Elinor Ostrom, Et Al. (1999)

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 5

H

REVIEW: S U S T A I N A B I L I T Y

Revisiting the Commons:


Local Lessons, Global Challenges
Elinor Ostrom,' Joanna Burger,' Christopher B. Field." Richard B. N ~ r g a a r dDavid
,~ PolicanskyS

truction of the resources on which they 1 scales. These resources continue to be impor-
bout such problems and the conditions 1 tant as sources of sustained biodiversity and
mon-pool resources. Some of the most human well-being. Some of the most difficult
of largescale resources that depend on future problems, however, will involve re-
r in international basins or large marine , sources that are difficult to manage at the
cosystems. lmtituti~laldiversity may be as important as biologicaldiversity
/ scale of a village, a large watershei or even
a single country. Some of these resources-
j
for example, fresh water in an international
basin or large marine ecosystems-become
'hirty years have passed since Garrett a reassessment of the generality of the theory effectively depletable only in an international
Hardin's influential article "The Trag- that has grown out of Hardin's original paper. context (10). Management of these resources
edy of the Commons" (I). At first, Here, we describe the advances in under- depends on the cooperation of appropriate
many people agreed with Hardin's metaphor standing and managing commons problems international institutions and national, region-
that the users of a commons are caught in an that have been made since 1968. We also al, and local institutions. Resources that are
inevitable process that leads to the destruc- describe research challenges, especially those intrinsically difficult to measure or that re-
tion of the very resource on which they de- related to expanding our understanding of quire measurement with advanced technolo-
pend. The "rational" user of a commons, global commons problems. gy, such as stocks of ocean fishes or petro-
Hardin argued, makes demands on a resource An important lesson from the empirical leum reserves, are difficult to manage no
until the expected benefits of his or her ac- studies of sustainable resources is that more matter what the scale of the resource. Others,
tions equal the expected costs. Because each solutions exist than Hardin proposed. Both for example global climate, are largely self-
user ignores costs imposed on others, individ- government ownership and privatization are healing in response to a broad range of hu-
ual decisions cumulate to a tragic overuse and themselves subject to failure in some instanc- man actions, until these actions exceed some
the potential destruction of an open-access es. For example, Sneath shows great differ- threshold ( I I).
commons. Hardin's proposed solution was ences in grassland degradation under a tradi- Although the number and importance of
"either socialism or the privatism of free tional, self-organized group-property regime commons problems at local or regional scales
enterprise" (2). versus central government management. A will not decrease, the need for effective ap-
The starkness of Hardin's original state- satellite image of northern China, Mongolia, proaches to commons problems that are glob-
ment has been used by many scholars and and southern Siberia (8) shows marked deg- al in scale will certainly increase. Here, we
policy-makers to rationalize central govern- radation in the Russian part of the image, examine this need in the context of an anal-
ment control of all common-pool resources whereas the Mongolian half of the image ysis of the nature of common-pool resources
(3) and to paint a disempowering, pessimistic shows much less degradation. In this in- and the history of successful and unsuccess-
vision of the human prospect (4). Users are stance, Mongolia has allowed pastoralists to ful institutions for ensuring fair access and
pictured as trapped in a situation they cannot continue their traditional group-property in- sustained availability to them. Some experi-
change. Thus, it is argued that solutions must stitutions, which involve large-scale move- ence from smaller systems transfers directly
be imposed on users by external authorities. ments between seasonal pastures, while both to global systems, but global commons intro-
Although tragedies have undoubtedly oc- Russia and China have imposed state-owned duce a range of new issues, due largely to
curred, it is also obvious that for thousands of agricultural collectives that involve perma- extreme size and complexity (12).
years people have self-organized to manage nent settlements. More recently, the Chinese
common-pool resources, and users often do solution has involved privatization by divid- The Nature of Common-Pool
devise long-term, sustainable institutions for ing the "pasture land into individual alloca- Resources
governing these resources (5-7). It is time for tions for each herding household" (8). About To better understand common-pool resource
three-quarters of the pasture land in the Rus- problems, we must separate concepts related
sian section of this ecological zone has been to resource systems and those concerning
'Center for the Study of Institutions, Population, and degraded and more than one-third of the Chi- property rights. We use the term common-
EnvironmentalChange and Workshop in PoliticalThe-
ory and Policy Analysis, Indiana University, Blooming-
nese section has been degraded, while only pool resources (CPRs) to refer to resource
ton, IN 47408, USA ZEnvironmentaland Occupation- one-tenth of the Mongolian section has suf- systems regardless of the property rights in-
al Health Sciences Institute, Rutgers University, 170 fered equivalent loss (8, 9). Here, socialism volved. CPRs include natural and human-
Frelinghuysen Road, Piscataway, NJ 08854, USA and privatization are both associated with constructed resources in which (i) exclusion
3Carnegie Institution of Washington, Stanford, CA
94305. USA. 4Energy and Resources Croup, University
more degradation than resulted from a tradi- of beneficiaries through physical and institu-
of California. Berkeley, CA 94720, USA. 5National tional group-property regime. tional means is especially costly, and (ii)
Research Council, Washington, DC 20418, USA. Most of the theory and practice of suc- exploitation by one user reduces resource
*To whom correspondence should be addressed. E- cessful management involves resources that availability for others (13). These two char-
mail: ostrorn@indiana.edu are effectively managed by small to relatively acteristics-difficulty of exclusion and sub-

9 APRIL 1999 VOL 284 SCIENCE www.sciencernag.org


tractability-create potential CPR dilemmas decades. But the enoimous competition to interested perspective in many settings, but
in which people following their ow11 short- catch a large share of the resource before can also use reciprocity to overcome social
telm interests produce outcomes that are not others did resulted in economic waste. danger dilemmas (22). Users of a CPR include (i)
in anyone's long-term interest. LVhen re- to the fishers. and reduced quality of fish to those who always behave in a narrow, self-
source users interact without the benefit of consumers. Limiting access alone can fail if interested way and never cooperate in dilem-
effective mles limiting access and defining the resource users compete for shares; and the ma situations (fiee-riders); (ii) those \vho are
rights and duties, substantial free-riding in resource can becoille depleted unless incen- unwilling to cooperate with others unless as-
t ~ v ofol-~nsis likely: oveiuse ~vithoutconcern rives or regulations prevent overexploitatioil sured that they will not be exploited by free-
for the negative effects on others. and a lack (17> 18). riders: (iii) those \\rho are willing to initiate
of contributed resources for maintaining and Four broad types of property rights have reciprocal cooperation in the hopes that oth-
improving the CPR itself. evolved or are designed in relation to CPRs ers will return their tmst; and (iv) perhaps a
CPRs have traditionally included terrestri- (Table 1). When valuable CPRs are left to an few genuine altruists who always try to
al and marine ecosystems that are simulta- open-access regime, degradation and poten- achieve higher returns for a group.
neously vie~vedas depletable and renewable. tial destruction are the result. The propositioil Whether nornls to cope with CPR dilem-
Characteristic of many resources is that use that resource users cannot themselves change inas evolve without extensive: self-conscious
by one reduces the quantity or quality avail- from no property rights (open access) to design depends on the relative proportion of
able to others, and that use by others adds group or individual property. however. can be these behavioral types in a particular setting.
negative attributes to a resource. CPRs in- strongly rejected on the basis of evidence: Reciprocal cooperation can be established,
clude earth-system components (such as Resource users tlrougl~the ages have done sustain itself, and even grow if the proportion
groundwater basins or the atmosphere) as just that (3-7, 13>15, 19). Both group-prop- of those who always act in a narrow: self-
well as products of civilization (such as irri- ei-ty and individual-property regimes are used interested manner is initially not too high
gation systems or the World Wide Web). to manage resources that grant individuals (23). LVllen interactions enable those who use
Characteristics of CPRs affect the prob- varying rights to access and use of a resource. reciprocity to gain a reputation for tmstwor-
lems of devising governance regimes. These The primary difference between group prop- thiness, others will be ~villingto cooperate
attributes include the size and caiqing capac- erty and individual property is the ease with with them to overcome CPR dilemmas,
ity of the resource system, the measurability which individual owners can buy or sell a ~vhichleads to increased gains for themselves
of the resource. the temporal and spatial share of a resource. Government property and their offspring (24). Thus; groups of peo-
availability of resource flows, the amount of involves ownership by a national: regional. or ple who can identify one another are more
storage in the system. whether resources local public agency that can forbid or allow likely than groups of strangers to draw on
move (like water, wildlife, and most fish) or use by individuals. Empirical studies show trust; reciprocity, and reputation to develop
are stationary (like trees and medicinal that no single type of property regime works norms that limit use. In earlier times, this
plants), how fast resources regenerate. and efficiently, fairly, and sustainably in relation restricted the size of groups who relied pri-
how various harvesting technologies affect to all CPRs. CPR problerns continue to exist marily upon evolved and shared norms. Cit-
patterns of regeneration (14). It is relatively in many regulated settings (1 7). It is possible, izen-band radios: tracking devices. the In-
easv to estimate the number and size of trees however, to identify design principles associ- ternet. geographic information systems, and
in a forest and allocate their use accordingly. ated with robust institutions that have suc- other aspects of modern technology and the
-
but it is much more difficult to assess migra- cessfi~lly governed CPRs for generations ae\vs media no\\, enable large groups to
tory fish stocks and available irrigation water (19). monitor one another's behavior and coor-
in a system ~vithoutstorage capacity. Tech- dinate activities ill order to solve CPR
nology can help to inform decisions by im- The Evolution of Norms and Design of oroblems.
proving the identification and monitoring of Rules Evolved noin~s,ho~vever;are not always
resources. but it is not a substitute for deci- The prediction that resource users are led sufficient to prevent overexploitation. Partic-
sion-making. On the other hand, major tech- inevitably to destroy CPRs is based on a ipants or external authorities must deliberate-
nological advances in assessing groundwater model that assumes all individuals are selfish: ly devise (and then monitor and enforce)
storage capacity, supply; and associated pol- nonn-free. and maximizers of short-mn re- rules that limit ~ ~ 1 1can
0 use a CPR, specify
lution have allowed more effective manage- sults. This model explains \vhy market insti- how much and ~vhenthat use will be allowed,
ment of these resources (1.5). Specific re- tutions facilitate an efficient allocation of pri- create and finance formal monitoring ar-
source systems in particular locations ofien vate goods and seivices, and it is strongly rangements, and establish sanctions for non-
include several types of CPRs and public suppoited by empirical data from open; com- confoimance. Whether the users themselves
goods with different spatial and teinporal petitive markets in industrial societies (20). are able to overcome the higher level dilem-
scales. differing degrees of uncertainty, and However, predictions based on this model are mas they face in bearing the cost of design-
complex interactions among thein (16). not suppoited i11 field research or in labora- ing, testing, and modifying governance sys-
tory experiments in ~vhichindividuals face a tems depends on the benefits they perceive to
Institutions for Governing and public good or CPR problem and are able to result from a change as well as the expected
Managing Common-Pool Resources communicate, sanction one another: or make costs of negotiating, monitoring, and enforc-
Solving CPR problems involves two distinct ne\v rules (21). Humans adopt a narrow. self- ing these niles (2.5). Perceived benefits are
elements: restricting access and creating in-
centives (usually by assigning individual Table 1. Types of property-rights systems used t o regulate common-pool resources (7).
rights to; or shares of. the resource) for users
to invest in the resource instead of overex- Property rights Characteristics
ploiting it. Both changes are needed. For
example, access to the 1101th Pacific halibut Open access Absence of enforced property rights
Group property Resource rights held by a group of users who can exclude others
fishery \\,as not restricted before the recent
Individual property Resource rights held by individuals (or firms) who can exclude others
introduction of mdividual transferable quotas Government property Resource rights held by a government that can regulate or subsidize use
and catch limits protected the resource for

www.sciencemag.org SCIENCE VOL 284 9 APRIL 1999 279


greater when the resource reliably generates native sources of water, both government a burden on the use of surface water and
valuable products for the users. Users need ownership and the presence of modem head- created conflicts with homeowners, other
some autonomy to make and enforce their works have a negative impact on water de- boaters, fishermen, and naturalists. The rapid
own rules, and they must highly value the livered to the tail end of a system, hence a rise of PWCs has created a burden on the use
future sustainability of the resource. Per- negative impact on overall system productiv- of shorelines, contributed to a disproportion-
ceived costs are higher when the resource is ity (27). ate increase in accidents and injuries, and
large and complex, users lack a common Imposing strong limits on resource use caused disturbances to aquatic natural re-
understanding of resource dynamics, and raises the question of which community of sources (30). Traditional users of the water
users have substantially diverse interests users is initially defined as having use rights surface feel threatened by the invasion of
(26). and who is excluded from access to a CPR. their space by a new, faster, and louder boat
The farmer-managed irrigation systems of The very process of devising methods of that reduces the value of surface waters. In
Nepal are examples of well-managed CPRs exclusion has substantial distributional con- many other settings, when new users arrive
that rely on strong, locally crafted rules as sequences (29). In some instances, those who through migration, they do not share a similar
well as evolved norms (27). Because the rules have long exercised stewardship over a understanding of how a resource works and
and norms that make an irrigation system resource can be excluded. A substantial what rules and norms are shared by others.
operate well are not visible to external ob- distributional issue will occur, for example, Members of the initial community feel threat-
servers, efforts by well-meaning donors to as regulators identify who will receive ened and may fail to enforce their own self-
replace primitive, farmer-constructed sys- rights to emit carbon into the atmosphere. restraint, or they may even join the race to use
tems with newly constructed, government- Typically, such rights are assigned to those up the resource (31).
owned systems have reduced rather than who have exercised a consistent pattern of Given the substantial differences among
improved performance (28). Govemment- use over time. Thus, those who need to use CPRs, it is difficult to find effective rules that
owned systems are built with concrete and the resource later may be excluded en- both match the complex interactions and dy-
steel headworks, in contrast to the simple tirely or may have to pay a very large entry namics of a resource and are perceived by
mud, stone, and trees used by the farmers cost. users as legitimate, fair, and effective. At
(Fig. 1). However, the cropping intensity The counterpoint to exclusion is too rapid times, disagreements about resource assess-
achieved by farmer-managed systems is sig- inclusion of users. When any user group ment may be strategically used to propose
nificantly higher than on government systems grows rapidly, the resource can be stressed. policies that disproportionately benefit some
(Table 2). In a regression model of system For example, in the last 10 years the annual at a cost to others (4). In highly complex
performance, controlling for the size of the sales of personal watercraft (PWCs) have systems, finding optimal rules is extremely
system, the slope of the terrain, variation in risen in the United States from about, 50,000 challenging, if not impossible. But despite
farmer income, and the presence of alter- to more than 150,000 a year. This has placed such problems, many users have devised their

Fig. 1. The govem-


ment-owned Chiregad
irrigation system (right
panel) was construct-
ed in Nepal to replace
five farmer-owned irri-
gation systems whose
physical infrastructures
were similar to the Ka-
thar farmer-managed
irrigation system (left
panel). In planning the
Chiregad system, de-
signers focused entirely
on constructing modem
engineering works and
not on learning about
the rules and norms
that had been used in
the five earlier sys-
tems. Even though the
physical capital is mark-
edly better than that
possessed by the earli-
er systems, the Chir-
egad system has never
been able to provide
water consistently to
more than two of the
former villages. Agri-
cultural productivity is
Lower now than it was
under farmer manage-
ment (37). Not only do
the farmers invest
I,.
F +

heavilv in the mainte-


nanciof the farmer-owned system on the Left, they have devised effective rules related to access and the allocation of benefits and costs. They achieve higher
productivity than most government-owned systems with modem infrastructure. [Photographs by C. Shivakoti (left) and E. Ostrom (right)]

280 9 APRIL 1999 VOL 284 SCIENCE www.sciencemag.org


own rules and have sustained resources over solutions for a particular environment. In all ability (34). I\;ational policy also affects
long periods of time. Allowing parallel self- cases. individuals must overcome their ten- factors such as human migration rates. the
organized governance regimes to engage in dency to evaluate thelr own benefits and costs flow of capital, technology policy, and
extensive trial-and-eror lea~niiingdoes not re- more intensely than the total benefits and hence the range of conditions local institu-
duce the probability of error for any one costs for a group. Collective-choice rules af- tioils must address to work effectively. Fi-
resource. but greatly reduces the probability fect who is involved in deciding about future nally, local institutions are only rarely able
of disastrous emors for all resources in a mles and hon preferences u ill be aggregated. to cope with the rclnlifications of civil or
region. Thus, these mles affect the breadth of inter- international war.
ests represented and involved in inaking In-
Lessons from Local and Regional stitutiollal changes, and they affect decisions Challenges of Global Commons
Common-Pool Resources about which policy instruments are adopted The lessons fro111 local and regional CPRs are
The einpirical and theoretical research stim- (33). encouraging, yet 11urnanlQ no\+ faces nen
ulated over the past 30 years by Garrett Har- challenges to establish global institutions to
din's article has s h o w that tragedies of the The Broader Social Setting manage biodiversity, climate change, and
c o n ~ m oare i ~ real,
~ but not inevitable. Solving I\Tl;'hetl~er
people are able to self-organize and other ecosystem services ( 3 5 ) . These new
the dileinmas of sustainable use is neither manage CPRs also depends on the broader challenges will be especially difficult for at
easy nor error-free even for local resources. social setting within which they work. Iia- least the follon ing leasons
But a scholarly consensus is emerging re- tional govenunents can help or hinder local Scalit~g-zppvoblertz. Havlng larger num-
garding the conditions most likely to stimu- self-organization. "Higher" levels of govern- bers of participants in a CPR increases the
late successf~~l self-organized processes for illent call facilitate the asselnblv of users of a difficulty of organizing, agreeing on rules.
local and regional CPRs (6, 26. 32). At- CPR in organizatioilal meetings, provide in- and ellforcing rules. Global eilvironlneutal
tributes of resource systems and their users formation that helps identify the problem and resources now involve 6 billion inhabitants of
affect the benefits and costs that users per- possible solutions, and legitiinize and help the globe. Organization at national and local
ceive. For users to see major benefits, re- enforce agreements reached by local users. levels call help. but it can also get in the way
source conditions must not have deteriorated Xational goverllinents can at times. however. of finding solutions.
to such an extent that the resource is useless, hinder local self-organization by defending C~rIt~lr.01
di~:et.sih,chcrlletzge. Along with
nor can the resource be so little used that few rights that lead to overuse or inaintalning that ecollomic globalization. we are in a period of
advantages resillt from organizing. Benefits the state has ultiinate control over resources reculturalization. Increasing culh1ra.l diversi-
are easier to assess \vhen users have accurate without actually monitoring and enforcing fication offers increased hope that the diver-
lu~owledgeof external boundaries and inter- existing regulations. sity of ways in ~vhichpeople have organized
nal lllicroellvironlllents and have reliable and Participants are more likely to adopt ef- locally around CPRs will not be quickly lost.
valid indicators of resource conditions. I\Tl~en fective rules in macro-regimes that facilitate and that diverse new ways will continue to
the flow of resources is relatively predictable, their efforts than in regimes that igllore re- evolve at the local level. However, cultural
it is also easier to assess how diverse man- source probleins entirely or that presume that diversity can decrease the likelihood of find-
agelnent regilnes will affect long-term bene- central authorities must make all decisions. If ing shared interests and understandings. The
fits and costs. local authority is not formally recogilized by problem of cultural dilersity 1s exacerbated
Users who depend on a resource for a larger regimes. it is difficult for users to by 'Lnortl~-soutl~" conflicts stelnilling from
illajor portion of their livelihood, and nrho establish enforceable 1-tlles. On the other ecoilomic differences between industrialized
have solne autonomy to make their oivn ac- hand. if ixles are inlposed by outsiders nith- and less-industrialized countries.
cess and harvesting l-tlles. are inore likely out consulting local pal?iclpants. local users Cor~~plic~tiorzs of irzfei.lirz/ied CPRs. -41-
than others to perceive benefits from their may engage in a game of "cops and robbers" though the links between grassland and forest
own restrictions. but they need to share an with outside authorities. In rnany countries. inanageinent are complex. they are not so
image of how the resource system operates two centuries of colonization followed by complex as those betweell ulaintainiilg biodi-
and how their actions affect each other and state-mil developlnent policy that affected versity and anleliorating cliinate change. As
the resource. Further. users nlust be interested some CPRs has produced great resistance to we address global issues, we face greater
in the sustainability of the particular resource externally iinposed mstitutlons. interactions between global systems. Similar-
so that expected joint benefits will outweigh The broader economic setting also affects ly. with increased specialization. people have
c u i ~ e n costs.
t If users have some initial tlx~st the level and distribution of gains and costs of become mole ~nterdependent. Thus, u e all
in others to keep promises, lo~v-costmethods organizing the inailageinent of CPRs. Expec- share one anothei's common interests, but in
of illollitoring and sanctioning can be de- tations of rising resource prices encourage more complex n a y s than the users of a forest
vised. Previous organizational experience better management. whereas falling. unsta- or grassland, While n e have becoine more
and local leadership reduces the users' costs ble, or unceltain resource prices reduce the conlplexly ~nterrelated,u e have also becolne
of coming to agreement and finding effective incentive to organize and assure future avail- more "distant" from each other and our en-
vironinental problems. Froin our increasingly
specialized uilderstandiilgs and particular
Table 2. Relationship of governance structures and cropping intensities [(27),p. 1061. A crop intensity of points 011 the globe. it is difficult to compre-
100% means t h a t all land i n an irrigation system is put t o full use for one season or partial use over
multiple seasons, amounting t o t h e same coverage. Similarly, a crop intensity of 200% is full use of all
hend the sigilificallce of global CPRs and
land for t w o seasons; 300% is full use for three seasons. how we need to uork together to govern
-
these resources success full^^. -4nd elven these
Farmer-owned Covernment- complexities, finding fair solutions is even
Parameter systems owned systems F P more challenging.
( N = 97) ( N = 21) dccelel-utirlg tzrfes of cl~nt~ge. Previous
generations complained that change occurred
Head-end crop intensities 246% 208% 10.51 0.002
Tail-end crop intensities 237% 182% 20.33 0.004
faster and faster. and the acceleratioll contin-
ues. Population grolvth. economic develop-

www.sciencemag.org SCIENCE VOL 284 9 APRIL


SCIENCE'S C O M P A S S

ment, capital and labor mobility, and techno- Systems (Research Report 4, World Resources Insti- The Handbook of Experimental Economics (Prince-
tute, Washington, DC, 1986). ton Univ. Press, Princeton, NJ, 1995). The model is
logical change push us past environmental
4. D. Ludwig, R. Hilborn, C. Walters, Science 260, 17 also not as robust in explaining exchange behavior
thresholds before we know it. "Learning by (1993). in traditional societies where evolved norms still
doing" is increasingly difficult, as past les- 5. B. J. McCay and J. M. Acheson, The Question of the strongly affect behavior.
sons are less and less applicable to current Commons: The Culture and Ecology of Communal 22. L Cosmides and J. Tooby, in The Adapted Mind:
Resources (Univ. of Arizona Press, Tucson, AZ, 1987); Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Cul-
problems. F. Berkes, D. Feeny, B. J. McCay, J. M. Acheson, Nature ture, J. H. Barkow, L Cosmides, J. Tooby, Eds. (Oxford
Requirement of unanimous agreement as 340, 91 (1989); F. Berkes, Common Property Resourc- Univ. Press, New York, 1992), pp. 163-228; L Cos-
a collective-choice rule. The basic collective- es: Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Devel- mides and J. Tooby, Am. Econ. Rev. 84, 327 (1994); E.
opment (Belhaven, London, 1989); D. W. Bromley et Hoffman, K. McCabe, V. Smith, ibid. 86, 653 (1996).
choice rule for global resource management ai, Making the Commons Work: Theory, Practice, and 23. R. Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (Basic Books,
is voluntary assent to negotiated treaties (36). Policy (ICS Press, San Francisco, 1992); S. Y. Tang, New York, 1984); Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 80, 1095 (1986).
This allows some national governments to Institutions and Collective Action: Self-Governance in 24. M. A. Nowak and K. Sigmund, Nature 355, 250
Irrigation (ICS Press, San Francisco, 1992); E. Pinker- (1992); D. M. Kreps, P. Milgrom, J. Roberts, R. Wilson,
hold out for special privileges before they
ton, Ed., Co-operative Management of Local Fisheries: J. Econ. Theory 27, 245 (1982).
join others in order to achieve regulation, New Directions for Improved Management and Com- 25. H. Demsetz, Am. Econ. Rev. 62, 347 (1967); D. North,
thus strongly affecting the kinds of resource munity Development (Univ. of British Columbia Press, ibid. 84, 359 (1994); C. M. Rose, Property &• Persua-
management policies that can be adopted at Vancouver, Canada, 1989); C. Hess, Common-Pool sion: Essays on the History, Theory, and Rhetoric of
Resources and Collective Action: A Bibliography, Vol. Ownership (Westview, Boulder, CO, 1994); J. E. Krier,
this.-level. 3, and Forest Resources and Institutions: A Bibliogra- Harvard J. Law Pub. Policy 15, 325 (1992); F. Mich-
We have only one globe with which to phy (Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analy- elman, in Liberty, Property, and the Future of Consti-
experiment. Historically, people could mi- sis, Indiana Univ., Bloomington, IN, 1996) (www. tutional Development, E. F. Paul and H. Dickman, Eds.
indiana.edu/~workshop/wsl/wsl.html). (State Univ. of New York Press, Albany, NY, 1990),
grate to other resources if they made a major 6. R. Wade, Village Republics: Economic Conditions for pp. 127-171; V. Ostrom, Brigham Young Univ. Law
error in managing a local CPR. Today, we Collective Action in South India (ICS Press, San Fran- Rev. 3, 857 (1990).
have less leeway for mistakes at the local cisco, 1994). 26. E. Ostrom, in The Commons Revisited: An Americas
7. D. Feeny, F. Berkes, B. J. McCay, J. M. Acheson, Hum. Perspective, J. Burger, R. B. Norgaard, E. Ostrom, D.
level, while at the global level there is no Ecol. 18, 1 (1990). Policansky, B. Goldstein, Eds. (Island, Washington, DC,
place to move. 8. D. Sneath, Science 2 8 1 , 1147 (1998). in press).
These new challenges clearly erode the 9. C. Humphrey and D. Sneath, Eds., Culture and Envi- 27. W. F. Lam, Governing Irrigation Systems in Nepal:
ronment in Inner Asia (White Horse Press, Cambridge,
confidence with which we can build from 1996), vol. 1.
Institutions, Infrastructure, and Collective Action (ICS
Press, Oakland, CA, 1998).
past and current examples of successful man- 10. R. Costanza et ai, Science 2 8 1 , 198 (1998). 28. World Dev. 24, 1301 (1996).
agement to tackle the CPR problems of the 11. W. S. Broecker, ibid. 278, 1582 (1997).
29. G. D. LibecapJ. Instl. Theor. Econ. 145, 6 (1989).
12. M. McGinnis and E. Ostrom, in The International
future. Still, the lessons from successful ex- 30. J. Burger, Condor 100, 528 (1998); in {26); L White-
Political Economy and International Institutions, O. R.
amples of CPR management provide start- man, National Parks 71, 22 (1997).
Young, Ed. (Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, 1996), vol. 2, pp.
31. F. G. Speck and W. S. Hadlock, Am. Anthropol. AS,
ing points for addressing future challenges. 465-493; R. O. Keohane and E. Ostrom, Eds., Local
355 (1946); C. Safina, Issues Sci. Technol. 10, 37
Some of these will be institutional, such as Commons and Global Interdependence: Heterogene-
(1994).
ity and Cooperation in Two Domains (Sage, London,
multilevel institutions that build on and 1995); S. Buck, The Global Commons: An Introduction 32. J.-M. Baland and J.-P. Platteau, Halting Degradation of
complement local and regional institutions (Island, Washington, DC, 1998). Natural Resources: Is There a Role for Rural Commu-
nities? (Clarendon, Oxford, 1996); M. A. McKean, J.
to focus on truly global problems. Others 13. E. Ostrom, R. Gardner, J. Walker, Rules, Games, and
Theor. Pol. 4, 247 (1992).
Common-Pool Resources (Univ. of Michigan Press,
will build from improved technology. For Ann Arbor, Ml, 1994). 33. J. Buchanan and G. Tullock, The Calculus of Consent
example, more accurate long-range weather 14. E. Schlager, W. Blomquist, S. Y. Tang, Land Econ. 70, (Univ. of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, Ml, 1962); J. B.
Wiener, Yale Law J. 108, 677 (1999).
forecasts could facilitate improvements in 294 (1994).
15. W. Blomquist, Dividing the Waters: Governing 34. C. W. Clark and G. R. Munro, in Investing in Natural
irrigation management, or advances in fish Capital: The Ecological Economics Approach to Sus-
Groundwater in Southern California (ICS Press, San
tracking could allow more accurate popu- Francisco, 1992). tainability, A. M. Jansson, M. Hammer, C. Folke, R.
lation estimates and harvest management. 16. R. Norgaard, Adv. Hum. Ecol. 4, 141 (1995); C. Gib- Costanza, Eds. (Island, Washington, DC, 1994), pp.
son, Politicians and Poachers: The Political Economy 343-361.
And broad dissemination of widely be- 35. See O. Young, Ed., Science Plan for Institutional Di-
of Wildlife Policy in Africa (Cambridge Univ. Press,
lieved data could be a major contributor to New York, 1999); A. Agrawal, Greener Pastures: Pol- mensions of Global Environmental Change (Interna-
the trust that is so central to effective CPR itics, Markets, and Community Among a Migrant Pas- tional Human Dimensions Programme on Global En-
vironmental Change, Bonn, Germany, 1999); Global
management. toral People (Duke Univ. Press, Durham, NC, 1999).
17. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Devel- Governance: Drawing Insights from the Environmental
In the end, building from the lessons of opment (OECD), Towards Sustainable Fisheries: Eco- Experience (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1997); P.
past successes will require forms of commu- nomic Aspects of the Management of Living Marine Haas, R. Keohane, M. Levy, Institutions for the Earth:
Resources (OECD, Paris, 1997); National Research Sources of Effective Environmental Protection (MIT
nication, information, and trust that are broad Press, Cambridge, MA, 1993).
Council, Sustaining Marine Fisheries (National Acad-
and deep beyond precedent, but not beyond emy Press, Washington, DC, 1999). 36. J. B. Wiener, Georgetown Law J., in press.
possibility. Protecting institutional diversity 18. H. S. Gordon, J. Pol. Econ. 62, 124 (1954); B. J. 37. R. M. Hilton, / Theor. Pol. 4, 283 (1992).
related to how diverse peoples cope with McCay, Coastal Ocean Manage. 28, 3 (1995). 38. This paper profited from ideas discussed at a sympo-
19. E. Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of sium on "The Commons Revisited: An Americas Per-
CPRs may be as important for our long-run Institutions for Collective Action (Cambridge Univ. spective" held in conjunction with the X General
survival as the protection of biological diver- Press, New York, 1990). Assembly of the Scientific Committee on Problems of
sity. There is much to learn from successful 20. C. R. Plott, Science 232, 732 (1986); K. A. McCabe, the Environment (SCOPE), June 1998. We thank the
S. J. Rassenti, V. L Smith, ibid. 254, 534 (1991). U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, NSF, and
efforts as well as from failures. 21. See S. Bowles, R. Boyd, E. Fehr, H. Gintis, Homo NASA for supporting the U.S. National Committee
reciprocans: A Research Initiative on the Origins, Di- for SCOPE, where this effort began. We thank F.
References and Notes mensions, and Policy Implications of Reciprocal Fair- Berkes, A. Blomqvist, P. Dalecki, D. Dodds, K. Dough-
1. G. Hardin, Science 162, 1243 (1968). ness (working paper, University of Massachusetts, erty, D. Feeny, T. Hargis-Young, C. Hess, B. J. McCay,
2. ibid. 280, 682 (1998). 1997); E. Ostrom and J. M. Walker, in Perspectives on M. McGinnis, M. Polski, E. Schlager, N. Sengupta, J.
3. J. E. M. Arnold, Managing Forests as Common Property Public Choice: A Handbook, D. C. Mueller, Ed. (Cam- Unruh, O. Young, and anonymous reviewers for their
(FAO Forestry Paper 136, Rome, 1998); D. Feeny, S. bridge Univ. Press, New York, 1997), pp. 35-72; J. M. useful comments. Supported by NSF grant
Hanna, A. F. McEvoy, Land Econ. 72, 187 (1996); F. Orbell, A. van de Kragt, R. M. Dawes, J. Personality SBR-9521918, the U.N. Food and Agriculture Orga-
Berkes and C. Folke, Eds., Linking Social and Ecological Soc. Psych. 54, 811 (1988); E. Ostrom, Am. Pol. Sci. nization (FAO), the Ford Foundation, and the
Systems: Management Practices and Social Mecha- Rev. 92, 1 (1998). In these experiments, the formal MacArthur Foundation (E.O.) and by U.S. Department
nisms for Building Resilience (Cambridge Univ. Press, structure of a dilemma is converted into a set of of Energy grant AI DE-FC01-95EW55084 to the Con-
New York," 1998); A. C. Finlayson and B. J. McCay, decisions made by subjects who are financially sortium for Risk Evaluation with Stakeholder Partici-
ibid., pp. 311-337; R. Repetto, Skimming the Water: rewarded as a result of their own and others' pation and National Institute of Environmental
Rent-seeking and the Performance of Public Irrigation decisions. See also J. H. Kagel and A. E. Roth, Eds., Health Sciences grant ESO 5022 (J.B.).

282 9 APRIL 1999 VOL 284 SCIENCE www.sciencemag.org

You might also like