Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Accounting, Organizations and Society


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/aos

Using negotiated budgets for planning and performance


evaluation: An experimental study q
Markus C. Arnold a, Robert M. Gillenkirch b,⇑
a
Institute for Accounting, University of Bern, 3012 Bern, Switzerland
b
Business Department, University of Osnabrück, 49069 Osnabrück, Germany

a b s t r a c t

Budgets are often simultaneously used for the conflicting purposes of planning and perfor-
mance evaluation. While economic theory suggests that firms should use separate budgets
for conflicting purposes this contrasts with existing evidence that firms rarely do so. We
address two open questions related to these observations in an experiment. Specifically,
we investigate how a planning task that is in conflict with the performance evaluation task
affects behavior in budget negotiations and their outcomes. Additionally, we analyze
whether a single budget can be effectively used for both purposes compared to two sepa-
rate budgets. We develop theory to predict that adding a planning task that is in conflict
with the superior’s performance evaluation task increases the subordinate’s cooperation
in and after the negotiation of a performance evaluation budget. Moreover, we predict that
subordinate cooperation increases even more when the superior is restricted to use a single
budget for both purposes. Our results broadly support our hypotheses. Specifically, we find
that when budgets are used for both planning and performance evaluation, this increases
the subordinate’s budget proposals during the negotiation and his performance after the
negotiation. These effects tend to be even larger when the superior is restricted to a single
budget rather than separate budgets for planning and performance evaluation, particularly
with respect to subordinate performance. In our experimental setting, the benefits of
increased subordinate cooperation even more than offset the loss in flexibility from the
superior’s restriction to a single budget. The results of this study add to the understanding
of the interdependencies of conflicting budgeting purposes and contribute to explain why
firms often use a single budget for multiple purposes.
Ó 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Introduction

Budgeting is one of firms’ most important coordination


q
The authors greatly appreciate the helpful comments and suggestions and control mechanisms (Luft & Shields, 2003; Merchant &
from Mike Shields (editor) and two anonymous reviewers, as well as from
Van der Stede, 2011). Usually, budgeting functions are
Ramji Balakrishnan, Lynn Hannan, Tim Mitchell, Steve Salterio, Wim van
der Stede, Ivo Tafkov, seminar participants at the Universities of
described as (1) operational planning and coordination,
Jönköping, Hannover, and Bern, and participants of the 2010 Management (2) motivation and performance evaluation, and (3) goal
Accounting Section midyear meeting, the 2009 AAA annual meeting, and communication and strategy formulation (Atkinson,
the 2009 and 2010 EAA annual meetings. We also thank Achim Hendriks Kaplan, Matsumura, & Young, 2011; Horngren, Datar, &
for his research assistance.
⇑ Corresponding author. Tel.: +49 (0) 541 969 2730. Rajan, 2011). Thus, budgeting functions encompass both
E-mail addresses: markus.arnold@iuc.unibe.ch (M. C. Arnold),
decision-making and control-oriented purposes of man-
robert.gillenkirch@uni-osnabrueck.de (R. M. Gillenkirch). agement accounting information. As these purposes often

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.aos.2015.02.002
0361-3682/Ó 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
2 M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16

conflict (Hopwood, 1972; Libby & Lindsay, 2010; Sprinkle, monetary incentives for planning accuracy when the sub-
2003), budget-setting can present firms with major ordinate is not aware of the superior’s planning task.
challenges. However, as in their research setting, the subordinate uni-
Our study investigates how a planning task that con- laterally determines the cost budget they do not investigate
flicts with the performance evaluation task affects behav- budget negotiations. Moreover, as the superior has no
ior in budget negotiations and their outcomes. In our authority in determining the performance evaluation bud-
setting, the two tasks are in conflict because the need to get, planning and control are unlikely to be perceived as
provide subordinates with sufficient financial incentives conflicting tasks for the superior in their setting.
counters the need for accurate planning and, thus, the In our setting, the budgeting purposes of performance
two budgets should be set to different levels. We further evaluation and planning are in conflict from the superior’s
analyze whether a single budget can be effectively used perspective because the need to provide subordinates with
for the two conflicting tasks as opposed to a separate bud- sufficient incentives to expend effort counters the need for
get for each task because this restriction may cause more accurate planning. We compare a condition with only a
cooperation in and after the budget negotiations. performance evaluation task to two conditions with an
Surprisingly little is known about the simultaneous use additional planning task. In all three conditions, superior
of budgets for different purposes and the conflicts arising and subordinate negotiate over the budget that is used
from their interaction (Sprinkle, 2003). Prior literature sug- for performance evaluation. In the first planning condition,
gests that the budgeting purposes are not determined the superior can set a separate second budget for the plan-
independent of organizational characteristics (e.g., ning task after the negotiation over the performance eval-
Moores & Yuen, 2001) and Shields and Shields (1998) find uation budget. In the second planning condition, the
that uses of budget participation for decision-making and superior is restricted to use a single budget for both tasks,
control-oriented purposes are caused by different antece- i.e., the planning budget automatically equals the perfor-
dents. However, most prior studies have focused on perfor- mance evaluation budget. As we focus on the subordinate’s
mance evaluation in isolation and have analyzed motives beyond monetary incentives, the subordinate’s
managers’ slack creating incentives (Brown, Evans, & compensation function is never affected by the superior’s
Moser, 2009; Shields & Shields, 1998; Sprinkle, 2003).1 planning task.
Only recently have studies begun to more closely analyze Because performance evaluation and planning are in
interactions between budgeting functions. For example, conflict, budgets should be set to different levels in our set-
research suggests that flexible budgets may be beneficial ting, and so a single budget cannot be used for both tasks
for planning but detrimental for performance evaluation optimally. The superior therefore should be better off
(Arnold & Artz, 2015; Ekholm & Wallin, 2011; Hansen & when she can use separate budgets unless this entails sig-
Van der Stede, 2004). Additionally, increased budget diffi- nificant additional costs (Baiman, 1982; Barrett & Fraser,
culty may help with performance evaluation but hurt the 1977; Churchill, 1984; Hopwood, 1972). This implication,
communication function of budgets (Hansen & Van der however, contrasts with empirical evidence (Merchant &
Stede, 2004). In contrast, positive externalities may arise Manzoni, 1989; Umapathy, 1987) that firms rarely use dif-
when a firm combines the resource-allocation and ferent budgets for different purposes.
performance-evaluation functions because a subordinate’s We develop theory to predict that with the additional
monetary incentives to compete for resources can counter- planning task, the subordinate is likely to perceive that
act his monetary incentives to create slack arising from the superior has a more complex task and to have an
performance evaluation (Fisher, Maines, Peffer, & Sprinkle, increased interpersonal accountability to the superior,
2002). and that this makes the subordinate more cooperative in
While the conflict between different budgetary purposes the budget negotiation. We further predict that increased
has been analyzed from an economic perspective (e.g., subordinate cooperation extends to subordinate behavior
Baiman & Evans, 1983; Christensen, 1982) little is known after the negotiation, leading to an increase in subordinate
about their behavioral effects beyond monetary incentives. performance in the presence of a planning task, particu-
Our study aims to contribute to the understanding of the larly after negotiation impasse. Finally, we also develop
effects of budgets used for performance evaluation vs. per- theory to predict that the superior’s restriction to a single
formance evaluation and planning. Fisher, Mitchell, Peffer, budget can further increase the subordinate’s cooperation
and Webb (2014a) investigate subordinates’ budget reports during and after the negotiation.
when the superior has a planning task and, in addition to the In our experiment, participants assume the role of
division’s net profit, receives payoffs from accurate fore- either a superior or a subordinate and negotiate a budget
casts. They find that subordinates make higher cost reports target for the subordinate’s performance evaluation. After
when they become aware of the superiors’ additional pay- the negotiation, subordinates perform a real-effort task.
offs from increased accuracy but do not participate in them. The experiment uses three settings: a baseline setting
In a related paper, Fisher, Mitchell, Peffer, and Webb where performance evaluation is the sole purpose of bud-
(2014b) analyze how a superior’s reliance on cost reports geting, a setting with separate budgets for planning and
and her planning task performance depend on her performance evaluation, and a setting with a single budget
for both tasks. In the separate-budgets condition, planning
1
Govindarajan (1986) measures both decision-making and control
is operationalized by making the superior forecast the sub-
dimensions of budgeting but collapses them into a single measure of firm ordinate’s actual performance. In the single-budget condi-
performance. tion, the performance evaluation budget simultaneously
M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16 3


serves as the superior’s forecast. In both planning condi- DXF if X 6 BEval
PSuper ¼ ð2Þ
tions, the superior has to bear planning costs if actual per- D  X  ½F þ A  ðX  BEval Þ if X > BEval
formance deviates from predicted performance.
Our results support our predictions. First, the superior’s where F is the subordinate’s fixed wage. X is the firm’s out-
planning task increases subordinate cooperation during put, which equals the subordinate’s actual performance. D
the negotiation as evidenced by increased initial sub- is the contribution margin per unit of output, and conse-
ordinate budget proposals. Second, after controlling for quently D  X is the firm’s contribution margin that is
monetary incentives, subordinate performance increases assigned to the superior. A is the bonus coefficient per unit
in the presence of the planning task, particularly following of output for exceeding the performance evaluation bud-
negotiation impasse. Third, when comparing the two plan- get, and A  (X  BEval) is the subordinate’s bonus if X
ning conditions, the effects on subordinate behavior tend exceeds BEval. The subordinate’s performance is a function
to be even larger when the superior is restricted to a single of his ability and effort, and the superior is not informed
budget, particularly with respect to performance. about her subordinate’s ability. Thus, when negotiating
The paper makes two primary contributions to the the budget with the subordinate, the superior is uncertain
literature. First, to our knowledge, this is the first study about the subordinate’s performance potential.
focusing on the effects of the use of budgets for conflict- We also investigate two conditions in which the super-
ing purposes on budget negotiations and their outcomes. ior has an additional planning task and her planning bud-
We thus respond to the call to investigate the interdepen- get, BPlan, is determined after the negotiation of BEval. BPlan
dencies stemming from the simultaneous use of manage- represents a forecast of actual performance, and deviations
rial accounting information for decision-making and between predicted and actual performance lead to plan-
control (Sprinkle, 2003). Our results provide evidence that ning costs for the superior. With the planning task, the
a superior’s additional task can affect subordinates superior receives the following payoff:
beyond monetary incentives in that subordinates coop- 
erate more as their impact on the superior’s outcome D  X  F  C  jX  BPlan j if X 6 BEval
Psuper ¼ ð3Þ
increases. Thus, cooperation in budget negotiations is D  X  ½F þ A  ðX  BEval Þ  C  jX  BPlan j if X > BEval
influenced not only by decreases in social distance
where BPlan is the superior’s forecast of actual performance
(Fisher, Frederickson, & Peffer, 2006) or by the informa-
X in the production period and C is the coefficient deter-
tion distribution between the parties (Chalos & Haka,
mining the superior’s planning costs when BPlan does not
1989) but also by the set of tasks and the restrictions
perfectly predict actual output. BPlan reflects a planned out-
the superior has to deal with.
put, such as the prediction of a sales volume for the instal-
Second, our findings help to reconcile the observation
lation of a production capacity, for procurement or supply-
that firms often use a single budget for multiple purposes
chain coordination (Atkinson et al., 2011, chap. 10). We
when economic theory predicts that they would employ
study both a condition in which the superior can set a
separate budgets for planning and control when these pur-
separate second budget for the planning task after the
poses are in conflict. Our results suggest that the benefits
negotiation over the performance evaluation budget
from increased subordinate cooperation may compensate
(‘‘separate-budgets condition’’) and a condition in which
for the loss in flexibility from using a single budget. Thus,
the superior must use a single budget for both tasks so that
in practice, the use of separate budgets vs. a single budget
the planning budget automatically equals the performance
will depend on the relative impacts of the two effects,
evaluation budget (BEval = BPlan: ‘‘single-budget condition’’).
which implies that firms can profit by taking into account
Planning costs emerge from both under- and over-fulfill-
the effects of social preferences when designing manage-
ment of BPlan. If the planning budget is under-fulfilled, then
ment control systems (Church, Hannan, & Kuang, 2012;
planning costs can be interpreted as, for example, costs of
Hannan, Rankin, & Towry, 2010).
unused capacity. If budgets are over-fulfilled, then extra
costs from operating at a level higher than expected arise,
Setting and benchmark analysis such as, for example, running machines at higher speeds or
acquiring additional production capacity externally.2
Setting According to the superior’s payoff function (3), planning
costs are symmetric in that any deviation of actual output
Our setting is a modification of the budget negotiation X from planned output BPlan, whether positive or negative,
setting of Fisher, Frederickson, and Peffer (2000). We study is equally costly to the superior.3 We assume that
superior-subordinate dyads in which the subordinate pro-
vides real effort. Prior to this effort, the parties negotiate a 2
Consistent with prior literature (e.g., Balachandran, Balakrishnan, &
budget for the subordinate’s performance evaluation, BEval. Sivaramakrishnan, 1997; Dunbar, 1971; Fisher, Frederickson, & Peffer,
In this baseline setting, the superior has only the perfor- 2002), we refer to the consequences of inaccurate plans as costs because
they represent ex post inefficiencies. Underlying is the perspective that the
mance evaluation task (‘‘performance evaluation-only con-
superior could plan output optimally if the subordinate did not withhold or
dition’’), and subordinate and superior receive the misrepresent private information.
following payoffs: 3
While the costs of unfavorable variances may be larger than the costs of
 favorable variances (Horngren et al., 2011; Merchant & Manzoni, 1989), we
F if X 6 BEval implemented symmetric planning costs in the experiment because the
PSubord ¼ ð1Þ symmetry in planning costs considerably facilitates the planning task for
F þ A  ðX  BEval Þ if X > BEval
the superior and increases experimental control.
4 M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16

D  A  C > 0, i.e., the superior always benefits from an budgets can have positive direct but also negative indirect
increase in output, even if this increase also increases the effects on planning accuracy we state a research question
subordinate’s bonus and the planning error. This implies (RQ2, right node) to investigate which forces affect plan-
that the superior has monotonic incentives to both opti- ning accuracy more strongly in our experimental setting.
mally motivate the subordinate and correctly plan
performance.
Benchmark analysis
The subordinate does not bear any planning costs, i.e.,
his payoff function (1) is unaffected by the planning task.4
Before deriving our hypotheses, we analyze the stan-
However, he is always informed about the superior’s plan-
dard economic implications for the setting we have just
ning task and planning costs. That is, at the time of the bud-
described. The superior’s difficulty in setting budgets arises
get negotiation, he is likely to be fully aware of the conflict
from the information asymmetry about the subordinate’s
between the two tasks, of his impact on the superior’s payoff
performance capability. The superior cannot expect the
from the performance evaluation task and, in the planning
subordinate to communicate his ability truthfully because
conditions, of the superior’s costs from planning errors.
his payoff function induces slack-creating incentives
This setting allows us to investigate how a superior’s
(Hansen, Otley, & Van der Stede, 2003; Murphy, 2000).
planning task affects the negotiation of a performance
The subordinate will thus try to decrease his performance
evaluation budget and the outcome of the superiors’ tasks
evaluation budget and will strategically communicate dur-
as well as whether these effects are amplified when the
ing the negotiation.
superior is restricted to use a single budget for planning
The superior’s symmetric planning costs imply that the
and performance evaluation. Fig. 1 summarizes our
optimal planning budget should be set equal to the median
research model and relates our main variables of interest
of the potential performance capabilities from the super-
to the whole budgeting process and its outcomes.
ior’s perspective after the negotiation (Weitzman, 1976).
The upper part of Fig. 1 illustrates our hypothesis and
That means, if the superior cannot infer any additional
research question on negotiation behavior (H1 and RQ1).
information about the subordinate’s capability from the
We propose that the superiors’ planning task motivates sub-
negotiation, then she will set the planning budget equal
ordinates to act more cooperatively during the negotiation
to the median capability according to her ex ante expecta-
and therefore increases initial budget proposals (H1 (i), left
tions. In contrast, if, from the information obtained in the
node) and that the superiors’ restriction to a single budget
negotiation, the superior can narrow the range of the sub-
for both tasks amplifies this effect (H1 (ii), right node).
ordinate’s potential capabilities compared to her ex ante
Further, we analyze superiors’ initial counteroffers to
expectations, then she should optimally set the planning
investigate whether and how the planning task and the sin-
budget to the median corresponding to this smaller range
gle budget restriction influence a superior’s behavior in
of the potential capabilities.
negotiations about performance evaluation budgets beyond
In any case, however, when determining the perfor-
her reactions to subordinate initial proposals. As explained
mance evaluation budget the superior has to take care that
in detail below, the potential direct and indirect effects of
the subordinate has sufficient financial incentives to
the planning task on superiors’ initial counteroffers work
expend effort without increasing the compensation costs
in different directions. We thus state a research question
(too much). If the performance evaluation budget were
(RQ1) to explore which of the effects dominates the super-
equal to the median of potential capabilities (i.e., the opti-
ior’s negotiation behavior in our experimental setting.
mal planning budget), then subordinates could not reach
The lower part of Fig. 1 relates to the outcomes of the
the performance evaluation budget in 50% of the cases.
superiors’ tasks as our second hypothesis and research
This could be optimal only if the superior had extreme
question (H2 and RQ2). Specifically, we propose that the
expectations about potential capabilities.5 Otherwise, the
superior’s planning task makes the subordinate act more
expected loss in subordinate performance due to insufficient
cooperatively also after the negotiation and that this
financial incentives would be too large. Thus, the superior
increases performance, particularly after negotiation
should set the performance evaluation budget below the
impasse (H2 (i), left node). We further propose that this
optimal planning budget (the median capability) to increase
effect is amplified when the superior is restricted to a single
the likelihood of higher effort.6 That means, in our setting,
budget (H2 (ii), right node). H2 focuses on the behavioral
performance evaluation and planning are in conflict because
forces beyond monetary incentives, thereby controlling
of the need to provide subordinates with sufficient mone-
for potentially different performance evaluation budgets.
tary incentives to counter the need for accurate planning.
Finally, we investigate how the single-budget restriction
influences the accuracy of the superior’s planning task. As
5
will be explained below, because the use of separate For example, if the superior expects the task to require some special
skills that half of the subordinates do not possess (i.e., their capabilities are
very low), the cost of reduced effort would be small for this group of
4
The subordinate does not participate in the superiors’ planning costs subordinates. In this case, the performance evaluation budget would be
for two reasons: First, this design choice increases experimental control optimally set close to or even above the median. Assuming that such a large
because it excludes any direct effect of the experimental conditions on the fraction of subordinates is not qualified for their task, though, does not
subordinate’s payoff and because the pay scheme (1) is easily understand- describe corporate practice.
6
able. Second, while there are theoretical analyses of truth-inducing pay This likely corresponds to actual company settings where incentive
schemes in which subordinates directly participate in planning accuracy systems usually provide sufficient monetary incentives for the majority, not
(e.g., Groves & Loeb, 1975; Weitzman, 1976), these pay schemes are rarely the minority, of the employees (Baker, Jensen, & Murphy, 1988; Merchant,
found in practice (Waller & Bishop, 1990). 2010).
M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16 5

Fig. 1. Research model and predictions.

Because the two budgets should be set to different Pommerenke, & Newton, 1993). This is expected to result
levels, the superior is better off when she can use separate in increased subordinate cooperation during and after the
budgets unless this entails significant additional costs. The negotiation. The theory we draw on to develop our
reason is that a single budget cannot solve both tasks opti- hypotheses relies on the existence of only some conflict
mally at the same time (Barrett & Fraser, 1977; Hopwood, between planning and performance evaluation from an
1972; Otley, 1982). Consequently, depending on the rela- economic perspective and on the subordinate perceiving
tive importance of the two tasks and on where the single this conflict.
budget is set, economic theory predicts that the restriction
to a single budget leads to increased costs from suboptimal Negotiation process
planning, suboptimal performance evaluation, or both.
These implications reflect the established result that plan- Prior research suggests that a subordinate’s behavior
ning and performance evaluation are often conflicting bud- during and after budget negotiations is affected by fairness
geting purposes (Barrett & Fraser, 1977; Merchant & concerns (Chalos & Haka, 1989; Fisher, Maines, et al.,
Manzoni, 1989; Merchant & Otley, 2007) and economics 2002). As fairness concerns are likely to change with the
theories that predict firms should use separate budgets negotiation setting and with the parties’ interdependence
for these different purposes (Baiman, 1982; Churchill, (De Dreu, Weingart, & Kwon, 2000; Giebels, De Dreu, &
1984). Van de Vliert, 2000), they may be influenced by the super-
ior’s planning task in addition to her performance evalua-
Hypotheses and research questions tion task. As pointed out above, a conflicting planning
task likely increases task complexity, thereby making the
In contrast to the standard economic benchmark analy- superior’s situation more difficult, and also increases the
sis, we propose that behavioral factors, beyond monetary subordinate’s impact on the superior’s outcome. These
incentives, also influence budget negotiations and subse- effects are likely to be important in the negotiation as a
quent performance. We suggest that with the planning factor determining negotiation behavior is an individual’s
task, the subordinate is likely to perceive that the superior accountability to the counterpart (Lerner & Tetlock, 1999;
has a more complex task owing to higher cognitive Tetlock, 1985). Accountability consists of two parts:
demands (Bonner, 1994; Campbell, 1988) and to have an responsibility for another person’s outcome and an audi-
increased interpersonal accountability to the superior ence (a third person or the individual himself) evaluating
owing to his increased impact on the superior’s com- the individual’s decision (Lerner & Tetlock, 1999;
pensation due to the potential planning costs (Kramer, Schlenker, Britt, Pennington, Murphy, & Doherty, 1994).
6 M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16

With the planning task in addition to the performance In contrast to the effects of planning on subordinate
evaluation task during budgeting, the subordinate’s behav- behavior, the effects on the superior are more ambiguous.
ior both during and after the budget negotiation increases Numerous studies have illustrated the importance of
his impact on the superior’s outcome and therefore is likely reciprocity for negotiations (e.g., Brett, Shapiro, & Lytle,
to increase his interpersonal accountability to the superior 1998; Kuang & Moser, 2009; Putnam & Jones, 1982).
(Kramer et al., 1993; Schlenker et al., 1994). The reason is According to the norm of reciprocity, a party will cooperate
that planning quality and thus the superior’s planning during a negotiation if the other party also does so (Benton
costs depend on her knowledge of the subordinate’s ability et al., 1972; Carnevale & Pruitt, 1992). Thus, if the super-
and on his performance after the negotiation. If an individ- ior’s planning task makes the subordinate increase his ini-
ual’s interpersonal accountability to his or her counterpart tial bids, then the superior may reciprocate and this may
increases, then the individual is likely to cooperate more lead to lower initial superior counteroffers. Similarly, if
and compete less (Kramer et al., 1993; Pruitt, 1981). superiors react reciprocally and the single-budget restric-
Therefore, the subordinate should cooperate more in the tion further increases initial subordinate bids, then it
negotiation when the superior has a planning and a perfor- should further decrease initial superior counteroffers.
mance evaluation task.7 Prior research on negotiations in However, prior research also suggests that the superi-
general (Benton, Kelley, & Liebling, 1972; Carnevale & ors’ counteroffers may be affected by anchoring in two dif-
Pruitt, 1992) and on budget negotiations in particular ferent ways. First, an initial offer can serve as an anchor
(Fisher et al., 2000; Fisher et al., 2006) suggests that less that biases the counteroffer (Bazerman & Neale, 1993;
extreme initial offers can be regarded as a signal for Kristensen & Gärling, 1997). This implies that higher initial
cooperation. Thus, we expect the subordinates’ initial bud- subordinate bids under planning and the additional
get proposals to increase when there is a planning task in increase in the bids under the single-budget case may
addition to the performance evaluation task.8 increase superiors’ initial counteroffers. Second, anchors
Compared to the case in which the planning task can be for negotiation offers also may arise from other salient
solved through a separate planning budget, the superior’s information (Kahneman, 1992). With an additional plan-
restriction to a single budget for both tasks is likely to ning task, a likely anchor for the superior’s initial coun-
increase the subordinate’s interpersonal accountability teroffer is the optimal planning budget given the
even more. In this case, the superior’s ability to solve the superior’s information before the negotiation. As analyzed
planning task is further restricted because the planning above, the optimal planning budget in this case is the med-
budget equals the performance evaluation budget. That ian of the potential performance capabilities according to
means, any decrease in the performance evaluation budget the superior’s ex ante expectations. Whether anchoring
would not only increase compensation costs but also on the ex ante optimal planning budget leads to higher
automatically increase the superior’s planning costs or lower counteroffers is unclear as the direction of the
because she has no possibility to adjust the planning bud- effect depends on the level of initial counteroffers without
get. Consequently, the superior’s restriction to a single the additional planning task. Yet, in this case, superiors’
budget for both tasks is likely to reinforce the effect on initial counteroffers should be concentrated more nar-
the subordinates’ initial proposals. We predict: rowly around the expected performance capabilities than
without the planning task. As the potential behavioral
H1. The subordinate’s initial budget proposal in the forces affecting the counteroffers point into different direc-
negotiation (i) increases when the superior has a planning tions, we do not derive a directional hypothesis but use the
and performance evaluation task and (ii) further increases following research question to investigate which effect
when the superior is restricted to the use of a single budget dominates superior behavior in budget negotiations in
for planning and performance evaluation instead of sepa- our experimental setting:
rate budgets for each task.
RQ1: How do the planning task and the restriction to
use a single budget for planning and performance eval-
uation affect a superior’s initial counteroffer in the
7
Increased cooperation in the negotiation may also incorporate aspects negotiation?
of strategic behavior. First, the subordinate may make higher offers because
he expects the superior to positively reciprocate his increased cooperation.
Subordinate performance
Second, the subordinate may anticipate the influence of the planning task
on the superior’s negotiation behavior. For example, if the subordinate
expects the planning task to reduce the superior’s concessions, he may A characteristic of a budget negotiation is that subse-
increase his offers to avoid negotiation impasses. However, whether quent to the negotiation, the subordinate provides non-
cooperation increases due to genuine or strategic concerns is largely contractible effort. Thus, an important question is the
semantic and does not affect our predictions as long as the increase is
effect of the negotiation’s procedures and results on sub-
systematic. We provide evidence on this question in the supplemental
analysis. ordinate performance. In the following, we develop theory
8
Research on bargaining theory shows that a negotiation party can have to predict that the planning task leads to more subordinate
incentives to communicate private information when bargaining impasse is cooperation not only during, but also after the negotiation.
costly to her and when she expects her counterpart to make no or few This increases the subordinate’s performance, particularly
concessions (e.g., Ausubel, Cramton, & Deneckere, 2002, chap. 50;
Rubinstein, 1985). In our setting, this might make subordinates’ offers
after a negotiation impasse. Further, we expect the
more informative about their capability when the superior has a planning restriction to a single budget for both tasks to reinforce
task. We provide evidence on this issue in the results section. the effect.
M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16 7

Prior research has shown that reciprocal reactions to justifiable with a single budget as the superior may have
the superior’s negotiation behavior strongly affect sub- no alternative to imposing a budget to keep the planning
ordinates’ effort choices after the negotiation (Fisher, error small. Thus, we predict the following effect of the
Frederickson, et al., 2002; Kuang & Moser, 2011). These planning task and the restriction to a single budget on sub-
reciprocal reactions are more positive when superiors are ordinate performance:
constrained as their intentions are perceived more posi-
tively in this case (Hannan, 2005). Because the presence H2. Controlling for the subordinate’s monetary incentives,
of a conflicting planning task is likely to make the sub- (i) the positive effect of the superior’s planning task
ordinate perceive the superior’s task as more complex beyond a performance evaluation task only on subordinate
and constrained, the planning task can positively affect performance is larger after negotiation impasse than after
subordinate performance. agreement and (ii) the superior’s restriction to a single
We propose, however, that this effect is likely to be budget amplifies this effect.
more pronounced after negotiation impasse than after
agreement for the following reason: If the two parties
Planning error
reach an agreement, then the subordinate’s aspiration level
is likely to be fulfilled (Kuang & Moser, 2011).
As we analyzed above, according to economic theory,
Consequently, although the superior’s negotiation behav-
the possibility of setting separate budgets should reduce
ior is likely perceived as more positive when a planning
the planning error, because the superior does not have to
task is present in addition to the performance evaluation
trade off the conflicting tasks in a single budget.
task, the effect of the planning task on subordinate perfor-
However, from the analysis leading to H1 and H2, the
mance is likely to be smaller under agreement. Prior
effects of the superior’s restriction to a single budget on
research supports this conjecture, showing that, when
her planning error are unclear under both agreement and
agreement is reached, the effects of all treatment condi-
impasse. First, after agreement, the superior cannot further
tions that have been manipulated so far in similar budget
adjust the budget for the planning task in the single-
negotiation settings on subordinate performances have
budget case. In contrast, in the separate-budgets case, the
been small (Arnold, 2015; Fisher et al., 2000; Fisher,
superior can adjust her planning budget, but a reduction
Frederickson, et al., 2002; Fisher et al., 2006).
in planning error may be difficult if the subordinate coop-
In contrast, the effect of the planning task on perfor-
erates less during the negotiation and hides his perfor-
mance is likely to be larger after a budget imposition when
mance capability. Further, as predicted in H1 (ii), the
negotiations fail because the planning task is likely to
subordinates’ initial budget proposals are likely to be
affect the subordinate’s attribution of the superior’s budget
higher when the superior is restricted to a single budget,
imposition and therefore his interpretation of the budget
and this could lead to higher performance evaluation bud-
imposition. Attribution theory suggests that an important
gets under agreement. Consequently, the performance
determinant of an individual’s reaction to another person’s
evaluation budget under agreement may be closer to the
actions is the attribution of that person’s behavior to exter-
subordinate’s actual performance when the superior is
nal (situational) or internal (dispositional) factors (Dobbins
restricted to a single budget.
& Russell, 1986; Gilbert & Malone, 1995; Ross, 1977). In the
Second, after negotiation impasse, the superior has to
unconstrained performance evaluation-only setting, the
trade off planning and performance evaluation in the sin-
subordinate is likely to attribute the superior’s budget
gle-budget case and therefore may not be able to solve
imposition to dispositional factors. Thus, he is likely to per-
the planning task as well as in the separate-budgets case.
ceive a budget imposition as unfair and to respond with
In contrast, the arguments for H2 (ii) imply that sub-
low effort (Fisher et al., 2000; Kuang & Moser, 2011). In
ordinate performance is likely to be lower in the sepa-
contrast, when the superior also has a planning task, the
rate-budgets case. Consequently, if the superior does not
subordinate cannot make unambiguous inferences about
perfectly anticipate the lower performance,9 then the plan-
the superior’s dispositions and may explain her behavior
ning error after negotiation impasse may be larger with
by the situation rather than by disposition (Arnold, 2015;
separate budgets than with a single budget. As the potential
Gilbert & Malone, 1995). That is, a budget imposition
effects of the behavioral forces on planning accuracy point in
may be more acceptable to the subordinate in a setting
different directions, we state a research question to investi-
with multiple budgeting tasks than in the performance
gate which of them dominates in our experimental setting:
evaluation-only task, because the subordinate may attri-
bute the lack of sufficient superior concessions during
RQ2: Will the realized planning error be different under
the negotiation to the superior’s increased task complexity
agreement and disagreement when the superior is
and her focus on the additional planning task. Thus, the
restricted to the use of a single budget than when she
increasing effect of the planning task on subordinate
can set separate budgets?
performance is likely to be larger following a budget
imposition.
Again, the effect of the planning task on performance is
likely to be amplified with a single budget for both tasks 9
Prior experimental evidence shows that decision makers’ abilities to
because the superior is even more constrained and, thus, anticipate the behavior of others in sequential bargaining games are very
her intentions are likely to be perceived even more posi- limited. See, e.g., Binmore, McCarthy, Ponti, Samuelson, and Shaked (2002),
tively. Specifically, a budget imposition may be more Johnson, Camerer, Sen, and Rymon (2002).
8 M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16

Experimental method (2) Then, the real effort task was explained. It consisted
of decoding two-digit numbers into letters in blocks
Participants and design of two each. Participants then completed a two-min-
ute practice round.
180 graduate and undergraduate students from a large (3) Next, all subjects completed three four-minute
European university (90 dyads) participated in the experi- training rounds. New decoding keys were dis-
ment—60 participants (30 dyads) in each of the three treat- tributed for each round. Subordinates were told that,
ments. Of the participants, 42% were female, and 59% were at the end of the experiment, one of the training
business or economics majors. Three sessions were con- rounds would be randomly selected and they would
ducted for each of the treatments. No participant partici- receive two points for every block correctly decoded
pated in more than one session. Sessions lasted between in this round. Subordinates were informed of the
60 and 75 min. Participants received a show-up fee of € number of correctly and incorrectly decoded blocks
5.00 and additional variable compensation. Average total after each training round. They improved their per-
compensation was €14.34 and varied between €5.00 and formance on average by 2.18 blocks from training
€23.80. rounds 1–2 and by 1.56 blocks from training rounds
We used a nested experimental design in which we var- 2–3. Superiors were not compensated and received
ied (between subjects) the existence of a planning task— no feedback in the training rounds.
present or absent. Nested within the planning task present, (4) After the third training round, subordinates were
we manipulated the restriction to use a single budget for asked to submit a best estimate of the number of
both purposes—present or absent. In all treatments, bud- blocks they could correctly decode in another four-
gets had a performance evaluation function. This nested minute work round. On average, the estimate was
design resulted in three treatments: performance evalua- larger by 0.34 blocks than the maximum perfor-
tion only, separate budgets for planning and performance mance in the training rounds.
evaluation (‘‘separate-budgets treatment’’), and a single (5) Next, participants were informed about their roles,
budget for planning and performance evaluation (‘‘single- the setting, the payoff functions, and the budgeting
budget treatment’’). The experimental design is summar- process in the experimental work round. The
ized in Fig. 2. parameter values were set to F = 250, A = 4, D = 10,
The planning task was operationalized by having the and C = 4.11 They guarantee that the superior has
superior predict output, i.e., actual performance, or not. monotonic incentives to motivate high subordinate
With the planning task, the superior had to bear planning performance and predict this performance accurately.
costs if actual output deviated from predicted output, as Specifically, for a given subordinate performance, any
included in Eq. (3). unit of deviation of the planning budget decreases
The restriction to a single budget was manipulated by the superior’s payoff by C = 4. Further, for a given
giving the superior the ability to set separate budgets for planning budget, the superior’s payoff increases mono-
performance evaluation and planning or not. That is, in tonically if subordinate performance increases. That
the single-budget treatment, the planning budget is, even if an increase in subordinate performance
automatically equaled the performance evaluation budget. increased both compensation and planning error,
The subordinate’s payoff function was never affected by the net effect on the superior’s payoff would still be
any manipulation. However, as the subordinate’s financial positive (D  A  C = 2). A and C were chosen to avoid
incentives after the negotiation depended on the perfor- a parameter-specific focus on one of the tasks: With
mance evaluation budget, we control for these incentives A = C, an increase in compensation is as costly as an
in our statistical analysis. increase in planning error. The values of A and C are
large enough to make the superior pay sufficient
Procedure attention to both tasks. Participants were informed
that the negotiation would last at maximum three
The experiment, including the negotiation process, was rounds and that the superior would set the final per-
computerized. Instructions appeared on the computer formance evaluation budget if no agreement was
screens and were simultaneously read aloud.10 The experi- reached at the end of the third round. In the single-
mental procedure consisted of the following steps: budget treatment, participants were further told that
the planning budget would be equal to the perfor-
(1) Upon arrival, participants were randomly assigned mance evaluation budget. In every negotiation round,
to computer terminals and were separated from the subordinate made the initial budget proposal, and
each other by panels. Superior and subordinate were the superior made the counteroffer, which resembles
paired anonymously and randomly. the structure of budgeting negotiations in practice
(Anthony & Govindarajan, 2007; Umapathy, 1987).

10 11
The instructions used context-free language. Moreover, to avoid that in The minimum compensation for the subordinates was F. To avoid
the planning conditions, one task was framed as profit increasing, and the having to pay the fixed wage from their own resources, superiors were
other was framed as profit decreasing, we treated the effects of the two endowed with 500 points. The remaining 250 points after the deduction of
tasks always identically. The instructions are available from the authors F ensured that the superior would have sufficient planning incentives even
upon request. in the case of low subordinate performance.
M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16 9

Performance evaluation only Planning and performance evaluation


Separate budgets Single budget
(Treatment 1) (Treatment 2) (Treatment 3)
Superior has only a Superior has a planning and a performance evaluation task
performance evaluation task
Superior can use separate Superior is restricted to use a
budgets for each task single budget for both tasks
BEval BEval and BPlan BEval = BPlan

Fig. 2. Overview of the experimental setting and design.

(6) Subjects then answered a quiz about the procedures Measures


and the payoffs. The quiz included questions about
the planning budget (planning treatments only) To analyze the negotiation process, we use FIRSTBID,
and the performance-evaluation budget (all treat- the subordinate’s initial budget proposal in the negotia-
ments). These questions were correctly answered tion, and FIRSTCOUNTER, the superior’s initial counterof-
in 92% of all cases in the first trial. Participants fail- fer. BEval and BPlan represent the performance evaluation
ing to give a correct answer had to read the relevant and the planning budget, respectively. X is the sub-
instructions again. The experiment did not start ^ is the subordinate’s
ordinate’s actual performance, and X
until all participants had answered all questions
estimate of his performance capability at the end of the
correctly.
training rounds. BONUSPot ¼ maxf0; 4  ðX^  BEval Þg repre-
(7) Before the negotiations started, all participants were
informed of the results of a pretest. They were told sents the potential subordinate bonus based on his esti-
that 80% of the participants in the pretest had cor- mated performance capability and is used to control for
rectly decoded between 29 and 49 blocks of num- the subordinate’s monetary incentives. ERROR = |X  BPlan|
bers in four minutes. No superior was informed is used to measure the planning error. Table 1 summarizes
about the performance of her specific subordinate the measures used in the experiment.
in the training rounds.
(8) Next, negotiations were conducted between superi- Results
ors and subordinates via the computer network.
This procedure ensured anonymity and removed Table 2 displays descriptive statistics and shows that
any interpersonal aspects of the negotiation. At any the subordinates’ estimated performance capabilities X ^
point in the negotiation, either party could accept are very similar across treatments. One-way ANOVAs show
the other party’s proposal, which would end the no significant difference across treatments with respect to
negotiation. If the superior and subordinate could the subordinates’ estimates and the subordinates’ maxi-
not reach an agreement within three rounds, then mum performances in the training round (p > .10 in both
the superior imposed the budget. cases). Thus, differences across treatments are not driven
(9) After the performance evaluation budget was set, by differences in performance capabilities.
each superior set the planning budget in the As our goal is to establish a conflict between planning
separate-budgets treatment. Subordinates were not and performance evaluation, we examine the means of
informed about the planning budget so as not to BPlan and BEval. Table 2 shows that, in the separate-budgets
affect their performance by presenting an additional treatment, mean BEval is lower than mean BPlan and this dif-
goal. This is consistent with the informal adjustment ference is significant (t-test, x ¼ 35:07 vs. 38.70, t = 3.11,
of performance evaluation targets for planning pur- p < .01).12 63% of the superiors adjusted the planning budget
poses observed in practice (Berry and Otley, 1975; upwards, consistent with the economic benchmark analysis.
Walker & Johnson, 1999). In the single-budget treat- In contrast, 27% of the superiors adjusted the planning bud-
ment, the planning budget automatically equaled get downwards. The majority of these cases (eight of nine)
the performance evaluation budget. occurred after a negotiation impasse, and the mean perfor-
(10) Finally, subordinates completed the experimental mance evaluation and planning budget in these cases are
work round for four minutes. Subjects interacted 36.85 and 32.57, respectively. This result suggests that,
for only one work round to avoid ambiguities when setting their planning budget, some superiors allowed
that may arise in repeated relationships, such as for the possibility that subordinates might reduce perfor-
reputation building and aspects of the social mance after a budget imposition. However, our finding that
interaction. At the end of the work round, subjects 90% of the superiors adjusted the planning budget confirms
were informed of the subordinate performance
and the payoffs. They completed a post- 12
We use one-tailed p-values for tests of directional predictions and two-
experimental questionnaire and received their cash tailed p-values for research questions without directional prediction. The
payments. unit of observation is the observation made for every dyad.
10 M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16

Table 1 experiment, performance evaluation seems to be more


Summary of the measures used in the analysis. important for superiors than planning.13
Measure Description
FIRSTBID Subordinate’s initial budget
Hypotheses tests
proposal
FIRSTCOUNTER Superior’s initial counteroffer
BEval Performance evaluation H1 predicts (i) an increase in initial budget proposals in
budget the planning treatments and (ii) an additional increase in
BPlan Planning budget the single-budget relative to the separate-budgets treat-
X Subordinate performance
ment. Consistent with these two predictions, Table 2 and
^
X Subordinate’s estimate of his
performance capability Fig. 3 show that the mean of FIRSTBID is higher in the
^  BEval Þg
BONUSPot ¼ maxf0; 4  ðX Potential subordinate bonus two planning treatments than in the performance evalua-
based on the subordinate’s tion-only treatment (H1 (i)) and is higher in the single-
estimated performance
budget treatment than in the separate-budgets treatment
capability
ERROR = |X  BPlan| Realized planning error
(H1 (ii)).
We conduct a nested ANOVA with FIRSTBID as the
dependent variable to test H1. The first factor in the
ANOVA is whether the planning task is present or absent.
the success of our manipulation of conflict between the This factor tests part (i) of H1. Nested within this factor,
performance evaluation and the planning tasks. the second factor captures whether the superior is
Finally, Table 2 reveals that the mean of single budget is restricted to a single budget. This factor tests part (ii) of
close to and not significantly different from the mean of H1. As reported in Panel A of Table 3, planning significantly
BEval in the separate-budgets case (t-test,  x ¼ 35:76 vs. affects FIRSTBID (p = .03). However, even though the effect
35.07, t = .50, p > .10) but significantly lower than BPlan of the single budget on FIRSTBID is in the predicted direc-
(t-test, 
x = 35.76 vs. 38.70, t = 2.22, p = .03). Thus, in our tion the nested term is not significant at conventional
levels (p = .13). These results support part (i) of H1 but
not part (ii).14
Table 2
RQ1 asks how the planning task and the restriction to a
Descriptive statistics: mean and standard deviation.
single budget affect superiors’ initial counteroffers. Table 2
Performance Planning and performance and Fig. 3 show that mean FIRSTCOUNTER is very similar
evaluation only evaluation across treatments and slightly above the mid-point (39)
Separate Single of the pre-test span (29–49) participants were informed
budgets budget about. We ran a nested ANOVA and a nested ANCOVA with
(Treatment 1) (Treatment 2) (Treatment 3)
FIRSTCOUNTER as the dependent variable and the same
^a
X 41.67 38.53 40.23 factors as used for testing H1 to test whether the
5.08 6.30 6.56 planning task affects FIRSTCOUNTER. In the ANOVA,
BEvalb 32.33 35.07 35.76
11.67 5.95 4.77
we test the overall treatment effects. In the ANCOVA,
BPlanc n.a. 38.70 35.76 we include FIRSTBID as a covariate to examine whether
n.a. 5.45 4.77 superior counteroffers are driven by reciprocity or
BONUSPotd 43.47 20.27 23.60 anchoring on subordinates’ initial bids. If superiors react
41.39 19.95 25.13
reciprocally, then increases in FIRSTBID should decrease
FIRSTBIDe 19.93 22.20 24.53
8.79 8.15 6.28 FIRSTCOUNTER. In contrast, if superiors anchor
FIRSTCOUNTERf 40.53 40.27 41.67 on FIRSTBID, increases in FIRSTBID should increase
17.20 6.99 8.66 FIRSTCOUNTER. Panel B of Table 3 reports the results.
Xg 30.80 28.87 37.00 They do not reveal any significant effect in the ANOVA or
19.21 19.19 14.71
ERRORh n.a. 14.10 12.83
the ANCOVA (p > .25 in all cases). That is, we find neither
n.a. 15.88 11.68 a significant effect of the treatment conditions nor of
No. of obs. 30 30 30
FIRSTBID. This lack in significant results contradicts the
view that superiors reciprocate or anchor on the sub-
Note: Mean and standard deviation for the performance evaluation-only ordinates’ initial bids.
condition (Treatment 1), planning and performance evaluation with
separate budgets (Treatment 2), and planning and performance evalua-
tion with a single budget (Treatment 3).
a ^
X is the subordinate’s estimate of his performance capability. 13
This finding is consistent with the perception of performance evalua-
b
BEval is the budget used for performance evaluation. tion as central in practice (e.g., Otley, 1978). However, it may not be
c
BPlan is the budget used for planning. In the single-budget case, BPlan generalizable because the optimal single budget also depends on the
automatically equals BEval. parameters A and C.
d
BONUSPot is the potential bonus the subordinate can earn based on his 14
We find no evidence consistent with subordinates’ budget proposals
estimated performance capability X. ^
revealing more about their capabilities in the planning conditions. Specifi-
e
FIRSTBID is the subordinate’s initial budget proposal in the cally, regression analyses show that the increase in budget proposals in the
negotiation. planning conditions varies neither linearly nor non-linearly (inversely
f
FIRSTCOUNTER is the superior’s initial counteroffer in the negotiation. U-shaped) with subordinates’ capabilities. These results contradict that the
g
X is the subordinate performance in the experimental work round. increased budget proposals are driven by an increased informativeness of
h
ERROR = |X  BPlan| is the realized planning error. subordinate offers.
M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16 11

Finally, a test of superiors’ anchoring on the ex ante


optimal planning budget requires a measure of the concen-
tration of FIRSTCOUNTER around the mid-point of the pret-
est span. Therefore, we used the standard deviation of
FIRSTCOUNTER. Table 2 reveals that the standard deviation
is much smaller in both planning treatments than in the
performance evaluation-only treatment, and this decrease
in standard deviation of FIRSTCOUNTER in the two plan-
ning treatments relative to the performance evaluation-
only treatment is significant (Bartlett’s test, v2 > 12,
p < .01 in both cases). This result is consistent with the
notion that in our experimental setting, superiors form
an a priori expectation about subordinates’ performance
capabilities and anchor on this expectation when a plan-
ning task is present.
H2 predicts that, after controlling for monetary incen-
tives, the superior’s planning task in addition to her perfor- Fig. 3. Subordinates’ initial budget proposals and superiors’ initial
mance evaluation task leads to a larger increase in counteroffers. Note: The figure displays subordinates’ average initial
budget proposal in the negotiation (FIRSTBID) and superiors’ average
subordinate performance after negotiation impasse than initial counteroffer (FIRSTCOUNTER) for the three experimental condi-
after agreement (H2 (i)). It further predicts that this effect tions (performance evaluation-only, planning with separate budgets, and
is amplified when the superior is restricted to a single bud- planning with a single budget).
get (H2 (ii)). Panel A of Table 4 displays the descriptive
statistics for subordinates’ performances contingent on
negotiation agreement. Fig. 4 graphs the performances Table 3
relative to the estimated performance capabilities in all Analysis of subordinates’ initial budget proposals and superiors’ initial
counteroffers.
experimental treatments. Table 4 and Fig. 4 show that
mean performance increases in the separate-budgets treat- df MS F p
ment relative to the performance evaluation-only treat- Panel A: FIRSTBID a

ment and further increases in the single-budget Planning 1 235.76 3.86 0.03
treatment. As predicted, both effects are mainly driven Single budget|planning 1 81.67 1.34 0.13
Error 87 61.04
by the changes after budget impositions, whereas after
agreement the performances are similar across treatments. Panel B: FIRSTCOUNTERb
To test H2, we run regressions with the subordinate ANOVA
performance, X, as the dependent variable.15 We use Planning 1 3.75 0.03 0.87
regressions instead of ANOVAs because a Levene test indi- Single budget|planning 1 29.40 0.21 0.65
Error 87 139.90
cates a violation of variance homogeneity (t = 22.69,
p < .01). In the regressions, we control for heteroscedasticity ANCOVA
FIRSTBID 1 174.21 1.25 0.27
by using the Huber–White estimator. To test the interaction Planning 1 0.68 <0.01 0.94
predicted by part (i) of H2, we regress X on BONUSPot, an Single budget|planning 1 14.11 0.10 0.75
indicator variable for planning (DPlan equal to 1 in the plan- Error 86 139.51
ning treatments and 0 in the performance evaluation-only Note: Panel A reports results of a nested ANOVA testing whether planning
treatment), an indicator variable for agreement (agree equal and the restriction to a single budget nested within planning affect sub-
to 1 when agreement was reached and 0 when the negotia- ordinates’ initial budget proposals in the negotiation. Panel B shows a
tion failed), and the interaction of the two indicator vari- nested ANOVA and a nested ANCOVA testing whether planning and the
restriction to a single budget affect superiors’ initial counteroffers in the
ables. To test part (ii) of H2, we include only the two
negotiation. The nested ANCOVA includes the subordinates’ initial pro-
planning treatments and regress X on BONUSPot, Agree, an posals as a covariate. p-values are one-tailed for directional predictions
indicator variable for the singe-budget treatment (DSingle and two-tailed otherwise.
a
equal to 1 in the single-budget treatment and 0 in the sepa- FIRSTBID is the subordinate’s initial budget proposal in the
rate-budgets treatment), and the interaction of the two indi- negotiation.
b
FIRSTCOUNTER is the superior’s initial counteroffer in the negotiation.
cator variables. In the regressions, BONUSPot controls for the
effect of monetary incentives. Panel B of Table 4 reports the
results.
Consistent with H2 (i) and (ii), the interaction coeffi- Model (1), the interaction coefficient indicates that the
cients are significantly negative in both regressions. In increase in subordinate performance (X) under planning
is smaller after agreement (b = 7.95, p = .09). This
supports H2 (i). In Model (2), the interaction coefficient
15
The use of X in the tests of H2 assumes that different performance indicates that the increase in X in the single budget-
capabilities are controlled by random assignment of the subordinates to the treatment is smaller after agreement (b = 11.10, p = .04).
treatment conditions. All statistical inferences remain the same if perfor-
^ as an This result supports H2 (ii).
mance capabilities are directly controlled by either including X
additional control variable or by using the performance relative to the Moreover, the regressions allow analyzing separately
performance capability (X/X) ^ as the dependent variable. whether the changes in X are significant both under
12 M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16

agreement and negotiation impasse. First, the baseline Table 4


condition of Model (1) is the performance evaluation-only Effects of the planning task and the restriction to a single budget on
subordinate performance.
treatment after negotiation impasse. Thus, the coefficient
of DPlan reveals that after negotiation impasse, X increases Panel A: Descriptive statistics for Xa. Mean, standard deviation, and
significantly under planning relative to performance eval- number of observations

uation-only (b = 10.37, p = .03). In contrast, a subsequent Performance Planning and performance


Wald-test combining the coefficients of DPlan and the evaluation only evaluation

interaction term in Model (1) reveals that the increase in Separate Single
X in the planning treatments is not significant after agree- budgets budget
(Treatment 1) (Treatment 2) (Treatment 3)
ment (b = 10.37–7.95 = 2.42, p = .20). Second, the baseline
condition of Model (2) is the separate-budgets treatment Negotiation 44.14 41.25 42.18
agreement 4.05 5.26 6.67
after negotiation impasse. Thus, the coefficient of DSingle
14 8 11
shows that X increases significantly in the single-budget
Negotiation 19.13 24.36 34.00
treatment after negotiation impasse (b = 10.08, p = .04).
impasse 19.68 20.48 17.26
However, a Wald-test in Model (2) combining the coeffi- 16 22 19
cients of DSingle and the interaction term shows that there
is no significant increase in X in the single-budget treat- Panel B: Regression analysis. Coefficient (p-value)
Model (1) All (2) Planning conditions
ment after agreement (b = 10.08–11.10 = 1.02, p = .68).
conditions only
Thus, the increasing effects of the planning task and the Dependent Xa Xa
restriction to a single budget on performance are only variable
prevalent after negotiation impasse. BONUSPotb 0.13 (0.01) 0.16 (0.05)
RQ2 asks whether the planning error with a single bud- Agree (0/1)c 18.94 (<0.01) 15.85 (<0.01)
get is different from the planning error with separate bud- DPlan (0/1)d 10.37 (0.03)
gets under agreement and impasse. As reported in Panel A Agree  DPlan 7.95 (0.09)
DSingle (0/1)e 10.08 (0.04)
of Table 5, mean ERROR is larger after agreement in the
Agree  DSingle 11.10 (0.04)
single-budget treatment than in the separate-budgets Constant 16.15 (<0.01) 21.37 (<0.01)
treatment ( x = 9.00 vs. 4.63). After negotiation impasse Adj. R2 0.25 0.16
and in total, mean ERROR is smaller in the single-budget N 90 60
treatment (disagreement:  x = 15.05 vs. 17.55, overall: Note: Panel A shows means, standard deviations, and numbers of obser-

x = 12.83 vs. 14.10). Panel B reports the results of two lin- vations for performance evaluation-only (Treatment 1), planning and
ear regressions run to investigate RQ2. Both regressions performance evaluation with separate budgets (Treatment 2), and plan-
ning and performance evaluation with a single budget (Treatment 3),
use ERROR as the dependent variable. The first regression contingent on whether agreement was reached during the negotiations.
uses the indicator variable DSingle for the single-budget Panel B shows the results of two linear regressions testing whether, after
treatment and analyzes whether the total difference in controlling for the effect of monetary incentives (BONUSPot), planning and
ERROR between the two planning treatments is significant. the restriction to a single budget affect subordinate performance differ-
ently after negotiation agreement and negotiation impasse. The regres-
The second regression uses DSingle, the indicator variable
sion uses Huber–White robust standard errors. p-values are one-tailed for
for agreement (Agree), and their interaction as indepen- directional predictions and two-tailed otherwise.
dent variables to investigate differences in ERROR sepa- a
X is the subordinate performance in the experimental work round.
b
rately for agreement and disagreement. As a Levene test BONUSPot is the potential bonus the subordinate can earn based on his
estimated performance capability X. ^
indicates a violation of variance homogeneity (t = 10.11, c
Agree is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the parties reached
p < .01), we use the Huber–White estimator to calculate agreement in the negotiation and 0 else.
standard errors. d
DPlan is an indicator variable equal to 1 in the two planning condi-
The first regression indicates a negative but insignifi- tions and 0 else.
e
cant coefficient for the single-budget treatment DSingle is an indicator variable equal to 1 in the single-budget con-
dition and 0 else.
(b = 1.27, p = 0.73), which contradicts the economic pre-
diction that the planning error should increase when only
a single budget is used. In the second regression, disagree- Supplemental analysis
ment in the separate-budgets case represents the baseline
condition. The results show that the use of a single budget To support our main analyses we conduct several sup-
leads to insignificantly lower planning errors after dis- plemental analyses. The results are presented in the
agreement (b = 2.49, p = .61), but a subsequent Wald test Appendix and summarized in the following. First, we ana-
combining the coefficients of DSingle and the interaction lyze subordinates’ last budget proposals in the negotiation
term reveals that the use of a single budget increases the and find that they are significantly higher in the two plan-
planning error under agreement (b = 2.49 + 6.87 = 4.38, ning treatments than in the performance evaluation-only
p = .09). These results show that, even though 90% of the treatment. As the evidence on RQ1 had shown that superi-
superiors in the separate-budgets case adjusted their ors do not decrease their counteroffers in the planning
planning budgets relative to the performance evaluation treatments, this result supports our conjecture that
budget, the benefits of using separate budgets for planning increases in initial subordinate bids in the planning treat-
are limited and only occur after agreement. ments are driven by genuine cooperativeness and not by
M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16 13

Table 5
Analysis of the planning error.

Panel A: Descriptive statistics for ERRORa. Mean, standard deviation,


and number of observations
Planning and performance evaluation
Separate budgets Single budget
(Treatment 2) (Treatment 3)
Negotiation 4.63 9.00
agreement 5.04 6.34
8 11
Negotiation 17.55 15.05
impasse 17.12 13.53
22 19
Total 14.10 12.83
15.88 11.67
30 30
Panel B: Regression analyses. Coefficient, (p-value)
Model (1) (2)
Fig. 4. Subordinate performance relative to estimated performance
Dependent ERRORa ERRORa
capability. Note: The figure displays subordinates’ average performances
variable
relative to their estimated capabilities for the three experimental
conditions (performance evaluation-only, planning with separate bud- DSingle (0/1)b 1.27 (.73) 2.49 (.61)
gets, and planning with a single budget). Agree (0/1)c 12.92 (<.01)
Agree  DSingle 6.87 (.22)
Constant 14.10 (<.01) 17.55 (<.01)
Adj. R2 0.00 0.06
strategic attempts to elicit lower counteroffers. Second,
N 60 60
also in line with increased subordinate cooperation in the
negotiation under planning, we find that performance Note: Panel A shows means, standard deviations, and number of obser-
vations for performance evaluation-only (Treatment 1), planning and
evaluation budgets after agreement are significantly higher
performance evaluation with separate budgets (Treatment 2), and plan-
in the planning treatments than in the performance eval- ning and performance evaluation with a single budget (Treatment 3),
uation-only treatment. contingent on whether agreement was reached during the negotiations.
Third, we ran an additional treatment (with N = 20 Panel B shows the results of two linear regressions testing whether the
dyads) in which the subordinate knew that the superior restriction to a single budget affects the planning error (ERROR). The
regressions use Huber–White robust standard errors. p-values are one-
had a second task in addition to the performance evalua- tailed for directional predictions and two-tailed otherwise.
tion task but did not know that it was a planning task lead- a
ERROR is the realized planning error.
ing to planning costs. Apart from that, the additional b
DSingle is an indicator variable equal to 1 in the single-budget con-
treatment was identical to the separate-budgets condition dition and 0 else.
c
Agree is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the parties reached
and the results are qualitatively similar. Specifically, in the
agreement in the negotiation and 0 else.
additional treatment, subordinates’ initial budget propos-
als and their performance after negotiation impasse are
significantly higher than in the performance evaluation-
only treatment. These results suggest that increasing the in budget negotiations and their outcomes. We further
complexity of the superior’s budgeting tasks can increase analyze whether a single budget can be effectively used
subordinate cooperation during and after budget negotia- for these two conflicting tasks as opposed to two separate
tions independent of the subordinate’s exact knowledge budgets because this restriction may cause more coopera-
of the task and its consequences. This supports the theory tion during and after the budget negotiations. We find that
underlying H1 and H2. the superior’s additional planning task enhances sub-
Finally, we investigate superiors’ and subordinates’ pay- ordinate cooperation during and after budget negotiations.
offs to shed further light on the consequences of the single- Specifically, the planning task increases the subordinate’s
budget restriction in our experimental set-up. Even though initial budget proposal and, even after controlling for
the benchmark analysis indicates that due to a loss in flexi- monetary incentives, increases his performance after the
bility, the superior’s return should be lower with a single negotiation. The effects tend to be even larger if the super-
budget than with separate budgets, we find that it is sig- ior is restricted to a single budget for both tasks, particu-
nificantly higher in the single budget treatment after larly with respect to performance. Our findings
negotiation impasse and not significantly different after contribute to the literature by demonstrating how an addi-
agreement. The same also holds for the subordinate payoff. tional superior budgeting task can affect subordinate
This indicates that increased subordinate cooperation behavior. Thus, we respond to Sprinkle’s (2003) call for a
under a single budget can benefit subordinate and superior better understanding of the simultaneous use of manage-
and, in our set-up, more than offsets the loss in flexibility. ment accounting information for decision-making and
control. We also provide evidence that not only decreases
Conclusion and discussion in social distance (Fisher et al., 2006) or the information
distribution between the parties (Chalos & Haka, 1989)
This study investigates how a planning task that con- affects cooperation in budget negotiations but also the
flicts with a performance evaluation task affects behavior set of tasks and the restrictions the superior has to deal
14 M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16

with. Despite the support for our hypotheses, however, our budget levels. Importantly, however, our hypotheses can
findings may be limited in the sense that we have no direct be generalized to any situation in which the subordinate
measures of the mediating variables (task complexity, perceives a conflict between the planning and performance
interpersonal accountability, fairness perceptions, and the evaluation tasks and an increasing complexity of the
attribution of the superior’s decisions) underlying our superior’s situation. The additional treatment we ran in
theoretical development. which the subordinate is only partially aware of the super-
Furthermore, we find evidence that the superior’s ior’s additional task provides evidence that increased sub-
restriction to a single budget for both planning and perfor- ordinate cooperation persists even if the subordinate is not
mance evaluation increases subordinate cooperation even informed about the exact nature and payoff consequences
further. In our experimental setting, the increased coopera- of the additional task. But it also indicates that the level of
tion even more than offsets for the loss in flexibility from subordinate cooperation may depend on this knowledge.
the restriction. This evidence may contribute to explain This implies that, instead of concealing the use of the
the inconsistency between theoretical suggestions to use negotiated budgets in practice, a superior may be better
multiple budgets for multiple tasks and empirical observa- off when she reveals her restrictions and complexities to
tions that firms rarely do so. Even though we used a setting the subordinate because this may lead to more
without additional costs of a second budget, the existence cooperation.
of such additional costs would represent a further draw- In the light of other research, however, this recommen-
back of the use of separate budgets. Thus, in practice, the dation may depend on how characteristics of the superior’s
use of separate budgets vs. a single budget may depend additional task and task outcomes beyond those investi-
on a more complex trade-off between economic and gated in this study affect a subordinate’s cooperativeness.
behavioral costs and benefits than suggested by standard For example, Fisher et al. (2014a) use a setting in which
economic theory. This trade-off likely also depends on the consequences of the superior’s planning task are
the firm’s environment, including the costs of inaccurate framed as an additional payoff that increases when plan-
planning and reduced performance. Consistent with our ning accuracy increases. They find that a subordinate cre-
results, though, existing empirical evidence suggests that ates more slack and therefore, seems to act less
less conflict in negotiations is associated with better out- cooperatively when he becomes aware of the superior’s
comes of performance evaluation and planning tasks additional payoff but does not participate in it. Even
(Hansen & Van der Stede, 2004; Libby & Lindsay, 2013). though the setting in Fisher et al. (2014a) is distinct from
Future research could investigate the conditions in which ours as the subordinate determines his budget unilaterally
firms rely on separate budgets for multiple tasks or a single and there is no subsequent subordinate performance, their
budget for multiple tasks to gain more insight into how results suggest that our findings on subordinate coopera-
these benefits and costs play out in practice. tion may not generalize to settings in which the conse-
Finally, evidence on our research questions indicates quences of planning errors are framed as additional
that in the planning conditions, superiors anchor on plan- benefits arising from increased planning accuracy. Yet,
ning budgets during the negotiation (RQ1) and that sepa- the combined evidence from both papers also suggests that
rate budgets do not even decrease planning costs in practice, firms may want to emphasize the complexity of
consistently compared to a single budget despite the addi- planning tasks and the costs from suboptimal coordination
tional flexibility (RQ2). These findings may be less general- rather than the additional profit from increased accuracy.
izable than the evidence on our hypotheses because we This seems to be particularly important when the sub-
cannot exclude that the underlying theoretical forces ordinate does not participate in this additional profit.
may play out differently in other settings. Nevertheless, Another limitation may be that our experiment was
the findings on RQ1 provide initial evidence that even if conducted in a one-shot setting to increase experimental
separate budgets are used, planning budgets may have control, but budgeting relationships in practice are likely
strong effects on superiors’ behavior in negotiations about repeated. Repeated interaction generally increases the
performance evaluation budgets. Moreover, the findings on cooperation of negotiating parties (Ben-Yoav & Pruitt,
RQ2 provide initial evidence that the use of separate bud- 1984; Fisher et al., 2006), but it is unclear whether their
gets may not lead to better planning outcomes thereby behavior would be affected equally strongly under all con-
contradicting suggestions in the prior literature (e.g., ditions. Finally, we assume that the subordinate is per-
Barrett & Fraser, 1977). These limitations also suggest that fectly informed about the outcome from his effort. In
additional research is needed to gain further insights into practice, however, subordinates may have imperfect infor-
the planning function of budgeting and its interaction with mation about this relation. While this is beyond the scope
the control function. of our paper, exploring the implications of increased sub-
Another limitation of this study may be that while the ordinate uncertainty about expected output may represent
existence of a conflict between multiple budgeting func- a fruitful avenue for future research.
tions in practice is well established (Barrett & Fraser,
1977; Merchant & Manzoni, 1989; Merchant & Otley,
2007), the degree of conflict also depends on the relative Appendix A. Supplementary material
importance of the two tasks. Similarly, assuming symmet-
ric planning costs helps to increase experimental control, Supplementary data associated with this article can be
but in practice, planning costs are likely to be asymmetric, found, in the online version, at http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/
which may lead to a smaller gap between the two optimal j.aos.2015.02.002.
M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16 15

References Fisher, J. G., Frederickson, J. R., & Peffer, S. A. (2000). Budgeting: An


experimental investigation of the effects of negotiations. The
Accounting Review, 75, 93–114.
Anthony, R. N., & Govindarajan, V. (2007). Management control systems
Fisher, J. G., Frederickson, J. R., & Peffer, S. A. (2002b). The effect of
(12th ed.). Boston et al.: McGraw-Hill.
information asymmetry on negotiated budgets: An empirical
Arnold, M. C. (2015). The effect of superiors’ exogenous constraints on
investigation. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 27, 27–43.
budget negotiations. The Accounting Review, 90(1), 31–57.
Fisher, J. G., Frederickson, J. R., & Peffer, S. A. (2006). Budget negotiations
Arnold, M. C., & Artz, M. (2015). Target difficulty, target flexibility, and
in multi-period settings. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 31,
firm performance: Evidence from business units’ targets. Accounting,
511–528.
Organizations, and Society, 40(1), 61–77.
Fisher, J. G., Maines, L. A., Peffer, S. A., & Sprinkle, G. B. (2002).
Atkinson, A. A., Kaplan, R. S., Matsumura, E. M., & Young, S. M. (2011).
Using budgets for performance evaluation: Effects of resource
Management accounting (6th ed.). New York: Prentice Hall.
allocation and horizontal information asymmetry on budget
Ausubel, L. M., Cramton, P., & Deneckere, R. J. (2002). Bargaining with
proposals, budget slack, and performance. The Accounting Review,
incomplete information. In R. J. Aumann & S. Hart (Eds.). Handbook of
77, 847–865.
game theory (Vol. 3). Amsterdam: Elsevier Press.
Giebels, E., De Dreu, C. K. W., & Van de Vliert, E. (2000). Interdependence
Baiman, S. (1982). Agency research in managerial accounting: A survey.
in negotiation: Effects of exit options and social motive on
Journal of Accounting Literature, 1, 154–213.
distributive and integrative negotiation. European Journal of Social
Baiman, S., & Evans, J. H. (1983). Pre-decision information and participate
Psychology, 30, 255–272.
management control systems. Journal of Accounting Research, 21(2),
Gilbert, D. T., & Malone, P. S. (1995). The correspondence bias.
371–395.
Psychological Bulletin, 117(1), 21–38.
Baker, G. P., Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1988). Compensation and
Govindarajan, V. (1986). Impact of participation in the budgetary process
incentives: Practice vs. theory. The Journal of Finance, 43(3), 593–616.
on managerial attitudes and performance: Universalistic and
Balachandran, B. V., Balakrishnan, R., & Sivaramakrishnan, K. (1997). On
contingency perspectives. Decision Sciences, 17(4), 496–516.
the efficiency of cost-based decision rules for capacity planning. The
Groves, T., & Loeb, M. (1975). Incentives and public inputs. Journal of
Accounting Review, 72(4), 599–619.
Public Economics, 4, 211–226.
Barrett, M. E., & Fraser, L. B. (1977). Conflicting roles in budgeting for
Hannan, R. L. (2005). The combined effect of wages and firm profit on
operations. Harvard Business Review, 55, 137–146.
employee effort. The Accounting Review, 80, 167–188.
Bazerman, M. H., & Neale, M. A. (1993). Negotiating rationally. New York:
Hannan, R. L., Rankin, F. W., & Towry, K. L. (2010). Flattening the
Free Press.
organization: The effect of organizational reporting structure on
Benton, A. A., Kelley, H. H., & Liebling, B. (1972). Effects of extremity of
budgeting effectiveness. Review of Accounting Studies, 15, 503–536.
offers and concession rates on the outcomes of bargaining. Journal of
Hansen, S. C., Otley, D. T., & Van der Stede, W. (2003). Practice
Personality and Social Psychology, 24(1), 73–83.
developments in budgeting: An overview and research perspective.
Ben-Yoav, O., & Pruitt, D. G. (1984). Resistance to yielding and the
Journal of Management Accounting Research, 15, 95–116.
expectation of cooperative future interaction in negotiation. Journal of
Hansen, S. C., & Van der Stede, W. A. (2004). Multiple facets of budgeting:
Experimental Social Psychology, 20, 323–335.
An exploratory analysis. Management Accounting Research, 15,
Berry, A. J., & Otley, D. T. (1975). The aggregation of estimates in
415–439.
hierarchical organization. The Journal of Management Studies, 12,
Hopwood, A. G. (1972). An empirical study of the role of accounting data
175–193.
in performance evaluation. Journal of Accounting Research, 10,
Binmore, K., McCarthy, J., Ponti, G., Samuelson, L., & Shaked, A. (2002). A
156–182.
backward induction experiment. Journal of Economic Theory, 104,
Horngren, C. T., Datar, S. M., & Rajan, M. V. (2011). Cost accounting—A
48–88.
managerial emphasis (14th ed.). New York: Prentice Hall.
Bonner, S. E. (1994). A model of the effects of audit task complexity.
Johnson, E. J., Camerer, C., Sen, S., & Rymon, T. (2002). Detecting failures of
Accounting, Organizations and Society, 19(3), 213–234.
backward induction: Monitoring information search in sequential
Brett, J. M., Shapiro, D. L., & Lytle, A. L. (1998). Breaking the bonds of
bargaining. Journal of Economic Theory, 104, 16–47.
reciprocity in negotiations. The Academy of Management Journal, 41(4),
Kahneman, D. (1992). Reference points, anchors, norms, and mixed
410–424.
feelings. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 51,
Brown, J. L., Evans, J. H., III, & Moser, D. V. (2009). Agency theory and
296–312.
participative budgeting experiments. Journal of Management
Kramer, R. M., Pommerenke, P., & Newton, E. (1993). The social context of
Accounting Research, 21, 317–345.
negotiation: Effects of social identity and interpersonal accountability
Campbell, D. (1988). Task complexity: A review and analysis. Academy of
on negotiator decision making. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 37,
Management Review, 13, 40–52.
633–654.
Carnevale, P. J., & Pruitt, D. G. (1992). Negotiation and mediation. Annual
Kristensen, H., & Gärling, T. (1997). The effects of anchor points and
Review of Psychology, 43, 531–582.
reference points on negotiation process and outcome. Organizational
Chalos, P., & Haka, S. (1989). Participative budgeting and managerial
Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 71, 85–94.
performance. Decision Sciences, 20, 334–347.
Kuang, X., & Moser, D. (2009). Reciprocity and the effectiveness of optimal
Christensen, J. (1982). The determination of performance standards and
agency contracts. The Accounting Review, 84, 1671–1694.
participation. Journal of Accounting Research, 20, 589–603.
Kuang, X., & Moser, D. (2011). Wage negotiation, employee effort, and
Church, B. K., Hannan, R. L., & Kuang, X. (2012). Shared interest and
firm profit under output-based versus fixed-wage incentive contracts.
honesty in budget reporting. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 37,
Contemporary Accounting Research, 28, 616–642.
155–167.
Lerner, J., & Tetlock, P. E. (1999). Accounting for the effects of
Churchill, N. C. (1984). Budget choice: Planning vs. control. Harvard
accountability. Psychological Bulletin, 125, 255–275.
Business Review, 62(4), 150–164.
Libby, T., & Lindsay, R. M. (2013). The effects of trust and budget-based
De Dreu, C. K. W., Weingart, L. R., & Kwon, S. (2000). Influence of social
controls on budget gaming and budget value. Working paper, SSRN.
motives on integrative negotiation: A meta-analytic review and test
Libby, T., & Lindsay, R. M. (2010). Beyond budgeting or budgeting
of two theories. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 78(5),
reconsidered? A survey of North-American budgeting practice.
889–905.
Management Accounting Research, 21, 56–75.
Dobbins, G. H., & Russell, J. M. (1986). The biasing effects of subordinate
Luft, J., & Shields, M. D. (2003). Mapping management accounting:
likeableness on leaders’ responses to poor performers: A laboratory
Graphics and guidelines for theory-consistent empirical research.
and a field study. Personnel Psychology, 39, 759–777.
Accounting, Organizations and Society, 28(2–3), 169–249.
Dunbar, R. L. M. (1971). Budgeting for control. Administrative Science
Merchant, K. A. (2010). Performance-dependent incentives: Some puzzles
Quarterly, 16(1), 88–96.
to ponder. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 25(4), 559–567.
Ekholm, B., & Wallin, J. (2011). The impact of uncertainty and strategy on
Merchant, K. A., & Manzoni, J. F. (1989). The achievability of budget
the perceived usefulness of fixed and flexible budgets. Journal of
targets in profit centers: A field study. The Accounting Review, 64,
Business Finance & Accounting, 38(1–2), 145–164.
539–558.
Fisher, J. G., Mitchell, W. T., Peffer, S. A., & Webb, R. A. (2014a).
Merchant, K. A., & Otley, D. T. (2007). A review of the literature on control
Subordinates’ knowing versus sharing in their managers’ incentives:
and accountability. In C. S. Chapman, A. G. Hopwood, & M. D. Shields
The effects of budget preparation and use. Working paper, SSRN.
(Eds.), Handbook of management accounting research (pp. 785–804).
Fisher, J. G., Mitchell, W. T., Peffer, S. A., & Webb, R. A. (2014b). Detecting
Amsterdam: Elsevier Press.
misreporting in subordinates’ budgets. Working paper, SSRN.
16 M.C. Arnold, R.M. Gillenkirch / Accounting, Organizations and Society 43 (2015) 1–16

Merchant, K. A., & Van der Stede, W. A. (2011). Management control Schlenker, B. R., Britt, T. W., Pennington, J., Murphy, R., & Doherty, K.
systems: Performance measurement, evaluation, and incentives (3rd ed.). (1994). The triangle model of responsibility. Psychological Review, 101,
London: Prentice Hall. 632–652.
Moores, K., & Yuen, S. (2001). Management accounting systems and Shields, J. F., & Shields, M. D. (1998). Antecedents of participative
organizational configuration: A life-cycle perspective. Accounting, budgeting. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 23(1), 49–76.
Organization and Society, 26(4), 351–389. Sprinkle, G. (2003). Perspectives on experimental research in managerial
Murphy, K. J. (2000). Performance standards in incentive contracts. accounting. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 28, 287–318.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, 30, 245–278. Tetlock, P. E. (1985). Accountability: The neglected social context of
Otley, D. T. (1978). Budget use and managerial performance. Journal of judgment and choice. Research in Organizational Behavior, 7, 297–
Accounting Research, 16(1), 122–149. 332.
Otley, D. T. (1982). Budgets and managerial motivation. Journal of General Umapathy, S. (1987). Current budgeting practices in U.S. industries. New
Management, 8, 26–42. York: Quorum Books.
Pruitt, D. G. (1981). Strategic choice in negotiation. American Behavioral Walker, K. B., & Johnson, E. N. (1999). The effects of a budget-based
Scientist, 27(2), 167–194. incentive compensation scheme on the budgeting behavior of
Putnam, L. L., & Jones, T. S. (1982). Reciprocity in negotiations: An analysis managers and subordinates. Journal of Management Accounting
of bargaining interaction. Communication Monographs, 49(3), Research, 11, 1–28.
171–191. Waller, W. S., & Bishop, R. A. (1990). An experimental study of pay
Ross, L. (1977). The intuitive psychologist and his shortcomings: schemes, communication, and intra-firm resource allocation. The
Distortions in the attribution process. Advances in Experimental Accounting Review, 65, 812–836.
social Psychology, 10, 173–220. Weitzman, M. L. (1976). The new soviet incentive model. The Bell Journal
Rubinstein, A. (1985). A bargaining model with incomplete information of Economics, 7(1), 251–257.
about time preferences. Econometrica, 53, 1151–1172.

You might also like