Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 53

The Cadbury Code and Recurrent

Crisis: A Model for Corporate


Governance? Donald Nordberg
Visit to download the full and correct content document:
https://textbookfull.com/product/the-cadbury-code-and-recurrent-crisis-a-model-for-co
rporate-governance-donald-nordberg/
More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant
download maybe you interests ...

Corporate governance in the aftermath of the global


financial crisis, Volume IV : Emerging Issues in
Corporate Governance First Edition. Edition Rezaee

https://textbookfull.com/product/corporate-governance-in-the-
aftermath-of-the-global-financial-crisis-volume-iv-emerging-
issues-in-corporate-governance-first-edition-edition-rezaee/

Corporate Governance Christine A. Mallin

https://textbookfull.com/product/corporate-governance-christine-
a-mallin/

The Oxford Handbook of Corporate Law and Governance


Gordon

https://textbookfull.com/product/the-oxford-handbook-of-
corporate-law-and-governance-gordon/

Corporate Governance: A Pragmatic Guide for Auditors,


Directors, Investors, and Accountants 1st Edition
Vasant Raval

https://textbookfull.com/product/corporate-governance-a-
pragmatic-guide-for-auditors-directors-investors-and-
accountants-1st-edition-vasant-raval/
Social Responsibility And Corporate Governance: Volume
1: Preconditions For Integration Matjaž Mulej

https://textbookfull.com/product/social-responsibility-and-
corporate-governance-volume-1-preconditions-for-integration-
matjaz-mulej/

Responsible Corporate Governance Towards Sustainable


and Effective Governance Structures 1st Edition Maria
Aluchna

https://textbookfull.com/product/responsible-corporate-
governance-towards-sustainable-and-effective-governance-
structures-1st-edition-maria-aluchna/

The Oxford Handbook of Corporate Law and Governance


Oxford Handbooks Gordon

https://textbookfull.com/product/the-oxford-handbook-of-
corporate-law-and-governance-oxford-handbooks-gordon/

THE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 1st Edi


Mike Wright

https://textbookfull.com/product/the-oxford-handbook-of-
corporate-governance-1st-edition-mike-wright/

Corporate Governance and Organisational Performance:


The Impact of Board Structure Naeem Tabassum

https://textbookfull.com/product/corporate-governance-and-
organisational-performance-the-impact-of-board-structure-naeem-
tabassum/
The Cadbury Code and
Recurrent Crisis
A Model for Corporate
Governance?

Donald Nordberg
The Cadbury Code and Recurrent Crisis

“A fascinating book, tracing the development of the UK Corporate Governance


Code and highlighting its continuity through successive crises. It identifies areas
of controversy and challenge, intriguingly suggesting that ‘defeated logics’ are
merely suspended, perhaps poised to return. Essential interdisciplinary reading
for all those interested in the UK’s corporate governance system.”
—Andrew Johnston, Professor of Company Law and Corporate Governance,
School of Law, University of Warwick

“The importance of the Cadbury Committee and the codes of corporate gover-
nance that followed in shaping the current form and scope of possibility for
corporate governance in the UK can hardly be underestimated. Nordberg’s fasci-
nating account of the process by which these have been shaped by individuals
and institutions is a welcome examination of how the code developed over time,
what it achieved, and what it left undone. Those who care about how boards of
directors work and how that work is guided by policy can learn much from this
study.”
—Dr. Jeroen Veldman, Associate Professor, Nyenrode Business
University, The Netherlands

“Professor Nordberg provides a timely and thoughtful discussion on a topic


which, if anything, is even more important than it was some three decades ago.
Recurrent corporate governance crises indeed indicate that the current paradig-
matic approach to good corporate governance, with its focus on internal control,
risk management, audit, overseen by a board, and increasingly dependent on the
contribution of the independent director, may provide limited assurance as to
its ability to prevent further cases of governance failures. Since the early 1990s
we have seen increasingly damaging examples of governance failures which must
give rise to the question whether the various corporate governance codes, guides,
laws and formal reviews address the core problem of governance, how to prevent
those entrusted with the assets of others from abusing their position, to a satisfac-
tory degree. This is not purely an academic concern. Gross failures of governance
can touch upon the livelihoods of entire nations and increasingly impact on the
global community through the concept of ecological governance which aims at
incorporating issues of biodiversity and species extinction into the heart of the
governance model. The late Sir Adrian Cadbury created an admirable and world
leading guide to best governance practice, setting in motion a process of contin-
uously reviewing, refining, and updating a Code which endured the test of time
and is adopted across many jurisdictions. Nordberg’s book strongly contributes
to the debate on how to address an age-old problem in a rapidly changing envi-
ronment. By reflecting on current insights, urging to learn from past mistakes,
emphasising a broad discussion, and most of all, keeping an open mind to poten-
tial future solutions, Nordberg continues the great tradition of asking critical
questions without necessarily providing predetermined answers.”
—Oliver Marnet is Associate Professor in Accounting at the Southampton Business
School, who has written extensively on corporate governance and external audit,
and has provided written evidence to BEIS, CMA, ICSA, ICAEW, PIRC, the
European Commission, and the FRC’s Guidance on Board Effectiveness
Donald Nordberg

The Cadbury Code


and Recurrent Crisis
A Model for Corporate Governance?
Donald Nordberg
Bournemouth University Business School
Bournemouth, UK

ISBN 978-3-030-55221-3 ISBN 978-3-030-55222-0 (eBook)


https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-55222-0

© The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer
Nature Switzerland AG 2020
This work is subject to copyright. All rights are solely and exclusively licensed by the
Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights
of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on
microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and
retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology
now known or hereafter developed.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc.
in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such
names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for
general use.
The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and informa-
tion in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither
the publisher nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, expressed or implied, with
respect to the material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been
made. The publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps
and institutional affiliations.

Cover credit: © Melisa Hasan

This Palgrave Macmillan imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature
Switzerland AG
The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland
Acknowledgements

The ideas in this book grew from the observations of many scholars and
practitioners I have known or whose work I have found stimulating. At
the time of the Cadbury deliberations, I was an editorial executive for
the news agency Reuters, then based in New York. There we were preoc-
cupied by the collapse of the Soviet Union and an emerging economic
order based on triumphant capitalism. As journalists, however, we could
not escape the concern for colleagues when Robert Maxwell’s two UK-
listed corporations—Mirror Group Newspapers and Maxwell Communi-
cation—collapsed. Also, Maxwell had sat as non-executive director on the
Reuters board as it listed on the London Stock Exchange and rapidly
moved into the FTSE100 index, serving alongside his arch-rival Rupert
Murdoch.
But there was more. The demise of Maxwell’s companies was foreshad-
owed by fraudulent use of their pension funds to prop up his faltering
share prices. Those who lost their retirement savings included reporters
and editors at the New York Daily News, which Maxwell owned. For jour-
nalists, this governance failure was personal. When I returned to London
a few years later, I discovered that a strange term—‘corporate gover-
nance’—had entered the everyday discourse, not just of investors and
corporate directors, but of journalists as well.
By the time ‘Cadbury’ morphed into the ‘Combined Code’, I was
involved in shareholder relations and met Bernard Taylor at Henley
Management College, who convened an annual conference on board

v
vi ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

effectiveness. There I got to know the famous US activist investor and


author Robert A.G. Monks. Through Tomorrow’s Company—a project
of the Royal Society of the Arts—I joined debates about reforming
company law. I also met the governance academics at the Business
School at City University of London, among them Georges Selim and
Rob Melville. They introduced me to Terry McNulty from the Univer-
sity of Liverpool, who had led a research project for the 2003 Higgs
Review. He supervised my doctoral studies, which commenced just as the
global financial crisis began. This book revisits themes from that study and
includes sections adapted from an article in Economics and Business Review
for a special issue on corporate governance co-edited by my colleague at
Bournemouth University, Steve Letza, and used here with permission.
Other helpful suggestions came from Kevin Tennant, Suzanne Konzel-
mann, Jeroen Veldman, David Gindis, Dionysia Katelouzou, Gerhard
Schnyder, and Lez Rayman-Bacchus. They all listened to aspects of the
research that led to this volume and provided insights and encourage-
ment. Any mistakes, however, are my own.

September 2020 Donald Nordberg


Prologue

Since 1992, corporate governance in the UK and much of the world has
been articulated in codes of conduct, rather than formal law and regu-
lations or even less formal social arrangements. Moreover, despite their
gradual revision over the years, their core tenets survived despite repeated
and arguably growing shocks to the system they were meant to protect.
That suggests the problems they sought to address have not been solved.
Britain—in particular its banks—was perhaps the worst hit by the global
financial crisis, at a cost to the state that continues more than a decade
later. How did various revisions fail to undertake fresh approaches to the
recurring crises?
This book explores how corporate governance in Britain came to be
codified, what key disputes took place during its major revisions, and how
it institutionalised a way of viewing what corporate governance should be.
This study also suggests that the while the flexibility that was built into the
code’s compliance regime allowed for variations, few companies took the
opportunities provided to experiment with other ways of organisation the
work of boards of directors. The code is much admired, with good reason.
And it has achieved wide legitimacy. But is it the model for corporate
governance?
The Cadbury Code and Report was the starting point for this new
direction. It combined a set of principles of good governance that served

vii
viii PROLOGUE

as a how to guide for listed companies. It established a regulatory frame-


work that guided equity capital markets and proposed ways that share-
holders—principally institutional investors—should relate to the compa-
nies in which they invest. This framework was loose because of a central
plank of the code: it was to be voluntary, subject the requirement
that companies explain why they decided not to comply. Although the
Cadbury Code did not use the phrase, this idea quickly attracted the label
‘comply-or-explain’.
Moreover, the influence of this domestic exercise was vast. The code’s
ideas were copied in countries around the world, from France to South
Africa to Germany, then to much of Africa and South America, and to
Russia and Japan. One of its core tenets even found its way into the listing
requirements of the New York Stock Exchange and Nasdaq, despite wide
criticism from American CEOs: the provision concerning the separation
of roles of the company chair and the chief executive officer (CEO), to
prevent one person having ‘unfettered’ boardroom control. There, too,
‘comply-or-explain’ applied.
The code’s influence grew even larger. Its principles informed other
codes, often written by professional bodies for a wide range of organi-
sation types far removed from the world of capital markets, investment
portfolios, and even shareholders.
The UK code of corporate governance is widely admired and imitated,
but it has not prevented the types of emergency that led to its creation—
recurring failures of large corporations because of the lack of oversight and
internal control. The biggest case was the financial crisis of 2007–2009,
in which the UK suffered disproportionate damage, as we shall see.
Were we expecting too much of a code of conduct? Why did the
framers of the code not recommend something stronger than a voluntary
code of conduct?
This study examines those questions through analysis of the debates
that led up to the drafting of the original Cadbury Code and then the
major revisions undertaken in 2003 and 2010 in response to renewed
crises. It does so through a critical discourse analysis of contributions
to the consultations that informed the drafting, undertaken against the
economic and political context that shaped the code and was then shaped
by it.
It shows, historically, how the process engaged actors from all parts
of the chain of investment, and how that process embedded power in the
hands of central actors. Theoretically, it shows how the logics employed in
PROLOGUE ix

the debate became institutionalised, but also how the form of their insti-
tutionalisation provided opportunities for change, leaving rejected logics
suspended not defeated, so they could resurface later, which enhanced
the legitimacy of the process. Practically, it demonstrates how the code’s
flexibility forestalled more radical action and won acceptance even among
those whose views it rejected.
The crisis in corporate governance is one MacAvoy and Millstein call
‘recurrent’. ‘The turnaround began taking place in the mid-1990s … The
die was cast for effective governance through board structure and process
and we could move on … but the new form was not universally and
instantaneously followed by changes in conduct’ (2003, pp. 2–3). They
were writing just as US financial markets had just been rocked by failures
of very large corporations, the collapse of the market in new technology
companies, and the implosion of one of the five global accountancy and
audit firms. They expressed their concern that the responses, in regula-
tion and corporate behaviour would prove disappointing. There was some
change in US practice, which included translating some aspects of UK
corporate governance into US listing requirements. Yet before the decade
was out, both countries would experience an even more serious corporate
governance crisis.
This study examines how the UK reforms, enacted in the 1990s and
repeatedly revised, kept options for different responses open to debate
but nonetheless left them unexplored in practice. It questions what might
have happened if the roads not taken had been followed, perhaps as exper-
iments rather than policy, and if in practice the code had been followed
with the degrees of freedom that its language of explanation proposed.
Instead of striving for formal compliance, and thus escape enforcement
via investors and the proxy voting agencies they employed, corporate
boards might have adopted a more thoughtful approach. They might
have adapted code recommendations and innovated in board design and
process to suit the peculiar circumstances of the company, rather than
shaping the board and its processes to fit the code. What sort of ethos
might then have developed?

Reference
MacAvoy, P., & Millstein, I. (2003). The recurrent crisis: in corporate governance.
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Contents

1 Successes in Corporate Governance—Or Failures? 1


References 12

2 The Problems and Remedies in Corporate Governance 15


Diagnoses in Corporate Governance 16
Boards and Management 17
Corporations and Shareholders 18
Corporations and Society 19
Remedies in Corporate Governance 19
The Ethics 20
The Politics 21
The Institutions 22
References 24

3 Codes and Their Contexts 29


Economic and Market Triggers and Code Response 32
The Political Context 34
References 36

4 Institutions, Logics, and Power 39


References 43

xi
xii CONTENTS

5 Issues Contested in the UK Code 45


Board Design 46
Boardroom Ethos 47
Compliance and Enforcement 49
The Unsettled Debates 50
References 51

6 Shape of the Board 53


Board Design in the 1992 Cadbury Debate 54
Investor Reactions 56
Accountancy Reactions 59
Corporate Reactions 61
Support for Two-Tier Boards 64
Board Design in the 2003, Post-Higgs Debate 67
Board Design in the 2009–2010, Post-financial Crisis Debate 70
Institutionalising Board Design 71
References 72

7 Ethos and Explanation 75


Boardroom Ethos 76
Board Ethos in the Cadbury Debate 76
Board Ethos in the Post-Higgs Debate 78
Board Ethos in the Post-financial Crisis Debate 80
Voices Present but Missing from This Debate 84
Explain, or Just Comply? 85
Compliance in the Cadbury Debate, 1992 85
Compliance in the Combined Code of 2003 86
The Dispute Over ‘Comply’ in the 2009–2010 Debate 88
Board Ethos, Corporate Explanation 90
References 91

8 Discussion 93
Institutions, Logics, and Work in Writing the UK Code 94
An Institution in Search of a Logic 94
Institutional Work in Corporate Governance 97
Codification and Identity 99
Process of Codification 100
Experimentation, and the Lack Thereof 104
CONTENTS xiii

Revisiting the Framework of Corporate Governance 106


Ethics and Ethos 106
Politics and Power 107
Institutionalisation—Benefits and Drawbacks 110
Fit with the Changing Context—Can the Centre Hold? 112
Changing Investors 113
Changing Investment Landscape 115
Changing Corporate Landscape 116
Implications for Process of Writing the Code 117
References 118

9 Conclusions 123
References 128

Epilogue 131

Appendix A—Research Methods 137

Appendix B—UK Share Ownership 141

Index 145
About the Author

Donald Nordberg is Associate Professor at Bournemouth University in


the UK and author of Corporate Governance: Principles and Issues (Sage,
2011). His research has been published in many journals, including
Corporate Governance: An International Review, Business History, Leader-
ship, Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance, European Manage-
ment Journal, and Philosophy of Management. He is also a governance
practitioner: chair of a major UK social care provider and non-executive
director of a company in the performing arts. Earlier he was a corre-
spondent and editorial executive at Reuters, based in London, Frankfurt,
Zurich, and New York. A native of Chicago, he was educated in the US
at Reed College in Portland, Oregon, and the University of Illinois at
Urbana-Champaign, and in Britain at the Universities of Warwick and
Liverpool.

xv
List of Figures

Fig. 2.1 A framework for board decisions 23


Fig. 8.1 Codification process 101
Fig. 8.2 Framework of board decisions, revisited 108
Fig. 8.3 UK equities by ownership type 1992, 2018 (Adapted from
ONS data) 114

xvii
List of Tables

Table 6.1 Responses of investors to Cadbury draft on board design 57


Table 6.2 Accountants’ responses to Cadbury draft on board design 60
Table 6.3 Corporate reaction to Cadbury draft on board design 62
Table B.1 The UK share ownership by type of investor, in % 141

xix
CHAPTER 1

Successes in Corporate
Governance—Or Failures?

Abstract Codes of corporate governance around the world have drawn


inspiration from the UK’s Cadbury Code and its subsequent iterations.
This widely admired and imitated regulative measure emerged from a
crisis in corporate governance and was designed in part to prevent corpo-
ration collapses. In the past three decades, however, corporate collapses
have continued and even intensified in impact. The chapter asks: In what
ways has codifying corporate governance succeeded? In what ways has it
failed?

Keywords Codes of corporate governance · Success · Failure

For nearly 30 years, corporate governance in the UK—and in the many


countries that followed its lead—has been defined in terms of a code
of conduct. It was a project conceived in a crisis and then gestated
through long processes of consultation, drafting, more consultation,
further drafting. It was an effort that engaged the sceptical, confronted
the hostile, and eventually won over a large body of believers, many who
have invested time, talent, and faith in both the code and the process
through which it was created.
The decision to codify what constitutes good, or even best, practice
in corporate governance is frequently seen as a masterstroke of regu-
latory genius. Though its authors could not have anticipated it at the

© The Author(s) 2020 1


D. Nordberg, The Cadbury Code and Recurrent Crisis,
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-55222-0_1
2 D. NORDBERG

outset, this voluntary arrangement—with very little punishment possible


for non-compliance—has all but extinguished pressure for what might
have been the alternative: a regime of regulation with tough civil or
criminal sanctions. But that does not mean that all is well.
Veldman and Willmott (2016), for example, warn of the limits of soft
regulation, like codes. What they call the ‘reflexive governance’ of codes
and comply or explain ‘promises to forestall potential pathologies and
crises that threaten confidence in corporate governance, and so bestows
upon the Code a degree of credibility and legitimacy’. At the same time,
however, it ‘supports a particular, financialized political economy where
the claims of wider constituencies are marginalized or even excluded’
(Veldman & Willmott, 2016, p. 583). Their observations highlight a
central problem in corporate governance and codes, however. As we shall
explore, if the freedom of explanation as a means of compliance leads
to reflexive, double-loop learning then it holds the promise of innova-
tive and even transformative governance. If it degenerates into surface
compliance and embeds power relationships, it can squeeze out other
voices, lose insights that mayvan benefit the company, and in time sap
the legitimacy of the code and the corporation. The alternative—hard
regulation, with legal enforcement to ensure those ‘wider constituencies’
share power—risks creating a regime that lacks flexibility to respond to
changing contexts.
This was a code fashioned for a particular crisis, in a particular country,
at a particular stage in the evolution of its capital markets, and at
particularly febrile moment in the politics of Britain. Yet that code—
initially named The Cadbury Code, after its principal author, the late Sir
Adrian Cadbury—has been widely imitated across geographies, institu-
tional systems, and market contexts. The principles it established have
found their way into codes written for other organisational types as well.
Charities, trade associations, neighbourhood committees, government
departments, and even parliament itself have copied its key recommen-
dations, sometimes verbatim. Those recommendations thus inform what
are often labelled as ‘corporate governance reports’ by entities that have
nothing else in common with the world of corporations, listed on stock
exchanges, with diverse and dispersed shareholders, the world for which
the code was designed.
Moreover, the process of its development has come to have many
imitators. It came about through a temporary body, established outside
government, without statutory grounding, with no power to compel
1 SUCCESSES IN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE—OR FAILURES? 3

participation in its fact-gathering. That unofficial, non-governmental


rule-making body nonetheless gained legitimacy, and not just among
those directly affected, but in the broader public as well. The Cadbury
Committee held consultations, informal and formal, filtering ideas
through a draft and then modifying the draft, and then building a
timetable for reviewing the ‘final’ version two years later, and then
roughly two years after that. The cycle of opportunities for revisions arose
through custom and practice, not a stipulation of an expiry date, and it
has persisted through nearly 30 years of practice. This winnowing and
filtering and revisiting makes it a living document, constantly open to revi-
sion, a standard in perpetual motion that nonetheless provides an anchor
to the way corporate governance works.
The language of the code and the discourse it created have evolved
over time in ways that suggest that its various authors are not compla-
cent (Nordberg & McNulty, 2013), but its core principles are remarkably
unchanged. According to Price, Harvey, Maclean, and Campbell (2018,
p. 1557) that stability shows the code ‘is institutionally embedded and
subject to institutional stasis’.
The original code (Cadbury, 1992) developed in response to a series
of corporate failures, and its major revisions in 2003 and 2010 were
motivated by similar and arguably more systemic problems in corporate
governance. Indeed, the global financial crisis of 2007–2009 nearly paral-
ysed the world’s financial system and triggered a recession of a scale not
seen since the 1930s. The UK was especially hard-hit, seeing its first run
on a bank since the mid-nineteenth Century.1 That bank was nation-
alised; and as the crisis spread around the world, Britain was forced to
part-nationalise two much larger banks, one of which had claimed the
distinction of being the world’s largest.
The UK code has focused attention on improving board effective-
ness, and it clearly succeeded in getting boards to work harder. The
time commitment that directors make has expanded. Board committees
meet more frequently, and board papers are generally more detailed.
Remuneration of non-executive directors has grown too. Direct data
on this is hard to come by across the time since the Cadbury Code,
as reporting requirements came into place only towards the end of the

1 A small bank: Northern Rock. Unlike other major economies, Britain escaped from
both the Wall Street Crash of 1929 and the Great Financial Crisis of 1914 without a
bank run. See Roberts (2014).
4 D. NORDBERG

1990s. However, one study showed that during a period of modest infla-
tion in the economy, from just before Enron imploded in 2001 to just
after the worst of the post-financial crisis recession had passed, director
fees for listed UK companies roughly doubled (Goh & Gupta, 2016).
It also demonstrated, against the grain of ‘tougher’ governance, that
fees increased more for well-connected non-executive directors, those
with wide personal networks among directors of other companies, and
rather less for those with characteristics that might lead them to hold
management to account.
But if the ambition of codes of corporate governance is to forestall
corporate collapse, how did the code—through repeated consultations
and reformulation, over two decades—fail to seek out other solutions,
even as experiments? Why haven’t we seen more vigorous interven-
tions—in law and regulation—with greater compulsion, to compensate
for the deficiency of what is, in effect, a voluntary code? These ques-
tions resonate in fields of public and organisational policy well beyond
corporate governance.
This study examines the first question through analysis of the discourse
developed as the code was being created and how its major revisions were
conducted. That analysis considers the economic and political context in
which the code developed, as well as the language in which the debate
was conducted and the resulting discourse it created. It addresses the
second through context-driven interpretation of those findings, which
then leads to unanswered questions that provide a direction for future
research in corporate governance and other fields. It does so by consid-
ering the process through which the code became institutionalised and
then came to be taken for granted as ‘good’ (Hodge, 2017), or even
‘best’ (Seidl, Sanderson, & Roberts, 2013) practice.
Many of the code’s provisions won over hearts and minds quickly,
conforming to common sense and confirming existing custom and prac-
tice at many listed companies. Boards are responsible for the business.
They should challenge management. That means they need in general
to be independent of management, though the definition of indepen-
dence might be difficult to discern from the outside. Directors should be
conscientious, paying close attention to the information they receive. To
do justice to the big issues, the code specified that certain tasks should be
delegated in the first instance to committees—remuneration, audit, and
nominating new directors, including importantly the chief executive.
1 SUCCESSES IN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE—OR FAILURES? 5

Somewhat controversial in 1992 was the stipulation that the role of


chairman and chief executive should not be combined. At many compa-
nies, however, this practice was already in place, reducing opposition to
the idea and making opponents seem self-serving, rather than serving
shareholder interests. Even though empirical evidence of its benefit
is mixed (Elsayed, 2007; Krause, Semadeni, & Cannella, 2014), this
provision became a hallmark of good corporate governance around the
world.
Over the years additional layers were added. A 1995 review of execu-
tive pay urged boards to pay greater attention to ensuring that executive
directors were not involved in decisions over executive pay. A 1998
review discussed interactions with major shareholders, seeking ongoing
and constructive dialogue. There were dangers in this, as such investors
might become privy the inside information and then not be able to trade
shares in the company, so investors were reluctant to get too involved.
Moreover, engagement with corporations was seen as expensive. Large
institutional fund managers, with hundreds of companies in the port-
folio and perhaps a thousand on the watch list, would require an army
of analysts to keep track of the companies and then engage in dialogue.
Companies would then face that army and their cacophony of opinions
about what the company should do next. But the guidance was broad,
non-specific, and easily avoided: ‘comply-or-explain’ is a very useful tool.
These guidelines were added to the Cadbury provisions, creating in
1998 a ‘Combined Code’ on corporate governance (see Committee on
Corporate Governance, 2000).
This was a relatively stress-free time in capital markets. The Labour
government elected in 1997 had avoided much of the feared anti-business
prescriptions, and after quickly setting in motion a major review of
Company Law, it then delayed any changes for several years. It had
come to appreciate the complexity and the depth of opposition. By 2003,
however, after a global crisis in corporate governance, the institutional
and market context would shift.
The 2001 collapse of Enron in the US, followed by WorldCom,
Tyco, and others, revealed flaws in the US system. The outcome was a
sharp legal and regulatory turn in the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (Library of
Congress, 2002), which prescribed much greater disclosure and director
duties, yet failed to address some of the key faults in governance exposed
by Enron and others (Nordberg, 2008). Moreover, this proved not
to be a US-specific crisis. Problems also arose in continental Europe
6 D. NORDBERG

(Ahold, Parmalat), Australia (HIH Holdings), and elsewhere (Deakin &


Konzelmann, 2004). While the UK was not directly affected in a big
way, it was difficult for the government to let things stay the same.
Company Law reform was back on the agenda, eventually taking effect
from 2006, and placing specific duties on company directors for the first
time (UK Government, 2007; UK Parliament, 2006). The corporate
governance code would also undergo a major revision (FRC, 2003).
Minor revisions followed in 2006 and 2008, the latter published just
as the global financial crisis struck, in which UK banks were among
those most damaged, and for reasons that were as much home-grown
as imported (Bank of England, 2015; FSA, 2011). A revision of the
Combined Code, scheduled for 2010, was brought forward a year. It
took the form of a three-stage consultation and took 18 months, before
the code was finally published in 2010. Even before that, the government
ordered a specific review of corporate governance for financial institutions,
which argued in part that bank governance might need to be different
from non-financial companies (Walker, 2009).
As Nordberg and McNulty (2013) demonstrate, the major revisions to
the code left the core principles largely unaltered, but they did involve a
shift in tone. The Cadbury Code (1992) emphasised in its selection of
metaphor and other language features the need for structures to provide
a foundation for good governance:

Our proposals aim to strengthen the unitary board system and increase its
effectiveness, not to replace it. (Paragraph 1.8)

The effectiveness of a board is buttressed by its structure and procedures.


One aspect of structure is the appointment of committees of the board,
such as the audit, remuneration and nomination committees. (Paragraph
4.21)

Raising standards of corporate governance cannot be achieved by structures


and rules alone. They are important because they provide a framework
which will encourage and support good governance. (Paragraph 3.13)

The symbolism was quiet, working in the rhetorical background to let


its prime audiences of directors and investors understand its purpose:
‘buttresses’ of structure and procedure ‘strengthen’ corporate gover-
nance, overcoming the weakness which had led to the series of corporate
1 SUCCESSES IN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE—OR FAILURES? 7

collapses. That it would be a ‘framework’ told them that there was still
much to be filled in. Director and management discretion would be
constrained but not eliminated.
That first code did not invent the idea of board committees; they
already existed in many companies, partly a mechanism for efficiency,
partly through imitating practice that had developed in the US, partic-
ularly for committees to consider audit issues. It put committees—for
nominating new directors, including the chief executive officer; for remu-
neration of the executives; and for audit—at the forefront of the code.
It structured their practice by giving non-executive directors a prominent
role. As we shall see, these structural elements of board design were rather
controversial and remained so in the early years.
The 2003 revision to the Combined Code, without changing the struc-
tures, shifted the weight of emphasis to director independence. While
Cadbury had given special value to the non-executive directors, the
experience of corporate collapses abroad—importantly in the US—raised
doubts about whether just being non-executive gave enough protection
against managerial power. In the worst US collapses, the outside directors
were anything but independent. Studies of board interlocks—directors
sitting on the boards of companies with directors on the other firm’s
board—show the presence of cosy relationships, which can impede crit-
ical thinking and boardroom challenge (Shipilov, Greve, & Rowley, 2010)
and increase executive pay (Hallock, 1997). Some of the evidence of
US experience post-Enron suggests board interlocks continue to be a
large and even growing part of the corporate landscape (Withers, Kim,
& Howard, 2018).
In the UK, a review of the effectiveness of non-executive directors,
conducted by the former investment banker Derek Higgs (2003), called
for sweeping changes. Unlike the Cadbury Committee, the Higgs Review
was directly a government intervention. It urged that all three board
committees be controlled by, not just include, non-executive directors
who had no ties to management. His recommendations were controver-
sial, as we shall see, and were not incorporated in their entirety in the new
Combined Code (FRC, 2003). But non-executives not deemed indepen-
dent almost vanished from the code. In the Cadbury Code, at least a
third of board members were supposed to be non-executive and most of
them independent; in 2003, at least half the seats should be held by non-
executives, all of whom would be independent. Moreover, in the 2003
8 D. NORDBERG

code, the chair should meet the standards of independence at the time of
appointment. No longer should a CEO ‘retire’ to the chairmanship.
In 2010, the post-financial crisis code left the Cadbury structures
and principles largely intact; the changes not only maintained but also
strengthened board independence. But in its diction and tone, the
renamed UK Corporate Governance Code (FRC, 2010) also placed
greater emphasis on relationships—between directors themselves, and
between the board and shareholders. In a new section near the start with
the heading ‘Comply or Explain’, it said:

The ‘comply or explain’ approach is the trademark of corporate governance


in the UK. It has been in operation since the Code’s beginnings and is
the foundation of the Code’s flexibility. It is strongly supported by both
companies and shareholders and has been widely admired and imitated
internationally.
The Code is not a rigid set of rules…. (‘Comply or Explain,’ Paragraphs
1–2)

The alliterations—‘foundation … flexibility’, then ‘not a rigid set of


rules’—build the sense that the structures of 1992 and the independence
in 2003 had missed something important. The equivalent section in the
Cadbury Code of 1992 is labelled simply ‘Compliance’, not a ringing call
for explanation:

Raising standards of corporate governance cannot be achieved by structures


and rules alone. They are important because they provide a framework
which will encourage and support good governance, but what counts is
the way in which they are put to use. (Paragraph 3.13)

Cadbury built structures and frameworks and placed the emphasis there,
while acknowledging that ‘what counts’ might lie elsewhere. The 2010
code encourages its principal audiences—directors and investors—to bend
the rules and pay more attention to what Cadbury thought ‘counts’. This
new code was, as Nordberg and McNulty (2013) put it, a recognition as
much of the limitations of codification as of its possibilities.
During these major revisions after crises, as well as the other peri-
odic reviews, the key principles and specific recommendations of the
code were left largely unchanged. Gradually other recommendations were
added, for example, on membership of and attendance at board commit-
tees, gender diversity, and board evaluation (Nordberg & Booth, 2019).
1 SUCCESSES IN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE—OR FAILURES? 9

These changes added layers of specific measures that required compli-


ance, albeit under the ‘comply-or-explain’ principle. Governance reports
became a regular reporting requirement, and then became longer and
more detailed, written increasingly in routine, standardised language, and
composed by public relations consultants who wrote the non-financial
sections of annual reports.
In the 2010 revision, the principal author, Sir Christopher Hogg,
warned against this ‘fungus’ of ‘boiler-plate’ (Paragraph 7), urging
company chairs to take personal responsibility of the governance report.2
The danger he saw was that corporate governance might become even
more of a ‘box-ticking’ exercise, and thus detract from the important
matter of strengthening board relationships and engaging in serious
debates.
The broad agreement on key elements of the code no doubt helped it
become institutionalised, that is, accepted as legitimate by most people
affected and largely taken for granted. But that does not mean these
consultations lacked controversy. Far from it. What was at stake in the
debates were issues that might have upset the established order. Much of
the custom and practice of boards pre-dated Cadbury. It also threatened
to upset existing power structures, including the balance of discretion
between corporate management, boards of directors, and shareholders.
Codifying new ways of working could open the door to more radical
measures—work representation on boards, rights to other constituencies,
constraints on direction and managerial discretion, revisions to the nature
of the accountability of audit.
This study focuses on three recurrent issues, ones that aroused contro-
versy in 1992 and would not go away: (a) board design, that is, its
structure and composition; (b) the resulting effects on the prevalent tone,
the custom and practice, that is, the ethos of the boardroom; and (c)
the nature of compliance. By examining the rhetoric in arguments used
by participants in the public consultations that led to the three major
versions of the code, we see how the language of the code and the

2 The 2010 code makes this recommendation. That it was the view of the Sir Christo-
pher comes from a personal conversation with the author of this study undertaken after
the code was published. Sir Christopher was chair of the Financial Reporting Council at
the time. A former CEO (of Courtaulds plc) and chairman (of Reuters Group plc), he
had in 1992 also served as adviser to Sir Adrian Cadbury in the later stages of formulating
the first code.
10 D. NORDBERG

discourse it created reflected the power dynamics in the system of corpo-


rate governance. Once its legitimacy was established, the code became
an impediment to more radical revisions. Veldman and Willmott (2016,
p. 581) discuss this process as one of a ‘single loop of reflexivity’, but one
that has not achieved the ‘double loop’ that permits more transforma-
tional change through ‘questioning underlying organization policies and
objectives’ (Argyris, 1977, p. 117). The debates also demonstrate that the
underlying problems persisted, and that alternative approaches resurface
with each attempt at revision, to be accommodated, if only in part.
This study develops our understanding of corporate governance in
three ways: Historically, it shows how the language of the code devel-
oped through the distillation of ideas arising in the consultation process.
That process, operating repeatedly in context of political indecision and
weakness, led to decisions that favoured central actors at the expense of
more peripheral ones with more radical ideas. It shows how, in the centre,
institutional investors wrested power from corporations. But it also shows
that the processes allowed ideas rejected at one stage to resurface. The
code thus was a living document, not a stale, historical artefact. Actors
across the spectrum of the investment chain had a stake in its success, and
in its perpetuation.
Theoretically, the study shows how logics of action, often voiced but
sometimes unstated, create a discourse that valorises certain ideas, which
come to be taken for granted as those logics become institutionalised.
The consultations led to structures that may blend contesting logics, but
by giving legitimacy to alternative discourses through their participation
in the process, it left others suspended and held in abeyance, but not
vanquished.
Practically, it demonstrates how the process of governing through
codes has greater flexibility than legislation or regulation, but also how the
institutionalisation of the process can inhibit stronger state intervention
or even experimentation with other ways of organising the governance of
organisations. The discussion suggests ways in which these lessons may
have application beyond the UK and in aspects of organisational life and
regulatory process other than in corporate governance.
The rest of the study is structured as follows: Chapter 2 provides an
overview of the field of corporate governance and provides a framework
for thinking about the issues it raises in terms of ethics, the political
processes of contestation over power, and how the rules thus devised
become institutions.
1 SUCCESSES IN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE—OR FAILURES? 11

Chapter 3 examines the context: The historical background and


key concepts of corporate governance, including differences in context
between the starting point of concern in the US during the Great Depres-
sion after the Wall Street Crash of 1929 and the UK, and then extending
that to the end of the twentieth century. A detailed look at institutional,
market, and political situations in the UK in which the code developed.
Chapter 4 describes institutions, institutional theory, and power:
formal and informal institutions, the problem of institutions outliving
their usefulness, how institutions disguise power, and how institutional
logics illuminate the relationship to power. Less theoretically and philo-
sophically inclined readers may decide to skip this chapter, but they
will miss some of the ideas that underpin the later discussion of power
relations and impact of the code.
Chapter 5 looks at how the institutional context for corporate gover-
nance—especially the battle between the UK and the European Union
over company law—created flashpoints for the framers of the first code:
the shape of the board of directors (board design), board ethos, and the
nature of compliance.
Chapter 6 provides a detailed historical analysis of the inputs of corpo-
rations, accountancy bodies and firms, lawyers, investors, and lobbyists
over the question of board design, covering 1992 and then the major
code revisions in 2003 and 2010, after fresh crises in corporate gover-
nance. Chapter 7, in parallel to the previous one, analyses the debates
concerning board ethos and compliance.3
Chapter 8 provides a critical analysis of what these debates show us
about the seat and shift of power between the key actors in the field—
corporations, mainstream institutional investors, professional services
firms and bodies, and more peripheral voices in the debate. Central actors
have embedded their authority over the process, marginalising more
peripheral voices but without excluding them, which allows their argu-
ments to resurface in the cycle of recurring code revision. It returns to the
framework outlined in Chapter 2 to show how the cycle of ethical choices,
political contestation and institutionalisation manifests in the debate over
codification.
Chapter 9 offers conclusions about how the code has influenced the
practice of corporate governance and how the process of developing the

3 A description of the research methods and document sampling appears in Appendix


A.
12 D. NORDBERG

code has both built a consensus, a logic of corporate governance while


also embedding a lack of experimentation that might have done more
to address the underlying problem of corporate collapse. It also notes
that participation in the more recent code debates has failed to reflect
the shifting patterns of investment in the UK equities market. It discusses
how the product of this long debate—the code itself—has changed organ-
isational governance well beyond listed companies and well beyond the
UK.
The book closes with an epilogue offering a contemporary postscript,
looking at the collapse of Carillion in 2018, a hesitant discussion during
the government of Theresa May over having employees on corpo-
rate boards, and following her fall from power in 2019 the ongoing
debate over regulation of accountancy and corporate governance more
widely. It ends with some very initial thoughts on the consequences of
the coronavirus pandemic on the economic and corporate governance
systems.

References
Argyris, C. (1977). Double loop learning in organizations. Harvard Business
Review, 55(5), 115–125.
Bank of England. (2015, November). The failure of HBOS plc. UK Financial
Conduct Authority and Prudential Regulatory Authority report. Retrieved
November 19, 2015, from http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/pra/Docume
nts/publications/reports/hbos.pdf.
Cadbury, A. (1992). The financial aspects of corporate governance. Retrieved
September 1, 2015, from http://www.ecgi.org/codes/documents/cadbury.
pdf.
Committee on Corporate Governance. (2000, May). Combined code: Prin-
ciples of corporate governance and code of good practice. UK Financial
Services Authority publication for the Committee on Corporate Governance.
Retrieved February 10, 2017, from http://www.ecgi.org/codes/documents/
combined_code.pdf.
Deakin, S., & Konzelmann, S. J. (2004). Learning from Enron. Corporate Gover-
nance: An International Review, 12(2), 134–142. https://doi.org/10.1111/
j.1467-8683.2004.00352.x.
Elsayed, K. (2007). Does CEO duality really affect corporate performance?
Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15(6), 1203–1214. https://
doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2007.00641.x.
1 SUCCESSES IN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE—OR FAILURES? 13

FRC. (2003). Combined code on corporate governance. UK Financial Reporting


Council. Retrieved June 20, 2006, from http://www.frc.org.uk/docume
nts/pagemanager/frc/Web%20Optimised%20Combined%20Code%203rd%
20proof.pdf.
FRC. (2010). The UK corporate governance code. UK Financial Reporting
Council. Retrieved May 29, 2010, from http://www.frc.org.uk/documents/
pagemanager/Corporate_Governance/UK%20Corp%20Gov%20Code%20J
une%202010.pdf.
FSA. (2011, December). The failure of the Royal Bank of Scotland plc. UK Finan-
cial Services Authority report. Retrieved November 19, 2015, from http://
www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/rbs.pdf.
Goh, L., & Gupta, A. (2016). Remuneration of non-executive directors:
Evidence from the UK. The British Accounting Review, 48(3), 379–399.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bar.2015.05.001.
Hallock, K. F. (1997). Reciprocally interlocking boards of directors and executive
compensation. Journal of Financial & Quantitative Analysis, 32(3), 331–344.
Higgs, D. (2003). Review of the role and effectiveness of non-executive directors.
Retrieved October 15, 2006, from http://www.ecgi.org/codes/documents/
higgsreport.pdf.
Hodge, C. (2017, February). Untangling corporate governance. ICSA Future of
Governance series. Retrieved March 6, 2017, from https://www.icsa.org.uk/
knowledge/research/the-future-of-governance.
Krause, R., Semadeni, M., & Cannella, A. A. (2014). CEO duality: A review and
research agenda. Journal of Management, 40(1), 256–286. https://doi.org/
10.1177/0149206313503013.
Library of Congress. (2002). H.R.3763, The Sarbanes-Oxley Act. Retrieved
October 15, 2006, from http://frwebgate.access.gpo.gov/cgi-bin/getdoc.
cgi?dbname=107_cong_bills&docid=f:h3763enr.txt.pdf.
Nordberg, D. (2008). Waste makes haste: Sarbanes-Oxley, competitiveness and
the subprime crisis. Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance, 16(4),
365–383. https://doi.org/10.1108/13581980810918422.
Nordberg, D., & Booth, R. (2019). Evaluating the effectiveness of corporate
boards. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society,
19(2), 372–387. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-08-2018-0275.
Nordberg, D., & McNulty, T. (2013). Creating better boards through codi-
fication: Possibilities and limitations in UK corporate governance, 1992–
2010. Business History, 55(3), 348–374. https://doi.org/10.1080/000
76791.2012.712964.
Price, M., Harvey, C., Maclean, M., & Campbell, D. (2018). From Cadbury to
Kay: Discourse, intertextuality and the evolution of UK corporate governance.
Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 31(5), 1542–1562. https://
doi.org/10.1108/AAAJ-01-2015-1955.
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
ENTRANCE TO THE “AFIN” OR RESIDENCE OF THE ALAFIN OF OYO,
SHOWING TYPICAL YORUBA THATCHING.

Take, for example, the land question. If there is one thing upon
which all the most experienced Nigerian administrators are agreed it
is the absolute essentiality, for the future of the people of the country,
that their use and enjoyment of the land should be secured, not only
against a certain type of European capitalist who covets this rich soil
for his own schemes, and, under the pretence of industrial
expansion, would cheerfully turn the native agriculturist, farmer, and
trader into a “labourer,” but against the class of native who, for his
own ends, for speculative purposes mainly, seeks to undermine
native law and to change the right of user upon which native land
tenure is based, into that of owner at the expense of the community
at large. More especially does this become a question of vital
importance to native communities where, as in Yorubaland, you have
a comparatively dense population which under the pax Britannica is
bound to increase at a very rapid rate, and thus requires every inch
of land for its own future uses. But as matters stand at present, we
cannot, in the Egba district, which, being nearer to Lagos, is more
accessible to certain undesirable influences, both European and
native, and to the infiltration of European laws and customs
regulating the tenure of land, take effective measures to counteract
these influences. We could, of course, if we chose, not in the Egba
district only, but throughout Yorubaland. But there has been a
lamentable reluctance both at home and in the Protectorate to
foresee and cope with a predicament which all realize, which some
from a natural bent of mind inclining them to favour the substitution
everywhere of direct for indirect rule, and others who are of the same
way of thinking but from motives of self-interest may secretly rejoice
at, but which the officials whose hearts are really in the country and
who have sufficient experience to understand the endless and
disastrous embarrassments that the disintegration of native law
relating to land would produce, deeply deplore. What has been the
result? The Egbas are beginning to buy and to sell land among
themselves in absolute violation of their own customs and laws,
thereby laying up for their country a heritage of trouble and inserting
the thin edge of the wedge of their own undoing by letting in the land
monopolist and speculator. This, according to all its professions and
to its actions in some specific circumstances, for which it is to be
warmly commended, is, in the view of the Administration, inimical to
the public interest of the Protectorate. What is springing up in
Abeokuta to-day will spread to the other districts to-morrow—nay, is
doing so.
Take another example. The welfare of an agricultural community
demands, for many reasons scientifically substantiated, that a stop
should be put to the reckless destruction of timbered areas such as
has been proceeding all over Yorubaland. This is inherently a public
interest, and the Forestry Officer in the discharge of his duties is
merely a servant of the public. But in the Western Province, for the
same reasons, we cannot or are unwilling to put our case to the
native authorities for the protection of the people against themselves
with the same moral force as in the case of the other two provinces.
We are confined, or think we are confined, to simple persuasion.
Now, persuasion by the Forestry Officer alone is one thing, and
persuasion by the Forestry Officer supported by direct
representations from the Executive at Lagos is a very different thing.
It is the latter form of persuasion that has been absent, and very
great credit is due alike to the Forestry Officers and to a
Commissioner trusted by the native rulers, Mr. W. A. Ross, as well
as to the intelligence of those native rulers themselves, that in the
Oyo district both State and communal reserves have been created,
the latter of great extent including the entire valley of the Ogun. But
in the Abeokuta and Ibadan districts persuasion has failed hitherto to
secure any really tangible results. It is almost unnecessary to point
out that the interests of the population do not suffer merely indirectly
and potentially, but directly thereby. Not only does Southern Nigeria
import quantities of timber from Europe when the country should
itself provide for all requirements, but even so primitive a necessity
as firewood is beginning to make itself felt round such towns as Ede,
Abeokuta, and Ibadan.
In these problems the policy of the Southern Nigeria
Administration has been to leave the matter to the native authorities,
in other words, to let the land question slide down a perilous
declivity, and to allow the question of forestry preservation to be left
to the unsupported efforts of the Forestry Department. If this policy of
non-interference had been consistently applied in other directions an
intelligible case, at least, might be made out for it. But the facts are
notoriously otherwise. To mention but one instance. Two years ago
pressure was put upon the Ibadan authorities to vote unpopular
licensing regulations in the interests of temperance, and one of the
incidents subsequently arising out of it was the stoppage of the
Bale’s stipend by the Acting Resident with the concurrence of the
Executive at Lagos! Only last February a Bill called the “Foreign
Jurisdiction Ordinance, 1911,” was passed through the Lagos
Legislative Council, which provides for the extension of the laws of
the colony to the Protectorate of Yorubaland (except Abeokuta)
without the native authorities being even consulted, the Attorney-
General adopting, in effect, the extraordinary position that the
Government could take no account of “agreements, understandings,
or letters” (concluded or written by previous Governors) with the
native chiefs! If the native chiefs realized what the logical outcome of
the Ordinance might mean for them, by an Executive in Lagos, which
adopted the legal argument quoted, there would be ferment from one
end of Yoruba to the other.
It must be clear from what precedes that the time has come when
the whole position of the Yoruba States in relation to the paramount
Power should be reconsidered. The railway and other agencies are
causing the country to move forward very fast, and conditions are
being evolved through the attempt to drive in two directions at once,
which can only lead, if not to the ultimate annexation of Yorubaland,
then to what would, if possible, be even worse—viz. the
strangulation by successive stages of every effective agency in
native government, leaving the chiefs and their councils mere
puppets in the hands of the Lagos Legislative Council. Now neither
of these courses is, I am convinced, desired by the Imperial
Government. The drift is, nevertheless, apparent to all that have
eyes to see and ears to hear. There is a strong party in Lagos
favouring direct rule. There is a combination of distinct influences—in
many respects working unconsciously—making for the break-up of
native land tenure and the undermining of native authority. There is
the increasing danger of leaving the land question unregulated and
the difficulty attending the adoption of adequate measures for forest
preservation.
Only one course would appear open to the authorities if they
desire to stop the dry rot. The first step would consist in getting the
Native Councils—i.e. the Chiefs in Council—of all the districts in the
Western Province to pass an identical measure of national land
preservation which would become known as the Yoruba Land Act.
Inalienability of land is the cardinal principle of Yoruba land tenure.
The preamble of the measure would define Yoruba law and custom
in regard to land. The body of the measure would declare to be
illegal all buying and selling of land, either between natives and
natives or between natives and non-natives, and would establish
limitations of area and time for the holding of leased lands by private
individuals or associations, with provision for revision of rentals at
specified periods. The need of such a measure should be
recognized and the action proposed sanctioned by the Secretary of
State, and the matter should be represented to the native authorities
with all the additional weight which in their eyes it would under those
circumstances possess. It cannot be doubted that were the measure
fully and thoroughly explained to the Native Councils and its urgency
in the interests of their people emphasized, little or no trouble would
be experienced in ensuring its adoption. In the improbable event of
difficulties arising it would be the plain duty of the Administration to
overcome them. The Administration should be able to count in a
matter of this kind upon the support of every patriotic educated
Yoruban. The second step would be more far-reaching—viz. the
general reconstruction of the machinery of national government over
the whole province, and the welding together under the headship of
the Alafin of Oyo—the “King and Lord of Yorubaland,” as he is
described in the British Treaty—working with a Council
representative of all Yorubaland, of the separate districts which
internal anarchy and external aggression between them have
caused to fall away from the central authority. The existing Councils
of the various districts would, of course, remain, but we should have
what we have not at present, a true “Yoruba Council,” a strong
central native Government through which the development, the
progress, and the common welfare of the country could proceed on
definite, ordered, national lines.
This would be Empire-building of the real kind. It would not be
unattended with difficulty. It would require time, much tact, and,
above all, full and frank exposition and explanation. But it is feasible
of accomplishment, and by a policy of this kind alone can one of the
most interesting and promising races of Western Africa hope to
reach, under our supreme direction, its full development. The
elements necessary to the success of such policy exist. They do not
need to be created, but only to have their vitality revived and their
course adjusted and guided.
PART III
NORTHERN NIGERIA
CHAPTER I
THE NATURAL HIGHWAY TO THE UPLANDS OF THE NORTH

A casual visitor provided by private kindness with the hospitality of


a stern-wheeler and not, therefore, exposed to the discomforts
(soon, it is to be hoped, to be a thing of the past, with the completion
of railway communications between Lagos and Zungeru) with which
an inexcusably inefficient service of river-boats afflicts the unhappy
official on his way to Northern Nigeria, packed like a sardine, and
feeding as best he can, may be pardoned for finding much of
captivating interest in 400 miles of leisurely steaming, with many a
halt en route, from Forcados to Baro, the starting-point of the
Northern Nigerian Railway to Kano. The heat of the afternoons, the
myriad insect visitors which are heralded by the lighting of the lamps,
blacken the cloth and invade every part of the person accessible to
their attentions, the stifling nights, spent, may be, at anchor under
the lee of perpendicular banks; these are trifles not worthy of
mention by comparison with the rewards they bring. Kaleidoscopic
varieties of scenic effects enchant the eye as hour follows hour and
day follows day on the bosom of this wonderful Niger, passing from
serpentine curves so narrow that the revolving paddles seem in
imminent danger of sinking into the bank itself or snapping against
some one of the many floating snags, to ever broadening and
majestic proportions with vistas of eternal forest, of villages nestling
amid banana groves, of busy fishermen flinging their nets, of
occasional dark massive heads lifted a brief second from the deeps
to disappear silently as they arose, of brilliant blue kingfishers darting
hither and thither. Now the river flows through some natural
greenhouse of palms and ferns, whose nodding fronds are reflected
in the still green waters, now past a fringe of matted creepers gay
with purple convolvulus pierced at intervals with the grey upstanding
hole of the silk cotton tree. Here its course is broken by long
stretches of fine hummocky sand across whose shining surface stalk
the egret and the crane, the adjoining rushes noisy with the cackle of
the spur-winged geese. Here it glides expanding between open
plains bordered with reeds, only to narrow once more as the plain
heaves upward and the tall vegetable growth gives way to arid
granite outcrops, ascending towards the far horizon into high
tablelands. If at dawn the Niger veils its secrets in billowy mists of
white, at sunset the sense of mystery deepens. For that, I think, is
the principal charm of this great highway into the heart of Negro
Africa, the sense of mystery it inspires. Cradled in mystery, for two
thousand years it defied the inquisitiveness of the outer world,
guarded from the north by dangerous shoals and rapids; hiding its
outlet in a fan-shaped maze of creeks. To-day when its sanctuaries
are violated, its waters churned and smitten by strange and ugly
craft, it is still mysterious, vast and unconquered. Mysterious that
sombre forest the gathering shades encompass. Mysterious that tall
half-naked figure on yonder ledge, crimson framed in the dying sun,
motionless and statuesque. Mysterious that piercing melancholy
note which thrills from the profundities beyond, fading away in
whispers upon the violet and green wavelets lapping against the side
of the boat. Mysterious those rapid staccato drumbeats as unknown
humanity on one shore signals to unseen humanity on the other.
Mysterious the raucous cry of the crown-birds passing in long lines
to their resting-place in the marshes. Mysterious those tiny lights
from some unsuspected haunt of natural man that spring into life as
the sun sinks to slumber, and darkness, deep unfathomable
darkness, rushes over the land there to rest until a blood-red moon,
defining once again the line of forest, mounts the sky.
OUTLINE MAP OF NORTHERN NIGERIA.

From the point of view of navigation and of commerce the Niger is


a most unsatisfactory and uncertain river to work. It can be
described, perhaps, as a river full of holes with shallows between
them. Its channels are constantly changing. It is full of sandbanks
which take on new shapes and sizes every year. The direction of the
water-flow below Samabri, where the bifurcation begins, is so
unreliable that within a few years the Nun has become virtually
useless, the Forcados gaining what the Nun has lost, while there are
recent indications that the process may again be altered in favour
once more of the Nun to the detriment of the Forcados. In the course
of the year the water level varies twenty-seven feet, the period of rise
being from June in an ascending scale until the end of September,
the fall then commencing, the river being at its lowest from
December to May. In the rainy season the banks are flooded in the
lower regions for miles around. In the dry season the banks tower up
in places fifteen feet above water level. Roughly speaking, the Niger
is navigable for steamers drawing five feet in June, six feet in July,
and so on up to twelve feet in the end of September; from November
to April for vessels drawing between four and five feet. But the
conditions of two consecutive years are seldom alike.
Government has done little or nothing to cope with these natural
difficulties. The Admiralty charts available to the captains of
steamers are ludicrously obsolete, and all wrong. No continuous
series of observations have been taken of the river, and no effort
made to tackle the problem of improving navigation. Four years ago,
by Sir Percy Girouard’s directions, soundings were, indeed, taken
over a distance of 350 miles from Burutu (Forcados) to Lokoja at the
junction with the Benue; with the result that only seven miles of
sand-bars were reported to require dredging in order to secure a six-
foot channel all the year round. The experienced merchant smiled.
He is a slightly cynical person, is the West African merchant who
knows his Niger. Anyhow he is still whistling for his six-foot channel.
One dredger, the best which money could buy, was purchased by
the Northern Nigerian Administration. It did a little dredging round
about Lokoja (and the merchants in the south declare that the
performance has made matters worse for them), has been used as a
passenger boat up the Benue, and is now, I believe, filling up the
swamps at Baro; but the six-foot channel still exists as an attractive
theory in the Government Blue Book. There is so much to praise,
administratively speaking, in Nigeria that one feels the freer to speak
bluntly of the failure of Government to handle this matter of Niger
navigation. It is one of the inevitable, one of the many deplorable,
results of dual control over a common territory; one of the
consequences of the long competition between the two rival
Administrations, each quite honestly playing for its own hand and
each quite satisfied that it alone can think imperially. The upshot has
been pernicious to the public interest. The river-service is shocking
from the point of view of efficiency, and enormously costly. The
steamers themselves are falling to pieces. There is no system of
public pilotage, or of lighting. Trading steamers must anchor at night,
which involves, in the aggregate, a great waste of time and money.
The two Administrations are so busy squabbling over their competing
railways and manœuvring to frame rates which will cut one another
out, that the great natural highway into the interior is utterly
neglected.
It is impossible that feelings of respect should not go out, not only
towards the official who labours under these conditions in the Niger
waterways but also towards the merchant building up in quiet,
unostentatious fashion the edifice of commercial enterprise upon
which, in the ultimate resort, the whole fabric of Administrative
activity reposes. I do not now speak of the heads of these powerful
trading firms in Europe, many of whom, by the way, have themselves
gone through the mill in their time. To them England is indebted for
the Imperial position she holds in Nigeria to-day, a fact which is too
apt to be forgotten. I refer to the men, mostly young, in charge of
trading stations on the banks of the Niger and its creeks, living a life
of terrible loneliness amid primitive surroundings in a deadly climate,
separated in many cases several days’ journey from another white
face, not nearly so well housed as the officials (I am describing
Southern Nigeria, be it remembered), and not, like them, helped by
the consciousness of power or stimulated by the wider horizon the
latter enjoy. Thrown entirely on their own resources, usually unfitted
by their previous life to face the privations and isolation of an
existence such as this, very hard-worked—their lot is not an enviable
one. No doubt the hardships they have to endure are incidental to a
career they freely choose, although often enough with little or no
previous comprehension of its character. No doubt the fibres of a
minority will be toughened by their experiences. No doubt these
hardships are infinitely less severe than those which the early
pioneers were compelled to undergo, many succumbing under the
process; but in that connection it should not be forgotten that the
latter had the incentive of carving out their fortunes with their own
hands, whereas the present generation out in Nigeria are not their
own masters. One cannot help reflecting upon the irony of the
contrast between the commiseration so freely lavished at home upon
the spiritual drawbacks of the Nigerian native, and the total lack of
interest displayed by the Church in the welfare of these young
fellows, many of them mere lads, exposed to all the moral
temptations of their savage environment in which only exceptional
natures will detect the broadening spiritual influences. What an
untold blessing would be a periodical visit to their African homes,
fronted by the silent river, invested by the tropical forest, from an
experienced, genial, sympathetic minister of God, who for a day or
two would share their lives and win their confidence.
There is another matter which should be raised. These young men
who come out from England—I refer to the English trading firms only,
not having inquired into the system prevailing among the Continental
firms—do so under a three years’ contract. This is an altogether
excessive period for the Niger. It should be cut down one half. Even
then it would be half as long again as the officials’ term of service.
Professors of tropical medicine and magnates at home may say
what they like about the improvement of health in the large European
settlements. The towns are one thing. The “bush” is quite another.
Speaking generally, the climate of Nigeria, and the conditions under
which four-fifths of white humanity have to live are such as combine,
even in favourable circumstances, to impose the severest strain,
both physical and mental, upon all but a select few. At the end of a
year’s continuous residence, the strain begins to make itself felt in a
multiplicity of ways. Not to acknowledge it, and not to make provision
for it, is, on the part of an employer, penny wise and pound foolish—
to put the matter on the lowest ground.
VIEW OF LOKOJA AND NATIVE TOWN FROM MOUNT PATTEY, LOOKING S.E.
—THE BENUE IN THE DISTANCE.

At Idah we leave Southern Nigeria. That bold bluff of red


sandstone crowned with grey-trunked baobabs and nodding palms—
black with roosting and repulsive vultures—which overhangs the
river at this point, stands out at the dying of the day, a sentinel
pointing to the north. Henceforth the appearance of the country
undergoes a remarkable transformation, more and more
accentuated with every hour’s steaming. High valleys, slopes and
tablelands; a sparser vegetation; masses of granite or red sandstone
vomited promiscuously from broken, arid plains and taking on
fantastic shapes; in the distance, mountain ranges and solitary
rounded eminences—on our right, King William’s range rising to
1200 feet, on our left, Mounts Jervis, Erskine, Soraxte, and many
others, varying from 400 to 1000 feet. The river curves, winds and
narrows, obstructed here and there by dangerous boulders, which
the falling waters bring into view. More substantial, better-thatched
huts appear upon the banks, and around them an increasing number
of robed Africans. Plantations of yams, and guinea corn set out on
parallel, raised ridges, attest a higher skill in cultivation. Cattle are
seen cropping the green stuffs near the water’s edge, and canoes
pass bearing cattle, sheep and goats to some neighbouring market.
We enter the spreading domain of Mohammedan civilization, and
before long we shall find ourselves in a new world, as our gallant
little vessel, none the worse for a narrowly averted collision and
grounding on a sandbank or two, casts anchor at Lokoja. Here
beneath the wooded heights of Mount Patte the wonderful prospect
afforded by the junction of the Niger and Benue unfolds itself, and
presently we shall mingle with robed and turbaned African humanity,
come from immense distances to this great market of the middle
Niger. The mangroves of the Delta, the awesome grandeur of the
forests, these are left far behind. We have entered the uplands of the
North.
CHAPTER II
NORTHERN NIGERIA PRIOR TO THE BRITISH OCCUPATION

The political events of which Northern Nigeria was the scene last
century are well known, but a brief recapitulation of them is
necessary by way of introduction to the study of its present
conditions, the life of its people, and the accomplishments and
problems of the British Administration.
In the opening years of the nineteenth century, what is now
Northern Nigeria consisted of the shattered remnants of the once
famous Bornu Empire; of seven independent states more or less
(generally less) controlled by chieftains of the remarkable so-called
“Hausa” race, invaders of a thousand years before “out of the East,”
and of the aboriginal inhabitants whose origin is lost in the mists of
antiquity. Scattered throughout the region and constantly shifting
their habitat in response to the necessities of their calling, were
tribes of light-coloured straight-haired people, Fulani, nomadic
herdsmen and shepherds. From the ranks of these people, spread
over West Africa from the Senegal to the Chad, had sprung from
time to time political leaders, divines and men of letters who had
played a conspicuous part in the history of the old Niger civilizations.
The Hausa Chieftains had established a nominal authority over a
wide expanse of territory and were constantly at war with the
aborigines on their borders. It was not, however, for warlike feats, but
for their commerce, farming, cotton and leather industry; for the
spread of their language; for the great centres of human activity they
had formed and for the fertility and prosperity of the land which they
had made their home, that the Hausas were justly renowned all over
Western and Northern Africa. They had evolved no great imperial
dominion whose various parts acknowledged a central Head, such,
alternately, as Melle, Ghanata, Kanem and Bornu; but they had
leavened with their intelligence and fertilised with their industrial
achievements some of the naturally richest areas of tropical West
Africa, and they had earned for themselves in these respects a
widespread fame.
It was at this period that a learned Fulani, Othman Fodio, fell foul
of the chieftain ruling over the most ancient and aristocratic of the
Hausa States, Gober. The latter, fearing for his authority, ordered all
the Fulani in his country to be slaughtered, with the result that
Othman found himself at the head of a numerous following.
Emerging successfully from the struggle, Othman preached a jihad,
confided sacred standards to his worthiest captains and despatched
them far and wide. The Hausa Chieftains were successively
overthrown and replaced by Fulani, and regions unassimilated
previously by the Hausas were occupied. Othman’s warriors even
crossed the Niger and invaded Yorubaland, a large part of which
they conquered and retained (Ilorin), the forest belt, Yoruba
resistance within it, and, probably, the tsetse fly proving an
insurmountable barrier to further progress southwards. Down the
Niger they advanced no further than the neighbourhood of Lokoja.
Othman adopted the title of Sarikin mussulmi, and during his life and
that of his son Bello, Hausaland experienced for the first time the
grip of a central, directing power. It is doubtful, however, if this
change in their rulers had much effect upon the mass of the
population, to whom dynastic convulsions mean very little, and it is
noteworthy that the Fulani conquerors possessed sufficient statecraft
to interfere but slightly with the complicated and efficient system of
administration and of taxation which the Hausas had introduced.
They took over the government of the towns from the Hausas, the
people in many instances assisting and welcoming them. The
general condition of the country remained pretty much what it had
been. Moreover—and this fact is significant in connection with the
arguments I shall presently adduce as regards the inspiring motive of
the Fulani uprising—such of the old Hausa families who by their
learning and piety had become invested with a special public sanctity
were not generally molested by the conquering Fulani. Thus the
Kauru, Kajura and Fatika families of Zaria, which had given birth to a
long line of Mallams, were preserved in all their authority and dignity
by Othman and his successors.
A period of comparative political quiet ensued. Othman issued
regulations, and caused them to be strictly enforced, inflicting the
severest punishments upon robbers and evil-doers generally. A
recrudescence of spiritual influence and of letters everywhere
manifested itself. Learned men flocked to Sokoto, where Othman
had built his capital, from West and North Africa. The trans-desert
trade revived. Security was so well established that Clapperton, who
visited the country during Bello’s reign, records the common saying
of the time that a woman could pass unmolested through the land,
even if she carried a casket of gold upon her head. With the death of
Bello the influence of the central power, enormously difficult to
maintain in any case owing to the greatness of the area and the
absence of ways of communication, declined. Administrative decay
gradually set in and extended with the years. Little by little the
authority of the Emir of Sokoto was openly questioned, in all save
spiritual matters. Allegiance slackened. Emirs quarrelled amongst
themselves. This or that chief acted on his own responsibility in
political affairs affecting the general weal, or entirely broke away
from control. The roads became infested with bands of highwaymen
whose proceedings differed in no way from the banditti of feudal
Europe. Rebellious chieftains formed robber strongholds. Military
operations degenerated into mere raiding for the capture and sale of
prisoners of war to replenish revenues from ordinary taxation which
the disturbed state of the country was causing to decrease.
There has probably been a natural tendency in recent years to
exaggerate the aggregate effect for evil upon the country which
accompanied the weakening of the Fulani dynasty. There is no proof
that the state of affairs was worse than what had obtained previous
to Othman’s jihad. It could hardly have been worse than the
condition of Western Europe at sundry stages in its history, when the
weakness of the paramount authority and the foraging and strife of
rival Barons combined to desolate the homesteads of the people and
lay waste the country side. Some notion of parallels in approaching
the events of West African history is very desirable, but not often
conspicuous. But there can be no doubt—the evidence of one’s own
eyes in ruined villages and once cultivated areas “gone to bush” is
conclusive—that when the alien Britisher arrived upon the scene as
a reforming political force, Northern Nigeria was once more urgently
in need of a power sufficiently strong to restore order. Such was the
condition of the Hausa States. In Bornu matters had gone from
disorder to chaos, culminating in the final tragedy of Rabeh’s
incursion, the slaughter of the Shehu and the sack of Kuka, the
capital.
There is no need here to describe the events which led to the
British occupation, or to narrate the circumstances attending it. We
have replaced the Fulani in supreme control of the destinies of
Northern Nigeria. We are there to stay. How are we carrying out our
self-imposed mission? What are the problems with which we have to
grapple? These are the questions to examine. But before doing so,
let us first see what manner of people they are over whom we rule
henceforth as over-lords. What is their mode of life, their principal
occupation, their character, and the material and spiritual influences
which direct their outlook and mould their existence?
CHAPTER III
THE INDIGENOUS CIVILIZATION OF THE NORTH

An attempted reconstruction of the prehistoric period—considered


locally—of that portion of Western Central Africa, now known as
Northern Nigeria, would take up many chapters, and would be
largely founded upon conjecture. It suffices to say that in the course
of ages, through the influences of Moorish, Semitic, and probably
pre-Semitic Egyptian culture, fused in later times with Mohammedan
law, learning and religion, there has been evolved in this region a
civilization combining a curious mixture of Africa and the East, to
which no other part of the tropical or sub-tropical continent offers
even a remote parallel. And this is the more remarkable since these
territories have been separated from the east by inhospitable, mainly
waterless stretches, and from the north by vast and desolate sandy
wastes; while southwards the forest and the swamp cut them off
from all communication with the outer world by sea. The peoples
responsible for the creation of this civilization did not acquire the art
of building in stone, but, at a cost of labour and of time which must
have been gigantic (slave-labour, of course, such as built the
pyramids) they raised great cities of sun-dried clay, encompassing
them and a considerable area around, for purposes of cultivation and
food-supply, with mighty walls. These walls, from twenty to fifty feet
high and from twenty to forty feet thick at the base, in the case of the
larger cities, they furnished with ponderous and deep towered
entrances, protecting the gates with crenellated loop-holes and
digging deep moats outside. They learned to smelt iron and tin; to
tan and fabricate many leather articles durable and tasteful in
design; to grow cotton and fashion it into cloth unrivalled for
excellence and beauty in all Africa; to work in silver and in brass; to
dye in indigo and the colouring juice of other plants; to develop a
system of agriculture including (in certain provinces) irrigated
farming, which, in its highest forms, has surprised even experts from
Europe; to build up a great trade whose ramifications extend
throughout the whole western portion of the continent; to accumulate

You might also like