Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 15

Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2019 ARTICLE 1 of 15

Legal Tests in EU Competition Law: Taxonomy

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


and Operation
Pablo Ibáñez Colomo*

I. Introduction Key Points


The Court of Justice (hereinafter, the ‘Court’, or the
‘ECJ’) defines the conditions under which practices are • There is not a unique legal test in EU competition
in principle prohibited or allowed. These conditions law. There is conduct that is prima facie unlawful
irrespective of its effects, and conduct that is lawful.
form the legal test to establish liability under Articles
In between, some practices are prohibited where
101 and/or 102 TFEU. There is not a unique legal test
actual or likely effects can be shown.
in EU competition law. Some practices are deemed
unlawful without it being necessary to establish their • This paper seeks to map the various tests by which
effects. This is the case, just to mention the most obvi- conduct is assessed under Articles 101 and 102
ous example, of cartel arrangements.1 Other practices TFEU and to explain the rationale and operation in
are deemed prima facie lawful. For instance, quantity practice of these tests.
rebates fall in principle outside the scope of Article 102 • The analysis explains, inter alia, how firms can
TFEU.2 There are, finally, practices that lie in between rebut the presumption that practices are capable of
the prima facie lawful and the prima facie unlawful. In having restrictive effects in light of the relevant eco-
such cases, it is necessary to show, at the very least, that nomic and legal context of which they are a part.
the behaviour under consideration has, or is likely to
• The paper also explains why indispensability is an
have, a negative impact on competition in the specific
element of the legal test in the context of some
factual and regulatory circumstances in which it is
practices (for instance, refusals to deal) but not
implemented.3 others (for instance, ‘margin squeeze’ and tying
Even though it is clear from the case law that the conduct). In this sense, it is submitted that, as the
legal tests to establish liability vary from one practice to law stands, the nature of the remedy determines the
another, this reality is not always acknowledged, or not application of one test or the other.
studied systematically. As a result, questions about the
boundaries between the various legal tests often arise in
relation to new cases or new factual scenarios. In fact, map of the existing legal tests, and to clarify where each
even the legal test that applies to well-known categories of the practices stands along a spectrum ranging from
of conduct is occasionally a source of uncertainty or those deemed prohibited irrespective of their effects and
debate. Suffice to mention an example in this sense. The those deemed lawful. A second objective is to explain
Court ruled – in Deutsche Telekom and TeliaSonera – the operation of these tests – that is, how they work in
that a ‘margin squeeze’ is only caught by Article 102 practice.
TFEU where it has, or is likely to have, anticompetitive Third, this paper seeks to explain the logic behind the
effects. However, statements repeating this established application of a legal test to specific practices. What
aspect of the case law attract the attention of commen- explains that a given practice is deemed unlawful irre-
tators, as if they were controversial or as if the question spective of its impact on competition and another is
had not been unambiguously settled.4 Against this back- deemed lawful? To use a concrete example: why is it
ground, one of the objectives of the paper is to draw the that an outright refusal to deal appears to be abusive

* London School of Economics and College of Europe. E-mail: P.Ibanez- 2 Case 85/76 Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v Commission, EU:C:1979:36,
Colomo@lse.ac.uk. I am also a Joint General Editor of the Journal paras 89–90.
European Competition Law & Practice. I am grateful to Martin Farley 3 See for instance Case C-234/89 Stergios Delimitis v Henninger Bräu AG,
and Andriani Kalintiri for their comments on a previous version of this EU:C:1991:91 and Case C-280/08 P Deutsche Telekom AG v Commission,
article. In accordance with the ASCOLA declaration of ethics, I am happy EU:C:2010:603.
to clarify that I have nothing to disclose. 4 Henry Vane, ‘Margin squeeze proof requires effects, says ECJ official’
1 The legal status of cartels as restrictive by object was clear from the Global Competition Review (London, 30 October 2014).
outset. See in this sense Case 57/69 Azienda Colori Nazionali – ACNA
SpA v Commission, EU:C:1972:78, paras 84–85.

© The Author(s) 2019. Published by Oxford University Press. All rights reserved. For Permissions, please email: journals.permissions@oup.com
2 of 15 ARTICLE Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2019

only where the relevant input is indispensable and such the conditions under – which firms involved in these
a condition does not seem to apply to ‘margin squeeze’ practices can escape the prohibition). Section 4, in turn,

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


conduct? Addressing these questions is helpful not only moves to the opposite end of the spectrum, with a view
because it makes it easier to navigate the case law, but to clarifying why some practices are deemed compatible
also because it helps tackle the challenges raised by new with Articles 101 and/or 102 TFEU (and how a claimant
practices. It is not unusual that more than one legal test or authority can show that they should be prohibited in
is seen as potentially applicable to a factual scenario that the specific circumstances of a case). Finally, Section 5
does not fit neatly into existing categories. For instance, tackles the practices the legality of which is contingent
a new practice may be simultaneously seen as analogous on a case-by-case assessment of their effects on compe-
to a ‘margin squeeze’ but also analogous to an outright tition. In particular, this last section purports to explain
refusal to deal. Making sense of the rationale behind the why indispensability is a condition in relation to some –
case law helps identify the most reasonable approach to but not all – conduct.
the assessment of conduct for which there are no prece-
dents unambiguously supporting a particular outcome.
This exercise, it is submitted, is valuable for several II. The variety of legal tests in EU
reasons, in particular at this juncture. First, mapping the competition law
case law, explaining its practical operation and uncover-
ing its underlying rationale all contribute to the clarity, A. The spectrum of legal tests: from the prima
predictability and consistency of the law. The exercise is facie unlawful to the prima facie lawful
crucial, in other words, to ensure that like practices are The legal tests to establish liability under Articles 101
treated alike and, by the same token, to avoid arbitrary and 102 TFEU fall somewhere along a spectrum,
decision-making. The legal test that applies to a given depicted in Fig. 1. As shown, there is conduct that is
practice does not and should not depend on the way it prima facie unlawful irrespective of its effects on compe-
is labelled (whether by a firm or a competition author- tition. These are practices, in other words, that are sub-
ity), but on the underlying issues to which it gives rise, ject to a (qualified) prohibition rule.6 Accordingly,
and on the extent to which these issues are comparable evidence that these practices have been implemented is
to one or more of the potentially applicable precedents. in principle sufficient for them to be caught by Articles
The Court has consistently made clear that it is sub- 101 and/or 102 TFEU. The example of cartels, men-
stance, not form, that matters in relation to the inter- tioned in the introduction, is one that comes to mind
pretation of EU competition law provisions. Concerning immediately, but is not the only one. In Intel, the Court
conduct potentially falling within the scope of Article reasserted the principle laid down in Hoffmann-La
101 TFEU, for instance, the ECJ has consistently held Roche, whereby exclusivity agreements and rebates con-
that the legal status of agreements depends on their ditional upon exclusivity are prohibited by their very
nature, which is to be assessed in light of the economic nature under Article 102 TFEU.7 Conversely, there are
and legal context of which they are a part.5 Second, this practices that are deemed compatible with the above-
article comes at a time when some recent developments mentioned provisions (that is, practices subject to a
in the field, which sometimes involve practices for legality rule). Under certain conditions, selective distri-
which there are no clear-cut precedents, have revealed bution and franchising fall outside the scope of Article
gaps in the literature. 101(1) TFEU and are thus not prohibited, whether by
The remainder of this piece is organised as follows. object or effect.
Section 2 presents the variety of legal tests that exists in In between these two ends of the spectrum, there is
the case law and maps the various practices along a conduct that is neither prohibited by its very nature nor
spectrum. Section 3 seeks to explain why some practices prima facie lawful. As far as these practices are con-
are deemed prima facie unlawful irrespective of their cerned, a claimant or authority would have to show not
effects and to shed light on the practical operation of only that they have been implemented, but that they
this legal test (in particular on the instances in – and have, or are likely to have, a negative impact on

5 See in this sense Case C‑32/11 Allianz Hungária Biztosító Zrt. and Others caught by Article 101(1) TFEU, it fulfils the conditions laid down in
v Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, EU:C:2013:160, para 36; Case C-67/13 P Article 101(3) TFEU. Similarly, it is always possible for a dominant firm
Groupement des cartes bancaires v Commission, EU:C:2014:2204, para 53; to bring forward evidence showing that its behaviour is objectively
and Case C‑345/14 SIA ‘Maxima Latvija’ v Konkurences padome, EU: justified or that the efficiencies it generates are sufficient to outweigh its
C:2015:784, para 25. (actual or likely) anticompetitive effects.
6 The rule is qualified in the sense that it is always possible for the parties 7 Hoffmann-La Roche (n 2), paras 89–90.
to bring forward evidence showing that, even though the agreement is
Pablo Ibáñez Colomo . Legal Tests in EU Competition Law ARTICLE 3 of 15

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


Fig. 1: Spectrum of legal tests in EU Competition Law.

competition in the specific context in which they are distribution systems fall outside the scope of Article 101
implemented. Practices subject to a case-by-case evalu- (1) TFEU altogether.11 In Pronuptia, it ruled that
ation of their anticompetitive effects are, in principle, in clauses that are ‘strictly necessary’ to preserve the know-
the middle of the spectrum. However, legal tests can be how and the uniformity and reputation of a franchise
calibrated to bring these practices closer to one or the are not restrictive of competition, whether by object or
other ends of the spectrum. For instance, a court may effect.12 These two cases are manifestations of a broader
introduce additional conditions that go beyond a trad- doctrine (the so-called ancillary restraints doctrine),
itional analysis of effects. As a result, evidence of the according to which clauses in an agreement that are
likely impact of a practice on competition would no objectively necessary to attain its (pro-competitive) aims
longer suffice to trigger liability. Conversely, they may – and thus ancillary to them – are not caught by Article
rely on filters and proxies that move the legal test in the 101(1) TFEU.
opposite direction, in the sense that they may dispense Finally, there are practices that are only prohibited
claimants or authorities from the need to engage in a under Article 101(1) TFEU where a claimant or author-
full-blown analysis of anticompetitive effects. ity can show, to the requisite legal standard, that they
have, or are likely to have, restrictive effects on competi-
tion. The leading example in this sense is Delimitis. In
B. The spectrum of legal tests under Article 101 that case, the Court ruled that exclusive dealing agree-
(1) TFEU ments are not prohibited by their very nature.
As the law stands, the spectrum of legal tests under Accordingly, they are only caught by Article 101(1)
Article 101 TFEU is relatively straightforward. At one TFEU where it can be shown that access to the market
end of the spectrum (depicted in Fig. 2), there are three is foreclosed to new entrants and, in addition, that the
broad categories of practices that are subject to a pro- bundle of agreements under consideration makes an
hibition rule, and thus prima facie unlawful irrespective appreciable contribution to foreclosure. The same test
of their effects. This is conduct that is deemed to have applies to practices having a similar nature and objective
as its object the restriction of competition. The first cat- purpose, in particular the arrangements at stake in
egory is that of cartel arrangements. The second com- Maxima Latvija.13 The analysis of effects also featured
prises agreements aimed at limiting or eliminating prominently in cases like Cartes Bancaires14 – where the
cross-border trade within the EU, and in particular Court concluded that it was inappropriate to categorise
agreements giving absolute territorial protection to a the practice as a ‘by object’ infringement – and
distributor8 and agreements hindering distributors’ abil- MasterCard.15
ity to resell the contractual goods in other Member
States.9 Finally, vertical price-fixing is deemed restrictive
of competition by its very nature, as the Court expressly C. The spectrum of legal tests under Article 102
held in Binon.10 TFEU
There are other practices that are not restrictive of In the context of Article 102 TFEU, there are practices
competition, whether by object or effect, and thus sub- that are subject to a prohibition rule. The legal treat-
ject to a legality rule. Some of these agreements have ment given to such conduct is not dissimilar to that
been mentioned above. In Metro I, the Court clarified given to agreements prohibited by object under Article
that, under certain conditions, qualitative selective 101(1) TFEU. Exclusionary practices that amount,
8 Joined Cases 56/64 and 58/64 Établissements Consten S.à.R.L. and de l’Emploi, EU:C:2011:649; and Case C-230/16 Coty Germany GmbH v
Grundig-Verkaufs-GmbH v Commission, EU:C:1966:41. Parfümerie Akzente GmbH, EU:C:2017:941.
9 Joined Cases C-501/06 P, C-513/06 P, C-515/06 P and C-519/06 P 12 Case 161/84 Pronuptia de Paris GmbH v Pronuptia de Paris Irmgard
GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission, EU:C:2009:610. Schillgallis, EU:C:1986:41, paras 16–17.
10 Case 243/83 SA Binon & Cie v SA Agence et messageries de la presse, EU: 13 Maxima Latvija (n 5), paras 25–29.
C:1985:284. 14 Cartes Bancaires (n 5). See also Case T-491/07 RENV Groupement des
11 Case 26/76 Metro SB-Großmärkte GmbH & Co. KG v Commission, EU: cartes bancaires v Commission, EU:T:2016:379.
C:1977:167 (‘Metro I’). These conditions were further confirmed in, inter 15 Case T-111/08 MasterCard, Inc. and Others v Commission, EU:
alia, Case C-439/09 Pierre Fabre Dermo-Cosmétique SAS v Président de T:2012:260; and Case C-382/12 P MasterCard Inc. and Others v
l’Autorité de la concurrence and Ministre de l’Économie, de l’Industrie et Commission, EU:C:2014:2201.
4 of 15 ARTICLE Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2019

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


Fig. 2: Spectrum of legal tests in the context of Article 101(1) TFEU.

prima facie, to an abuse of dominance irrespective of prohibited when it can be shown that they have, or are
their effects comprise exclusivity agreements and rebate likely to have, anticompetitive effects. Such practices are
schemes having an equivalent object or effect, including subject to an analysis that is in every way similar to that
rebates conditional upon exclusivity or quasi- laid down in Delimitis. This test is referred to herein-
exclusivity16 and rebate schemes that set individual tar- after as the ‘standard effects’ test. To begin with, the
gets corresponding to the customers’ needs.17 It is clear Court clarified in Deutsche Telekom that a ‘margin
from Hilti, Tetra Pak II and Microsoft I that tying squeeze’ that forces an equally efficient rival to sell at a
arrangements are also prohibited by their very nature loss on the relevant downstream market is not abusive
under Article 102 TFEU.18 Finally, it is abusive for a in itself.24 Accordingly, it is necessary to consider the
dominant firm to charge prices below its average vari- economic and legal context in which the practice is
able costs (or to sell below average total costs as part of implemented, including factors such as the extent of the
an exclusionary strategy).19 dominant position as well as the features of the product
At the other end of the spectrum, as shown in Fig. 3, and of the relevant market. Evidence that the input at
there is conduct that is subject to a legality rule, and stake in a case is indispensable for downstream rivals to
thus deemed prima facie lawful even when implemented compete can be taken into consideration in this
by a dominant firm. The category comprises, first, quan- regard.25 Where a standardised rebate scheme is neither
tity rebates, that is, rebates conditional upon the volume purely conditional on volume nor on exclusivity, liabil-
sold. The legality rule applies insofar as the rebates are ity is also contingent on an analysis of its likely impact
given in respect of each individual order and reflect the on competition. As explained in Post Danmark II, fac-
cost savings made by the dominant supplier.20 In such tors such as the coverage of the practice and the length
instances, liability can only be established if the author- of the obligations are of particular relevance in the
ity or the claimant can show that the rebates given bear analysis.26
no relationship with the economies of scale made by the There are practices that are subject to what is
dominant firm.21 Second, it is not abusive for a domin- referred to hereinafter as an ‘enhanced effects’ test, by
ant firm to price aggressively (whether it does so select- which it is meant that the standard analysis described
ively or across the board) provided that the prices above does not, alone, suffice to establish liability.
charged remain above average total costs.22 As a matter Conduct evaluated under ‘enhanced effects’ test is clo-
of principle, equally efficient rivals would be able to ser in the spectrum to practices deemed prima facie
match such prices, as they would not force them to sell lawful. As shown in Fig. 4, one can identify two add-
at a loss.23 itional points at the right end of the spectrum. One can
The spectrum of exclusionary behaviour subject to identify, first, cases where prima face liability is contingent
an analysis of effects is richer in the context of Article on evidence showing that the input to which access is
102 TFEU. There are, first, practices that are only requested is indispensable to compete on a neighbouring

16 Hoffmann-La Roche (n 2), paras 89–90. 22 This is implicit from AKZO (n 19), paras 70–71. The point was
17 Case 322/81 NV Nederlandsche Banden Industrie Michelin v Commission, confirmed in Case C-209/10 Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet, EU:
EU:C:1983:313 (‘Michelin I’); and Case C-95/04 P, British Airways plc v C:2012:172 (‘Post Danmark I’), in particular paras 22, 30 and 33.
Commission, EU:C:2007:166. 23 See in particular Post Danmark I (n 22), para 38 (‘to the extent that a
18 Case T-30/89 Hilti AG v Commission, EU:T:1991:70, paras 99–101; Case dominant undertaking sets its prices at a level covering the great bulk of
T-83/91 Tetra Pak International SA v Commission, EU:T:1994:246 (‘Tetra the costs attributable to the supply of the goods or services in question, it
Pak II’), para 135; and Case T-201/04 Microsoft Corp v Commission, EU: will, as a general rule, be possible for a competitor as efficient as that
T:2007:289 (‘Microsoft I’), para 1054. undertaking to compete with those prices without suffering losses that
19 Case C-62/86 AKZO Chemie BV v Commission, EU:C:1991:286, para are unsustainable in the long term’) and Post Danmark II (n 20), para 66.
71–72. 24 Deutsche Telekom (n 3), para 250.
20 Case C-23/14 Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet, EU:C:2015:651 25 Ibid, para 255.
(‘Post Danmark II‘), para 28. 26 Post Danmark II (n 20), paras 39–46.
21 See in this sense Case C-163/99 Portugal v Commission, EU:C:2001:189,
paras 52–53; and Case T-203/01 Manufacture française des pneumatiques
Michelin v Commission, EU:T:2003:250 (‘Michelin II’), paras 58–60.
Pablo Ibáñez Colomo . Legal Tests in EU Competition Law ARTICLE 5 of 15

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


Fig. 3: Spectrum of legal tests in the context of Article 102 TFEU.

Fig. 4: The ‘enhanced effects’ test in the context of Article 102 TFEU.

market.27 According to the Court in Bronner, indispens- constraint on existing products but that, vice versa, is
ability is an element of the relevant legal test in instances not constrained by them.33
where a vertically integrated firm withdraws access to a The legal tests in Bronner (which required indispens-
physical input or refuses to deal with a would-be rival on ability to trigger liability) and Magill (which required, in
a neighbouring market.28 Such is the case, for instance, addition to indispensability, evidence that the refusal pre-
where a dominant firm decides to stop supplying a raw vents the emergence of a new product) are different from
material to a customer once it decides to start manufac- the ‘standard effects’ test endorsed in Deutsche Telekom
turing the final product itself (the issue at stake, for and Post Danmark II in another respect. Under the test
instance, in Commercial Solvents).29 Such is also the case, laid down in the latter two judgements, it is sufficient to
Bronner implies, where a newspaper publisher requests show that the anticompetitive effects are likely. It would
access to a delivery service.30 appear that it would be enough to establish that such
Second, there are instances where evidence of indis- effects are ‘more likely than not’ to occur.34 The probabil-
pensability is as such insufficient to establish liability. ity of harm occurring, in other words, would be at >50%.
These instances include – at the very least – factual The threshold in Bronner and Magill, on the other hand,
scenarios where the relevant input is an intangible asset is set at a higher level. The test laid down in the two cases
protected by intellectual property rights.31 Accordingly, suggests that establishing that anticompetitive effects are
a refusal to license a copyright or a patent is abusive not ‘more likely than not’ to occur is not enough. Bronner
simply because the relevant input is indispensable and Magill, together with IMS Health, make it clear that
within the meaning of Bronner, but also because, in liability requires evidence that the refusal would lead to
addition, the refusal prevents the emergence of a new the elimination of ‘all competition’ on the relevant down-
product for which there is potential consumer stream market. This vocabulary – when considered
demand.32 There is not much guidance in the case law together with the indispensability condition – suggests
concerning the boundaries of this ‘new product’ condi- that intervention is only justified where it can be shown
tion. It would seem from the Magill case, in any event, that anticompetitive effects are certain or virtually certain
that a new product is one that places a competitive to occur in the event of a refusal.35

27 See in particular Joined Cases 6 and 7/73 Istituto Chemioterapico Italiano C:1995:98 (‘Magill’). The question of whether intangible property that is
S.p.A. and Commercial Solvents Corporation v Commission, EU: not protected by intellectual property rights would be subject to the same
C:1974:18; Case 311/84 Centre belge d’études de marché - Télémarketing v test is an open question. The issue was discussed in Microsoft (n 18),
SA Compagnie luxembourgeoise de télédiffusion and Information publicité paras 283–290.
Benelux, EU:C:1985:394; and Case C-7/97 Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co. 32 Magill (n 31), para 54. See also Case C-418/01 IMS Health GmbH & Co.
KG v Mediaprint Zeitungs- und Zeitschriftenverlag GmbH & Co. KG, OHG v NDC Health GmbH & Co. KG, EU:C:2004:257, paras 48–49.
Mediaprint Zeitungsvertriebsgesellschaft mbH & Co. KG and Mediaprint 33 For a discussion of this question, see Robert O’Donoghue and Jorge
Anzeigengesellschaft mbH & Co. KG, EU:C:1998:569 Padilla, The Law and Economics of Article 102 TFEU (2nd edn, Hart
28 Bronner (n 27), paras 38–41. Publishing 2013) 559–562.
29 Commercial Solvents (n 27) and CBEM-Télémarketing (n 27). 34 See in this sense Opinion of AG Kokott in Case C-23/14 Post Danmark
30 Bronner (n 27), para 41. A/S v Konkurrencerådet, EU:C:2015:343, para 82.
31 Joined Cases C-241/91 P and C-242/91 P Radio Telefis Eireann (RTE) and 35 For an extensive analysis of this question, see Pablo Ibáñez Colomo, The
Independent Television Publications Ltd (ITP) v Commission, EU: Shaping of EU Competition Law (Cambridge University Press 2018).
6 of 15 ARTICLE Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2019

III. Prima facie unlawfulness: rationale fact that the agreement would completely insulate the
distributor from intra-brand competition would be suf-
and operation

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


ficient, in and of itself, to trigger the prima facie prohib-
A. The rationale behind the case law ition. The same would be true where a dominant firm
As a matter of principle, practices are prima facie pro- refuses to meet ordinary orders from its wholesalers
hibited irrespective of their effects where two cumulative with a view to restricting cross-border trade.40 Second,
conditions are fulfilled. In the first place, the application resale price maintenance is restrictive of competition by
of a prohibition rule is considered appropriate in rela- object, even though its plausible pro-competitive bene-
tion to practices that are deemed to have no plausible fits were explicitly acknowledged by the Court in
pro-competitive object. These are instances, in other Binon.41 As the law stands, such pro-competitive bene-
words, where the restriction of competition is the only fits can only be invoked under Article 101(3) TFEU.42
plausible rationale of the behaviour under consideration. In the second place, the prohibition rule applies only
There are several cases where the Court was explicit on where it is at least plausible that a restriction would
this point. In Hoffmann-La Roche, for instance, it took result from the implementation of the practice.
the view that exclusive dealing, as well as rebates condi- Conduct, in other words, is only prima facie unlawful
tional upon exclusivity, ‘are not based on an economic irrespective of its impact if it is at least capable of having
transaction which justifies this burden or benefit but are anticompetitive effects. This is true not only of practices
designed to deprive the purchaser of or restrict his pos- that are examined in accordance with the default condi-
sible choices of sources of supply’.36 In other words, the tion described above but also of practices that depart
Court suggested that the only purpose of such conduct from it – that is, resale price maintenance and restric-
is to foreclose competition. AKZO is equally explicit. In tions to cross-border trade. The case law suggests that
that case, the Court discussed the rationale behind the the capability threshold is relatively low. Accordingly, a
prima facie prohibition, by its very nature, of pricing practice can be prima facie prohibited by its very nature
below average variable costs. It explained that pricing at even when the anticompetitive effects are not particu-
such a level is in principle irrational for an undertaking. larly likely, provided that the lessons of experience and
Accordingly, such a profit sacrifice can only be plausibly economic analysis do not suggest that a restriction is
rationalised as part of a strategy to drive its rivals out of implausible.43 In T-Mobile, for instance, the Court con-
the market.37 Similarly, the EU courts typically assumed cluded that the plausibility threshold could be met even
that tying has no purpose other than the exclusion of though the practice involved a single meeting in which
competition.38 competitors exchanged sensitive information.44
There are two main exceptions to this principle. Similarly, tying is prima facie unlawful under Article
Thus, some practices are prohibited under Articles 101 102 TFEU even when it can be shown that rivals thrive
(1) and 102 TFEU even though they have a plausible on the market and have other means to reach consu-
pro-competitive object. This alternative line of case law mers.45 The mere fact that tying gives the dominant
is relevant, first, when the integration of Member States’ firm’s product a competitive advantage is sufficient to
economies is at stake. In such circumstances, practices trigger the prohibition.46
are prima facie unlawful irrespective of their effects The fact that some behaviour is subject to the prima
where it can be shown that the means used to achieve facie prohibition only where anticompetitive effects are
the object of the agreement restrict cross-border trade. plausible does not mean that an authority or a claimant
Thus, it would be irrelevant, for instance, that an agree- must establish, on a case-by-case basis, that such prac-
ment giving absolute protection to a distributor is a tices are capable of having a restrictive impact. As
plausible means to achieve a pro-competitive aim.39 The already pointed out, they can discharge their burden of

36 Hoffmann-La Roche (n 2), para 90. 43 See in this sense Ioannis Lianos, ‘Judging’ Economists: Economic
37 AKZO (n 19), para 71 Expertise in Competition Law Litigation’ in Ioannis Kokkoris and Ioannis
38 See in particular Tetra Pak II (n 18), para 135. Lianos (eds), The Reform of EC Competition Law: New Challenges
39 See in this sense Opinion of AG Roemer in Joined Cases 56/64 and 58/64 (Kluwer 2010).
Établissements Consten S.à.R.L. and Grundig-Verkaufs-GmbH v 44 Case C-8/08 T-Mobile Netherlands BV, KPN Mobile NV, Orange
Commission, EU:C:1966:19. Nederland NV and Vodafone Libertel NV v Raad van bestuur van de
40 Joined Cases C-468/06 to C-478/06 Sot. Lélos kai Sia EE and Others v Nederlandse Mededingingsautoriteit, EU:C:2009:343, para 31.
GlaxoSmithKline AEVE Farmakeftikon Proïonton, formerly 45 Microsoft I (n 18), para 1054.
Glaxowellcome AEVE, EU:C:2008:504. 46 Ibid. See also Microsoft (tying) (Case COMP/C-3/39.530) Commission
41 Binon (n 10), para 42. Decision of 16 December 2009 (‘Microsoft II’), para 39–46.
42 Ibid, para 46.
Pablo Ibáñez Colomo . Legal Tests in EU Competition Law ARTICLE 7 of 15

proof merely by showing that they have been imple- practice under consideration is at least capable of
mented. In this sense, the Court has consistently held restricting competition. The Court has made clear –

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


that object and effect are alternative conditions. Thus, if in Murphy,50 in relation to Article 101 TFEU, and in
it is shown that a practice has an anticompetitive object, Intel,51 in relation to Article 102 TFEU – that firms can
it need not be shown that it is capable or likely to have rebut this presumption by bringing forward evidence
restrictive effects on competition.47 This is also true in showing that the behaviour is incapable of restricting
the context of Article 102 TFEU, where the EU courts competition – in other words, that anticompetitive
have occasionally relied upon virtually identical vocabu- effects are implausible in the economic and legal context
lary to express the same idea.48 Against this back- of which it is a part. In essence, the rebuttal consists of
ground, it would seem that practices subject to a prima showing that the behaviour is not capable of restricting
facie prohibition are presumed to be at least capable of competition that would have existed in its absence.52 It
having restrictive effects. is clear from both Murphy and Intel that this analysis is
It is safe to presume that a practice that has no plaus- independent of that undertaken under Article 101(3)
ible purpose other than the restriction of competition is TFEU and of the possibility of advancing an objective
at least capable of having anticompetitive effects. Since justification and/or efficiency claims in the context of
such a practice would lack credible pro-competitive Article 102 TFEU.53
benefits, a rational, profit-maximising firm can only be There are essentially two ways in which the rebuttal
expected to engage in it if the prospect of restricting of the presumption of capability can take place in prac-
competition were at least a plausible one – in the sense tice. First, firms can show that any actual or potential
that such a prospect would be compatible with the les- effects on competition would not be attributable to their
sons of experience and/or economic analysis. As behaviour. The absence of a causal link between the
explained by the General Court in Michelin II, the two practice and its effects can be established, to begin with,
cumulative conditions can be seen as two sides of the by reference to the relevant legal context. There are
same coin.49 The second cumulative condition – cap- instances in which anticompetitive effects are implaus-
ability of the anticompetitive effects – can be safely ible due to the fact that any scope for competition is
inferred from the first – the absence of a plausible pro- already restricted by the relevant regulatory framework.
competitive object. By the same token, if it appears that It may be the case, for instance, that the legal regime
the practice is incapable of having anticompetitive gives – de iure or de facto – exclusive rights to a par-
effects, one can safely presume that it has a pro- ticular firm. In such circumstances, any practice aimed
competitive object. If the restriction of competition is an at restricting entry on the relevant market is incapable
implausible outcome, then the rationale behind the con- of restricting competition that would otherwise have
duct is, in all likelihood, a different one – again, one existed. This is, in essence, the scenario at stake in E.On
cannot expect a profit-maximising firm to engage in a Ruhrgas.54 Similarly, a firm may be able to show that
course of action that, experience and economic analysis market entry would be implausible, with and without
suggest, it would not be able to attain. the practice, by virtue of the intellectual property regime
in place. Such was the scenario at stake in Coditel II.55
In that case, what precluded the cross-border provision
B. Escaping the prima facie prohibition in of services was not the agreement granting an exclusive
practice territorial licence, but the copyright system, which gave
It has been explained above that, inherent in the prima the right holder (and, crucially, the exclusive licensee)
facie prohibition there is a presumption that the the right to authorise or prohibit any communication

47 Case 56/65 Société Technique Minière, EU:C:1966:38, 249; T-Mobile (n 51 Case C-413/14 P Intel Corp v Commission, EU:C:2017:632.
44), para 28; and Case C-286/13 P, Dole Food Company Inc. and Dole 52 In Société Technique Minière (n 47), 250, the Court explained that the
Fresh Fruit Europe v Commission, EU:C:2015:184, paras 111–135. notion of competition ‘must be understood within the actual context in
48 See in particular Michelin II (n 21), paras 237–245. which it would occur in the absence of the agreement in dispute’.
49 Ibid, para 241: ‘[…] for the purposes of applying Article 82 EC, 53 Murphy (n 50), paras 140 and 145; and Intel (n 50), para 140.
establishing the anti-competitive object and the anti-competitive effect 54 Case T-360/09, E.ON Ruhrgas AG and E.ON AG v Commission, para 104.
are one and the same thing […]. If it is shown that the object pursued by See also Case T-370/09, GDF Suez SA v Commission, para 97.
the conduct of an undertaking in a dominant position is to limit 55 Case 262/81 Coditel SA, Compagnie générale pour la diffusion de la
competition, that conduct will also be liable to have such an effect’. télévision, and others v Ciné-Vog Films SA and others, EU:C:1982:334
50 Joined Cases C-403/08 and C-429/08 Football Association Premier League (‘Coditel II’).
Ltd and Others v QC Leisure and Others and Karen Murphy v Media
Protection Services Ltd, EU:C:2011:631.
8 of 15 ARTICLE Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2019

to the public taking place in the Member State in link between any actual or potential effects and the
question.56 practice.62

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


More generally, it is possible for firms to show that Second, it is possible for firms to show that anticompe-
harm to competition is implausible in light of the prac- titive effects are implausible in light of the fact that a
tice and the features of the relevant market. This is the practice is objectively necessary to attain a pro-
important clarification introduced by the Court in Intel. competitive aim and thus it is only capable of creating,
As explained above, the principle whereby exclusive rather than restricting, competition. This idea was already
dealing and rebates conditional upon exclusivity are pri- present in Société Technique Minière.63 In that case, the
ma facie prohibited irrespective of their effects was Court explained that, if a restraint is really necessary for
upheld. On the other hand, the Court clarified that, a supplier to enter a new market, the said practice is not
when a firm brings forward evidence57 showing that the capable of restricting competition that would otherwise
practice is incapable of having anticompetitive effects, have existed.64 The Guidelines on vertical restraints elab-
the Commission cannot simply dismiss this evidence. It orate on this point, and provide a concrete example of
must examine the factors identified in cases like the sort of evidence that firms can put forward. As
Deutsche Telekom and Post Danmark II, and in particu- explained above, practices aimed at restricting cross-
lar, the extent of the dominant position, the coverage of border trade are prima facie prohibited under Article 101
the practice as well as the precise features of the practice (1) TFEU. This category includes clauses aimed at limit-
(including the length of the obligations). ing distributors’ ability to engage in passive selling. The
The Intel case provides an illustration of the sort of Commission explains in the abovementioned Guidelines,
evidence that may be advanced by a firm in this regard. however, that even distribution agreements restricting
At stake in that case was the question of whether a passive sales can escape the prohibition where, given the
dominant firm can invoke the so-called ‘as efficient substantial investments required, the practice is object-
competitor’ test (hereinafter, the ‘AEC test’) to show ively necessary for a supplier to enter a new market.65
that a rebate scheme is incapable, or unlikely, to have There is no case law explicitly dealing with this question
anticompetitive effects.58 The AEC test seeks to ascer- in the context of Article 102 TFEU. However, there seems
tain whether the rebate scheme put in place by the dom- to be no reason to rule out the possibility for a dominant
inant supplier would force an equally efficient rival to firm to avoid a prima facie prohibition by showing, against
sell its products below cost.59 A key premise behind the the relevant counterfactual, that their practice is objectively
test is that above-cost prices are incapable of driving necessary to attain a pro-competitive aim. Several reasons
equally efficient rivals out of the market. Accordingly, can be advanced in this regard. First, this possibility is argu-
any anticompetitive effects of a scheme that does not ably implicit in Intel. Establishing that a practice is object-
force rivals to sell at a loss would not be attributable to ively necessary is indeed another way of showing that it is
it, but to rivals’ inefficiency. And, as the Court has con- incapable of restricting competition. Second, excluding this
sistently held, Article 102 TFEU is not concerned with possibility in the context of Article 102 TFEU but allowing
the exclusion of rivals that are less efficient than the it under Article 101 TFEU would lead to an inconsistency
dominant firm,60 or at least not in principle.61 Thus, the that would not be easy to justify. Finally, one cannot ignore
AEC test can be, in a particular economic and legal the fact that the analysis of effects in the context of Article
context, a powerful indicator that there is no causal 102 TFEU must not be ‘purely hypothetical’.66 Arguably, it

56 This point was clarified in a prior ruling relating to the same set of facts. Patrick Rey and James S Venit, ‘An Effects-Based Approach to Article
See Case 62/79 SA Compagnie générale pour la diffusion de la télévision, 102: A Response to Wouter Wils’ (2015) 38 World Competition 3.
Coditel, and others v Ciné Vog Films and others, EU:C:1980:84. 59 Guidance on the Commission’s enforcement priorities in applying Article
57 The level of the evidence that needs to be provided remains unclear at 82 of the EC Treaty to abusive exclusionary conduct by dominant
present. There are reasons to believe that it is sufficient that this evidence undertakings [2009] OJ C45/7 (hereinafter, the ‘Guidance’), paras 37–45.
has an ‘air of reality’ to require the Commision to engage in an 60 Post Danmark I (n 22), para 22 and Intel (n 51), para 134.
assessment of the capability of the practice having restrictive effects. See 61 See in this sense Post Danmark II (n 20), paras 51–62.
in this sense Pablo Ibáñez Colomo, ‘The Future of Article 102 TFEU after 62 Post Danmark II (n 20), para 58 and Intel (n 51), paras 142–143.
Intel’ (2018) 9 Journal of European Competition Law & Practice 293.
63 Société Technique Minière (n 47), 250.
58 For an overview of the questions, see the arguments of the parties in Intel
64 Ibid: ‘it may be doubted whether there is an interference with
(n 51), paras 108–128 as well as Opinion of AG Wahl in Case C-413/14 P
competition if the said agreement seems really necessary for the
Intel Corp v Commission, EU:C:2016:788. The applicability of the AEC
penetration of a new area by an undertaking’.
test gave rise to considerable controversy among commentators in the
context of the Intel case. See in particular Wouter PJ Wils, ‘The Judgment 65 Guidelines on Vertical Restraints [2010] OJ C130/1, para 61.
of the EU General Court in Intel and the So-Called More Economic 66 Post Danmark II (n 20), para 65.
Approach to Abuse of Dominance’ (2014) 37 World Competition 405;
Pablo Ibáñez Colomo . Legal Tests in EU Competition Law ARTICLE 9 of 15

follows from this principle that the objective necessity of network.67 Similarly, suppliers would not have recourse
the practice would inevitably have to be considered as part to franchising agreements if they were not allowed to

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


of the economic and legal context of which the practice is take the necessary measures to preserve their know-how
a part. as well as the reputation and uniformity of the system.68

IV. Prima facie lawfulness: rationale B. Challenging the prima facie lawfulness in
practice
and practical operation
It is possible for an authority or claimant to show why a
A. The rationale behind the case law practice that is in principle lawful should be prohibited
The discussion above is also helpful to understand why in a given economic and legal context. One can identify
some practices are prima facie lawful. To begin with, three main scenarios in this regard. To begin with, the
there is behaviour that is deemed to fall outside the scope claimant or the authority can show why, in the specific
of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU due to the fact that any economic and legal context of which the practice is a
actual or potential effects identified would not be attrib- part, some of the principles underpinning the case law
utable to it. As already explained, above-cost pricing by a should be disapplied. In particular, the Court seems to
dominant firm (whether applied selectively or across the accept that, in certain circumstances, the analysis of
board) is in principle incapable of driving an equally effi- effects should not be based on the position of an equally
cient rival out of the market. Accordingly, such behav- efficient competitor. In Post Danmark II, it held that, in
iour is prima facie compatible with Article 102 TFEU. the economic and legal context of the case, the AEC test
The same is true of a ‘margin squeeze’ that would not was of limited relevance to assess the lawfulness of the
force equally efficient rivals to sell at a loss. In such cir- practice. This is so due to the very large market share of
cumstances, the downstream division of the dominant the dominant firm and the fact that it enjoyed structural
firm would not be offering its goods or services below advantages flowing, in particular, from the protection by
cost. The prima facie legality of quantity rebates rests on exclusive rights of some of these activities.69
an identical premise. Where a rebate scheme reflects the The claimant or the authority bear the burden of
cost savings made in the context of a particular transac- explaining why even the exclusion of a less efficient rival
tion, any advantage resulting from it can be safely pre- should justify intervention where the practice is prima
sumed to be explained by the dominant firm’s superior facie lawful. The Commission’s Guidance on exclusion-
efficiency alone. As such, it would be beyond reproach. ary abuses70 (hereinafter, the ‘Guidance’) provides some
A second reason why some practices are deemed law- examples of the arguments that may be advanced in this
ful under Articles 101 and/or 102 TFEU relates to sense. Aggressive above-cost pricing may be problem-
instances in which conduct is objectively necessary to atic, for instance, where there are strong network effects
achieve the objectives of a pro-competitive transaction. in a particular market.71 In such circumstances, any
In their absence, the said transaction would simply not competitive advantage enjoyed by the dominant firm
take place and there would be less competition, not may have the effect of tipping the relevant market in its
more. This is the principle behind the so-called ancillary favour, which may in turn justify action to prohibit pri-
restraints doctrine, mentioned above. In Metro I, the ma facie lawful conduct. The legal and economic litera-
Court acknowledged that a selective distribution system ture has explored other instances in which it may be
cannot operate in the absence of some vertical justified to depart from the principle whereby only the
restraints, and in particular a prohibition imposed on exclusion of equally efficient competitor justifies inter-
distributors from selling to non-members of the vention under Article 102 TFEU.72

67 Metro I (n 11), para 27 (‘[t]o be effective, any marketing system based on 69 Post Danmark II (n 20), para 59 (‘in a situation such as that in the main
the selection of outlets necessarily entails the obligation upon wholesalers proceedings, characterised by the holding by the dominant undertaking
forming part of the network to supply only appointed resellers and, of a very large market share and by structural advantages conferred, inter
accordingly, the right of the relevant producer to check that that alia, by that undertaking’s statutory monopoly, which applied to 70% of
obligation is fulfilled’). mail on the relevant market, applying the as-efficient-competitor test is of
68 Pronuptia (n 12), paras 15–17 (‘[i]n order for the system to work two no relevance inasmuch as the structure of the market makes the
conditions must be met. First, the franchisor must be able to emergence of an as-efficient competitor practically impossible’).
communicate his know-how to the franchisees and provide them with 70 Guidance (n 59).
the necessary assistance in order to enable them to apply his methods 71 Ibid, para 24.
[…]. Secondly, the franchisor must be able to take the measures 72 See for instance Aaron S Edlin, ‘Stopping Above-Cost Predatory Pricing’
necessary for maintaining the identity and reputation of the network (2002) 111 Yale Law Journal 941. For a general discussion, which builds
bearing his business name or symbol […]’). on the cited article, see US Department of Justice, Competition and
10 of 15 ARTICLE Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2019

One can think of a second scenario in which prima TFEU, they may have a restrictive impact on competi-
facie lawful conduct could be prohibited under Articles tion where the cumulative implementation of parallel

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


101 or 102 TFEU. As explained above, the status of networks leads to foreclosure or to the softening of
some practices as compatible with the said provision competition among suppliers or distributors and, in
relies on a series of premises. Underlying the prima facie addition, the supplier under consideration makes a sig-
compatibility of quantity rebates there is the idea that nificant contribution to such effects.76
this contractual device reflects the cost savings made by
the dominant supplier in the context of an individual
transaction. Similarly, the premise behind the compati- V. Making sense of the ‘enhanced
bility of quantitative selective distribution systems with effects’ test
Article 101(1) TFEU is that some of the clauses are
objectively necessary for the operation of this distribu- A. The problem: the respective scope of each
tion method. Against this background, it is possible for legal test is unclear
a claimant or an authority to put forward evidence It has been explained above that some practices are sub-
showing that these underlying premises do not apply in ject to a ‘standard effects’ test while other practices are
a particular context. subject to an ‘enhanced effects’ one that requires, at the
The case law provides several examples confirming very least, evidence that an input is indispensable to
not only that this possibility is open to authorities or compete on one of the relevant markets. The co-
claimants but also gives insights on the way in which it existence of different legal tests – two of them stricter
may operate in practice. In Portugal v Commission, for than the standard test – is a source of uncertainty in
instance, the Commission successfully argued that, even practice. It is not always easy to tell apart the practices
though the rebates applied by the State-owned airport that are subject to different legal tests. This is the case,
operator were formally contingent on volume, they had in particular, of ‘margin squeeze’ practices, on the one
been crafted in a way that favoured incumbent opera- hand, and outright refusals to deal, on the other. It is
tors and were not justified by economies of scales or also difficult to distinguish in certain circumstances
other cost savings.73 The Commission advanced a simi- between tying and refusal to deal. As a result of these
lar argument in Michelin II.74 In Coty, the Court was difficulties, there may be instances in which two or
confronted with the question of whether some clauses more legal tests are seen as potentially applicable to a
were objectively necessary for the operation of a select- factual scenario.
ive distribution system. More precisely, the claimant Consider, to begin with, the similarities between a
argued that a ban on the use of online marketplaces was refusal to deal and ‘margin squeeze’ behaviour.
not comparable to the clauses identified as prima facie Typically, the two practices involve a vertically inte-
lawful in Metro I.75 grated entity that supplies an input on which non-
There is, finally, a third scenario in which it may be integrated rivals rely to operate in a downstream mar-
possible to establish liability in relation to a prima facie ket. In such circumstances, an integrated operator with
lawful practice. This scenario does not entail a departure an incentive to exclude its rivals from the downstream
from the principles of the case law, nor does it question market can achieve its objective in two ways. First, it
the premises on which the legality rule is based. Instead, can refuse, outright, to start dealing with a would-be
it brings forward factors relating to the economic and rival (as in Bronner) or it can decide to discontinue,
legal context which do not affect, in principle, the legal altogether, its supplies (as in Commercial Solvents).
status of prima facie lawful conduct. In Metro I, the Second, it can refuse to give access (or stop supplying
Court clarified that it may be possible for a claimant or access) in a constructive manner, that is, by dealing
an authority to bring forward considerations that are with rivals on such conditions that make it impossible
not inherent in these practices but that may arise in a for them to profitably operate on the relevant down-
given relevant market and may lead to them having stream market (at least in the long run).
anticompetitive effects in the specific circumstances of Against this background, it would be reasonable to
a case. For instance, even though selective distribution conclude that the two scenarios (an outright and a con-
systems are as such compatible with Article 101(1) structive refusal) should be subject to the same legal

Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act 75 Coty (n 11). The argument was ultimately not successful, at least not in
(September 2008), 58–60. the specific circumstances of the case.
73 Portugal v Commission (n 21). 76 Metro I (n 11), para 22. See also Case 75/84 Metro SB-Großmärkte GmbH
74 Michelin II (n 21), paras 237–245. & Co. KG v Commission, EU:C:1986:399 (‘Metro II’).
Pablo Ibáñez Colomo . Legal Tests in EU Competition Law ARTICLE 11 of 15

test. This was in fact the position advanced by the simultaneously practices that were labelled as ‘margin
Commission in its Guidance. In that document, it pro- squeeze’ and as refusal to deal.81 Importantly, both

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


posed to examine ‘margin squeeze’ practices as a par- groups of practices appeared to be part of a single, over-
ticular manifestation of a refusal to deal, which would all strategy aimed at foreclosing new entrants from the
only be prioritised by the authority where, inter alia, relevant market. It is not obvious to see why, in such
there is evidence that the input in question is indispens- circumstances, some practices would be subject to an
able (or ‘objectively necessary’ to turn to the expression ‘enhanced effects’ test and other practices to a ‘standard
used in the Guidance).77 The US Supreme Court effects’ test. According to the Commission’s position in
adopted a similar approach in the linkLine case, where the case, both sets of practices should be subject to the
it refused to recognise ‘margin squeeze’ as a distinct cat- latter.82 This is, at the time of writing, still a contentious
egory of exclusionary conduct. In his opinion, Justice issue, as the first instance judgment of the General
Roberts explained that such conduct could give rise to Court has been appealed.83
liability under Section 2 of the Sherman Act either It is also difficult to distinguish, in some circum-
where it can be shown that the retail prices charged by stances, between tying (which is prima facie unlawful
the vertically-integrated provider are predatory or where irrespective of its effects) and refusal to deal scenarios.
a duty to deal can be established.78 This is particularly the case where the mechanism
As explained above, this route does not seem to be through which two products are combined is technical
the one taken by the Court in its case law. In (or technological) as opposed to contractual. Suppose
TeliaSonera, it was invited to rule, inter alia, on whether that two products – for instance, a piece of hardware
indispensability is an element of the legal test to estab- and a piece of software – are designed in such a way
lish the abusive nature of a ‘margin squeeze’. In its rul- that they do not work with products offered by rivals.
ing, the Court followed the Commission’s submission, Such a scenario could be examined as a form of tying.
which departed from the position expressed by the As a result of the design of the two products, the argu-
authority in its Guidance.79 Thus, it concluded that ment would go, customers are coerced to use one of the
indispensability is not an element of the legal test, and products (say, the software) when they intend to use the
that ‘margin squeeze’ conduct is subject to a standard other (say, the hardware). It would thus make sense to
approach to the analysis of effects. The Court argued, in make the practice prima facie unlawful in accordance
particular, that requiring evidence of indispensability in with the test set out in Hilti and Microsoft I. On the
such a factual scenario would mean that indispensability other hand, one could argue that such a scenario is, in
would be a precondition to establish an abuse in every reality, not fundamentally different from the one at
case involving the application of Article 102 TFEU. stake in refusal to deal cases. After all, what a claimant
TeliaSonera gave rise to controversy, as commenta- in such a case would be demanding is access to a plat-
tors disputed the Court’s reasoning and the logical form – the hardware – on non-discriminatory terms
inconsistency to which the judgment arguably led.80 and conditions.
More important than the controversy itself, however, is The unclear boundaries between these two categories
the administrative practice that followed the ruling. became apparent in the context of the Microsoft saga. In
Subsequent Commission decisions reveal that drawing its 2004 decision (Microsoft I), the Commission argued
the line between the respective scopes of application of that the licensing of Microsoft’s operating system –
Bronner and TeliaSonera is a difficult, if not impossible, Windows – had been made conditional upon the acqui-
exercise in practice. There is conduct in a grey area sition of Windows Media Player and took the view that
between the two that can be categorised either as a the practice amounted to unlawful tying.84 The remedy
refusal to deal within the meaning of Bronner (or applied to address the infringement – ordering
Commercial Solvents) or as a ‘margin squeeze’ within Microsoft to sell a version of Windows without
the meaning of TeliaSonera. Slovak Telekom illustrates Windows Media Player – is the sort of intervention that
this idea particularly well. This case involved one would expect in ordinary tying cases. Crucially, it

77 Guidance (n 59), paras 80–81. 81 Slovak Telekom (Case AT.39523) Commission Decision of 15 October
78 Pacific Bell Telephone Co v linkLine Communications, Inc, 555 US 438 2014.
(2009). 82 Ibid, paras 363–371.
79 Submission of the Commission in Case C-52/09, on file with the author. 83 Case T-851/14 Slovak Telekom, a.s. v Commission, EU:T:2018:929 and
80 For a discussion of the issues, see O’Donoghue and Padilla (n 33) Case C-165/19 P Slovak Telekom, a.s. v Commission, pending.
399–404. 84 Microsoft (Case COMP/C-3/37.792) Commission Decision of 24 May
2004, paras 792–989.
12 of 15 ARTICLE Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2019

failed. The evolution of markets showed that there was imposed, and gave rise to litigation regarding the
no demand for the operating system without a media appropriate price point that would only be solved sev-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


player functionality.85 The remedy endorsed in its eral years later.90
2009 decision (Microsoft II) was, unsurprisingly, dif- The positive obligations imposed in refusal to deal
ferent in nature. This second case was closed once scenarios contrast greatly with the negative remedies
Microsoft accepted, inter alia, a ‘must-carry’ obliga- imposed in ‘margin squeeze’ cases like Deutsche
tion, whereby the operating system would present Telekom. In that case, the infringement could be
users with a ‘ballot box’ displaying Microsoft’s product brought to an end simply by imposing a cease-and-
(Internet Explorer) together with rival web browsers.86 desist order on the company.91 The fundamental differ-
As observed by commentators at the time, this remedy ence with Bronner – and the reason a negative remedy
suggested that the case was not so much about tying – was enough to bring the dominant firm’s behaviour in
even though the Commission presented it as such – as line with Article 102 TFEU – relates to the regulatory
about a refusal to deal.87 After all, the ‘ballot box’ rem- context underpinning the practice. Unlike refusal to
edy in the case can be seen as a way of regulating the deal cases like Magill or Commercial Solvents, there was
conditions of access to a platform – the operating already a sector-specific regime in place that ensured
system. that access to the infrastructure would be granted, and
this, on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory condi-
tions.92 The positive obligations, in other words, existed
B. The remedy determines the applicability of the already by virtue of the applicable regulatory frame-
‘enhanced effects test’ work, and did not have to be created via the application
There is a way in which Bronner/Commercial Solvents, of Article 102 TFEU.
on the one hand, and TeliaSonera, on the other, can Against this background, the scope of application of
be reconciled. As already observed, the factual the two sets of tests seems clear. What seems to deter-
scenario behind the two cases is similar, and it is rea- mine the application of one test or the other is not the
sonable to view a ‘margin squeeze’ as a specific mani- label given to the practice (that is, whether conduct is
festation of a refusal to deal. There is, however, a key formally presented as a ‘margin squeeze’ or a refusal to
difference between the two lines of case law, which is deal) but the remedy to bring the infringement to an
the remedy. In scenarios like those at stake in Bronner end. There can indeed be refusal to deal instances sub-
or Commercial Solvents, a finding of liability demands ject to a ‘standard effects’ test and, vice versa, ‘margin
from a court or authority the imposition of positive squeeze’ behaviour subject to the stricter test. The latter
obligations – an obligation to supply, assorted with – ‘enhanced effects’ – appears appropriate whenever
other conditions relating, typically, to the price at remedial action would lead to the imposition of positive
which supplies are to take place. The case law provides obligations on firms – including, as already mentioned,
several examples of what the implementation of these an obligation to supply on regulated terms and condi-
obligations involves in practice. In Commercial tions. As the examples discussed above show, the
Solvents, the Commission prescribed the quantities to design, implementation and/or monitoring of these pro-
be supplied to a downstream rival and set a maximum active remedies is inherently more complex. The ‘stand-
price for these supplies.88 In Magill, three broadcasters ard effects’ test, on the other hand, seems appropriate in
were required to license their information on a non- instances where remedial action does not go beyond the
discriminatory basis to each other and to any request- negative obligations – a cease-and-desist order, possibly
ing third party.89 In Microsoft, a similar obligation was assorted with a fine.

85 ‘EU ruling on Microsoft ‘flawed’’ (BBC News 24 April 2006) (‘‘As of 89 See Article 2 of Magill TV Guide/ITP, BBC and RTE (Case IV/31.851)
today no PC maker has shipped a version of XPN […] not a single one’ Commission Decision 89/205/EEC [1989]
said Microsoft’s lawyer, Jean-Francois Bellis, noting that such companies OJ L78/43.
accounted for nine out of 10 sales of Windows. As for the rest, stores 90 Article 5 of the Commission Decision in Microsoft I (n 83). See also
ordered 1,787 copies of XPN among 35 m copies of Windows, giving it Microsoft (Case COMP/C-3/37.792) Commission Decision of
an order ratio of 0.005%, he said’). Commission Decision of 27 February 2008 fixing the definitive amount
86 Microsoft II (n 46). of the periodic penalty payment imposed on Microsoft Corporation
87 Nicolas Petit and Norman Neyrinck, ‘Back to Microsoft I and II: Tying Decision C(2005)4420 final and Case T-167/08, Microsoft Corp v
and the Art of Secret Magic’ (2011) 2 Journal of European Competition Commission, EU:T:2012:323.
Law & Practice 117. 91 See Article 3 of Deutsche Telekom AG (Case COMP/C-1/37.451, 37.578,
88 See Article 2 of Zoja/CSC-ICI (Case IV/26.911) Commission Decision 72/ 37.579) Commission Decision 2003/707/EC [2003] OJ L263/9.
457/CEE [1972] OJ L299/51. 92 Ibid, paras 15–25.
Pablo Ibáñez Colomo . Legal Tests in EU Competition Law ARTICLE 13 of 15

The dilemma posed by Slovak Telekom can be easily C. The rationale behind the ‘enhanced effects’
solved by reference to this framework. The two sets of test

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


practices in the case – ‘margin squeeze’ and refusal to
A legal filter such as the indispensability condition
deal – were evaluated by the Commission under a
ensures that, where intervention is proactive in nature
‘standard effects’ test, the choice of which was validated
(that is, where remedial action takes the form of positive
at first instance by the General Court.93 This is a sens-
obligations), liability is only established in exceptional
ible outcome that is line with the logic underpinning
circumstances. The introduction of this legal filter
the preceding case law. Remedial action in that case did
comes across as a sensible aspect of the case law. First
not involve setting up a regulatory apparatus by means
(and this is something discussed above), proactive rem-
of positive obligations. In fact, it would be appropriate
edies are inherently more complex to design, monitor
to characterise Slovak Telekom’s behaviour as an
and implement. With increased complexity the likeli-
attempt to avoid the regulatory constraints imposed by
hood that the remedy is ineffective also rises, as does
the sector-specific regime, and more precisely its obliga-
the likelihood that intervention has unintended conse-
tions relating to the unbundling of the local loop.94 As
quences. From this perspective, the failure of the Media
in Deutsche Telekom, the sector-specific regime defined
Player remedy in Microsoft I would not be an isolated
in detail the conditions under which the said firm had
instance, but a recurrent and foreseeable issue that can
to share its facilities with rivals. The ways in which the
be expected to emerge whenever positive obligations are
incumbent operator sought to avoid such obligations
imposed. These difficulties came to the fore again in
feature prominently in the decision.95
Google Shopping.96 Instead of crafting a particular rem-
These insights are also useful to identify the circum-
edy, the Commission left it for the firm to decide how
stances in which an ‘enhanced effects’ test may be neces-
to bring the infringement to an end.97 Not only did this
sary to establish liability in a case that is presented as an
approach prove controversial,98 but it extended the legal
instance of tying. As already mentioned, the formal label
uncertainty after the adoption of the decision.99
that is attached to the practice – tying or any other –
Second, one should bear in mind that, in EU compe-
would not be decisive. The relevant question relates
tition law, the restrictive nature of practices is not exam-
instead to the way in which the hypothetical infringe-
ined from an ex post perspective alone. Ex ante
ment would be brought to an end. In a traditional
considerations play a crucial role in the analysis – and
instance of tying, where coercion is achieved by means
this is true across the board. For instance, such consid-
of a contractual device, a negative obligation – an obliga-
erations help explain why franchising and selective dis-
tion not to condition the sale of product A to the sale of
tribution are prima facie lawful under Article 101(1)
product B – will typically address any concerns. Things
TFEU. If these vertical restraints were evaluated by ref-
are likely to be different in some of the scenarios
erence to ex post factors alone, they could be found to
described above, which involve the design and/or the
restrict inter-brand and intra-brand competition in a
technical integration of products. A negative obligation
variety of ways. Once the ex ante perspective is intro-
in the Microsoft I case failed to address any concerns. As
duced, however, it becomes safe to presume that, absent
Microsoft II showed, only proactive remedies were effect-
some core restraints, suppliers would simply not have
ive in that context. This fact reveals that the underlying
recourse to some distribution methods, including the
concerns related not so much to the combined sales of
abovementioned two. It is also in light of these same ex
two products as to the very design of the operating sys-
ante considerations – and for the same reasons – that
tem – and more precisely to the conditions of access by
conduct that is prima facie unlawful irrespective of its
competing software providers to this operating system.
effects can escape the prohibition. When firms claim
As explained by the commentators cited above, the rem-
that a practice is incapable of restricting competition
edy suggests that the case, however labelled, had more in
insofar as it is objectively necessary to attain a pro-
common with cases like Bronner than with traditional
competitive aim, they claim, in essence, that, seen ex
tying scenarios like the one at stake in Hilti.

93 See Commission Decision in Slovak Telekom (n 81) and Case T-851/14 98 See for instance Gary Reback, ‘Google outwits the European Commission
Slovak Telekom (n 83). once again’ Financial Times (London, 26 October 2017); and Matt
94 Commission Decision in Slovak Telekom (n 81), paras 36–49. Richards, ‘Google not complying with shopping remedies, rivals claim’
95 Ibid, paras 428–821. Global Competition Review (London, 22 November 2018).
96 Google Search (Shopping) (Case AT.39740) Commission Decision of 27 99 Rochelle Toplensky, ‘Google overhauls European search results to avoid
June 2017. probe’ Financial Times (London, 19 March 2019).
97 Ibid, Articles 3–5.
14 of 15 ARTICLE Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2019

ante, the practice in question enables, rather than conditions are fulfilled: first, the practice subject to this
restricts, competition. prohibition rule is deemed to have no purpose other

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


From an ex ante perspective, the factual scenarios than the restriction of competition and, second, it is
subject to the ‘enhanced effects’ test, on the one hand, deemed capable of having anticompetitive effects. It is
and franchising and selective distribution agreements, on possible for a firm to escape the prima facie prohibition
the other, are not fundamentally different. In the same by providing evidence showing that the practice is
way that one cannot expect franchising or selective distri- incapable of restricting competition in a specific eco-
bution to exist absent some core restraints, one cannot nomic and legal context. This point has been confirmed
simply assume that a firm would invest in the creation by the Court in Murphy (in relation to Article 101
or development of an infrastructure or intellectual prop- TFEU) and Intel (in relation to Article 102 TFEU).
erty if it does not have a reasonable prospect to appro- A firm can rebut the presumption in two ways: either
priate the fruits of its efforts. Put differently, one cannot by showing that the practice is objectively necessary to
take for granted that the competition enabled by the attain a pro-competitive aim or by showing that any
said efforts would have existed if the firms had been effect would not be attributable to its conduct.
required, from the outset, to deal with rivals (or, more The applicable remedy to bring an infringement to
generally, do business) on the terms and conditions pro- an end explains why the Court, in some instances,
actively set by a court or a competition authority – in applies an ‘enhanced effects’ test – as opposed to a
particular where these terms and conditions amount to ‘standard effects’ test. Thus, indispensability is required
subsidising rival entry. This basic insight is after all where the remedy involves the imposition of positive
behind the award of intellectual property rights and, obligations on a firm – such as remedies requiring a
more generally, the protection of property (whether tan- firm to supply an input to a rival (as in Magill) or to
gible or intangible).100 For the same reasons, a ‘standard redesign a product (as in Microsoft II). It is sensible to
effects’ test, which presumes that competition would set a higher bar when positive obligations are involved,
have existed in the absence of the practice, does not as the Court has done. The design, implementation and
seem to account for the peculiarities of these cases. monitoring of proactive remedies and the positive obli-
A higher threshold that restricts interference with ex gations they entail are all inherently more complex, and
ante incentives to a limited set of scenarios seems thus more prone to errors. Positive obligations may
appropriate instead. have unintended consequences or may prove ineffective.
Secondly, the stricter test is an acknowledgement that
one cannot simply assume that the competition created
VI. Conclusions by virtue of a practice would have existed under the
Legal tests in EU competition law can be grouped in terms and conditions determined by a court or an
four main categories. First, some practices are prima authority. It is a way of acknowledging, in other words,
facie unlawful irrespective of their effects (or subject to that ex ante considerations matter (and have always
a prohibition rule). Second, some are deemed prima mattered, since Société Technique Minière) in EU com-
facie lawful (or subject to a legality rule). Third, there is petition law analysis.
behaviour subject to a ‘standard effects’ test, which seeks A key corollary to the above is that the way in which
to ascertain whether it has, or is likely to have, anticom- practices are labelled cannot, and does not, determine
petitive effects in the economic and legal context in their legal status. Whether a practice is formally pre-
which it is implemented. Finally, an ‘enhanced effects’ sented as a form of tying or as a (constructive or out-
test applies in some instances. The ‘enhanced effects’ right) refusal to deal does not seem to be a relevant –
test involves showing – at the very least – that the input let alone crucial – factor when determining whether it is
to which access is requested is indispensable to compete subject to a ‘standard effects’ test or to an ‘enhanced
on a neighbouring market. This paper has sought to effects’ test instead. The relevant considerations, as
shed light on the practical operation of each of these already observed, are instead the issues raised by the prac-
tests and on why they apply in certain instances but not tice in the specific economic and legal context of which it
in others. is a part. There should be nothing surprising about this
As a matter of principle, conduct is prima facie pro- conclusion, which is very much in line with a consistent
hibited irrespective of its effects where two cumulative line of case law. Indeed, the Court has always emphasised

100 See, generally, William M Landes and Richard A Posner, The Economic
Structure of Intellectual Property Law (Harvard University Pres 2003).
Pablo Ibáñez Colomo . Legal Tests in EU Competition Law ARTICLE 15 of 15

that substance, not form, is the crucial consideration when action in exclusionary cases requires proactive
when establishing liability. remedies. It has long been understood, to give a con-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jeclap/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/jeclap/lpz045/5554316 by Georgetown University Library user on 26 August 2019


Exploitative practices are virtually absent from the crete example, that determining whether a price is
analysis. The main reason is that the relative scarcity excessive – let alone identifying what the fair price of a
of cases addressing these practices makes it difficult to product should be – is particularly difficult. In this
draw meaningful conclusions about the rationale and sense, the conclusions of this paper suggest that calls
operation of the relevant legal tests. At the same time, to refine the law so as to confine action against exploit-
this paper provides valuable insights that help explain ative conduct to truly exceptional circumstances may
why these cases have not been prioritised by the be justified.101
Commission. Addressing exploitative conduct gives
rise to similar (if not the same) challenges observed doi:10.1093/jeclap/lpz045

101 Massimo Motta and Alexandre de Streel, ‘Excessive Pricing in


Competition Law: Never say Never?’ in The Pros and Cons of High
Prices (Swedish Competition Authority 2007).

You might also like