Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 21

Research Article • DOI: 10.

2478/tekhne-2019-0012 Tékhne • 17(1) • 2019 • 10-30

Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND INCOME INEQUALITY:


A DYNAMIC SPATIAL PANEL DATA ANALYSIS

Hanen Ragoubi*, Sana El Harbi

Research Laboratory for Economy, Management and Quantitative Finance (LaREMFiQ), University of Sousse, Tunisia

Received: 29 June 2019; Accepted: 28 October 2019


Abstract
This paper extends the empirical debate of Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018) on the dynamic relationship between entrepreneurship and
income inequality. Using a dynamic spatial panel data analysis for both 33 high-income countries and 39 middle-income and low-
income countries over the period 2004–2014, the main empirical findings are summarised as follows. First, the results indicate that
entrepreneurship is a spatial and persistent phenomenon. Second, there is strong support for the existence of an inverted U-shaped
relationship between entrepreneurship and income inequality espoused by the Kuznets Curve hypothesis for middle-income and
low-income countries. Third, the interaction between income inequality and income per capita has a significant negative effect on
the entrepreneurial activity for middle-income and low-income countries. Fourth, a significant positive association is found between
the interaction variable and entrepreneurship for high-income countries. Fifth, the findings show evidence of significant positive and
negative short-run direct effects of income inequality on the entrepreneurial activity for middle-income and low-income countries.
Finally, there are significant negative short-run spillover effects of income inequality on the entrepreneurial activity for middle-income
and low-income countries.

Keywords
Entrepreneurship • income inequality • dynamic spatial panel data • Kuznets hypothesis • spillover effect

1. Introduction 2011; Hamilton, 2000). Nevertheless, attention to the potential


implications of these patterns for macro-level income distribution
has been scant in the entrepreneurship literature. In the income
The last few decades have witnessed a notable rise in inequality literature, new types of models have been developed
entrepreneurial activity in both developed and developing to decompose and problematise different sources of income
countries. Besides, much public policy in this context has inequality (Cowell & Fiorio, 2011; Creedy & Hérault, 2011;
been directed towards increasing the supply of entrepreneurs Halvarsson, Korpi, & Wennberg, 2018). However, these studies
(Blanchflower, 2000; Steinmetz & Wright, 1989). At the same have tended to overlook entrepreneurship as one of these
time, there has been a dramatic rise in income inequality potential sources. As argued by Audretsch (2009), this oversight
around the world (Atkinson, 2003; Autor, 2014; Goldthorpe, is problematic since entrepreneurship is an increasingly
2010; Jaumotte, Lall, & Papageorgiou, 2013) over the past prevalent occupational choice in many economies.
two decades. In addition, there have been increasing efforts Despite these two parallel economic trends, there is a lack of
by national governments to enact policies that stimulate theoretical insights regarding the causal relationships between
and support entrepreneurial activity (Anokhin & Wincent, entrepreneurial activity and income inequality (Bapuji, 2015;
2012). In the entrepreneurship literature, numerous studies Lewellyn, 2018; Lippmann, Davis, & Aldrich, 2005; Packard
have documented a two-pronged effect of entrepreneurship & Bylund, 2018; Van Praag & Versloot, 2007; Wright & Zahra,
on individual income. They argue that entrepreneurship is 2011). Based on the idea that the concentration of wealth in
a source of enhanced income mobility for some but results the hands of a few can affect the competitive dynamics in the
in lower-than-average income for the large fraction of the industry, Lippmann et al. (2005) develop theoretical propositions
self-employed workforce (Åstebro, Chen, & Thompson, about this relationship and argue that inequality affects the

Corresponding author: Hanen Ragoubi


E-mail: hragoubi2205@gmail.com

Open Access. © 2019 Hanen Ragoubi et al., published by Sciendo


This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 4.0 License.
10
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...

nature of entrepreneurship in society. They claim that the rich Some recent empirical studies have explored the extent
can engage in opportunity entrepreneurship, which is aimed to which inequality influences entrepreneurial activity rates.
at building large corporations and generating returns from the Xavier-Oliveira, Laplume, & Pathak, (2015) examine the
capital. On the other hand, they highlight that the poor have effect of resource endowments (financial and human capital)
fewer resources and engage in necessity entrepreneurship on necessity and opportunity entrepreneurship and the
aimed at sustenance and build small-scale and medium- contingent effect of economic inequality. Using multicountry
scale firms. Bapuji (2015) presents a theoretical framework data on income inequality and entrepreneurship, they show that
to study how economic inequality affects organisational individuals with higher financial and human capital are more
performance. In particular, he suggests that economic likely to engage in opportunity entrepreneurship but less likely
inequality indirectly affects organisational performance via to engage in necessity entrepreneurship. However, as income
human development in the society and directly via its effects inequality in a society increases, individuals with financial
on individual employees and their workplace interactions, and human capital are more likely to engage in necessity
as well as via the institutions in which the organisations are entrepreneurship; financial and human capitals do not stop
embedded. them from being pushed into it. In contrast, only financial
Turning to empirical studies that focus specifically on capital facilitates entry into opportunity entrepreneurship
the relationship between entrepreneurship and income when income inequality is high. In other words, when
inequality, we note a thinner empirical literature that inequality is high, human and financial capitals do not matter
highlights the association between inequality within unless the levels of financial capital are extremely high. These
organisations and employees’ transition to entrepreneurship. results suggest that economic inequality effectively creates
Instead of exploring potential relations to workforce income two social classes – extremely rich who can thrive under all
dispersion per se, some of these studies have typically levels of inequality and the rest who can thrive only when
focused on the conditions in which income dispersion inequality is low. Furthermore, Pathak and Muralidharan
within firms may represent a source of upward earnings (2018) explore the extent to which income inequality and
mobility among individuals choosing to leave these firms for income mobility facilitate or constrain the emergence of social
entrepreneurship (Carnahan, Agarwal, & Campbell, 2012; entrepreneurship. Using multilevel analysis, they demonstrate
Kacperczyk & Balachandran, 2017; Sørensen & Sharkey, that country-level income inequality increases the likelihood of
2014). Nevertheless, a few macro-oriented studies have individual-level engagement in social entrepreneurship, while
highlighted that the greater the number of small firms in an income mobility decreases this likelihood. In addition, they
economy, the more unequal the earnings distribution in that find that income mobility negatively moderates the influence
economy is (Cobb & Lin, 2017; Davis, 2013; Fields & Yoo, of income inequality on social entrepreneurship, such that the
2000). To explain this pattern, the literature has typically condition of low-income mobility and high-income inequality is
provided very broad structural explanations. For instance, a stronger predictor of social entrepreneurship.
Lippmann et al. (2005) provide cross-country evidence on Another empirical study advanced by Sarkar, Ru,
the possible link between the rate of entrepreneurship and & Haughton, (2018) explores the relationship between
workforce income inequality using Global Entrepreneurship inequality and entrepreneurial activity. Using cross-sectional
Monitor (GEM) data. They argue that entrepreneurship rates data from a large-scale survey of the economic conditions of
are higher in countries with significant income inequality individuals across India, they develop several dimensions of
and discuss seven structural factors broadly associated inequality to explore empirically how inequality interacts with
with this pattern: level of economic development, foreign entrepreneurship, operationalised as self-employment or as
direct investment, government policies, increasing labour employing other people. Their findings show that there are
market flexibility, wealth-transfer programmes, service sector thresholds to becoming self-employed, and even more so
growth and variation in worker unionisation. As explained by to assembling the combinations of resources and personal
Lippmann et al. (2005), the logic for this perspective assumes attributes required to become an employer. Moreover, they
that segments of society with greater wealth will possess the find that greater inequality leaves more people unable to make
financial means to invest in entrepreneurial ventures, thus the transition to self-employment, leaving casual labouring as
increasing the rate of entrepreneurial activity driven by market the occupation of necessity. Furthermore, they demonstrate
opportunities. Another argument advanced by Lippmann et al. that inequality increases the number of employers in society,
(2005) is that high-income inequality suggests that a greater by concentrating resources – particularly land and finance –
proportion of the population resides in the lower income enough for significant numbers of people to be able to cross
segment and therefore necessity entrepreneurial activity this higher threshold.
becomes the most expedient way for low-income individuals Alternatively, Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018) empirically
to support themselves. analyse the relationship between entrepreneurship and

11
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

income inequality using a static spatial panel data approach. this regard and following Lippmann et al. (2005), we address
They argue that income inequality is a great contributor to the following assumption: countries with greater income
increasing entrepreneurial activities. A possible explanation is inequality have higher rates of entrepreneurial activity. To
that high-income inequality suggests a greater population in answer that fundamental question, our empirical research
the lower level of the economy ladder, and therefore, necessity extends the study of Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018) by using the
entrepreneurship becomes the preferred choice to make a dynamic spatial panel data (DSPD) models. Recently, there is
living. Furthermore, they point out that ‘entrepreneurship’ is a growing literature on DSPD models, both theoretically and
often assumed to have positive connotations, with inequality empirically. Compared with non-spatial dynamic panel data
having negative connotations, and they ask whether this models where serial correlation occurs in the time dimension,
is consistent, given that entrepreneurship might induce the DSPD models may have a correlation in the time
inequality? In addition, Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018) follow dimension as well as spatial correlation across spatial units. As
Lippmann et al. (2005) by proposing a formulation of the argued by Baltagi, Fingleton, & Pirotte, (2019), Elhorst (2012,
Kuznets’ curve (Kuznets, 1955, 1963) that hypothesises 2014a, b), Elhorst, Zandberg, & de Haan, (2013), Fingleton
a non-linear, inverted U-shaped relationship between (2017, 2019), Fingleton and Szumilo (2019), Lee and Yu
entrepreneurship and income inequality. They conclude that (2010a b, 2014), Yesilyurt and Elhorst (2017), among others,
income inequality can improve entrepreneurial activity after DSPD models are able to deal with unobservable spatial,
an economy has reached an adequate level of inequality, individual and/or time-period specific effects. They also tackle
which means that entrepreneurial activity is highest at an more efficiently endogeneity problems, such as the potential
intermediate level of income inequality. They contend that bias in the coefficient of the spatial lag of the dependent
the increasing phase may be explained by the fact that when variable. Gains of using dynamic spatial versus static spatial
there are small inequalities, there is not sufficient wealth. panels are somewhat described by Doran and Fingleton
They also argue that as inequalities increase, there is wealth (2018), Fingleton (2017) and among others. Fingleton (2017)
accumulation leading to more enterprise creation. However, takes a constructively critical view of spatial econometrics by
after reaching a certain inequality threshold, this relationship focusing on the advantages of DSPD modelling approach.
turns out to be negative. As argued by Doran and Fingleton (2018), DSPD modelling
The detailed statistical analysis of Ragoubi and El approach has a clear advance on the static spatial panel
Harbi (2018) suggest that the picture is, as is usually the approach, which does not take into account, the time
case, far more complex than that. The association between dependency in spatiotemporal series. Besides, they state
entrepreneurship and inequality and indeed the relationship that DSPD estimation considers the potential endogeneity of
between each of these and a variety of other factors – such the regressor. In addition, DSPD approach allows avoiding
as a country’s degree of economic development, per capita omitted variables bias by introducing covariates.
income, research and development, globalisation – are mixed In this article, we contribute to the previous empirical
and contingent on each other and other factors. For instance, literature in two ways. First and foremost, we extend the
while inequality implies that the wealthy will have resources empirical work of Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018) by investigating
that may be invested entrepreneurially, unequal possession of the spatial dependence and intertemporal dynamics of
resources can hamper the ability of other groups to engage in entrepreneurship jointly using dynamic spatial panel data
entrepreneurial activity. Fundamentally, Ragoubi and El Harbi econometrics. Accordingly, we provide new statistical support
(2018) find that the spatial aspects of entrepreneurship, within to the view of others on the empirical relationship between
and between countries, are important. They also conclude entrepreneurship and income inequality (Lippmann et al.,
that public policy can and does have important effects on all 2005; Ragoubi & El Harbi, 2018; Reynolds, Hay, & Bygrave,
the above factors, so the key is that such policies that are 2002; Stiglitz, 2012; Xavier-Oliveira et al., 2015). To the best
aimed at promoting entrepreneurship, and those that are of our knowledge, this work is the first to assess the effects
aimed at tackling excessive inequality, need to take proper of income inequality on entrepreneurial activity using dynamic
account of the variety of possible intended and unintended spatial panel data models. Note that a better understanding
consequences, so that both sets of policies can deliver of the spatial and serial dynamics of entrepreneurship is
successfully their outcomes, of fostering an entrepreneurship important since the literature shows that entrepreneurship
that does not require or create inequality. matters for regional growth (Acs, Braunerhjelm, Audretsch, &
In this article, we provide a novel empirical study by Carlsson, 2009; Audretsch & Keilbach, 2004; Carree & Thurik,
attempting to estimate the influence of income inequality 2003; Fossen & Martin, 2018; Pijnenburg & Kholodilin, 2014).
on entrepreneurship. We seek to address this gap in the Accordingly, we analyse how entrepreneurial activity spreads
literature, which also forms the basis of our overall research over to neighbouring countries and its local persistence over
question: Does income inequality affect entrepreneurship? In time. Besides, both spatial dependence and serial dynamics

12
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...

of entrepreneurial activity are considered as indicators of time-period specific effects, where is an vector
knowledge spillovers over space and time. Second, and of ones, which allow controlling for all time-specific, unit-
contrary to Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018), we avoid an arbitrary invariant variables whose omission could bias the estimates
choice of the spatial weights matrix and instead apply a in a typical time-series study. It should be stressed that these
Bayesian approach to find the parameterised matrix that spatial and time-period specific effects may be treated as fixed
best reflects spatial dependence of entrepreneurial activity effects (FE) or as random effects (RE). Finally,
(LeSage, 2014, 2015). denotes vectors of disturbance terms, whose elements
The remainder of this article is structured as follows. have zero mean and finite variance .
Section 2 outlines the econometric methodology. Section 3 is an matrix with non-negative elements
gives an overview of the data and spatial weight matrices. describing the spatial arrangement of the spatial units in the
The empirical results are presented in section 4 and section sample. By assumption, the diagonal elements of are set to
5 concludes the paper. 0 since no spatial unit can be viewed as its own neighbour. As
argued by LeSage and Pace (2009), if is row normalised,
then and are defined on the interval , where
2. Methodology
equals the most negative purely real characteristic root
of .
Model and estimation strategy Three types of spatial dynamic models are considered by
Following Elhorst et al. (2013), the DSPD model takes the Anselin (2001) and Anselin et al. (2008): pure space recursive
following form: model , time–space recursive model
and time–space simultaneous model . In this study,
(1) we take the model in Eq. (1) as our point of departure. Yu
et al. (2008) consider the log-likelihood function of Eq. (1) in
where is an vector consisting of one observation of order to estimate the parameters of this model. They take into
the dependent variable for every spatial unit account the Jacobian term that reflects the endogeneity of the
in the sample at a particular point in time , variable, that is, the fact that one spatial unit can affect
and denotes an matrix of exogenous explanatory another spatial unit and vice versa. The obtained estimator
variables. Note that a vector or a matrix with subscript is called the Quasi Maximum Likelihood (QML) estimator.1
stands for its serially lagged value, while a vector Furthermore, Yu et al. (2008) show that this QML estimator
or a matrix premultiplied by denotes its spatially lagged is biased when both the number of spatial units and
value. Moreover, the matrix denotes a non- the number of time points in the sample go to infinity
negative matrix of known constants describing the spatial such that . In addition, they introduce
arrangement of the units in the sample. It should be stressed a bias-corrected QML estimator, which produces consistent
that the diagonal elements of the matrix are set to 0 by parameter estimates, provided that the model is stable, that
assumption since no spatial unit can be viewed as its own is, .
neighbour. Furthermore, the parameters , and denote It should be stressed that when , their QML and
the response parameters of the dependent variable lagged bias-corrected QML estimators are found to be consistent.
in time, , the dependent variable lagged in space, However, Yu et al. (2008) point out that when ,
, and the dependent variable lagged in both space the bias-corrected QML estimator is an improvement upon the
and time, . The variables and stand consistency of the QML estimator. Besides, Yu et al. (2008)
for contemporaneous and lagged endogenous interaction argue that if the condition is not satisfied, the
effects among the dependent variables. Besides, is (bias-corrected) QML estimator needs further adjustment.
called the spatial autoregressive coefficient, while might
be labelled the lagged spatial autoregressive coefficient. Non-stability
Note that the parameter is assumed to be restricted to As argued by Elhorst (2014a, b) and Elhorst et al. (2013),
the interval . In addition, the vector stands the estimation of the DSPD model is not straightforward if it
for the response parameters of the exogenous explanatory turns out that the condition is not satisfied,
variables. that is, if the model is unstable. Lee and Yu (2010a) and Yu
Following Baltagi (2005), the vector et al. (2012) propose to transform the model in spatial first
contains spatial specific effects , differences to exclude potentially unstable components in .
which allow controlling for all spatial-specific, time-invariant
variables whose omission could bias the estimates in a typical 1 The term ‘quasi’ is used because the error terms are not assumed
cross-sectional study. Likewise, denote to be normally distributed.

13
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

This is done by taking every variable in the DSPD model in by the matrix that allows dropping the number of
deviation of its spatially lagged value. Mathematically, this is observations. However, Elhorst (2014a, b) argues that this
equivalent to multiplying Eq. (1) by the matrix , which decrease in the number of observations is only a reduction
yields the following expression: in the number of degrees of freedom because the information
of all observations is still implied in the data. Second,
(2) since the transformation reverses the transformation
(except for degrees of freedom), we have
. Third, Lee and Yu (2010a) point out
where denotes the identity matrix of order and that since
.
Eq. (2) has some important properties, which require further (4)
explanation. First, since , all time-period
FE are eliminated from the DSPD model. As noted by Elhorst Eq. (3) can be rewritten as follows:
(2014a, b), these FE do remain effective, since the estimation
of a model formulated in levels produces the same parameter (5)
estimates as the estimation of that model reformulated in
spatial first differences without time-period FE. According to Elhorst (2014a, b) note that the parameters of Eq. (5) can
Elhorst (2014a, b), the reason to renounce the first approach is be consistently estimated by the same bias-corrected (Q) ML
the need to remove the inconsistency caused by the possibly estimator that is used to estimate Eq. (1). Furthermore, Yu
unstable character of the dependent variable . Second, et al. (2012) demonstrate that the transformed model will be
Elhorst (2014a, b) points out that since first differencing in stable if , where is the
time would reduce the number of observations available for second largest eigenvalue of the spatial weights matrix . It
estimation, so does first differencing in space. Third, since is important to note that the latter restriction is less restrictive
it is assumed that and , then than the original restriction .
, where . It should be stressed that there are three differences
According to Elhorst (2014a, b), this change of the variance– between Eqs. (5) and (1). First, the number of degrees of
covariance matrix from into needs to be accounted freedom in each time period is instead of . Second,
for when estimating the parameters of Eq. (2). time-period FE are wiped out, although their effectiveness is
Following Elhorst (2014a, b), since the eigenvalues of not. Third, the matrix is replaced by . Note that the row
the matrix are equal to elements of , in contrast to those in , do not necessarily
, where each is a particular eigenvalue of the spatial sum up to 1. However, the eigenvalues of are
weights matrix , and the largest eigenvalue of is identical to those of that remain after the unit eigenvalue
1 , provided that is normalised, at least one of is excluded.
eigenvalue of the matrix will be 0. This implies that
and thus that this matrix does not have full Direct, indirect and spatial spillover effects
rank. Furthermore, if does have rank instead Following Elhorst et al. (2013) and Yu, de Jong, & Lee,
of , so does . Let denote the (2012), the DSPD model in Eq. (1) has the following error
diagonal matrix of non-zero eigenvalues of , and correction model (ECM) representation (see also Elhorst,
the corresponding orthonormal matrix of 2014a, b):
eigenvectors. Then, Eq. (2) can be transformed by the matrix
, to get the following expression: (6)

where denotes first differences in time, that


(3) is, the change of the dependent variable in time. Furthermore,
Eq. (6) may be rewritten as follows:
According to Elhorst (2014a, b), the latter transformation has
three possible effects. First, since is an (7)
matrix, the transformation reduces the
length of to . It should be stressed that the same Note that Eq. (7) can also be obtained from Eq. (1) by
applies to the length of the transformed matrices or vectors subtracting from and adding to both sides of
, and . This represents the perfect linear combination this equation and rearranging terms. Eq. (7) shows that the
among the observations owing to the multiplication of Eq. (1) change in the dependent variable in period is explained

14
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...

not only by the initial level of the dependent variable of the the diagonal elements of the so-called spatial multiplier matrix
spatial unit itself in the preceding year , but also by are different for different spatial units, provided
the initial levels of the dependent variables of other spatial that . Likewise, indirect effects are different since the
units in the preceding time period . Besides, it non-diagonal elements of that matrix are different. Since the
should be stressed that the coefficient of the initial level in the direct and the indirect effects are different for different spatial
spatial unit itself, , is smaller than 0. This observation units in the sample, the presentation of both effects is not
indicates that an increase of the dependent variable becomes straightforward. Therefore, LeSage and Pace (2009) propose
more likely if the initial value of that variable is relatively low. to measure the direct effect by the average of the diagonal
Furthermore, the sign of the coefficient of the initial levels in elements and the indirect effect by the average of either the
other spatial units, , is expected to be positive. This row sums or the column sums of the non-diagonal elements
evidence indicates that an increase of the dependent variable of that matrix. Moreover, the total effect is the sum of the
becomes also more likely if the initial value of that variable in direct and indirect effects. Besides, Eq. (8) shows that these
other spatial units is already relatively high. marginal effects estimates are independent of the time index.
Furthermore, Eq. (7) indicates that the dependent One could compute the effects estimates of convergence.
variable in one spatial unit is explained by the dependent Using the ECM representation in Eq. (6), we get the following
variable in other spatial units, depending on the specification expression:
of the spatial weights matrix . Note that this term
represents the regional diffusion effect and allows for different (9)
specifications of the spatial weights matrix .
It should be stressed that several empirical studies use Importantly, Elhorst (2014a, b) and Elhorst et al. (2013)
point estimates of one or more spatial regression models suggest that the average diagonal element of this matrix
to test the assumption as to whether or not spatial spillover measures the strength of the convergence effect of the spatial
effects exist. Nevertheless, this may lead to erroneous units themselves and the average row sum of the off-diagonal
conclusions (LeSage & Pace, 2009). In addition, LeSage and elements of the convergence effect of other spatial units.
Pace (2009) point out that a partial derivative interpretation According to Yu et al. (2012), a specific situation occurs
of the impact of changes to the variables of different model if , which is labelled as spatial cointegration.
specifications represents a more valid basis for testing this They point out that the cointegration matrix is
hypothesis. and the cointegration rank is the number of eigenvalues of
Following Elhorst (2014a, b) and Elhorst et al. (2013), one that are smaller than , which is . Furthermore, if
could focus on the ECM representation and, related to that, , we get the following expression:
on the marginal (direct and indirect) effects estimates of a
change in one of the explanatory variables or the change in (10)
the dependent variable in the short term and in the long
term. The matrix of partial derivatives of with respect
to the kth explanatory variable of in spatial unit up to It should be stressed that if is row normalised, the total
spatial unit (say for , respectively), both effect of this partial derivative equals 0 by construction.
at a particular point in time , take the following form: According to Elhorst (2014a, b) and Elhorst et al. (2013),
this finding is due to the perfect linear combination among
the observations caused by the matrix . Note that
the direct effect of this matrix equals 1 because the diagonal
(8)
elements of the identity matrix are 1 and of are 0.
Moreover, the indirect effect of this matrix equals since
the off-diagonal elements of the identity matrix sum up to 0
Besides, these partial derivatives have the following and of to 1, provided that is row normalised. Therefore,
properties. First, if a particular explanatory variable in a the total effect equals 0 . This result means that
particular spatial unit changes, not only the dependent the change in the dependent variable in different spatial units
variable in that spatial unit will change but also the dependent over time does not converge if this variable turns out to be
variable in other spatial units. The first is called a direct effect spatially cointegrated.
and the second an indirect effect. Note that every diagonal As argued by Elhorst (2014a, b) and Elhorst et al.
element of the matrix on the right-hand side of Eq. (8) (2013), the direct and indirect effects on the change in the
represents a direct effect and that every non-diagonal element dependent variable , which can be computed from Eq.
represents an indirect effect. Direct effects are different since (8), are identical to the short-term direct and indirect effects

15
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

of changes in the explanatory variables on the level of the trimmed to 72 countries and included only those countries
dependent variable (see also Debarsy, Ertur, & LeSage, that simultaneously appeared in the World Income Inequality
2012). Nevertheless, this property does not hold for the long- Database, WBGES, Worldwide Governance Indicator, World
term effects (Elhorst, 2014a, b; Elhorst et al., 2013). In addition Economic Outlook, World Economic Forum and globalisation
to the one-period ahead, Debarsy et al. (2012) derive the data sets during the 2004−2014 period. Following Ragoubi
-period ahead matrix from which the long-term direct and and El Harbi (2018), the entrepreneurial activity rate could
indirect effects of changes in the explanatory variables on be measured through the New Business Entry Density (see
the dependent variable can be computed. Elhorst (2014a, b) also Armington & Acs, 2002; Bartelsman, Haltiwanger, &
and Elhorst et al. (2013) point out that this matrix reduces to Scarpetta, 2004; Herrera-Echeverri, Haar, & Estevez-Breton,
in the long term. They also 2014; Klapper, Laeven, & Rajan, 2006; Klapper & Love, 2010;
indicate that if the model is spatially cointegrated, the matrix Verheul, 2009) and the self-employment rate (see also Acs &
in square brackets is singular, as a result of which the long- Amoros, 2008; Amoros & Cristi, 2008; Amoros, Fernandez, &
term direct and indirect effects are not defined. Accordingly, Tapia, 2012; Carree, Van Stel, Thurik, & Wennekers, 2002,
this evidence justifies the treatment of as a 2007). The New Business Entry Density is calculated as the
special case and the focus on rather than . number of new companies registered by every 1000 people of
working age (using a standard range of 15–64 years of age).
The self-employment (or business ownership) is measured as
3. Data, variables and spatial weight matrices
a percentage of employment.
Similar to Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018), we consider
The sample consists of 72 countries2, over the period three categories of independent and control variables in
2004−2014, for which we subdivided3 it into two subgroups: : economic, social and demographic. The GINI coefficient
the high-income countries (HIC) (N=33, T=11) and middle- of income inequality is chosen as the main independent
income and low-income countries (MLIC) (N=39, T=11). Note variable (Ragoubi & El Harbi, 2018). As control variables, we
that this categorisation is justified due to the socioeconomic use the gross domestic product (GDP) per capita (Ragoubi
and political differences between MLIC and HIC. In addition, & El Harbi, 2018; Van Stel, Carree, & Thurik, 2005), the
this separation of countries makes each group of countries governance or institutional quality index4 (Herrera-Echeverri
more homogenous and therefore enables us to reduce the et al., 2014; Kaufmann, Kraay, & Mastruzzi, 2009, 2010;
level of heteroskedasticity that otherwise we might face when McMullen, Bagby, & Palich, 2008; Ragoubi & El Harbi, 2018;
estimating the models. Van Stel, Storey, & Thurik, 2007; Wennekers et al., 2005),
We gathered data on the entrepreneurial activity, the Konjunkturforschungsstelle (KOF) globalisation index5
income inequality and other macroeconomic indicators (Dreher, 2006; Dreher, Gaston, & Martens, 2008; Ragoubi &
from several sources (see Table 1). Spatial econometric El Harbi, 2018), the gross domestic expenditure on research
research requires that the spatial panel be balanced. and development (Deeds, 2001; Ragoubi & El Harbi, 2018),
Therefore, missing observations should be avoided as far the population growth rate (Armington & Acs, 2002; Ragoubi
as possible. Note that the initial sampling point is the World & El Harbi, 2018; Wennekers et al., 2005) and the global
Bank Group Entrepreneurship Snapshot (WBGES) data set
4 World wide Governance Indicators (WGI) comprises aggregate
of 115 developed and developing countries for the 2004–
and individual governance indicators for 215 countries and territories
2014 period. In the analysis, the world sample was finally covering the period 1996−2014. It covers six dimensions of institutio-
nal quality: voice and accountability (VA); political stability and the ab-
2 The list of HIC includes Austria, Belgium, Canada, Chile, Croa- sence of violence/terrorism (PS); government effectiveness (GE); re-
tia, Cyprus, Czech, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, gulatory quality (RQ); rule of law (RL); and control of corruption (CC).
Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Latvia, Lithuania, The definitions and sources for the calculation of each one are found
Luxembourg, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slo- in Kaufmann et al. (2010). A principal component analysis (PCA) is
venia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States performed over this set of indicators to reduce data to a suitable num-
of America, and Uruguay. The list of middle and low income coun- ber of dimensions. For both HIC and MLIC, the analysis reveals that
tries includes Argentina, Armenia, Bolivia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, one single factor is extracted from the PCA (the results are available
Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Burkina Faso, Cambodia, China, Colom- upon request).
bia, Congo Democratic Republic, Costa Rica, Dominica, Dominican 5 The overall index covers the economic, social, and political di-
Republic, El Salvador, Ethiopia, Georgia, Ghana, Guatemala, India, mensions of globalization. Following Clark (2000) and Keohane and
Indonesia, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Mace- Nye (2000), it defines globalization as the process of creating net-
donia, Malawi, Malaysia, Mauritius, Moldova, Montenegro, Panama, works of connections among actors at multicontinental distances,
Peru, Romania, Russian Federation, Tunisia, Turkey, and Ukraine. mediated through a variety of flows including people, information and
3 World Bank’s classification of countries by income. ideas, capital, and goods.

16
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...

Table 1. Variables and data sources

Variables Data source

Entry density (NEW DENSITY) World Bank Group Entrepreneurship Snapshots (WBGES).
http://www.doingbusiness.org/data/exploretopics/entrepreneurship
Self-employment World Bank
GINI index (GINI) World Bank annual Doing Business report
UNU/WIDER World Income Inequality Database (WIID).
http://www.wider.unu.edu/research/Database/en_GB/database/
Gross domestic product per capita World Bank
World Economic Outlook (WEO)
Government (institutional quality) index Author’s calculation.
Gross domestic expenditure on Research Research and Development Statistics (RDS) – Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
and Development (GERD) www.oecd.org/sti/rds
Population growth rate (POP_GR) World Development Indicators (WDI) – World Bank
http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators
KOF index of globalisation Konjunkturforschungsstelle (KOF) Index
http://globalization.kof.ethz.ch/.
Global Competitiveness Index World Economic Forum (WEF)
The Global Competitiveness Reports
http://www.weforum.org/reports/global-competitiveness-report.

Table 2. Descriptive statistics.


Panel A: HIC Panel B: MLIC

Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev.

1.201 0.865 0.128 1.642

2.685 0.398 3.517 0.571

3.426 0.182 3.697 0.219

4.395 0.090 4.052 0.177

1.566 0.173 1.389 0.132

10.308 0.673 8.031 1.034

0.357 0.654 −1.072 0.977

0.000 1.000 0.000 1.000

0.405 0.793 1.142 1.078

HIC, high-income countries; MLIC, middle-income and low-income countries.

competitiveness index6 (Amoros et al., 2012; Ragoubi and including the spatial lags of all explanatory variables in the
El Harbi, 2018). Note that except governance and population model, we can separate spillovers from characteristics of
growth rate, all the remaining variables enter the empirical neighbouring countries.
model in logarithmic form. It should be also stressed that by Summary statistics are reported in Table 2. In general, all
the variables show a high variability suitable for exploratory
6 The World Economic Forum has been measuring national com- investigations. From Table 2, it can be seen that the
petitiveness and filing Global Competitiveness Reports (GCR). The standard deviation of both dependent variables, that is,
key purpose of the GCR is to evaluate the capacity of the world’s ln(NEWDENSITY) and ln(SELF), is higher for MLIC than
economies to achieve sustained economic growth. The GCR me-
that for HIC. In addition, the mean values of these series are
thodology has been based on the model developed by McArthur and
positive across the two country groups.
Sachs (2002), known as the Growth Competitiveness Index (GCI).
Following Elhorst et al. (2013) and Yesilyurt and Elhorst
The GCI attempts to quantify the impact of a number of key factors
that contribute to create the conditions for competitiveness, with par- (2017), we use four principles in order to construct the
ticular focus on the macroeconomic environment, the quality of the following four spatial weight matrices:
country’s institutions, and the state of the country’s technology and • The first-order binary contiguity matrix, denoted by :
supporting infrastructure. sharing a common land or maritime border (Goldsmith,

17
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

2007; Skogstad, 2016; Yesilyurt & Elhorst, 2017). Note 4. Results and discussions
that maritime borders are based on the United Nations
Convention on the Law of the Sea and additional sources Baseline results
further explaining this convention. Tables 3 and 4 report the Bayesian posterior model probabilities
• The second-order binary contiguity matrix, denoted of the different spatial panel data models (spatial autoregressive
by : the influence of a country might go beyond its (SAR), spatial Durbin model (SDM), spatial error model (SEM),
immediate neighbours, as implied by the inverse distance spatial Durbin error model (SDEM)) in combination with the
matrix (Goldsmith, 2007) and the different cut-off points four proposed spatial weight matrices. These probabilities are
(Florez, 2011). computed for both static and dynamic versions of the model
• The third-order binary contiguity matrix, denoted by : specifications. With these probabilities, the most likely spatial
a country may respond to the threat of even more distant panel econometric model and the most likely spatial weight
countries, which is also the main reason that elements of matrix could be simultaneously identified. It should be stressed
the weight matrix within a certain radius of a country are that the probabilities are based on the log-marginal likelihood
not always set to 0. obtained by integrating out all parameters of the model over
• The spheric matrix, denoted by : this matrix is based the entire parameter space on which they are defined. Besides,
on the calculation of distances using the spherical these probabilities are normalised such that the probabilities
distance (in km) between geographic centroids of the of all 16 combinations sum to 1. As argued by Goldsmith
countries.7 (2007), LeSage (2014, 2015), Skogstad (2016) and Yesilyurt
Following the literature, one can predict that and Elhorst (2017), this normalisation is based on the (non-
geographically closer countries will have a stronger linear) property that the Bayesian posterior model probability
influence on a country in terms of entrepreneurial activity increases if the log-marginal likelihood value of one model or
than more distant countries. However, the theory does not one exceeds that of another model or .
give guidance on how quickly the influence diminishes when The results in Table 3 show that the SDM outperforms the
distance increases. This is an empirical question that we other models in almost all 16 cases, for both the HIC and MLIC
aim to answer in this study. Therefore, we parameterise data sets. Row totals for this model range from 0.9936, based
the spatial weight matrix search for the most appropriate on the first, to 0.9937 for the second data set. This finding is
matrix by using a Bayesian comparison approach (da Silva, not striking, especially considering that the SDM is much general
Elhorst, & da Mota Silveira Neto, 2017; Elhorst et al., 2013; than both the SAR and SEM specifications and requires that the
LeSage, 2014, 2015; Yesilyurt & Elhorst, 2017). By finding coefficients of all exogenous spatial lags are jointly significant
an optimal spatial weight matrix between close and distant . This finding corroborates previous results by Ragoubi
neighbours, this approach delivers a good approximation of and El Harbi (2018). The spatial interaction among countries
the underlying spatial dependence of entrepreneurial activity. appears driven not only by the endogenous spatial lag, and
In addition, this procedure allows us to inspect the sensitivity countries adapt their entrepreneurial activity rate to those of their
of the estimated coefficients with respect to different spatial neighbours and also to other variables observed in neighbouring
weight matrices. countries. Therefore, the extension of the entrepreneurial activity
function with the variable is necessary.
The most likely spatial weight matrix differs across the
two data sets. The HIC data set favours the third-order binary
7 With the exception of the matrix based on the common border
contiguity matrix . This matrix outperforms others no matter
countries, the spatial weight matrix could be also based on the calcu-
which spatial panel econometric model is used. The MLIC data
lation of distances using the spherical distance between geographic
centroids of the countries (Abate, 2016; Eckel, Löffler, Maurer, &
set instead favours the spheric contiguity matrix .
Schmidt, 2011; Longley et al., 2001). Accordingly, for each country The results in Table 4 are similar to those reported in Table
pair, we compute the distance between headquarter locations based 3. More precisely, they show that the SDM outperforms the
on the geographical coordinates of the countries. Formally, the spheri- other models in almost all 16 cases, for both the HIC and
cal distance (in km) between the centroids of two countries and is MLIC data sets. Row totals for this model range from 0.7745,
defined as follows: based on the second, to 0.9577 for the first data set. This
finding also corroborates the previous findings by Ragoubi
and El Harbi (2018).
where denotes the earth radius ( miles or km),
which is the approximate distance from Earth’s center to its surface, Estimation results
represents the latitude of the centroid of country , while is the In this section, we are interested in simultaneously estimating
longitude of the centroid of country . spatial dependence and serial dynamics of entrepreneurial

18
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...

Table 3. Simultaneous Bayesian comparison of model specifications and spatial weight matrices (dependent variable: )
(Source: Own calculations, based on LeSage (2014, 2015)).

Data Model Row total

HIC SAR 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

SDM 0.0000 0.0008 0.9877 0.0051 0.9936

Dynamic model SEM 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

SDEM 0.0000 0.0002 0.0026 0.0036 0.0064

SAR 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

MLIC SDM 0.0000 0.0040 0.0002 0.9895 0.9937

Dynamic model SEM 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

SDEM 0.0000 0.0053 0.0001 0.0010 0.0064

The highest probability in each row is in italics and the probabilities in each block sum to 1.
HIC, high-income countries; MLIC, middle-income and low-income countries; SAR, spatial autoregressive; SDM, spatial Durbin model, SEM,
spatial error model, SDEM, spatial Durbin error model.

Table 4. Simultaneous Bayesian comparison of model specifications and spatial weight matrices (dependent variable: ) (Source:
Own calculations, based on LeSage (2014, 2015)).
Data Model Row total

HIC SAR 0.0001 0.0002 0.0000 0.0001 0.0004


SDM 0.0000 0.0003 0.0130 0.9444 0.9577
Dynamic model SEM 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001
SDEM 0.0000 0.0001 0.0079 0.0338 0.0418
SAR 0.0004 0.0009 0.0005 0.0005 0.0023
MLIC SDM 0.0000 0.0003 0.0000 0.7742 0.7745
Dynamic model SEM 0.0004 0.0008 0.0006 0.0004 0.0022
SDEM 0.0000 0.0002 0.0000 0.2207 0.2209

The highest probability in each row is in italics and the probabilities in each block sum to 1.
HIC, high-income countries; MLIC, middle-income and low-income countries; SAR, spatial autoregressive; SDM, spatial Durbin model, SEM,
spatial error model, SDEM, spatial Durbin error model.

activity rates while controlling for spatial unit and FE Following the results of the Bayesian model comparison, the
and covariates pertaining to the focal countries and their dynamic variant of SDM, which includes the spatial lags of all
neighbours. We estimate a general and flexible model including explanatory variables, is expressed as follows:
spatial, serial and spatiotemporal lags of the entrepreneurial
activity rate. Spatial interactions of entrepreneurial activity (11)
might occur within a year, that is, instantaneously in our
model based on annual observations, which is especially In Eq. (11), the endogenous variable is the log
plausible if fast knowledge spillovers play a central role, entrepreneurial activity rate in country and year . We include
or they could unfold with a longer time lag. Accounting for the time lag with the intertemporal autoregressive
country unit and FE and further control variables is necessary coefficient , which captures the path dependency of
to separate interactions among entrepreneurial activity from entrepreneurial activity within the geographical country.
other potential effects. This strengthens the interpretation Potential spatial interactions with other countries are modelled
of space and time dynamics as knowledge flows from by including a spatial lag , where is the total
entrepreneurial activity rates to other entrepreneurial activity number of countries and is the spatial weight. It represents
rates in neighbouring countries or subsequent years. the element of a non-negative spatial weight

19
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

matrix , which defines the neighbouring countries. The cannot be rejected, the model may be said to be spatially
weight may be 0 when the distance between countries cointegrated. Moreover, Elhorst et al. (2013) and Lee and Yu
and is large. The spatial autoregressive coefficient to (2010a) argue that when the model turns out to be non-stable
be estimated indicates the strength of spatial dependence (explosive or spatially cointegrated), it must be reformulated
of country entrepreneurial activity. The vector in spatial first differences and its coefficients must be re-
includes the control variables and the vectors includes estimated according to its transformation in Eq. (3) for which
and the coefficients that reflect the influences of these we use Eq. (5) to obtain consistent parameter estimates. As
variables in the same country and from the neighbouring shown in Table 5, a necessary and sufficient condition for
countries of the focal country. The model includes unobserved stationarity, , is also satisfied.
country FE , and is the remaining error term. In Table 6, we present the estimation results of the
In our baseline specification, we include a spatiotemporal dynamic SDM specification, based on the MLIC data set
lag of the dependent variable, that is, we use the restriction and the matrix, and with as the
, as not often done in the literature (e.g., Devereux, dependent variable. As shown in Table 6, the entrepreneurial
Lockwood, & Redoano, 2007; Elhorst, 2005, 2010; Parent & activity indicator strongly depends on its value in the
LeSage, 2012). previous year; its coefficient amounts to and is
Table 5 reports the main empirical findings of the highly significant (1% level). Moreover, the coefficient of the
dynamic SDM specification, based on the HIC data set entrepreneurial activity observed in neighbouring countries in
and the matrix and with as the the previous period is negative but not statistically significant
dependent variable. Note that the model parameters are ( , -value ). However, countries
estimated using the bias-corrected ML estimator (Lee & Yu, respond to the entrepreneurial activity in neighbouring
2010a). As argued by Baltagi (2005), the bias correction countries in the same year, such that the coefficient takes
is necessary since the demeaning procedure to eliminate a negative value of and is highly significant (
the country FE in a standard panel data model produces a -value ). It should be stressed that the inclusion
singularity among the transformed error terms if the model of the endogenous spatial lag has a downward effect on the
is augmented with a spatial lag in the dependent variable, entrepreneurial activity parameter.
causing the asymptotic distributions of the parameters not to Furthermore, the results show strong support for the
be properly centred. existence of an inverted U-shaped relationship between
As shown in Table 5, the estimation results indicate entrepreneurship and income inequality espoused by the
that the coefficients of the dependent variables lagged in Kuznets Curve hypothesis. This important finding confirms
time and in both space and time some of the results of previous work of Ragoubi and El Harbi
are, respectively, positive and (2018) (see also Lippmann et al., 2005; Reynolds et al., 2002;
negative but not statistically significant in the dynamic SDM. Xavier-Oliveira et al., 2015). Furthermore, entrepreneurship
However, the coefficient of the dependent variable lagged has a significant non-linear relationship with GDP per capita
in space is negative and statistically (Acs & Amoros, 2008; Amoros & Cristi, 2008; Carree et al.,
significant at the 1% level. Besides, the coefficient estimates 2007; Ragoubi & El Harbi, 2018; Wennekers et al., 2005,
of the independent variables show that the GINI and the 2010). Additionally, the coefficient estimates of the remaining
squared GINI are successively positive and negative but independent variables show that the interaction between
not statistically significant. GDP per capita is negative income inequality and economic development is negative
and thus significantly set back the entrepreneurial activity. and thus significantly set back the entrepreneurial activity.
Conversely, the squared GDP per capita, the interaction On the contrary, the globalisation index leads to significant
between income inequality and economic development, higher entrepreneurial activity. The Wald test reported in Table
the global competitiveness and the globalisation lead to 6 shows that the dynamic SDM of the entrepreneurial activity
significant higher entrepreneurial activity. rate is stable because the condition that is
To find out whether the model including country FE is satisfied.
stable, we calculated and carried out a Wald test In Table 7, we present the estimation results of the
to investigate the (null) hypothesis . This dynamic SDM specification, based on the HIC data set
Wald test has also been used in the two empirical illustrations and the matrix, and with as the dependent
of Elhorst et al. (2013) and Lee and Yu (2010a). As argued by variable. The coefficients of the dependent variables
Elhorst et al. (2013) and Lee and Yu (2010a), if lagged in time and in both space and time
turns out to be significantly smaller than 1, the model is are both positive and statistically significant
stable. Besides, if is greater than 1, the model in the dynamic SDM. Besides, the coefficient of the dependent
is explosive. In addition, if the hypothesis variable lagged in space is negative and

20
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...

statistically significant. In addition, the coefficient estimates a country’s income inequality, for example, measures how a
of the independent variables show that only globalisation and change in a particular country affects the perceived levels of
governance indicators have significant positive impacts on entrepreneurial activity in that same country.
the entrepreneurial activity rate. A necessary and sufficient The estimated short-run direct effect of the GINI variable
condition for stationarity, , is also on the entrepreneurial activity indicator is positive and
satisfied. statistically significant at the 1% level but greater than . This
In Table 8, we present the estimation results of the dynamic result indicates that entrepreneurial activity rate increases with
SDM specification, based on the MLIC data set and the the level of GINI but more than proportionally. Alternatively,
matrix, and with as the dependent variable. a one standard deviation8 increase in income inequality in a
The coefficients of the dependent variables lagged in time given country leads to a standard deviation increase in
and in both space and time the perceived levels of entrepreneurial activity in that country.
are both positive and statistically significant in the dynamic Besides, the direct effects are different from the estimates of
SDM. Besides, the coefficient of the dependent variable the response parameters (see Table 6) in the dynamic SDM.
lagged in space is negative and statistically This is caused by the feedback effects9 that arise as a result
significant. The coefficient estimates of the independent of impacts passing through to other countries and back to
variables show that income inequality and per capita income the country itself. Since the direct effect and the coefficient
significantly set back entrepreneurial activity. Conversely, estimate of income inequality (GINI) are, respectively, 23.0546
both squared income inequality and squared per capita and 15.3501, its feedback effect is 7.7045.
income lead to significant higher entrepreneurial activity. Furthermore, the direct effect of the GDP variable on the
These results do not confirm some of the results of previous entrepreneurial activity rate is also positive and statistically
work of Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018). Therefore, the inverted significant. On the other hand, a one standard deviation
U-shaped relationship between entrepreneurship and income increase in income per capita in a given country leads to a
inequality is not supported. A necessary and sufficient standard deviation increase in the perceived levels
condition for stationarity, , is also of entrepreneurial activity in that country. Besides, the
satisfied. impacts of both the interaction variable and the
global competitiveness index on a country’s
Short-run and long-run effects entrepreneurial activity rate are negative and statistically
In this section, we use the parameter estimates of the dynamic significant but greater than ; the entrepreneurial activity
SDM to compute direct and indirect effects of the different rate increases with the levels of these variables but less than
explanatory variables on entrepreneurial activity, that is, the proportionally. A one standard deviation increase in global
average of the diagonal elements and the row/column sums competitiveness, for example, in a given country leads to a
of the matrix of partial derivatives. These direct and indirect standard deviation decrease in the perceived levels of
effects, as well as the total effects, are reported in Tables entrepreneurial activity in that country.
5–8, respectively. Table 5 reports the short-run and long-run In addition, the direct effects of both the KOF index of
effects from the dynamic SDM, based on the HIC data set globalisation and governance index
and the matrix, and with as the variables are significantly positive, implying that the
dependent variable. Both the short-run and long-run effects entrepreneurial activity indicator increases with a higher level
are decomposed into direct and indirect (spillover) effects of these explanatory variables. Alternatively, a one standard
in order to isolate the spatial spillover effects. In a dynamic deviation increase in both globalisation and governance
context, if the short-term effect is smaller than the long-term indices in a given country lead to, respectively, and
effect, then the lagged effects are important. Besides, the standard deviation increases in the perceived levels of
total effect takes into account both own-country and spillover entrepreneurial activity in that country. The same interpretation
effects. It should be stressed that both the direct and indirect holds for both squared income inequality and squared GDP
short-run effects and the direct and indirect long-run effects per capita. Therefore, controlling for spatial effects seems to
are all statistically insignificant. Therefore, we do not interpret be relevant. However, a potential change in an explanatory
these marginal effects. variable could have a long-term effect on the perceived levels
Table 6 displays the short-run and long-run effects from
the dynamic SDM, based on the MLIC data set and the
8 It is defined as the ratio of the standard deviation of an explana-
matrix, and with as the dependent tory variable and that of the dependent variable multiplied by the esti-
variable. The coefficient estimates and short-term direct mated coefficient (Donfouet et al., 2016).
effects estimates derived from the parameter estimates exhibit 9 Feedback effect direct effect− coefficient estimate (Elhorst et al.,
a plausible model structure. The direct effect of a change in 2013).

21
22
Table 5. Results of the dynamic SDM, with as the dependent variable, HIC data and .
Short-term effects Long-term effects
Determinants Coefficients
Direct Indirect (Spillover) Total Direct Indirect (Spillover) Total

Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value
−0.2371*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.6151 0.1847 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.0634 0.1707 – – – – – – – – – – – –
6.5749 0.8340 33.0276 0.2130 26.7429 0.1836 59.7705* 1.7290 9.6939 0.0133 41.9708 0.0575 51.6647* 1.7252
−2.3062 0.4500 −5.9478 −0.3038 −4.6436 −0.2509 −10.5914*** −2.8225 −3.3516 −0.0396 −5.8064 −0.0686 −9.1580*** −2.8716
−8.5713*** 0.0071 −12.5657 −0.8938 −10.9915 −0.7466 −23.5572*** −3.4297 −14.7616 −0.0687 −5.7570 −0.0268 −20.5186*** −3.4533
0.3032*** 0.0041 0.5214 0.5696 0.4610 0.5066 0.9824*** 5.3665 0.5747 0.0997 0.2823 0.0491 0.8571*** 4.9064
0.7168* 0.0581 0.5411 0.2161 0.4254 0.1832 0.9665 0.7925 1.0145 0.0323 −0.1812 −0.0058 0.8332 0.8018
1.5151** 0.0158 2.1478 0.7391 0.9074 0.3204 3.0552*** 6.8556 5.0680 0.1107 2.6816*** 5.6071
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

−2.3864 −0.0521
1.4460* 0.0534 3.9318 0.3213 3.5786 0.3059 7.5105*** 6.4342 3.5485 0.0614 2.9994 0.0519 6.5479*** 5.1728
0.1521 0.1157 0.4059 0.2141 0.2994 0.1649 0.7054*** 3.5542 0.1619 0.0238 0.4425 0.0651 0.6044*** 4.1887
−0.0540 0.4697 −0.0510 −0.4019 −0.0018 −0.0145 −0.0528 −0.7218 −0.1452 −0.0559 0.0942 0.0363 −0.0510 −0.7567
0.1593 0.2879 0.1356 0.3420 −0.0044 −0.0116 0.1313 0.6257 0.5269 0.0716 −0.4100 −0.0558 0.1168 0.6416
15.8400 0.2729 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−2.7834** 0.0243 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−6.1308*** 0.0003 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.2566*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.2444 0.1949 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.7746*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
1.9844*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.1877*** 0.0001 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.0127 0.3846 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0281 0.7965 – – – – – – – – – – – –
R-squared 0.9469 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0867 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
Log-likelihood 49.5915 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.3146 – – – – – – – – – – – – –

Wald test 41.0567*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –


Wald test for dynamic spatial
155.3223*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
lag model
Wald test for dynamic spatial
116.4366*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
error model

Country fixed effects are included. *Significant at 10%; **significant at 5%; ***significant at 1%.
Table 6 Results of the dynamic SDM, with as the dependent variable, MLIC data and .
Coefficients Short-term effects Long-term effects
Direct Indirect (Spillover) Total Direct Indirect (Spillover) Total
Determinants
Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value
-value
−0.2419*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.5577*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.0886 0.5070 – – – – – – – – – – – –
15.3501*** 0.0022 23.0546*** 2.5415 −21.7241** −2.1657 1.3305 0.1809 −36.1670 −0.0297 23.6415 0.0236 −12.5255 −0.0529
−1.5314*** 0.0081 −2.3585** −2.0329 2.3160* 1.9162 −0.0425 −0.0535 3.9969 0.0314 −2.5783 −0.0247 1.4186 0.0567
4.3460*** 0.0000 4.9789*** 3.7102 −1.8212 −1.1946 3.1577*** 2.5989 −1.9530 −0.0088 3.3727 0.0182 1.4197 0.0351
−0.1355*** 0.0000 −0.1365*** −3.2002 0.0028 0.0516 −0.1337*** −2.9309 −0.0265 −0.0047 −0.0818 −0.0170 −0.1082 −0.1120
−0.6035** 0.0070 −0.7979*** −2.9710 0.5591* 1.8486 −0.2388 −0.9053 0.7942 0.0206 −0.6299 −0.0198 0.1643 0.0219
0.0007 0.9271 −0.4192* −1.7130 1.1765*** 3.1891 0.7572*** 2.9913 1.9935 0.0496 −0.6996 −0.0201 1.2939 0.2256
0.7987*** 0.0076 1.6903*** 2.7813 −2.5194*** −4.1291 −0.8291** −2.0782 −5.6804 −0.0468 3.3544 0.0327 −2.3260 −0.1119
−0.0517 0.1212 0.1242 1.4742 −0.5010*** −2.6022 −0.3768*** −2.8889 −0.9264 −0.0623 0.2660 0.0229 −0.6604 −0.1927
−0.0196 0.4663 0.1295 1.2915 −0.4300*** −4.3483 −0.3005*** −4.0129 −0.8165 −0.0544 0.3035 0.0237 −0.5129 −0.2142
0.1454 0.1126 0.1938** 2.0564 −0.1484 −1.1218 0.0454 0.4154 −0.4140 −0.0267 0.3321 0.0252 −0.0818 −0.0318
−5.1881* 0.0568 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.5771* 0.0607 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.3068 0.8293 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.0317 0.4352 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0833 0.2343 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.4854*** 0.0058 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.8499*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.2231*** 0.0004 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.1838*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.0291 0.5990 – – – – – – – – – – – –
R-squared 0.9819 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0426 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
Log-likelihood 74.7587 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.2272 – – – – – – – – – – – – –

Wald test 140.4861*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –


Wald test for dynamic spatial
lag model 88.9607*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
Wald test for dynamic spatial
error model 83.1097*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –

Notes: Country fixed effects are included. *Significant at 10%; **significant at 5%; ***significant at 1%.

23
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

of entrepreneurial activity. It should be stressed that none of ( -value ), while its indirect effect is also positive and
the explanatory variables exhibits significance levels for the significantly different from 0 ( , -value ).
long-term direct effects. By contrast, the indirect effect of a change in the governance
There is also an indirect or spillover effect that non- variable in a particular country on other countries appears
spatial panel models cannot capture. Furthermore, based to be approximately 67.6758% of the direct effect within that
on the -statistics calculated from a set of 1000 simulated country. A possible explanation of this indirect effect is that if
parameter values,10 seven of these indirect effects appear to the governance variable in a particular country changes, not
be statistically significant in the short term, but none in the only the entrepreneurial activity rate of that country itself but
long term. It concerns the impact of income inequality and its also that of other countries will change. Furthermore, the direct
squared form, the interaction between economic development effects in the dynamic SDM are different from the estimates
and income inequality, competitiveness, globalisation, of the response parameters as shown in Table 7. This could
gross domestic expenditure on research and development be explained by the feedback effects that arise as a result of
and population growth rate. In other words, if one of these impacts passing through to other countries and back to the
explanatory variables in a particular country changes, not country itself. However, these feedback effects turn out to be
only the entrepreneurial activity rate of that country itself but small. For instance, since the direct effect and the coefficient
also that of other countries will change. For instance, the estimate of governance (gov) are, respectively, and
entrepreneurial activity rate decreases not only with the level , its feedback effect is only . Moreover, since
of income inequality in the own country but also, to a lesser the direct effect and the coefficient estimate of globalisation
extent, with that in neighbouring countries. Alternatively, a one (KOF) are, respectively, and , its feedback
standard deviation increase in income inequality in a given effect is only .
country leads to a standard deviation decrease in the Table 8 displays the short-run and long-run effects from
perceived levels of entrepreneurial activity in neighbouring the dynamic SDM, based on the MLIC data set and the
countries. matrix, and with as the dependent variable. The
The same interpretation holds for globalisation, gross estimated short-run direct effect of the GINI variable on the
domestic expenditure on research and development and entrepreneurial activity is negative and statistically significant
population growth rate variables. Conversely, the squared at the 5% level but smaller than −1. This finding indicates
income inequality, the interaction between economic that entrepreneurial activity rate decreases with the level of
development and income inequality and the global income inequality but more than proportionally. Alternatively,
competitiveness index show significant positive spillover a one standard deviation increase in income inequality in a
effects. This finding indicates that the entrepreneurial activity given country leads to a standard deviation increase in
rate increases not only with the level of each of these variables the perceived levels of entrepreneurial activity in that country.
in the own country but also with that in neighbouring countries. Besides, since the direct effect and the coefficient estimate of
Alternatively, a one standard deviation increase in the global income inequality are, respectively, and
competitiveness index, for example, in a given country leads , its feedback effect amounts to . Besides, the direct
to a standard deviation increase in the perceived levels effect of the GDP per capita variable on the entrepreneurial
of entrepreneurial activity in neighbouring countries. activity rate is also negative and statistically significant.
Table 7 displays the short-run and long-run effects from the Alternatively, a one standard deviation increase in GDP per
dynamic SDM, based on the HIC data set and the matrix, capita in a given country leads to a standard deviation
and with as the dependent variable. By examining decrease in the perceived levels of entrepreneurial activity
the marginal effects reported in Table 7, the direct effect of in that country. Moreover, the impacts of both the squared
the globalisation variable is positively significant and amounts income inequality and the squared GDP per capita
to ( -value ), while its indirect effect is on a country’s entrepreneurial activity rate are
( -value ), but not statistically significant. positive and statistically significant but smaller than ; the
The total effect is larger than both direct and indirect effects, entrepreneurial activity rate increases with the levels of these
but still significantly positive ( , -value ). variables but less than proportionally.
In addition, the direct effect of the governance variable is Furthermore, based on the -statistics computed from a
positive and statistically significant, which amounts to set of 1000 simulated parameter values, four of the spillover
effects appear to be statistically significant in the short term,
10 In order to draw inferences regarding the statistical significance but none in the long term. For example, the entrepreneurial
of these effects, we used the variation of 1000 simulated parameter activity rate increases not only with the levels of GDP
combinations drawn from the multivariate normal distribution implied per capita, squared GDP per capita and gross domestic
by the ML estimates (LeSage & Pace, 2009).

24
Table 7. Results of the dynamic SDM, with as the dependent variable, HIC data and .
Short-term effects Long-term effects
Coefficients
Determinants Direct Indirect (Spillover) Total Direct Indirect (Spillover) Total
Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value
−0.2374*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.8250*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.1251*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−3.7870 0.3271 −2.6966 −0.6295 3.2066 0.7053 0.5100 0.0804 −16.2497 −0.0365 16.6970 0.0376 0.4474 0.0293
0.2967 0.4732 0.2022 0.4370 −0.3003 −0.5991 −0.0981 −0.1430 1.5364 0.0412 −1.6919 −0.0455 −0.1554 −0.0945
−0.3615 0.4636 −0.0558 −0.0614 0.7138 0.7935 0.6580 0.5555 2.1331 0.0261 −0.6810 −0.0083 1.4521 0.5221
−0.0097 0.8602 −0.0196 −0.7436 −0.0219 −0.8456 −0.0415 −1.3160 −0.1829 −0.0412 0.0863 0.0194 −0.0967 −1.2824
0.1643 0.2805 0.1198 0.8137 −0.1168 −0.7419 0.0030 0.0137 0.4605 0.0220 −0.4305 −0.0206 0.0300 0.0580
0.1195 0.3324 0.1210 1.0635 0.0097 0.0800 0.1307 1.6093 3.5715 0.0374 −3.2607 −0.0341 0.3108 1.5461
0.4097* 0.0795 0.4854*** 2.3685 0.2585 1.1734 0.7439*** 3.8902 2.9568 0.0594 −1.2067 −0.0242 1.7501*** 3.3987
0.0178 0.1611 0.0226 0.6801 0.0072 0.2229 0.0298 0.7692 −0.0939 −0.0092 0.1718 0.0168 0.0780 0.7790
−0.0020 0.9619 0.0009 0.0901 0.0072 0.6422 0.0081 0.6851 −0.1874 −0.0539 0.2069 0.0595 0.0194 0.6687
0.0786*** 0.0033 0.1024*** 3.0598 0.0693* 1.8937 0.1717*** 4.3411 0.3747 0.0556 0.0299 0.0044 0.4046*** 3.4520
0.2800 0.8485 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.0383 0.8976 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.1924 0.6877 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.0110 0.2092 – – – – – – – – – – – –
−0.0051 0.8319 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0312* 0.0673 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.1892*** 0.0004 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0078 0.8371 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0022 0.5815 – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0436*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
R-squared 0.9813 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0032 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
Log-likelihood 477.3558 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.7127 – – – – – – – – – – – – –

Wald test 31.4316*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –


Wald test for dynamic spa-
168.9519*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
tial lag model
Wald test for dynamic spa-
216.4791*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
tial error model

Notes: Country fixed effects are included. *Significant at 10%; **significant at 5%; ***significant at 1%.

25
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...
Table 8. Results of the dynamic SDM, with as the dependent variable, MLIC data and .

26
Short-term effects Long-term effects
Coefficients
Direct Indirect (Spillover) Total Direct Indirect (Spillover) Total
Determinants
Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value Estimate -value
−0.2361*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.3877*** 0.0001 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.0525** 0.0176 – – – – – – – – – – – –

−4.6003** 0.0199 −5.0986** −2.0830 2.7339 0.5903 −2.3647 −0.5797 −23.7207 −0.0782 20.0683 0.0678 −3.6524 −0.3733

0.6824*** 0.0060 0.6701** 2.2449 0.0844 0.1528 0.7546 1.4837 2.3801 0.0876 −1.3378 −0.0507 1.0422 0.9913

−0.6341* 0.0614 −0.8276** −2.0686 1.0787* 1.6718 0.2512 0.4886 −4.0925 −0.0761 4.3181 0.0821 0.2256 0.1557

0.0481*** 0.0000 0.0425*** 3.4895 0.0337* 1.7087 0.0761*** 5.2314 0.0546 0.0526 0.0467 0.0457 0.1014*** 3.6743

−0.0663 0.3029 0.0130 0.1435 −0.4533*** −2.8433 −0.4403*** −2.9714 0.8404 0.0488 −1.3967 −0.0825 −0.5562 −1.4165

0.0481 0.2905 0.0403 0.5735 0.0311 0.3719 0.0714 1.4745 0.0027 0.0007 0.0869 0.0232 0.0896 0.6776
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

−0.1571 0.2334 −0.2051 −1.0759 0.2729 1.1148 0.0677 0.4912 −0.9530 −0.0562 1.0304 0.0615 0.0774 0.2591

−0.0153 0.1685 −0.0261 −1.4269 0.062** 2.2517 0.0365 1.6179 −0.1259 −0.0623 0.1720 0.0862 0.0461 1.0571

−0.0238 0.1606 −0.0322 −1.1099 0.0456 0.9921 0.0134 0.4057 −0.1197 −0.0666 0.1368 0.0770 0.0171 0.3361

−0.0362 0.1122 −0.0456 −1.5115 0.0458 1.0740 0.0003 0.0085 −0.1681 −0.0630 0.1673 0.0635 −0.0008 −0.0145

−0.4612 0.8384 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.1800 0.2074 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.0957 0.3361 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.0191*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –

−0.1190*** 0.0002 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.0175 0.1091 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.0255 0.3598 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.0106* 0.0927 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.0046 0.3809 – – – – – – – – – – – –

0.0014 0.8725 – – – – – – – – – – – –
R-squared 0.9901 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.0046 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
Log-likelihood 407.9594 – – – – – – – – – – – – –
0.2041 – – – – – – – – – – – – –

Wald test 117.3938*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –


Wald test for dynamic
92.3960*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
spatial lag model
Wald test for dynamic
102.9814*** 0.0000 – – – – – – – – – – – –
spatial error model

Notes: Country fixed effects are included. *Significant at 10%; **significant at 5%; ***significant at 1%.
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...

expenditure on research and development in the own a better understanding of the potential relationship between
country, but also, to a lesser extent, with that in neighbouring entrepreneurship and income inequality. Using panel data
countries. Alternatively, a one standard deviation increase from 33 HIC and 39 MLIC for 2004−2014, we estimated
in both GDP per capita and gross domestic expenditure DSPD models of entrepreneurial activity in these two sets
on research and development variables in a given country of countries. In addition, we systematically searched for the
leads to, respectively, and standard deviation most suitable DSPD model as well as the best spatial weights
increase in the perceived levels of entrepreneurial activity in matrix. The empirical evidence in favour of the dynamic SDM
neighbouring countries. However, the interaction between model is based on our application of a Bayesian comparison
economic development and income inequality shows approach (LeSage, 2014, 2015) to four potential spatial
significant negative spillover effect. According to this result, models (SAR, SEM, SDM and SDEM). The dynamic SDM
the entrepreneurial activity rate decreases not only with the produces global spillover effects, that is, countries adopt their
level of the interaction variable in the own country but also entrepreneurial activity to those of other countries, even if they
with that in neighbouring countries. are not neighbours – so the spatial weight matrix is likely to be
In line with the Bayesian results in Tables 5–8, the dynamic sparse. Furthermore, our empirical results demonstrate that
SDM is an improvement over the dynamic SAR model: the entrepreneurship is a spatial and persistent phenomenon.
hypothesis about whether it can be simplified to the dynamic We provide evidence of significant spatial dependence and
SAR model can be rejected. This implies that the empirical intertemporal dynamics of entrepreneurial activity in both the
evidence in favour of the seven significant country spillover HIC and MLIC. The evidence is based on DSPD estimators
effects in the short-term hinges strongly on the previous that take into account unobserved spatial unit and fixed effects
finding that the spatial interaction among countries is not and control for relevant covariates of the focal countries and
driven only by the endogenous spatial lag. In addition, the their neighbours.
hypothesis about whether the dynamic SDM can be reduced Using a DSPD modelling structure, our empirical work
to the dynamic SEM can be rejected. Then, the dynamic SDM provides strong support for the existence of an inverted
is the best one and thus should be adopted. U-shaped relationship between entrepreneurship and income
inequality for only MLIC. In addition, we showed the existence of
an inverted U-shaped relationship between entrepreneurship
5. Conclusion
and economic development for MLIC. However, a significant
non-linear U-shaped relationship is found between new
This article outlines a dynamic spatial panel approach that business density and GDP per capita for HIC. We also
seeks to problematise and probe the ways in which income provided evidence for the existence of a significant negative
inequality may contribute to entrepreneurship. Previous association between the interaction variable and new business
empirical studies have examined the determinants of entry density for MLIC. Nevertheless, the interaction variable
entrepreneurship in the context of cross-section and panel positively influences the new business entry density for HIC.
data. However, exploring spatial dependence as well as spatial These findings further support and validate our contention
spillovers of entrepreneurship from a panel data standpoint is that greater levels of income inequality are favourable for
seldom addressed in previous works. Ragoubi and El Harbi entrepreneurship. The proposed explanations for the positive
(2018) were the first to use static spatial panel data models in linkage between entrepreneurship and income inequality
order to analyse the relationship between entrepreneurship posit a direct effect of inequality on entrepreneurship. At the
and income inequality. Unlike Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018), broadest level, this article’s results validate those found by
this article investigates the dynamic linkage between Lippmann et al. (2005) and Ragoubi and El Harbi (2018).
entrepreneurship and income inequality by considering both The findings indicate that globalisation has significant
spatial dependence and serial dynamics of entrepreneurial positive impacts on the entrepreneurial activity for both HIC and
activity as indicators of knowledge spillovers over space MLIC. Furthermore, we found that both the competitiveness
and time. To the best of our knowledge, the present work and governance variables have significant positive impacts
is also the first to use DSPD models to account for spatial on the entrepreneurial activity for HIC. Furthermore, we found
dependence and spatial spillovers in entrepreneurship and to empirical evidence in favour of significant positive as well
provide a clear picture of the dynamics that drive the linkage as and negative short-run direct effects of income inequality
between entrepreneurship and income inequality. on the entrepreneurial activity for MLIC. Finally, the results
We empirically investigated the main determinants of indicate the existence of significant negative short-run
entrepreneurship while accounting for spatial externalities in spillover effects of income inequality on the entrepreneurial
a dynamic context. More specifically, we have sought to gain activity for MLIC.

27
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

Our empirical findings suggest that policymakers would be Atkinson, A.B. (2003). Income inequality in OECD countries: Data
well advised to consider the influence of income inequality if and explanations. CESifo Economic Studies, 49(4), 479−513.
they wish to influence job growth via entrepreneurship. Some Audretsch, D.B. (2009). The entrepreneurial society.Journal of Tech-
minimum level of income inequality is likely necessary to help nology Transfer, 34(3), 245−254.
breed entrepreneurship. If the results of this study are causal, they Audretsch, D.B., & Keilbach, M. (2004). Entrepreneurship capital and
should raise a flag for policymakers. Income inequality is currently economic performance.Regional Studies, 38(8), 949−959.
on an upward trend, and as a result, our work would suggest Autor, D.H. (2014). Skills, education, and the rise of earnings inequal-
more entrepreneurship from MLIC and less entrepreneurship ity among the” other 99%”.Science, 344(6186), 843-851.
from HIC. Policymakers interested in spurring job growth through Baltagi, B.H. (2005). Econometric analysis of panel data. Chichester:
entrepreneurship might consider policies that directly address Wiley.
the income inequality trend or that could increase opportunity Baltagi, B.H., Fingleton, B., & Pirotte, A. (2019). A time-space dynam-
entrepreneurship and decrease necessity entrepreneurship. ic panel data model with spatial moving average errors. Regional
Such policies might include increasing employment flexibility via Science and Urban Economics, 76, 13−31.
a workforce that is more highly educated and skilled, developing Bapuji, H. (2015). Individuals, interactions and institutions: How eco-
a strong working class, structuring welfare programmes to nomic inequality affects organizations. Human Relations, 68(7),
develop entrepreneurs, providing a social safety net that reduces 1059−1083.
the risk of failure for potential entrepreneurs, and constructing the Bartelsman, E., Haltiwanger, J., & Scarpetta, S. (2004). Microeco-
tax code to encourage opportunity entrepreneurship. nomic evidence of creative destruction in industrial and developing
countries.The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3464.
Blanchflower, D.G. (2000). Self-employment in OECD countries.La-
References
bor Economics, 7(5), 471−505.
Carnahan, S., Agarwal, R., & Campbell, B.A. (2012). Heterogeneity
Abate, G.D. (2016). On the link between volatility and growth: A spatial in turnover: The effect of relative compensation dispersion of firms
econometrics approach. Spatial Economic Analysis, 11(1), 27−45. on the mobility andentrepreneurship of extreme performers. Stra-
Acs, Z. J., & Amoros, J.E. (2008). Entrepreneurship and competitive- tegic Management Journal, 33(12), 1411−1430.
ness dynamics in Latin America.Small Business Economics, 31 Carree, M., Van Stel, A., Thurik, R., & Wennekers, S. (2002). Eco-
(3), 305−322. nomic development and business ownership: An analysis using
Acs, Z.J., Braunerhjelm, P., Audretsch, D.B., & Carlsson, B. (2009). data of 23 OECD countries in the period 1976–1996. SmallBusi-
The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship.Small Busi- ness Economics, 19(3), 271−290.
ness Economics, 32(1), 15−30. Carree, M., Van Stel, A., Thurik, R., & Wennekers, S. (2007). The
Amoros, J.E., & Cristi, O. (2008). Longitudinal analysis of entrepre- relationship between economic development and business own-
neurship and competitiveness dynamics in Latin America.Interna- ership revisited. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development:An
tional Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 4(4), 381−399. International Journal, 19 (3), 281−291.
Amoros, J.E., Fernandez, C., & Tapia, J. (2012). Quantifying the re- Carree, M.A., & Thurik, R. (2003). The impact of entrepreneurship on
lationship between entrepreneurship and competitiveness devel- economic growth. In Z. A. Acs & D.B. Audretsch (Eds.), Handbook
opment stages in Latin America. International Entrepreneurship of entrepreneurship research (pp. 437−471). Boston; MA: Kluwer.
andManagement Journal, 8(3), 249−270. Clark, W.C. (2000). Environmental globalization. In J.S. Nye & J. D.
Anokhin, S., & Wincent, J. (2012). Start-up rates and innovation: A Donahue (Eds.), Governance in a globalizing world (pp.86−108).
cross-country examination. Journal of International Business Stud- Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
ies, 43, 41-60. Cobb, J.A., & Lin, K.H. (2017). Growing apart: The changing firm-size
Anselin, L. (2001). Spatial econometrics. In Badi H. Baltagi (Ed.), A wage premium and its inequality consequences. Organization Sci-
companion to theoretical econometrics (pp. 310−330). Malden, ence, 28(3), 429−446.
MA: Blackwell Publishers. Cowell, F., & Fiorio, C. (2011). Inequality decompositions - A reconcili-
Anselin, L., Le Gallo, J., & Jayet, H. (2008). Spatial panel economet- ation. Journal of Economic Inequality, 9(4), 509−528.
rics. InL. Matyas & P. Sevestre (Eds.),The econometrics of panel Creedy, J., & Hérault, N. (2011). Decomposing inequality and social
data, fundamentals and recent developments in theory and prac- welfare changes: The use of alternative welfare metrics. Mel-
tice (pp. 901−969). Dordrecht: Kluwer. bourne Institute WorkingPaper Series No. 8/11.
Armington, C., & Acs, Z. (2002). The determinants of regional varia- da Silva, D.F.C., Elhorst, J.P., & da MotaSilveiraNeto, R. (2017). Ur-
tion in new firm formation.Regional Studies, 36(1), 33−45. ban and rural population growth in a spatial panel of municipalities.
Åstebro, T., Chen, J., & Thompson, P. (2011). Stars and misfits: Self- Regional Studies, 51(6), 894−908.
employment and labor market frictions. Management Science, Davis, G.F. (2013). After the corporation.Politics & Society, 41(2),
57(11), 1999−2017. 283−308.

28
H. Ragoubi et al.: Entrepreneurship and income inequality...

Debarsy, N., Ertur, C., & LeSage, J.P. (2012). Interpreting dynamic Florez, A.Q. (2011). Alliances as contiguity in spatial models of mili-
space-time panel data models. Statistical Methodology, 9(1−2), tary expenditures. Conflict Management and Peace Science,
158−171. 28(4), 402−418.
Deeds, D.L. (2001). The role of R&D intensity, technical develop- Fossen, F.M., & Martin, T. (2018). Entrepreneurial dynamics over
ment and absorptive capacity in creating entrepreneurial wealth space and time.Regional Science and Urban Economics, 70,
in high technology start-ups. Journal of Engineering andTechnol- 204−214.
ogy Management, 18(1), 29−47. Goldsmith, B.E. (2007). Arms racing in ‘space’: Spatial modelling of
Devereux, M. P., Lockwood, B., & Redoano, M. (2007). Horizontal military spending around the world. Australian Journal of Political
and vertical indirect tax competition: Theory and some evidence Science, 42(3), 419−440.
from the USA. Journal of Public Economics, 91(3−4), 451−479. Goldthorpe, J.H. (2010). Analysing social inequality: A critique of two
Donfouet, H.P.P., Jeanty, P.W., & Malin, E. (2016). Analysing spatial recent contributions from economics and epidemiology. European
spillovers in corruption: A dynamic spatial panel data approach. Sociological Review, 26(6), 731-744.
Papers in Regional Science, 97(S1), S63-S78. Halvarsson, D., Korpi, M., & Wennberg, K. (2018).Entrepreneurship
Doran, J., & Fingleton, B. (2018). US metropolitan area resilience: and income inequality. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organi-
Insights from dynamic spatial panel estimation. Environment and zation, 145, 275−293.
Planning A, 50(1), 111−132. Hamilton, B.H. (2000). Does entrepreneurship pay? An empirical
Dreher, A. (2006). Does globalization affect growth? Evidence analysis of the returns of self-employment.Journal of Political
from a new index of globalization. Applied Economics, 38(10), Economy, 108(3), 604-631.
1091−1110. Herrera-Echeverri, H., Haar, J., & Estevez-Breton, J.B. (2014).For-
Dreher, A., Gaston, N., & Martens, P. (2008). Measuring globaliza- eign direct investment, institutional quality, economic freedom and
tion-gauging its consequence. New York, NY: Springer. entrepreneurship in emerging markets. Journal of BusinessRe-
Eckel, S., Löffler, G., Maurer, A., & Schmidt, V. (2011). Measuring search, 67(9), 1921−1932.
the effects of geographical distance on stock market correlation. Jaumotte, F., Lall, S., & Papageorgiou, C. (2013). Rising income in-
Journal of Empirical Finance, 18(2), 237−247. equality: Technology, or trade and financial globalization. IMF Eco-
Elhorst, J.P. (2005). Unconditional maximum likelihood estimation nomic Review, 61, 271−309.
of linear and log linear dynamic models for spatial panels. Geo- Kacperczyk, A.J., & Balachandran, C. (2017). Vertical and horizontal
graphical Analysis, 37(1), 85−106. comparisons and mobility outcomes: Evidence from the Swedish
Elhorst, J.P. (2010). Dynamic panels with endogenous interaction ef- micro-data.MIT Sloan Research Paper No. 5169−16.
fects when T is small. Regional Science and Urban Economics, Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2009). Governance matters
40(5), 272−282. VIII: Aggregate and individual governance indicators, 1996−2008.
Elhorst, J.P. (2012). Dynamic spatial panels: Models, methods and World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4978.
inferences. Journal of Geographical Systems, 14, 5−28. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2010). The worldwide
Elhorst, J.P. (2014a). Spatial econometrics: From cross-sectional governance indicators: Methodology and analytical issues. World
data to spatial panels. Heidelberg: Springer. Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 5430.
Elhorst, J.P. (2014b). Matlab software for spatial panels.International Keohane, R.O., & Nye, Jr, J.S. (2000). Globalization: What’s new?
Regional Science Review, 37, 389−405. What’s not? (And so what?). Foreign Policy, 118, 104−119.
Elhorst, J.P., Zandberg, E., & de Haan, J. (2013). The impact of inter- Klapper, L., Laeven, L., & Rajan, R. (2006). Entry regulation as a bar-
action effects among neighboring countries on financial liberaliza- rier to entrepreneurship. Journal of Financial Economics, 82(3),
tion and reform: A dynamic spatial panel data approach. Spatial 591-629.
Economic Analysis, 8(3), 293−313. Klapper, L., & Love, I. (2010). The impact of the financial crisis on
Fields, G.S., & Yoo, G. (2000). Falling labour income inequality in Ko- new firm registration.World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
rea’s economic growth: Patterns and underlying causes. Review 5444.
of Income and Wealth, 46(2),139−159. Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic growth and income inequality. Ameri-
Fingleton, B. (2017). Dynamic spatial econometrics models: A critical can Economic Review, 45(1), 1−28.
review. ScienzeRegionali, 16(1), 7−30. Kuznets, S. (1963). Quantitative aspects of the economic growth of
Fingleton, B. (2019). Exploring Brexit with dynamic spatial panel nations.Economic Development and Cultural Change, 11(2), 1-80.
models: Some possible outcomes for employment across the EU Lee, L.F., & Yu, J. (2010a). A spatial dynamic panel data model with
regions. The Annals of Regional Science, 63, 1−37. both time and individual fixed effects. Econometric Theory, 26(2),
Fingleton, B., & Szumilo, N. (2019). Simulating the impact of trans- 564−597.
port infrastructure investment on wages: A dynamic spatial panel Lee, L.F., & Yu, J. (2010b). Some recent developments in spatial pan-
model approach. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 75, el data models.Regional Science and Urban Economics, 40(5),
148−164. 255−271.

29
Tékhne – Review of Applied Management Studies

Lee, L.F., & Yu, J. (2014). Efficient GMM estimation of spatial dynamic Skogstad, K. (2016). Defence budgets in the post-Cold War era: A
panel data models with fixed effects. Journal of Econometrics, spatial econometric approach. Defence and Peace Economics,
180(2), 174−197. 27(3), 323−352.
LeSage, J.P. (2014). Spatial econometric panel data model specifica- Sørensen, J.B., & Sharkey, A.J. (2014). Entrepreneurship as a mobil-
tion: A Bayesian approach. Spatial Statistics, 9, 122−145. ity process.American Sociological Review, 79(2), 328−349.
LeSage, J.P. (2015). Software for Bayesian cross-section and pan- Steinmetz, G., & Wright, E.O. (1989). The fall and rise of the petty
el spatial model comparison. Journal of Geographical Systems, bourgeoisie: Changing patterns of self-employment in the postwar
17(4), 297−310. United States. American Journal of Sociology, 94(5), 973−1018.
LeSage, J.P., & Pace, R.K. (2009). Introduction to spatial economet- Stiglitz, J.E. (2012). The price of inequality: How today’s divided so-
rics. Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press Taylor & Francis Group. ciety endangers our future. New York, NY: W. W. Norton & Com-
Lewellyn, K.B. (2018). Income inequality, entrepreneurial activity, and pany.
national business systems: A configurational analysis. Business & Van Praag, C.M., & Versloot, P.H. (2007). What is the value of en-
Society, 5 7(6), 1114−1149. trepreneurship? A review of recent research.Small Business Eco-
Lippmann, S., Davis, A., & Aldrich, H.E. (2005).Entrepreneurship and nomics, 29(4), 351−382.
inequality. Research in the Sociology of Work, 15, 3−31. Van Stel, A.J., Carree, M.A., & Thurik, A.R. (2005). The effect of en-
Longley, P.A., Goodchild, M.F., Maguire, D.J., & Rhind, D.W. trepreneurial activity on national economic growth.Small Business
(2001). Geographic information science and systems.Hoboken, Economics, 24(3), 311−321.
NJ: Wiley. Van Stel, A.J., Storey, D., & Thurik, R. (2007). The effect of business
McArthur, J., & Sachs, J. (2002). The Growth Competitiveness Index: regulations on nascent and young business entrepreneurship.
Measuring Technological Advancement and the Stages of Devel- Small Business Economics, 28, 171−186.
opment. In M. Porter, J. Sachs, P. K. Cornelius, J. McArthur, & K. Verheul, I. (2009). Regional opportunities and policy initiatives for
Schwab (Eds.), The global competitiveness report 2001−2002 (pp. new venture creation. International Small Business Journal,27(5),
28–51). New York, NY: Oxford University Press. 608-625.
McMullen, J., Bagby, D., &Palich, L. (2008). Economic freedom and Wennekers, S., Van Stel, A.J., Carree, M., & Thurik, R. (2010). The re-
the motivation to engage in entrepreneurial action. Entrepreneur- lationship between entrepreneurship and economic development:
ship: Theory and Practice, 32(5), 875-895. Is it u-shaped? Foundations and Trends inEntrepreneurship, 6(3),
Packard, M.D., & Bylund, P.L. (2018). On the relationship between 167−237.
inequality and entrepreneurship.Strategic Entrepreneurship Jour- Wennekers, S., Van Stel, A.J., Thurik, A.R., & Reynolds, P. (2005).
nal, 12(1), 3−22. Nascent entrepreneurship and the level of economic develop-
Parent, O., & LeSage, J.P. (2012). Spatial dynamic panel data mod- ment. Small Business Economics, 24(3), 293−309.
els with random effects. Regional Science and Urban Economics Wright, M., & Zahra, S. (2011). The other side of paradise: Examin-
42(4), 727-738. ing the dark side of entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship Research
Pathak, S., & Muralidharan, E. (2018). Economic inequality and social Journal, 1(3), 1-7.
entrepreneurship.Business & Society, 57(6), 1150−1190. Xavier-Oliveira, E., Laplume, A.O., & Pathak, S. (2015). What moti-
Pijnenburg, K., & Kholodilin, K.A. (2014). Do regions with entrepre- vates entrepreneurial entry under economic inequality? The role of
neurial neighbours perform better? A spatial econometric ap- human and financial capital.Human Relations, 68(7), 1183−1207.
proach for German regions.Regional Studies, 48, 866-882. Yesilyurt, M.E., & Elhorst, J.P. (2017). Impacts of neighboring coun-
Ragoubi, H., & El Harbi, S. (2018). Entrepreneurship and income in- tries on military expenditures: A dynamic spatial panel approach.
equality: A spatial panel data analysis. International Review of Ap- Journal of Peace Research, 54(6), 777-790.
plied Economics, 32(3), 374−422. Yu, J., de Jong, R., & Lee, L.F. (2008). Quasi-maximum likelihood
Reynolds, P.D., Hay, M., & Bygrave, W.D. (2002).Global entrepre- estimators for spatial dynamic panel data with fixed effects when
neurship monitor: 2002 global executive report. Kansas City, MO: both n and T are large. Journal of Econometrics, 146(1), 118−134.
Kauffman Foundation. Yu, J., de Jong, R., & Lee, L.F. (2012). Estimation for spatial dynamic
Sarkar, S., Rufin, C., & Haughton, J. (2018). Inequality and entrepre- panel data with fixed effects: The case of spatial cointegration.
neurial thresholds.Journal of Business Venturing, 33(3), 278−295. Journal of Econometrics, 67(1), 16−37.

30

You might also like