Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 29

Journal of Business Ethics (2010) 92:151–179  Springer 2010

DOI 10.1007/s10551-010-0575-1

Developing a Normatively Grounded Darryl Reed


Bob Thomson
Research Agenda for Fair Trade: Ian Hussey
Examining the Case of Canada Jean-Frédéric LeMay

ABSTRACT. This paper examines two issues related to FF: Fairtrade Foundation; FT: (Certified) fair trade;
research of certified fair trade goods. The first is the NGO: Non-governmental organization; RIPESS: Inter-
question of how agendas for fair trade research should be national Network for the Promotion of the Social
developed. The second issue is the existence of major gaps Solidarity Economy; SE: Social economy; SR: Socially
in the fair trade literature, including the study of the responsible; TFC: TransFair Canada; TFI: TransFair
particular features of fair trade practice in individual International; TFUSA: TransFair USA; WFTO: World
northern countries. In taking up the first of these issues, Fair Trade Organization
the paper proposes that normative analysis should provide
the basis for developing research agendas. Such an
approach is important to ensure that the necessary types of
questions to make normative judgments and policy
decisions are posed and that biases that tend to favor This paper examines two issues related to the
mainstreaming practices in the generation of knowledge research of certified fair trade (FT) goods.1 The first
are minimized. The paper addresses the second research is the question of how FT research agendas should
issue by examining the development of research agendas be developed, a topic that has received surprisingly
at the level of individual countries, using Canada as a case.
little attention in the literature (Moore, 2004). The
second issue relates to another significant gap in FT
KEY WORDS: alternative trade, certification, co-
operatives, development, fair trade, licensing, non-state research. This is the study of FT in the north and,
regulation, social economy more specifically, the trends and defining features of
FT practice within individual countries.
ABBREVIATIONS: ATO: Alternative Trade Organi- This paper takes up the first of these issues from
zation; CCFT: Canadian Coalition for Fair Trade; ED: the perspective of applied ethics. Applied ethics is
Endogenous development; FLO: Fair labeling organiza- concerned with two basic tasks, making normative
tion; FLO-I: Fair Labeling Organizations International; evaluations and guiding practice to bring it into
conformity with justified goals and norms. From this
perspective, research agendas need to be elaborated
Darryl Reed is associate professor of Business and Society at on the basis of a well-developed understanding of
York University (Toronto). the normative issues at play as only such an under-
Bob Thomson is the retired Ex-founder and Managing Director standing can systematically generate the data and
(1994–2000) of TransFair Canada. He is currently working analysis necessary for normative judgments and
on a book on zero growth. policy decisions that are likely to be effective in
Ian Hussey is a Ph.D. student (sociology, York University), and
promoting practices and results in line with our
was the founding Co-director of the Canadian Students Fair
Trade Network.
norms and goals. The importance of a guiding role
Jean-Frédéric LeMay (Ph.D., anthropology) is a researcher on for normative theory is particularly strong in the case
trade and agriculture at the NGO, Équiterre (Montreal) and of FT for three reasons.
a postdoctoral researcher at the Université du Québec en First, there is the complexity of the normative
Outaouais. issues involved in FT. Not only is there a large
152 Darryl Reed et al.

number of issues involved, but there are qualitatively addition, however, Canada is of interest because of
different types of normative questions (e.g., issues of its patterns of socio-economic development, espe-
procedure, conceptions of the good life, etc.), which cially its strong social economy (SE)2 tradition
need to be addressed (and prioritized). This allows (MacPherson, 2009), and the particular features of
for a wide variety of competing norms and goals its FT practice, e.g., its governance structure, its
within FT (not only across, but also within specific licensee composition, etc.
normative traditions), a situation that can be over- In this examination of FT research agendas, we
whelming for researchers. Without a clear statement draw upon the tradition of critical theory (Haber-
of the nature of the normative issues, it is unlikely mas, 1990, 1996; Reed, 1999, 2009). We use this
that researchers will systematically ask the types of tradition not so much to provide criteria for
questions, which can supply the data and analysis answering specific normative questions, but rather to
that ethicists, policy makers and practitioners borrow categories to differentiate types of normative
want. issues. More specifically, we will distinguish: (1) the
Second, there is a complexity and range of data realm of morality, which concerns questions of
and analysis that need to be produced. Without an procedural fairness; (2) the realm of ethics, which
overarching understanding of the normative issues involves questions of the good life; and (3) the realm
involved, it is difficult to ensure that researchers of legitimacy, which addresses issues of governance
from different disciplines and interdisciplinary fields and the norms of democracy.
will be able to work effectively together to generate The paper proceeds in the following manner.
the full range of data and forms of analyses that are Each of the following three sections examines one of
needed to contribute to answers to complex nor- the three normative realms. In each section, the
mative judgments and policy decisions. key normative issues are first identified. Next, an
Finally, there is the project of FT itself, which account is provided of how these normative issues
seeks to generate alternative practices to support relate to the Canadian context. Third, policy pro-
marginalized groups. Without explicit guidance posals are provided for the Canadian context, which
from normative theory, there is a strong possibility could potentially bring FT practice more in line with
that analysis from the social science (and profes- justifiable norms, while potential trade-offs (and
sional) disciplines will be dominated by mainstream possible conditions for success) are also noted. In the
assumptions, methods and traditions. This could lead final section, a research agenda is developed based on
to a bias in the knowledge that is generated, as such the information that would be required to make
approaches may underinvestigate or even overlook more informed choices regarding the adoption of
important practices and institutions that (could specific policy proposals.
potentially) provide important forms of support for There are several caveats that should be noted.
the alternative strains of FT. First, this paper does not attempt to examine all
The paper addresses the second research issue, the normative issues related to FT. The focus is on the
lack of attention to the practice of FT in individual major normative issues that arise in the practice of
northern countries, by examining the development FT in northern countries, especially Canada. Many
of research agendas using the example of a single issues relating more specifically to producers and
country, namely, Canada. In adopting this approach, certification processes are not discussed.3 A number
the goal is not to provide a well-elaborated social of other, less prominent northern issues are also not
science analysis of FT in Canada, nor is it to offer a dealt with. In addition, we have abstracted from
full normative evaluation. Rather, a particular many, but by no means all, issues relating to Fair
country has been chosen to highlight the facts that Labelling Organizations International (FLO-I). Fi-
FT practice varies across countries and that we have nally, this paper does not address normative issues
not generated the research on specific cases that is that arise at the macro-level of the international trade
necessary to inform cogent normative evaluations regime. While it is essential that such issues be
and develop effective policy in particular contexts. analyzed (and that we do not forget this larger
We have chosen Canada for this task in large context in which FT is situated), such a task is be-
part due to our own familiarity with this case. In yond the scope of this paper.
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 153

Fairness within fair trade network. While this move was initially seen as a
concession to a shortage of production by small
In the tradition of critical theory, morality refers to a producers in some sectors, the use of estate pro-
realm of procedural fairness. The defining feature of duction has grown rapidly in recent years. As these
moral norms is that they are universal in nature. three developments have diversified the practice of
They gain universal validity because all parties to a FT, a variety of issues of procedural fairness have
discourse must be able to consent to them. The arisen. Most of these issues can be subsumed under
reason that moral norms are only procedural in three main categories (Reed, 2009).
nature has to do with the fact that it would not be
possible to get universal consent on more substantive Fairness in licensing
norms relating to issues of the good life (as con- One basic issue in FT is whether all actors of a
ceptions of the good life are inexorably linked to certain category, for example, licensees,4 should be
socialization processes within particular lifeworld treated identically. At first blush, the notion of
contexts). fairness would seem to imply such equal treatment.
The practical use of moral analysis tends to play Upon reflection, however, there may be important
out not so much in efforts to assemble actors reasons for distinguishing between different types of
together to agree on procedural norms, but in the a given actor and treating them differently. In the
critique of norms that aspire to be universal, the case of licensees, there are two closely related reasons
evaluation of whether particular practices are in why some licensees might merit different treatment.
conformity with (potentially) universal norms (e.g., The first reason is that some licensees might live up
the conditions of ideal markets as norms for regu- to higher standards than others (e.g., they purchase
lating actual markets) and the evaluation of whether only FT goods, they provide additional benefits to
we should have common procedural norms for ac- small producers, they engage in FT education and
tors when they operate in different circumstances promotion, etc.) and differential treatment (e.g., a
(Reed, 1999). It is in these latter two ways that we different status, a lower fee structure, etc.) might
will address issues of fairness within FT. encourage such desirable behavior. The second
reason to treat these licensees differently is that their
more commendable practices may entail a higher
The issues cost structure and place them at a competitive dis-
advantage. Treating such licensees differently may
Before the advent of certification, fair trade almost offset this competitive disadvantage to some degree.
exclusively comprised small SE actors who main- Given such differences in practices between licens-
tained close relations in very short value chains. ees, it might appear that a strong case could be made
With the introduction of certification, however, for differential treatment. Interestingly, however, the
three major changes involving the participation of adoption of ISO 65 standards by FLO-I and many
traditional firms have occurred to make the practice fair labeling organizations (FLOs) would actually
much more complex. One change was the incor- seem to make it more difficult for these orga-
poration of traditional retail outlets (first, large gro- nizations to treat licensees differently (Tallontire,
cery chains and, later, specialty shops and other retail 2009).
chains). Initially, retail outlets were not involved as
licensees, but over time there has been a significant Fairness in the FT market
move in this direction. The second development A second issue of fairness relates to the fact that FT
was the entrance of large agro-food corporations, as markets tend not to approximate ideal markets.
well as small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), There are two basic concerns in this regard. On the
into the FT market as licensees. This first occurred in one hand, there are information deficiencies. Con-
a significant way among retail coffee chains and sumers generally do not know much about FT
service providers, but has now spread to other licensees and how they differ (e.g., what their
products as well. The third major change has been business strategies are, what levels of support they
the incorporation of estate production within the FT provide from small producers, etc.). More significant
154 Darryl Reed et al.

still, however, is the fact that corporate licensees may strong commitment to FT. In this regard, Canada is
deliberately withhold information (e.g., what per- similar to most other FT markets. One difference
cent of their sales come from FT products) and between Canada and some of the European markets,
actively seek to confuse consumers about what FT is however, is the lack of a dominant role by NGO-
and how it differs from more corporate-friendly, initiated FT social enterprises (Krier, 2008). In
rival labels (Fridell, 2007; Renard, 2005). Canada, Oxfam Canada was actively involved in
In addition, licensees may also engage in anti- running an FT social enterprise, but the experiment
competitive practices. The types of anti-competitive did not last long and the business was eventually sold
practice that typically occur in the sectors in which to former members of the management team
FT products compete include exclusivity deals (Fridell, 2007). Subsequently, Oxfam Quebec could
(where retailers or wholesalers can only contract later establish its own FT business and brand
from a given supplier), tying (that links products (Équita). While prominent in the Quebec market,
together which are not naturally related), dumping this enterprise has not reached the scale of its
(selling products in competitive markets at below European counterparts.5
cost), limit pricing (setting artificially low prices to By 2000, for-profit businesses, including the first
discourage new entrants) and the use of subsidies corporate licensees, had started to enter the market.
(in the case of FT this might involve cross-subsidi- The influx of traditional business into FT has helped
zation of FT products). In addition, companies to sustain a continual growth of licensees in Canada
might also gain unfair advantages by lowering costs (see Table I) and has resulted in Canada having one
in other problematic ways (e.g., policies and prac- of the highest per capita densities of licensees
tices designed to undermine unionization). It is (135,412) of any country (see Table II). More sig-
typically only larger firms with significant market nificant, perhaps, is the fact that the average sales of
power (oligopolistic status) that can effectively licensees has continued to grow even with the
employ anti-competitive practices (Bagchi, 1998). addition of new licensees. On the other hand,
In FT markets, there are two types of actors, in however, it must be noted that the average per capita
particular, who are in a place to engage in anti- sales of FT goods (e2.42 in 2007) remains relatively
competitive practices, large agro-food corporations low in comparison with leading FT markets such as
and large grocery retailers. They might do so either Switzerland (e21.06) and the UK (e11.57) (Krier,
as licensees or not (Smith, 2010). 2008).
To examine issues of fairness, it is necessary to
categorize FT licensees. As the issues identified
The Canadian context above concern differences in practices among
licensees (and how this might lead to different cost
During its first 2 years of operation, 1997–1998, structures) as well as differences in their size and
TransFair Canada (TFC) licensed 13 businesses. All market power, two basic types of criteria would
of these initial licensees were SE enterprises with a seem to suggest themselves. The first are those that

TABLE I
Growth of TransFair Canada licensees

Type of licensee Year

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

New licensees 5 8 17 41 25 20 25 12 24 45 59 38
Total licensees 5 13 30 65 77 97 110 124 145 185 239 264
Net increase (%) 160 130 117 18 26 13 13 17 28 29 10
Average sales/licensee (‘000s $CDN) 73.2 110.5 141.9 201.9 254.5 321.7 431.2 480.0 757.6

Source: TransFair Canada (2005), Krier (2008).


Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 155

TABLE II
Distribution of licensees in Canada (by provincea and type, 2010)

Province Fair trade business Socially responsible business Traditional businesses Total Pop/licensee

Coop Soc Eprz SEnt Mixed Coop Soc Eprz SEnt Corp SME Pvt Corp Pub Corp

AB 3 6 9 325,922
BC 4 17 15 6 42 109,540
MT 1 1 1,207,959
NB 1 2 3 249,100
NL 1 1 253,947
NS 1 2 3 6 117,288
ON 2 1 4 1 23 31 12 4 78 152,105
PEI 1 1 139,818
QC 3 3 13 3 11 1 50 4 88 83,338
SK 1 1 1,015,985
YK 1 1 2 16,572
Foreignb 3 1 1 1 1 4 4 15 N/A
Total 6 4 25 1 2 3 60 1 111 26 8 247 N/A
RoCc 3 1 12 1 2 49 64 22 8 153 N/A

Source: TransFair Canada (2010).


a
In Canada, there is a distinction between provinces and territories. The latter have much smaller populations and are less
economically developed. All three territories are located in the northern part of the country. Only the Yukon has any FT
licensees. There are none in Nunavut or the Northwest Territories.
b
Foreign = 3rd party + foreign TFC licensees.
c
RoC = Rest of Canada (Total - Quebec).

offer a measure of the commitment of licensees to Fairness in licensing


FT, while the second provide a description of the The distinction of the various types of licensees in
basic business structure of licensees. From the liter- Table III incorporates significant differences in
ature (e.g., Huybrechts and Defourny, 2008; Ray- practices. The first broad category, FT businesses,
nolds, 2009), one might derive a set of criteria to can be subdivided into four groups: FT co-opera-
measure the commitment of firms to FT that in- tives (including buyer and worker coops), FT social
cludes: (a) the percentage of their sales deriving from enterprises (established by non-governmental orga-
FT-certified products; (b) the nature of their rela- nizations (NGOs) as not-for-profit businesses to
tionship with and support for small producers (as promote FT), FT social entrepreneurs (who have set
indicated by the principle of governance of the value up their own SMEs with the purpose of promoting
chain); and (c) their commitment to growing the fair FT) and mixed FT enterprises (with ownership by a
trade movement (as measured by their commitment group of SE businesses dedicated to promoting FT).
to education and advocacy work). The second set of What these businesses have in common are: (1) a
criteria to differentiate business types might involve near 100% commitment to selling FT products; (2) a
standard distinctions made in the analysis of business, direct relationship with small producers based on
including size (large, medium, small), purpose (for solidarity and a commitment to capacity building;
profit, not for profit) and form of incorporation and (3) a commitment to building the fair trade
(privately held corporation, publically held corpo- movement through education and advocacy work.
ration, cooperative, not-for-profit enterprise). Based All of these firms can be categorized as SE
on these criteria, it is possible to distinguish three enterprises.
broad categories of licensees, each containing several Second, there are socially responsible (SR)
subcategories (see Table III).6 businesses.7 These firms are characterized by a
156 Darryl Reed et al.

TABLE III
Fair trade licensees in Canadaa (2010)

Business type Commitment to FT

Fair trade businesses Socially responsible businesses Profit-driven businesses Total

Social economy enterprises


Co-operatives 6 2 8
Social enterprises 4 3 7
SMEs (social entrepreneurs) 25 60 85
Partnerships and mixed ventures 1 1
Traditional firms
SMEs (traditional firms) 111 111
Corporations (privately held) 1 26 27
Corporations (publicly held) 8 8
Total 36 66 145 247

Source: TransFair Canada (2010).


a
In 2009, TFC started to distinguish between: (1) licensees; (2) sub-licensees (with fewer reporting obligations); (3) third
party licensees (who are licensed in a third country, but have signed an agreement with TFC to use its label; and (4) cross
border licensees (who sell products in Canada using a mark from another FLO) (TFC, 2010). This table includes all of the
first three categories. Although there are some licensees in the fourth category (e.g., Divine), TFC does not list such firms
unless it has information on their operations. When we refer to Canadian licensees, we will include all of the above (unless
otherwise indicated).

commitment that falls short of that of FT businesses and none is committed to promoting the FT move-
in at least two of the following ways: (1) they do not ment. Included in this category are SMEs and pri-
sell FT products exclusively; (2) they do not have vately and publicly held corporations. Among these
direct relations with small producers based on soli- firms, corporations rarely if ever sell high percentages
darity; and/or (3) they do not demonstrate a strong of FT products, but SMEs that focus more exclusively
commitment to growing the FT movement. Four on niche markets may.
types of SR business can be distinguished: cooper-
atives (which transform or distribute some FT Fairness in the FT market
products, but do not do so exclusively); social In Canada, the number of corporate licensees has
enterprises (which are committed to selling FT been expanding in recent years, but their presence
products, but the revenue of which is primarily has not been as prominent as in the US or UK. In
oriented toward a different social purpose); social particular, some of the larger companies which have
entrepreneurs (who try to balance FT with making historically been accused of anti-competitive and
profits and/or other social causes); and socially socially irresponsible practices do not (yet) have a
responsible corporations (which have a significant presence in the Canadian market. Thus, for example,
commitment to FT sales, but well short of 100% and while Cadbury recently announced (before being
which tend not to have direct relationships with bought out by Kraft) that it would enter the
small producers and little commitment to building Canadian market, its larger rival Nestlé has not yet
the FT movement). All of these firms, except the last indicated any such intentions (Sampson, 2009).
type, could be categorized as SE enterprises. Similarly, while some of the largest transnational
Third, some businesses are engaged in FT primarily corporations in the fruit sector have become licensed
because of the relatively high profit margins that FT in other countries, such as banana giant Dole (in the
can generate as a niche market (and possibly also for US), they have not yet entered the Canadian market.
image washing purposes). None of these firms main- On the retail side, Wal-Mart has also not yet entered
tain close relationships with producer organizations the Canadian market as a licensee. Exceptions to this
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 157

trend have been Minute Maid (Coca-Cola) and the that their products supply (McMurtry, 2009). The
coffee retail giant Starbucks, which have a significant primary trade-off involved in adopting such a pro-
presence in the Canadian market. posal for a differentiated label is that it might dis-
The extent to which such corporate licensees8 courage participation by corporate licensees in FT
tend to withhold information from consumers and and induce a drop in FT sales. Another concern is
engage in non-competitive practices has not been that such a distinction might further contribute to
widely studied, though some individual cases have confusion among consumers as to what FT is.
been examined,9 nor has the impact of their par- A second policy proposal that TFC could poten-
ticipation in the FT market been well documented. tially implement to promote greater fairness would
Most notable of our concerns in this regard is the involve measures designed to reduce the cost dis-
extent to which they are growing the market or advantages that FT business licensees face when
squeezing out SE licensees, or both. trying to live up to what they see as the spirit of FT.
Particular reform measures here might include a
differential fee structure, more marketing/public
Policy proposals relations support from TFC, etc. Assuming that such
a policy could be effectively implemented, the basic
TFC could potentially address the types of norma- trade-offs involved would include costs to TFC
tive issues raised above by adopting its own policies (e.g., the opportunity costs of not using such funds
and/or advocating within FLO-I for policy changes. for other purposes) and its potential to induce
Whether the implementation of policies will lead to defection by corporate licensees. The likelihood of
successful fulfillment of the intended goals can such a policy being effectively implemented would
depend on a range of actors and factors. Moreover, depend on the mix of measures and the costs
there is also the prospect that success will only be structures of FT business licensees.
partial and may involve undesirable consequences as A third policy proposal that TFC could adopt
well. In deciding on particular policy proposals, would be to increase the licensing requirements for
therefore, decision makers need to be able to identify all licensees. Of particular importance in this regard
the conditions for and likelihood of successful might be establishing significant minimum pur-
implementation. In what follows, some policy pro- chasing requirements. Such a policy, depending on
posals are proffered, which could potentially address where the minimum standards are set, could limit
the key normative issues raised above, along with an the ability of corporations to unfairly draw upon
indication of some of the trade-offs and conditions their status as an FT licensee for public relations and
for success that may be involved. The list of marketing purposes while procuring the bulk of
proposals is clearly not exhaustive. their product under non-FT conditions. Again, the
obvious potential disadvantage of such a proposal is
Fairness in licensing that it might reduce the propensity of corporations
TFC could introduce three basic policy reforms to to participate in FT (inducing a drop in sales and
address issues of fairness in licensing. The first would fewer opportunities for small producers to partici-
entail distinguishing between types of licensees. pate in FT). The extent to which minimum pur-
There are two basic criteria on which licensees chasing requirements would induce such a reaction
might be distinguished: (1) whether they source from corporate licensees is not immediately evident,
from estates or small producers and (2) the degree of but it may be telling that TransFair USA (TFUSA)
their commitment to FT (as measured, for example, felt the need to drop an informally agreed upon 5%
by the percentage that FT sales comprise their total minimum purchasing level to induce Starbucks to
sales). Currently, most consumers do not seem to be sign on as a licensee in 2000) (Jaffee, 2007).
aware of such differences in FT practices (or their
potential implications). Providing consumers such Fairness in FT markets
information through differentiated labels could The traditional markets in many of the sectors in
potentially improve fairness by enabling FT business which FT products have been introduced (e.g.,
licensees to market the additional ‘‘ethical value’’ coffee, bananas, cocoa) have long been dominated
158 Darryl Reed et al.

by large agro-food corporations, which have his- Fairness in licensing


torically engaged in uncompetitive practices. When The key issue of fairness in relationship to licensing
these large corporations decide to move into the FT raised above concerned the facts that FT businesses
market, they bring with them the same potential for have different goals (to drive as much value to small
using their market power to restrict competition. An producers as possible) and different cost structures
urgent question for FT is what can be done to ensure than corporate licensees. One proposal for address-
that that these corporations compete fairly in the FT ing this issue was to develop a separate label for estate
market. In principle, TFC could try to establish its production. The first requirement for assessing the
own monitoring system to ensure fair market com- feasibility of such a proposal is an analysis of the
petition. Given resource constraints, however, a nature and impact of the current practice. Specifi-
more feasible policy approach might be the devel- cally, it is necessary to know the extent of sales that
opment of a complaints mechanism. Small licensees come from estate production in given sectors and
(and possibly even producer organizations) could use how these sales are realized (i.e., in what types of
such a mechanism to report potentially anti-com- retail outlets, at what price and margin, etc.). Fol-
petitive practices on the part of their larger, more lowing on from this, it is necessary to calculate the
powerful rivals (and partners). While a complaints degree to which these sales are currently displacing
mechanism might be a lower cost option to a full sales from small producers and what the long-term
monitoring system, there could be trade-offs in trends may be (Bacon, 2010). To this end, case
terms of the effectiveness of inhibiting anti-com- studies of retailers in particular sectors can be used to
petitive practices (Ascoly and Zeldenrust, 2003). determine whether they have switched from FT
A second problem relating to fairness involves business licensees (and small producer suppliers) to
the lack of information available to consumers and corporate licensees (and estate production). A second
efforts by corporate licensees to confuse consumers approach to investigating the feasibility of this pro-
through their participation in rival labeling bodies. posal is to gather information from consumers
An obvious policy option to address the former issue (through surveys, interviews, focus groups) on their
would be for TFC to require licensees to provide preferences for supporting small producers (and FT
more information as a condition of licensing (e.g., business licensees) over estate production (and cor-
what percent FT sales make up of their total sales). porate licensees) and at what cost. A third step in
With regard to the latter issue, TFC could choose evaluating the desirability of such a proposal would
not to license companies that participate in rival be to estimate the costs entailed in its introduction
certifying programs. Once again, the trade-offs and operation (as well as the likelihood of consumers
involved in adopting such policies come in the form following through on any expressed preferences they
of potential losses in sales due to corporate defections have for small producer production) (Table IV).
from FT (and the resulting impacts on small pro- A second proposal to address issues of fairness
ducers). involved TFC offering support to FT businesses to
help them offset their costs differentials. To evaluate
the viability of such a proposal basic cost–benefit
The need for research analysis can be used. This would require estimating
the effectiveness of such measures (e.g., reduced
Developing policy proposals based on a full range of licensing fees, promotion of licensees) in boosting
normative questions allows for the elaboration of a the competitiveness of FT business (vis-à-vis cor-
more complete research agenda, around which porate licensees. If the benefits are likely to be
individual (and groups of) researchers can orient marginal, then funds that would be required could
their work. It also facilitates the identification of probably be put to better use.
specific research questions that are important for A third proposal to increase fairness in licensing
the effective promotion of FT. Developing and consisted of increasing standards for all licensees
following through on more complete research (e.g., a high minimum sales requirement, stricter
agendas may involve a wide range of methodological pre-financing requirements, etc.). This could
approaches, including action research. potentially reduce the possibilities of corporate
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 159

TABLE IV
Researching issues of fairness

Issue Canadian context Proposal Research agenda

Licensing • Licensee growth • Label for estate • Displacement of small


• Prominent SE licensee sector production producers?
• No dominant SE licensees • Support for 100%ers • Displacement of SE licensees?
• Increasing corporate presence • Minimum • Consumer support?
requirements (e.g., • SE licensee cost structures
procurement) • Costing of proposal
Competition • Overall sales growth • Complaints • Competition strategies of
• Relative contribution of sales mechanism estates and corporate licensees
Estates versus small producers? • Licensing restrictions • Impact on small producers and
SE versus corporate licensees? (e.g., disclosure) SE licensees
• Effectiveness of (non-state)
anti-competitive measures

licensees cross-subsidizing their relatively small FT by other non-state regulatory initiatives to imple-
offerings (Fridell, 2009). It is not clear, however, ment complaints mechanisms (e.g., the Workers’
whether such a proposal is more likely to level out Rights Consortium) (O’Rourke, 2006). A final
costs structures and significantly increase the com- requirement for evaluating the feasibility of such a
petitiveness of FT businesses than it is to induce proposal entails a costing of different variants of
corporate flight from FT. To estimate its impact, it complaint mechanisms (as well as the estimation of
would be necessary to undertake a series of case the likely impact of imposing such a system on
studies of firms in different FT sectors to determine participation by corporate licensees in FT).
what factors induce or inhibit corporate participation Similarly, efforts to evaluate a policy to prohibit
and what weight individual factors tend to carry. participation by FT licensees in rival labeling bodies
need to first gather data on the extent of this practice
Fairness in the FT market and then develop an analysis of how the practice fits
To address the issue of fairness in FT markets, and into corporate strategies (e.g., whether it is intended
the possible need for a complaints mechanism, it is to undermine FT standards, to squeeze out FT
first necessary to develop an accurate understanding business licensees, etc.). On this basis, along with
of the extent of the problem of anti-competitive estimates of the potential impact on sales, a more
practices. This requires case studies and sector studies informed decision can be made about the trade-offs
of practices in both traditional and FT markets.10 involved in this policy.
Such analysis needs to focus both on the level of
production as well as the level of distribution,
including the relationship between large agro-food Ethical issues
processors and grocery distribution chains (Renard,
2010; Smith, 2010). A second related area of re- In the tradition of critical theory, the notion of ethics
search involves the manner in which FT business refers to issues of identity and substantive conceptions
licensees are being impacted by the entrance of of the good life. Because our conceptions of the good
corporate licensees, in particular, whether and to life are not independent of the context in which we
what extent they are being squeezed out of main- have been socialized, it is not realistic to expect
stream distribution channels. A third area of research universal agreement on questions of ethics. There
essential for evaluating such a proposal entails the can, however, be rational discourse on what the good
study of regulatory measures designed to try to life is and some degree of consensus may be arrived at
control anti-competitive practices, including efforts in particular communities.
160 Darryl Reed et al.

There are a number of components, which may local and national as well as export markets.
be involved in conceptions of the good life (e.g., the Underlying the strategy of ED is the assumption that
importance of maintaining traditional lifestyles, cul- local communities can draw upon local physical and
ture and language, the meaning of work, the form of human resources to develop innovative production
one’s relationship with the natural world, etc.) Such strategies (‘‘repertoires’’) that are grounded in SE
complex conceptions of the good life may them- relations and that enable local communities to react
selves be categorized in different ways. In the con- to external challenges in the global economy. It is
text of FT, one such category that is particularly this model of development that seems to be most
relevant is the notion of normative conceptions of compatible with the aspirations of small producer
development. In this section, we will contrast organizations, especially in Latin American (Vander-
competing normative conceptions of development Hoff Boersma, 2009; Wilkinson and Mascarenhas,
to explore the nature of the ethical issues within two 2007a, b).
key realms of FT. In contrast to ED, the dominant market-based
models of development rely on corporate actors to
generate growth and employment. As a normative
The issues model, variants of the corporate-led growth per-
spective typically do not explicitly hold any strong
The ethics of production substantive values apart from an emphasis on the
While there are a number of ethical issues relating to freedom of economic activity. Among such models,
FT production, the overarching point of contention is two are most important for our purposes. On the
the existence of two distinct forms of production, one hand, there is a neo-liberal variant that seeks to
namely, by small producers and by large, privately minimize regulatory interference in markets, while
owned estates (Renard and Pérez-Grovas, 2007). on the other hand there is a socially regulated variant
This situation is of great importance from an ethical that seeks to introduce voluntary restraints on cor-
perspective, because these different forms of produc- porations (backed up by consumer pressure) to
tion can largely determine the prospects for pursuing ensure conformance to minimum labor and/or
different models of local development. For the sake of environmental standards (Mukherjee Reed and
simplicity, we can contrast two different normative Reed, 2009a).
models of local development that correspond to these It is the latter variant of the model, socially reg-
two different models of production in FT (Mukherjee ulated corporate-led growth, which is promoted
Reed and Reed, 2009a). through the use of estate production in FT. In this
As a normative model, endogenous development version, development is understood in terms of
(ED) advocates that local actors be viewed as the income levels (though there is still the requirement
primary protagonists in the development enterprise of a social premium, which workers control) and
and highlights the importance of their participation respect for basic labour rights. Empowerment means
in ownership and control over the local economy. increasing the ability of workers to use the industrial
These substantive values of control over the local relations process to negotiate a better contract
economy also have an important instrumental value (as well as initiating social development projects
in terms of allowing local communities to pursue though the social premium). Empowerment, how-
other, related substantive goals (e.g., preservation of ever, does not extend to participation in decision-
culture, language and traditional life forms, etc.). making regarding production, investment and
The basic features that define an ED model are SE marketing strategies, nor does it entail participating
enterprises that are linked together in a self-rein- in other decisions about the development of the
forcing network of relations and an openness to local economy (in ways that the small producer
collaboration with outside actors (Ray, 1999).11 As a model of production might) (Renard and Pérez-
local development strategy, ED encourages the Grovas, 2007; Shreck, 2005).
movement up the value chain into primary and The existence of two distinct production models
secondary processing, the diversification of produc- in FT, which benefit two different marginalized
tion into different sectors and the development of groups and which tend to promote two different
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 161

models of development, raises some basic questions some producer organizations to compromise the
of priorities. Specifically at issue are two related promotion of such relationships in order to grow
questions: Should FT favor one group (agricultural sales (and to better enable more producer organiza-
workers or small producers) over the other? Should tions to engage in ED). Some would argue that this
FT favor one development model (socially regulated strategy was embodied in the establishment of Max
corporate-led growth or endogenous development) Havelaar, the first FT labeling body. The nature of
over the other? The most obvious option between these compromises, including their relevance today,
the apparent dilemmas might be not to choose. This can be more clearly explained in terms of different
is in fact what FLO-I has done by allowing both variants of the FT value chains (Reed, 2009).
forms of production. The concern that small pro- Before certification, the practice of fair trade
ducers have, however, is that the decision not to (commonly referred to as alternative trade) was
choose may in fact be a choice, which results characterized by short value chains composed entirely
in estate production ultimately displacing small of SE enterprises. When Max Havelaar developed the
producers from FT. To the extent that estate pro- first certifying body for the coffee sector, traditional
duction has a lower cost structure, ceteris paribus, businesses, including large corporate actors, entered
traditional business licensees and retailers will tend to into the value chain. Three types of large traditional
prefer it over small producers. For this reason, many businesses would become involved in FT, namely,
small producers have been adamantly opposed to the large retail grocery chains, large agro-food processing
increasing expansion of estate production within FT companies and large agricultural estates (see
(Renard and Pérez-Grovas, 2007). Table V).12 While the original alternative trade value
chains (1) would continue to exist with the intro-
The ethics of exchange duction of FT certification, some alternative trade
There are two basic models of exchange that can organizations (ATOs) embraced the notion of
occur within FT markets. On the one hand, there is expanding distribution through such distribution
a liberal notion that evaluates exchange in terms of channels, in the process creating a new variant of the
procedural fairness as defined by the basic conditions FT value chain (2). With the entry of large agro-food
for ideal markets. Underlying such a liberal con- corporations in FT, another variant of the FT value
ception is a formal agnosticism about the good. chain would emerge (3) as corporate licensees
Exchange is a purely instrumental function, with no distributed their products through grocery retailers or
strong ethical significance. This is the dominant (as was the case with coffee retail chains) through their
understanding of exchange in traditional businesses, own distribution networks. Finally, the introduction
including those operating as FT licensees. In contrast of estate production would lead to another develop-
to this liberal notion, market exchanges can also be ment in the FT value chain (4).13
understood as having ethical import in their own In terms of our concern with the ethics of
right. This can occur in exchanges between SE exchange, what should be noted at this stage is that
enterprises, which have a social purpose for being in two quite distinct groups can be distinguished
business. When such firms share a common purpose, among these four variants of the FT value chain. On
market exchanges express relationships of solidarity the one hand, the first two variants continue to be
and serve as a method for achieving a common goal (predominantly) characterized by exchange relations
(not just a means for maximizing individual interests based on solidarity between SE actors (except for the
in a fair way). This is the understanding of exchange inclusion of traditional corporate retailers at the end
that commonly exists among SE licensees and small of the first chain). On the other hand, the latter two
producers (where the common goal is typically the variants are based on liberal exchange relations
promotion of a model of ED). between traditional business and small producer
The basic ethical question relating to exchange is organizations (3) or just liberal exchange relation-
whether FT should favor one or the other of these ships between traditional businesses (4). In the sec-
types of exchange. Historically, of course, alternative tion on policy proposals, the nature of the trade-offs
trade movements favored the latter model. Concerns involved in choosing between these different vari-
about the need to expand the market, however, led ants of the FT value chain will be further developed.
162 Darryl Reed et al.

TABLE V
Four variants of the fair trade value chain

Type of the value chain Level of corporate involvement Nature of exchange

(1) Wholly social economy None Solidarity-based relations


(2) Social economy dominated Retail Solidarity-based relations
(3) Corporate dominated Retail, licensing Socially regulated market relations
(4) Wholly corporate Retail, licensing, production Socially regulated market relations

The Canadian context other FT markets. First, there may be cost consid-
erations, which would make estate-produced FT
In examining the ethics of production and exchange products cheaper (Renard and Pérez-Grovas, 2007).
in Canada, there are two basic issues to touch upon. To the extent that corporate retailers are primarily
The first is the nature of the actual practices (namely, driven by profits, then they will choose the least cost
the extent of estate production vis-à-vis small pro- option. Second, even if corporate retailers do want
ducer production and the extent of the role of to support small producers (either because of con-
FT business licensees vis-à-vis traditional business sumer demand or out of some sense of social
licensees). The second is the understanding of and responsibility), they may find these organizations
support by key stakeholder groups for the underlying incapable of meeting their demands (Robinson,
ethical positions to which these different forms of 2009). Under such circumstances, it is not unrea-
production and exchange are linked. sonable to anticipate that small producers (and their
northern FT business partners) operating in these
Ethics of production sectors will be forced to subsist in alternative distri-
There have been no studies on the extent of the sales bution outlets (whole food stores, world shops, etc.),
of FT products in Canada produced under estate even if they are able to develop new, innovative
conditions. Of course, as in other countries, the ownership and capacity building strategies.14
majority of FT sales in Canada historically has not With regard to public awareness and support for
come from products grown under estate conditions different forms of production (and exchange) within
because key sectors (coffee, cocoa, cotton) have not FT, the available data are best described as limited
been certified for estate production. In those sectors and partial. This is especially true with respect to
that are so certified, however, there has been consumers. In Canada, very little empirical work has
tremendous sales growth in recent years, especially been done on consumers, while that which has been
in fruit (bananas) and tea (TFC, 2008). While there undertaken focuses narrowly on a general awareness
are small producers operating in these sectors, the of FT, the price elasticity of consumer demand and
capacity of their organizations is being dwarfed other related factors that might affect the willingness
by the increasing number of estates that are being to buy FT products, e.g., convenience, quality, etc.
certified. In the case of bananas, for example, while (Arnot et al., 2006; Hira and Ferrie, 2006). No effort
much of the original FT production came from small has been made to probe consumers’ understanding
producers in the Caribbean, in recent years there has of how FT operates and the existence of different
been a large shift to estate production from Latin practices within FT.
America (Frundt, 2009; Robinson, 2009). In development organizations, not surprisingly,
While we do not have data, the recent incorpo- there are much stronger indications of awareness of
ration of large grocery retailers into FT in Canada as the existence and implications of different modes of
licensees might lead one to assume that most of the production in FT. This understanding is rooted in a
production in sectors such as tea and bananas comes significant shift in their understanding of develop-
from estates. There would be two good reasons for ment dating back to the 1970s and 1980s. At that
such an assumption, based on what has happened in time, as the prospects for the modernization project
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 163

in the south were being called into question, l’économie sociale du Québec’’. In engaging in FT, these
development organizations began to see their man- organizations have done so with an eye to supporting
dates less in terms of philanthropy and more in terms locally controlled development models in the south
of social justice. Local people were increasingly (Favreau, 2003; Lemay, 2004; Mendell, 2002).16
perceived as collaborators rather than recipients of
aid (Hira and Parfitt, 2004; Navarro-Flores, 2009). The ethics of exchange
The 1990s saw a further shift in the understanding and In Canada, as in most other northern countries, the
practice of development organizations, induced lar- original FT licensees were SE enterprises committed
gely by processes of economic globalization and the to developing long-term trade relationships based on
reaction to these changes by local communities. In solidarity. Today, we can see that SE enterprises still
a climate of decreased government support and comprise a large percentage of FT licensees in
increased economic distress, local communities not Canada (see Table III). What is less clear, however,
only developed sharp critiques of national and inter- is the actual contribution of such licensees to total
national structures, but also turned increasingly to self- sales of FT goods and, therefore, the degree to
organization to promote their development aspira- which alternative trade relations actually characterize
tions. In this context, development organizations FT practice within Canada. One particularly signif-
increasingly came to see local communities in the icant feature of this question may be the degree to
south as partners in a shared agenda of global justice which the practice of FT varies within Canada itself.
(Favreau, 2008; Navarro-Flores, 2009). For many This question is potentially important because dif-
such organizations, the FT relationships between small ferent patterns of practice within Canada might map
producers and northern consumers and ATOs have onto other differences in the Canadian economy
come to symbolize this understanding of partnership. (most notably support for the SE more generally
Another key population in Canada among which from consumers, citizens, governments, etc.) and
the awareness of and support for FT has grown provide insights into the role of the larger SE in
significantly in recent years is the SE sector. SE actors, supporting FT and FT business licensees. One point
especially cooperative bodies, have long been actively of entry into examining this issue is to look at the
involved with local partners in the south in the regional distribution of different types of FT
promotion of local development (MacPherson, 2009). licensees (see Table II).
Among Canadian provinces, the role of Quebec The results of such a mapping are suggestive. The
has been particularly prominent in recent years, espe- one feature that stands out clearly is the difference in
cially with the development of international SE SE involvement in FT across regions. Most notable
networks such as RIPESS (Favreau, 2003).15 FT has in this regard is the fact that Quebec, the province
played an increasingly large role in these efforts in widely regarded to have the most dense SE network
recent years, with a variety of national and provincial and the strongest public support for SE enterprises,
level organizations becoming actively involved, includ- has the highest per capita level of FT businesses of
ing the Canadian Community Economic Devel- any province. While it might appear reasonable to
opment Network (CCED-Net) and the anglophone try to extrapolate from such a distribution of FT
and francophone co-operative associations, This business licensees to support for such licensees by
involvement not only includes support for their other actors (consumers, citizens, development
individual members that are FT businesses, but also NGOs, others SE actors) in their region, two points
extends to active participation in education and should be noted. First, we do not have the data to
advocacy activities. The Manitoba chapter of CCED- support such projections. As noted above, there is
Net, for example, has worked closely with Fair Trade very limited survey data on FT and the data that does
Manitoba in the development of a provincial pur- exist do not indicate preferences for particular types
chasing policy. They have also been active in devel- of FT licensees. Second, the number of SE firms may
oping provincial-wide campaigns to promote sales be a poor estimator of public support for FT
of FT goods. Similar activities and levels of involve- licensees (and FT more generally). The province
ment have been co-ordinated in Quebec by the of Manitoba, which has one of the strongest SE
provincial-wide SE organization, ‘‘Le Chantier de traditions in the country,17 would seem to be a case
164 Darryl Reed et al.

in point. While there is only one FT licensee, it is be significantly and rapidly increased to meet the
the only province with its own provincial FT demands of large retailers and avoid their defection
organization (which is closely tied to the regional to rival ethical certification schemes is an open
community economic development organization). question (Robinson, 2009). TFC would also be
Also, its legislature is currently considering a prov- impacted by such a policy change, as a drop-off in
ince-wide FT purchasing policy, another first in sales would imply decline in licensing fees (which
Canada. What this means is that the existing distri- could impact on its ability to offer services to
bution of FT licensees probably underestimates the licensees, engage in promotion, etc.).
level of popular support for FT in some regions, The second policy option would be (to advocate in
including the potential for marshaling support for FLO-I for) the adoption of a differentiated label,
new and existing FT businesses. which clearly identifies whether a product has been
produced by small producers or whether it has come
from an estate. This policy should represent an
improvement over the current situation for small
Policy proposals producers as it would better enable them to distin-
guish their products. The effectiveness of such a
The ethics of production policy, however, would depend on the ability of
TFC could pursue two basic policy options to deal consumers to recognize the difference between the
with the ethical concerns in this area. The first of variants of the FT labels, their having a preference to
these would be not to licensee firms that source from support small farmers and the existence of compet-
estates (and to advocate that FLO-I not certify estate itive markets that would respond to this demand.
production). This option, which effectively elimi- There are two closely related concerns about such a
nates the fourth variant of the FT value chain dis- policy. On the one hand, it could serve to merely
tinguished above, would have the practical effect of slow down the process of squeezing out small pro-
incorporating more small producers in FT and ducers from these sectors of FT trade. On the other
enabling them to pursue an ED strategy. The related hand, such a differentiated label could facilitate
benefits of such a strategy for TFC could include extending estate production into the remaining FT
solidifying its core mission (of supporting small sectors in which it is not currently permitted (coffee,
producers), bringing its mission more in line with its cotton, cocoa and honey). Such scenarios could
public image and increasing brand integrity and eventually eliminate any role for FT in promoting
consumer confidence. If adopted more widely alternative forms of development (Renard and
within the FT network, this strategy would greatly Pérez-Grovas, 2007).
alleviate tensions between small producer associa-
tions and the labeling organizations (Renard and
Pérez-Grovas, 2007). Ethics of exchange
Such a policy would likely also have costs. One In the case of exchange, two similar policy proposals
of the groups that could be adversely impacted could be introduced. The first would be to restrict
would be agricultural workers. The extent to licensing to FT business (and other SE) licensees, a
which they would be affected, however, is difficult proposal which would eliminate the third version of
to evaluate. It would depend largely on whether the FT value chain described above. Such a proposal
those estates that were formerly FT certified chose would help to ensure that FT trade is based on
to join a rival label (e.g., Rainforest Alliance, Utz relations of solidarity, a practice which in turn would
Certified, etc.) and the degree to which these rival help to ensure that small producers can pursue an ED
organizations differ in practice from FT estate strategy. Such effects would also bring the practice of
production. Such a policy would likely impact sales FT more in line with its public image (associated
of FT goods as well, especially in the short run, as with the empowerment of small producers) and
the infrastructure for incorporating small producers eliminate the practice of ‘‘fair washing’’ and any
in the sectors affected is underdeveloped. The ex- negative impacts that it has had on the FT brand
tent to which the capacity of small producers could (Renard, 2005).
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 165

Again, the implementation of such a policy would relating to current practices and models in Canada,
probably be accompanied by considerable costs. The the analysis of these practices and the investigation of
most significant would likely be a sizable drop in the potential resources for promoting SE alternatives
sales of FT goods, especially in the short term. The (to estate production and corporate licensees).
extent of the drop in sales and the prospects for
recovery in the medium to long term are not The ethics of production
immediately evident for a couple of reason. First, we Proposals to restrict the participation of estate pro-
do not know what the current contribution of such duction in FT highlight in the first instance the need
licensees to FT is (as such data is not readily to collect data. On the one hand, it is important to
obtainable). Second, it is not easy to estimate the establish the extent of the presence of estate-
extent to which losses in sales by corporate licensees produced goods in the FT market in Canada (and
might be made up by FT businesses. Third, there is elsewhere). On the other hand, it is necessary to
the prospect that additional measures could be taken generate data on how workers fare under estate
to promote FT, which could help to recoup some of production (both in FT and rival labeling bodies).
the lost sales. In terms of analysis, there are two key features that
The second policy proposal that could be devel- require investigation. In relation to estate produc-
oped to address the ethics of exchange is for a dif- tion, it is essential to develop causal explanations of
ferentiated label, which clearly distinguishes FT the growing presence of this mode of production in
businesses from traditional business licensees. Unlike FT (e.g., the interests of large agro-firms and
the previous proposal, this one compromises support national labeling bodies, the role of market struc-
for trade relations based on solidarity with an eye to tures, etc.) and how the practices of actors in estate-
growing sales (more rapidly). Under this proposal, based value chains impact the ability of small pro-
small producers not only can continue to maintain ducers to penetrate the Canadian market (e.g., the
their relationships with FT businesses licensees, but setting up of barriers to entry).18 With respect to
also consumers can more readily identify and small producers, it is necessary to investigate the
patronize such licensees, while the small producers various weaknesses than can arise in the value chains
can continue to enjoy the benefits of an expanded in which they operate (e.g., especially factors that
market which comes from the participation of cor- limit the ability to grow FT businesses that can
porate licensees. effectively meet the demand of large retailers for FT
The potential costs of such a proposal take the products commonly produced on estates, e.g., tea,
form of two significant risks. On the one hand, by bananas, etc.).
not eliminating corporate licensees, the prospect Finally, there is a need to analyze strategies em-
remains for them out-competing FT businesses and ployed elsewhere, e.g., in other countries (such as
eventually driving them out of the market. This the FT universities campaign in the UK) and other
would result in the end of alternative trade based on movements (e.g., ‘‘No Sweat Movement’’), and
the relationship of solidarity. In addition, there is the identify potential resources in Canada that can be
possibility that the continued presence of corporate deployed to improve the competitiveness of small
licensees in FT, through their lobbying for extend- producer-based value chains. This is an area where
ing the practice of estate production to all FT action research can be particularly important. On the
products, could eventually result in the elimination demand side, efforts to promote such value chains
of small producers themselves from FT trade could include SE and other civil society actors
(Renard and Pérez-Grovas, 2007). engaging in campaigns to pressure conventional
retailers (to offer small producer-based FT products)
and public institutions (to adopt FT procurement
The need for research policies, which support small producers), as well as
SE actors committing to source as many inputs and
There are three basic research tasks, which need to products as possible from small producers. On
be undertaken with respect to issues of ethics in the supply side, it could involve SE actors supply-
production and exchange. These are data collection ing more support (e.g., financial, organizational,
166 Darryl Reed et al.

TABLE VI
Researching ethical issues

Issue Canadian context Proposal Research agenda

Production • No distinction among producers • Only small producers • Development impact of estates
relations • Strong support for ED • Differentiated label FT versus rival estate production
models by SE actors/ FT estate versus small producers
development NGOs • Weak links in SE value chains
• Consumer support? • Northern SE actors’ untapped
potential
Generating demand
Support services for producers
N–S joint ownership schemes
• Consumer knowledge/support
Exchange • No distinction among licensees • Only SE licensees • Sales and distribution networks
relations • Significant no. of SE licensees • Differentiated label SE versus corporate licensees
• No dominant SE licensees • Northern SE actors’ untapped
• Strong SE sector in Canada potential
• Consumer support? Developing new SE licensees
Supporting existing licensees
• Consumer knowledge/support

technical) through their apex organizations (e.g., which FT businesses are being squeezed out or
Canadian Cooperative Association) and other marginalized with the entrance of corporate licens-
international SE networks (e.g., RIPESS). A par- ees. Moreover, when combined with case study
ticularly intriguing question is whether larger analysis (from within Canada and abroad) and more
cooperatives in Canada (perhaps with coordination sophisticated data on consumer demand, this data
through their apex bodies) could play a similar role should provide for causal accounts of these changing
that development NGOs have played in the Neth- patterns, including an analysis of the conditions
erlands and the UK in developing new multi- under which FT businesses can survive and grow
stakeholder ownership models (e.g., solidarity (and the likely costs of restricting or eliminating
cooperatives) to involve small producers in the south corporate licensees).
in ownership of FT retail and distribution networks The other key areas of research involve the
in Canada (Davies, 2009; Doherty and Tranchall, analysis of existing practices in other places to sup-
2007) (Table VI). port SE licensees and of the resources potentially
available in Canada for this purpose, especially
The ethics of exchange among socially economic actors (Becchetti and
Proposals to restrict licensing point to the need of Costantino, 2010). On the demand side, this can
better understanding the generation of sales in the involve more concerted efforts on the part of SE
FT market. The first task in the endeavor is gath- actors to support SE licensees (e.g., through educa-
ering more detailed data on sales. More specifically, tion campaigns, procurement policies), while on the
it is important to establish the breakdown of sales on supply side it might involved more systematic efforts
the basis of different types of licensees (namely, FT to supply financial and other resources to new and
businesses vis-à-vis corporate licensees), both across existing SE licensees (e.g., establishing capital funds),
sectors and geographic regions within the country. as well as large, successful SE enterprises (e.g., dairy
Such data should be able to provide the basis for a cooperatives, insurance cooperatives, credit unions,
mapping of the changing patterns of licensee etc.) becoming involved as licensees themselves
involvement, including analysis of the extent to (e.g., in stakeholder cooperatives). Again, action
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 167

research projects could be particularly important in bodies, several issues would seem to arise. The first,
this area. and most fundamental, is whether democracy is the
necessary basis for legitimacy. If it is conceded that
the legitimacy of NGOs needs to be founded on
democratic practice, then other questions follow as
Issues of legitimacy to what democracy means in NGOs. Of particular
concern in this regard are the problems of defining
Discourse can in principle provide us with norms for the constituencies of the decision-making bodies and
procedural justice based on consensus and, in more designing the decision-making institutions. Below,
limited cases, help us to articulate shared under- these three questions are examined in turn.
standings of the good life. As noted above, however,
conceptions of the good life are inherently linked to The basis of legitimacy
particular contexts in ways which make it unlikely In contemporary societies, democratic practice has
that we can have universal conceptions of the good become the ultimate basis of legitimacy for nation
life. Moreover, disagreements can arise as to how to states, as well as at other levels of government. While
apply shared values and procedural principles in the literature on democratic theory is quite diverse
particular circumstances, especially in a timely fash- in nature, there does tend to be a broad agreement
ion. In such instances, we cannot rely upon con- on some basic principles. These include the notions
sensus, but must have procedures which allow us to that governments derive their legitimacy from their
cut off discourse and engage in decision-making in a constituents (popular sovereignty) and that they do
fair manner. From a critical theory perspective, this so on the basis of establishing and ensuring basic
is what the institutions and practices of political rights to and procedures for participation, includ-
democracy enable. They allow us to channel societal ing the election of representatives (Cunningham,
discourses, in which all competent actors have the 2002).19
right to participate, through democratic institutions While democracy is nearly universally acclaimed
in ways that provide us with legitimate rules (law) as the only valid basis of legitimacy for governments,
we can act upon. What grounds the legitimacy of not everyone would agree that the legitimacy of
the rules is the fact that they have emerged from a NGOs, such as TFC, has to be grounded in dem-
process of discussion in which all actors have an ocratic practice. Some scholars argue that NGOs,
equal opportunity to participate and in which power especially those working with marginalized popula-
differentials (based on economic resources, status, tions, might base their legitimacy on a combination
military might, etc.) do not play a role. Only the of competency, the merits of their mandate and
better arguments win. The formal decision-making certain procedural norms (some of which may be
processes are primarily a way of channeling public key components of democratic practice, e.g., trans-
discourse, not the primary criteria for evaluating parency). There are two basic grounds for not hav-
democratic practice. ing democratic practice as the basis for legitimacy.
In the section, we investigate the question of the First, it could be argued that such NGOs are
legitimacy of decision-making processes and insti- essentially socio-economic, not political organiza-
tutions in FT. While, FLO-I, the umbrella decision- tions and, therefore, what is more important is the
making body within FT, is an obvious object of question of efficacy (i.e., how well they are able to
concern, our focus is primarily on the national fulfill their given mandate). Second, one might
FLOs, especially TFC, and the legitimacy of their contend that while democratic practice is a long-
decision-making processes. term goal, in the short to medium run it is not
practical when marginalized groups are involved
(as they are not able to effectively represent themselves).
The issues Thus, in the short to medium run at least, legitimacy
must be based on other criteria, e.g., the importance of
In taking up the question of the legitimacy of non- its goals, transparency, competence, efficacy, etc. (Atack
state bodies such as TFC and other FT labeling 1999; van den Berghe, 2006).
168 Darryl Reed et al.

The latter argument does not so much challenge series of institutional reforms, which have resulted in
the importance of democratic practice as argue that the current structure in which small producer
the conditions for its implementation are not always organizations are recognized along with the national
in place (and in their absence, people still need to act FLOs as members of FLO-I and have the right to
to support marginalized communities). The former elect 4 of the 14 members to the FLO-I board. They
argument more directly challenges the necessity of also have representation on key FLO-I committees,
democracy for NGO legitimacy. The problem with most notably the standards committee. The national
this argument is that it does not adequately distin- FLOs, however, still retain a plurality of the votes
guish between the different tasks NGOs engage in. and one of their representatives serves as the chair
For NGOs involved in relief services, for example, (features that small producers oppose) (Renard and
the notion of legitimacy may not apply in the same Pérez-Grovas, 2007).
way as it does for rule-making NGOs. Insofar as the Despite the ongoing debate as to whether reforms
former do not generate rules which they expect in FLO-I have gone far enough, there is no doubt
different parties to be able to accept, they may not that these reforms reflect an (implicit) acknowledg-
need to legitimate their own practice through ment of the part of FLO-I of the need to base its
democratic procedures. Their requirements for legitimacy on democratic practice. However, such a
legitimacy may only extend to living up to existing commitment to democratic practice, albeit implicit,
legitimate law (which typically requires standards for is not a defining feature of all of the national FLOs.
transparency, accountability, etc.). For NGOs that Here, there seem to be two different tendencies. On
seek to develop norms of action, however, the sit- the on hand, in some FLOs founding organizations
uation is arguably different. Insofar as they expect (typically national development NGOs) have the
parties to consent to their norms, then the validity of right to elect members to the board of the labeling
these norms need to be justified through democratic body. In this model, these member organizations
practice. function as the key constituencies of the FT network
This understanding of the need for rule- and the board is responsible to them (FF, 2010a).
making NGOs to have democratic legitimacy is While such FLOs might be criticized with respect to
not an abstract question for the organizations in the makeup of their membership, these structures
question. On the contrary, it is very much an reflect a certain degree of democratic practice. In
ongoing topic of debate, especially among civil contrast, other FLOs, TFUSA being the most
society initiated, non-state regulatory initiatives. notable example, do not have member organiza-
Indeed, many organizations, such as the Forest tions. In these cases, the board is a self-appointing
Stewardship Council, have not only acknowledged institution. The practice of the board choosing its
the need for democratic legitimacy, but have also own members means that it is not formally
established elaborate structures and practices accountable to any other actors. In such cases, the
(Dingwerth, 2008).20 organizations seeks to justify its structures and
In the case of FLO-I, there has been an implicit practice not on the basis of democratic practice, but
acknowledgment in recent years of an initial dem- rather on its efficacy in promoting FT (as measured,
ocratic deficit and significant governance reforms. for example, through sales, the number of licensees,
When FLO-I was initially constituted in 1997, the etc.) (Jaffee, 2010).
discussions leading up to its formation were domi-
nated by the national FLOs, who decided that only Key constituencies
they would be full voting members. Such an Non-governmental regulatory bodies differ from
apparent contradiction within the organization governmental bodies in that they have a much more
(which was committed to the empowerment of limited mandate. They are voluntary organizations
small producers, but which did provided the latter that are established for a particular purpose. If we
with opportunities to take part in decision-making) accept the notion that such bodies should seek their
was unacceptable to small producer organizations legitimacy through democratic practice, then there
who continued to press for representation. As a would seem to be two criteria which could combine
result of their pressure, FLO-I has undertaken a to establish the constituencies of the organization,
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 169

namely, the commitment to democratic practice and In terms of distinctions within these two types of
the mission of the organization. constituencies, there is a major controversy in FT
In relation to the mission of the organization, with regard to whether both small producers and
there would seem to be a basic distinction between agricultural workers should be seen as key constit-
two types of constituencies. On the one hand, there uencies (or as having the same status as constituen-
may be constituencies that the organization seeks to cies).21 At issue is whether small producers have
support as part of its mission. In the case of FT, the some priority due to their pioneering role in
two groups that are most commonly identified as developing the first FT labeling body and/or their
such constituencies are small producers and agri- status as the initial target group identified by FT
cultural workers. On the other hand, there may be a labeling bodies. On either basis, it could be argued
range of potential constituencies, which derive their that it was illegitimate for FLO-I to support the
status from their commitment to contributing to the recognition of agricultural workers (along with small
fulfillment of the organization’s mission. In the case producers) as key constituents in FT, without the
of FT, these include typically FT businesses, devel- consent of small producers themselves (Renard and
opment NGOs, environmental groups, student Pérez-Grovas, 2007; VanderHoff Boersma, 2009).
associations, social justice organizations, coopera- A final question regarding constituencies and
tives, community economic development organiza- democratic legitimacy is the extent and nature of the
tions, labour unions, etc. A strong case could be commitment that organizations should have to
made that traditional businesses should not be con- democratic practice to participate in the governance
sidered as constituencies, because their primary goal of FT. In the case of producer organizations (and
is making profits which can conflict with the pro- agricultural workers), they are required (as part of
motion of FT (and the demands of democratic the certification process) to have internal democratic
practice). structures. The same is not true, however, of insti-
With respect to legitimacy, a key question that tutional members of the FLOs. The question is
arises is whether there should be any distinction whether it is sufficient for institutional member to
made between the status and rights across or within participate in democratic practice within the gov-
these two types of constituencies. Insofar as the ernance of FT, without practicing it in their own
mission of FT entails empowering specific groups institutions.
(small producer and agricultural worker organiza-
tions), it would seem that these groups have the Governance structures
strongest claims to representation in the governance There are a wide variety of issues relating to the
structure of the FT bodies (unless for some reason it governance of NGOs, including the nature of the
can be shown that they are unable to take on the basic responsibilities of board members (strategy
tasks of self-representation). Historically, this has not formation, policy, oversight, etc.). The most signif-
been the practice. As noted above, southern pro- icant for our purposes, however, is the nature of
ducer organizations (though not workers associa- their governance structures. The key criteria, again,
tions) have recently been granted the right to elect for developing governance structures are the mission
their own representatives to the FLO-I board. The of the organization and need to root legitimacy
national FLOs, however, have not yet adopted a in democratic practice. On this basis, three key cri-
similar practice, with the notable exception of the teria can be posited for evaluating FT governance
Fairtrade Foundation (FF) in the UK. The FF structures.
recently decided to have three representatives of The first criterion is the provision that the key
producer organizations on their board, one each constituencies have the form of representation to
from Africa, Asia and Latin America and the which they are entitled. Of particular importance
Caribbean (FF, 2010b). Unlike in the case of FLO-I, here are those constituents that are the object of the
however, the producer organizations from these FT mission, namely, small producers (and possibly,
regions do not have the right to elect their own agricultural workers). At issue is not the right of such
representatives (T. Matthews, personal communi- groups to representation as much as the extent of
cation). their right to representation. Insofar as they are the
170 Darryl Reed et al.

object of the network’s mission (which includes necessarily guarantee such an outcome. For this rea-
promoting their empowerment) and arguably the son, other provisions may need to be put in place to
most at risk in the decisions being made, a strong allow for the effective functioning of the board (e.g.,
case could be put forward that they should have an ability of the board itself to appoint outside
some form of special status in the decision-making members with particular expertise and/or experi-
structures (e.g., a majority/plurality of votes, veto ence, as needed).
power on key issues), at least at the level of FLO-I.
Insofar as the mission of TFC also is oriented
toward supporting small producers, a prima facie The situation in Canada
argument would seem to exist that small producers
also have a right to representation on the TFC board The emergence of a Canadian labeling organization
(and to choose their own representatives). The occurred in a context in which several competing
implications of this argument with respect to rep- labeling initiatives in Europe, such as Max Havelaar,
resentation, however, are potentially complicated by TransFair International (TFI) and the FF, were in talks
their representation in FLO-I, especially at the to develop an international umbrella organization. It
practical level. Depending on the level of represen- was in this context that TFI began to look beyond
tation that they have within FLO-I (and the degree Europe in an effort to grow the FT market and assert
of centralization of decision-making), small pro- its influence. In early 1994, Martin Kunz, the TFI
ducers may not require extensive representation in Secretary-General wrote to the Managing Director of
national FLOs. Minority representation might be Bridgehead Trading enquiring if there might be
more appropriate, though a case might still be made interest in a fair trade certification label in Canada.23 In
for some form of veto over major policy issues at the October 1994, TFI, anxious to get a toe-hold in the
national level.22 North American market, accepted Fair TradeMark
A second criterion that democratic legitimacy Canada as its Canadian member (Thomson, 1995).
would seem to imply is that the governance struc- Fair TradeMark Canada was incorporated very
tures should allow all of the northern constituencies quickly using Industry Canada’s standard non-profit
a fair opportunity to participate in governance. As membership-based corporation bylaws. The small
we noted above, some FLOs do have governance group initially responsible for its launch gradually
structures, which allow for democratic representa- expanded its membership through informal efforts to
tion and accountability through the mechanism of involve Canadian churches, unions and NGOs as
institutional membership. The primary concern with board members and donors. Board members were
this system is the fact that in many instances the chosen on the basis of their willingness to volunteer
range of representation has been quite narrow, with skills and time, and at times as informal ‘‘represen-
most members being Christian-based development tatives’’ of sectors, e.g., churches.
NGOs (in the case of the FF, for example, founding
member organizations included Oxfam, Christian The basis of legitimacy
Aid and the Catholic Agency for Overseas Devel- The speed with which it was organized, and the
opment). To the extent that there are other sectors, perceived urgency of its task, initially discouraged
which have a strong interest in and commitment to TFC from developing the institutional membership,
FT, there would seem no compelling case to deny which might have provided it with a democratic
them the opportunity to participate in governance basis for its legitimacy. In the absence of such a basis
(as has occurred in the FF, which has developed a for legitimacy, TFC has employed several other
more diverse membership). strategies. The first of these has been to appeal to the
A final criterion that follows from the FT mission is nature of its mission as a promoter of FT. Second,
that the governance structures should ensure that TFC has sought to use its association with umbrella
the board will be composed of individuals with the bodies, first TFI and later FLO-I, to demonstrate
requisite skills (professional, technical, organizational, that it is part of a broader international network.
etc.) to effectively promote its goals. Democratic Third, these umbrella organizations have provided
elections may allow for such results, but do not TFC with claims to a certain professionalism. TFI, for
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 171

example, provided a fledgling TFC with a basic model licensees in its own promotional and educational
for running a labeling body (including offering basic materials. TFC has also nurtured close working
‘‘templates’’ for contracts, license agreements, etc.) relationships with various movement actors involved
(Thomson, 1995, 1999). In a similar vein, FLO-I has and has been supportive of the development of the
initiated developments that TFC has been able to newly formed CCFT. It remains unclear, however,
copy. Most significant among these, perhaps, has been how its relationship with this new organization will
TFC’s formation of a separate certification branch, develop and the status that it perceives the CCFT
which is moving toward becoming compatible with has.
the ISO 65 compliant systems of FLO-CERT.
The governance structure
Key constituencies As noted above, TFC did not develop institutional
In Canada, a wide range of actors have been membership in the same way that many European
involved in the promotion of FT and the develop- FLOs did. In this regard, its governance structures,
ment of a broader fair trade movement over the which include a self-appointing board, would for-
years, including FT business licensees and World mally seem to most closely resemble those of
Fair Trade Organization (WFTO) members, devel- TFUSA. In practice, however, there are arguably
opment NGOs, environmental groups, student some noticeable differences between the two orga-
associations, social justice organizations, cooperatives nizations. First, while it has not had institutional
and community economic development organiza- members, TFC has maintained a practice of having a
tions, among others. In 2008, representatives of diverse board. which is largely drawn from civil
these different sectors came together to form a society (but does not include any licensees)
national organization, the Canadian Coalition for (Thomson, 1999). Unlike TFUSA, TFC has not
Fair Trade (CCFT). This newly formed organization been accused of having lost contact with movement
is still not fully consolidated in that it is still trying to actors, nor of having a board dominated by corpo-
decide on an organizational structure, it has not rate interests (Jaffee, 2010; Raynolds and Murray,
issued a detailed mission statement and it does not 2007). One of most important contributing factors
have functioning caucuses or sub-committees. here has probably been the practice of hiring key
For its part, it is not entirely clear who TFC sees staff members who come out of the FT movement.
as its primary constituencies or, correspondingly, This seems to have contributed to a much greater
what the dominant aspects of its mission are. There willingness on the part of TFC to engage with
are some groups, however, which would appear to movement actors and to not view itself as the
get more of its attention than others. First, TFC dominant representative of fair trade in Canada. On
seems to maintain close relationships with small the other hand, TFC has not been particularly
producer organizations (especially in Latin America). innovative in developing its governance practices
It regularly sponsors tours of producer groups and and structures, nor has it followed some of the more
highlights them in its promotional materials. In progressive practices of other FLOs (e.g., the FF’s
contrast, agricultural workers seem to be much less initiative of appointing directors from producer
prominent in the education and outreach materials organizations).
of TFC. In a similar vein, TFC maintains close
relationships with the small FT business licensees
(most of whom sell FT products exclusively), while Policy proposals
being more distant from its traditional business
licensees. This may be in large part due to the fact The basis of legitimacy
that the latter do not show much interest in the The most obvious way in which TFC could address
promotion of FT. It is only the former who attend any perceived legitimacy deficits would be to
licensee meetings and are willing to participate in introduce more democratic governance practices.
promotional and educational events (B. Barrett, The most significant step in this regard would be a
personal communication). It may not be totally requirement that the board of directors be elected by
surprising then that TFC tends to highlight these key constituencies within the FT network and the
172 Darryl Reed et al.

broader fair trade movement. As noted above, such a inclusion of agricultural workers into FT (and its
practice already exists to some degree in some of the justification of plantation production) is not a benign
other FLOs. In addition to providing greater legiti- event. It fundamentally changes the practice of FT in
macy, such reforms could have several other positive ways which seriously threaten the interests of small
impacts. First, they could generate greater public producers. Not including agricultural workers as
(and consumer) confidence in TFC (especially vis-à- primary stakeholders in FT, of course, could have
vis rival labeling organizations). Second, they could negative consequences, as noted above (e.g.,
promote greater accountability with the organiza- diminished life prospects for workers, a drop in FT
tion. Specifically, they could help to address any sales, negative publicity, etc.).
‘‘agency problems’’ that exist. Third, they could A second proposal to improve the legitimacy of
induce member organizations to deepen their TFC could be that key domestic constituencies
commitment to FT, including their commitment to should be broadly defined on the basis of a dem-
providing human and material resources. Fourth, it onstrated commitment to the mission of FT and to
could have important benefits for channeling more democratic practice in the governance of FT. The
information, especially from the grassroots into key rationale for defining domestic constituencies on
decision-making structures. this basis is that it is consistent with democratic
There are, on the other hand, potential trade-offs principles.25 More practically, however, it might also
that could occur with the requirement of an elected serve as an effective means of bringing in more
board. Perhaps, primary among these is the prospect resources into the labeling body and increasing the
that an electoral process might result in a board, tangible commitments of different constituencies to
which does not have an appropriate mix of the the cause of FT. Broadening representation, how-
requisite experience and professional and/or tech- ever, could have some negative effects in the form of
nical skills. In such a scenario, the board may prove fractionalization within the movement (which could
ineffective in fulfilling some of its key responsibilities result in less confidence in the label).
(e.g., determining strategic directions, developing
effective policies to implement strategy, etc.). Such a The governance structure
lack of effectiveness could serve to undermine Several key proposals could be developed to bring
confidence in the labeling body and decrease par- TFC governance structures in line with normative
ticipation by licensees as well as sales by consumers. concerns regarding legitimacy. The first of these
would be the development of a board structure,
Constituencies which provides appropriate representation to the key
A second important step that could enhance the constituency of FT, small producers. This need not
legitimacy of TFC is to clearly define its key con- involve a dominant position (i.e., a majority or
stituents, all of whom should have opportunities for plurality of votes), but should allow for an effective
participating in governance. One proposal to this end veto on key issues. Some of the practical side effects
would be to define small producers as the primary of increasing the legitimacy of the label in this way
constituents toward which FT is oriented. So could include increased consumer confidence and a
acknowledging small producers and their rights to greater willingness on the part of SE and other civil
participate in governance is in line with democratic society organizations to collaborate in FT. Producer
practice and reduces the possibilities that any vestiges representation could also potentially increase TFC’s
of paternalistic relationships will endure. The pro- access to on the ground information. There would
posal that only small producers should be considered seem to be relatively few potential negative impacts
a key constituent, and not agricultural workers, is of incorporating producer representatives into the
based on two closely related issues.24 The first is the TFC board, apart from the expenses involved in
fact that it was small producers who were involved their participation (travel, translation, interpretation,
in initiating the first FT label (to promote their etc.).
products) and the decision to expand the label to A second proposal would be to develop a system
plantation production was done so without their that enables all domestic constituencies to have the
consent. The second issue is the fact that the possibility to participate in governance (through the
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 173

ability to nominate board members and to vote on insofar as it can determine the extent to which
nominees) and ensures widespread representation on opposition to more democratic practice is well
the board of different constituencies. The advantage grounded in empirical studies (e.g., demonstrating
of such a system is, in the first instance, its com- inefficiencies in democratic structures) or whether it
patibility with democratic values. Such a system, as reflects particular ideological positions and/or vested
noted above, might also further serve to encourage interests (Table VII).
greater commitment from constituencies (in terms of
time, resources, etc.) and spur more constituencies Constituencies
to become involved. Some possible negative out- Two types of constituencies were identified above as
comes of more representative structures could potentially having a role in the governance of FT.
include a decrease in the professional and technical The first of these were southern actors, who are
competencies of board members, less well-con- understood to be the beneficiaries of FT. It was
nected board members, more cumbersome decision- proposed on the basis of particular normative argu-
making processes, etc.26 ments that only small producers (and not agricultural
workers) should be included in this category. To
determine whether such a proposal should be
The need for research adopted, it is necessary to confirm that the small
producers themselves agree with this stand (and to
The basis of legitimacy what extent). While some producer organizations
The question of the proper basis of legitimacy for would seem to hold this position (e.g., in Latin
TFC cannot be determined solely on the basis of the America), it is not clear that there is the same support
opinions of the affected actors, but rather involves a in other regions (Renard and Pérez-Grovas, 2007;
much larger discourse about democratic practice in Wilkinson and Mascarenhas, 2007a). Any such
an age of globalization. Yet, it is important to know differences in the levels of support not only need to
whether actors conceive of democracy as a necessary be determined but also accounted for, as the causes
basis for legitimacy. If none of the key actors see the of these differences (e.g., the more diverse nature of
need for democracy as the basis for legitimacy, then the Asian producer organizations, their more recent
any proposal for governance reforms is unlikely to origins) may impact on our evaluation of their
go forward. A more likely scenario, however, is that normative weight.27
there are divergent opinions on this point. It is With regard to potential northern constituencies,
necessary to know how support for democratizing it would be important to investigate the opinions of
governance is distributed (especially any differences different stakeholders. The reason for this is pri-
between southern and northern actors) and what marily pragmatic in nature, in that while there is no
factors condition such support (in principle and in a priori reason to exclude groups who meet the
practice). criteria elaborated above, it is important to under-
A variety of methods might be used to generate stand why some stakeholders may want to limit
such knowledge (e.g., case studies of TFC and other participation in governance.
FLOs, opinion surveys, focus groups, in-depth
interviews). An important concern in investigating Governance structure
this issue is being able to track the change over time It has been proposed above that small producers
of opinions on this subject (i.e., whether learning should have the right of representation on the board
occurs with experience). Such studies might indicate of TFC and even some form of special status. In
the degree to which ideological perspectives, loca- deciding whether to adopt and implement such a
tion, the length of involvement in (and degree of proposal, one key area of investigation relates to
knowledge of) the network, particular experiences whether small producers actually see such partici-
in the network and other factors influence support pation as desirable and what factors condition their
for democratic practice in governance. Such views on this matter (e.g., their prospects for effec-
knowledge can have a significant impact on debates tively inserting their concerns into policy, oppor-
about the need for governance reforms, especially tunity costs of expending their limited resources in
174 Darryl Reed et al.

TABLE VII
Researching issues of legitimacy

Issue Canadian context Proposal Research agenda

Basis of legitimacy • Mission • Democracy • Studies of stakeholder


• Professionalism opinions
• Network links • Analysis of the dynamics
• Efficacy of stakeholder opinion
formation
Constituencies • No preference for small • Small producers • Studies of stakeholder
producers over agricul- • Range of domestic groups opinions
tural workers • Analysis of the dynamics
• No formal domestic of stakeholder opinion
constituencies formation
Structures • Self-appointing board • Election by constituencies • Studies of other FLOs
• Role for small producers • Studies of producer
organizations
• Studies of other
organizations

this way, etc.). A closely related area that needs decisions of FLOs (and other related bodies) to
examination is the experience that small producers restrict participation in governance are based on
have already had in the governance of other FT genuine (and substantiated) concerns about efficacy
labeling bodies (namely, FLO-I, FF), especially the or whether they reflect other factors (e.g., inertia,
identification of the features of these institutions that ideology, agency issues, etc.).
have facilitated/inhibited effective participation
(e.g., representation structures, power differentials
between actors, etc.). Another topic of investigation Conclusion
should be the examination of other decision-making
models, especially ones in which marginalized FT is a complex and highly contested socio-eco-
groups have participated in the design (including the nomic practice. From the perspective of applied
producers’ own organizations). ethics, there are two tasks involved in the analysis of
With respect to representation by domestic actors, FT; the evaluation of current practices and the
it was proposed that all groups with a demonstrated promotion of measures that will bring current
commitment to FT and democratic practice should practice more in line with justified norms and the
have the opportunity to participate in the gover- achievement of desired goals. Both of these tasks
nance of FT. The only potentially cogent argument require the generation of two types of knowledge.
against such a proposal would seem to be that par- On the one hand, there is normative knowledge in
ticipation by such a broad spectrum of actors could the form of the nature of the key normative issues
adversely affect the mission of the FT network. A involved in the practice of FT. A key feature of such
first research task then would be to identify the normative analysis is the identification of the ten-
manner in which such a model of participation could sions involved in trying to address distinct types of
have any adverse impact on performance. A second normative issues, which involve multiple norms and
task would be to examine whether there is actual goals. In this paper, we have laid out part of the
evidence of such impacts on performance within range of such normative issues (i.e., those that more
FLOs and other related organizations that do directly concern the practice of FT in northern
encourage widespread participation in governance. countries). Establishing the nature of the normative
A final task would be to examine whether the issues involved in FT is an essential task, both in
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 175

undertaking the normative analysis of current prac- Notes


tices and the promotion of measures to promote more
1
normatively acceptable practices. On this basis, par- There are two commonly recognized fair trade
ticular criteria can be proposed in a more systematic net- works. One is centered around a labeling body,
way for the evaluation of current practices and for the Fair Labelling Organizations International (FLO-I),
guiding policy proposals. In this paper, we have not which was established by national fair labeling organi-
zations (FLOs). FLO-I certifies agricultural products.
systematically engaged in the evaluation of current
The other, the World Fair Trade Organization
practice, but we have put forth specific policy pro-
(WFTO), is a member-based organization composed
posals (based on specific normative criteria) to show of small producer organizations committed to fair
how the explicit formulation of normative criteria is trade. Its members have historically focused on handi-
necessary for the generation of social science analysis crafts, but more are now moving into agricultural
necessary for more effective policy. products as well. In addition, there are rival, business-
This leads to the second type of knowledge that is friendly and business-initiated rival labeling bodies. In
necessary from an applied ethics perspective, social this article, we are primarily concerned with the
science analysis. For the evaluation of current FT FLO-I network.
2
practice and the development of effective policies to There is much debate about the definition of SE
guide future practice, we need to know how FT enterprises. While a social purpose is an agreed upon
actually functions, what the available resources are criterion, there is significant debate over whether the
definition should include: (1) offering of products or
for improving current practice, and what obstacles
services in the market, and (2) democratic control of
exist that are likely to inhibit the desired changes.
the enterprise (Defourny and Develtere, 1999). We are
Asking these questions is logically posterior to the using an intermediate definition here, which assumes SE
normative questions addressed above. Evaluating enterprises have a social purpose and offer goods and/or
current practices and the development of strategies services in the market, but does assume that they are
and tactics to promote FT should be predicated democratically controlled.
3
upon a sophisticated understanding of the issues One particularly important issue is that of gender
involved in FT and the elaboration of well-defined equality, which arises at different levels within FT, from
norms and goals. A complicating factor, as noted the family all the way up to participation in apex pro-
above, is that in FT there can be multiple norms and ducer organizations (McMurtry, 2009).
4
goals, which compete with each other. While the We focus on the role of licensees, because historically
elaboration of priority rules can potentially resolve they have been the actors who have been most capable
of influencing relationships in the value chain. As Smith
most of the tensions involved in making evaluations
(2010) point outs, however, larger grocery retail chains
of current practice, the evaluation of policy pro-
in the UK have increasingly been able to dominate FT
posals is complicated by the fact that contingent value chains without being licensees.
factors (e.g., the profile of specific markets, the 5
The disparity can be seen by comparing the 2006
availability of key resources, etc.) can affect the sales of Équita (1.8 m e) with those of European social
optimal balance of different values and goals that are enterprises such as Agrofair (62.1 m e) in the Nether-
likely to be achieved (over different possible time lands, CaféDirect (32.8 m e) in the UK, Oxfam
frames) by different strategies. From the perspective Belgium (18.8 m e), Ethiquable (17.8 m e) in France,
of applied ethics, it is the understanding of these etc. (Krier, 2008).
6
factors (and how they vary over time and space) that We have primarily relied on information from Web
should drive the social science research agenda of sites in making this categorization, but have also con-
FT. In this paper, using the example of Canada, we sulted with FT practitioners familiar with particular
licensees.
have tried to illustrate the development of one such 7
Unlike Raynolds (2009), we speak of SR SMEs
research agenda and how it should best provide
(rather than ‘‘mission-driven SMEs’’), because some
decision makers the information that they need to ‘‘mission-driven’’ SMEs (i.e., artisanal vintners and cof-
evaluate which policies will mostly likely provide fee roasters) are primarily interested in quality and sell
results compatible with the most desirable balance of FT products for this reason rather than out of any
competing norms and goals. strong social or environmental commitments.
176 Darryl Reed et al.
8
While the largest sector of traditional business licens- most notably through the Canadian Student Fair Trade
ees comprises SMEs, we will largely focus on corporate Network and Engineers Without Borders.
17
licensees in our analysis. This is because of their potential See, for example the recent survey by Communica-
to influence the governance on FT value chains. tion Services Manitoba (2009) on cooperatives.
9 18
Starbucks in particular has come under sharp critique In addition, it is necessary to collect data on the
for its misuses of the FT label and its efforts to under- understanding of producer organizations with regard to
mine unionization (Fridell 2009; Renard 2005). their development aspirations and support for different
10
In many sectors, there is a lot of historical evidence development models.
19
of such practices, which have led to the current oligop- The focus of democratic theory on the nation state
olistic market structures. See, for example, Striffler and has come under increasing attack in recent years. Dem-
Moberg (2003) and Fridell (2007). ocratic theorists have been challenged to expand their
11
The ED model is closely associated in literature with the purview with the rise of globalization and increased
experience of northern Italy (the ‘‘Emilian model’’) and contestation of the legitimacy of multilateral bodies and
similar European contexts in which industrialization is a agreements, as the burgeoning literature on transnational
key component of the model (Amin, 1999). The practice, democracy attests (McGrew, 2004). It is not only multi-
however, is much wider than the European experience. lateral bodies that have become the object of scrutiny.
12
FT practice is more complex than this model sug- As transnational NGOs have sought to advocate for
gests, especially with the more aggressive role that large marginalized groups, the question of their status has also
grocery retailers have adopted in controlling value been challenged (Hudson, 2001). In this regard, the sit-
chains and the addition of new products with longer uation of FLO-I is not unusual.
20
value chains (e.g., cotton). These complexities do not One of the critiques of many such ‘‘stakeholder’’ mod-
alter the basic point about the existence of different els (especially from a critical theory perspective) is that
types of exchange (and production) relationships within when they incorporate corporate actors as participants,
FT, which result in products of different ethical value. they fail to neutralize power relations in governance and,
13
Initially, SE actors introduced estate production very therefore, cannot ensure the conditions for fair and open
selectively to supplement supplies in the face of a lack discourse (Mukherjee Reed and Reed, 2009b).
21
of small producers in some sectors (Murray and Ray- A similar question could be asked in terms of domes-
nolds, 2000). It is with the influx of corporate licensees tic constituencies as to whether some organizations
(and their support for it), however, that estate produc- should have a different status than others. While it is a
tion has really expanded and created a fourth variant of more difficult case to make, it could be argued that
the FT value chain (Frundt, 2009). founding members of FLOs should have some special
14
The case of the large Canadian grocery retailer Lob- rights (e.g., when it comes to changing the mission of
laws is instructive. When Loblaws originally decide to organizations that they have helped to found). In the
source FT bananas, they contacted the FT business Oké case of Canada, this would be a moot point, insofar as
USA (a joint venture of three SE enterprises, Equal there were no founding institutional members.
22
Exchange, the Red Tomato and southern producers). In the case of the FF, while they do not have formal
While Oké was keen to work with Loblaws, the prob- veto power, the three small producer representatives
lem was that they were not a large enough organization feel that they can exercise effective veto power when
to meet the demands of a national supermarket. By way they act in concert (T. Matthews, personal communica-
of compromise, Loblaws decided that it would source tion).
23
from Oké for its stores in the eastern part of the coun- After a meeting in May, between Kunz and several
try and would use a traditional firm to source for its actors associated with Bridgehead, a decision was taken to
store in the west. Eventually, Loblaws found that this incorporate Fair TradeMark Canada (later to be renamed
compromise was not working and switched all their TFC). Its board included Bill Singleton, a former Bridge-
sourcing to the larger traditional firm (J. Rosenthal, head general manager, Pina Gianneschi, the manager of
personal communication). the Toronto Bridgehead store and Bob Thomson, a for-
15
Réseau Intercontinental de Promotion de l’Econo- mer Bridgehead board member who served as the organi-
mie Sociale et Solidaire (RIPESS) is the French (and zation’s executive director.
24
Spanish) acronym for the International Network for the These same arguments would hold for efforts to
Promotion of the Social Solidarity Economy (www. include northern producers in FT through the develop-
ripesslac.net). ment of domestic FT programs.
16 25
In addition to these groups, students play an espe- There is also the question raised above of whether
cially important role in the promotion of FT in Canada, this commitment to democracy need only to apply to
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 177

the governance of FT bodies or should also extend to Economics as Ideology and Experience: Essays in Honour of
the internal structures of the organizations in question. Ashok Mitra (Frank Cass Publishers, London), pp. 96–124.
If the latter is the case, then many organizations (e.g., Becchetti, L. and M. Costantino: 2010, ‘Fair Trade in
some Christian-based development NGOs) might not Italy: Too Much ‘‘Movement’’ in the Shop?’, Journal of
meet this criterion. Business Ethics, doi:10.1007/s10551-010-0578-y.
26
One way to address concerns about the board having Communication Services Manitoba: 2009, ‘Cooperatives:
access to the necessary technical, professional and orga- A Survey of Manitobans’, http://www.manitoba.
nizational skills that it needs to effectively fulfill its man- coop/uploads/File/Manitoba%20Public%20Survey%
date would be to include provisions for the board to 20About%20Co-operatives.pdf.
elect a limited number of independent directors (to fill Cunningham, F.: 2002, Theories of Democracy: A Critical
in gaps that it feels might be missing). Introduction (Routledge, NY).
27
Even if it could be argued that southern producer Davies, I.: 2009, ‘Alliances and Networks: Creating
organizations alone should have the right to determine Success in the UK Fair Trade Market’, Journal of
whether there should be estate production, it would Business Ethics 86(Supplement 1), 109–126.
also be important to establish the level (and nature) of Defourny, J. and P. Develtere: 1999, ‘The Social Econ-
support for such a proposal among northern constituen- omy: The World-Wide Making of the Third Sector’, in
cies. The reason for this is that southern producers may J. Defourny, P. Develtere and B. Fonteneau (eds.),
not want to follow through on exerting such a right for L’économie sociale au Nord et au Sud (De Boeck, Brussels).
pragmatic reasons (e.g., if they feel that there is not sig- Dingwerth, K.: 2008, ‘North–South Parity in Global
nificant support for it among northern constituencies Governance: The Affirmative Procedures of the Forest
and pursuing it might jeopardize their relationships with Stewradship Council’, Global Governance 14, 53–71.
these constituencies). Doherty, B. and S. Tranchall: 2007, ‘‘Radical Mainstreaming’
of Fair Trade: The Case of the Day Chocolate Company’,
Equal Opportunities International 26(7), 693–711.
Favreau, L.: 2003, Commerce equitable, économie
Acknowledgments sociale et mondialisation. Cahiers de la CRDC, Série
Conférence no. 9, 19 pp.
Darryl Reed would like to acknowledge support from Favreau, L.: 2008, Coopération nord-sud et développement. Le
the Social Science and Humanities Research Council of défi de la réciprocité (Presses de l’Université du Québec
Canada (Social Economy Suite competition), which and Karthala, St. Foy, Québec and Paris).
made the writing of this paper possible. FF.: 2010a, ‘Who we are’, http://www.fairtrade.org.uk/
what_is_fairtrade/fairtrade_foundation.aspx. Accessed
28 Jan 2010.
FF: 2010b, ‘Fairtrade Foundation Board Members’,
References http://www.fairtrade.org.uk/what_is_fairtrade/fairtrade_
foundation.aspx. Accessed 28 Jan 2010.
Amin, A.: 1999, ‘The Emilian Model: Institutional Fridell, G.: 2007, Fair Trade: The Prospects and Pitfalls of
Challenges’, European Planning Studies 7(4), 389–405. Market-Driven Social Justice (University of Toronto
Arnot, C., P. Boxall and S. B. Cash: 2006, ‘Do Ethical Press, Toronto).
Consumers Care About Price? A Revealed Preference Fridell, G.: 2009, ‘The Co-Operative and the Corpora-
Analysis of Fair Trade Coffee Purchases’, Canadian tion: Competing Visions of the Future of Fair Trade’,
Journal of Agricultural Economics 54, 555–565. Journal of Business Ethics 86(Supplement 1), 81–95.
Ascoly, N. and I. Seldenrust: 2003, Considering Complaint Frundt, H.: 2009, Fair Bananas: Farmers, Workers and
Mechanisms: An Important Tool for Code Monitoring and Consumers Strive to Change an Industry (University of
Verification (SOMO, Amsterdam). Arizona Press, Tuscon, AZ).
Atack, I.: 1999, ‘Four Criteria of Development NGO Habermas, J.: 1990, Moral Consciousness and Communicative
Legitimacy’, World Development 27(5), 855–864. Action (Polity Press, Cambridge).
Bacon, C.: 2010, ‘Who Decides What is Fair in Fair Habermas, J.: 1996, Between Facts and Norms: Contributions
Trade? The Agri-Environmental Governance of to a Discourse Theory of Law and Democracy, trans.
Standards, Access, and Price’, Journal of Peasant Studies William Rehg (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA).
37(1), 111–147. Hira, A. and J. Ferrie: 2006, ‘Fair Trade: Three Key
Bagchi, A.: 1998, ‘Local and Global Monopolies and the Challenges for Reaching the Mainstream’, Journal of
Prospects for Global Democracy’, in D. Nayyar (ed.), Business Ethics 63, 107–118.
178 Darryl Reed et al.

Hira, A. and T. Parfitt: 2004, Development Projects for a Navarro-Flores, O.: 2009, Le partenariat en coopération inter-
New Millenium (Praeger, Westport). national: Paradoxe ou compromis? (Presses de l’Université
Hudson, A.: 2001, ‘NGOs’ Transnational Advocacy du Québec and Karthala, St. Foy, Québec and Paris).
Networks: From ‘Legitimacy’ to ‘Political Responsi- O’Rourke, D.: 2006, ‘Multi-Stakeholder Regulation:
bility’?’, Global Networks 1(4), 331–352. Privatizing or Socializing Global Labor Standards?’,
Huybrechts, B. and J. Defourny: 2008, ‘Are Fair Trade World Development 34(5), 899–918.
Organizations necessarily Social Enterprises’, Social Ray, C.: 1999, ‘Towards a Meta-Framework of Endog-
Enterprise Journal 4(3), 186–201. enous Development: Repertoires, Paths, Democracy
Jaffee, D.: 2007, Brewing Justice; Fair Trade Coffee, Sus- and Rights’, Sociologia Ruralis 39(4), 521–537.
tainability, and Survival (University of California Press, Raynolds, L. T.: 2009, ‘Mainstreaming Fair Trade Cof-
Berkley). fee: From Partnership to Traceability’, World Devel-
Jaffee, D.: 2010, ‘Fair Trade Standards, Corporate Par- opment 37(6), 1083–1093.
ticipation, and Social Movement Responses in the Raynolds, L. T. and D. L. Murray: 2007, ‘Fair Trade:
United States’, Journal of Business Ethics, doi:10.1007/ Contemporary Challenges and Future Prospect’, in L.
s10551-010-0583-10. T. Raynolds, D. Murray and J. Wilkinson (eds.), Fair
Krier, J. M.: 2008, Fair Trade 2007: New Facts and Figures Trade: The Challenges of Transforming Globalization
from an Ongoing Success Story (Dutch Association of (Routledge, London and New York), pp. 223–
World Shops, Culemborg). 234.
Lemay, J.-F.: 2004, ‘Les avancée du commerce equitable Reed, D.: 1999, ‘Three Realms of Corporate Responsi-
au Québec’, in L. Favreau, G. Larose and A. Salam Fall bility: Distinguishing Legitimacy, Morality and Ethics’,
(eds.), Altermondialisation, économie et coopération inter- Journal of Business Ethics 21(3), 23–35.
nationale (Presses de l’Université du Québec and Reed, D.: 2009, ‘What do Corporations have to do with
Karthala, St. Foy, Québec and Paris), pp. 65–75. Fair Trade: Positive and Normative Analysis from a
MacPherson, I.: 2009, A Century of Co-Operation Value Chain Perspective’, Journal of Business Ethics
(Canadian Co-operative Association, Ottawa). 86(Supplement 1), 3–26.
McGrew, T.: 2004, ‘Transnational Democracy: Theory Renard, M.-C.: 2005, ‘Quality Certification, Regulation
and Prospects’, Key-Note Paper Presented at the and Power in Fair Trade’, Journal of Rural Studies 21,
International Workshop ‘Democracy and Globaliza- 419–431.
tion’, Gl. Vrå Castle, Denmark, 4–5 May (Center Renard, M.-C.: 2010, ‘In the Name of Conservation:
for Globalisation, Europeanisation and Democracy, CAFE Practices and Fair Trade in Mexico’, Journal of
Aalborg University). Business Ethics, doi:10.1007/s10551-010-0584-0.
McMurtry, J. J.: 2009, ‘Ethical Value-Added: Fair Trade Renard, M.-C. and V. Pérez-Grovas: 2007, ‘Fair Trade
and the Case of Café Femenino’, Journal of Business Coffee in Mexico: At the Center of the Debates’, in
Ethics 86(Supplement 1), 27–49. L. T. Raynolds, D. Murray and J. Wilkinson (eds.),
Mendell, M.: 2002, ‘The Social Economy in Quebec: Fair Trade: The Challenges of Transforming Globalization
Discourses and Strategy’, in A. B. Bakan and (Routledge, London and New York), pp. 138–156.
E. Macdonald (eds.), Critical Political Studies: Debates Robinson, P. K.: 2009, ‘Responsible Retailing: Regu-
and Dialogues from the Left (McGill-Queen’s Uni- lating Fair and Ethical Trade’, Journal of International
versity Press, Montreal). Development 21, 1015–1026.
Moore, G.: 2004, ‘The Fair Trade Movement: Parame- Sampson, S.: 2009, ‘Dark, Rich and Good for Farmers
ters, Issues and Future Research’, Journal of Business Dairy Milk Bar Earns Fair Trade Certification’, The
Ethics 53, 73–86. Toronto Star, http://www.thestar.com/article/686349.
Mukherjee Reed, A. and D. Reed: 2009a, ‘Fair Trade Accessed 28 Jan 2010.
and Development: What are the Implications of Shreck, A.: 2005, ‘Resistance, Redistribution and Power
Mainstreaming’, Universitas Forum 1(2), 1–8. in the Fair Trade Banana Initiative’, Agriculture and
Mukherjee Reed, A. and D. Reed: 2009b, ‘Partnerships Human Values 22, 17–29.
for Development: Four Models of Business Involve- Smith, S.: 2010, ‘For Love or Money? Fairtrade Business
ment’, Journal of Business Ethics 90(1), 3–37. Models in the UK Supermarket Sector’, Journal of
Murray, D. and L. Raynolds: 2000, ‘Alternative Trade in Business Ethics, doi:101007/s10551-010-0582-2.
Bananas: Obstacles and Opportunities for Progressive Striffler, S. and M. Moberg (eds.): 2003, Banana Wars:
Social Change in the Global Economy’, Agriculture and Power, Production, and History in the Americas (Duke
Human Values 17, 65–74. University Press, Durham, NC).
Developing a Fair Trade Research Agenda 179

Tallontire, A.: 2009, ‘Top Heavy? Governance Issues Wilkinson, J. and G. Mascarenhas: 2007a, ‘Southern Social
and Policy Decisions for the Fair Trade Movement’, Movements and Fair Trade’, in L. T. Raynolds,
Journal of International Development 21, 1004–1014. D. Murray and J. Wilkinson (eds.), Fair Trade: The
Thomson, B.: 1995, ‘A History of Fair Trade Labels’, Challenges of Transforming Globalization (Routledge,
unpublished paper, http://ca.geocities.com/bthomson London and New York), pp. 125–137.
100/label_history.html. Wilkinson, J. and G. Mascarenhas: 2007b, ‘The Making
Thomson, B.: 1999, ‘Lessons for Fair Trade’, Small of the Fair Trade Movement in the South: The
Enterprise Development 10(4), 56–60. Brazilian Case’, in L. T. Raynolds, D. Murray and J.
TransFair Canada: 2005, 2004-2005 Annual Report Wilkinson (eds.), Fair Trade: The Challenges of Trans-
(TransFair Canada, Ottawa). forming Globalization (Routledge, London and New
TransFair Canada: 2008, TransFair Canada – Annual York), pp. 157–179.
Report 2007-2008 (TransFair Canada, Ottawa).
TransFair Canada: 2010, ‘Understanding the Registered Darryl Reed and Ian Hussey
Company Listing’, http://transfair.ca/en/content/under York University, Toronto, ON, Canada
standing-registered-company-listing. Accessed 28 Jan 2010. E-mail: dreed@yorku.ca
van den Berghe, F.: 2006, Good Coffee, Bad Governance?
The Legitimacy of FLO, Center for Human Rights and Bob Thomson
Global Justice Working Paper Series, No. 12 (NYU Ottawa, Canada
School of Law, New York).
VanderHoff Boersma, F.: 2009, ‘The Urgency and the Jean-Frédéric LeMay
Necessity of a Different Type of Market: The Perspective Équiterre, Montreal, QC, Canada
of Producers Organized Within the Fair Trade Market’,
Journal of Business Ethics 86(Supplement 1), 51–61.

You might also like