ L2p ÞÞþ 2mgs ðLp ð2bc þ d ar þ wr ð2bd Lp ÞÞ
2 2
þ gp ð2bc þ wn ð2b þ d Lp ÞÞÞLs þ ð4mgp ðbc þ bwr þ d wn gp Þþ ð2mð2bc
2 2 2
2bwn þ d ðan þ wr gp ÞÞþ d ðcwn Þg2s ÞLp þ 2md wn L2p ÞL2s
2 2
þ d ðc þ wn ÞLp L4s =½4mðg2p L2p Þð4bmd L2s Þ

gs ¼ 0 dð2mar þ ðc þ wr Þb2s þ 2mðwn gp wr Lp ÞÞ


tn ¼  2 2
4bm þ d bs

bs ð2bcd2 ar d2 wn gp þ wr ð2b þ d2 Lp ÞÞ


snr ¼ 2 2
4bm þ d bs

ðwn cÞbs
snn ¼
2m

2 2 2 2
pnr ¼ ½ð4bmd bs Þgp ð2man þ ðcwn Þbs þ 2mwr gp Þ2mð4bmar þ bs ð2bc þ 2bwr
2 2 2 2 2
þ d wn gp ÞÞLp þ 4mwr ð2bm þ d bs ÞL2p =½4mð4bmd bs Þðg2p L2p Þ
2 2 2 2 2
pnn ¼ ½4mgp ð2bmar þ bðwr cÞbs þ wn ðd bs 2bmÞgp Þ þ ðð4bmd bs Þð2man þ ðwn
2 2 2 2 2 2 2
cÞbs Þþ 2md wr bs gp ÞLp þ 2mwn ðd bs 4bmÞL2p =½4mð4bmd bs Þðg2p L2p Þ

gp ¼ 0 dð2mar Ls ððc þ wn Þgs þ cLs Þ þ wr ð2mbp þ L2s ÞÞ


tn ¼  2
4bm þ d L2s

Ls ð4bcm þ wr ð4bm2md2 bp Þ þ d2 ð2mar þ ðcwn Þgs Ls ÞÞ


snr ¼ 2
2mð4bmd L2s Þ

ðwn cÞLs
snn ¼
2m

2
2bmðar þ wr bp Þþ bðcwn Þgs Ls ðbc þ wr ðb þ d bp ÞÞL2s
pnr ¼ 2
bp ð4bmd L2s Þ

1 2 2 2
pnn ¼ 2
ð8bm ðan þ wn bp Þ þ 2mð2bcd ar þ wr ð2b þ d bp ÞÞgs Ls
4mbp ð4bmd L2s Þ
2 2 2 2
ð2mð2bc þ d an þ wn ð2b þ d bp ÞÞ þ d ðcwn Þg2s ÞL2s þ d ðcwn ÞL4s Þ

gp , gs ¼ 0 dð2mar þ cb2s þ wr ð2mbp b2s ÞÞ


tn ¼ 2 2
4bm þ d bs

2 2
ð2bcd ar þ wr ð2b þ d bp ÞÞbs
snr ¼  2 2
4bmd bs

ðwn cÞbs
snn ¼
2m
C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507 501

Table 1 (continued )

Scenarios Equilibrium decisions

2 2 2 2
2bmar bcbs þ wr ðbbs þ bp ð2bmd bs ÞÞ
pnr ¼
bp ð4bmd2 b2s Þ

2 2
2man cbs þ wn ð2mbp þ bs Þ
pnn ¼
4mbp

bundled with the lower service level. In contrast, when remanu- Proposition 5. (i) t* is increasing in gp ; and (ii) t* is increasing in gs
facturing results in higher cost-savings, more effort is invested in whenever
production such that the higher service level and price are chosen pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2 bmððwn cÞgs þðc þ wn 2wr ÞLs Þ
by the remanufacturer and the retailer, respectively. Note that d Z qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ;
when d ¼ 0, the remanufacturer will abandon the remanufactur- Ls ð4mðar þ wn gp wr Lp Þðwn cÞgs Ls þ ðwn cÞL2s Þ
ing (i.e., t* ¼ 0) and behaves as a traditional manufacturer.
The equilibrium service level s*n of the new product is inde-
pendent of the remanufacturing costs, but the value of the t* is decreasing in gs , otherwise.
remanufacturer’s service level is influenced by b and d. Moreover,
the effects of d and b on p*n depend on price and service Proposition 5 shows that price competition induces the rema-
competition. When the intensity of price competition gp is nufacturer to improve his remanufacturing effort, because rema-
sufficiently large (i.e., gp 4 bp gs =bs ), decreasing p*r stimulates p*r nufacturing leads to price advantages due to cost-savings.
to decrease. Alternatively, when the intensity of service competi- However, service competition does not inevitably increase the
tion gs is sufficiently large (i.e., gs 4 bs gp =bp ), the retailer chooses a remanufacturing effort. If the remanufacturer has sufficient cost-
higher sales price of the new product. Hence, in the absence of savings, service competition also improves t* ; otherwise, it
price competition, p*n always increases in b yet decreases in d. In reduces t* . Hence, the remanufacturer possessing the superiority
the absence of service competition, p*n decreases in b yet increases in terms of cost-savings would choose the higher remanufactur-
in d. Moreover, in the absence of the price and service competi- ing effort when either price competition or service competition is
tion, p*n is independent of b and d. severer, that is, the remanufacturing is an effective competitive
Next, we characterize chain members’ equilibrium decisions advantage (as in the base example shown in Table 2).
with respect to the investment of service m as follows:
Proposition 6. (i) s*r and s*n are increasing in gs . (ii) s*r is increasing
Proposition 4. (i) , t *
s*r , s*n
are decreasing in m. (ii) Let Fr  @s*r =@m in gp , and s*n is independent of gp .
and Fn  @sn =@m. Whenever bs p 4 ½bp ðFn s Fr Ls Þ=ðFn þ Fr Þ, p*r
*
g g We intuitively observe in Proposition 6 that if the two
decreases in m; otherwise, p*r increases in m. Whenever manufacturers engage in more intensive service competition,
bs p 4 ½bp ðFn Ls Fr s Þ=ðFn þ Fr Þ, p*n decreases in m; otherwise, p*n
g g they choose higher service levels. Moreover, price competition
increases in m. only has an influence on the remanufacturer’s service level, which
increases in the intensity of price competition.
Proposition 4 first shows that both manufacturers’ service
levels are decreasing in m in equilibrium, and in turn, the
decreasing service levels lead to a decrease in the remanufactur- 4.3. Comparisons between the equilibrium decisions for the two
ing effort. This indicates that increasing service cost indirectly products
crowds out the remanufacturer’s investment in remanufacturing.
The effects of m on equilibrium prices depend on the intensities of One incentive of the remanufacturing is cost-savings, and thus,
competition as well as the effects Fr and Fn of m on equilibrium we consider compare equilibrium decisions between the new and
service levels. It is intuitive that severe price competition stimu- remanufactured products with regard to cost-savings. First, in
lates the retailer to choose lower equilibrium prices of the Proposition 7, we compare the relationship between the equili-
products. Moreover, p*r and p*n behave differently with respect to brium prices of the two products, and we obtain a threshold for d,
p
the effect of m on its equilibrium service level. If Fr is greater, denoted by d , below which the equilibrium price of the rema-
increasing m likely leads the retailer to select the smaller p*r ; nufactured product is smaller than that of the new product.
however, if Fn is greater, the retailer is likely to select the greater Because of the lower wholesale price of the remanufactured
p*n in response to the increasing m. Considering different interac- product, the retailer consequently chooses the lower prices,
tions, we find that in the absence of price interaction, both leading the remanufactured product to be more competitive in
equilibrium prices will increase in m; and in the absence of terms of price. However, when d exceeds the threshold, p*r is
service interaction, p*r always decreases in m, but p*n increases in m greater than p*n . Because when the remanufacturer has superiority
when gp o½bp Fn =ðFn þ Fr Þ. Thus, in the scenario with the mod- in terms of cost-savings, he chooses a better service level, as
erate price interaction, greater m causes p*r to decrease and p*n to stated in Proposition 8. Then, higher service level of the remanu-
increase, leading p*n to be less competitive than p*r . factured product mitigates by its pressure from price competition,
inducing the retailer to shift the price of remanufactured product.
4.2. Competitive effects on the equilibrium decisions of the
Proposition 7. Let C1 ¼ an 2mar þ ðwn wr Þ½2mðgp þ Lp Þ þ Ls
manufacturers
ðgs þ Ls Þ and C2 ¼ ðLs ð2mgs ðar þ wn gp wr Lp Þ þ ð2man þ cg2s 2
2 3
mwr ðgp þ 2Lp þ wp
p Þffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ffiffiffiffiffiffiffi gp gs þ2mLp ÞÞLs þ ðc þ wn ÞLs ÞÞ.
n ð4m
Regarding the effects of the competition on the two manufac- p
If d Z d ¼ 2 C1 = C2 , pr Z pn ; otherwise, pr opn .
* * * *
turers’ equilibrium decisions (i.e., the remanufacturing effort and
s
service levels), we first consider t* trends with respect to gp and gs . In Proposition 8, the threshold of d for s*r Z s*n is designated by d .
502 C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507

Table 2
Parameter values and the equilibrium results.

Interactions Decisions Demand Profits

t* s*r s*n p*r p*n *


dr
*
dn PM
r * PM
n * PRr * PRn * PR
*

gp ¼ gs ¼ 0 0.7155 0.4527 0.5000 3.9310 4.2000 7.1553 6.000 7.8206 8.2500 10.2393 7.2000 17.4393
gp ¼ 0, gs ¼ 3 0.7773 0.8100 0.8750 4.0545 4.3695 7.7726 6.8475 7.3145 7.9743 12.0827 9.3775 21.4602
gp ¼ 2, gs ¼ 0 0.7672 0.4612 0.5000 3.9379 4.1966 7.6724 5.5000 8.5059 7.5000 11.0324 6.5810 17.6134
gp ¼ 2, gs ¼ 3 0.8329 0.8263 0.8750 4.0767 4.3538 8.3295 6.3231 8.0158 7.1878 13.1332 8.5601 21.6934

s
Proposition 8. If d Z d , s*r Zs*n ; otherwise, s*r o s*n ; where
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
s 2 bmðwn wr Þ
d ¼ qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi :
2mðar þwn gp wr Lp Þ þ ðcwn Þgs Ls þðc þ wn ÞL2s

Remanufacturing is more effective in saving production cost,


the remanufacturer would provide a higher service level than the
s
manufacturer. This indicates that if d o d , the remanufactured
product is inferior to the new product in terms of service
s
competition. We further analyze d by taking the first derivatives
p
of d with respect to the service investment, recycling cost, and
the intensities of price and service competition, and we obtain y
s s s s Fig. 1. Influences of gp and gs on d with the different values of m(‘‘—’’: effect of gs
@d =@m 4 0, @d =@b 40, @d =@gs 40, and @d =@gp o 0. As a result,
when gp ¼ 2; and ‘‘- - -’’: effect of gp when gs ¼ 3, under the setting as ar ¼ an ¼ 25,
the remanufacturer bears higher costs in service or recycling b¼ 5, m¼ 6, c ¼1.5, d ¼ 0:5, bp ¼ 5, and bs ¼ 4.)
investments, and thus, he provides a lower service level than the
manufacturer. Moreover, when service competition is severe, the
more cost-savings are required for the remanufacturer to provide intuitively increases in the remanufacturer’s recycling cost. That
a higher service level. However, price competition behaves is, the remanufacturer will keep producing the remanufactured
s
inversely on d ; namely, the remanufacturer may wish to provide product when the cost-savings from the remanufacturing com-
y y
a higher service level than the manufacturer under more pensate for recycling cost. Setting wr ¼wn in d , we obtain d ¼ 0,
intense price competition. With the aid of Proposition 7, we know meaning that when the two manufacturers obtain equal unit
that the remanufactured product is competitive in terms of price revenues from the retailer, the remanufacturer obtains greater
competition, and thus, the fierce price competition is more profitable profits than the manufacturer, because the remanufacturer grabs
to the remanufacturer, leading to a higher service level. all the benefits from remanufacturing. Such a scenario with
identical wholesale prices is common in the real life when the
remanufacturer has the capability to produce the remanufactured
4.4. Comparisons between the manufacturers’ equilibrium profits
products as well as new products (i.e., they are indistinguishable
to the consumers), such as the case of one-time use cameras
The two manufacturers’ equilibrium profits are presented in
where remanufacturing is profitable to remanufacturers
(A.1). We investigate the relationship between the two manufac-
(Majumder and Groenevelt, 2001; Mukhopadhyay and Ma,
turers’ profit with respect to unit cost-savings. If the equilibrium
2009; Savaskan et al., 2004; Savaskan and Van Wassenhove,
profit of the remanufacturer is greater than that of the manufac-
2006).
turer, the remanufacturing strategy is more attractive to the
To provide more insight regarding price and service, Fig. 1
manufacturers. y
depicts the influences of price and service competition on d .
Proposition 9. (i) The equilibrium profit PM
r * is increasing in d, yet
As service competition becomes severer, the remanufacturer
PM y M M requires greater cost-savings from remanufacturing to gain super-
n * is decreasing in d. (ii) If d Z d , Pr * Z Pn *; otherwise,
M M ior profit as compared to the manufacturer. This indicates that
Pr * o Pn *. Note that
under the intense service competition, the remanufacturer should
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2 bm½4mððwn cÞan ðwr cÞar Þðwn wr ÞO1  improve cost-savings by remanufacturing. Conversely, severe
dy ¼ qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
ffi, y
price competition leads d to decrease because of price advantage
4m2 ðar þwn gp wr Lp Þ2 þ ðwn cÞO2 L2s ðwn cÞ2 L4s
of the remanufactured products. Thus, remanufacturing becomes
more beneficial under more intense price competition. Moreover,
O1 ¼ 4mðwn þ wr ÞLp ðwn þwr 2cÞL2s 4cmgs , improving the service investment cost is more favorable to the
y
manufacturer than the remanufacturer, and thus, d increases
O2 ¼ 4mðan þ wr gp wn Lp Þðwn cÞg2s : with lower m.

Proposition 10. The equilibrium profit PM


r * is increasing in gp , but
As can be seen in Proposition 9, PM M
r * increases in d, yet Pn * PMn * is decreasing in gp .
decreases in d. The value of d is directly profitable to the
remanufacturer, yet it is indirectly detrimental to the manufac- Proposition 10 states that price competition is beneficial to the
turer due to price competition. The remanufacturer obtains a remanufacturer yet harmful to the manufacturer. This echoes
higher profit than the manufacturer when the unit cost-savings with Proposition 7; i.e., the remanufacturer is competitive in
y
from the remanufacturing is above a threshold d , which terms of price competition.
C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507 503

5. Numerical experiments because the profit increase from the remanufactured product
offsets the profit decrease from the new product. In addition, the
Thus far, we have investigated the closed forms of chain retailer prefers to sell the remanufactured products in the
members’ equilibrium decisions with respect to the parameters, presence of service competition.
and we have compared the equilibrium decisions and profits Effects of recycling cost b. It is intuitive that increasing the
between the two manufacturers. Now, we turn to numerical recycling cost b is detrimental to the profits of the remanufac-
analyses of the parameters and competition influences on chain tured product (i.e., PM R
r * and Pr *), and conversely, it is beneficial
members’ equilibrium profits. A selected set of parameters is as to the profits from the new product (i.e., PM R
n * and Pn *), as shown
follows: wn ¼3, wr ¼2.5, ar ¼ an ¼ 252, b¼5, m¼ 6, c¼1.5, d ¼ 0:5, in Fig. 3. However, the positive effect of b on the manufacturer’s
gp ¼ 2, gs ¼ 3, bp ¼ 5, and bs ¼ 4. profit and the retailer’s profit from the new products is insignif-
The results of the base example are summarized in Table 2. icant in the absence of service competition. Furthermore, we note
Comparing the four interactions, we observe that the sales price that the two manufacturers’ and the retailer’s profits for the two
of the remanufactured product is lower than that of the new products converge in b, implying that if remanufacturing is
product, because of the cost-savings of the remanufactured uneconomic, the remanufacturer will abandon remanufacturing
product from remanufacturing. (From Proposition 7, we see that process and acts as a traditional manufacturer.
p
the setting is below the threshold d ¼ 0:5 o d ¼ 0:7943.) In the Effects of service investment cost m. As shown in Fig. 4, in the
case with no price and service competition (i.e., gp ¼ gs ¼ 0), the absence of price competition, all chain members’ profits decrease
remanufactured product’s price competitiveness for stimulating in service investment cost m. In the presence of price competition,
demand vanishes, and the remanufacturer chooses the lowest the remanufacturer’s and retailer’s profits still decrease in m, but
effort in remanufacturing. Under service competition, both man- while the manufacturer’s profit initially increases and then
ufacturers enhance their efforts in terms of service and thus decreases in m. In summary, increasing m is unfavorable not only
provide higher service levels. Moreover, we observe that s*n 4 s*r for the two manufacturers but also for the retailer. This is because
under the four interactions, which corresponds to the results that the two manufacturers provide lower services to customers
following from Proposition 8 that d ¼ 0:5 is smaller than under the higher m, which in turn lowers retail sales.
ds ¼ 0:5872 with neither price nor service competition, Effects of elasticities on demand bp and bs . From Figs. 5 and 6, we
ds ¼ 0:5590 without price competition, ds ¼ 0:5680 without ser- observe that all chain members’ equilibrium profits decrease in
s
vice competition, and d ¼ 0:5423 with both price and service bp , yet they increase in bs . The retailer’s profit is more sensitive to
competition. Service competition increases the retailer’s profit, price and service elasticities than that of the manufacturers,
but it is harmful to the two manufacturers’ profits, because the because she is closer to the market. With respect to the effects
service costs are born by the manufacturers. However, under of bp , the manufacturer’s decreasing profit rate is greater than
price competition, the remanufactured product’s price advantage that of the remanufacturer. Thus, in the presence of price
compels the new product’s price to decrease, but the remanufac- competition, the remanufacturer’s profit is always higher than
tured product’s price increases to gain additional revenue. Hence, the manufacturer’s profit, and in the absence of price competition,
price competition increases the remanufacturer’s profit and the the remanufacturer’s profit is higher than the manufacturer’s
retailer’s profits from the remanufactured product, but it is profit as long as bp is sufficiently large. This result indicates that
detrimental to the manufacturer’s profit (as stated in the remanufacturing process enables the remanufacturer to
Proposition 10) as well as the retailer’s profit from the new mitigate the negative influence of increasing price elasticity, and
products. In addition, the remanufacturer’s profit is greater than moreover, even when price competition is absent, remanufactur-
the manufacturer’s profit in the presence of price competition, but ing is profitable in the face of a highly price-sensitive market. In
the result is reversed in the absence of price competition. This contrast, while all chain members’ profits increase in bs , bs does
finding that PM M
r * 4 Pn * can be derived from Proposition 9 not change the relations of the profits between the new and
y
because d ¼ 0:54 d ¼ 0:3974 in the presence of price competi- remanufactured products. Namely, the manufacturer’s profit is
tion; however, PM M y
r * o Pn * because d ¼ 0:5o d ¼ 0:5715 in the larger than that of the remanufacturer in the absence of price
absence of price competition. The example reveals that chain competition, while the contrary is true in the presence of price
members’ equilibrium decisions and profits behave differently competition. This finding indicates that the service sensitivity of
with respect to price and service competition. market demand does not change the manufacturer’s attitude
Now, we examine the effects of cost-savings, recycling cost, regarding whether to adopt remanufacturing.
service investment cost, and demand elasticities on chain mem-
bers’ profits under the four competitive interactions.
Effects of unit cost-savings d. Fig. 2 shows that as d increases,
the remanufacturer’s and retailer’s profits from the remanufac- 6. Summary and future research
tured product increase, but the manufacturer’s and retailer’s
profits from the new products decrease. With the aid of In this study, we proposed a supply chain model with a
Proposition 9, the threshold d for PM M
y
r * Z Pn * can be obtained, common retailer and two manufacturers—one manufacturer
as shown in the figure. In addition, the presence of service produces a new product and the other produces a remanufactured
competition amplifies the effects of d. This finding indicates that product. Both manufacturers provide service for their products,
remanufacturing is more effective in improving profit; as the and the retailer determines the prices of the products for the
cost-savings increase, the remanufactured product becomes more market, which is incentive in terms of price and service. Four
competitive than the new product, and moreover, service com- competitive interactions are considered: no price and service
petition magnifies the remanufacturer’s superiority in terms of competition, price competition only, service competition only,
cost-savings. For the retailer, increasing d is overall beneficial, and both price and service competition. Furthermore, our model
enables us to examine the influences of price and service
competition on chain members’ interactions with respect to
2
To avert the effects of the difference between the primary demands for the
decisions and profitabilities. Our contribution is substantive as
two products, we set ar ¼ an . Note that this would not affect the trends in the no prior research has considered service competition in a closed-
equilibrium decisions and profits with respect to the parameters. loop supply chain with remanufacturing. More importantly, our
504 C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507

Fig. 2. Influence of cost-savings on chain members’ equilibrium profits.

Fig. 3. Influence of recycling cost on chain members’ equilibrium profits.

Fig. 4. Influence of service investment cost on chain members’ equilibrium profits.

Fig. 5. Influence of price elasticity on chain members’ equilibrium profits.

Fig. 6. Influence of service elasticity on chain members’ equilibrium profits.

results also provide guidelines for choosing marketing strategies remanufacturer delegates more effort to remanufacturing under
for price and service decisions under different interactions. competition, while the reverse is hold without competition. Price
Our analysis yields the following insights. The intensities of price and service have different impacts on chain members’ profits. Price
and service competition affect the trends in equilibrium decisions competition generally increases the remanufacturer’s and the retai-
with respect to recycling cost and service investment, especially ler’s profit from the remanufactured product because of lower cost
for the new-product manufacturer’s equilibrium decisions. The of that product. Service competition is profitable for the retailer yet
C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507 505

detrimental to both manufacturers; this is because service costs are p, s price and service, respectively
born by the manufacturers. However, if cost-savings are significant
and recycling cost is low, remanufacturing is an effective strategy for Superscripts
the remanufacturer under service competition with the traditional R, M retailer and manufacturers, respectively
manufacturer. Moreover, remanufacturing is also beneficial to the [ best response functions
remanufacturer under a highly price-sensitive market, even in the * Nash equilibrium
absence of price competition.
Nonetheless, this paper has made several assumptions;
relaxing these assumptions may allow us to better comprehend
the interactive dynamics in a closed-loop supply chain. For A.2. Equilibrium profits of the two manufacturers
instance, wholesale prices are considered to be predetermined,
as in the previous studies (Hsieh and Wu, 2009; Lee et al., 2000; The remanufacturer’s and manufacturer’s equilibrium profits
Tsay and Agrawal, 2000). Thus, an extension of this paper would are as follows:
be to allow the manufacturers to choose their wholesale prices, 2 2 2 2 2 2
yet this may lead the model to be very complex and, thus, PM
r * ¼ 1=ð8mð4bmd Ls ÞÞ½4m d ar þ 16bcm wr Lp
2 2
analytically intractable. Second, we assumed that the demand is 16bm w2r Lp þ 4m2 d w2r L2p
deterministic, and if the model is treated as stochastic, more 2 2
8bc mgs Ls þ 8bcmwr gs Ls 4cmd wr gs Lp Ls
findings might be obtained, for example, regarding the influence
2
of random factor of demand on the remanufacturing effort, chain þ 4bc mL2s 8bcmwr L2s
members’ interactions, and performances. Third, it is insightful to 2 2
þ 4bmwr L2s þc2 d g2s L2s þ d w2n ð2mgp þ gs Ls Þ2
2
consider the availability of collection, which may constrain the
2 2
remanufacturing and change the interaction between the pro- þ 2wn ð2mgp gs Ls Þð4bcm þwr ð4bm2md Lp Þ þ cd gs Ls Þ
ducts (Atasu et al., 2008; Ferrer and Swaminathan, 2006). Finally, 2
the power structure between the manufacturers and the retailer 4mar ðwr ð4bm þ 2md Lp Þ
2 2
should be taken into account, as it may shed lights on whether þ d wn ð2mgp þ gs Ls Þ þ cð4bmd gs Ls ÞÞ,
the current results will hold if the retailer has a greater power
than the manufacturers or if all chain members have equal PM 2 2 2
n * ¼ 1=ð8mð4bmd Ls ÞÞ½ðcwn Þ ð16bm wn Lp 8bcmgs Ls
power. 2 2
þ 4md ar gs Ls þ4md wn gp gs Ls þ4bcmL2s 4bmwn L2s
2 2 2 2
þ 2cd g2s L2s 2d wn g2s L2s 4md wn Lp L2s cd L4s
Acknowledgment
2 2
þ d wn L4s þ4man ð4bm þ d L2s Þ
The author thanks the anonymous referee for the constructive 2
4mwr ðgs ð2b þ d Lp ÞLs þ gp ð4bmd L2s ÞÞÞ:
2
ðA:1Þ
comments and suggestions that significantly enhanced the paper.
This research was supported by National Science Council, Taiwan,
ROC, under Grant #NSC-99-2410-H-224-028-MY2.
Proof of Proposition 1. (i) Assuming PM r in (3) is not a hyper-
2
bolic function; then, the inequality bm 4 d ðbs þ gs Þ2 must hold.
The Hessian matrix of PM r with respect to t and sr is
Appendix A 0 2 M 2 M1
@ Pr @ Pr !
B @t2 @t@sr C b dðbs þ gs Þ
A.1. Summary of notation HM
r ¼ @ 2 M 2 M A ¼ ,
@ Pr @ Pr dðbs þ gs Þ m
@sr @t2 @sr
Symbols

j indicator of product j A fr,ng and the determinate of the Hessian det HM 2 2


r ¼ bmd ðbs þ gs Þ 4 0,
b remanufacturer’s recycling cost M
i.e., negative definite Hessian. Hence, Pr is concave in t and sr. (ii)
c each manufacturer’s product cost The second derivative of PM in (2) with respect to sn is
n
dj market demand of product j A fr,ng @2 PM M
n =@sn ¼ m o0, and thus Pn is concave in sn. (iii) The
2
m each manufacturer’s service investment cost R
determinate of the Hessian of P in (4) is
pj retailer’s sales price of product j A fr,ng 0 2 R 1
@ P @2 PR !
sj sales level of product j A fr,ng 2ðbp gp Þ 2gp
R B @p2r @pr @pn C
wj wholesale price of product j A fr,ng det H ¼ det@ @2 PR A ¼ det
@2 PR
2
2gp 2ðbp gp Þ
@pn @pr @pn
d cost-savings from remanufacturing
t remanufacturer’s effort in remanufacturing ¼ 4bp ðbp þ 2gp Þ 4 0,
(0 r t r1)
P Profit function and hence, PR is concave in pr and pn. &
aj market base of product j A fr,ng
Proof of Proposition 2.. The parameters b are assumed to be
bp , bs price and service elasticities on market demand, 2 2
large enough so that 4bmd gs Ls d L2s Z 0. The first derivatives
respectively of the equilibrium decisions with respect to c are as follows:
gp , gs intensities of price and service competition,
respectively @t* dbs Ls
¼ 2
r0,
Lk overall effects of k A fp,sg on demand @c 4bm þ d L2s
(Lk ¼ bk þ gk ) !
d2 bs Ls
Subscripts ðbs þ gs Þ 1þ 2
@s*r 4bm þ d L2s
¼ r0,
r, n remanufactured and new products, respectively @c 2m
506 C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507

@s*n b þ gs Note that @t* =@m is less than or equal to zero, except when wn is
¼ s r 0,
@c 2m extremely large. However, this extreme case is not examined in
! this paper.
d2 ðbs gp þ bp ðbs þ gs ÞÞLs The derivatives of s*r and s*n with respect to m are given by
bs ðbs þ gs Þ 1 þ 2
@p*r ðbp þ2gp Þð4bm þ d L2s Þ  
@t*
 
¼ r0, L d m t ðw cÞ
@c 4mbp @s*r @s[ @t* @s[r s
@m
r
¼ r þ ¼ r 0,
2 2 2 2
@m @t @m @m 2m2
@p*n bs ðbs þ gs Þðgp ð8bm þ d bs Ls 2d L2s Þ þ bp ð4bmd gs Ls d L2s ÞÞ
¼ r0:
@c 2
4mbp ðbp þ 2gp Þð4bmd L2 Þ @s*n @s[ @t* @s[n Ls ðcwn Þ
s ¼ n þ ¼ r 0:
@m @t @m @m 2m2
Hence, all equilibrium decisions are decreasing in c. &
The proof of (i) is completed.
Proof of Proposition 3. Let O  2mðar þwn gp Þ þ Ls ðcbs þwn gs Þ Taking the derivatives of p*r and p*n with respect to m yields
þwr ð2mLp L2s Þ. Then, t* in (7) can be simplified as
2
ðdOÞ=ð4bm þ d L2s Þ. Because t* Z 0, we obtain O r0. @p*r @p[ @s* @p[ @s* @p[
¼ r r þ r nþ r
We first consider the derivatives with respect to d. The first @m @sr @m @sn @m @m
derivative of t* with respect to d is bs gp ðFn þ Fr Þ þ bp ½Fr bs þ ðFr Fn Þgs 
¼ ,
2bp ðLp þ gp Þ
2
@t* Oð4bm þ d L2s Þ
¼ 2
Z0:
@d ð4bm þ d L2 Þ2 @p*n @p[ @s* @p[ @s* @p[
s ¼ n r þ n nþ n
@m @sr @m @sn @m @m
Taking the derivatives of s*r , s*n , p*r , and p*n with respect to d then
bs gp ðFn þ Fr Þ þ bp ½Fn bs þ ðFn Fr Þgs 
yields ¼ :
2bp ðLp þ gp Þ
 
@t*
ðb s þ gs Þ t þ d Hence, if bs gp 4½bp ðFn gs Fr Ls Þ=ðFn þ Fr Þ, p*r decreases in m;
@s*r @s[ @t* @s[r @d
¼ r þ ¼ Z 0, otherwise, p*r increases in m. If bs gp 4 ½bp ðFn Ls Fr gs Þ=ðFn þ Fr Þ,
@d @t @d @d 2m
p*n decreases in m; otherwise, p*n increases in m. The proof of (ii) is
@s*n completed. &
¼ 0,
@d
Proof of Proposition 5. Taking the first derivative of t*
@p*r @p[ @s* @p[ @s* @p[ ½bs gp þ bp ðbs þ gs Þ @s*r with respect to gp , we obtain @t* =@gs ¼ ½ð2mdðwn wr Þ= ð4bm
¼ r rþ r nþ r ¼ Z0,
@d @sr @d @sn @d @d 2bp ðbp þ 2gp Þ @d d2 L2s Þ Z 0, and thus, t* is increasing in gp , as stated in (i). Next, we
take the first derivative of t* with respect to gs :
@p*n @p[ @s* @p[ @s* @p[ ðbs gp bp gs Þ @s*r
¼ n rþ n nþ n ¼ : @t* 1 2 2
@d @sr @d @sn @d @d 2bp ðbp þ 2gp Þ @d ¼ ð4mdðbc þ d ar þ wn ðb þ d gp Þ
@gs 2
ð4bm þ d L2s Þ2
s*r and p*r are increasing in d. If bs gp Z bp gs , p*n is increasing in d; 2 3 2
þwr ð2bd Lp ÞÞLs þ d ðc þ wn ÞL3s þ dðcwn Þgs ð4bm þ d L2s ÞÞ,
otherwise, p*n is decreasing in d.
We now turn our attention to the derivatives of the equilibrium and then we derive the conditions of d by solving @t* =@gs ¼ 0. We
decisions with respect to b. The first derivative of t* with respect note that if
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
to b is 2 bmððwn cÞgs þðc þ wn 2wr ÞLs Þ
d Z qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ,
@t* 4mdO Ls ð4mðar þ wn gp wr Lp Þðwn cÞgs Ls þ ðwn cÞL2s Þ
¼ 2
r 0:
@b ð4bm þ d L2s Þ2 t* is increasing in gs ; otherwise, t* is decreasing in gs . The proof of
The derivatives of s*r , s*n , p*r , and p*n with respect to b are as follows: (ii) is completed. &

@s*r @s[r
@t *
@s[r
dLs @t *
Proof of Proposition 6. Consider the following derivatives:
¼ þ ¼ r 0,
@b @t @b @b 2m @b
@s*r @s[ @s[ @t*
¼ r þ r ,
@s*n @gs @gs @t @gs
¼ 0,
@d
@s*n wn c
¼ 4 0,
@p*r @p[ @s* @p[ @s* @p[ dLs ðbs gp þ bp Ls Þ @t* @gs 2m
¼ r rþ r nþ r ¼ r 0,
@b @sr @b @sn @b @b 4mbp ðbp þ2gp Þ @b
2
@s*r d ðwn wr ÞLs
¼ 40,
@p*n @p[ @s* @p[ @s* @p[ dLs ðbs gp bp gs Þ @t* @gp 2
4bmd L2s
¼ n rþ n nþ n ¼ :
@b @sr @b @sn @b @b 4mbp ðbp þ 2gp Þ @b
@s*n
Contrary to the influences of d, s*r and p*r are decreasing in b. ¼ 0: ðA:2Þ
@gp
If bs gp Z bp gs , p*n is decreasing in b; otherwise, p*n is increasing
in b. & It is straightforward that s*n is increasing in gs , s*r is increasing in
gp , and s*n is independent to gp . Observing @s*r =@gs , we note that the
Proof of Proposition 4. The first derivative of t* with respect to first term of (A.2) is always positive, but the second term depends
m is as follows: on @t* =@gs . With the aid of Proposition 5, we find that @t* =@gs
2 decreases in d, we then input d ¼ 0 into (A.2), and obtain
@t* 2dLs ðd Ls ðar þwn gp wr Lp Þ2bðwr Ls wn gs cbs ÞÞ
¼ r 0: @s*r =@gs ¼ ðwr cÞ=2m 40. Hence, s*r is increasing in gs , and the
2
@m ð4bm þ d L2 Þ2 s proof is completed. &
C.-H. Wu / Int. J. Production Economics 140 (2012) 496–507 507

Proof of Proposition 7. Taking the first derivatives of p*r p*n with Ferrer, G., Ketzenberg, M.E., 2004. Value of information in remanufacturing
respect to d yields complex products. IIE Transactions 36, 265–277.
Ferrer, G., Swaminathan, J.M., 2006. Managing new and remanufactured products.
@ðp*r p*n Þ 2bLs ðgs þ Ls Þt* Management Science 52 (1), 15–26.
¼ 2
4 0: Global Industry Analysts, 2 2010. Automotive Remanufacturing—A Global Strate-
@d ðgp þ Lp Þð4bmd L2s Þ gic Business Report.
Goyal, M., Netessine, S., 2007. Strategic technology choice and capacity investment
p
Thus, solving p*r p*n ¼ 0 for d gives the threshold, denoted by d , as under demand uncertainty. Management Science 53 (2), 192–207.
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffiffi Gray, C., Charter, M., 2007. Remanufacturing and Product Design: Designing for
dp ¼ 2 C1 = C2 , where C1 ¼ an 2mar þðwn wr Þ½2mðgp þ Lp Þ the 7th Generation. The Centre for Sustainable Design University College for
þ Ls ðgs þ Ls Þ and C2 ¼ ðLs ð2mgs ðar þ wn gp wr Lp Þ þð2man þ cg2s  the Creative Arts, Farnham, UK.
Guide, V., Daniel, R.J., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2009. The evolution of closed-loop
2mwr ðgp þ2Lp Þ þ wn ð4mgp g2s þ2mLp ÞÞLs þ ðc þ wn ÞL3s ÞÞ. Hence, supply chain research. Operations Research 57 (1), 10–18.
p
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffiffi Gupta, S., Loulou, R., 1998. Process innovation, production differentiation, and
if d Z d ¼ 2 C1 = C2 , p*r r p*n ; otherwise, p*r 4p*n . &
channel structure: strategic incentives in a duopoly. Marketing Science 17,
301–316.
Proof of Proposition 8. With the aid of Proposition 3, we obtain Hauser, W., Lund, R.T., 2008. Remanufacturing: Operating Practices and Strategies.
the threshold of d for s*r Z s*n by solving s*r s*n ¼ 0 as Department of Manufacturing Engineering, Boston University.
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi Hsieh, C.C., Wu, C.H., 2009. Coordinated decisions for substitutable products in a
2 bmðwn wr Þ common retailer supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research 196
d Z ds ¼ qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi : &
(1), 273–288.
2mðar þ wn gp wr Lp Þ þ ðcwn Þgs Ls þ ðc þ wn ÞL2s Hsueh, C.-F., 2011. An inventory control model with consideration of remanufac-
turing and product life cycle. International Journal of Production Economics
133 (October (2)), 645–652.
Proof of Proposition 9. For (i), the first derivatives of PM
r * and Kurata, H., Nam, S.-H., 2010. After-sales service competition in a supply chain:
2
PM
n * with respect to d are @PM *
r *=@d ¼ bt =d 4 0 and optimization of customer satisfaction level or profit or both. International
2 2
Journal of Production Economics 127 (1), 136–146.
M
@Pn *=@d ¼ ½2bðwn cÞgs Ls t =ð4bmd Ls Þ o 0,
*
respectively. Lau, A.H.L., Lau, H.S., 2002. The effects of reducing demand uncertainty in a
Note that proof of (ii) is analogous to the proof of Proposition 8. manufacturer-retailer channel for single-period products. Computers & Opera-
tions Research 29, 1583–1602.
Thus, solving PM M
r * Z Pn * for d yields Lee, E., Staelin, R., 1997. Vertical strategic interaction: implications for channel
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pricing strategy. Marketing Science 16, 185–207.
2 bm½4mððwn cÞan ðwr cÞar Þðwn wr ÞO1  Lee, H.L., Padmanabhan, V., Taylor, T.A., Whang, S., 2000. Price protection in the
d Z dy ¼ qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
ffi,
personal computer industry. Management Science 46 (4), 467–482.
4m2 ðar þ wn gp wr Lp Þ2 þ ðwn cÞO2 L2s ðwn cÞ2 L4s Liang, Y., Pokharel, S., Lim, G.H., 2009. Pricing used products for remanufacturing.
European Journal of Operational Research 193 (March (2)), 390–395.
where O1 ¼ 4mðwn þwr ÞLp ðwn þ wr 2cÞL2s 4cmgs and O2 ¼ Majumder, P., Groenevelt, H., 2001. Competition in remanufacturing. Production
and Operations Management 10 (2), 125–141.
4mðan þ wr gp wn Lp Þðwn cÞg2s . Thus, the proof is completed. &
McGuire, T.W., Staelin, R., 1983. An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream
vertical integration. Marketing Science 2 (2), 161–192.
Proof of Proposition 10. The proof follows directly from the first Mitra, S., Webster, S., 2008. Competition in remanufacturing and the effects of
derivatives, i.e., @PM * M
r *=@gp ¼ msr ðwn wr Þ=Ls 40 and @Pn *=@gp ¼ government subsidies. International Journal of Production Economics 111
2 2 2
½ðwn cÞðwn wr Þð4bm þ d ðgs Ls ÞLs Þ=ð8bm2d Ls Þ o0. There- (February (2)), 287–298.
M* Mukhopadhyay, S.K., Ma, H., 2009. Joint procurement and production decisions in
fore, we note that PM r * increases in gp , but Pn r decreases remanufacturing under quality and demand uncertainty. International Journal
in gp . & of Production Economics 120 (July (1)), 5–17.
Pokharel, S., Liang, Y., 2012. A model to evaluate acquisition price and quantity of
used products for remanufacturing. International Journal of Production Eco-
References nomics 138 (July (1)), 170–176.
Ray, S., 2005. An integrated operations-marketing model for innovative products
Atasu, A., Sarvary, M., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2008. Remanufacturing as a market- and services. International Journal of Production Economics 95 (March (3)),
ing strategy. Management Science 54 (10), 1731–1746. 327–345.
Ba, S., Stallaert, J., Zhang, Z., 2008. Oligopolistic price competition and adverse Robotis, A., Bhattacharya, S., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2005. The effect of remanu-
price effect in online retailing markets. Decision Support Systems 45 (November facturing on procurement decisions for resellers in secondary markets.
(4)), 858–869. European Journal of Operational Research 163 (June (3)), 688–705.
Bernstein, F., Federgruen, A., 2007. Coordination mechanisms for supply chains Robotis, A., Boyaci, T., Verter, V., Investing in reusability of products of uncertain
under price and service competition. Manufacturing and Service Operations remanufacturing cost: the role of inspection capabilities. International Journal
Management 9 (3), 242–262. of Production Economics /http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2012.04.017S, in
Cachon, G.P., Lariviere, M.A., 1999. Capacity allocation using past sales: when to press.
turn-and-earn. Management Science 45 (5), 686–703. Savaskan, R.C., Bhattacharya, S., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2004. Closed-loop supply
Choi, S.C., 1991. Price competition in a channel structure with a common retailer. chain models with product remanufacturing. Management Science 50 (2),
Marketing Science 10 (4), 271–296. 239–252.
Choi, S.C., 1996. Price competition in a duopoly common retailer channel. Journal Savaskan, R.C., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2006. Reverse channel design: the case of
of Retailing 72 (2), 117–134. competing retailers. Management Science 52 (1), 1–14.
Cohen, M.A., Whang, S., 1997. Competing in product and service: a product life- Trivedi, M., 1998. Distribution channels: an extension of exclusive retailership.
cycle model. Management Science 43 (4), 535–545. Management Science 44 (7), 896–909.
Dan, B., Xu, G., Liu, C., 2012. Pricing policies in a dual-channel supply chain Tsay, A.A., Agrawal, N., 2000. Channel dynamics under price and service competi-
with retail services. International Journal of Production Economics 139 (1), tion. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 2 (4), 372–391.
312–320. /http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2012.05.014S. Vadde, S., Zeid, A., Kamarthi, S.V., 2011. Pricing decisions in a multi-criteria setting
Darian, J.C., Wiman, A.R., Tucci, L.A., 2005. Retail patronage intentions: the relative for product recovery facilities. Omega 39 (April (2)), 186–193.
importance of perceived prices and salesperson service attributes. Journal of Winter, R.A., 1993. Vertical control and price versus nonprice competition.
Retailing and Consumer Services January (12) (1), 15–23. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (February (1)), 61–76.
De Borger, B., Van Dender, K., 2006. Prices, capacities and service levels in a Xia, Y., Gilbert, S.M., 2007. Strategic interactions between channel structure and
congestible Bertrand duopoly. Journal of Urban Economics 60 (September (2)), demand enhancing services. European Journal of Operational Research 181 (1),
264–283. 252–265.
Debo, L.G., Toktay, L.B., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2005. Market segmentation and Xiao, T., Yang, D., 2008. Price and service competition of supply chains with risk-
product technology selection for remanufacturable products. Management averse retailers under demand uncertainty. International Journal of Production
Science 51 (8), 1193–1205. Economics 114 (July (1)), 187–200.
Desiraju, R., Moorthy, S., 1997. Managing a distribution channel under asymmetric Zhen, L., 2012. An analytical study on service-oriented manufacturing strategies.
information with performance requirements. Management Science 43 International Journal of Production Economics 139 (1), 220–228./http://dx.
(December (12)), 1628–1644. doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2012.04.010S.

You might also like