Varian9e - LecturePPTs - Ch21 - Cost Minimization

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 82

Chapter 21

Cost
Minimization
Cost Minimization

uA firm is a cost-minimizer if it
produces any given output level y ³ 0
at smallest possible total cost.
u c(y) denotes the firm’s smallest
possible total cost for producing y
units of output.
u c(y) is the firm’s total cost function.
Cost Minimization

u When the firm faces given input


prices w = (w1,w2,…,wn) the total cost
function will be written as
c(w1,…,wn,y).
The Cost-Minimization Problem

u Consider a firm using two inputs to


make one output.
u The production function is
y = f(x1,x2).
u Take the output level y ³ 0 as given.
u Given the input prices w1 and w2, the
cost of an input bundle (x1,x2) is
w1x1 + w2x2.
The Cost-Minimization Problem

u Forgiven w1, w2 and y, the firm’s


cost-minimization problem is to
solve min w 1x1 + w 2x 2
x1 ,x 2 ³ 0
subject to f ( x1 , x 2 ) = y.
The Cost-Minimization Problem
u The levels x1*(w1,w2,y) and x2*(w1,w2,y)
in the least-costly input bundle are the
firm’s conditional demands for inputs
1 and 2.
u The (smallest possible) total cost for
producing y output units is therefore
c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
+ w 2x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ).
Conditional Input Demands

u Given w1, w2 and y, how is the least


costly input bundle located?
u And how is the total cost function
computed?
Iso-cost Lines

uA curve that contains all of the input


bundles that cost the same amount
is an iso-cost curve.
u E.g., given w1 and w2, the $100 iso-
cost line has the equation
w 1x1 + w 2x 2 = 100.
Iso-cost Lines

u Generally,given w1 and w2, the


equation of the $c iso-cost line is
w 1x1 + w 2x 2 = c
i.e. w c
x 2 = - 1 x1 + .
w2 w2

u Slope is - w1/w2.
Iso-cost Lines
x2

c” º w1x1+w2x2

c’ º w1x1+w2x2

c’ < c”

x1
Iso-cost Lines
x2 Slopes = -w1/w2.

c” º w1x1+w2x2

c’ º w1x1+w2x2

c’ < c”

x1
The y’-Output Unit Isoquant
x2
All input bundles yielding y’ units
of output. Which is the cheapest?

f(x1,x2) º y’
x1
The Cost-Minimization Problem
x2
All input bundles yielding y’ units
of output. Which is the cheapest?

f(x1,x2) º y’
x1
The Cost-Minimization Problem
x2
All input bundles yielding y’ units
of output. Which is the cheapest?

f(x1,x2) º y’
x1
The Cost-Minimization Problem
x2
All input bundles yielding y’ units
of output. Which is the cheapest?

f(x1,x2) º y’
x1
The Cost-Minimization Problem
x2
All input bundles yielding y’ units
of output. Which is the cheapest?

x2*
f(x1,x2) º y’
x1* x1
The Cost-Minimization Problem
At an interior cost-min input bundle:
x2 * *
(a) f ( x1 , x 2 ) = y ¢

x2*
f(x1,x2) º y’
x1* x1
The Cost-Minimization Problem
At an interior cost-min input bundle:
x2 * *
(a) f ( x1 , x 2 ) = y ¢ and
(b) slope of isocost = slope of
isoquant

x2*
f(x1,x2) º y’
x1* x1
The Cost-Minimization Problem
At an interior cost-min input bundle:
x2 * *
(a) f ( x1 , x 2 ) = y ¢ and
(b) slope of isocost = slope of
isoquant; i.e.
w1 MP1
- = TRS = - at ( x*1 , x*2 ).
w2 MP2
x2*
f(x1,x2) º y’
x1* x1
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
uA firm’s Cobb-Douglas production
function is
y = f ( x1 , x 2 ) = x11/ 3x 22/ 3 .

u Inputprices are w1 and w2.


u What are the firm’s conditional input
demand functions?
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
At the input bundle (x1*,x2*) which minimizes
the cost of producing y output units:
(a) y = ( x* )1/ 3 ( x* ) 2/ 3 and
1 2
(b)
w1 ¶ y / ¶ x1 (1 / 3)( x*1 ) -2/ 3 ( x*2 ) 2/ 3
- =- =-
w2 ¶ y / ¶ x2 ( 2 / 3)( x*1 )1/ 3 ( x*2 ) -1/ 3
x*2
=- .
2x*1
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
w x*
* 1/ 3 * 2/ 3 1 = 2 .
(a) y = ( x1 ) ( x 2 ) (b)
w 2 2x*1
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
w x*
* 1/ 3 * 2/ 3 1 = 2 .
(a) y = ( x1 ) ( x 2 ) (b)
w 2 2x*1
* 2w 1 *
From (b), x 2 = x1 .
w2
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
w x*
* 1/ 3 * 2/ 3 1 = 2 .
(a) y = ( x1 ) ( x 2 ) (b)
w 2 2x*1
* 2w 1 *
From (b), x 2 = x1 .
w2
Now substitute into (a) to get
2/ 3
* 1/ 3 æ 2w 1 * ö
y = ( x1 ) ç x ÷
è w 2 1ø
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
w x*
* 1/ 3 * 2/ 3 1 = 2 .
(a) y = ( x1 ) ( x 2 ) (b)
w 2 2x*1
* 2w 1 *
From (b), x 2 = x1 .
w2
Now substitute into (a) to get
2/ 3 2/ 3
* 1/ 3 æ 2w 1 * ö æ 2w 1 ö
y = ( x1 ) ç x1 ÷ =ç ÷ x*1 .
è w2 ø è w2 ø
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
w x*
* 1/ 3 * 2/ 3 1 = 2 .
(a) y = ( x1 ) ( x 2 ) (b)
w 2 2x*1
* 2w 1 *
From (b), x 2 = x1 .
w2
Now substitute into (a) to get
2/ 3 2/ 3
* 1/ 3 æ 2w 1 * ö æ 2w 1 ö
y = ( x1 ) ç x1 ÷ =ç ÷ x*1 .
è w2 ø è w2 ø
2/ 3
æ w ö
So x*1 = ç 2 ÷ y is the firm’s conditional
è 2w 1 ø
demand for input 1.
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization 2/ 3
2w 1 * æ w ö
Since x*2 = x1 and x*1 = ç 2 ÷ y
w2 è 2w 1 ø
2/ 3 1/ 3
2w 1 æ w 2 ö æ 2w 1 ö
x*2 = ç ÷ y=ç ÷ y
w 2 è 2w 1 ø è w2 ø
is the firm’s conditional demand for input 2.
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
So the cheapest input bundle yielding y
output units is

(x*1 ( w1 , w 2 , y), x*2 ( w1 , w 2 , y))


æ æ w ö 2/ 3 æ 2w ö 1/ 3 ö
= çç 2 ÷ y, ç 1
÷ y÷÷ .
ç è 2w 1 ø è w 2ø
è ø
Conditional Input Demand Curves
Fixed w1 and w2.

y¢¢¢
y¢¢

Conditional Input Demand Curves
y
Fixed w1 and w2.

y x*2 ( y¢ ) x*2

y¢¢¢
x*2 ( y¢ ) y¢¢ y¢

x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1
Conditional Input Demand Curves
y
Fixed w1 and w2.

y¢¢

y x*2 ( y¢ ) x*2
x*2 ( y¢¢ )

x*2 ( y¢¢ )
y¢¢¢ y¢¢
x*2 ( y¢ ) y¢¢ y¢

x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1
x*1 ( y¢¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢ )
Conditional Input Demand Curves
y
Fixed w1 and w2.
y¢¢¢
y¢¢

y x*2 ( y¢ ) x*2 ( y¢¢¢ ) x*2


*
x*2 ( y¢¢¢ ) x 2 ( y¢¢ )
y¢¢¢
x*2 ( y¢¢ )
y¢¢¢ y¢¢
x*2 ( y¢ ) y¢¢ y¢

x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢¢ ) x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢¢ ) x*1
x*1 ( y¢¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢ )
Conditional Input Demand Curves
y
Fixed w1 and w2.
y¢¢¢
y¢¢
output

expansion
path y x*2 ( y¢ ) x*2 ( y¢¢¢ ) x*2
*
x*2 ( y¢¢¢ ) x 2 ( y¢¢ )
y¢¢¢
x*2 ( y¢¢ )
y¢¢¢ y¢¢
x*2 ( y¢ ) y¢¢ y¢

x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢¢ ) x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢¢ ) x*1
x*1 ( y¢¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢ )
Conditional Input Demand Curves
y Cond. demand
Fixed w1 and w2. for
y¢¢¢ input 2
y¢¢
output

expansion
path y x*2 ( y¢ ) x*2 ( y¢¢¢ ) x*2
*
x*2 ( y¢¢¢ ) x 2 ( y¢¢ )
y¢¢¢ Cond.
x*2 ( y¢¢ ) demand
y¢¢¢ y¢¢
x*2 ( y¢ ) y¢¢ for

y¢ input 1
x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢¢ ) x*1 ( y¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢¢ ) x*1
x*1 ( y¢¢ ) x*1 ( y¢¢ )
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
For the production function
y = f ( x1 , x 2 ) = x11 / 3x 22 / 3
the cheapest input bundle yielding y output
units is
(x*1 ( w1 , w 2 , y), x*2 ( w1 , w 2 , y))
æ æ w ö 2/ 3 æ 2w ö 1/ 3 ö
= çç 2 ÷ y, ç 1
÷ y÷÷ .
ç è 2w 1 ø è w 2ø
è ø
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
So the firm’s total cost function is
c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) + w 2x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
So the firm’s total cost function is
c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) + w 2x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
2/ 3 1/ 3
æ w ö æ 2w 1 ö
= w1 ç 2 ÷ y + w2ç ÷ y
è 2w 1 ø è w2 ø
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
So the firm’s total cost function is
c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) + w 2x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
2/ 3 1/ 3
æ w ö æ 2w 1 ö
= w1 ç 2 ÷ y + w2ç ÷ y
è 2w 1 ø è w2 ø
2/ 3
æ 1ö
=ç ÷ w 11/ 3 w 22/ 3 y + 21/ 3 w 11/ 3 w 22/ 3 y
è 2ø
A Cobb-Douglas Example of
Cost Minimization
So the firm’s total cost function is
c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) + w 2x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
2/ 3 1/ 3
æ w ö æ 2w 1 ö
= w1 ç 2 ÷ y + w2ç ÷ y
è 2w 1 ø è w2 ø
2/ 3
æ 1ö
=ç ÷ w 11/ 3 w 22/ 3 y + 21/ 3 w 11/ 3 w 22/ 3 y
è 2ø
1/ 3
æ w 1w 22 ö
= 3çç ÷÷ y.
è 4 ø
A Perfect Complements Example
of Cost Minimization
u The firm’s production function is
y = min{4x1 , x 2 }.

u Input prices w1 and w2 are given.


u What are the firm’s conditional
demands for inputs 1 and 2?
u What is the firm’s total cost
function?
A Perfect Complements Example
of Cost Minimization
x2
4x1 = x2

min{4x1,x2} º y’

x1
A Perfect Complements Example
of Cost Minimization
x2
4x1 = x2

min{4x1,x2} º y’

x1
A Perfect Complements Example
of Cost Minimization
x2
4x1 = x2 Where is the least costly
input bundle yielding
y’ output units?

min{4x1,x2} º y’

x1
A Perfect Complements Example
of Cost Minimization
x2
4x1 = x2 Where is the least costly
input bundle yielding
y’ output units?

x2* = y min{4x1,x2} º y’

x1* x1
= y/4
A Perfect Complements Example
of Cost Minimization
The firm’s production function is
y = min{ 4x1 , x 2 }
and the conditional input demands are
y
x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = *
and x 2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = y.
4
A Perfect Complements Example
of Cost Minimization
The firm’s production function is
y = min{ 4x1 , x 2 }
and the conditional input demands are
y
x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = *
and x 2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = y.
4
So the firm’s total cost function is
c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
+ w 2x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
A Perfect Complements Example
of Cost Minimization
The firm’s production function is
y = min{ 4x1 , x 2 }
and the conditional input demands are
y
x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = *
and x 2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = y.
4
So the firm’s total cost function is
c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
+ w 2x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
y æw ö
= w 1 + w 2 y = ç 1 + w 2 ÷ y.
4 è 4 ø
Average Total Production Costs

u Forpositive output levels y, a firm’s


average total cost of producing y
units is c( w 1 , w 2 , y )
AC( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = .
y
Returns-to-Scale and Av. Total
Costs
u The returns-to-scale properties of a
firm’s technology determine how
average production costs change with
output level.
u Our firm is presently producing y’
output units.
u How does the firm’s average
production cost change if it instead
produces 2y’ units of output?
Constant Returns-to-Scale and
Average Total Costs
u Ifa firm’s technology exhibits
constant returns-to-scale then
doubling its output level from y’ to
2y’ requires doubling all input levels.
Constant Returns-to-Scale and
Average Total Costs
u Ifa firm’s technology exhibits
constant returns-to-scale then
doubling its output level from y’ to
2y’ requires doubling all input levels.
u Total production cost doubles.
Constant Returns-to-Scale and
Average Total Costs
u Ifa firm’s technology exhibits
constant returns-to-scale then
doubling its output level from y’ to
2y’ requires doubling all input levels.
u Total production cost doubles.
u Average production cost does not
change.
Decreasing Returns-to-Scale and
Average Total Costs
u Ifa firm’s technology exhibits
decreasing returns-to-scale then
doubling its output level from y’ to
2y’ requires more than doubling all
input levels.
Decreasing Returns-to-Scale and
Average Total Costs
u Ifa firm’s technology exhibits
decreasing returns-to-scale then
doubling its output level from y’ to
2y’ requires more than doubling all
input levels.
u Total production cost more than
doubles.
Decreasing Returns-to-Scale and
Average Total Costs
u Ifa firm’s technology exhibits
decreasing returns-to-scale then
doubling its output level from y’ to
2y’ requires more than doubling all
input levels.
u Total production cost more than
doubles.
u Average production cost increases.
Increasing Returns-to-Scale and
Average Total Costs
u Ifa firm’s technology exhibits
increasing returns-to-scale then
doubling its output level from y’ to
2y’ requires less than doubling all
input levels.
Increasing Returns-to-Scale and
Average Total Costs
u Ifa firm’s technology exhibits
increasing returns-to-scale then
doubling its output level from y’ to
2y’ requires less than doubling all
input levels.
u Total production cost less than
doubles.
Increasing Returns-to-Scale and
Average Total Costs
u Ifa firm’s technology exhibits
increasing returns-to-scale then
doubling its output level from y’ to
2y’ requires less than doubling all
input levels.
u Total production cost less than
doubles.
u Average production cost decreases.
Returns-to-Scale and Av. Total
Costs
$/output unit

AC(y) decreasing r.t.s.

constant r.t.s.

increasing r.t.s.

y
Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs

u What does this imply for the shapes


of total cost functions?
Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs
Av. cost increases with y if the firm’s
$ technology exhibits decreasing r.t.s.

c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’


= AC(2y’).
Slope = c(y’)/y’
= AC(y’).
c(y’)

y’ 2y’ y
Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs
Av. cost increases with y if the firm’s
$ technology exhibits decreasing r.t.s.
c(y)
c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’
= AC(2y’).
Slope = c(y’)/y’
= AC(y’).
c(y’)

y’ 2y’ y
Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs
Av. cost decreases with y if the firm’s
$ technology exhibits increasing r.t.s.
c(2y’)
Slope = c(2y’)/2y’
c(y’) = AC(2y’).
Slope = c(y’)/y’
= AC(y’).

y’ 2y’ y
Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs
Av. cost decreases with y if the firm’s
$ technology exhibits increasing r.t.s.
c(y)
c(2y’)
Slope = c(2y’)/2y’
c(y’) = AC(2y’).
Slope = c(y’)/y’
= AC(y’).

y’ 2y’ y
Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs
Av. cost is constant when the firm’s
$ technology exhibits constant r.t.s.
c(2y’) c(y)
=2c(y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’
= 2c(y’)/2y’
= c(y’)/y’
c(y’)
so
AC(y’) = AC(2y’).

y’ 2y’ y
Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
u In the long-run a firm can vary all of
its input levels.
u Consider a firm that cannot change
its input 2 level from x2’ units.
u How does the short-run total cost of
producing y output units compare to
the long-run total cost of producing y
units of output?
Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
u Thelong-run cost-minimization
problem is xmin w1 x1 + w 2 x 2
,x ³0
1 2

subject to f (x1, x 2 ) = y.

u The short-run
� cost-minimization
problem is min w1 x1 + w 2 x¢2
x ³0 1 �
subject to f (x1, x¢2 ) = y.


Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
u The short-run cost-min. problem is the
long-run problem subject to the extra
constraint that x2 = x2’.
u If the long-run choice for x2 was x2’
then the extra constraint x2 = x2’ is not
really a constraint at all and so the
long-run and short-run total costs of
producing y output units are the same.
Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
u The short-run cost-min. problem is
therefore the long-run problem subject to
the extra constraint that x2 = x2’.
u But, if the long-run choice for x2 ¹ x2’
then the extra constraint x2 = x2’ prevents
the firm in this short-run from achieving
its long-run production cost, causing the
short-run total cost to exceed the long-
run total cost of producing y output units.
Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
y ¢¢¢
x2 Consider three output levels.
y ¢¢

x1
Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
y ¢¢¢ In the long-run when the firm
x2
is free to choose both x1 and
y ¢¢
x2, the least-costly input
y¢ bundles are ...

x1
Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
y ¢¢¢
x2 Long-run
y ¢¢ output
expansion
y¢ path
x ¢¢¢
2
x ¢¢2
x ¢2

x1¢ x1¢¢ x1¢¢¢ x1


Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
Long-run costs are:
y ¢¢¢ c( y ¢ ) = w 1x1¢ + w 2x ¢2
x2 Long-run c( y ¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢ + w 2x ¢¢¢
2
y ¢¢ output c( y ¢¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢¢+ w 2x ¢¢¢
2
expansion
y¢ path
x ¢¢¢
2
x ¢¢2
x ¢2

x1¢ x1¢¢ x1¢¢¢ x1


Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
u Now suppose the firm becomes
subject to the short-run constraint
that x1 = x1”.
Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
Long-run costs are:
y ¢¢¢ Short-run c( y ¢ ) = w 1x1¢ + w 2x ¢2
x2 output c( y ¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢ + w 2x ¢¢¢
2
y ¢¢ expansion
c( y ¢¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢¢+ w 2x ¢¢¢
2
path

x ¢¢¢
2
x ¢¢2
x ¢2

x1¢ x1¢¢ x1¢¢¢ x1


Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
Long-run costs are:
y ¢¢¢ Short-run c( y ¢ ) = w 1x1¢ + w 2x ¢2
x2 output c( y ¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢ + w 2x ¢¢¢
2
y ¢¢ expansion
c( y ¢¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢¢+ w 2x ¢¢¢
2
path

x ¢¢¢
2
x ¢¢2
x ¢2

x1¢ x1¢¢ x1¢¢¢ x1


Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
Long-run costs are:
y ¢¢¢ Short-run c( y ¢ ) = w 1x1¢ + w 2x ¢2
x2 output c( y ¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢ + w 2x ¢¢¢
2
y ¢¢ expansion
c( y ¢¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢¢+ w 2x ¢¢¢
2
path
y¢ Short-run costs are:
c s ( y ¢ ) > c( y ¢ )
x ¢¢¢
2
x ¢¢2
x ¢2

x1¢ x1¢¢ x1¢¢¢ x1


Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
Long-run costs are:
y ¢¢¢ Short-run c( y ¢ ) = w 1x1¢ + w 2x ¢2
x2 output c( y ¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢ + w 2x ¢¢¢
2
y ¢¢ expansion
c( y ¢¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢¢+ w 2x ¢¢¢
2
path
y¢ Short-run costs are:
c s ( y ¢ ) > c( y ¢ )
x ¢¢¢
2 c s ( y ¢¢ ) = c( y ¢¢ )
x ¢¢2
x ¢2

x1¢ x1¢¢ x1¢¢¢ x1


Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
Long-run costs are:
y ¢¢¢ Short-run c( y ¢ ) = w 1x1¢ + w 2x ¢2
x2 output c( y ¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢ + w 2x ¢¢¢
2
y ¢¢ expansion
c( y ¢¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢¢+ w 2x ¢¢¢
2
path
y¢ Short-run costs are:
c s ( y ¢ ) > c( y ¢ )
x ¢¢¢
2 c s ( y ¢¢ ) = c( y ¢¢ )
x ¢¢2
x ¢2

x1¢ x1¢¢ x1¢¢¢ x1


Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
Long-run costs are:
y ¢¢¢ Short-run c( y ¢ ) = w 1x1¢ + w 2x ¢2
x2 output c( y ¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢ + w 2x ¢¢¢
2
y ¢¢ expansion
c( y ¢¢¢ ) = w 1x1¢¢¢+ w 2x ¢¢¢
2
path
y¢ Short-run costs are:
c s ( y ¢ ) > c( y ¢ )
x ¢¢¢
2 c s ( y ¢¢ ) = c( y ¢¢ )
x ¢¢2 c s ( y ¢¢¢ ) > c( y ¢¢¢ )
x ¢2

x1¢ x1¢¢ x1¢¢¢ x1


Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
u Short-run total cost exceeds long-run
total cost except for the output level
where the short-run input level
restriction is the long-run input level
choice.
u This says that the long-run total cost
curve always has one point in
common with any particular short-
run total cost curve.
Short-Run & Long-Run Total
Costs
A short-run total cost curve always has
$
one point in common with the long-run
total cost curve, and is elsewhere higher
than the long-run total cost curve.
cs(y)
c(y)
F=
w 2x ¢¢2
y¢ y ¢¢ y ¢¢¢ y

You might also like