Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 101

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/311424056

MINIMIZING THE PROBABILITY OF ULTIMATE RUIN BY PROPORTIONAL


REINSURANCE AND INVESTMENTS

Thesis · September 2011


DOI: 10.13140/RG.2.2.23708.90241

CITATIONS READS

6 701

1 author:

Christian Kasumo
Mulungushi University
22 PUBLICATIONS 0 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Christian Kasumo on 05 December 2016.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


MINIMIZING THE PROBABILITY OF ULTIMATE
RUIN BY PROPORTIONAL REINSURANCE AND
INVESTMENTS

Christian Kasumo

M.Sc. (Mathematical Modelling) Dissertation


University of Dar es Salaam

September 2011
MINIMIZING THE PROBABILITY OF ULTIMATE
RUIN BY PROPORTIONAL REINSURANCE AND
INVESTMENTS

By

Christian Kasumo

A Dissertation Submitted in Partial Fulfilment of the Requirements for


the Degree of Master of Science (Mathematical Modelling) of the

University of Dar es Salaam

University of Dar es Salaam


September 2011
i

CERTIFICATION

The undersigned certify that they have read and hereby recommend for acceptance
by the University of Dar es Salaam a dissertation entitled Minimizing the Prob-
ability of Ultimate Ruin by Proportional Reinsurance and Investments,

in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science (Mathematical


Modelling) of the University of Dar es Salaam.

Dr. Charles W. Mahera

(Supervisor)

Date:

Dr. Juma Kasozi

(Supervisor)

Date:
ii

DECLARATION AND COPYRIGHT

I, Christian Kasumo, declare that this dissertation is my own original work and
that it has not been presented and will not be presented to any other University for
a similar or any other degree award.

Signature:

This dissertation is copyright material protected under the Berne Convention, the

Copyright Act 1999 and other international and national enactments, in that behalf,
on intellectual property. It may not be reproduced by any means, in full or in part,
except for short extracts in fair dealings, for research or private study, critical schol-

arly review or discourse with an acknowledgement, without the written permission


of the Directorate of Postgraduate Studies, on behalf of both the author and the
University of Dar es Salaam.
iii

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

The author wishes to pay tribute to several persons without whose help, direct or
indirect, this work would not have been completed. First and foremost, I wish to
express my gratitude to God for giving me such a wonderful opportunity to study in

Tanzania and for supplying the understanding I needed to pursue my research and
complete my studies. Without Him, I could have done absolutely nothing.

Secondly, my thanks go to all my lecturers who, out of their wealth of experience

and expertise, imparted to me vital knowledge in various aspects of Mathemat-


ics. Thirdly, special thanks are due to my supervisors, Dr Charles Wilson Mahera

(UDSM, Tanzania) and Dr Juma Kasozi (Makerere University, Uganda) who saw
to it that I made adequate progress in my research and offered valuable corrective
suggestions and guidance throughout. I will forever value the encouragement and

support that they gave me throughout the hectic period of research and dissertation
writing. I cannot find words to adequately thank them for all their help. Through
their knowledge and expertise I have learned much about insurance modelling and

without them this document would simply not have been completed.

In the fourth place, I wish, from the bottom of my heart, to thank the Council
and Management of Mulungushi University (MU) for the scholarship awarded to me

which made it possible for me to pursue postgraduate studies at UDSM. I am deeply


appreciative for the financial support I have enjoyed throughout my studies. May
the University continue with its good work of developing academics who will enhance

MU’s mission of pursuing the frontiers of knowledge in various fields.

Fifthly, let me take this opportunity to thank the Coordinator of the Norad Pro-

gramme for Masters Studies (NOMA) in the Department of Mathematics at UDSM,


Dr Charles Wilson Mahera, for his inspiration and motivation throughout my studies.
iv

Sixthly, my thanks go to all my colleagues in the Master of Science (Mathemati-


cal Modelling) class for 2009/10 for their encouragement throughout my studies at

UDSM. They were there for me when the going got tough and through their friend-
ship I was able to safely navigate the stormy seas of scientific research and to reach
the shore.

Finally, my heartfelt thanks go to my dear wife, Baptista, and our daughters, Chab-
ota, Choolwe, Chimuka and Christabel, who put up with my long absence from home
so that I might pursue my postgraduate studies in Dar es Salaam. Even when I was

home and busy working on my research, they were very understanding and gave me
the time and space I needed to complete my research. I am blessed to have such a
wonderful family.
v

DEDICATION

To my family
Baptista, Chabota, Choolwe, Chimuka and Christabel
vi

ABSTRACT

The study was conducted on the topic: Minimizing the Probability of Ultimate Ruin
by Proportional Reinsurance and Investments. The purpose of the study was to
determine the role of investments in minimizing the probability of ultimate ruin of an

insurance company, to assess the impact of proportional reinsurance on the survival


of insurance companies as well as to determine the optimal reinsurance percentage
b ∈ (0, 1].

The study considered a risk process comprising a diffusion-perturbated insurance


process and a diffusion-perturbated investment generating process in which invest-

ments were modelled as a Black-Scholes model. The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB)


equation for this problem was derived, as well as its corresponding Volterra integro-
differential equation which was then tranformed into a linear Volterra integral equa-

tion of the second kind. This integral equation was then solved using the block-by-
block numerical method for the retention percentage that minimizes the probability
of ultimate ruin. The major findings of this study were as follows:

1. That, as expected, the higher the investment rate, the lower the ruin probabil-
ity. Furthermore, the study has revealed that volatility of stock prices results

in higher ruin probabilities.

2. That for a given initial surplus, the ruin probabilities keep reducing as the value
of the retention level b reduces. After a certain b, however, the ruin probabilities
begin rising again, giving an indication of the location of the optimal retention

percentage b∗ .

3. That the optimal retention level, given certain assumptions regarding the flow
of premium incomes, is b∗ = 0.315034 for the small claim case and b∗ = 0.461538
in the case of large claims.
vii

Some recommendations have also been made with regard to strategies that could be
used by insurance companies to minimize their ultimate ruin probabilities. The study

has recommended that in order to minimize their ruin probabilities insurers should
invest their surplus in both risky and risk-free assets. It has also been recommended
that insurers buy reinsurance as it helps in reducing the probability of ultimate

ruin for insurance companies. But, given certain assumptions regarding the flow of
premium incomes, insurers can only reinsure optimally when b∗ = 0.315034 for small
claims and b∗ = 0.461538 for large ones.
Contents

Certification . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . i

Declaration and Copyright . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ii

Acknowledgements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iii

Dedication . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v

Abstract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vi

List of Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xii

List of Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiii

List of Abbreviations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiv

Notation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xv

1 CHAPTER ONE
INTRODUCTION 1

1.1 General Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1

1.1.1 Background to the Study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1

1.1.2 Definitions of Terms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2

viii
ix

1.2 Statement of the Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

1.3 Research Objectives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

1.3.1 General Objective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

1.3.2 Specific Objectives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

1.4 Significance of the study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

1.5 Research hypotheses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

1.6 Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

1.7 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

2 CHAPTER TWO
LITERATURE REVIEW 18

2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

2.2 Reinsurance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

2.3 Investments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

2.4 Reinsurance and investments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

2.5 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

3 CHAPTER THREE

MODEL FORMULATION 27

3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

3.2 Cramér-Lundberg Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27


x

3.3 Basic Insurance Process without Reinsurance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

3.4 Insurance Process with Reinsurance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

3.5 Investment Generating Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

3.6 Risk Process with Reinsurance and Investments . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

3.7 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

4 CHAPTER FOUR

MODEL ANALYSIS 35

4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

4.2 Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Equation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38

4.3 Integro-differential Equation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40

4.4 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

5 CHAPTER FIVE

NUMERICAL RESULTS 44

5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

5.2 Numerical Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

5.3 Numerical Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48

5.3.1 Exponential distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49

5.3.2 Pareto distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55

5.4 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
xi

5.4.1 Role of investments in minimizing the probability of ultimate


ruin . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62

5.4.2 Impact of reinsurance on the survival of insurance companies . 62

5.4.3 Optimal reinsurance percentage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63

5.5 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64

6 CHAPTER SIX

CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS 65

6.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65

6.2 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65

6.3 Recommendations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65

6.4 Open problems for future research . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66

REFERENCES 67

APPENDICES 75
List of Tables

5.1 Ruin probabilities for p = 6, λ = 2, µ = 0.5 and h = 0.01 . . . . . . . 51

5.2 Ruin probabilities for p = 6, λ = 2, µ = 0.5 and h = 0.1 . . . . . . . . 52

5.3 Ruin probabilities for p = 6, λ = 2, µ = 0.5 and h = 0.001 . . . . . . 52

5.4 Ruin probabilities for constant force of interest for p = 6, λ = 2 and

µ = 0.5 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

5.5 Ruin probabilities for C-L model with proportional reinsurance for
p = 6, λ = 2, µ = 0.5, 0.2 ≤ b ≤ 1.0 and h = 0.01 . . . . . . . . . . . 56

5.6 Ruin probabilities with exponentially distributed jumps for σP = 0.2 57

5.7 Ruin probabilities for Pareto-distributed claim sizes with p = 6, λ =

2, α = 3 and κ = 2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58

5.8 Ruin probabilities for Pareto-distributed claim sizes with p = 6, λ =

2, α = 2 and κ = 1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59

5.9 Asymptotic ruin probabilities for large claims with proportional rein-

surance (for p = 6, θ = 6.5 and η = 5) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60

5.10 Ruin probabilities for Pareto-distributed jumps with α = 2, σP = 0.2


and σR = 0.2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61

xii
List of Figures

1.1 Sample path of Brownian motion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

1.2 Sample path of Brownian motion with drift . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

1.3 Sample path of geometric Brownian motion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

5.1 Effect on ruin probability of changes in volatility of the stock price (σR ) 63

xiii
xiv

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS

HJB Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman
ECOMOR Excédent du coût moyen relatif (‘excess of the average cost’)
XL Excess-of-loss
B-by-B Block-by-block method
VIDE Volterra integro-differential equation
VIE Volterra integral equation
GBM Geometric Brownian Motion
BM Brownian Motion
SDE Stochastic differential equation
C-L Cramér-Lundberg model
iid independent and identically distributed
a.s. almost surely
iff if and only if
w.r.t. with respect to
s.t. such that
xv

NOTATION

R the real numbers


R+ the non-negative real numbers
Q the rational numbers
Z the integers
P basic probability measure
Ω sample space (or event space) on which probabilities are defined
F σ-algebra of the probability space
{Ft } filtration
AT transpose of the matrix A
detA determinant of the nxn matrix A
C q [c, d] space of functions that are q-times continuously differentiable on [c, d]
A generator of an Itô process
W (t) standard Brownian motion
ξ(t) white noise process
N (t) claim number process
λ claim arrival intensity
Ti i-th occurrence time
p premium rate
b retention percentage for proportional reinsurance
ψ(y) ruin probability
φ(y) survival probability
τb time of ruin
MX (s) moment-generating function of X
F (s), f (s) claim-size distribution, density
F̄ (s) tail distribution F̄ := 1 − F
xvi

s∧t the minimum of s and t (or min(s, t))


lim, lim the same as lim inf, lim sup
∀ for all
 end of proof
CHAPTER ONE
INTRODUCTION

1.1 General Introduction

This study seeks to investigate the impact of proportional reinsurance and invest-
ments on the ruin probability of an insurance company. The purpose of the study is
to determine the role of investments in minimizing the probability of ultimate ruin

of an insurance company, to assess the impact of proportional reinsurance on the


survival of insurance companies as well as to determine the optimal reinsurance per-
centage b ∈ (0, 1]. The chapter outlines the background to the study, defines some

key terms used in the study and gives a statement of the problem. It also states
the objectives of the study as well as the research hypotheses that will guide the
research. In addition, the chapter indicates the significance of the study and outlines

the methodology to be used in undertaking the study. It concludes with a summary


and an indication of what will follow in Chapter Two.

1.1.1 Background to the Study

Modern life is characterized by risks of different kinds, some threatening all persons
and others restricted to the owners of property, while still others are typical for some

individuals or for special occupations. Insurance was born to take all or part of
such risks from the risk-bearer. Under an insurance contract the insurer accepts to
pay part or all of the policyholder’s loss on the occurrence of an uncertain specified

event or risk covered by the contract. In return for this protection or cover the
policyholder accepts to pay the prescribed sum of money, called a premium, on an

agreed regular basis into a pool out of which the unfortunate individuals who actually

1
2

suffer expected loss are compensated.

Insurance therefore operates on the basis of the fortunate many (who do not suffer

loss) helping the unfortunate few (who actually suffer loss through the occurrence of
the risk concerned). In other words, insurance cover or protection is accomplished
through a pooling mechanism whereby many individuals who are vulnerable to a

common risk are joined together into a risk pool. By pooling both the financial
contributions and the risks of a large number of policyholders, the insurer is typically
able to absorb losses incurred over any given period much more easily than would

the uninsured individual. (Merriam-Webster’s Collegiate Encyclopedia, 2000).

However, in providing insurance cover, insurance companies run the risk of their

surplus becoming negative, thus resulting in ‘technical ruin’ (Dutang et al., 2009).
Insurers must therefore take measures to reduce the chances of their surplus becoming
non-positive (that is, the probability of ruin). These measures include investment

of the surplus, taking reinsurance, portfolio selection and volume control through
the setting of premiums. Hipp (2004) referred to these possible actions as control
variables. This study focuses on reinsurance coupled with investment as mechanisms

for reducing the risk in an insurance portfolio. Reinsurance (which is the insurance
of insurance companies) is essential not only from a legal standpoint but also due to
the fact that the risk left to the first-line insurer is usually substantially large.

1.1.2 Definitions of Terms

To clarify ideas about insurance in general, it is necessary to define the following


terms:

Definition 1.1.1. (Insurance) Insurance is an arrangement by which a company


gives customers financial protection against loss or harm such as theft or illness in

return for a payment called a premium (Encarta World English Dictionary, 1999).
3

Definition 1.1.2. (Reinsurance) This is the transfer of risk from a direct insurer
(the cedent) to a second insurance carrier (the reinsurer). It may also be defined

as ‘insurance for insurers.’ It serves the purpose of offering protection to cedents


against very large individual claims or fluctuations in their aggregate portfolio of
risks, as well as diversifying the financial losses caused by it (Centeno and Simões,

2009; Charpentier, 2005; Engelmann and Kipp, 1995).

Definition 1.1.3. (Risk) This is the probability of loss to an insurer or the amount
that an insurer is in danger of losing (Microsoft Encarta Encyclopedia, 2009).

Definition 1.1.4. (Risk theory) Risk theory ‘refers to a body of techniques to


model and measure the risk associated with a portfolio of insurance contracts’ (Du-
tang et al., 2009). It is ‘a synonym for non-life insurance mathematics, which deals

with the modeling of claims that arrive in an insurance business and which gives
advice on how much premium has to be charged in order to avoid bankruptcy (ruin)
of the insurance company’ (Mikosch, 2004).

Definition 1.1.5. (Claim) A claim is a demand made by the insured, or the in-
sured’s beneficiary, for payment of the benefits as provided by the insurance policy
(Insurance Dictionary, 2009).

With reinsurance, therefore, the first-line insurer passes on some of its premium
income to a reinsurer who, in turn, covers a certain proportion of the claims that
occur (Albrecher and Thonhauser, 2009). Indeed, it has been argued very specifically

by Engelmann and Kipp (1995) that reinsurance plays an important role in risk-
reduction for first-line insurers in that it is able to offer additional underwriting
capacity for cedents as well as to reduce the probability of a direct insurer’s ruin.

This is one of the hypotheses that is investigated in this study. But if, in addition,
the company decides to invest its surplus, it must decide on an investment strategy
that aims at contributing to the minimization of the infinite time ruin probability.

This study, therefore, focuses on the determination of a reinsurance strategy that


4

minimizes the probability of ultimate ruin for an insurance company in the presence
of investments.

Definition 1.1.6. (Surplus) A surplus is the amount of money that remains after

all liabilities have been met. In other words, an insurance company accumulates a
surplus when the premiums collected over a given period of time exceed the claims
that have been paid over that period (Encarta World English Dictionary, 1999; Mo,

2002).

The difference between insurance and risk theory highlighted in Definitions 1.1.1
and 1.1.4 is also underscored by Malinovskii (2000). According to him, insurance
is a method of coping with risks, while the object of risk theory is to give a mathe-

matical analysis of random fluctuations in the insurance business and to discuss the
various means of protection against their inconvenient effects. Classical risk theory
focuses its attention on the outflow process, looking first at claim numbers, then

at the distribution of claim sizes and finally combining these two into an aggregate
claim amount process. The income process, which is the initial capital plus premium
income, is introduced in a fairly simple way, growing linearly in time at a constant

rate. If the insurance company also invests some of its surplus, then the resulting
surplus process of the company can be thought of as:

Initial capital + P remium income + Investments − Outf low

It should be noted that claims arrive at an insurance company in a random manner


due to the fact that in most cases financial losses occur abruptly. Because of this,

the mathematical analysis of an insurance business calls for a branch of mathematics


which deals with modelling uncertainty or randomness. This branch is called proba-
bility theory. In this regard some key concepts from general probability theory will

now be defined:
5

Definition 1.1.7. (Sample space) A sample space Ω is the set of all possible
outcomes of some random experiment (Kijima, 2003).

Definition 1.1.8. (σ-algebra) A σ-algebra (or σ-field) is a collection F of subsets

of Ω with the following properties:

1. ∅, Ω ∈ F

2. If A ⊂ Ω ∈ F, then Ac = Ω\ A ∈ F.

S∞ T∞
3. If A1 , A2 , . . . ∈ F, then k=1 Ak , k=1 Ak ∈ F

(Evans, 2006; Kijima, 2003).

Definition 1.1.9. (Probability measure) Let F be a σ-algebra of subsets of Ω.


Then the probability measure is a set function P : F → [0, 1] defined on F and

satisfying the following properties:

1. P(∅) = 0, P(Ω) = 1

2. 0 ≤ P(A) ≤ 1 for any event A ∈ F

S∞ P∞
3. If A1 , A2 , . . . ∈ F, then P( k=1 Ak ) ≤ k=1 P(Ak )

S∞ P∞
4. If A1 , A2 , ... is a sequence of disjoint sets in F, then P( k=1 Ak ) = k=1 P(Ak )
It follows that if A, B ∈ F, then A ⊆ B implies P(A) ≤ P(B)

(Evans, 2006; Kijima, 2003).

Definition 1.1.10. (Random variable) Let Ω be a non-empty finite set and let

F be the σ-algebra of all subsets of Ω. A random variable X is an F-measurable


function X : Ω → R if the probability of each outcome of X can be calculated based
on the probability measure P (Øksendal, 1998; Kijima, 2003).
6

Definition 1.1.11. (Probability space) A Probability space is the triple (Ω, F, P),
where Ω is a non-empty set, F is a σ-algebra consisting of subsets of Ω and P the

probability measure on Ω (Øksendal, 1998; Geiss, 2010).

Definition 1.1.12. (Filtration) Let Ω be a non-empty finite set. A filtration

{F}t∈R+ is a sequence of σ-algebras F0 , F2 , . . . , Fn s.t. each σ-algebra in the


sequence contains all the sets contained by the previous σ-algebra (Chalasani and
Jha, 1998).

Definition 1.1.13. (Filtered probability space) This is a quadruple


(Ω, F, {F}t∈R+ , P), where {F}t∈R+ is the filtration which models the flow of infor-

mation up to time t ≥ 0 (that is, which determines the timing of the revelation of
information) (Irgens and Paulsen, 2004; Duffie, 2009).

Definition 1.1.14. (Stochastic process) A stochastic process is a parameterized


collection of random variables X(t) (t ∈ T ) defined on a probability space (Ω, F, P)
and assuming values in Rn . In other words, it is a family of random variables X(t)

parameterized by time t ∈ T , where T is the parameter set of the stochastic process


(Øksendal, 1998; Kijima, 2003).

It will be assumed that all stochastic quantities and random variables (see Defini-
tions 1.1.10 and 1.1.14) are defined on a large enough filtered probability space

(Ω, F, {F}t∈R+ , P) where Ω is the sample space, F the σ-algebra on Ω, {F}t∈R+ the
filtration and P the probability measure defined on F.

Definition 1.1.15. (Poisson process) An integer-valued stochastic process N =


{N (t)}t∈R+ is a Poisson process if it starts at zero, if it has independent increments,
if the random variable N (t + s) − N (s), 0 ≤ s < t, is Poisson distributed and if it has

càdlàg (continue à droit, limite à gauche) sample paths. For a detailed definition,
see Geiss (2010), Mikosch (2004) and Ramasubramanian (2005).

Definition 1.1.16. (Claim number process) The claim number process is a


7

counting process N = {N (t)}t∈R+ which models the number of claims that occurred
up to time t ≥ 0 (Mikosch, 2004).

The most common claim number process is the Poisson process because of its good

theoretical properties (as seen in Definition 1.1.15). The jump sizes (or claim sizes)
will be modelled by an exponential distribution (for small claims). In his 1903 the-
sis, Lundberg exploited it as a model for the claim number process {N (t)} (Mikosch,

2004). However, because the (homogeneous) Poisson process does not always de-
scribe claim arrivals in an adequate way, other processes to model the number of
claims were developed. Examples of these are:

1. Renewal process

Definition 1.1.17. (Renewal process) Let {Xi } be an iid sequence of a.s.

positive random variables. Then the random walk

T0 = 0, Tn = X1 + X2 + ... + Xn , n ≥ 1,

is said to be a renewal sequence and the counting process

N (t) = #{i ≥ 1 : Ti ≤ t}, t ≥ 0,

is the corresponding renewal (counting) process.

2. Mixed Poisson process

Definition 1.1.18. (Mixed Poisson process) Let Ñ be a standard homo-


geneous Poisson process and µ be the mean value function of a Poisson process

on [0, ∞). Let θ > 0 a.s. be a (non-degenerate) random variable independent


of Ñ . Then the process

N (t) = Ñ (θµ(t)), t ≥ 0,
8

is said to be a mixed Poisson process with mixing variable θ

(Mikosch, 2004; Geiss, 2010).

Definition 1.1.19. (Homogeneous Poisson Process) A Poisson process with


a mean value function µ defined as µ(t) = λt, t ≥ 0 for some λ > 0, is said to
be homogeneous, inhomogeneous otherwise (Mikosch, 2004). The major difference

between a homogeneous Poisson process and an inhomogeneous one is that for the
former the arrival rate λ is constant, whereas the latter allows for the arrival rate to
be a function of time λ(t) (Daniel, 2007; Gershman and Wilkerson, 2010).

The quantity λ is the intensity or rate of the homogeneous Poisson process. If λ = 1,

then N is called a standard homogeneous Poisson process.

Mikosch (2004) further asserts that a homogeneous Poisson process {N (t)}t∈R+ with

intensity λ:

1. has càdlàg sample paths,

2. starts at zero,

3. has independent and stationary increments, that is, for any 0 ≤ s ≤ t and

h > 0, N (s, t) has the same distribution as N (s + h, t + h). That is, the random
variables N (t) − N (s) and N (t + h) − N (s + h) have the same distribution
or probability law. This means that the probability law of the number of

claim arrivals in any interval of time depends on the length of the interval
(Ramasubramanian, 2005),

4. is P ois(λt) distributed for every t > 0,

5. is a non-decreasing process. That is, if 0 ≤ s < t, then N (s) ≤ N (t). Note


that N (t) − N (s) denotes the number of claims in the interval (s, t] (Ramasub-

ramanian, 2005).
9

Definition 1.1.20. (Lévy Process) A process on R+ with properties 1 − 3 above


is called a Lévy process. (Mikosch, 2004)

The homogeneous Poisson process is one of the prime examples of Lévy processes

with vast applications in life. Ramasubramanian (2005) adds two other properties
of the claim number process {N (t)}:

1. The probability of two or more claim arrivals in a very short time span is
negligible, that is, P(N (h) ≥ 2) = o(h), as h ↓ 0.

2. In a very short time interval, the probability of exactly one claim arrival

is roughly proportional to the length of the interval, that is, ∃ λ > 0 s.t.
P(N (h) = 1) = λh + o(h), as h ↓ 0.

Definition 1.1.21. (Wiener process) Let {W (t)}t∈R+ be a stochastic process de-


fined on some filtered probability space (Ω, F, {F}t∈R+ , P), where Ω is a non-empty
finite set, F the σ-algebra of all subsets of Ω, {F}t∈R+ the filtration that models flow

of information up to time t ≥ 0 and P a probability measure. The process {W (t)}t∈R+


is a Brownian motion or Wiener process if:

1. W (0) = 0.

2. It has independent increments

3. The increments W (t) − W (s) are Gaussian with mean zero and variance t − s,
independently of time t.

4. The sample paths t ∈ [0, ∞) → W (t, ω) of the process {W (t)} are continuous

functions of time.

(Kijima, 2003; Cosimano and Himonas, 2009)


10

Note: The white noise process ξ(t) is a stochastic process and is the derivative
of Brownian motion (that is, dW (t) = ξ(t)dt). White noise is introduced to model

uncertainties in the underlying deterministic differential equation. However, there


are several other stochastic processes that model systems that vary randomly in time.

Definition 1.1.22. (Sample paths of Brownian motion) An occurrence of a


Brownian motion {W (t)}t∈R+ observed from time 0 to time T is called a realisation

or sample path of the process on the time interval [0, T ]. (Kijima, 2003)

Figure 1.1, which was simulated using the MATLAB program simbrownian.m in
Appendix E(1), shows such a path.

According to Kijima (2003), paths as functions of t, W (t, ω) for ω ∈ Ω, have the

following properties: Almost every sample path

1. is a continuous function of time t,

2. is nowhere differentiable, that is, not differentiable at any point of time,

3. has infinite variation on any interval, no matter how small the interval is, and

4. has quadratic variation on [0, t] equal to t, for any t ∈ [0, T ].

Brownian motion has several applications; for quite some time, Brownian motion

has been used to model prices of risky assets such as share prices, foreign exchange
rates, and many others.

Definition 1.1.23. (Brownian motion with drift) Let W (t) be a Brownian


motion and let µ and σ be two real numbers. Then

S(t) = µt + σW (t) (1.1)

is called a Brownian motion with drift (or arithmetic Brownian motion). (Di-

ener, 2007)
11

1.5

0.5
W(t)

-0.5

-1

-1.5
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
b=0.2

Figure 1.1: Sample path of Brownian motion

Brownian motion (and later Brownian motion with drift) was proposed by Bachelier
in 1900 as a model for stock prices. However, this model had one drawback, namely,

that the stock prices could assume negative values (as both Figure 1.1 and Figure 1.2
clearly show). For this reason, mathematicians and financial analysts have since

resorted to the geometric Brownian motion as a better model for stock prices. This
model was first proposed by Samuelson (1965) who argued that real stock prices
could not be negative because of the limited liability of shareholders.

Definition 1.1.24. (Properties of sample paths of Brownian motion with

drift) Consider a real-valued Brownian motion with drift, S(t) = µt+σW (t), defined
on a filtered probability space. Then the sample paths of S(t) possess the following
properties:

1. Sample paths are a.s. continuous.


12

2. Sample paths are of infinite variation on any finite interval [0, t].

3. The quadratic variations of Brownian motions with drift are finite on any in-
terval [0, t] and a.s. converge to σ 2 t in the limit n → ∞ (as the partition

becomes finer and finer).

(Matsuda, 2005)

Figure 1.2, simulated using the MATLAB program brownian.m in Appendix E(2),
shows a sample path of Brownian motion with drift.

20
BM with drift
quadratic variation
15

10
X(t)

-5
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
Drift = 10, diffusion coefficient = 5

Figure 1.2: Sample path of Brownian motion with drift

Definition 1.1.25. (Geometric Brownian motion) A stochastic process {S(t)}

is said to follow a geometric Brownian motion if it satisfies the following stochastic


differential equation (SDE):

dS(t) = µS(t)dt + σS(t)dW (t), (1.2)


13

where W (t) is a standard Brownian motion, µ the percentage drift or expected change
in S(t) and σ the percentage volatility or the variance of the change, whose solution
n 2
 o
is S(t) = S(0) exp µ − σ2 t + σW (t) (Hubbard and Saglam, 2006).

In other words, geometric Brownian motion is a continuous-time stochastic process


in which the logarithm of the randomly varying quantity follows a Brownian mo-

tion. The process {S(t)} is a log-normally distributed random variable with mean
 
2
E[S(t)] = S(0)eµt and variance var[S(t)] = S(0)2 e2µt eσ t − 1 . Geometric Brow-
nian motion has applications in such fields as insurance, economics, mathematical

epidemiology, and so on, and has gained a lot of popularity in the field of finance as a
model for prices of risky assets owing to its very important property of not taking on
negative values. A sample path of geometric Brownian motion was simulated using

the MATLAB program geometric brownian.m in Appendix E(3) and is shown in


Figure 1.3.

geometric Brownian motion


80
quadratic variation

60
S(t)

40

20

0
0 1 2 3 4 5
 = 1,  = 1

Figure 1.3: Sample path of geometric Brownian motion

Definition 1.1.26. (Compound Poisson process) A stochastic process {S(t)}t∈R+


14

N (t)
X
is called a compound Poisson process if it can be represented by S(t) = Si ,
i=1
t ≥ 0, where {N (t)}t∈R+ is a (homogeneous) Poisson process and S1 , S2 , . . . are iid
random variables that are also independent of {N (t)}t∈R+ (Boxma and Yechiali, 1995;
Kijima, 2003).

Depending on the choice of the counting process {N (t)}, there are different models
for the total claim amount process {S(t)}. For example, in the Cramer-Lundberg
model, where {N (t)} is a homogeneous Poisson process, {S(t)} is modelled as a

compound Poisson process. Another prominent model for S(t) is called the renewal
or Sparre-Andersen model, where {N (t)} is a renewal process (see Geiss (2010) for
details).

Note: The information about the asymptotic growth of the total claim amount
enables one to give advice as to how much premium should be charged in a given
time period in order to avoid bankruptcy (ruin) in the portfolio. Common classical

premium calculation principles include the net or equivalence principle, the expected
value principle, the variance principle and the standard deviation principle, all of
which are well described in Mikosch (2004).

Definition 1.1.27. (Total claim amount process) The total (or aggregate) claim
N (t)
X
amount process {S(t)} is defined as S(t) = Si , t ≥ 0, where {N (t)} is the claim
i=1
number process.

The distribution of the total claim amount process can be calculated using an exact
numerical procedure known as the Panjer recursion scheme (Mikosch, 2004). The

distribution of the claim size can also be approximated using the central limit theorem
or by means of Monte Carlo simulation techniques. Suffice it to say that the total
claim amount process {S(t)} is a compound Poisson process (see Definition 1.1.26).

Collective risk theory disregards individual claims in favour of the total gain or loss
15

of the insurance company. Therefore, this section will discuss the issues that are
addressed by collective risk theory. A claim size distribution is a distribution that

represents the sizes of claims that the insurance company has to pay. The question
that arises here is, ‘What are the realistic claim size distributions?’ In the literature,
many different types of distributions have been suggested. These are grouped into

two:

1. Light-tailed distributions

These are distributions of small claims. In order to determine whether a dis-

tribution of the claim size is light-tailed or heavy-tailed we use the exponential


distribution as a benchmark. Thus, if

F̄ (x)
lim sup <∞
x→∞ e−λx

for some λ > 0, where F̄ (x) = 1 − F (x), x > 0, then F is referred to as light-
tailed. According to Mikosch (2004) (see Table 3.2.17), examples of light-tailed

distributions include the exponential (common for its desirable properties),


gamma, Weibul and truncated normal.

2. Heavy-tailed distributions

These are distributions of large claims. Such claim size distributions typically
occur in a reinsurance portfolio, where the largest claims are insured. If

F̄ (x)
lim inf >0
x→∞ e−λx

∀ λ > 0, then F is called heavy-tailed. Examples of heavy-tailed distributions


include, among others, Pareto and log-normal distributions. (See Table 3.2.19,

Mikosch, 2004; also Günther, 2008).

Alternatively, a distribution is said to be heavy-tailed if its mean excess function,


Z ∞
1
defined as eF (u) = F̄ (y)dy, u ∈ [0, sr ), converges to infinity as u → ∞,
F̄ (u) u
16

whereas if eF (u) converges to a finite constant as u → ∞, then F is said to be


light-tailed.

This study considers a risk model comprising two distinct processes: a surplus-
generating process and an investment-generating process. The surplus-generating
process to be considered here is a diffusion-perturbated classical risk process that

incorporates proportional reinsurance and investments and is an extension of the


classical risk process or the Cramér-Lundberg model. The investment-generating
process includes investment in both risk-free and risky assets. The study seeks to

determine the value of the retention percentage b that minimizes the probability of
ultimate ruin in the presence of investments and to compare this with the case when
there is no reinsurance.

1.2 Statement of the Problem

Due to the ever-present possibility of frequent or large claims, an insurance company

is always faced with the risk of ruin. Of the many risk-reduction strategies available
to the company, it is assumed that the company uses reinsurance and investment.
In particular, it is assumed that the company takes out a quota-share proportional

reinsurance contract and invests its surplus in the money market as well as the stock
market. With these assumptions, the study seeks to find an optimal reinsurance
percentage b ∈ (0, 1], that is, the value of b that minimizes the probability of ultimate

ruin ψ b (y) or, equivalently, maximizes the ultimate survival probability φb (y) =
1 − ψ b (y).
17

1.3 Research Objectives

1.3.1 General Objective

The general objective of the study is to minimize the probability of ultimate ruin by
proportional reinsurance and investments.

1.3.2 Specific Objectives

The specific objectives of the study are to:

1. Determine the role of investments in minimizing the probability of ultimate


ruin of an insurance company.

2. Assess the impact of proportional reinsurance on the survival of insurance


companies.

3. Determine the optimal reinsurance strategy b ∈ (0, 1].

1.4 Significance of the study

This study is significant in the following ways:

• It will assist decision-makers in the insurance industry (such as managers of

insurance companies) in choosing appropriate retention percentages aimed at


minimizing the probability of ultimate ruin.

• It will add to the existing body of knowledge on mathematical applications in


the insurance industry.
18

1.5 Research hypotheses

In this study, it was hypothesized that:

1. Investments play a key role in minimizing the probability of ultimate ruin of


an insurance company.

2. Proportional reinsurance has a positive impact on the survival of insurance

companies.

3. There exists an optimal reinsurance strategy b ∈ (0, 1], that is, a value of the

retention percentage b that maximizes the probability of ultimate survival, thus


minimizing the probability of ultimate ruin of the insurance company.

1.6 Methodology

• The risk model is formulated theoretically with all the parameters (e.g., volatil-
ity constant, rate of premium flow, rate of return from the investments, and so
on) assumed to be unknown but from a certain set. All the theorems necessary

for the existence of solutions, as well as verification theorems, are given and
proved.

• The optimal value of the retention percentage b is found by solving an integro-


differential equation (IDE). In cases where exact solutions are hard to find,

numerical schemes to approximate the solutions are developed. These schemes


should have been tested for cases where exact solutions exist to verify their
levels of accuracy.

• The model is validated using parameters that are commonly used in the insur-
ance literature. Model validation has been done with the help of FORTRAN

and MATLAB.
19

1.7 Conclusion

This chapter has outlined the background, significance and objectives of the study,

as well as the problem statement, research hypotheses and format of the study. The
objectives of the study were presented as to determine the role of investments in
minimizing the probability of ultimate ruin of an insurance company, to assess the

impact of proportional reinsurance on the survival of insurance companies and to


determine the optimal reinsurance percentage b ∈ (0, 1]. Chapter Two provides a re-
view of literature relevant to optimal control involving investments and proportional

reinsurance.
CHAPTER TWO
LITERATURE REVIEW

2.1 Introduction

The aim of this chapter is to review relevant literature on optimal control involving
proportional reinsurance and investments. In this regard, the publications reviewed
are organized into three categories: those dealing with reinsurance, those dealing

with investments and those dealing with both reinsurance and investments. These
three categories of literature are presently reviewed.

2.2 Reinsurance

According to Mikosch (2004), reinsurance treaties are of two types: Random walk
type reinsurance which includes proportional, excess-of-loss (XL) and stop-loss rein-

surance, and extreme value type reinsurance which includes largest claims and ECO-
MOR reinsurance (Excédent du coût moyen relatif or ‘excess of the average cost’).
Proportional reinsurance is a common form of reinsurance for claims of ‘moderate’

size, and requires the reinsurer to cover a fraction of each claim equal to the fraction
of total premiums the reinsurer receives from the cedent. Excess-of-loss (XL) rein-
surance involves the reinsurer paying for all individual losses in excess of some limit

D (called a deductible or retention) (Mikosch, 2004; Centeno and Simões, 2009).


Stop-loss reinsurance involves the reinsurer covering losses in the portfolio exceeding
a well-defined limit K (the cedent’s retention). With largest claims reinsurance, at

time t = 0 the reinsurer guarantees to cover the k largest claims occurring in the
time period [0, t]. An ECOMOR reinsurance treaty is really an XL reinsurance with

20
21

a random deductible determined by the k-th largest claim in the portfolio (Mikosch,
2004). This study considers proportional reinsurance, which is also of two types:

quota-share and surplus reinsurance. With quota-share reinsurance the insurer and
reinsurer agree to share claims and premiums in the same proportion and this pro-
portion remains constant throughout the portfolio. In a surplus treaty the reinsurer

agrees to accept an individual risk with sum insured in excess of the direct reten-
tion limit set by the ceding company (expressed in monetary units) (Goovaerts and
Vyncke, 2004).

The problem of optimal reinsurance was first studied by Bruno de Finetti(1940). In


his study, de Finetti analysed quota-share proportional reinsurance policies, referring
to both a one-year period and an infinite time horizon and using the mean-variance

method to find optimal retention levels. de Finetti’s approach starts from considering
that any reinsurance policy reduces the insurer’s risk (in terms of the variance of the
random profit and the related ruin probability) as well as the expected profit. He

then proposed a two-step method: The first step involves minimizing the variance
under the constraint of a given expected profit, whereas the second one, assuming the
expected profit as a parameter, leads to the choice, based on a preference system,

of a particular solution (Pitacco, 2004). In solving the problem of the retentions


ri , 0 ≤ ri ≤ 1, i = 1, 2, . . . , n, that would minimize the retained variance, de Finetti
n o
µ[(1−ci )Pi −E(Si )]
derived the solution ri =min V ar(Si )
, 1 , where ci is the commission rate, Pi

is the gross premium (before expenses and reinsurance) for risk Si , and µ depends on
the cedent’s expected profit. He then concluded that if a risk is actually reinsured,
the retention is directly proportional to the safety loading and inversely proportional

to the variance of the risk.

Waters (1983) studied the behaviour of the adjustment coefficient as a function

of the retention for quota-share (r) and for excess-of-loss (M ). Under the usual
assumptions, he proved that r < 1 when the premium is calculated using the variance
22

principle or the exponential principle. He further proved that if the aggregate claims
are compound Poisson and the reinsurance premium is calculated according to the

expected value principle (with loading coefficient β), the optimal retention is attained
at the unique point M satisfying M = R−1 ln(1 + β), where R is the adjustment
coefficient.

In a study that complements the work of Waters (1983), Hald and Schmidli (2004)
considered the problem of maximizing the adjustment coefficient under proportional
reinsurance both for the Cramér-Lundberg model and the Sparre-Andersen model

in which {N (t)} is a renewal process. As an improvement on Waters (1983), they


computed the maximal adjustment coefficient R(b0 ) and the maximizing parameter
b0 in an efficient way using a method that results in a unique solution. Instead of

solving the so-called Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation and using it to calculate the


optimal reinsurance strategy, they calculated the asymptotic value of the optimal
reinsurance.

Glineur and Walhin (2006) revisited de Finetti’s retention problem for proportional
reinsurance by applying the convex optimization method. They extended the result

to variable quota-share and surplus reinsurance with table of lines and found, by
means of a numerical example, that neither variable quota share reinsurance nor
surplus reinsurance with table of lines may be considered as optimal reinsurance

structures. They were able to determine the optimal quota-share and surplus rein-
surance strategies. However, the numerical example also led them to the conclusion
that there exists no general rule asserting superiority of either quota-share-type or

surplus-type reinsurance above the other.

These results differ from those arrived at in an earlier study by Lampaert and Walhin

(2005) on the optimality of proportional reinsurance. In their study, they considered


a numerical example which confirmed that quota-share reinsurance is suboptimal
when compared to all other types of proportional reinsurance. They found that,
23

in fact, quota-share reinsurance would only be of interest to the ceding company


when the reinsurer’s safety loading is smaller than that of the insurer. Lampaert

and Walhin (2005) also observed that surplus reinsurance with a table of lines based
on the inverse frequency or inverse rate method, is not optimal when compared to
surplus reinsurance with one single line. This goes against the traditional belief of

practitioners. They did not prove that this is always true but simply that a table
of lines is not always optimal. They also derived, using de Finetti’s criterion, the
optimal table of lines which their numerical example showed to be more efficient

than the other proportional reinsurance programmes.

2.3 Investments

In their study on stochastic control theory for optimal investment, Castillo and
Parrocha (2003) sought to determine the investment strategy that minimizes infinite
time ruin probability. In this regard, they considered an insurance business with a

fixed amount available for investment in a portfolio consisting of one risk-free asset
and one risky asset and gave a numerical algorithm for solving the resulting HJB
equation. Assuming exponential claim-sizes, they used several numerical examples to

derive the optimal investment portfolio for different investment scenarios. Different
from Liu and Yang (2004) the examples showed that, assuming an amount A(t)
available for investment, the fraction of A(t) invested in a risky asset is directly

proportional to the insurer’s surplus. They also concluded, based on the numerical
results, that the optimal combinations of the risk-free and risky asset varies with the
value of A(t) allotted for investment, and that no single optimal combination can

optimize every investment amount. No attempt was made, however, to incorporate


reinsurance in their model.

Liu and Yang (2004) studied the problem of optimal investment for an insurer to
24

minimize its probability of ruin. Their model was a generalization of the model in
Hipp and Plum (2000) and assumed that the insurance company receives premiums

at a constant rate and that it can invest in the money market and in a risky asset
such as stocks. They investigated the investment behaviour numerically for various
claim-size distributions and computed the optimal investment policy and the solution

of the associated HJB equation under each assumed claim-size distribution. They
also investigated the effects of changes in various factors, such as stock volatility, on
optimal investment strategies and survival probability. Furthermore, they extended

their model to allow for cases in which borrowing constraints or (stop-loss) rein-
surance are present. They found that with exponentially distributed claim-sizes the
insurer’s surplus is inversely proportional to the level of investment in the stock mar-

ket, whereas with a Pareto claim-size distribution the optimal investment strategy
is to invest more in stocks when the initial surplus is large. As for the effects of un-
derlying factors on the survival probability, they found that the survival probability

is directly proportional to the risk-free interest rate, the expected rate of return of
stocks, the safety loading and the expected claim-size, but inversely proportional to
the stock price volatility and the intensity λ of the claim number process N (t). Their

study did not explore the possibility of proportional reinsurance and what impact
it would have on the probability of survival (and, therefore, of ruin) in the light of
those various underlying factors.

Paulsen et al. (2005) considered the problem of minimizing the infinite time ruin
probabilities for the diffusion-perturbated classical risk process compounded by a

linear Brownian motion and allowed for stochastic return on investments. They gave
sufficient conditions for the survival probability function to be four times continu-
ously differentiable, which in particular implies that the survival probability is the

solution to a second order integro-differential equation. Transforming this equation


into an ordinary Volterra integral equation of the second kind, they analyzed prop-
erties of its numerical solution by applying the order-four block-by-block method in
25

conjunction with Simpson’s rule. This study, though allowing for investment, does
not incorporate reinsurance of any kind.

2.4 Reinsurance and investments

Schmidli (2002) studied the problem of minimizing the probability of ruin by invest-

ment and reinsurance. He considered a classical risk model and allowed investment
into a risky asset modelled as a Black-Scholes model as well as proportional reinsur-
ance. Using the HJB approach, he found optimal levels of investment and reinsurance

which minimize the ruin probability. Among other things, he found that, for Pareto
distributed claim sizes (for the case where the whole insurance risk is reinsured), in-
vestment and reinsurance decrease the ruin probability considerably for larger initial

capital. But, again, this study assumed investment in a risky asset only.

Irgens and Paulsen (2004) studied the problem of maximizing the expected utility
of the assets of an insurance company at a terminal time by factoring reinsurance

and investments into a diffusion-perturbated classical risk process. In their study


they assumed that the company is allowed to invest its surplus in either a risk-free
asset or a risky one. They also incorporated reinsurance in their model, allowing for

the possibility that the company could cover some of its risk using a proportional
reinsurance contract and the remaining risk using XL reinsurance. They used three

different utility functions: power utility with termination at ruin, logarithmic utility
and exponential utility. By means of the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation
they verified that the suggested solutions were in fact optimal among a fairly large

easily verifiable admissible class of controls. However, in addition to using two types
of reinsurance (proportional and XL), their study did not include the fact that the
insurance company could invest in both a risk-free and a risky asset.

Ma et al. (2008) considered the problem of minimizing the probability of ruin under
26

interest force. Their study focused on the classical risk process and allowed for
the possibility of investing in a risk-free asset as well as purchasing proportional

reinsurance. They found that the optimal proportional reinsurance did actually
minimize the probability of ultimate ruin (by maximizing the survival probability).
They derived the HJB equation but found, differently from Schmidli (2001) and

Schmidli (2002), that it did not always have a smooth solution. For this reason,
they considered two cases. The first case was a trivial case in which they found the
corresponding minimal probability of ultimate ruin and the optimal proportional

reinsurance strategy directly. In the second case, they used the HJB equation to
obtain the minimal probability of ruin and the optimal proportional reinsurance
strategy by means of a new verification theorem. It should be noted that the study

by Ma et al. (2008) did not include the possibility of investing in a risky asset as
well.

In their study, Kim and Lee (2008) sought to determine stochastic optimal rein-

surance and investment strategies for the surplus of an insurance company. They
applied proportional reinsurance and investments to the Cramér-Lundberg model

as well as to a linear diffusion model. The surplus process (with reinsurance)


(F (t))t∈[0,T ] in their study was given by dF (t) = (µ − (1 − u(t))λ) dt + u(t)σ0 dW0 (t),
where µ and λ are the safety loadings of the cedent and reinsurer respectively and

u(t) ∈ [0, 1] is the risk exposure or retention level. This model is the same as the one
in Højgaard and Taksar (1998) who considered a proportional reinsurance policy π
applied to the surplus processRπ (t) of an insurance company governed by an SDE

dRπ (t) = (µ − (1 − aπ (t))λ) dt + aπ (t)σdW (t), where aπ (t) satisfying 0 ≤ aπ (t) ≤ 1


is the control process where 1 − aπ (t) denotes the fraction of all incoming claims that
is reinsured at time t. Kim and Lee’s (2008) model also assumed investment of all

of the insurer’s surplus in a financial market with two stocks whose prices were de-
scribed by linear SDEs. The purpose of their paper was to give an explicit expression
for the optimal reinsurance and investment strategy which maximizes the expected
27

exponential utility of the final value of the surplus of a life insurance company at the
end of the T -th year. To do this, they derived and solved the corresponding HJB

equation. This study only considered investment of the surplus in risky assets and
did not include the case where part of the surplus could be invested in a risk-free
asset.

Paulsen’s (2008) study on ruin models with investment income is a survey that
treats the problem of ruin in a risk model when assets earn investment income. He
introduces the risk process by means of a basic insurance process and an investment-

generating process. In addition to a general presentation of the problem, the study


also presents the relevant integro-differential equations and obtains exact and numeri-
cal solutions thereunto. Furthermore, Paulsen (2008) obtains asymptotic results and

bounds on the ruin probability, finally exploring the possibility of minimizing the
ruin probability by investment and possibly reinsurance control. In particular, he
considers the case where the insurer has the possibility of purchasing a proportional

reinsurance contract with retention percentage b(t) ∈ (0, 1] as well as investing in


both a risk-free and risky asset having, respectively, rates of return r0 and r, with a
view to minimizing the ruin probability. The risk model in Paulsen (2008), as well

as those in Paulsen and Gjessing (1997b) and Paulsen et al. (2005), forms the basis
of the model to be studied in the research currently being undertaken.

Liu and Ma (2009) studied optimal reinsurance and investment problems for gen-
eral insurance models. Their study considered the utility optimization problem for
an insurance company whose surplus process is described by an SDE driven by a

Brownian motion and a Poisson random measure. Their optimization problem was
based on the consideration that the company can manage its surplus, hence risk,
by investments, proportional reinsurance and consumption. It is assumed that the

company invests its surplus in one risk-free asset and in some risky assets and that
it is allowed to change its investment positions continuously. Additionally, Liu and
28

Ma (2008) assumed that the insurance company can cede a fraction of the incoming
claims, while at the same time yielding a fraction of its premium, to a reinsurance

company. Finally, the insurance company is also allowed to ‘consume’ (in the form of
dividend, refund, etc.). Rather than use the HJB equation approach and optimizing
the survival probability, they used the utility optimization approach by optimizing

a ‘truncated’ utility function with the help of the theory of backward stochastic
differential equations (BSDEs).

In their study on optimality results for dividend problems in insurance, Albrecher

and Thonhauser (2009) discussed several model extensions and possibilities of con-
trol actions on the insurance portfolio surplus process which included reinsurance
and investment. They discussed investment in a risky asset and underscored the role

of proportional and XL reinsurance as control variables for minimizing the ruin prob-
ability but because their interest was in dividends, they did not discuss investment
and reinsurance to any detail.

Edoli and Runggaldier (2010) studied optimal investment in a reinsurance context


with a point process market model. Instead of using the traditional HJB approach

which requires appropriate regularity of the value function as well as other properties
that are not always easy to verify and for which analytic solutions are difficult to
come by, their study focused on value iteration that does not require these regularity

assumptions and that, in certain cases, allows for an analytic solution. In those
cases where an analytic solution may be difficult to obtain, value iteration makes
it possible to compute the optimal values and control to any degree of accuracy.

In fact, the optimal value turns out to be the fixed point of a suitable contraction
operator. The solution therefore involves the determination of this fixed point that
can be arbitrarily closely approximated by iterating this operator sufficiently often.

Thus Edoli and Runggaldier (2010) showed that, by choosing an exponential utility
function that combines features of ruin minimization and utility maximization, it
29

is possible to obtain a semianalytic solution to the problem in the sense that the
solution to the fixed point problem can be expressed in terms of two Volterra integral

equations that can be solved explicitly. They then obtained the optimal investment
and proportional reinsurance strategies numerically.

None of the literature reviewed in this chapter deals with the retention percentage b ∈

(0, 1] for reinsurance as the only control variable in the presence of investments (as the
current study proposed to do). Those dealing with reinsurance and investments all
consider both the reinsurance and investment strategies as control variables. In other

words, they determine the values of the retention level b ∈ (0, 1] and the investment
level a ∈ [0, 1] (where a is the proportion of the insurer’s surplus invested in a
risky asset) that minimize the probability of ultimate ruin of an insurance company.

Furthermore, to the researcher’s knowledge, no study exists prior to this that applies
the block-by-block method to optimal control problems involving reinsurance. Hence
the importance of this study.

2.5 Conclusion

This chapter of the study has reviewed the relevant literature on proportional rein-

surance and investments. The next chapter outlines the model formulation process
and states the model to be studied.
CHAPTER THREE
MODEL FORMULATION

3.1 Introduction

In this chapter, the model for the study is formulated and the model formulation
process is clearly outlined. This study considers a jump-diffusion model with rein-
surance and investments. But before looking at this model it is necessary to state

the Cramér-Lundberg Model, otherwise referred to as the classical risk process, as it


forms the basis for the model to be formulated.

3.2 Cramér-Lundberg Model

The theoretical foundations of modern risk theory were laid in 1903 by the Swedish
actuary Filip Lundberg. One of Lundberg’s major contributions was the introduction

of a simple model that was capable of describing the dynamics of a homogeneous


insurance portfolio. The principal objective of Lundberg’s model and its extensions
was the determination of the probability of ultimate ruin, that is, the probability

that the insurer’s surplus level ever falls below zero, thus making the firm technically
bankrupt. Lundberg’s model was subjected to rigorous mathematical treatment
about 30 years later by the famous Swedish actuary and probabilist Harald Cramér

(1930). For this reason, this model has come to be called the Cramér-Lundberg
model (or the classical risk process). Cramér extensively developed collective risk
theory, also called ruin theory, by using the total claim amount process S(t) with

Poisson-distributed claim arrivals.

30
31

The Cramér-Lundberg model is given by


N (t)
X
Y (t) = y + pt − Si , t ≥ 0, (3.1)
i=1

where

• Y (t) is the surplus of the insurance company at time t.

• y = Y (0) is the initial surplus or capital.

• p is the premium rate (that is, the the insurer’s premium income per unit time
assumed to be received continuously) which may be given by p = (1 + η)λµ,
where η is the insurer’s safety loading.

• pt is the amount of premium income received by the insurer up to time t.

• {Si } is a sequence of strictly positive independent and identically distributed


(iid) random variables representing the claim sizes, with distribution function

F (s). This study considers Exp(µ) for small claims so that F (s) = 1 − e−µs
κ α

and Pareto(α, κ) for large claims so that F (s) = 1 − κ+s .

• {N (t)} is a homogeneous Poisson process (with intensity λ) which is the count-


ing process for the claims.

• {N (t)} and {Si } are independent.

PN (t)
• i=1 Si (usually denoted by S(t)) is a compound Poisson process with an
average number of claims per time period of λ. This process (also called the

total claim amount process) represents the aggregate losses to the insurance
company.

The classical risk process in (3.1) is the surplus process without reinsurance and has
dynamics given by  
N (t)
X
dY (t) = pdt − d  Si  (3.2)
i=1
32

with initial reserve or surplus Y (0) = y. The Cramér-Lundberg model with reinsur-
ance will be discussed as one of the cases of the jump-diffusion model when certain

parameters are set to zero.

3.3 Basic Insurance Process without Reinsurance

The basic insurance (or surplus-generating) process is given by


NP (t)
X
P (t) = pt + σP WP (t) − SP,i , t ≥ 0, P (0) = 0 (3.3)
i=1

where p is the premium rate, that is, the insurer’s premium income per unit time

assumed to be received continuously. The first term therefore represents the ex-
pected premium income of the insurance company. WP is a standard Wiener process
independent of the compound Poisson process N
P P (t)
i=1 SP,i , {SP,i } is the aggregate

claim amount process of an insurance portfolio, paticularly representing large claims,


and {NP (t)} is a homogeneous Poisson process (with intensity λP ) which models the
number of claims up to time t ≥ 0. In other words, it is the counting process for the

claims. The claim sizes are a sequence of strictly positive independent and identi-
cally distributed (iid) random variables {SP,i }i∈N which are independent of the claim
arrival and claim number processes. We denote by FP the distribution function of
 
SP,i , by µP = E[SP,i ] its mean value and by MS (r) = E erSP,i its moment-generating
function. We will assume that FP (0)=0 and that at least one of σP or λP is non-zero.

The Brownian term σP WP represents random variations in the insurance process.


It should be noted that, given an initial surplus y, when there is no volatility in
the surplus and claim amounts (that is, when σP = 0) then equation (3.3) becomes

the classical risk process (or the Cramér-Lundberg model). If the initial surplus of
the insurance company is y, then equation (3.3) is referred to as the classical risk
process perturbed by a diffusion or a diffusion-perturbated classical risk process (e.g.

in Furrer and Schmidli, 1994; Irgens and Paulsen, 2004; Cai and Xu, 2006).
33

3.4 Insurance Process with Reinsurance

But equation (3.3) represents the insurer’s surplus process without reinsurance. Now

suppose that the insurer can take out reinsurance. In other words, suppose it is able
to cede some of the risk it carries to a reinsurer. Then the company can only do so
at the expense of a share of the premiums it receives from its clients. Reinsurance

was defined in definition 1.1.2 and is of two types: Random walk type reinsur-
ance which includes proportional, excess-of-loss (XL) and stop-loss reinsurance, and
extreme value type reinsurance which includes largest claims and ECOMOR rein-

surance (Excédent du coût moyen relatif or ‘excess of the average cost’). A full
description of these types of reinsurance is given in Mikosch(2004), Geiss (2010),
Goovaerts and Vyncke (2004) and Centeno and Simões (2009) (see also Chapter

Two). While the literature generally points to non-proportional forms of reinsurance


(such as stop-loss or XL reinsurance) as more efficient (for example, Denuit and
Vermandele, 1998; Lippman, 1972; Borch, 1969), this study focuses on proportional

reinsurance which, as Lampaert and Walhin (2005) point out, is the easiest way of
covering an insurance portfolio.

With proportional reinsurance, the first-line insurer (which is the ceding company
or cedent) and the reinsurer agree on a cession percentage for each policy in the
insurance portfolio. These two parties may also have to agree as to which type

of proportional reinsurance to adopt: quota-share type reinsurance or surplus-type


reinsurance. Glineur and Walhin (2006) have shown, by means of a numerical exam-
ple, that there exists no general rule asserting superiority of either of these types of

proportional reinsurance above the other. For this reason, this study restricts itself
to quota-share proportional reinsurance.

The cession percentage represents how both premiums and claims will be shared

between the two parties. Let the stochastic process {b(t)}t∈R+ , where b(t) is the
34

retention level at time t for reinsurance, represent a reinsurance strategy with values
in (0, 1]. This means that the insurer pays b(t)SP,i of the i-th claim SP,i occurring

at time t (i ∈ R+ ), while the reinsurer is liable for (1 − b(t))SP,i . Similarly, if pi is


the premium corresponding to the i-th policy, then the reinsurer receives (1 − b(t))pi
while the insurer retains b(t)pi . For quota-share reinsurance, however, the retention

level, as well as the cession percentage, is constant over the entire insurance portfolio,
that is, b(t) = b for all risks occurring at any time t (Paulsen, 2008; Schmidli, 2002).
Thus under a quota-share proportional reinsurance contract, the reinsurer is liable

for (1 − b)SP,i while the insurer covers bSP,i of the i-th claim occurring at time t.
The factor (1 − b) is the cession percentage for the reinsurance which represents
the proportion of claims ceded to the reinsurer as well as the share of premiums the

reinsurer is to receive from the first-line insurer (Glineur and Walhin, 2006; Lampaert
and Walhin, 2005; Schmidli, 2001; Ma et al., 2008).

If b = 0 then all the risk is reinsured, whereas if b = 1 then there is no reinsurance.

Thus, if reinsurance is possible, the retention percentage will be a fraction between


0 and 1. If the expected value premium principle is used, then for the reinsurance

a premium rate of (1 − b)(1 + θ)λE[S] has to be paid, where θ is the reinsurer’s


safety loading. This means that under proportional reinsurance the premium rate
left to the insurer is bp. The insurer’s surplus-generating process (with reinsurance)

becomes
NP (t)
X
b
P (t) = bpt + bσP WP (t) − bSP,i (3.4)
i=1
having dynamics
 
NP (t)
X
dP b (t) = bpdt + bσP ξ(t)dt − d  bSP,i  (3.5)
i=1

where ξ(t) is a white noise process. Assuming an initial surplus y and setting σP
to zero in equation (3.4) yields the Cramér-Lundberg model with reinsurance. This
(the classical risk process with reinsurance) is the model which was studied by Ma

et al. (2008) who obtained the minimal probability of ruin as well as the optimal
35

proportional reinsurance strategy using the dynamic programming approach, as well


as by Schmidli (2002) who allowed for investment into a risky asset modelled as

a Black-Scholes model and obtained, by means of an HJB equation, the optimal


reinsurance and investment strategies for minimizing the ultimate ruin probability.
Equation (3.4) represents the jump-diffusion insurance process to be used in this

study.

3.5 Investment Generating Process

The classical risk model represented by equation (3.1), though simple, is rather
inadequate for modelling real-world insurance processes. As Taylor and Buchanan
(1988) have observed, ‘While this theory is well developed and well known, there

are a number of respects in which it lacks realism to a point which militates against
its practical use without substantial modification.’ One of the major limitations of
the Cramér-Lundberg model is that it does not account for interest earned on the

reserve (Hipp, 2003; Kasozi and Paulsen, 2005b). In other words, it assumes that the
insurance company does not earn any interest on its surplus. In addition, according
to Hipp (2004), the Cramér-Lundberg model does not account for long tail business

with claims that are settled long after occurrence of the claim, nor does it include
time-dependence or randomness of premium income and of the size of the portfolio.

This study deviates from the classical setting and assumes that in addition to rein-
surance the company invests some of its surplus in a risk-free asset such as a bond at
a positive risk-free rate r0 and the rest in a risky asset such as a stock or market in-

dex described by the geometric Brownian motion. In other words, for simplicity, we
consider only two assets in the financial market: a risk-free bond and a risky asset,
namely stocks (Liu and Yang, 2004). The first attempt to incorporate investments

in the Cramér-Lundberg model was undertaken in 1942 by Segerdahl whose assump-


36

tion was that capital earned interest at a fixed rate. This assumption also appears in
Paulsen (2003). Other researchers have expanded on this area since then and it has

increasingly become popular (for example, Black and Scholes (1973) whose model
is discussed below). Paulsen and Gjessing (1997b) considered a risk process with
stochastic return on investments. This study seeks to modify Paulsen and Gjessing’s

model by incorporating proportional reinsurance.

The Black-Scholes model is a model of the varying price of financial instruments, in


particular stocks, over time. In this model, the main assumption is that the price

of the underlying instrument follows a geometric Brownian motion with constant


drift and volatility. In the Black-Scholes model, the time set is an interval of the
form [0, T ]. The price of the risk-free bond is the bank account process B(t) whose

dynamics is:

dB(t) = r0 B(t)dt

where B(t) is the price of the risk-free bond at time t, and r0 > 0 is the risk-free
interest rate.

The price of the stock is the process S(t) which is modelled by a geometric Brownian
motion with dynamics:

dS(t) = rS(t)dt + σR S(t)dWR (t)

where S(t) is the price of the stock at time t, r is the expected instantaneous rate of re-
turn of the stock (r > 0), σR is the volatility of the stock price (σR > 0), {WR (t)}t∈R+
is a standard Brownian motion defined on the probability space (Ω, F, P) and inde-

pendent of {WP (t)}t∈R+ (Liu and Yang, 2004), and dWR (t) = ξ(t)dt (ξ(t) being
white noise). The risky asset (stock) yields a higher return than the risk-free bond,
that is, r0 < r.
37

Combining all these into a return on investments process (as in Paulsen and Gjessing,
1997b) gives the following:
NR (t)
X
R(t) = rt + σR WR (t) + SR,i , t ≥ 0, R(0) = 0 (3.6)
i=1

where WR (t) is another Brownian motion independent of the surplus process P (t)
and N
P R (t)
i=1 SR,i is another compound Poisson process. Taking λR > 0 makes the

model more realistic in that it ensures that sudden changes in the value of the stock

are taken into account; however, it will be assumed here that λR = 0, so that we
have the Black-Scholes model:

R(t) = rt + σR WR (t), t ≥ 0, R(0) = 0 (3.7)

In other words, the insurance company can invest part of its surplus in a risk-free

asset and the rest in a risky asset. The interpretation of (3.7) is that r is the risk-
free part of the investments so that R(t) = rt implies that one unit invested at time
zero will be worth ert at time t. The term σR WR (t) then takes account of random

fluctuations in the investment returns.

3.6 Risk Process with Reinsurance and Invest-

ments

The risk process after taking out reinsurance and obtaining investment returns is a

combination of the two processes in equations (3.4) and (3.7). It is the process Y b =
{Y b (t)}t∈R+ which represents the insurance portfolio, that is, the insurance process
compounded by the return on investment process and by proportional reinsurance.

Versions of this process have been extensively studied for ultimate ruin probability
by several authors (see, for example, Paulsen et al. (2005), Paulsen (1998), Paulsen
(2008), Paulsen and Gjessing (1997b), Paulsen and Rasmussen (2003) and Sundt
38

and Teugels (1995)). That is, the risk process has the dynamics

dY b (t) = dP b (t) + Y b (t− )dR(t) (3.8)

Mathematically, this means that Y b is the solution of the linear SDE


Z t
b
Y (t) = y + P (t) +b
Y b (s− )dR(s) (3.9)
0

where the non-negative constant y = Y b (0) > 0 is the initial capital or surplus of
the insurance company, P b (t) is the basic insurance (or surplus-generating) process

in equation (3.4), R(t) the investment process in equation (3.7) and Y b (t− ) denotes
the insurer’s surplus just prior to time t.

In summary, this work analyses the model represented by equations (3.4), (3.7) and
(3.9):
NP (t)
X
P b (t) = bP (t) = bpt + bσP WP (t) − bSP,i
i=1
(3.10)
R(t) = rt + σR WR (t)
Z t
b b
Y (t) = y + P (t) + Y b (s− )dR(s)
0

3.7 Conclusion

In this chapter the model to be studied has been formulated. This is equation (3.9)
which comprises the surplus process (equation (3.4)) and the investment generating
process (equation (3.7)). The next chapter analyses the model by way of stating the

HJB equation and its corresponding Volterra integro-differential equation (VIDE).


CHAPTER FOUR
MODEL ANALYSIS

4.1 Introduction

In this chapter the model ((3.10) comprising equations (3.4), (3.7) and (3.9)) is
analyzed. The problem’s HJB equation is stated, as is the corresponding Volterra
integro-differential equation (VIDE) which is then transformed into a linear Volterra

integral equation (VIE) of the second kind.

Definition 4.1.1. (Time of ruin) This is the first time that an insurer’s surplus
process becomes negative and is mathematically defined as


τb = inf t > 0 : Y b (t) < 0|Y b (0) = y ,

with τb = ∞ if Y b (t) remains positive, where Y b (t) is the risk process (equation (3.9)
above) incorporating quota-share proportional reinsurance with strategy b(t) = b ∈

(0, 1]. (Paulsen, 2008; Liu and Yang, 2004)

Then the corresponding probability of ultimate ruin is defined as follows:

Definition 4.1.2. (Probability of ultimate ruin) This is the probability that the
surplus of an insurance company ever drops below zero (Burnecki and Miśta, 2005)

and is mathematically represented as


ψ b (y) = P τb < ∞|Y b (0) = y = 1 − φb (y)

where φb (y) is the probability of survival.

39
40

When the company chooses a quota-share proportional reinsurance strategy b ∈ (0, 1]


and invests its surplus in a risky and risk-free asset, the question then becomes:

‘What value of the retention level b should the insurer choose in order to minimize
the probability of ruin, or in order to maximize the probability of survival?’ This is
the question to be answered in this work. The study seeks to maximize the survival

probability, that is, to find the optimal value

φ(y) = sup φb (y) (4.1)


b∈(0,1]


and, hopefully, the optimal reinsurance strategy {b∗ (t)} s.t. φ(y) = φb (y). The
quantity φ(y) in equation (4.1) is the value function associated with the reinsurance

strategy b ∈ (0, 1]. The survival probability is therefore the objective function and
the control variable to be adjusted so that the objective function is maximized is
the rentention percentage b ∈ (0, 1] for the quota-share proportional reinsurance.

Equation (4.1) will therefore be used to derive the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB)


equation to be solved. The problem is now to find the value of b that will maximize
the probability of ultimate survival (thus minimizing the probability of ultimate

ruin).

By Paulsen (1993), the solution of (3.9) is


 Z t 
b −1 b
Y (t) = R̄(t) y + R̄ (s)dP (s) (4.2)
0

where

r − 21 σR2 t + σR WR (t) ,
 
R̄(t) = exp t≥0

is the geometric Brownian motion so extensively used in Mathematical Finance and


Itô
is the solution of dR̄(t) = rR̄(t)dt + σR R̄(t)dWR (t), with R̄(0) = 1.

Since the investment generating process R(t) follows (3.7), it follows that under weak

assumptions the ruin probability ψ(y) is twice continuously differentiable on (0, ∞)


41

and is a solution to the equation (see Paulsen and Gjessing, 1997b)

Aψ(y) = −λP F̄ (y) (4.3)

(where F̄ (y) = 1 − F (y)) with boundary conditions lim ψ(y) = 0 and ψ(y) = 0 if
y→∞

σP > 0 (see Theorem 4.1.1 below). Here A is the integro-differential operator


Z y
1 2 2 2 2
 00 0
Ag(y) = σ y + b σP g (y) + (ry + bp)g (y) + λP (g(y − bs) − g(y)) dFP (s)
2 R 0
(4.4)

Sometimes it is more convenient (as we do in this study) to work with the survival

probability φ(y) = 1 − ψ(y), in which case (4.3) becomes

Aφ(y) = 0.

The integro-differential operator (4.4), which is the infinitesimal generator for Y b , is


so complicated that explicit analytical solutions involving it are difficult to implement

(Y b solves the linear SDE in (3.9)). It is therefore necessary to resort to the following
simple but useful result which was proved in Paulsen and Gjessing (1997b) and
Constantinescu (2003).

Theorem 4.1.1. Let τb = inf t > 0 : Y b (t) < 0|Y b (0) = y be the time of ruin

where we set τb = ∞ if Y b (t) ≥ 0 ∀ t. Then with the above notation we have


the following:

1. Assume that ψ(y) is bounded and twice continuously differentiable on y ≥ 0


with a bounded first derivative there, where at y = 0 is meant the right-hand

derivative. If ψ(y) solves Aψ(y) = 0 on y > 0, together with the boundary


conditions

ψ(y) = 1 on y < 0,

ψ(0) = 1 if σP2 > 0, (4.5)

lim ψ(y) = 0,
y→∞
42

then

ψ(y) = P(τb < ∞)

Note: Paulsen et al. (2005) used the probability of survival φ(y) = 1 − ψ(y)
with boundary conditions

φ(y) = 0 on y < 0,

φ(0) = 0 if σP2 > 0, (4.6)

lim φ(y) = 1
y→∞

2. Assume that qα (y) is bounded and twice continuously differentiable on y ≥


0 with a bounded first derivative there, where at y = 0 is meant the right-

hand derivative. If qα (y) solves Aqα (y) = αqα (y) on y > 0, together with the
boundary conditions

qα (y) = 1 on y < 0,

qα (0) = 1 if σP2 > 0, (4.7)

lim qα (y) = 0,
y→∞

then

qα (y) = E[eατb ]

4.2 Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Equation

The HJB equation is a partial differential equation which is central to optimal control
theory. The solution to the HJB equation is the value function that needs to be

optimized. In this study, the survival probability φ(y) = 1 − ψ(y) is the value
43

function or objective function to be optimized and the retention percentage b ∈ (0, 1]


is the control variable to be adjusted so that the objective function is maximized,

thus minimizing the ultimate ruin probability (subject to the boundary conditions
in Part 1 of Theorem 4.1.1). The HJB equation for the problem is motivated as
follows (Schmidli, 2008):

Let (0, h] be a small interval, and suppose that for each surplus y(h) > 0 at time h we
ε
have a reinsurance strategy bε s.t. φb (y(h)) > φ(y(h)) − ε. We let b(t) = b ∈ (0, 1]
for t ≤ h. Then

 ε
φ(y) ≥ φb (y) = E φb Y b (h) 1{τb >h}
 

 ε
= E φb Y b (τb ∧ h)


≥ E φ Y b (τb ∧ h) − ε
 
(4.8)

Because ε is arbitrary, we can choose ε = 0. By Itô’s formula, provided that φ(y) is


twice continuously differentiable, we have
Z τb ∧h 
 1 2 2
b
(ry + bp)φ0 Y b (s) + σR y + b2 σP2 φ00 Y b (s)
  
φ Y (τb ∧ h) = φ(y) +
0 2
Z y 
b b
 
+ λ φ Y (s) − a(s, b) dF (s) − φ Y (s) ds (4.9)
0

where a(s, b) = bs denotes the part of the claim SP,i paid by the cedent. Substituting
(4.9) into the expected value (4.8) yields
Z τb ∧h

 1 2 2
(ry + bp)φ0 Y b (s) + σR y + b2 σP2 φ00 Y b (s)
 
E
0 2
Z y  
b b
 
+λ φ Y (s) − bs dF (s) − φ Y (s) ds ≤ 0
0

Dividing by h and letting h → 0 yields, provided that limit and expectation are

interchangeable,
Z y 
0 1 2 2
σR y + b2 σP2 φ00 (y) + λ

(ry + bp)φ (y) + φ (y − bs) dF (s) − φ(y) ≤ 0
2 0
44

This equation must hold ∀ b ∈ (0, 1], that is,


 Z y 
0 1 2 2 2 2
 00
sup (ry + bp)φ (y) + σ y + b σP φ (y) + λ φ (y − bs) dF (s) − φ(y)
b∈(0,1] 2 R 0

≤0 (4.10)

Suppose that there is an optimal strategy b ∈ (0, 1] s.t. lim b(t) = b(0). Then, as
t↓0

above,
Z τb ∧h

 1 2 2
(ry + bp)φ0 Y b (s) + σR y + b2 σP2 φ00 Y b (s)
 
E
0 2
Z y  
b b
 
+λ φ Y (s) − bs dF (s) − φ Y (s) ds = 0
0

1 2 2
Dividing by h and letting h → 0 yields (ry + b0 p)φ0 (y) + σR y + b20 σP2 φ00 (y) +

Z y  2
λ φ(y − b0 s)dF (s) − φ(y) = 0
0

which motivates the HJB equation


 Z y 
0 1 2 2 2 2
 00
sup (ry + bp)φ (y) + σ y + b σP φ (y) + λ φ (y − bs) dF (s) − φ(y)
b∈(0,1] 2 R 0

=0 (4.11)

with boundary conditions φ(y) = 0 on y < 0 and lim φ(y) = 1 (see Theorem 4.1.1).
y→∞

The function φ(y) will satisfy (4.11) only if φ(y) is strictly increasing, strictly concave,
twice continuously differentiable and satisfies φ(y) → 1 for y → ∞ (Hipp and Plum,
2000). In the following, therefore, φ(y) will be assumed to be strictly increasing.

This is consistent with the smoothness assumption and the intuition that the more
wealth there is (through investment), the higher the probability that the insurer
will survive. It will also be assumed that φ(y) is concave. To ensure smoothness

and concavity, the claim density function must be locally-bounded (Liu and Yang,
2004). The following results provide verification of the existence and property of the
solution of the HJB equation (4.11).

Proposition 4.2.1. (Existence of solution) Let the claim-size distribution have


a locally-bounded density. Then the HJB equation has a bounded twice continuously

differentiable solution φ ∈ C 2 (0, ∞) ∩ C 1 [0, ∞).


45

The proof of this result has been given in Hipp and Plum (2003).

Proposition 4.2.2. (Property of the solution) If φ(y) is twice continuously


differentiable and solves the HJB equation (4.11), then it is strictly increasing and

strictly concave.

This result has been proved in Hipp and Plum (2000) and Schmidli (2002).

4.3 Integro-differential Equation

The integro-differential equation for the survival probability φ(y), which follows from
the HJB equation (4.11), is of the form Aφ(y) = 0 (since, by (4.6), φ(y) = 0 for
y < 0), where A is the infinitesimal generator (4.4) of the underlying risk process

(Hipp, 2003), that is,


Z y
1 2 2
σR y + b2 σP2 φ00 (y, b) + (ry + bp)φ0 (y, b) + λP

φ(y − bs, b)dF (s) − λP φ(y) = 0,
2 0
(4.12)

for 0 < y ≤ ∞. Henceforth we drop the subscript in λP and simply write λ. Equation
(4.12) could then be rewritten as
Z y
1 2 2
σR y + b2 σP2 φ00 (y) + (ry + bp)φ0 (y) + λ

φ(y − bs)dF (s) − λφ(y) = 0, (4.13)
2 0

for 0 < y ≤ ∞. Equation (4.13) is a second-order integro-differential equation of the

Volterra type (VIDE). However, repeated integration by parts transforms it into an


ordinary Volterra integral equation (VIE) which will be used in this study.

Theorem 4.3.1. The integro-differential equation (4.13) can be represented as the


Volterra integral equation of the second kind
Z y
φ(y) + K(y, s)φ(s)ds = α(y) (4.14)
0
46

where, for the case with no diffusion (i.e., when σP2 = σR2 = 0) and with no reinsur-
ance (i.e., when b = 1),
r + λF̄ (y − s)
K(y, s) = − ,
ry + p
(4.15)
p
α(y) = φ(0),
ry + p
with F̄ (s) = 1 − F (s). When there is diffusion (i.e., when σP2 + σR2 > 0), but with no

reinsurance, the kernel and forcing function are, respectively,


(2r − 3σR2 + λ)s + p + λF2 (y − s) − (r − σR2 + λ)y
K(y, s) = 2 ,
σR2 y 2 + σP2

 2p (4.16)
2 φ(0) if σP2 = 0,
α(y) = σR y 2
 σP y φ0 (0) if σ 2 > 0,
2 y 2 +σ 2
σR P
P

Rs
with F2 (s) = 0
F (v)dv

But when there is reinsurance, for the case with no diffusion, we have
r + λ (1 − bF (y − bs))
K(y, s) = − ,
ry + bp
(4.17)
bp + λbF2 (s)
α(y) = φ(0),
ry + bp

with F2 (s) defined as above.

Proof. The proof for the case without reinsurance is given in Paulsen et al. (2005).
Here we present the proof for the case with proportional reinsurance. Integrating
equation (4.13) by parts w.r.t. to y on [0, z] gives
Z z
1 2 2  0 1 2 2 0
2 2
σ z + b σP φ (z) − b σP φ (0) − σR 2
yφ0 (y)dy + (rz + bp))φ(z) − bpφ(0)
2 R 2
Z z Z z Z y0 Z z
−r φ(y)dy + λ φ(y − bs)dF (s)dy − λ φ(y)dy = 0
0 0 0 0

(4.18)

Evaluating the third term in (4.18) by integrating by parts yields


 Z z 
1 2 2 2 2
 0 1 2 2 0 2
σ z + b σP φ (z) − b σP φ (0) − σR zφ(z) − φ(y)dy + (rz + bp)φ(z)
2 R 2 0
Z z Z zZ y Z z
−bpφ(0) − r φ(y)dy + λ φ(y − bs)dF (s)dy − λ φ(y)dy = 0,
0 0 0 0
47

which on further simplification becomes

1 2 2 1
σR z + b2 σP2 φ0 (z) − b2 σP2 φ0 (0) + (r − σR2 )z + bp φ(z) − bpφ(0)
 
2 Z2 z Z zZ y
2

− r + λ − σR φ(y)dy + λ φ(y − bs)dF (s)dy = 0.
0 0 0

(4.19)

To simplify the double integral in (4.19) we again use integration by parts and
switch the order of integration using Fubini (Günther, 2008; Schmidli, 2008). Recall
that F (0) = 0 and F (s− ) = F (s) for s ∈ R (F being absolutely continuous w.r.t.
Lebesgue measure). So
Z z Z y Z z  Z y 
0
φ(y − bs)dF (s)dy = φ(y − by)F (y) − φ(y)F (0) + b F (s)φ (y − bs)ds dy
0 0
Z0 z Z zZ y 0

= φ(y − by)F (y)dy + b F (s)φ0 (y − bs)dsdy


Z0 z Z0 z 0 Z z
= φ(y − by)F (y)dy + b F (s) φ0 (y − bs)dyds
Z0 z Z0 z bs
Z z
= φ(y − by)F (y)dy + b F (s)φ(z − bs)ds − b φ(0)F (s)ds
0 0 0
(4.20)

Using the boundary condition that as y → ∞, φ(y) = 1 results in


Z z Z y Z z Z z
φ(y − bs)dF (s)dy = b F (s)φ(z − by)ds − b φ(0)F (s)ds
0 0 0 0

The convolution integral on the right hand side can be written as


Z z
b F (z − by)φ(s)ds. Replacing z with y and y with s and substituting into (4.19)
0
gives

1 2 2 1
σR y + b2 σP2 φ0 (y) − b2 σP2 φ0 (0) + (r − σR2 )y + bp φ(y) − bpφ(0)
 
2 Z y Z2 y Z y
2

− r + λ − σR φ(s)ds − λb φ(0)F (s)ds + λb F (y − bs)φ(s)ds = 0
0 0 0

(4.21)

or
1 2 2 1
σR y + b2 σP2 φ0 (y) − b2 σP2 φ0 (0) + (r − σR2 )y + bp φ(y) − bpφ(0)
 
2 Z2 y
Z y (4.22)
λbF (y − bs) − r + λ − σR2 φ(s)ds = 0

−λb φ(0)F (s)ds +
0 0
48

If there is no diffusion, i.e., if σP2 = σR2 = 0, then this is simply (4.14) and (4.17). If
either σP or σR is non-zero, then integrating (4.22) by parts over y on [0, z] yields

the desired result for the diffusion case.

For illustrative purposes, this study will restrict itself to reinsurance in the non-

diffusion case. The following result has been proved in Ola (2006).

Theorem 4.3.2. The Volterra integral equation of the second kind (4.14) has a
unique solution φ ∈ C ([c, d]) for any continuous α.

4.4 Conclusion

In this chapter the problem’s HJB equation has been stated as well as its correspond-
ing Volterra integro-differential equation (VIDE) which was then transformed into a

linear Volterra integral equation (VIE) of the second kind. Chapter Five proposes
a numerical method for solving this VIE and presents some numerical results based
on light- and heavy-tailed claim-size distributions.
CHAPTER FIVE
NUMERICAL RESULTS

5.1 Introduction

This chapter presents a numerical method for solving the VIE (4.14) and some nu-
merical results based on this method both for small and large claims. In this regard,
results are presented based on the exponential and Pareto distributions for small and

large claims, respectively.

5.2 Numerical Methods

This section discusses numerical solutions of the survival probability φ(y) using a
fixed grid y = 0, h, 2h, . . .. It is assumed throughout that the assumptions of Theorem
4.1.1 hold. For this to happen, by Theorem 4.3.1, it is necessary that r > 12 σR2 (since,

by Paulsen (1998), if φ(y) is the survival probability and p > 0, r > 0 and λ > 0,
then φ(y) > 0 iff r > 12 σR2 , and in this case φ(∞) = 1. When r ≤ 21 σR2 , φ(y) = 0 ∀ y).
The numerical solution of the general linear Volterra integral equation of the second

kind
Z y
g(y) + K(y, s)g(s)ds = β(y), (5.1)
0

where the kernel K(y, s) and the forcing function β(y) are known functions and g(y)
is the unknown function to be determined, is of the form
n
X
gn + h wi Kn,i gi = βn (5.2)
i=1

where gi is the numerical approximation to g(ih), Kn,i = K(nh, ih), gn = g(nh) and
βn = β(nh). The wi are the integration weights. Here, the block-by-block (B-by-

B) method will be used in conjunction with Simpson’s rule of integration (which is

49
50

known to have an error of order 4, see Theorem 5.2.2 and Remark 5.2.3) to obtain
solutions in blocks of two values.

According to Press et al. (1992), the general consensus is that the B-by-B method,
which was first proposed by Young (1954), is the best of the higher order methods for
solving (5.1). The B-by-B methods are essentially extrapolation procedures which

produce a block of values at a time and have the advantage over linear multistep
and step-by-step methods in that they can be of high order and still be self-starting
(Makroglou, 1980; Saeed and Ahmed, 2008; Delves and Mohamed, 1985; Delves and

Walsh, 1974). Apart from not requiring special starting procedures, B-by-B methods
are simple to use and switching step-size presents no problem (Linz, 1969).

Linz (1969) describes a two-block B-by-B method which he used to solve non-linear
Volterra integral equations of the second kind. AL-Asdi (2002) also used two- and
three-block methods for solving Hammersetien-Volterra integral equations of the

second kind, while Saify (2005) solved a system of linear Volterra integral equations
of the second kind using two-, three- and four-block methods. Makroglou (1980)
applied a B-by-B method to the solution of non-linear Volterra integro-differential

equations (VIDEs) with continuous kernels and later (1981) adapted it to VIDEs
with weakly singular kernels. More recently, Kasozi and Paulsen (2005a) used the
two-block B-by-B method to study the flow of dividends under a constant force

of interest. They derived a linear Volterra integral equation of the second kind
and applied an order-four B-by-B method of Paulsen et al. (2005a) in conjunction
with Simpson’s rule to solve the Volterra integral equation for the optimal dividend

barrier.

In another study, Kasozi and Paulsen (2005b) applied an order-four B-by-B method

to the numerical solution of the Volterra integral equation for ultimate ruin in the
Cramér-Lundberg model compounded by a constant force of interest. More pertinent
literature on the B-by-B method is available, for example, in Paulsen (2003) and
51

Paulsen and Gjessing (1997a). But as yet the B-by-B method has not been used in
stochastic control problems involving reinsurance, hence its adoption in the current

study.

To briefly describe the method, Simpson’s rule gives, for any k ∈ C 4 [ih, (i + 2)h],
Z (i+2)h
h
k(s)ds = (k(ih) + 4k((i + 1)h) + k((i + 2)h)) + O(h5 )
ih 3

Therefore, (5.2) becomes

h
g2 + (K2,0 g0 + 4K2,1 g1 + K2,2 g2 ) = β2 (5.3)
3

Here, g1 is unknown, but using the same rule with gridsize h2 , Simpson’s rule gives

h 
g1 + K1,0 g0 + 4K1, 1 g 1 + K1,1 g1 = β1 (5.4)
6 2 2

Quadratic interpolation gives that g 1 ≈ 38 g0 + 34 g1 − 81 g2 . Substituting this into (5.4)


2

yields
   
h 3 3 1
g1 + K1,0 g0 + 4K1, 1 g0 + g1 − g2 + K1,1 g1 = β1 ,
6 2 8 4 8

that is,
  
h 3   1
g1 + K1,0 + K1, 1 g0 + K1,1 + 3K1, 1 g1 − K1, 1 g2 = β1 , (5.5)
6 2 2 2 2 2

Equations (5.3) and (5.5) are a pair of equations to solve for g1 and g2 . Continuing
in this manner in blocks of 2 with wi = 31 {1, 4, 2, ..., 2, 4, 1}, i = 0, 1, . . . , 2m, we get
2m
X h
g2m+2 + h wi K2m+2,i gi + (K2m+2,2m g2m + 4K2m+2,2m+1 g2m+1 + K2m+2,2m+2 g2m+2 )
i=0
3
= β2m+1 (5.6)

and
2m
X h 
g2m+1 + h wi K2m+1,i gi + K2m+1,2m g2m + 4K2m+1,2m+ 1 g2m+ 1 + K2m+1,2m+1 g2m+1
i=0
6 2 2

= β2m+1 (5.7)
52

Now, g2m+ 1 is not known, but may be estimated by quadratic interpolation. Thus,
2

approximating g2m+ 1 by 83 g2m + 34 g2m+1 − 18 g2m+2 and inserting this into (5.7) yields
2

a pair of linear equations for g2m+1 and g2m+2 .

To solve each block from (5.6) and (5.7) for g2m+1 and g2m+2 , we make use of their
form, AG = β, where the 2 x 2 matrix A has entries

h h
a11 = 1 − K2m+1,2m+ 1 − K2m+1,2m+1
2 2 6
h
a12 = K 1
12 2m+1,2m+ 2
4h
a21 = − K2m+1,2m+2
3
h
a22 = 1 − K2m+2,2m+2
3

and vector G=(g2m+1 , g2m+2 )T and vector β = (β1 , β2 )T with


2m  
X h 3
β1 = g2m+1 + h wi K2m+1,i gi + K2m+1,2m g2m + K2m+1,2m+ 1 g2m+ 1
i=0
6 2 2 2

2m
X h
β2 = g2m+2 + h wi K2m+2,i gi + K2m+2,2m g2m
i=0
3

Let d=detA = a11 a22 − a12 a21 6= 0. Then

G = A−1 β
1
(g2m+1 , g2m+2 )T = (β1 a22 − β2 a12 , β2 a11 − β1 a21 )T
d

That is,

β1 a22 − β2 a12
g2m+1 =
d
β2 a11 − β1 a21
g2m+2 =
d

Definition 5.2.1. (Convergence) Let g0 (h), g1 (h), . . . denote the approximation

obtained by a given method using step-size h. Then a method is said to be convergent


53

iff

|gi (h) − g(yi )| → 0, f or i = 0, 1, 2, . . . , N

as h → 0, N → ∞, s.t. N h = a.

Definition 5.2.2. (Order of convergence) A method is said to be of order q if q

is the largest number for which there exists a finite constant C s.t.

|gi (h) − g(yi )| ≤ Chq , i = 0, 1, 2, . . . , for all h > 0

We need to show that the method given by equations (5.6) and (5.7) converges and
also establish its order of convergence. We need the following lemma which forms

the basis for the theorem that follows (Linz, 1969).


n−1
X
Lemma 5.2.1. If |ξn | ≤ A |ξi | + B, A > 0, B > 0 then |ξn | ≤ B(1 + A)n
i=0

The proof follows immediately by induction. As a corollary we have that, if A = hK


and y = nh, then

|ξn | ≤ BeKy (5.8)

Theorem 5.2.2. The approximation method given by equations (5.6) and (5.7) is
convergent and its order of convergence is four.

The proof of theorem 5.2.2 is given by Linz (1969).

Remark 5.2.3. By Theorem 3.1 in Paulsen et al. (2005) and from results in Chapter
7 of Linz (1985), it follows that for a fixed y so that nh = y, the solution satisfies

|gn − g(y)| = O(h4 ), (5.9)

provided that g is four times continuously differentiable as is the case here by The-

orem 2.4 in Paulsen et al. (2005). On the other hand, for the B-by-B method
|g2m+2 − g2m+1 | = O(h4 ) as well.
54

5.3 Numerical Results

This section presents some numerical results obtained using the block-by-block method

outlined in Section 5.2 above. This will be done for the exponential distribution (for
small claims) and the Pareto distribution (for large claims). The ruin probabilities
for the Cramér-Lundberg model are computed and compared with those for the case

when the C-L model is compounded by reinsurance and a constant force of interest
both for the non-diffusion and diffusion cases. For illustrative purposes, the impact
of proportional reinsurance is investigated only for the non-diffusion case, though

results for the diffusion case can also be obtained.

For a given y, ψh (y) is the calculated ruin probability when a gridsize h is used.

Exp(µ) refers to the exponential density f (s) = µe−µs . Thus the distribution function
for the exponential distribution is F (s) = 1 − e−µs and F̄ (s) = 1 − F (s) = e−µs . The
1
mean excess function for the Exp(µ) distribution is eF (s) = µ
, so that F2 (s) =
s − µ1 F (s). Since in the case of the exponential distribution the exact solution ψ(y)

is known for the C-L model, it is possible to compute the absolute percentage relative
error as

ψh (y) − ψ(y)
Dh (y) = 100
ψ(y)

where ψ(y) for Exp(µ) distributed claims is given in Rolski et al. (1998) and Hipp
(2004) by the following equations:

1 −Ry 1
ψ(y) = e ; ψ(0) = (5.10)
1+Λ 1+Λ
pµ Λ
where Λ = λ
− 1 and R = µ 1+Λ . The parameter R is referred to as the adjustment
coefficient or Lundberg’s constant. Equation (5.10) shows that ψ(0) depends only

on the expected claim size and not on the specific form of the claim size distribu-
tion F (s). This distribution makes it possible to gauge the accuracy of the B-by-B
method. Hence the exponential distribution is used extensively in the examples that

follow. However, the Pareto distribution will also be used for modelling large claims.
55

The probability density function of the Pareto distribution is

ακα
f (s) = , (5.11)
(κ + s)α+1

κ α

where α > 0, κ = α − 1 > 0 and the distribution function F (s) = 1 − κ+s . Hence
κ α κ κ
 
the tail distribution is F̄ (s) = κ+s . Also, F2 (s) = s − 1 + κ+s . Note also that
κ+s
the Pareto distribution has a mean excess function eF (s) = α−1 (or 1 + κs ), meaning
that F2 (s) can alternatively be written as s − 1 + κs F (s). All the calculations in


this section were performed on a Toshiba Satellite L300 PC with an Intel Celeron

550 processor at 2.0GHz and 1.0GB internal memory. The B-by-B method was
implemented using the FORTRAN programming language and taking advantage of
its Double Precision feature to obtain satisfactory accuracy. Slower programs like

Splus, R, MATLAB, Maple or Mathematica could, of course, have been used but at
the expense of considerably longer computing time.

5.3.1 Exponential distribution

1. The case without diffusion

Example 1: Ultimate Ruin in the Cramér-Lundberg model


Recall that the model being considered in this study is given by (3.10) (comprising
equations (3.4), (3.7) and (3.9)):
NP (t)
X
b
P (t) = bP (t) = bpt + bσP WP (t) − bSP,i
i=1
R(t) = rt + σR WR (t)
Z t
b b
Y (t) = y + P (t) + Y b (s− )dR(s)
0

To begin with, consider the case when σP = σR = r = 0, b = 1 (meaning there is no


reinsurance) and SP is exponentially distributed with expectation µ. Then the SDE
56

(3.9) takes the form of the classical risk process


NP (t)
X
Y (t) = y + pt − SP,i
i=1

By Itô’s formula, the infinitesimal generator for Y is given by


Z y
0
Ag(y) = pg (y) + λ (g(y − s) − g(y)) dF (s)
0

resulting in the VIDE


Z y
0
pφ (y) + λ (φ(y − s) − φ(y)) dF (s) = 0 (5.12)
0

Integrating by parts on [0, y] transforms (5.12) into a VIE of the second kind:
Z y Z y
p (φ(y) − φ(0)) + λ F (y − s)φ(s)ds − λ φ(s)ds = 0
0
Z y Z 0y
pφ(y) = pφ(0) + λ φ(s)ds − λ F (y − s)φ(s)ds
0 0
Z y
= pφ(0) + λ (1 − F (y − s)) φ(s)ds
0
Z y
= pφ(0) + λ F̄ (y − s)φ(s)ds
0
λ y
Z
φ(y) = φ(0) + F̄ (y − s)φ(s)ds
p 0

that is, (5.12) can be expressed as an ordinary VIE of the second kind
Z y
φ(y) = g(y) + K(y, s)φ(s)ds
0

λF̄ (y−s)
where the forcing function g(y) = φ(0) and the kernel K(y, s) = p
(with
F̄ (s) = 1 − F (s)).

This dissertation does not concern itself with parameter estimation. For this reason,

the paramaters used in the programs are the ones commonly used in the literature.
The process parameters are p = 6, λ = 2 and µ = 0.5. The FORTRAN program
lberg.for in Appendix A has been used to obtain the results in Table 5.1. From Table

5.1, it can be seen that the results are excellent by any standards. Furthermore, the
results satisfy Theorem 4.1.1.
57

Table 5.1: Ruin probabilities for p = 6, λ = 2, µ = 0.5 and h = 0.01

y ψ(y) ψ0.01(y) D0.01(y)


0 0.66666667 0.66666667 0.00000000
5 0.28973213 0.28973214 0.00000345
10 0.12591706 0.12591707 0.00000794
15 0.05472333 0.05472333 0.00000000
20 0.02378266 0.02378266 0.00000000
25 0.01033590 0.01033590 0.00000000
30 0.00449196 0.00449196 0.00000000
35 0.00195220 0.00195220 0.00000000
40 0.00084842 0.00084842 0.00000000

Table 5.2: Ruin probabilities for p = 6, λ = 2, µ = 0.5 and h = 0.1

y ψ(y) ψ0.1(y) D0.1(y)


0 0.66666667 0.66666667 0.00000000
5 0.28973213 0.28973204 0.00003106
10 0.12591706 0.12591690 0.00012707
15 0.05472333 0.05472314 0.00034720
20 0.02378266 0.02378243 0.00096709
25 0.01033590 0.01033568 0.00212850
30 0.00449196 0.00449169 0.00601074
35 0.00195220 0.00195193 0.01383055
40 0.00084842 0.00084794 0.05657575
58

It can be seen by comparing Tables 5.1 and 5.2 that the smaller the step-size h,
the more accurate the results. The results in Table 5.2 (obtained with a step size 10

times that used for results in Table 5.1) are less accurate as is clear from comparing
the absolute percentage relative errors in the two tables. This is in line with our
expectation that the smaller the value of h, the better the results.

But, interestingly, when h decreases, say to 0.001, the results are less accurate,
contrary to what is expected. Table 5.3 shows the results after reducing the value of
h. The errors here are much higher than those in Table 5.1.

Table 5.3: Ruin probabilities for p = 6, λ = 2, µ = 0.5 and h = 0.001

y ψ(y) ψ0.001(y) D0.001(y)


0 0.66666669 0.66666663 0.00000900
5 0.28973213 0.28973186 0.00009319
10 0.12591706 0.12591606 0.00079417
15 0.05472333 0.05472296 0.00067613
20 0.02378266 0.02378273 0.00029433
25 0.01033590 0.01033640 0.00483751
30 0.00449196 0.00449181 0.00333930
35 0.00195220 0.00195068 0.07786087
40 0.00084842 0.00084829 0.01532260

Example 2: Ultimate Ruin under a Constant Force of Interest


Consider the case when σP = σR = 0, r > 0 and b = 1 with exponentially distributed
claims. Thus (3.9) now becomes the Cramér-Lundberg model compounded by a

constant force of interest


NP (t) Z t
X
Y (t) = y + pt − SP,i + r Y (s)ds
i=1 0

Then, by Kasozi and Paulsen (2005b), the survival probability φ(y) satisfies the
59

VIDE
Z y
0
(ry + p)φ (y) + λ (φ(y − s) − φ(y)) dF (s) = 0 (5.13)
0

Obviously, φ(y) = 0 for y < 0 (by (4.5)) and it is well known (by Theorem 4.1.1)
that lim φ(y) = 1. Integrating by parts on [0, y] brings (5.13) into a linear VIE of
y→∞

the second kind. That is,


Z y Z y
[(rz + p)φ(z)]y0 −r φ(z)dz + λ [F (y − s)φ(s) − φ(s)] ds = 0
0 0
Z y Z y
(ry + p)φ(y) − pφ(0) = r (1 − F (y − s)) φ(s)ds
φ(s)ds + λ
0 0
Z y Z y
p r λ
φ(y) = φ(0) + φ(s)ds + F̄ (y − s)φ(s)ds
ry + p ry + p 0 ry + p 0
Z y
p r + λF̄ (y − s)
= φ(0) + φ(s)ds
ry + p 0 ry + p

that is,
Z y
φ(y) = g(y) + K(y, s)φ(s)ds
0

p r+λF̄ (y−s)
where g(y) = ry+p
φ(0) and K(y, s) = ry+p
(with F̄ (s) = 1 − F (s)).

Using the FORTRAN program lberg.for with p = 6, λ = 2, µ = 0.5 and a constant


force of interest r = 0.1 yields the results in Table 5.4. As would be expected, the

higher the value of the investment rate r, the lower the value of the ruin probability.
Thus, using r = 0.2 results in lower ruin probabilities than are obtained when the
surplus is invested at 10% (that is, when r = 0.1). Similarly, investing the surplus at

30% further reduces the ultimate ruin probabilities compared to the ones obtained
if the investment rate is 20% (as is clear from Table 5.4).

Example 3: Ultimate Ruin under Proportional Reinsurance

Next, assume that σP = σR = r = 0 and 0 < b < 1 (that is, the Cramér-Lundberg
model compounded by proportional reinsurance). Then (3.9) becomes
NP (t)
X
b
Y (t) = y + bpt − bSP,i
i=1
60

Table 5.4: Ruin probabilities for constant force of interest for p = 6, λ = 2 and
µ = 0.5

y ψr=0.1(y) ψr=0.2(y) ψr=0.3(y)


0 0.61991511 0.58965945 0.56628834
5 0.21190867 0.16970729 0.14156294
10 0.06587874 0.04216804 0.02965548
15 0.01883184 0.00931477 0.00545558
20 0.00499659 0.00186956 0.00090907
25 0.00124044 0.00034661 0.00014016
30 0.00029012 0.00006011 0.00002029
35 0.00006431 0.00000984 0.00000279
40 0.00001357 0.00000153 0.00000037

By Itô’s formula, the infinitesimal generator for Y b is given by


Z y
0
Ag(y) = bpg (y) + λ (g(y − bs) − g(y)) dF (s)
0

and φ(y) satisfies the VIDE


Z y
0
bpφ (y) + λ (φ(y − bs) − φ(y)) dF (s) = 0
0

This VIDE reduces to the VIE of the second kind (4.14) with K(y, s) and α(y) given
by (4.17) when r = 0. For a given y, let ψb (y) be the calculated ruin probability when
a retention percentage b ∈ (0, 1] is used. Then Table 5.5 summarizes the results for

the Cramér-Lundberg model compounded by proportional reinsurance (i.e., when


r = 0). These results are obtained using the FORTRAN program kasozi.for (in
Appendix B ) with slight modifications. The second column shows the exact ruin

probabilities for the C-L model which are approximated by those in the third column
obtained without reinsurance (i.e., for b = 1). As can be seen by comparing with
Table 5.1 (for y = 0, y = 5 and y = 10) these are the same probabilities obtained
61

earlier. The ruin probabilities, obtained for small values of y, reduce very fast as
the retention percentage reduces (or as the insurance company insures more of its

portfolio of risks). This is to be expected, because the smaller the value of b, the
higher the reinsurance actually bought by the insurer and therefore the lower the
ruin probability.

It is clear from Table 5.5 that the optimal reinsurance percentage lies somewhere
between 20% and 30% (i.e., 0.2 ≤ b∗ ≤ 0.3), meaning that in order to minimize
its probability of ultimate ruin the insurance company should reinsure between 70%

and 80% of its portfolio of risks. According to Schmidli (2008), for exponential
claims the optimal choice of b that maximizes the adjustment coefficient R(b) is
R η
 1

given by b = b ∧ 1, where b = 1 − θ 1 + 1+θ (θ and η are, respectively, the

safety loadings of the reinsurer and insurer). Because maximising the adjustment
coefficient yields the asymptotically best strategy, it is expected that the optimal b
will tend to bR . We assume in this study that the expected value premium principle

is used and that p = 6, θ = 6.5 and η = 5, thus fulfilling the net profit condition.
We also assume that λ = 2 and µ = 0.5 (so that λµ = 1). With these assumptions,
we have the asymptotically optimal bR = 0.315034. It is likely that b∗ is closer to

0.3 than to 0.2, thus tending to the asymptotically optimal bR .

2. The case with diffusion

Example 4: Diffusion model with investments


The diffusion model considered here is represented by equation (4.13), coupled with
(4.14) and (4.16), with b = 1 (that is, when there is no reinsurance). In this example,

the values p = 1.1, λ = 1, µ = 1, σP = 0.2 and σR = 0.2 are fixed. Experimenting


with different interest rates in the FORTRAN program sigma.for (in Appendix C )
gives the results in Table 5.6 below. From the table, it can be seen that the ruin

probability reduces exponentially fast as r increases.


62

Table 5.5: Ruin probabilities for C-L model with proportional reinsurance for p = 6,
λ = 2, µ = 0.5, 0.2 ≤ b ≤ 1.0 and h = 0.01

y ψ(y) ψ1.0(y) ψ0.9(y) ψ0.8(y) ψ0.7(y)


0 0.66666663 0.66666663 0.66666663 0.66666663 0.66666663
1 0.56432116 0.56432110 0.54688060 0.52148592 0.48221368
2 0.47768751 0.47768754 0.44110048 0.38298672 0.28463280
3 0.40435377 0.40435374 0.34833825 0.25113380 0.07227731
4 0.34227809 0.34227806 0.26722115 0.12469435 -
5 0.28973213 0.28973210 0.19616288 0.00166780 -
6 0.24525295 0.24525309 0.13350427 - -
7 0.20760214 0.20760208 0.07762325 - -
8 0.17573142 0.17573130 0.02700675 - -
9 0.14875343 0.14875335 - - -
10 0.12591706 0.12591708 - - -

Y ψ 0.6(y) ψ 0.5(y) ψ0.4(y) ψ0.3(y) ψ0.2(y)


0 0.66666663 0.66666663 0.66666663 0.66666663 0.66666663
1 0.41538268 0.28135574 - - 0.66797197
2 0.09730411 - - - 0.66886067
3 - - - - 0.66943407
4 - - - - 0.66978168
5 - - - - 0.66998798
6 - - - - 0.67009580
7 - - - - 0.67011440
8 - - - - 0.67007297
9 - - - - 0.66999257
10 - - - - 0.66989911
63

Table 5.6: Ruin probabilities with exponentially distributed jumps for σP = 0.2

y ψr=0.1(y) ψr=0.2(y) ψr=0.3(y)


0 1.00000000 1.00000000 1.00000000
5 0.16875151 0.06426304 0.03291060
10 0.03804262 0.00496415 0.00126629
20 0.00390630 0.00005848 0.00000298
30 0.00083081 0.00000213 0.00000001
50 0.00010930 0.00000003 0.00000001
100 0.00000660 0.00000000 0.00000000
150 0.00000116 0.00000000 0.00000000

5.3.2 Pareto distribution

The exponential distribution, on which the above discussion has been based, is light-
tailed. This means that the probability of an extraordinary event is very small. For

this reason, it is safe to say that the insurer can withstand the risk from claims. To
investigate the effect of claim-size distributions more comprehensively, heavy-tailed
distributions also need to be studied.

As Embrechts, Klüppelberg and Mikosch (1997) have shown, a heavy-tailed distri-


bution should be used to model the claim-size distribution. One distribution that

can be studied is the Pareto distribution, which is often more appealing because it
allows the occurrence of extreme events, an important feature of claims in the real
world.

κ α

The distribution function for Pareto(α, κ), F (s) = 1 − κ+s
, will now be used to
show that the block-by-block method still works. The non-diffusion and diffusion
cases will both be investigated for the Cramér-Lundberg model with and without
64

investments and proportional reinsurance.

1. The case without diffusion

Example 5: Ruin probabilities for Pareto(3,2) claim sizes


Using the FORTRAN program lberg.for with appropriate adjustments, and assum-

ing the claim sizes are Pareto-distributed with α = 3 and κ = 2,the ruin probabilities
are computed for the Cramér-Lundberg model and for a constant force of interest.
For a given y, let the calculated ruin probability be given by ψh,r (y), where r ∈ [0, 1]

is the rate of return on investments. Then the results are summarized in Table 5.7
below. The second column shows results for the Cramér-Lundberg model while the
remaining three columns contain results when the Cramér-Lundberg model is com-

pounded by a constant force of interest (for, respectively, r = 0.2, r = 0.2 and


r = 0.3). As can be seen, when the insurance company invests its surplus, its ruin
probability reduces (as expected), and, as with the exponential distribution (see Ta-

ble 5.4), the higher the investment rate, the lower the probability of ultimate ruin of
the insurance company.

Table 5.7: Ruin probabilities for Pareto-distributed claim sizes with p = 6, λ =


2, α = 3 and κ = 2

y ψ0.01,0.0(y) ψ0.01,0.1(y) ψ0.01,0.2(y) ψ0.01,0.3(y)


0 0.33332478 0.32016216 0.31020199 0.30190632
10 0.01803111 0.01219039 0.00930485 0.00752118
50 0.00079770 0.00026306 0.00015865 0.00011347
100 0.00018822 0.00003971 0.00002229 0.00001548
200 0.00003726 0.00000494 0.00000265 0.00000181
300 0.00000941 0.00000098 0.00000052 0.00000035
65

Example 6: Ruin probabilities for Pareto(2,1) claim sizes


Here we consider Pareto(2,1) claim sizes, that is, Pareto distributed claim sizes with
1
distribution function F (s) = 1 − (1+s)2
. Using the FORTRAN program lberg.for
with appropriate adjustments, the ruin probabilities are computed for the Cramér-
Lundberg model and for a constant force of interest. For a given y, let the calculated

ruin probability be given by ψh,r (y), where r ∈ [0, 1] is the rate of return on invest-
ments. Then the results are summarized in Table 5.8.

Table 5.8: Ruin probabilities for Pareto-distributed claim sizes with p = 6, λ =


2, α = 2 and κ = 1

y ψ0.01,0.0(y) ψ0.01,0.1(y) ψ0.01,0.2(y) ψ0.01,0.3(y)


0 0.33247979 0.31035037 0.29738115 0.28743806
10 0.04797877 0.02926035 0.02196535 0.01767497
50 0.00908839 0.00265361 0.00157771 0.00112224
100 0.00385459 0.00074369 0.00041361 0.00028632
200 0.00126421 0.00016199 0.00008649 0.00005897
300 0.00040916 0.00004225 0.00002224 0.00001509

Example 7: Asymptotic ruin probabilities for large claims with propor-


tional reinsurance

Since the optimal retention percentage b tends to the asymptotically optimal bR


that maximizes the adjustment coefficient, we consider here the asymptotic values
of the ruin probability which, for large claims (e.g., Pareto), is given by ψ b (y) ≈
  
1 b
bθ−(θ−η) 1+ y (Schmidli, 2008). Using the FORTRAN program asymprop.for
b

(in Appendix D) the asymptotic ruin probabilities are computed for the large claim
case with p = 6, θ = 6.5 and η = 5. The ruin probabilities are for the Cramér-

Lundberg model compounded by proportional reinsurance. For a given surplus y


66

and retention level b ∈ (0, 1], let the calculated ruin probability be given by ψb (y).
The results for different values of b are summarized in Table 5.9 from which the

optimal retention level can be deduced.

Table 5.9: Asymptotic ruin probabilities for large claims with proportional reinsur-
ance (for p = 6, θ = 6.5 and η = 5)

y ψ1.0(y) ψ0.9(y) ψ0.8(y) ψ0.7(y) ψ0.6(y) ψ0.5(y) ψ0.4(y)


0 0.20000000 0.20689656 0.21621622 0.22950819 0.25000000 0.28571430 0.36363634
5 0.03333334 0.03156049 0.02982293 0.02818522 0.02673797 0.02597403 0.02693603
10 0.01818182 0.01708320 0.01601602 0.01501455 0.01415094 0.01360544 0.01398601
15 0.01250000 0.01171113 0.01094766 0.01023285 0.00961538 0.00921659 0.00944510
20 0.00952381 0.00890942 0.00831601 0.00776115 0.00728155 0.00696864 0.00713012
25 0.00769231 0.00718946 0.00670438 0.00625120 0.00585938 0.00560224 0.00572656
30 0.00645161 0.00602611 0.00561601 0.00523309 0.00490196 0.00468384 0.00478469
35 0.00555556 0.00518682 0.00483165 0.00450016 0.00421348 0.00402414 0.00410889
40 0.00487805 0.00455274 0.00423953 0.00394732 0.00369458 0.00352734 0.00360036

From Table 5.9 it can be concluded that the optimal retention percentage for Pareto-

distributed claims, assuming that p = 6, θ = 6.5 and η = 5, lies between 0.4 and 0.5
(i.e., 0.4 ≤ b ≤ 0.5). The actual optimal value b∗ can be obtained from

1 b 1
ψ b (y) ≈ y = 1.5
 y

6.5b − 1.5 1 + b 6.5 − b
1+ b

3y
The right hand side is minimized for b = 6.5y−1.5
. Letting y → ∞ yields the optimal
3
bR = 6.5
= 0.461538. This is the asymptotically optimal proportional reinsurance
level b∗ . It is also evident from Table 5.9 that when y = 0, the ruin probabilities
increase as b reduces. This is because purchasing reinsurance when the insurance

company has no initial surplus only increases its indebtedness (e.g., to financial
institutions) and therefore seriously jeopardizes its chances of survival.
67

2. The case with diffusion

Example 8: Ruin probabilities for Pareto-distributed jumps with α = 2

and σP = 0.2
Here S has the distribution (5.11) with α = 2, σP = 0.2 and σR = 0.2. The results,
obtained using the FORTRAN program sigma.for with appropriate adjustments,

are summarized in Table 5.10 and clearly show that, as for the exponential dis-
tribution, the ruin probabilities decreased exponentially fast with an increase in r
(compare with Table 5.6).

Table 5.10: Ruin probabilities for Pareto-distributed jumps with α = 2, σP = 0.2


and σR = 0.2

y ψr=0.1(y) ψr=0.2(y) ψr=0.3(y)


0 1.00000000 1.00000000 1.00000000
5 0.20914611 0.09802090 0.05982530
10 0.07639938 0.02290627 0.01171972
20 0.01669192 0.00314645 0.00153139
30 0.00559253 0.00088666 0.00044506
50 0.00123871 0.00018084 0.00009461
100 0.00014082 0.00002088 0.00001122
150 0.00003444 0.00000522 0.00000282

5.4 Discussion

In this section, the impact of investments and reinsurance on the probability of


ultimate ruin is discussed based on the results presented in the previous section.

The discussion is arranged according to the objectives of the study.


68

5.4.1 Role of investments in minimizing the probability of


ultimate ruin

An increase in the rate of return on investments, r, should result in an increase in


the survival probability or a reduction in the ruin probability. Clearly, this is what

happens, as can be seen from Table 5.4 in the previous section. For p = 6, λ = 0.2
and µ = 0.5, as the rate of return on investments increases, the ruin probability
reduces. This is true for both the small and large claim cases, as well as for the

diffusion and non-diffusion cases. This is because the return on investments is higher
if the interest rate is higher, thus the ruin probability is lower. It can therefore
be concluded that investments play a major role in helping insurance companies to

minimize their probabilities of ultimate ruin. The more of their surplus insurance
companies invest in risky and risk-free assets, the lower their ruin probabilities.
Insurers can never reach a point (in terms of investment rate) beyond which it is not

profitable to invest.

However, as stock prices become more volatile (that is, as σR increases), the ruin

probability also increases, and vice versa, as confirmed by Figure 5.1 below. Volatil-
ity is actually a measure of the riskiness of a stock. If the volatility of the stock price
increases but the expected rate of return of the stock stays the same, then the insurer

will find the reward for accepting the risk unattractive and would rather invest less
in stocks and invest more in bonds. Conversely, if the volatility of the stock price
decreases, then the insurer will receive the same return but with a lower risk and

will find that it makes economic sense to invest in the stock. The foregoing applies
to the exponential distribution but is also valid for other distributions (for example,
Pareto).
69

1
 R=0.2
0.9
 R=0.3
Ruin probability ( ) 0.8  R=0.4

0.7  R=0.5

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
Initial surplus (y)

Figure 5.1: Effect on ruin probability of changes in volatility of the stock price (σR )

5.4.2 Impact of reinsurance on the survival of insurance


companies

From the findings on the impact of reinsurance on the ruin probability, it is evident
that for a given b ∈ (0, 1] the ruin probabilities keep reducing up to a given retention
level, after which they begin to increase. This is true for both the light-tailed (ex-

ponential) and heavy-tailed (Pareto) cases. This means that the optimal retention
level for proportional reinsurance lies somewhere around the point at which the ruin
probabilities begin to rise again after consistently falling with a reduction in b. This

is in line with our expectation that the ruin probabilities should keep reducing as the
retention percentage reduces and then start rising again after a certain b, giving an
indication of where the optimal retention percentage lies. The results from the pre-

vious section indicate that proportional reinsurance does have a positive impact on
the survival of insurance companies as it minimizes their ultimate ruin probabilities.
70

5.4.3 Optimal reinsurance percentage

The findings show that insurance companies can reinsure optimally when b∗ =

0.315034 for small claims (for p = 6, λ = 0.2 and µ = 0.5) and when b∗ = 0.461538
for large claims (for p = 6, θ = 6.5, η = 5, where θ and η are, respectively, the safety
loadings of the reinsurer and insurer). This means that an insurance company should

reinsure 70% of its portfolio in the small claim case and about 55% of its risks in the
large claim case. The reason for this difference is that because large claims are also
extremal and therefore rare the company can afford to retain more of its large-scale

risks. Also, since small claims are more frequent the company should retain less of
them and cede a bigger chunk to a reinsurer.

5.5 Conclusion

In this chapter, a numerical method for solving the VIE (4.14) has been presented as
well as some numerical results based on this method both for small and large claims.

In this regard, results have been presented based on the exponential and Pareto
distributions for small and large claims, respectively. The chapter has also analyzed,

discussed and interpreted the findings based on each of the research objectives. The
next chapter draws conclusions and makes recommendations based on the research
findings and the analyses made.
CHAPTER SIX
CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS

6.1 Introduction

This chapter draws conclusions based on the findings from the study. It also makes
recommendations which should be of benefit to insurance companies in terms of
measures they could take to minimize their ultimate ruin probabilities or to ensure

their survival. The chapter closes with an indication of open problems for future
research.

6.2 Conclusion

Findings from the study indicate that investment of the surplus plays an important
role in the survival of insurance companies as it significantly drives down the ultimate

ruin probabilities. Proportional reinsurance also has an impact on the minimization


of the probability of ultimate ruin of insurance companies, thus enhancing their
chances of survival in the market. The study has therefore succeeded in achieving

all the objectives that it proposed to accomplish.

6.3 Recommendations

Based on the findings from this study, it is recommended that insurance companies
should invest more of their surplus in risky and risk-free assets in order to enhance
their chances of survival. Furthermore, insurers should reinsure part of their portfo-

lios in order to minimize their probabilities of ultimate ruin. But, given the assump-

71
72

tions made in this study concerning the flow of premiums, insurers can only reinsure
optimally when b∗ = 0.315034 (small claims) or b∗ = 0.461538 (large claims).

6.4 Open problems for future research

A possible problem for future research would be to apply stop-loss or XL reinsurance

to the model considered in this study. Another problem would involve extending
the model considered in this study by adding a compound Poisson process to the
investment generating process (as in Gjessing and Paulsen (1997) and Paulsen and

Gjessing (1997)) and then applying proportional reinsurance (or some other type of
reinsurance). Thus the investment generating process would be as in (3.6), that is,
NR (t)
X
R(t) = rt + σR WR (t) + SR,i , t≥0
i=1

where WR is another Brownian motion, independent of the compound Poisson process


PNR (t)
i=1 SR,i and NR is a homogeneous Poisson process having intensity λR . The same

numerical method used here would be appropriate for the VIE that would arise. The

task would involve identifying the appropriate forcing function and kernel to use in
the FORTRAN program.
73

REFERENCES

AL-Asdi, A. S. (2002), The Numerical Solution of Hammersetien-Volterra


Second-Kind Integral Equations, M.Sc. Thesis, University of AL-Mustansiriya,
Iraq

Albrecher, H. and Thonhauser, S. (2009), Optimality Results for Dividend


Problems in Insurance, Real Academia de Ciencias Serie A. Matemática, España,

2, 295-320

Black, F. and Scholes M. (1973), The Pricing of Options and Corporate Lia-

bilities, Journal of Political Economy, 81, 637-659

Bloomsbury Publishing Plc (1999), Encarta World English Dictionary, New


York, St. Martin’s Press

Borch, K. (1969), The Optimal Reinsurance Treaty, ASTIN BULLETIN, 5,


293-297

Boxma, O. J. and Yechiali, U. (1995), Poisson Processes, Ordinary and Com-


pound, [Online]. Available from: http : //www.tau.ac.il/~uriy/P apers/encyc57.pdf ,
[accessed: 5 August, 2010]

Burnecki, K. and Miśta, P. (2005), Ruin Probabilities in Infinite Time, Hugo


Steinhaus Center, Wroclaw University of Technology

Cai, J. and Xu, C. (2006), On the Decomposition of the Ruin Probability for
a Jump-Diffusion Surplus Process Compounded by a Geometric Brownian
Motion, North American Actuarial Journal, 2, 120-132

California Lawyers’ Professional Liability Insurance (2009), Insurance Dictionary,


Geisen Insurance Brokers, Inc.
74

Castillo and Parrocha (2003), Stochastic Control Theory for Optimal Invest-
ment, Working Paper, Department of Actuarial Studies, University of New South

Wales

Centeno, M. L. and Simões, O. (2009), Optimal Reinsurance, Real Academia de


Ciencias Serie A. Matemática, España, 2, 387-405

Chalasani, P. and Jha, S. (1997), Steven Shreve: Stochastic Calculus and


Finance, Steven E. Shreve

Charpentier, A. (2005), Optimal Reinsurance with Ruin Probability Target,


University of Rennes

Constantinescu, C. D. (2003), Ruin Theory Under Uncertain Investments,


Unpublished M.Sc. Thesis, Oregon State University

Cosimano, T. and Himonas, A. (2009), Mathematical Methods in Financial

Economics, Lecture Notes 18 & 19

Cramér, H. (1930), On the Mathematical Theory of Risk, Skandia Jubilee

Volume, Stockholm

Daniel, J. W. (2007), Poisson processes (and mixture distributions), Austin


Actuarial Seminars

Delves, L. M. and Mohamed, J. L. (1985), Computational Method for Integral


Equations, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press

Delves, L. M. and Walsh, J. L. (1974), Numerical Solution of Integral Equa-


tions, Oxford, Clarendn Press

Diener, F. (2007), Continuous Time Models in Finance and Stochastic Cal-


culus, Hanoi IMAMIS-CIMPA School
75

de Finetti, B. (1940), Il problema dei pieni, Giornale dell’Istituto Italiano degli


Attuari, 9, 1-88

Denuit, M. and Vermandele, C. (1998), Optimal Reinsurance and Stop-Loss


Order, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 22, 229-233

Duffie, D. (2009), A Review of Steven E. Shreve’s Stochastic Calculus for


Finance, Volumes 1 and 2 , Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society, 1,
165-174

Dutang, C., Goulet, V. and Pigeon, M. (2009), Risk Theory Features of actuar

Edoli, E. and Runggaldier, W. J. (2010), On Optimal Investment in a Reinsur-

ance Context with a Point Process Market Model, Insurance: Mathematics


and Economics (Preprint)

Embrechts, P., Klüppelberg, C. and Mikosch, T. (1997), Modelling Extremal

Events for Insurance and Finance, New York, Springer

Engelmann, B. and Kipp, S. (1995), ‘Reinsurance’, in: Moles, P. (ed.): Encyclo-

pedia of Financial Engineering and Risk Management, New York, Routledge

Evans, L. C. (2006), An Introduction to Stochastic Differential Equations,


Version 1.2, Department of Mathematics, University of California, Berkeley

Furrer, H.J. and Schmidli, H. (1994), Exponential Inequalities for Ruin Prob-
abilities of Risk Processes Perturbed by Diffusion, Insurance: Mathematics

and Economics, 15, 23-36

Geiss, C. (2010), Non-Life Insurance Mathematics, Lecture Notes, University

of Jyväskylä
76

Gershman, D. and Wilkerson, D. (2010), The Poisson Process, PowerPoint Pre-


sentation

Gjessing, H. K. and Paulsen, J. (1997), Present value distributions with ap-


plications to ruin theory and stochastic equations, Stochastic Processes and
their Applications, 71, 123-144

Glineur, F. and Walhin, J. F. (2006), de Finetti’s Retention Problem for Pro-


portional Reinsurance Revisited, Mathematics and Statistics, 3, 451-462

Goovaerts, M. and Vyncke, D. (2004), ‘Forms of Reinsurance’, in: Teugels, J. L.


and Sundt, B. (2004) (eds.), Encyclopedia of Actuarial Science, Vol. III, 1403-1404,
Chichester, John Wiley and Sons

Günther, R. (2008) Ruin Theory in the Cramér-Lundberg Model: When and


How Ruin Occurs, Unpublished M.Sc. Thesis, Berlin University of Technology

Hald, M. and Schmidli, H. (2004), On the Maximization of the Adjustment


Coefficient Under Proportional Reinsurance, ASTIN BULLETIN, 34, 75-83

Hipp, C. (2004), Stochastic Control with Applications in Insurance, Stochas-


tic Methods in Finance, Lecture Notes in Mathematics, 1856, 127-164, Berlin,
Springer-Verlag

Hipp, C. and Plum, M. (2000), Optimal Investment for Insurers, Insurance:


Mathematics and Economics, 27, 215-228

Hipp, C. and Plum, M. (2003), Optimal Investment for Investors with State-
dependent Income, and for Insurers, Finance Stoch., 3, 299-321

Højgaard, B. and Taksar, M. (1998), Optimal Reinsurance Policies for Diffu-


sion Models with Transaction Costs, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics,
22, 41-51
77

Hubbard, T. P. and Saglam, Y. (2006), Stochastic Processes, Itô Calculus and


Applications in Economics, Lecture Notes, Department of Mathematics, Univer-

sity of Iowa

Irgens, C. and Paulsen, J. (2004), Optimal Control of Risk Exposure, Rein-


surance and Investments for Insurance Portfolios, Insurance: Mathematics

and Economics, 35, 21-51

Kasozi, J. and Paulsen, J. (2005a), Flow of Dividends under a Constant Force

of Interest, American J. of Applied Sci., 2(10), 1389-1394

Kasozi, J. and Paulsen, J. (2005b), Numerical Ultimate Ruin Probabilities


under Interest Force, J. of Math. and Stat., 1(3), 246-251

Kijima, M. (2003), Stochastic Processes with Applications to Finance, New


York, Chapman & Hall/CRC

Kim, J. H. and Lee, E. S. (2008), On Stochastic Optimal Reinsurance and


Investment Strategies for the Surplus, Korean Journal of Mathematics, 2, 145-
156

Lampaert, I. and Walhin, J. F. (2005), On the Optimality of Proportional


Reinsurance, Casualty Actuarial Society FORUM, Spring 2005

Linz, P. (1969), A Method for Solving Nonlinear Volterra Integral Euqations


of the Second Kind, Math. Comput., 23(107), 595-599

Linz, P. (1985), Analytical and Numerical Methods for Volterra Equations,


SIAM Studies in Applied Mathematics, Philadelphia

Lippman, S. A. (1972), Optimal Reinsurance, The Journal of Financial and


Quantitative Analysis, 5, 2151-2155
78

Liu, Y. and Ma, J. (2009), Optimal Reinsurance/Investment Problems for


General Insurance Models, Annals of Applied Probability, 19, 1495-1528

Liu, C. S. and Yang, H. (2004), Optimal Investment for an Insurer to Minimize


its Probability of Ruin, North American Actuarial Journal, 2, 11-31

Lundberg, F. (1903), I. Approximerad Framställning av Sannolikhetsfunk-


tionen. II. Återförsäkering av Kollektivrisker, Akad. Afhandling. Almqvist
och Wiksell, Uppsala

Ma, J., Bai, L. and Liu, J. (2008), Minimizing the Probability of Ruin under
Interest Force, Applied Mathematical Sciences, 17, 843-851

Makroglou, A. (1980), Convergence of a Block-by-Block Method for Non-


linear Volterra Integro-Differential Equations, Math. Comput., 35(151), 783-
796

Makroglou, A. (1981), A Block-by-Block Method for Volterra Integro-Differential


Equations with Weakly-Singular Kernels, Math. Comput., 37(155), 95-99

Malinovskii, V. K. (2000), Probabilities of Ruin When the Safety Loading


Tends to Zero, Advances in Applied Probability, 3, 885-923

Matsuda, K. (2005), Introduction to Brownian Motion, Lecture Notes, Depart-


ment of Economics, City University of New York

Merriam-Webster Inc. (2000), Merriam-Webster’s Collegiate Encyclopedia,

Springfield, MA, Merriam-Webster Inc.

Microsoft Corporation (2008), Microsoft Encarta 2009, Microsoft Corporation

Mikosch, T. (2004), Non-Life Insurance Mathematics: An Introduction with


Stochastic Processes, Berlin, Springer-Verlag
79

Mo, K. C. K. (2002), Ruin Probabilities with Dependent Claims, Unpublished


B.Com.(Hons) Thesis, University of New South Wales

Øksendal, B. (1998), Stochastic Differential Equations: An Introduction


with Applications, Fifth Edition, Corrected Printing, Heidelberg, Springer-Verlag

Ola, P. (2006), Lectures on Linear Integral Equations, University of Helsinki,


Finland

Paulsen, J. (1993), Risk theory in a Stochastic Economic Environment,

Stochastic Processes and their Applications, 46, 327-361

Paulsen, J. (1998), Sharp Conditions for Certain Ruin in a Risk Process with

Sochastic Return on Investments, Stochastic Processes and their Applications,


75,135-148

Paulsen, J. (2003), Optimal dividend payouts for diffusions with solvency

constraints, Finance Stoch., 7, 457-473

Paulsen, J. (2008), Ruin Models with Investment Income, Probability Surveys,

5, 416-434

Paulsen, J. and Gjessing, H. K. (1997a), Optimal choice of dividend barriers


for a risk process with stochastic return on investments, Insurance: Math.

and Econ., 20, 215-223

Paulsen, J. and Gjessing, H. K. (1997b), Ruin Theory with Stochastic Return

on Investments, Advances in Applied Probability, 29, 965-985

Paulsen, J. and Rasmussen, B. N. (2003), Simulating Ruin Probabilities for a

Class of Semi-Martingales by Importance Sampling Methods, Scandinavian


Actuarial Journal, 178-216
80

Paulsen, J., Kasozi, J. and Steigen, A. (2005), A Numerical Method to Find the
Probability of Ultimate Ruin in the Classical Risk Model with Stochastic

Return on Investments, Submitted

Pitacco, E. (2004), ‘de Finetti, Bruno (1906-1985)’, in: Teugels, J. L. and Sundt,
B. (2004) (eds.), Encyclopedia of Actuarial Science, Vol. I, 421-423, Chichester, John

Wiley and Sons

Press, W. H., Teukolsky, S. A., Vetterling, W. T. and Flannery, B. P. (1992), Nu-

merical Recipes in FORTRAN 77: The Art of Scientific Computing, 2nd


Edition, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press

Ramasubramanian, S. (2005), Poisson Process and Insurance: An Introduc-

tion, Statistics and Mathematics Unit, Indian Statistical Institute

Rolski, T., Schmidli, H., Schmidt, V. and Teugels, J. L. (1999), Stochastic Pro-

cesses for Insurance and Finance, Chichester, Wiley

Saeed, R. K. and Ahmed, C. S. (2008), Approximate Solution for the System


of Non-linear Volterra Integral Equations of the Second Kind by using

Block-by-block Method, Australian J. of Basic and Applied Sci., 2(1), 114-124

Saify, S. A. A. (2005), Numerical Methods for a System of Linear Volterra

Integral Equations, M.Sc. Thesis, University of Technology, Iraq

Samuelson, P. (1965), Rational Theory of Warrant Pricing, Industrial Manage-


ment Review, 6, 13-31

Schmidli, H. (2001), Optimal Proportional Reinsurance Policies in a Dy-


namic Setting, Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 55-68

Schmidli, H. (2002), On Minimizing the Ruin Probability by Investment and


Reinsurance, Annals of Applied Probability, 12, 890-907
81

Schmidli, H. (2008), Stochastic Control in Insurance, Probability and Its Appli-


cations, London, Springer-Verlag

Schmidt, K. D. (1995), Lectures on Risk Theory, Lehrstuhl für Versicherungs-


mathematik, Technische Universität Dresden

Segerdahl, C. O. (1942), Über einige risikotheoretische Fragestellungen, Skan-


dinavisk Aktuartidsskrift, 25, 43-83

Sundt, B. and Teugels, J. (1995), Ruin Estimates Under Interest Force, Insur-

ance: Mathematics and Economics, 16, 7-22

Taylor, G. and Buchanan, R. (1988), ‘The Management of Solvency’, in: Clas-

sical Insurance Solvency Theory, ed. Cummins, J. D. and Derrig, R. A., Chapter 2,
49-151, Boston, MA, Kluwer Academic Publishers

Young, A. (1954), The application of approximate product-integration to

the numerical solution of integral equations, Proc. Roy. Soc. London Ser. A,
224, 561-573

Waters, H. R. (1983), Some Mathematical Aspects of Reinsurance, Insurance:


Mathematics and Economics, 2, 17-26
82

APPENDICES

View publication stats

You might also like