Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 12

Searching for Leviathan: An Empirical Study

Wallace E. Oates

The American Economic Review, Vol. 75, No. 4. (Sep., 1985), pp. 748-757.

Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198509%2975%3A4%3C748%3ASFLAES%3E2.0.CO%3B2-L

The American Economic Review is currently published by American Economic Association.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained
prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in
the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/journals/aea.html.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is an independent not-for-profit organization dedicated to and preserving a digital archive of scholarly journals. For
more information regarding JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

http://www.jstor.org
Tue Apr 24 16:35:51 2007
Searching for Leviathan: An Empirical Study

Total government intrusion into the stand on their heads many of the basic theo-
economy should be smaller, ceteris rems in public finance for an efficient and
puribus, the greater the extent to which equitable tax system. If, in fact, the Leviathan
taxes and expenditures are decentral- view is an inaccurate depiction of the func-
ized. . . . tioning of the public sector, the introduction
[Brennan and Buchanun, 1980, p. 1851
of their policy proposals is likely to make a
In several papers and a recent book, sorry mess of the fiscal system.
Geoffrey Brennan and James Buchanan The Leviathan model does, however, have
(1977, 1978, 1980) have put forth a striking some straightforward implications for ob-
and controversial view of the vublic sector. servable fiscal behavior. It is the purpose of
Drawing by analogy on the conventional the- this paper to examine one of these testable
ory of monopoly in the private sector, they implications. Brennan and Buchanan stress
envision a monolithic government that sys- that fiscal decentralization is itself a power-
tematically seeks to exploit its citizenry ful constraint on Leviathan: competition
through the maximization of the tax reve- among governments in the context of the
nues that it extracts from the economy. From "interjurisdictional mobility of persons in
this perspective, they develop a fiscal con- pursuit of 'fiscal gains' can offer partial or
stitution-whose central is to con- possibly complete substitutes for explicit fis-
strain "Leviathan" by limiting in various cal constraints on the taxing power" (1980,
ways its access to tax and other fiscal instru- p. 184). Such competition among govern-
ments. ments in a federal system that places heavy
While the Leviathan hv~othesishas been reliance on "local" fiscal decisions will greatly
the source of lively debate'and a wide range limit the capacity of Leviathan to channel
of policy proposals, it has not been the sub- resources into the public sector. In short, as
ject of much systematic empirical work or indicated by the epigraph to this paper, the
testing.' This is a matter of some importance Leviathan model implies that, other things
since the policy implications of the Leviathan equal, the size of the public sector should
view are disturbing, to put it mildly. In par- vary inversely with the extent of fiscal de-
ticular, Brennan and Buchanan virtually centralization.*

*Department of Economics and Bureau of Business 2 ~ Musgrave


s has pointed out to me. other sorts of
and E c o n o ~ n ~Research,
c University of hfaryland. Col- models besides Leviathan could produce such an out-
lege Park. M D 20742. I am grateful to Mark Eiswerth come. H e notes, in particular. the redistribution func-
and Christopher Graves for their excellent assistance tion. Under a highly decentralized public sector, there is
with the computations; to Jonathan Levin of the likely- to be comparatively little in the way of assistance
Government Finance Statistics Division of the Interna- to the poor for two reasons. First. sorting out along
tional Monetary Fund for his invaluable help with the Tiebout lines will imply relatively income-homogeneous
data: and to the Alfred P Sloan Foundation for its jurisdictions with little scope for redistribution from
support of this work For helpful comments on an wealthy to poor wlthin jurisdictions. And. second. the
earlier draft. I thank Fred Abraham, Charles Brown, fear of attracting h no bile poor with relatively generous
Bnice Hamilton, Harry Kelejian. Michael Luger. Edwin support programs will tend to deter the adoption of
Mills. Richard Musgrave, D a n ~ e l Rubinfeld, Robert such programs. All this suggests that the scope for
Schwab, and participants in the George Mason Public p u b l ~ crelief programs will be more circumscribed under
Choice Se~ninar and the Sloan Workshop in Urban a relatively decentralized fiscal system. This would lead
Public Economics at the Univers~tyof Maryland. us to expect comparatively larger budgets where the
' F o r a critical appraisal of the Leviathan model. see public sector is more centralized as a result of a greater
Richard Musgrave (1981 ). demand for assistance to low-income households.
VOL.. 75 KO. 4 OATES: SE.4 RCHIhrG FOR LE 1/'1,4 THA:Y 74Y

I. More on the Empirical Test wider range of choice available to mobile


consumers may more than offset the ad-
Brennan and Buchanan thus see a de- ditional administrative expenditures. The
centralized public sector as a mechanism for point is simply that fiscal decentralization
limiting the growth or size of government. may be relatively expensive in budgetary
But there is an alternative view. Suppose that terms. Thus, a more competitive view of the
instead of a monopolistic setting, compe- functioning of the public sector would sug-
tition among political parties produces an gest, contrary to the Leviathan model, an
outcome that conforms fairly closely to the absence of a positive association between
tastes of the citizenry-as under the conven- government size and fiscal centralization with
tional median-voter model. In such a com- the possibility that this association might
petitive political environment, one would even be negative.
have no reason to expect a negative associa- John Wallis, an American economic histo-
tion between the size of public budgets and rian, has suggested to me an even stronger
the degree of fiscal decentralization. In a hypothesis. He contends that since individu-
centralized setting, the outcome would con- als have more control over public decisions
form to the preferences of the "overall" at the local than at the state or national level,
median voter. If, in contrast, levels of output they will wish to empower the public sector
were set independently in each jurisdiction, with a wider range of functions and responsi-
the median voter in each locality would bility where these activities are carried out at
effectively choose the budget. It is impossible more localized levels of government. Based
to determine whether the average level of on his reading of American history, Wallis
output in the decentralized case would ex- offers the coniecture that over time and across
ceed or fall short of output under centralized states, the state-local sector has tended to be
decision making without knowing both the larger, the more decentralized is fiscal deci-
distribution of tastes and the location of the sion making.
p~pulace.~ The resolution of this debate requires re-
In fact. one might argue for the compet- course to the actual facts of governmental
itive case that, from a purely budgetaty structure and budgetary outcomes. A little
perspectrue, increased fiscal decentralization over a decade ago in the context of a larger
would typically result in a higher level of study. I undertook a cursory examination of
government expenditure. Greater decentral- the relationship between the size of govern-
ization may result in the loss of certain ment and the extent of fiscal decentraliza-
"economies of scale" with a consequent in- tion, using a cross-sectional sample of 57
crease in costs of administration. This, of countries (1972, pp. 209-13). Regressing a
course, need not imply an inferior outcome; measure of the size of the public sector (tax
the welfare gains from the tailoring of local revenues as a fraction of national income) on
budgets to local preferences and from the a fiscal centralization ratio (i.e., central-
government tax revenues as a percentage of
total tax revenues), I found a strong and
'AS Musgrave suggested to me, the result is likely to statistically significant negative association.
depend critically on the arrangement of preferences in Increased fiscal decentralization in this sim-
the tails of the distnbution. Suppose. for example, that ple regression equation was associated with a
the upper tail of the distribution of tastes stretcheb out larger government sector. However, after
quite far. This will have little impact on the outcome
under centralized decision making, since the distribution controlling for the effect of the level of in-
of the tail has no effect on the median voter. Under a come on the size of government (i.e.,
more decentrali7,ed system, however, these high de- Wagner's "Law"), the relationship between
manders rnight reside together in a jurisdiction with an the two variables of interest became much
extraordinarily high lekel of output. Musgrave conjec-
tures that the tail on the high side might be expected to weaker: the sign remained negative but was
be the Inore skewed so that. ceterrs purrbur. the budget not significantly different from zero at the
is likely to be larger under decentralization. usual confidence levels. This earlier work thus
750 T H L A M E R I C A N ECONOMIC R E V I E U' S E P T E M B E R 1985

does not support the Brennan-Buchanan those states with a more decentralized fiscal
model of Leviathan; in none of the statistical structure should have a smaller state-local
tests did the results suggest that fiscal de- sector.
centralization was significantly associated The testing procedure will be to take as
with a relatively small public sector. the null hypothesis the proposition that
In view of the renewed interest in this government size and the extent of decentral-
issue, I turn in this paper to a more careful ization bear no relation to one another. Since
study of this relationship, making use of two the various views discussed above suggest
quite different bodies of data. First, the In- that the relationship between these two vari-
ternational Monetary Fund (1982) has re- ables could be either negative or positive, it
cently provided an extraordinarily rich set of is appropriate to use a two-tailed test to
information on public finances disaggregated determine if we can reject the null hypothesis
by level of government. From this data, I in favor of the alternatives.
have been able to assemble measures of the
extent of fiscal centralization for a sample of 11. Empirical Results: The State-Local Sector
43 countries. The second sample is quite
different: it consists of the state-local sector As a measure of the "size" of the public
in each of the 48 contiguous states in the sector, the Leviathan view suggests that we
United States. For this second sample, I focus on the level of tax revenue that the
explore the association between the budget- state extracts from the economy. Normaliz-
ary size of state and local government in ing for the level of income, I take as the
each state and the degree of decentralization dependent variable for this part of the study
of the state-local " fisc." aggregate state-local tax receipts in each state
Each of the two samples has its relative as a fraction of personal income (G). The
strengths and weaknesses for purposes of appropriate measure of the extent of de-
this study. The international sample encom- centralization is less clear. In consequence, I
passes much greater diversity in governmen- have used three plausible indices of state-local
tal structure and consequently provides con- decentralization. The first two are fiscal
siderably more variation in the variables of centralization ratios: the state share of state-
interest. There is, in a sense, more to work local general revenues ( R , a revenue mea-
with here. However, this comes at some cost, sure) and the state share of state-local total
for the state-local data are undoubtedly more expenditure (E, an expenditure measure). As
reliable and comparable than those from a third and a nonfiscd index of decentraliza-
different countries; there should, therefore, tion, I have employed the absolute number
be less in the way of measurement error and of local government units in the state ( L ) . 4
differing classifications of budgetary items. This variable is suggested by Brennan and
Finally, there is the issue of the extent of Buchanan's observation that "the ~otential
fiscal mobility. There must typically exist for fiscal exploitation varies inversely with
greater mobility across state than national the number of competing governmental units
boundaries suggesting that fiscal decen- in the inclusive territory" (1980, p. 185).'
tralization, from the Brennan-Buchanan
perspective, should enforce a greater fiscal
"discipline" on state than on national 4 1 experimented with some variants of L involving
governments. In short, the scope for state the normalization of the number of local governments
governments to extract "surplus" from their for land area and for population size. In these forms, its
explanatory power was considerablv reduced compared
residents is probably less than for the central to its unnorrnalized Corm
government. Nevertheless, state governments 5 ~ ann interesting theoretical paper, Dennis Epple
are surely in a much less constrained posi- and Allan Zelenitz. (1981) have explored the extent to
tion than are the myriad of smaller local which cornpetition among local jurisdictions can limit
the power of local governments to extract tax revenues
governments that compete with one another frorn their residents. They find that increasing the num-
within a state's borders. The Leviathan model ber of local jurisdictions limits the scope for such taxa-
would thus predict that, other things equal, tion. but cannot eliminate it entirely.
V O L . 75 NO. 4 OA TES: S E A R C H I N G FOR LEVIA T1IA.V 751

Variable Mean Maximum Minimum SD Variable Correlation


Pair Coefficient t-Statistic

Note: G = total state-local tax receipts as a fraction of


state personal income: R = state share of state-local
general revenues; E = state share of state-local total tends to be associated with a smaller state-
expenditures: L = number of local government units;
and S D = standard deviation. local sector. Although the negative corre-
lation runs counter to the prediction of the
Leviathan model, the association is not suffi-
Table 1 reports the basic summary statis- ciently strong in either case to reject the null
tics for the four variables. State-local tax hypothesis of a zero correlation at a .05
revenues as a fraction of personal income significance level using a two-tailed test.6 In
(G) have a mean value of .12 and vary from contrast, the correlation between G and L,
a high of .18 for New York to a low of .10 the number of local governments, has the
for Ohio. There is considerable diversitv in negative sign implied by the Leviathan hy-
the extent of fiscal concentration: the cen- pothesis; however, the relationship is very
tralization ratio for revenues (R), for exam- weak, and again we cannot reject the null
ple, varies from a maximum of .78 for New hypothesis of a zero correlation. The simple
Mexico to a minimum of .43 for New ham^- rank correlations thus do not support the
shire with a mean value of .58. Likewise, the Leviathan model.
number of local governments ranges from In an attempt to control for other vari-
6,620 in Illinois to only 120 in Rhode Island. ables that influence the size of the public
The sources of the data are listed in the sector, I move next to a multiple-regression
Appendix. I would note that the fiscal data analysis. In the absence of a fully specified
come from the 1977 Census of Governments. model of the economy, I have resorted to a
It seemed advisable to use a year prior to the series of admittedly ad hoc, reduced-form
"disturbances" introduced bv the numerous equations using explanatory variables that
measures enacted under the fiscal-limitation other studies have found to be of significance
movement in the United States. in explaining the size of the government sec-
As a first and admittedly crude examina- tor.7 The regression analysis requires one fur-
tion of the associations among these vari- ther modification: since the dependent vari-
ables, I looked at the simple rank correlation able has a range limited to the zero-to-one
between G and each of the three measures of interval, the basic assumptions of the regres-
state-local decentralization. While this fails
to hold constant for the influence of other
variables, it does give some sense of the hAs an alternative testing procedure. I might have
focused on the Brennan-Buchanan prediction of a posi-
simple relationship between the pairs of vari- tive relationship between G and the measure of fiscal
ables without imposing any a priori assump- centralization and taken it as the alternative to the null
tions concerning the probability distribution hypothesis of no relationship. This procedure would
of the population from which the sample imply a one-tailed test of l I , against [I,. However, as
the regression results will make clear, thls form of test
was drawn. Table 2 reports the value of would not alter the basic findings.
the Spearman rank correlation coefficient ' ~ l t h o u ~Ih am unhappy with my inability to derive
(Spearman's rho) between G and each of the formally the equation to be estimated frorn a fully
decentralization measures and the associated specified structural model. I would note that the depen-
t-statistic (Sidney Siegel, 1956, p. 202). The dent variable is the ratio of government revenues to
personal income. The complete structural model would
correlation between G and each of the fiscal thus have to determine both the level of government
centralization ratios is negative, indicating budgetary activity and the level of private income-a
that a more centralized state-local sector formidable task.
T H E AMERICAN ECONOMIC RE VIEW SEPTEMBER 1985

Note: The numbers in parentheses below the estimated coefficients are the absolute
values of the t-statistic. An asterisk indicates that the estimated coefficient is statisticall?
significant at the .05 level (using a two-tail test). U = percentage of state's population
residing within Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas (SMSA): P = population (in
millions); Y = state personal income per capita: I = intergovernmental grants as a
percentage of state-local general revenues.

sion model are not satisfied. To correct for services to more densely populated areas.8
this, I have used the logistic transformation There exists a body of theoretical and econo-
to create a new dependent variable whose metric work suggesting that intergovernmen-
value can range over the whole set of real tal grants provide a significant stimulus to
numbers (see, for example, Robert Pindyck expenditures by the recipient. The findings
and Daniel Rubinfeld, 1981, p. 287). Table 3 here are consistent with this. The variable I,
reports the findings for the-transformed G the percentage of state-local general revenues
(denoted G'). The results, incidentally, do that comes from intergovernmental grants,
not differ substantively from those if the has the expected positive coefficient and is
transformation is not used. statistically significant in equation (2R).
The first three eauations in Table 3 are the Of central interest here is the effect of
simple regressions of G ' on each of the mea- including these control variables on the mea-
sures of decentralization. They are roughly sured influence of the decentralization vari-
consistent with the rank correlations, indicat- ables. The fiscal centralization ratios, R and
ing negative associations of G' with R and E, retain their negative sign, but in neither
E. The simple correlation with L is now case can we reject the null hypothesis of no
positive but remains very weak. The next association. The number of local govern-
three equations attempt to control for the ments L now has a negative sign (consistent
influenck of other kev variables on the size of with the Leviathan view) and a somewhat
the public sector. The level of per capita larger t-statistic, but we are likewise unable
income ( Y ) , for example, has a positive and to reject the null hypothesis of no association
significant association with the size of the at the .05 level. The results of the multiple-
public sector (consistent with earlier studies regression analysis do not appear to provide
of Wagner's Law). Population size ( P ) ex-
hibits a postivie sign but is not significantly
different from zero in any of the three equa- ' ~ u b i n f e l d has suggested that the negative and sig-
tions. Next. the extent of urbanization ( U ) is nificant sign of the estimated coefficient of the urbaniza-
negatively ;elated to G' and is statistically tion vanable could be interpreted as providing support
significant in one of the three equations. for Leviathan. The contention is that in more highl?
urbanized areas. the Tiebout process of sorting can
Other things equal, the more urbanized a better work itself out. Thus, more highly urbanized
state, the smaller is its public sector, reflect- states are likely, from this perspective. to be effectively
ing perhaps some economies in providing more decentralized.
VOL. 75 NO. 4 O A T E S : S E A R C H I N G FOR LE VI,4 THA,V 753

real support for either the view that de- TABLE


4-SUMMARY STATISTICS
centralitation constrains the size of the pub-
Variable Mean Maximum Minimum SD
lic sector or that it results in a more ex-
pansive government sector. I would note, (a) World Sample ( N = 43)
moreover, that these findings seem quite G .31 .57
robust. I experimented with several different R .85 .99
E .79 .99
specifications of the multiple-regression equa- (b) Industrial Countries ( N = 18)
tion, including the use of some nonlinear G .42 .57
transformations of the key variables. In a R .76 .96
few instances, the fiscal centralization vari- E .65 .92
(c) Developing Countries ( N = 25)
ables were both negative and statistically sig- G .22 .50
nificant, providing some support for the R .92 .99
Wallis hypothesis. But in no cases did I E .89 .99
find any significant coefficients with the sign
predicted by the Leviathan model.9 .Vote: G = total public revenues as a fraction of G D P :
R = central government share of total government reve-
nue: E = central government share of total public ex-
111. Empirical Results: The World Sample penditure.

The procedures for analyzing the data from


my international sample of 43 countries are and industrialized countries in terms of both
essentially the same as those for the state- the size and structure of the public sector.
local study. First I have computed the Spear- Table 4 presents the summary statistics for
man rank correlation coefficients between a the world sample. The government-size vari-
revenue measure of government size and my able G (here defined as total public revenues
measures of fiscal centralization. And sec- divided by gross domestic product) exhibits
ond, I present estimates of regression equa- considerably more variation than in the set
tions using basically the same control vari- of state-local data. Tax revenues as a fraction
ables as earlier. In addition to results for the of GDP have a mean value of .31 and range
world sample as a whole, I report the esti- from a high of .57 in Sweden to a low of .12
mated equations for two subsamples: a group in Bangledesh. For the international sample,
of 18 industrialized countries (so classified I have onlv fiscal measures of the extent of
by the IMF) and the remaining 25 "develop- centralization: R is the fraction of total gen-
ing" countries. As will become apparent eral revenues going to the central govern-
shortly, there are some striking and im- ment, and E is the fraction of total public
portant differences between the developing expenditure attributable to the central gov-
ernment. For purposes of E, intergovern-
mental grants are excluded from the grantor's
here is a further issue. Since some grant funds take expenditures so that E is the central gov-
a matching form. the level of public spending may ernment's share of total disbursements. As
influence the amount of intergovernmental grants-maid.
Intergovernmental grants ( I ) thus may be taken to be Table 4 indicates, the extent of fiscal
an endogenous variable in the multiple-regression equa- centralization ranges widely w i t h the sam-
tions implying the presence of simultaneous-equation ple, reaching from almost complete central-
bias. Likewise, one can make a case for the endogeneity ization of .99 to a central government share
of the fiscal centralization ratios, R and E. To address
this matter, I reestimated equations ( 2 R ) . (2E), and
of well under one-half.
(2 I.) using the two-stage least squares procedure (ZSLS) Panels (b) and (c) of Table 4 reveal the
and treating I, R , and C as endogenous variables. In dramatic differences between the typical in-
the -7SI.S equations, the estimated coefficient for the dustrialized and developing country. The in-
grant variable remained positive but its t-statistic de- dustrialized countries exhibit both a much
clined somewhat. The estimated coefficients of the
centralization variables ( R , E, and L ) retained their larger size of the public sector (a mean value
negative signs but were not significantly different from of G of .42 compared to .22) and a far less
zero. centralized government sector (a mean of E
7-54 T f f E 4MERICARi E C O N O M I C R E V I E W S E P T E M B E R 1085

of .65 compared to 39). The developing TABLE5-SPEARMAN R A N K CORRELATION


CO~YF~C~ENT
countries are characterized by relatively Correlation
small, but highly centralized, public sectors. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic
A listing of the data and their sources
appears in the Appendix. I have used IMF (a) World Sample
G. R - .39 2.71
data to construct the fiscal centralization G. E - .49 3.60
ratios. From the IMF Government Finance (b) Industrialized Countries
Statistics Yearbook (1982), I included in this G,R - .02 0.08
study every country for which I had reason- G,E -.IS 0.61
able assurance that the data encompassed all (c) Developing Countries
G. R .20 0.98
the relevant levels and units of government. I G, E .12 0.58
computed the centralization ratios for the
most recent year for which data were avail-
able-1980 or 1981 in most cases-but
reaching back as far as 1976 in a few in- (2 E ) are the multiple-regression equations,
stances. This produced the sample of 43 where the control variables are basically the
countries. Regarding the nonfiscal data, I same as in the state-local equations. Withn
have used as a measure of per capita income each of the samples, equation (2R) is virtu-
(in U.S. dollars) the recent estimates by ally identical with (2E), suggesting that it
Robert Summers et al. (1980) from the Inter- makes little difference whether we use a reve-
national Comparison Project of the United nue or expenditure measure of the extent of
Nations. fiscal centralization. For the entire world
Table 5 reports the rank correlation coeffi- sample, the multiple-regression equations
cients and associated t-statistics between G have substantial explanatory power: they can
and R and between G and E for the entire "explain" nearly 80 percent of the variation
world sample and for the two subsamples. in the size of the public sector. In particular,
For the entire set of 43 countries, the rank I find that other things equal, high-income
correlation between the size of the public countries typically have relatively large pub-
sector and the extent of centralization is lic sectors, populous nations tend to have
strongly and significantly negative. A rela- comparatively small government sectors, and
tively decentralized public sector is typically countries that rely heavily on intergovern-
comparatively large. However, this result is mental grants have, on average, large public
misleading. It reflects the fact just noted that sectors. However, the measures of fiscal
the poorer developing countries have small, centralization, R and E, contribute virtually
centralized public sectors, while the in- nothing to the explanatory power of the
dustrialized countries have relatively large equations. The extent of centralization in the
and decentralized governments. When we ex- public sector appears to have little effect on
amine the coefficients for the two subsam- the size of government.''
ples, we find that there is no longer a signifi-
cant relationship between the variables.
Within the subsamples, government size lURrsponding to the empirical findings for the inter-
seems to have little relation to the degree of national sample. Edwin Mills has offered the interesting
centralization in the public sector. suggestion that to measure Leviathan's monopoly power.
Turning next to the regression analysis in the fiscal autonomy of decentralized governments is
probably a better measure than their share of taxes or
Table 6 (where again I make use of the spending. Mills suggests a constitutional variable: the
logistic transformation of G, denoted G'), existence of a federal constitution. Following up on this,
note first that the simple regressions (1R) I find that if I divide the total sample into 8 federal and
and (IE ) confirm the rank-correlation analy- 35 nonfederal countries, the mean size of the public
sis. For the whole sample, G is negatively sector as a fraction of GDP (i.e., G in the earlier
equations) is slightly larger for federal countries. Prob-
and significantly related to both R and E, ably of more relevance. however, within the subsample
but within each subsample, this association of 18 industrialized countries, the mean value of G is
effectively disappears. Equations (2R) and somewhat leas for the 6 federal countries than for the 12
V O L . 75 3 0 . 4 OA TES: SEA RCHrNG FOR LE V I A T H A S 755

(a) World Sample


(1R) G'= 0.8 - 2.0Rt R 2 =.16
(1.3) (2.8)
(1E) G'= 0.6 -1.9E*
(1.6) (3.8)
G ' = - 1.9 + .0003Yt .004P*
- + ,00115' +0.61* +O.lR
(3.7) (5.0) (2.8) (0.4) (2.5) (0.2)
(2E) G'= - 1.9 + , 0 0 0 3 ~ ' .004Pt
- + .COIL' +0.61t +0.1E
(4.6) (5.2) (2.9) (0.4) (2.7) (0.3)
(b) Industrialized Countries
(1R) G' = - 0.3 - .07R
(0.5) (0.1)
(1E) G'= -
,003 -0.5E
(0.0) (0.8)
( 2R ) G'= - 1.8 + .0004Y* - .005P* - .007L' +0.71 + 0.4R
(2.3) (3.0) (3.1) (1.2) (1.8) ( 0 . 5 )
( 2E ) G ' - 1.9 + ,0004Y' - ,005P' - .007L' +0.81t + 0.4E
(2.6) (3.2) (3.2) (1.3) (2.3) (0.7)
(c) Developing Countries
(1R) G'= - 2.2 + 0.9R
(1.8) (0.7)

.Yore: The numbers in parentheses below the estimated coeflicients are the absolute values of the associated t-statistic.
An asterisk indicates that the estimated coeflicient is statistically significant at the .05 level (using a two-tail test):
Y = income per capita in U.S. dollars for 1977; P = population (in millions); L' = percentage of population living in
urban areas; I = intergovernmental grants as a percentage of total government general revenues.

The multiple-regression equations for the


nonfederal nations-a result thai is presumably con- two subsamples tell pretty much the same
sistent with the Leviathan hypothesis. However, in story (except that the t-ratios for the sub-
neither case could a simple te;; for the difference be- of developing countries tend to be
tween the means reject the null hypothesis that the smaller), =he fiscal-centralization
observations come from the same population (at a .95
level of confidence). I also reestimated the regression have positive but the
eauations in Table 6 substituting for the fiscal central- t-ratios remain quite small. Finally, like the
ization ratios a dummy variable-equal to one for those results for the state-local analysis: the find-
countries with a federal constitution and zero othemise. ings for the international sample seem quite
In the multiple regression equations. the estimated
coeficients o n the dummy variable were of negative
robust. The use of a number of alternative
sign. Taking the point estimate for this coeflicient from specifications of the equations and variables
the equation for the industrialized countries. one finds did not alter the substance of the results."
that, ceteri.spurihw-, the value of G for a federal country
is about 5 percentage points less than for a nonfederal
nation. However, in none of the equations was the "AS with the state-local sample, I reestimated the
t-statistic of suficient size to reject the null hypothesis multiple-regression equations using S L S and treating
of n o association. Related to this. Richard Bird (1984) intergovernmental grants ( I ) and the centralization
using a sample of 13 countries from a study by Morris ratios ( R and E ) as endogenous variables. The general
Beck (1981) finds that, over the period 1950-77. the rate pattern of the results remained s~milarto those reported
of growth of real government expenditure in relation to in Table 6 although there was a substantial reduction in
GNP was actually slightly higher in federal than in the t-statistic for the grant variable ( r ) The estimated
nonfederal countries. It seems hard to find any really coefficients for the centralization ratios remained statis-
significant differences here tically insignificant.
756 T H E 4,MERICA ?r E C O N O M I C R E V I E W S E P T E M B E R 198.5

IV. Conclusion Germany (West) Norway


Greece Pakistan
Overall, the results of this study suggest Honduras Panama
that there does not exist a strong, systematic Iceland Paraguay
relationship between the size of government Iran Philippines
and the degree of centralization of the public Ireland South Africa
sector. At the offset, I set forth as the null Israel Spain
hypothesis the proposition that centraliza- Kenya Sweden
tion and the size of government have little to Korea Switzerland
do with one another. We certainly cannot Luxembourg Thailand
reject this proposition from the findings in Malawi Tunisia
any of the samples or subsamples in this Mauritius United Kingdom
study. Mexico United States
What in~plicationscan we draw from all Netherlands Uruguay
this? I would stress that the basic finding New Zealand
does not imply that there is no place in
public economics for the revenue-maximiza- Sources of data for the state-local study:
tion hypothesis. There is, in fact, consider- Fiscal data: 1977 Census of Governments,
able evidence to support budget-maximizing Vol. 4, No. 5 , Tables 23, 24. 35, and 39. The
behavior by public agents in certain sorts of same source was used for total population,
institutional settings (for example, the liter- urban population, number of local govern-
ature on bureaucracy). But it is another mat- ments, and income per capita, but came from
ter to try to characterize the entire public Table 46. The land area, population density,
sector as a monolithic, monopolistic actor and date entered the union is from The
with the sole objective of making the govern- World Almanac.. ., 1980.
ment sector as large as possible. The results,
it seems to me, cast considerable doubt on Sources of data for the international study:
the usefulness of the Leviathan model. If, in Fiscal data: IMF Government Statistics
fact, potentially pervasive revenue-maximiz- Yearbook, Vol. VI, 1982; the income per
ing forces are at work in the public sector, capita: Summers et al., pp. 19-66 (data used
we should expect to see these forces manifest for 1977); GDP: United Nations Yearbook of
themselves in terms of larger budgets where National Accounts Statistics, 1980, Vol. 1 ,
given the opportunity to do so. As Brennan 1982; total population: United Nations De-
and Buchanan suggest, Leviathan will have mographic Yearbook 1981, Table 6 , 1983;
much more scope for action in a relatively urban population was from the same source
centralized public sector. But I seem to find but supplemented by The World Almanac.. . ,
no real difference in outcomes whether 1983.
Leviathan is constrained by decentralization
or not. Perhaps. after all, Leviathan is a
mythical beast. REFERENCES

Beck, Moms, Government Spending, Trends


and Issues, New York: Praeger, 1981.
Sample of countries: Bird, Richard M., "Federal Finance in Com-
parative Perspective," Working Paper No.
Australia Cyprus 84-22, Department of Economics and In-
Austria Denmark stitute for Policy Analysis, University of
Bangledesh Ecuador Toronto, June 1984.
Brazil Ethiopia Brennan, Geoffrey, and Buchanan, James, The
Canada Fiji Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a
Chle Finland Fiscal Constitution, Cambridge; New York:
Costa Rica France Cambridge University Press, 1980.
VOI.. 75 .VO. 4 0 A TES: SEA RCIiING FOR 1.E VIA T f f A.V 757

- and , "Tax Instruments as Siegel, Sidney, Nonparametric Statistics for the


Constraints on the Disposition of Public Behavioral Sciences, New York: McGraw-
Revenues," Journal of Public Economics, Hill, 1956.
June 1978, 9 , 301-18. Summers, Robert, Kravis, Irving and Heston,
and , "Towards a Tax Con- Alan, "International Comparison of Real
stitution for Leviathan," Journal of Public Product and its Composition: 1950-77,"
Economics, December 1977, 8 , 255-73. Review of Income and Wealth, March 1980,
Epple, Dennis and Zelenitz, Allan, "The Impli- Series 26, No. 1, 19-66.
cations of Competition Among Jurisdic- International Monetary Fund, Government Fi-
tions: Does Tiebout Need Politics?," Jour- nance Statistics Yearbook, Vol. VI, Wash-
nal of Political Economy, December 1981, ington: International Monetary Fund,
89, 1197-1217. 1982.
Musgrave, Richard, "Leviathan Cometh-or United Nations, Yearbook of National Accounts
Does He?," in H. Ladd and T. N. Tide- Statistics, 1980, Vol. 1, New York: United
man, eds.. Tax and Expenditure Limita- Nations, 1982.
tions, COUPE Papers on Public Econom- , Demographic Yearbook, 1981, New
ics, 5, Washington: The Urban Institute, York: United Nations, 1983.
1981, 77-120. U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1977 Census of
Oates, Wallace, Fiscal Federalism, New York: Governments. Vol. 4, No. 5: Compendium
Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1972. of Government Finances, Washngton: US-
Pindyck, Robert and Rubinfeld, Daniel, Econo- GPO, August 1979.
metric Models and Economic Forecasts, 2d The World Almanac and Book of Facts, 1980;
ed., New York: McGraw-Hill, 1981. 1983.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 1 of 1 -

You have printed the following article:


Searching for Leviathan: An Empirical Study
Wallace E. Oates
The American Economic Review, Vol. 75, No. 4. (Sep., 1985), pp. 748-757.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198509%2975%3A4%3C748%3ASFLAES%3E2.0.CO%3B2-L

This article references the following linked citations. If you are trying to access articles from an
off-campus location, you may be required to first logon via your library web site to access JSTOR. Please
visit your library's website or contact a librarian to learn about options for remote access to JSTOR.

[Footnotes]

5
The Implications of Competition Among Jurisdictions: Does Tiebout Need Politics?
Dennis Epple; Allan Zelenitz
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 89, No. 6. (Dec., 1981), pp. 1197-1217.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28198112%2989%3A6%3C1197%3ATIOCAJ%3E2.0.CO%3B2-W

References

The Implications of Competition Among Jurisdictions: Does Tiebout Need Politics?


Dennis Epple; Allan Zelenitz
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 89, No. 6. (Dec., 1981), pp. 1197-1217.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28198112%2989%3A6%3C1197%3ATIOCAJ%3E2.0.CO%3B2-W

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.

You might also like