Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 58

WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE PETITIONER [TABLE OF CONTENTS]

TABLE OF CONTENTS

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS………………………………………………………… iii

INDEX OF AUTHORITIES .......................................................................................................... vi

STATEMENT OF JURISDICTION........................................................................................xviii

STATEMENT OF FACTS .......................................................................................................... xix

ISSUES FOR CONSIDERATION .............................................................................................xxii

SUMMARY OF ARGUMENTS ...............................................................................................xxiii

WRITTEN ARGUMENTS ............................................................................................................ 1

ISSUE A: WHETHER NOVAK IS IN VIOLATION OF SECTION 3 OF THE ACT ...................... 1

[I.] THE RELEVANT MARKET IS NOT LIMITED TO FILMS AND TV SERIES ON OTT
PLATFORMS .......................................................................................................... 2

[II.] NOVAK HAS NO MARKET POWER .................................................................................. 6

[III] THE CO-PRODUCTION AGREEMENTS AND ARTIST AGREEMENTS DO NOT


CAUSE AAEC......................................................................................................... 7

[IV] THE PRO-COMPETITIVE EFFECTS OUTWEIGH ITS ANTI-COMPETITIVE


EFFECTS ................................................................................................................. 9

[V.] THE AGREEMENT CAN BE OBJECTIVELY JUSTIFIED .............................................. 12

ISSUE B: WHETHER NOVAK IS IN VIOLATION OF SECTION 4 OF THE COMPETITION


ACT .............................................................................................................................. 13

[I] THE RELEVANT MARKET IS NOT LIMITED TO FILMS AND TV SERIES ON OTT
PLATFORMS ........................................................................................................ 14

[II] NOVAK DOES NOT HAVE A DOMINANT POSITION IN THE RELEVANT MARKET
................................................................................................................................ 14

[III] NOVAK HAS NOT ABUSED ITS DOMINANCE UNDER SECTION 4 OF THE
COMPETITION ACT ........................................................................................... 18

ISSUE C: WHETHER MR. SAMESH RIPPY HAS LOCUS TO CHALLENGE THE ORDER OF THE
CCB WITHIN THE MEANING OF SECTION 53B OF THE COMPETITION ACT, 2002 .................. 23
i
FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE PETITIONER [TABLE OF CONTENTS]

[I]. THE PHRASE ‘ANY PERSON’ UNDER § 53B MUST BE CONSTRUED


NARROWLY ........................................................................................................ 24

[II]. THE SIERRA ACQUISITION DOES NOT HARM MR. SAMESH’S LEGAL
INTERESTS .......................................................................................................... 25

ISSUE D: WHETHER SIERRA ACQUISITION CAUSES AAEC IN THE MARKET IN LIGHT


OF VARIOUS FACTORS UNDER SECTION 20(4) OF THE COMPETITION
ACT? ............................................................................................................................ 26

[I.] THE CCB GAVE DUE CLEARANCE TO THE COMBINATION..................................... 26

[II.] THERE IS NO SIGNIFICANT IMPEDIMENT TO EFFECTIVE COMPETITION IN THE


RELEVANT MARKET......................................................................................... 27

[III.] THE COMBINATION DOES NOT CAUSE AAEC IN THE MARKET .......................... 28

[IV.] THE COMBINATION CAN BE OBJECTIVELY JUSTIFIED BASED ON


EFFICIENCIES ARISING FROM IT ................................................................... 30

PRAYER ……………………………………………………………………………………….58

FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024


ii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS]

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS

S. No. ABBREVIATI MEANING


ON

1. Section

2. Paragraph

3. & And

4. Percentage
%

5. AAEC Appreciable Adverse Effect on


Competition

6. AIR All India Reporter

7. Another

8. Assn Association

9. BCLT BinTin Land Company Law Tribunal

10. CCB Competition Commission of BinTin Land

11. CCI Competition Commission of India

12. CO Company

13. COMPAT Competition Appellate Tribunal

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 iii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS]

14. Corp Corporation

15. DG Director-General

16. DRJ Delhi Report Judgement

17. ECJ European Court of Justice

18. ECR European Court Reports

19. Ed Edition

20. Etc. Etcetera

21. EU European Union

22. FDI Foreign Direct Investment

23. GDP Gross Domestic Product

24. IPR Intellectual Property Rights

25. LLP Limited Liability Partnership

26. Ltd Limited

27. NCLAT National Company Law Appellate Tribunal

28. OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and


Development

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 iv


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS]

29. OFT Office of Fair Trading

30. OJ Official Journal

31. Ors Others

32. OTT Over The Top

33. OUP Oxford University Press

Pvt.
34. Private

35. Reg. Regulation

SC
36. Supreme Court

SCC
37. Supreme Court Cases

Small but Significant and Non-Transitory Increase in


38. SSNIP Price

Television
39. TV

40. UOI Union of India

41. v. Versus

42.
3D Three Dimensional

43.
4D Four Dimensional

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 v


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [ÍNDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

INDEX OF AUTHORITIES

S.No. INDIAN PAGE No.


CASES

Accessories World Car Private Limited v. Sony India Pvt Ltd,

l. Case No. 03 of 2020 (CCI) 6

All Índia Online Vendors Assn. v. Flipkart Índia Pvt. Ltd., Case

2. No. 20 of 2018 (CC1) 4

Ashish Ahuja v. Snapdeal, Case no. 17 of 2014 (CCI)

3. 5

Automobiles Dealers Assn. v. Global Automobiles Ltd. and Anr.,

4. Case No. 33 of 2011 (CCI) 6

5. Belaire Owners Association v. DLF Ltd. Case no. 19 of 2010 5


(CCI)

6. Eros International Media Limited v. Central Circuit Cine 7


Association, Case No. 56 of 2010 (CCI)

FICCI Multiplex Assn of India v. United Producers/Distributors 15


Forum, Case No. 01 of 2009 (CCI)
7.

THE FIFFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 vi


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [ÍNDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

8. FX Enterprise Solutions India Pvt. Ltd. v. Hyundai Motor India 13


Ltd, Case No. 36 of 2014 (CCI)

Hemant Sharma and Other v. All India Chess Federation, Case no.
79 of 2011(CCI)
9. 12

Jasbhai Motibhai Desai v. Roshan Kumar AIR 1976 SC 578

10. 24-25

Jasper Infotech v. Kaff Appliances, Case no. 61 of 2014 (CCI).

11. 1

Jeetender Gupta v. Competition Commission of India, Appeal No.


30 of 2014 (COMPAT)
12. 24

13. M/s Atos Worldline India Pvt Ltd. v. M/s Verifone India Sales Pvt. 5
Ltd. Case no. 56 of 2012 (CCI).

14. M/s ESYS Information Technologies Pvt. Ltd. v. Intel Corp. & 1
Ors, Case no. 48 of 2011 (CCI).

Mahindra & Mahindra v. UOI (1979) 2 SCC 529

15. 7

THE FIFFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 vii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [ÍNDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

MCX Stock Exchange Ltd and Ors v. NSE of India, Case no. 13 of
2009 (CCI)

16. 5

Mr Ramakant Kini and Dr L.H. Hiranandani Hospital, Powai,


Mumbai, Case No. 39 of 2012 (CCI

17. 1

Prime Mag Subscription Services v. Wiley India Pvt. Ltd., Case


No. 07 of 2016 (CCI)

18. 6

Ramachandran v. JSW Cements Limited CCI Case No. 76/2017. 14

19.

20. R.V. Ramgopal v. Shri Ram Transport Finance Co. Ltd., 2012 SCC 15, 17
OnLine CCI 167

Saint Gobain Glass India Limited Vs Gujarat Gas Company


Limited, Case no. 20 of 2013. (CCI)
21. 3

Samir Agarwal v. Competition Commission of India (2021) 3 SCC


136
22. 24

Shri Avtar Singh Vs M/s. Ansal Township and Land Development


Ltd., Sh. Pranav Ansal and Sh. Anil Kumar. Case no. 03 of 2014
23. (CCI) 2

THE FIFFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 viii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [ÍNDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

Shri Ghanshyam Das Vij v M/s Bajaj Corporation Limited and


Ors, Case No. 68 of 2013 (CCI).
25. 9

26. Sonam Sharma v. Apple, Case no. 24 of 2011 (CCI). 12

Tamil Nadu Consumer Products v. Fangs Technology Private Ltd,


Case no. 15 of 2018 (CCI)
27. 6

Tata Engineering and Locomotive Co. Ltd v. The Registrar of


Restrictive Trade Agreement, AIR 1977 SC 973
28. 7,9

29. Vilakshan Kumar Yadav v. ANI Technologies Private Limited CCI 15


Case No. 21/2016

THE FIFFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 ix


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [INDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

S.No. STATUTES PAGE No.


AND
REGULATIO
NS

1. Competition Act, 2002 21, 22,

2. Competition Commission of India (General) Regulations 2009 30, 33

S.No. ARTICLES PAGE No.

1. Ben Holles de Peyer, ‘EU Merger Control and Big Data’ (2018) 30
13(4) Journal of Competition Law and Economics

Evens, Tom (2014) : Clash of TV platforms: How broadcasters and


2. distributors build platform leadership, 25th European Regional
Conference of the International Telecommunications Society (ITS) 10

Frank H. Easterbrook, Vertical Agreements and the Rule of


Reason, 53 Antitrust Law Journal (1984)
3. 6

Hedda Berto, ‘Sharing is caring – An Examination of the Essential


Facilities Doctrine and its Applicability to Big Data’ (2020),
http://www.diva-
4. portal.se/smash/get/diva2:1435499/FULLTEXT01.pdf 28

x
THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [INDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

5. Rossella Incardona, ‘Distribution Agreements Under EC 9


Competition Law’ (2005)
<https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1185371>

Vikas Kathuria, ‘Vertical Restraints under Indian Competitio


Economics’ (2022), 10(1), Journal of Antitrust Enforcement,

6
6.

7. Competition Commission of India, ‘Market Study on E-Commerce 11, 21


in India’ (2020) < https://www.cci.gov.in/economics-
research/market-studies/details/18/6 >

xi
THE FITEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [INDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

S.No. BOOKS PAGE No.

Atilano Jorge Padilla, The Role of Supply Side Substitution in the


definition of the relevant market in Merger Control (Neera 2001).

2. David S. Evans, ‘Vertical Restraints in a Digital World’ in The 10, 11


Evolution of Antitrust in the Digital Era: Essays on Competition
Policy (Boston: Competition Policy International, 2020)

3. Peter Roth QC, Bellamy & Child: European Union of Law 8


Competition 497 (OUP 2018)

4. Richard Whish and David Bailey, COMPETITION LAW, (OUP 7th 4, 12, 28
Edn, 2008)

5. 9, 25

S M Duggar, S M Duggar’s Guide to Competition Act, 2002 261


(LexisNexis 2017).

6. Seung-Hyeok Baek, Min-Gown Park and Jin-Hua Zang, ‘An 13


Exploratory Study on the Benefit Sharing of Broadcasting Content
Industry’ in Computer and Science Information (Roger Lee eds,
Springer 2019)
S Bishop and M Walker (1999), ‘The Economics of EC Competition
7. Law: Concepts, Application and Measurement’ (2007) (3rd Edition, 17, 21
London, Sweet and Maxwell)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [INDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

S. NO. REPORTS, NOTICE GU IDELINES PAGE


NO.

1. Competition Commission of India, ‘Market Study on E-Commerce 11,21


in India’ (2020) < https://www.cci.gov.in/economics-
research/market-studies/details/18/6 >

2. Competition Commission of India, ‘Market Study on the Film 10


Distribution Chain in India’ (2022) <
https://www.cci.gov.in/images/whatsnew/en/market-study-on-the-
film-distribution-chain-in-india1665747371.pdf >

3. EU Guidelines on vertical restraints OJ C-130/1 (2010) 6

European Commission, ‘Guidelines on the Assessment of


Horizontal Mergers under the Council Regulation on the control of
4. concentrations between undertakings’, OJ C-31 (2004) 8

5. European Commission, ‘Notice on the Definition of the Relevant 4


Market for the Purposes of [EU] Competition Law’, OJ C-372/5
(1997),

6. Office of Fair Trading, ‘Assessment of Market Power’, OFT-415 7


(2004)

7. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 28


‘Merger Remedies’ (OECD, 2003) <
https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/34305995.pdf>

8. Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development, 34


‘Competition Policy and a Changing Broadcast Industry’ (1993)

9. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, ‘Start- 20


ups, Killer Acquisitions and Merger Control’, (OECD, 2020)
<https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/start-ups-killer-
acquisitions-and-merger-control-2020.pdf>

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xiii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [INDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

10. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, ‘The 21


Evolving Concept of Market Power in the Digital Economy’,
(OECD Competition Policy Roundtable Background Note, 2022)

11. Report of High level Committee on Competition Policy and Law 22


(Raghavan Committee)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xiv
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [INDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

S.No. FOREIGN PAGE No.


CASES

1. Airtours v Commission [2002] 5 CMLR 317 26,27

2. Association belge des consommateurs test v. European 25


Commission, [2011] ECR 773

3. Bertelsmann AG v Independent Music Publishers and Labels 26


Association [2008] 5 CMLR 1073.

Commission v Tetra Laval BV [2005] 4 CMLR 573


26
4.

Dr Pepper/Seven-Up Companies v Federal Trade Commission


991 F.2d 859 (D.C. Cir. 1993
5. 29

Federal Trade Commission v Staples 970 F. Supp. 1066 (D.D.C.


1997)
6. 29

7. Film Purchases by German Televisions Stations OJ [1989] L 13,19


284/36

7. General Electric Company v Commission [2006] 4 CMLR 686. 26

Hugin Kassaregister AB v. Commission 22/78 [1979] ECR 1896

8. 4

Illinois Brick Co. v Illinois [1977] 97 S.Ct.2061.

9. 24

10. Maxima Latvija v. Konkurences Padome Case No. 345 of 2014 8


(ECJ)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xv


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [INDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xvi
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [INDEX OF AUTHORITIES]

11. Plaumann & Co v. Commission of the European Economic 25


Community, 25/62 [1963] ECR 93.

12. Pronuptia de Paris GmbH v Schillgalis, Case No. 161 of 1984 13


(ECR)

13. Société Générale des Grandes Sources and others v Commission of 25


the European Communities, 96/92 [1992] ECR 118

14. Société Technique Minière v. Maschinenbau Ulm [1966] ECR 1


337

15. Tetra Laval v Commission [2002] 5 CMLR 1182 26

United Brands v Commission Case 27/76 [1978] ECR 207


16. 2,12

Michelin v. Commission [1983] ECR 3461 24

USA v. Paramount Pictures 334 U.S. 131 (1948) 25

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xvii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [STATEMENT OF JURISD ICTION]

STATEMENT OF JURISDICTION

I. COMPETITION APPEAL (BA) NO. 2222 OF 2023

The Petitioner, Novak has approached this Hon’ble Tribunal under Section 53B of the BinTin

Land Competition Act, 2002. The Respondent, Orion humbly submits to the jurisdiction of the

tribunal.

II. COMPETITION APPEAL (BA) NO. 2192 OF 2023

The Petitioner, Novak has approached this Hon’ble Tribunal under Section 53B of the BinTin

Land Competition Act, 2002. The Respondent, Assistant Director humbly submits to the

jurisdiction of the tribunal.

III. COMPETITION APPEAL (BA) NO. 2323 OF 2023

The Petitioner, Samesh Rippy has approached this Hon’ble Tribunal under Section 53B of the

BinTin Land Competition Act, 2002. The Respondents, Novak and CCB humbly submit to the

jurisdiction of the tribunal.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xviii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [STATEMENT OF FACTS]

STATEMENT OF FACTS

[BACKGROUND FACTS]

BinTin Land is a diversified middle-income economy where the media and entertainment sector

has been a major contributor to GDP since the 2000s. This sector consists of two segments: films

and TV shows, which have a worldwide reputation due to their complex and humorous storylines,

subtle acting and direction.

Traditionally the film segment was dominated by large production houses and exhibitors,

relegating small producers to the periphery as fringe players. Similarly, the TV segment was

dominated by large conglomerate networks. Under a traditional setup, the producers had a

revenue-sharing arrangement with exhibitors. However, owing to the increasing dependency of

producers on multiplexes, exhibitors started to impose non-negotiable terms on all producers,

leaving a consolidated market with only 4-5 major production houses and no new entrants in

recent years.

In 2021 due to the Novid-19 pandemic, a lockdown was imposed in BinTin Land, forcing people

to stay home. As a result, numerous OTT platforms, including Novak, emerged to provide people

with content in their homes.

[CO-PRODUCTION AGREEMENTS]

With the entry of OTT platforms, many producers viewed these platforms as an additional source

of revenue along with multiplexes and television networks. In the film segment, Novak entered

into Co-Production agreements with small producers, thereby allowing them to effectively

compete in the market. This diversified the market and also started to counteract the hegemony of

the exhibitors. One such Co-Production Agreement was between Novak and Capsicum, a

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xix
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [STATEMENT OF FACTS]

production house that sought to screen its films on Novak’s platforms instead of multiplexes due

to the dishonest practices of exhibitors. To cater to its viewers, Novak also had to adopt clauses

to control the quality of the films through vetting rights and choice of lead actors. Keeping the

interests of consumers in mind, another clause of the agreement allowed multiplexes to screen

movies requiring 3D/4D technologies. Gradually, the use of such agreements became a standard

practice in the segment. However, to ameliorate the concerns of its business partners, Novak also

altered its agreement to reduce the term from 5 years to 3 years and introduced a revenue-sharing

agreement giving producers a 2% stake in the total revenue generated from the clicks on the

platform.

Nonetheless, alleging reduced footfall in multiplexes, Orion, a group of multiplexes, filed an

information with the CCB against Novak, alleging abuse of market dominance through denial of

market access and vertical restraints.

[ARTIST AGREEMENTS]

In the TV segment, Novak had to balance the interests of the consumers demanding the same actor

to play a specific character and artists who wished to take up other projects for career growth. As

a result, Novak entered into multiple Artist Agreements with various actors/actresses in TV shows.

One such agreement was forged between Novak and Asmita Sengupta. This agreement obligated

Sengupta to exclusively work with Novak during the continuance of the 6 seasons of the show to

ensure continuity. Moreover, there was a provision of conflict-free windows during which the

artists could work with other producers.

Yet, another important requirement was to ensure the non-leakage of important information

relating to Novak’s TV shows. As a result, Novak signed a confidentiality clause with the artists.

Since these TV series were produced by Novak itself, another clause of the agreement allowed

Novak to retain its merchandising and trademark rights over the characters. An Assistant Director

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xx


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [STATEMENT OF FACTS]

submitted an anonymous Information to the CCB, alleging abuse of dominance by Novak due to

the use of such agreements.

[COMMISSION’S DECISION]

Concerning Orion’s information, the CCB, on receiving the DG’s Investigation Report and

hearing both parties, held that Novak has violated sections 3 and 4 of the Competition Act.

Similarly, for the anonymous information filed by the Assistant Director, the CCB held that

sections 3 and 4 have been contravened.

[THE SIERRA ACQUSITION]

To cater to the consumer demand for a variety of content, Novak acquired a 28% equity

shareholding in Sierra, another small OTT platform. This acquisition was notified to the CCB

under section 6(2) in the interest of full disclosure. The CCB found that the market is characterized

by multiple small OTT platforms and, hence, approved the acquisition on May 26, 2023. However,

Mr. Samesh Rippy, a majority shareholder in Bart, the OTT platform with the highest market

share, requested a detailed review of this transaction before the BCLT.

[APPEAL BEFORE BCLT]

Following the issuance of orders by the CCB against Novak for violation of the Competition Act,

the aggrieved platform has approached the BCLT under section 53. It has filed two separate

appeals, challenging the holding of the CCB about both, the information filed by Orion and the

anonymous Information submitted by the Assistant Director.

Mr. Samesh Rippy has also filed an appeal before the BCLT under section 53, challenging CCB’s

approval of the acquisition of Sierra by Novak.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xxi
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [ISSUES FOR CONSIDERATION]

ISSUES FOR CONSIDERATION

-ISSUE A-

WHETHER NOVAK IS IN VIOLATION OF SECTION 3 OF THE ACT

- ISSUE B -

WHETHER NOVAK IS IN VIOLATION OF SECTION 4 OF THE ACT

- ISSUE C-

WHETHER MR. SAMESH RIPPY HAS LOCUS TO CHALLENGE THE ORDER OF


THE CCB DATE MAY 26, 2023 WITHIN THE MEANING OF SECTION 53B OF THE
COMPETITION ACT, 2002

- ISSUE D -

WHETHER T HE SIERRA ACQUISITION CAUSES AAEC IN


THE MARKET IN LIGHT OF VARIOUS FACTORS UNDER
SECTION 20(4) OF THE COMPETITION ACT?

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 xxii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [SUMMARY OF ARGUMENTS]

SUMMARY OF ARGUMENTS

ISSUE A

It is submitted that Novak has not violated §3(4)(c) of the Competition Act. Under §3(4), vertical

restraints are declared to be anti-competitive only if they cause AAEC. In the present case, the

Co-Production Agreements and Artist Agreements entered into by Novak do not cause AAEC.

This is because firstly, the relevant market for the two agreements is not restricted to OTT

platforms and extends to the entirety of the industry. Secondly, Novak does not possess any market

power in the defined relevant market. Thirdly, the said agreements do not result in anti-competitive

effects since neither do they create barriers for new entrants nor do they cause foreclosure of the

market. Moreover, the said agreements have led to accrual of consumer benefits, improvement in

the production or distribution of goods and promotion of technical and economic development.

Therefore, the pro-competitive effects of the said agreements outweigh their anti-competitive

effects. Lastly, the agreements can be objectively justified because they reasonably protect the

economic interests of Novak and the restrictive clause on retaining merchandising rights is

exempted under §3(5).

ISSUE B

It is submitted that Novak has not violated section 4 of the Competition Act. This is because

firstly, Novak does not have a dominant position in the market. The absence of Novak’s

dominance is evidenced by the relatively low market share it possesses, the presence of

significant other players with higher market shares in the market, and the high countervailing

buyer power consumers possess in the film and TV series market. Secondly, Novak also does

not have a position in the market that enables it to affect its consumers and competitors in its

favor. Once the non-dominance of Novak is established, it is submitted that even if Novak has

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024


xxiii
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [SUMMARY OF ARGUMENTS]

a dominant position in the market, it has not abused its position through denial of market access

or imposition of illegal vertical restraints. This is because firstly, film and TV series content is

not an essential facility in the relevant market, and secondly, even if we consider them as an

essential facility, Novak has not engaged in their denial. Moreover, the vertical integration

undertaken by Novak adds efficiency to the production process and is not directed towards

acquiring control of the market, and is, thus, allowed.

ISSUE C

It is submitted that Mr. Samesh Rippy does not have locus to challenge the order of the CCB dated

May 26, 2023 within the meaning of § 53B of the Act. Under § 53B an appeal to the appellate

tribunal can be preferred by any person aggrieved by an order, decision or direction. In the present

case, Mr. Rippy has challenged the approval given by CCB to the acquisition of Sierra by Novak.

Mr. Rippy does not have locus to challenge CCB’s approval because firstly, the phrase ‘any

person’ under § 53B must be construed narrowly. An order or direction under the Competition

Act cannot be challenged by any person who is in no manner concerned with the transaction in

question. Moreover, here it must be considered that Mr. Rippy is not a mere consumer, instead,

he is a majority shareholder of Bart, a dominant player in the OTT market. Secondly, in order to

meet the statutory requirement of locus standi the person must have suffered some harm that

peculiarly affects their legal interests. In the present case, the Sierra Acquisition does not affect

the legal interests of Mr. Rippy.

ISSUE D

It is submitted that the combination is not anti-competitive because firstly, the CCB has already

approved the combination of Novak and Sierra. The CCB considered the anti-competitive

concerns when approving the said merger. Thus, CCB has already given due clearance to the said

merger after considering all the relevant factors. Secondly, there is no significant impediment to

effective competition in the relevant market as even after the combination, Novak and Sierra are

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024


xxiv
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APPELLANT [SUMMARY OF ARGUMENTS]

not in a dominant position in the relevant market. Thirdly, the combination does not violate the

factors listed in Section 20(4) of the Competition Act as the combination does not increase barriers

to entry in the relevant market and there exists significant countervailing buyer power in the

market even after the combination. Lastly, the combination leads to pro-competitive efficiencies.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024


xxv
WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

WRITTEN ARGUMENTS

ISSUE A: WHETHER NOVAK IS IN VIOLATION OF SECTION 3 OF THE ACT

[¶ 1.] Novak, an OTT platform entered into various agreements with production houses. § 3(4) of

the Competition Act refers to vertical agreements where the enterprises operate at different levels

in the same production chain. 1 In the present case, Novak, production houses and artists are

enterprises under § 2(h). 2 In the Co-Production agreement, Novak and other production houses

operate at different levels of the same production chain i.e. production of films. Similarly, in the

Artist Agreement, there is a vertical relationship between Novak and the concerned actor, where

the former avails the services of the latter for shooting TV shows. Therefore, the agreements fall

within the ambit of § 3(4). Moreover, since the two agreements limit the supply of goods and

services, to some extent, they can be termed as exclusive distribution agreements under § 3(4)(c).3

[¶ 2.] However, as opposed to §3(3), vertical agreements under § 3(4) are not per se void.4 Such

agreements are treated more leniently than horizontal agreements. 5 It is a settled legal position

that agreements under § 3(4) can be rendered void under § 3(2) only if it causes or is likely to

cause AAEC.6 Moreover, exclusive distribution agreements need not necessarily be anti-

competitive.7 It is submitted that the agreements entered into by Novak do not cause anti-

1 The Competition Act, 2002. § 3(4), M/s ESYS Information Technologies Pvt. Ltd. v. Intel Corp.
& Ors, Case no. 48 of 2011 (CCI).
2 The Competition Act, 2002. § 3(4).
3 The Competition Act, 2002. § 3(4)(c).
4
Report of High level Committee on Competition Policy and Law (Raghavan Committee), ¶ 4.3.1
5
Mr Ramakant Kini and Dr L.H. Hiranandani Hospital, Powai, Mumbai, Case No. 39 of 2012
(CCI).
6 The Competition Act, 2002. § 3(4) and § 3(1), Jasper Infotech v. Kaff Appliances, Case no. 61

of 2014 (CCI).
7 Société Technique Minière v. Maschinenbau Ulm [1966] ECR 337

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 1


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

competitive effects in the market because, firstly (I) the relevant market is not limited to films and

TV series on OTT platforms. Secondly (II) Novak does not have market power. Thirdly (III), the

agreements do not cause AAEC. Fourthly (IV), the pro-competitive effects of the agreement

outweigh its anti-competitive effects. Lastly (V), the agreement can be objectively justified.

[I.] THE RELEVANT MARKET IS NOT LIMITED TO FILMS AND TV SERIES ON OTT

PLATFORMS

[¶ 3.] Since § 3 refers to ‘relevant market,’ it is essential to delineate the relevant market to assess

the AAEC caused by the agreements under § 3(4). 8 The purpose of defining this market is to

analyse the competitive constraints faced by the undertakings participating in the concerned

market.9 The ‘relevant market’ 10 can be determined by examining the relevant geographic and

product markets.11 It is submitted that firstly [A], the relevant geographic market is the Union of

BinTin Land and secondly [B], the relevant product market for the Co-Production Agreement

encompasses films streamed and exhibited on all platforms, while for the Artist Agreement, the

market includes services provided by actors for filming of TV shows streamed on TV channels

and OTT platforms. Though the relevant markets are distinct, they are not independent of each

other. Therefore, it is important to assess the agreements in conjunction as their effect on the

market is intertwined.

A. The relevant geographic market is the Union of BinTin Land

[¶ 4.] The relevant geographic market under § 2(s) refers to an area of market where the conditions

of competition for the supply of goods or provisions of services or demand of goods or services

8
CCI v. Coordination Committee of Artists And Technicians of WB Films and Television and
Others AIR 2017 SC 1449.
9 Ibid, Hemant Sharma and Other v. All India Chess Federation, Case no. 79 of 2011(CCI)
10 Competition Act, § 2(r)
11 Id. At § 19(5)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 2


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

are homogenous.12 The facts of the present case indicate that the condition throughout the Union

of BinTin Land are homogenous therefore the relevant geographic market is limited to the Union

of BinTin Land.

B. The relevant product market for the Co-Production Agreements and Artist Agreements is the

entirety of the films and TV series industry respectively.

[¶ 5.] Under § 2(t) the relevant product market is defined in terms of all those goods and

services that are interchangeable or substitutable due to their characteristics, price and intended

use.13 This market depends on various factors such as consumer preferences, technology etc. 14

It is submitted that the films and TV Series streamed on OTT Platforms are substitutable with

the films screened in multiplex theatres and TV series streamed via conglomerate networks.

This is because firstly [i], the characteristics of OTT platforms are similar to that of multiplex

theatres and satellite TV channels. Secondly [ii], the application of the SSNIP test suggests that

OTT platforms are substitutable by theatres and TV channels. Thirdly [iii], the end usage of

OTT platforms is similar to that of other streaming platforms.

i. Characteristics of OTT platforms are similar to that of multiplex theatres and satellite

TV channels

[¶ 6.] If two products or services have similar characteristics then they are likely to be substitutes

of each other.15 In assessing these similarities the preferences of the consumers is an important

consideration.16 In the current scenario, OTT platforms like Novak have begun streaming first-

12 Shri Avtar Singh Vs M/s. Ansal Township and Land Development Ltd., Sh. Pranav Ansal and
Sh. Anil Kumar. Case no. 03 of 2014 (CCI). United Brands v Commission Case 27/76 [1978] ECR
207
13
Competition Act 2002, § 2(t)
14 Atilano Jorge Padilla, The Role of Supply Side Substitution in the definition of the relevant

market in Merger Control (Neera 2001).


15 Saint Gobain Glass India Limited v Gujarat Gas Company Limited, Case no. 20 of 2013. (CCI)
16 Competition Act 2002, § 19(7)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 3


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

run movies and producing original TV series, mirroring traditional market practices observed in

multiplexes and satellite channels. Consequently, from the perspective of end consumers, these

platforms are interchangeable. Moreover, considering Capsicum’s decision to enter into an

agreement with Novak instead of other multiplexes, it can be said that even the producers consider

these platforms to be interchangeable. 17

[¶ 7.] The substitutability of products can be determined based on government policies and

regulations. In All India Online Vendors Association v. Flipkart India Private Limited 18 the CCI

had considered government regulation such as the FDI policy in determining whether online retail

stores and online platforms lie in the same relevant market. In the present case, the Government

of BinTin Land has permitted 100% FDI in the media and entertainment sector without making a

distinction between OTT platforms and other traditional modes of streaming films and TV series. 19

OECD in its report held that the broadcast and video distribution of motion pictures were close

substitutes of theatrical distribution despite the former having the ‘comfort of house’ factor. 20

Instead, here the revenue potential of the substitute was considered. 21 In the present case, the

revenue potential of OTT platforms is closer to that of theatres due to the streaming of first-run

films. Therefore, the fact that OTT platforms provide the comfort of home and other advantages

is irrelevant. Hence, notwithstanding the technological innovations introduced by OTT platforms,

they remain substitutable by traditional platforms such as multiplexes and satellite channels.

17 Facts-on-record, ¶ 20
18
All India Online Vendors Association v. Flipkart India Private Limited, Case no. 20 of 2018
(CCI)
19 Facts-on-record, ¶ 6
20 Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development, ‘Competition Policy and a

Changing Broadcast Industry’ (1993) pp.95.


21 ibid

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 4


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

ii. Applying the SSNIP test

[¶ 8.] The SSNIP test is used to highlight the relevant product market. 22 The test determines if two

products lie in the same market based on small but significant and non-transitory changes in

prices.23 The test assesses whether a customer would shift to another product when the price of

the product in question is hypothetically increased by 5-10%.24

[¶ 9.] In the present fact scenario, Novak had increased its subscription fee by 10% which resulted

in the non-renewal of the subscription by many of its existing subscribers. 25 Therefore, a small

but significant non-transitory increase in prices resulted in a loss of market share of Novak. Hence,

the application of the SSNIP test suggests that OTT platforms and other traditional modes of

streaming lie in the same relevant market.

iii. The end usage of OTT platforms is similar to that of streaming other platforms.

[¶ 10.] Along with the characteristics of the product, its end usage is an important factor in

delineating the relevant product market. 26 Mere technological advancements may not result in

different products.

[¶ 11.] In Sonam Sharma v. Apple27 the CCI refused to distinguish the relevant market based on

different technological features. Moreover, in Ashish Ahuja v. Snapdeal28 it was held that the

offline and online markets for shopping products were merely different channels of distribution

and did not denote two distinct product markets. Similarly, OTT platforms such as Novak merely

22 European Commission, ‘Notice on the Definition of the Relevant Market for the Purposes of
[EU] Competition Law’, OJ C-372/5 (1997), Hugin Kassaregister AB v. Commission 22/78
[1979] ECR 1896, Belaire Owners Association v. DLF Ltd. Case no. 19 of 2010 (CCI)
23 Richard Whish and David Bailey, C OMPETITION LAW, (OUP 7th Edn, 2008) p.31.
24
MCX Stock Exchange Ltd and Ors v. NSE of India, Case no. 13 of 2009 (CCI).
25
Facts-on-record, ¶ 34.
26 Competition Act of 2002, § 19(7), M/s Atos Worldline India Pvt Ltd. v. M/s Verifone India Sales

Pvt. Ltd. Case no. 56 of 2012 (CCI).


27 Sonam Sharma v. Apple, Case no. 24 of 2011 (CCI).
28 Ashish Ahuja v. Snapdeal, Case no. 17 of 2014 (CCI).

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 5


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

provide novel technological modes of distribution of films and TV series however the relevant

product market remains the same. The production houses still have the option to produce other

movies and TV shows and screen them in theatres and TV channels. Therefore, the relevant

market cannot be defined narrowly and be restricted to OTT platforms.

[II.] NOVAK HAS NO MARKET POWER

[¶ 12.] In assessing vertical restraints under § 3(4), market power is an important factor that must

be considered.29 Vertical agreements are void if the parties entering into such agreements have

market power.30 Therefore, such agreements can be subjected to investigation only when the

contracting parties have market power. 31

[¶ 13.] The market power of an enterprise depends on the enterprise’s market share. Usually, if

neither of the contracting parties has a market share exceeding 30% then the vertical agreement is

not deemed as anti-competitive.32 In Automobiles Dealers Association v. Global Automobiles

Limited and Anr 33 CCI refused to intervene in a case involving vertical restraint where the parties

had a market share less than the threshold of 30%. Therefore, if the market share of the enterprise

is minuscule then the vertical agreements are not void under § 3(2).34

[¶ 14.] In the present case, the market share of Novak Studios LLP in the OTT platforms market

is 25% which is below the given threshold. 35 Further, the majority market share of 40% lies with

29 Accessories World Car Private Limited v. Sony India Pvt. Ltd, Case no. 3 of 2020 (CCI).
30 Vikas Kathuria, ‘Vertical Restraints under Indian Competition Law: Whither Law and
Economics’ (2022), 10(1), Journal of Antitrust Enforcement, pp. 194–215, Tamil Nadu Consumer
Products v. Fangs Technology Private Ltd, Case no. 15 of 2018 (CCI)
31 Frank H. Easterbrook, Vertical Agreements and the Rule of Reason, 53 Antitrust Law Journal

(1984)
32
EU Guidelines on vertical restraints [2010] OJ C-130/1
33 Automobiles Dealers Association v. Global Automobiles Limited and Anr Case No. 33 of 2011

(CCI)
34 Prime Mag Subscription Services v. Wiley India Pvt. Ltd., Case No. 07 of 2016 (CCI)
35 Facts-on-record, Annexure 1

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 6


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

Bart leaving Novak with negligible market power. 36 Additionally, since the relevant market for

the co-production and artist agreement is not limited to only OTT platforms, the market share of

Novak in the entire film and TV series industry is less than 25%. 37 The film market is dominated

by large exhibitors who own multiple cinema halls. Similarly, in the TV market, most of the

market power lies with large conglomerate networks.38 Moreover, Novak has minimal viewer

traffic in the genres of romance, horror, comedy and demand (focused on BinTin Land). 39

Therefore, it cannot be said that Novak has market power in the relevant market.

[III] THE CO-PRODUCTION AGREEMENTS AND ARTIST AGREEMENTS DO NOT CAUSE

AAEC

[¶ 15] Vertical agreements under § 3(4) are subjected to the rule of reason approach to determine

their anti-competitiveness.40 This rule requires an examination of the nature of the competitive

restraint and its actual or potential effects.41 § 19(3) lists down factors that must be considered in

assessing if an agreement under § 3 causes or is likely to cause AAEC. 42 It is submitted that the

Co-Production and Artist Agreements do not cause AAEC as firstly [A], the agreements do not

increase entry barriers. Secondly [B], the agreement does not lead to foreclosure of the market.

A. The Agreements do not increase entry barriers

[¶ 16] Entry barriers refer to costs incurred by new entrants for entering into the market. 43 It is a

36 ibid
37 Memorandum, ¶ [1][B]
38 Facts-on-record, ¶ 9
39 Facts-on-record, ¶ 14
40
Tata Engineering and Locomotive Co. Ltd v. The Registrar of Restrictive Trade Agreement, AIR
1977 SC 973; Eros International Media Limited v. Central Circuit Cine Association, Case No. 56
of 2010 (CCI)
41 Mahindra & Mahindra v. UOI (1979) 2 SCC 529.
42 The Competition Act, 2002, § 19(3).
43 Office of Fair Trading, ‘Assessment of Market Power’, OFT-415 (2004)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 7


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

factor that must be considered in determining the validity of an agreement under § 3(4). 44 The

facts on record indicate that around 8000 films and TV series are produced yearly in BinTin

Land.45 Meanwhile, Novak has entered into an exclusive deal with production houses for the

production of only 4 movies over a period of 3 years.46 This constitutes a mere fraction of the

number of films and TV series produced in BinTin Land. This also implies that other platforms

and exhibitors can enter into agreements with various production houses for streaming movies.

Therefore, there are no entry barriers raised by the use of the Co-Production Agreement. In fact,

its use has incentivised market entry of small producers who were merely fringe players in the

earlier traditional setup. 47

[¶ 17] Additionally, the Artist agreement binds the artist only till the completion of shooting for a

particular show.48 This is akin to the standard market practice followed by production houses of

signing a contract with actors for a period of 2 years to make movies. 49 Moreover, the artists can

work with other producers during the conflict-free windows of at least 6 months. 50 Therefore,

these agreements do not raise entry barriers in any manner

B. The agreement does not lead to foreclosure of the market

[¶ 18] § 19(3) lists foreclosure of market as a relevant factor in assessing § 3(4) vertical restraints. 51

An agreement is set to foreclose a market when it affects the ability of the competitors to enter the

market or increase their share in the market. 52 The test of foreclosure inquires whether there are

real or concrete possibilities for a new rival to establish itself in the market. 53

44 The Competition Act, 2002, § 19(3).


45 Facts-on-record, ¶ 3
46 Facts-on-record, ¶ 32
47 Facts-on-record, ¶ 12
48
Facts-on-record, ¶ 27
49
Facts-on-record, ¶ 8
50 Facts-on-record, ¶ 32
51 Competition Act 2002, § 19(3)(c)
52 Peter Roth QC, Bellamy & Child: European Union of Law Competition 497 (OUP 2018)
53 Maxima Latvija v. Konkurences Padome Case No. 345 of 2014 (ECJ)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 8


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

[¶ 19] Here it is important to consider the market power exercised by the enterprises and the

duration of the exclusive agreements.54 If the agreement does not last for a long duration then no

contravention of § 3(4) is made out. 55 In the present case, the duration of the Co-production

Agreement entered into by Novak is merely for a period of 3 years. The Artist agreement lasts for

a reasonable period till the completion of the shooting of the TV series. Therefore, considering

that the duration of the agreements is not very long, there is no foreclosure of market. Additionally,

since the domination of Novak LLP extends to only a few genres, artists can tie up with production

houses that are producing movies in other genres. Therefore, there is no market foreclosure.

[IV] THE PRO-COMPETITIVE EFFECTS OUTWEIGH ITS ANTI-COMPETITIVE EFFECTS

[¶ 20.] Vertical agreements are not held to be ‘per se void’ because they can cause pro-competitive

effects.56 Even if an agreement is said to cause AAEC, an enterprise can justify its validity by

proving that the agreement’s pro-competitive effects outweigh its anti-competitive effects.57 This

balancing of the pro-competitive and anti-competitive effects is incorporated under a rule of

reason framework.58 Under this framework, even exclusive agreements can have pro-competitive

effects.59

[¶ 21.] Consequently, it is submitted that the pro-competitive effects outweigh the anti-

competitive effects because firstly [A], the agreement resulted in accrual of benefits by the

consumers. Secondly [B], it improves the production of goods or distribution of goods or provision

of services.

54
Guidelines on vertical restraints (n 31) p.88.
55
Sonam Sharma (n 22)
56 S M Duggar, S M Duggar’s Guide to Competition Act, 2002 261 (LexisNexis 2017).
57 The Competition Act, 2002, § 19(3).
58 Kathuria (n 25), Tata Engineering (n 41) ¶ 693.
59 Shri Ghanshyam Das Vij v M/s Bajaj Corporation Limited and Ors, Case No. 68 of 2013 (CCI).

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 9


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

A. The agreement resulted in the accrual of benefits by the consumers

[¶ 22.] § 19(3) lists accrual of benefits to consumers as a relevant factor in determining AAEC

caused by agreements under § 3. The use of exclusive distribution agreements leads to a reduction

in logistical and transactional costs due to economies of scale which allows a notable reduction in

prices offered to the end consumers. 60 In the present case, the use of Co-Production Agreements

allows small producers to produce movies thereby increasing the supply of movies which along

with economies of scale reduces production costs thereby incentivizing a decrease in prices. Such

agreements dilute the concentration of market power among big production houses and exhibitors.

[¶ 23.] Generally, demand in the film market is unpredictable due to erratic changes in consumer

preferences.61 However, due to the network effects of digital intermediaries such as OTT

platforms, content can be curated according to the specific preferences of consumer groups. 62 This

allows producers to build a direct relationship with the end consumer thereby leading to economic

efficiencies.63 In the present factual matrix, the use of Co-Production agreements has allowed

Novak to establish and facilitate a direct relationship between producers and consumers. This is

evidenced by Novak’s gradual experimentation with its genres based on consumer preferences.64

This allows consumers to avail themselves of an extensive selection of films and TV shows from

the comforts of their house, a benefit of notable significance in the backdrop of the Novid-14

pandemic.

[¶ 24.] The imposition of exclusive but reasonable restrictions on actors through Artist

60 Rossella Incardona, ‘Distribution Agreements Under EC Competition Law’ (2005)


<https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1185371>
61 Competition Commission of India, ‘Market Study on the Film Distribution Chain in India’

(2022) < https://www.cci.gov.in/images/whatsnew/en/market-study-on-the-film-distribution-


chain-in-india1665747371.pdf >
62
David S. Evans (n 38) pp.17.
63 Evens, Tom (2014): Clash of TV platforms: How broadcasters and distributors build platform

leadership, 25th European Regional Conference of the International Telecommunications Society


(ITS)
64 Facts-on-record, ¶ 29.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 10


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

Agreements allows Novak to protect the interests and expectations of the audience regarding the

consistent portrayal of a particular character by the same actor. 65 Therefore, the use of both

agreements results in the accrual of consumer benefits.

B. It improves the production of goods or provision of services

[¶ 25.] Improvement in production or distribution is another positive factor listed under § 19(3).66

Usually, agreements premised on collaboration between producers and intermediaries allow

economies of scale by coordinating consumer demand.67 In the present case, such a collaboration

between film producers and OTT platforms has been facilitated through the use of Co-Production

Agreements. Moreover, due to the contribution from Novak’s side, such agreements allow Small

Budget Producers to produce more movies and thereby accrue additional revenue. 68 The

agreement also dilutes the dependency on multiplexes and therefore does not allow them to

unilaterally impose unconscionable revenue-sharing agreements with young and independent

producers.69 Moreover, clause 10 of the Co-Production Agreement incentivizes the screening of

films containing 3D and 4D technology in theatres. 70 Therefore, it is submitted that the use of such

agreements has not restricted consumers from availing of more technologically advanced modes

of distribution in the market.

[¶ 26.] Earlier in the traditional setup, multiplexes would miscalculate the revenue generated from

ticket sales thereby portraying the producer’s actual income to be lower than the projected

income.71 Moreover, this lack of transparency prevails in the TV broadcasting sector where there

is an underreporting of TV subscribers. 72 Generally, the use of online intermediaries inculcates

65 Facts-on-record, ¶ 28
66 The Competition Act, 2002, § 19(3)
67
David Evans (n 38), Ghanshyam Das Vij (n 51)
68
Facts-on-record, ¶ 12
69 Facts-on-record, ¶ 9
70 Facts-on-record, ¶ 21
71 Facts-on-record, ¶ 20
72 Competition Commission of India (n 60)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 11


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

price transparency which thereby incentivises competitive practices in the market. 73 In the present

case, the terms in Novak’s Co-Production agreement ensure transparency by determining the

revenue share of producers based on the number of clicks generated. 74

[¶ 27.] Similarly, the Artist Agreements improve the conditions prevailing in the TV series market

by safeguarding the interests of the end-consumers.75 Therefore, the use of such agreements has

improved the production of goods or distribution of goods or provision of services.

[V.] THE AGREEMENT CAN BE OBJECTIVELY JUSTIFIED

[¶ 28.] An exclusive distribution agreement can be objectively justified if it results in economic

efficiencies.76 It is submitted that the Co-Production Agreements and Artist Agreements entered

into by Novak can be objectively justified because they reasonably protect the commercial

interests of the enterprise

A. They reasonably protect the commercial interests of the enterprise

[¶ 29.] The use of restrictive agreements to secure an enterprise’s commercial interest can be

deemed legitimate if they are objectively justified.77 In the present case, the Co-Production

Agreement entered into by Novak contains a clause which confers on it “the right to vet the script

and choose the lead actors.”78 While such clauses are restrictive in nature, they allow

intermediaries to control the quality of films produced under the contract thereby maximising the

joint revenue of the producers and intermediaries. 79

73 Competition Commission of India, ‘Market Study on E-Commerce in India’ (2020) <


https://www.cci.gov.in/economics-research/market-studies/details/18/6 >
74 Facts-on-record, ¶ 32
75
Memorandum, ¶ 22
76
Ghanshyam Das Vij (n 51) ¶ 75, Richard Whish (n 18) p.212.
77 FX Enterprise Solutions India Pvt. Ltd. v. Hyundai Motor India Ltd, Case No. 36 of 2014 (CCI),

United Brands (n 12)


78 Facts-on-record, ¶ 20
79 OECD (n 19) p117.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 12


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

[¶ 30.] Another clause of the agreement creates a revenue-sharing agreement where the revenue

of the producer is contingent on the number of clicks generated on the OTT platform. Owing to

the technological components, the number of clicks is calculated accurately, unlike in

multiplexes.80 Therefore, this clause is objectively justified. Moreover, such revenue-sharing

agreements serve as incentives for stakeholders to refrain from anti-competitive practices that may

harm the other party.81

[¶ 31.] The Artist Agreement contains a clause obligating an actor to exclusively work with Novak

during the continuance of the TV shows.82 This clause is justified since it allows actors to work

with other producers during conflict-free windows.83 In Film Purchases by German Televisions

Stations,84 an agreement conferring exclusive licensing rights was held valid due to the presence

of ‘window periods’ where the enterprise was allowed to deal with third parties. Similarly, the

non-disclosure clause under the Artist Agreement is justified as it protects the commercial

interests of Novak. 85 The use of such clauses helps preserve the know-how of an enterprise and is

therefore legitimate.86

ISSUE B: WHETHER NOVAK IS IN VIOLATION OF SECTION 4 OF THE

COMPETITION ACT

[¶ 32.] Novak has sought to expand its business operations since the rise of OTTs during the

80 Facts-on-record, ¶ 20
81 Seung-Hyeok Baek, Min-Gown Park and Jin-Hua Zang, ‘An Exploratory Study on the Benefit
Sharing of Broadcasting Content Industry’ in Computer and Science Information (Roger Lee eds,
Springer 2019) p.220.
82
Facts-on-record, ¶ 27
83 Facts-on-record, ¶ 32
84 Film Purchases by German Televisions Stations OJ [1989] L 284/36
85 Facts-on-record, ¶ 32
86 Pronuptia de Paris GmbH v Schillgalis, Case No. 161 of 1984 (ECR)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 13


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

Novid-14 era.87 In its efforts to expand its range and services, it has entered into numerous

arrangements. The OP has sought to label the efforts of Novak as a violation of Section 4 of the

Competition Act, 2002 which provides for the prohibition of abuse of dominance by a dominant

enterprise in the relevant market. 88 Therefore, it is humbly submitted that the actions of Novak do

not constitute a violation of Section 4 because firstly, [I] The relevant market is not limited to

films and TV series on OTT platforms. Secondly, [II] Novak does not have a dominant position

in the relevant market and thirdly, [III] Novak has not abused its dominance under section 4 of

the Competition Act.

[I] THE RELEVANT MARKET IS NOT LIMITED TO FILMS AND TV SERIES ON OTT

PLATFORMS
89
[¶ 33.] The relevant market in the present case is the films and TV series market.

[II] NOVAK DOES NOT HAVE A DOMINANT POSITION IN THE RELEVANT MARKET

[¶ 34.] Section 4 of the Competition Act defines the dominant position as a position of strength

that enables the enterprise to operate independently of the competitive forces in the relevant

market or to affect its competitors, consumers or the relevant market in its favour. 90 To assess this,

the Commission assesses the position of the dominant enterprise using the factors mentioned in

Section 19(4) including, inter alia, the market share of the entity, its size and resources, size and

importance of competitors. It is humbly submitted that based on these factors, Novak does not

have a dominant position in the market since they preclude it from operating independently or

affecting its competitors or consumers in the relevant market.

A. Novak cannot Operate Independently in the Relevant Market

[¶ 35.] One of the requirements for an entity to be dominant in the relevant market is its ability to

87 Facts-on-record ¶10,11.
88 Competition Act, section 4.
89 See memorandum ¶2.
90 ibid

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 14


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

operate independently of its competitors.91 It is submitted that Novak does not have that position

in the market due to its low market share and presence of other competitors.

i. The Market Share of Novak is Inadequate to make it a Dominant Entity

[¶ 36.] Market share is one criterion mentioned in Section 19(4) for the assessment of dominance.

It is one of the foremost values used in assessing market power and is used as a screening tool for

negating the possibility of dominance. 92 As one of the key factors in the assessment of dominance,

courts have held that it is implausible that any entity with a low market share will be in a dominant

position in the market.93 Importantly, the European Union also has a threshold of 40% below

which entities are not assessed for dominance. The EU Commission has declared only one entity

to be dominant below the threshold of 40% in the case of British Airways.94 The share of the

dominant entity in this case was 39.7%. Principally, thus, the enterprise must have a high market

share in the relevant market for it to be dominant.

[¶ 37.] It is submitted that Novak, with a market share of 25% in the OTT market, has an even

lower presence in the films and TV series market which is characterised by the presence of large

distributors and exhibitors with numerous multiplex cinemas.95 The market also has the presence

of large conglomerates. 96 Further, in the market of films and TV series, Novak only has a

namesake presence in genres such as romance, horror, reality shows, and science fiction. 97 It must

also be noted that Bart, another competitor in the same market, has a higher market share than

Novak, implying that there is effective competition. Thus, the market share of Novak strongly

suggests that it is not a dominant entity in the relevant market.

91 Competition Act, section 4, explanation.


92
Ramachandran v. JSW Cements Limited CCI Case No. 76/2017.
93
Vilakshan Kumar Yadav v. ANI Technologies Private Limited CCI Case No. 21/2016.
94 Virgin/British Airways OJ [2000] L 30/1.
95 Facts-on-record ¶9
96 ibid.
97 Facts-on-record ¶ 13,14.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 15


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

ii. Size and Resources of Novak, the Size and Importance of the Competitors and the

Economic Power of Novak including Commercial Advantages

[¶ 38.] The size and resources of the entity under scrutiny become important factors when

assessing its dominance. The CCI has relied upon it in numerous cases to determine the dominance

of any entity. In one case, an enterprise with a market share of 25% was rejected as a dominant

entity because other players in the market had significant shares. 98 It is submitted that the presence

of Bart, with a market share of 40%, Velar with 20% market share, and other big exhibitors and

production houses implies the presence of significant players in the relevant market.

[¶ 39.] In the present case, Novak is the only independent OTT platform in the country without

any large satellite television broadcasting conglomerate behind it. 99 Moreover, it must also be

noted that Novak, being solely a streaming platform, only has the streaming platform as its major

source of revenue.100 On the other hand, other players in the market have a multitude of operations

that also helped them quickly enter the OTT market during its rise in 2021. 101 Furthermore, in the

film and TV series market, there has been a historical dominance enjoyed by large production

houses implying their commercial dominance. Thus, Novak does not occupy a dominant position

in the market due to its relatively smaller size and resources.

[¶ 40.] Not only the size of entities, the films and TV series market is also characterised by the

presence of multiple important players. In OTT media, Bart, Velar and several small, regional and

innovative players indicate the presence of effective competition.102 Moreover, the rise of

platforms such as Velar, Mickey, and MFTV also highlights the lack of barriers imposing

production efficiency costs in the market. It must also be noted that Novak only has a high

audience in a few genres, while in genres like comedy, romance, local drama, horror, and science

98
R.V. Ramgopal v. Shri Ram Transport Finance Co. Ltd., 2012 SCC OnLine CCI 167
99 Facts-on-record ¶33.
100 ibid.
101 Facts-on-record ¶11.
102 ibid.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 16


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

fiction, the other OTT services dominate. 103 Furthermore, there are also numerous production

houses including Rambo, Rocky, and Swathe which dominate the film and TV series market. 104

Thus, it is submitted, that there are numerous other significantly important players in the relevant

market which ensure the presence of effective competition.

B. Novak cannot affect its competitors, consumers, and the relevant market in its favour

[¶ 41.] Another way in which the dominance of an entity is assessed is its ability to affect its

competitors, consumers and the relevant market in its favour.105 It is submitted that Novak does

not have adequate market power to affect its competitors, consumers or the relevant market in its

favour due to the market structure of the films and TV series market, the absence of consumer

dependence on Novak and the absence of strategic entry barriers.

[¶ 42.] As shown above, the relevant market is characterised by the presence of numerous regional

and national level players who specialize in different genres of movies and also have substantial

market shares. Such presence of significant players in the market has been used by the CCI to

reject the dominance of entities since they keep the enterprise in check for its actions. 106 Thus,

Novak cannot be said to affect its competitors due to their substantial market power.

[¶ 43.] As already shown above, the consumers in the film and TV series market cannot thus be

said to be dependent on Novak.

[¶ 44.] A strategic entry barrier may be defined as artificial costs that newer entrants have to face

due to the actions of the incumbents. 107 It is submitted that Novak has not indulged in the creation

of these artificial barriers. The co-production agreement entered into with numerous production

houses does not exclusively bind them to only produce movies with Novak. 108 This means that

these production houses can enter into similar arrangements with other platforms as well.

103 Facts-on-record ¶14.


104
Facts-on-record ¶7.
105
Competiton Act, section 4.
106 Ramgopal (n 106).
107 S Bishop and M Walker (1999), ‘The Economics of EC Competition Law: Concepts,

Application and Measurement’ (2007) (3rd Edition, London, Sweet and Maxwell) 189.
108 Facts-on-record ¶20.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 17


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

[¶ 45.] Neither do the agreements bind them to never release these movies on other platforms. 109

This stipulation of the agreement follows a commercial logic of recovery of investment given that

filmmaking is a risky investment. Moreover, the agreements also carve the exception for movies

requiring 3D technologies to be presented in theatres and then shown on Novak’s platform. 110

[¶ 46.] It should also be noted here that by providing for large conflict-free window periods in

artist agreements,111 Novak has also sought to provide other players with the access to actors while

they are not busy with shooting for Novak’s show. Ensuring the availability of actors during the

shooting of such long-term shows also has an important commercial goal since the viewers come

to associate particular actors with the characters in the movies and shows and any perturbance

with that affects the ratings of the show impacting the commercial viability of the entire project.

[¶ 47.] Thus, it is submitted that Novak does not occupy a dominant position in the relevant market

due to the non-fulfilment of either of the requirements under the Act.

[III] NOVAK HAS NOT ABUSED ITS DOMINANCE UNDER SECTION 4 OF THE

COMPETITION ACT

[¶ 48.] A determination of non-dominance precludes an analysis of abuse of dominance under the

Competition Act. However, even if the Hon’ble Court finds that Novak is in a position of

dominance, it is submitted, that such position has not been abused by Novak because firstly, (a) it

has not denied market access to any enterprise and secondly, (b) it has not imposed vertical

restraints on any enterprise.

A. Novak has not denied market access to any enterprise

[¶ 49.] Denial of market access by the conduct of a dominant entity is covered by Section 4(2)(c)

of the Competition Act.112 It is submitted that the actions of Novak, by indulging in co-production

agreements and artist agreements have not caused any denial of market access to any enterprise.

109 ibid.
110 ibid.
111 Facts-on-record ¶27.
112 Competition Act, section 4(2)(c).

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 18


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

This is because the test for denial of market access by withholding essential facilities is not

satisfied in the present case.

i. There is no denial of essential facilities:

[¶ 50.] It is submitted Novak has not engaged in denial of market access because the test laid out

in Shamsher Kataria, which settles the law on the issue of market denial in India, does not stand

fulfilled.113 This is because firstly, Novak does not control the facilities, namely the film and TV

series content and actors. Secondly, the competing enterprises can reproduce the facility, thirdly,

Novak has not denied access to these facilities and fourthly, Novak cannot feasibly provide access

to these facilities.

[¶ 51.] Novak does not control the film and TV series content because of two reasons. Firstly, the

co-production agreements entered into by Novak do not impose obligations on the production

houses to only make movies with Novak. 114 This means that these production houses can enter

into different arrangements with other market players to carry out different projects. It is submitted

that having these options in the agreements, Novak cannot be said to exercise control over the

film and movie content. Secondly, Novak has entered into an exclusive agreement with Capsicum,

which is not a significant production house like Rambo, Rocky, or Swathe.115 There is nothing to

suggest that Novak has control over a substantial chunk of the production market by having

arrangements with the major production houses. Based on these, it is submitted that Novak does

not control the essential facilities in the market.

[¶ 52.] In the context of artist agreements, it must be noted that the logic of the artist agreements

is primarily to ensure the availability of the artists to serve the needs of the consumers. 116 By

incorporating clauses requiring the availability of actors during shooting, Novak could not be said

to control the upstream market since these artists can also perform in other shows during the

113 In re: Shamsher Kataria v. Honda Siel Cars India Ltd & Others Case No. 03/2011.
114 Facts-on-record ¶20.
115 Facts-on-record ¶7.
116 Facts-on-record ¶28.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 19


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

conflict-free period. It is submitted that the services of actors in the shooting of film and TV series

content constitute a rivalrous market and, hence, some excludability is bound to happen, especially

during the shooting of a show. Moreover, such non-compete artist agreements involving conflict-

free window periods for the actors have also been upheld previously. 117 Thus, it is submitted that

Novak cannot be said to control the essential facilities for the film and TV series market.

[¶ 53.] As shown above, even though movies and TV series are not perfectly substitutable goods,

consumers still switch between movies based on extraneous factors indicating some

substitutability. Moreover, the production of movies and TV shows has been prevalent and

thriving in BinTin Land since the 2000s. 118 Even the Government has also sought to favour artists

including the producers and actors. 119 Logically, thus, producing movies is not an enormously

infeasible task in the country, particularly for production houses. Therefore, it is submitted that

movies are reproducible content and, thus, the second prong of the Kataria test also stands

satisfied.

[¶ 54.] In terms of the artist agreements, it is conceded that while the reproduction of artists, along

with the fame they enjoy, is a difficult task, the restriction imposed on them by Novak is logically

and commercially justified.

[¶ 55.] In the third prong of the EF test, it is submitted that Novak has not denied access to other

players from using its co-produced films. Instead, it has imposed a period equal to the co-

production agreement wherein the movies will only be shown on its platform. 120 Beyond such a

period, other firms may access these movies to showcase them on their platforms. On the other

hand, the artist agreements only impose objectively justified restrictions on the actors for specified

periods. Such restriction cannot be said to deny market access as it is otherwise infeasible for

Novak which has to ensure timely delivery of content.

117 Film Purchases by German Televisions Stations OJ [1989] L 284/36.


118 Facts-on-record ¶3.
119 Facts-on-record ¶6.
120 Facts-on-record ¶20.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 20


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

[¶ 56.] Finally, it is also submitted that Novak cannot provide access to the film and TV series

content and actors for the period of shooting because it impedes with the shooting of the content

which may transform into a delay in delivery. This impacts the expectations of the consumers and

also tarnishes Novak’s image. Such repercussions may also translate into commercial harm to

Novak.

[¶ 57.] Moreover, multiple work arrangements of actors also increase the transaction costs on

Novak which has to manage its shooting process based on numerous factors. It is submitted that

by reducing these transaction costs, the Artist Agreement brings in production efficiency for

Novak, along with ensuring consumer welfare. Thus, if the exclusive artist agreement is removed

by Novak, the risk exposure will rise. Moreover, it must also be noted, that long-term agreements

are also made to protect the commercial investment made into these projects because re-casting

of actors to perform the same role can lead to a reduction in viewers, as is also seen in BinTin

Land where people want the same actors to perform a specific character.

[¶ 58.] Similarly, the co-production agreements, by providing for exclusive streaming of film and

TV series content, for specified periods, are also objectively justified and their removal will be

infeasible for Novak. To understand this, it is important to note that there are three risks inherent

in the film and TV series market, namely- the risk of non-rivalrous and partially-excludable nature

of films imposes huge risks on the producers because they cannot totally prevent the leakage of

the product, the ease of piracy and its prevalence, and the unpredictability of demand. 121

[¶ 59.] As a result, it is an industry practice to undertake steps towards recoupment of investment

and mitigation of risk. 122 It is submitted that the co-production agreements with exclusive

distribution clauses for a specified period ensure that the wide availability of the film and TV

series content, which makes it more vulnerable to practices such as piracy, is curbed for a period

until the investment is recouped. Moreover, Novak’s access to its consumer data can predict, with

121 Competition Commission of India, ‘Market Study on E-Commerce in India’ (2020) <
https://www.cci.gov.in/economics-research/market-studies/details/18/6 >
122 Ibid.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 21


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

some certainty, the success or failure of a movie or TV series. However, if the same movie is

released in the broader market for which Novak does not have adequate data, the risks of failure

become even higher. As a result, Novak may suffer from significant monetary losses. Thus, it is

submitted that the actions of Novak have a rational justification, and it is infeasible for it to do

away with these measures.

B. Novak has not imposed illegal vertical restraints

[¶ 60.] Vertical integration refers to a practice where activities at different levels of the value chain

are carried out by the same enterprise. 123 It plays an important role by allowing firms to reduce

their transaction costs by engaging with the upstream market. 124 However, it is submitted that

vertical integration is not, per se, illegal.125 A vertically integrated enterprise is only held liable

when the integration was done to acquire control over a market segment to suppress the

competition.126

[¶ 61.] It is submitted that Novak has not engaged in any exercise aimed towards acquiring control

over the market. The co-production agreements ensure efficiency of production and availability

and continuity of content- all of which are significant for an OTT platform. Moreover, it is also

submitted that Novak is a relatively smaller market player in the relevant market compared to

much bigger players such as Bart, Rambo and Rocky, and its actions of entering into co-

production agreements with smaller entities such as capsicum cannot be coloured as attempts

towards acquiring substantial control over the market.

[¶ 62.] Furthermore, Novak cannot be said to have aimed towards acquiring control over the film

and TV series content market because of its consistent efforts towards harmonizing the interests

of all the stakeholders, including the customers and other market players. Initially, Novak had a

long-term co-production agreement, but the term was reduced to three years, which is somewhat

123 Bishop and Walker (n 117) 189.


124 Michelin v. Commission [1983] ECR 3461 ¶58.
125 USA v. Paramount Pictures 334 U.S. 131 (1948)
126 Ibid.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 22


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

similar to the previous market practice of two years, owing to the dissatisfaction of the production

houses.127 Moreover, an alteration to the revenue clause was also made to assuage the discontent

of production houses party to the co-production agreements.

[¶ 63.] In the artist agreements, Novak is bound to deliver timely and quality content to its viewers

and, as a result, has entered into the contract that limits the availability of actors to other producers

during the period of shooting of the TV series. However, Novak does not put any restraint on the

actors to work for other producers in the conflict-free period. This also highlights the attempts of

Novak to ameliorate the concerns of actors. Moreover, such agreements have been upheld in the

past as legal because they balance the commercial interests of enterprises with competition norms.

[¶ 64.] It is submitted that these windows of availability ensure that even during the period of

agreement, actors can work on multiple platforms to further their career. It is submitted that Novak

is completely cognizant of the public policy of BinTin Land which supports actors, and, thus, tries

to ensure that their creative expression is not stifled. However, at the same time, it is pertinent to

understand that Novak has access to its consumer data which provides it better estimates about

which actor to engage for a successful project. Thus, it has sought to include arrangements on

having a say in the choice of lead actors. Such a clause provides benefits to all the stakeholders.

[¶ 65.] Thus, it is submitted that Novak has not engaged in anti-competitive conduct aimed at

acquiring control over the upstream and downstream market in order to acquire control over a

market segment by quelling competition. Therefore, the vertical restraints imposed by Novak are

entirely legal and it cannot be said to have engaged in abusive conduct.

ISSUE C: WHETHER MR. SAMESH RIPPY HAS LOCUS TO CHALLENGE THE ORDER

OF THE CCB WITHIN THE MEANING OF SECTION 53B OF THE COMPETITION ACT,

2002

127 Facts-on-record ¶32.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 23


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

[¶ 66.] In order to expand the genres of films and TV shows streamed on it platforms and compete

effectively, Novak LLP strategically acquired some equity shareholding in Sierra, an OTT

platform. Due to the absence of any AAEC, this acquisition was approved by the CCB.128

However, Mr. Samesh Rippy, a majority shareholder of Bart, has challenged the approval given

to the Sierra Acquisition by the CCB under § 53B to the BCLT. 129 Under § 53B(1) an appeal to

the appellate tribunal can be filed only by an enterprise or any person who has been aggrieved by

any direction or order by the CCI.130 In consequence, it is submitted that Mr. Samesh Rippy has

no locus standi to challenge CCB’s approval under § 53B because firstly [I], the phrase ‘any

person’ under § 53B must be construed narrowly and secondly [II], The Sierra Acquisition does

not harm Mr. Samesh’s legal interests.

[I]. THE PHRASE ‘ANY PERSON’ UNDER § 53B MUST BE CONSTRUED NARROWLY

[¶ 67.] Only a person aggrieved by a direction or order is entitled to appeal the § 53B. It is an

established legal principle that an appeal under the Competition Act cannot be filed by a person

who has no interest or concern with the transaction or dispute at hand. 131 The phrase ‘aggrieved

person’ has been narrowly interpreted by the Supreme Court to refer to persons who have suffered

legal harm.132

[¶ 68.] Under the competition law regime in the USA, there is a requirement of “direct antitrust

injury” where the onus is on the person alleging misconduct to prove that the injury they have

suffered is legal in nature and specifically falls within the ambit of antitrust law.133 Therefore, the

phrase ‘any person’ under § 53B must be construed narrowly. In Samir Agarwal v. Competition

128
Facts-on-record, ¶ 35.
129
ibid
130 Competition Act 2002, § 53B(1)
131 Jeetender Gupta v. Competition Commission of India, Appeal No. 30 of 2014 (COMPAT)
132 Jasbhai Motibhai Desai v. Roshan Kumar AIR 1976 SC 578
133 Illinois Brick Co. v Illinois [1977] 97 S.Ct.2061.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 24


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

Commission of India,134 this phrase was interpreted widely to protect the interests of consumers.

Moreover, public interest is pivotal component in deciding the locus standi of a person in the

context of the Competition Act. 135 However, in the present case, Mr. Samesh Rippy is not merely

a consumer, he is a majority shareholder of Bart, a dominant OTT platform with a 40% share in

the market.136 Therefore, Mr. Samesh Rippy does not have any locus standi to challenge CCB’s

approval.

[II]. THE SIERRA ACQUISITION DOES NOT HARM MR. SAMESH’S LEGAL INTERESTS

[¶ 69.] In order to qualify as an aggrieved person under § 53B the person in question must have

suffered some harm that affects their legal interests.137 Moreover, the mere fact that the legal

position of the concerned person has changed is not sufficient to establish locus standi.138 The

decision must affect them directly and individually.139 This effect must be peculiar to the

concerned person, differentiating them from all other persons.140

[¶ 70.] In the present case Mr. Samesh Rippy has not suffered any legal injury and the approval

given to the Sierra Acquisition by CCB does not affect him directly or individually. In Jasbhai

Motibhai Desai v. Roshan Kumar, the setting up of a rival cinema house was dismissed as a

ground for constituting locus standi.141 Therefore, the mere fact that this acquisition may harm the

economic interests of Mr. Samesh Rippy is not sufficient to meet the statutory requirement of

locus standi under § 53B.

134 Samir Agarwal v. Competition Commission of India (2021) 3 SCC 136


135 Competition Commission of India (General) Regulations 2009, Regulation 25.
136 Facts-on-record, Annexure 1
137 S M Duggar, S M Duggar’s Guide to Competition Act, 2002 261 (LexisNexis 2017)
138
Association belge des consommateurs test v. European Commission, [2011] ECR 773
139
Ibid, Plaumann & Co v. Commission of the European Economic Community, 25/62 [1963]
ECR 93.
140 Société Générale des Grandes Sources and others v Commission of the European Communities,

96/92 [1992] ECR 118


141 Jasbhai (n 132)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 25


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

ISSUE D: WHETHER SIERRA ACQUISITION CAUSES AAEC IN THE MARKET IN

LIGHT OF VARIOUS FACTORS UNDER SECTION 20(4) OF THE COMPETITION

ACT?

[¶ 71.] It is submitted that the Competition Commission of BinTin Land did not err in approving

Novak’s acquisition of Sierra under Section 5 of the Competition Act. 142 It is submitted that the

merger is not anti-competitive because firstly (I), the Combination already got the due clearance

from the CCB. Secondly (II), the Combination does not hinder or impede effective competition

since it does not hold dominant position in the relevant market. Thirdly (III), the Combination

does not cause Appreciable Adverse Effect on Competition since it does not violate any of the

factors mentioned under Section 20(4) of the Competition Act. 143 Fourthly (IV), the combination

leads to pro-competitive efficiencies.

[I.] THE CCB GAVE DUE CLEARANCE TO THE COMBINATION

[¶ 72.] It is submitted that the CCB has already given clearance to the Combination after assessing

the factors of the combination. 144 The burden of proof is on the Commission which has to establish

that the merger is incompatible with the market forces.145 In the case of Bertelsmann AG v

Independent Music publishers and Labels Association, the Court held that there is no presumption

against the merger or that it is incompatible with the internal market. 146 After conducting its

investigation and assessing the relevant factors concerning the Combination and market, the CCB

has given due clearance to the Combination.

142 The Competition Act, 2002, § 5,


143 The Competition Act, 2002, § 20(4).
144
Facts on Record, ¶ 35.
145
Airtours v Commission [2002] 5 CMLR 317; Tetra Laval v Commission [2002] 5 CMLR 1182;
Commission v Tetra Laval BV [2005] 4 CMLR 573; General Electric Company v Commission
[2006] 4 CMLR 686.
146 Bertelsmann AG v Independent Music Publishers and Labels Association [2008] 5 CMLR

1073.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 26


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

[¶ 73.] It is, therefore, submitted that the Combination does not impede effective competition in

the common market and the acquisition of Sierra by Novak is not incompatible in the economic

and legal sphere of the market.

[II.] THERE IS NO SIGNIFICANT IMPEDIMENT TO EFFECTIVE COMPETITION IN THE

RELEVANT MARKET

[¶ 74.] It is submitted that the Combination does not significantly impede the effective competition

in the relevant market. As already established, the relevant market is the OTT platforms. 147 The

SSNIP test it makes it apparent that Novak cannot increase subscription prices on its platform

without losing its consumer base and market share to other OTT platforms 148.

[¶ 75.] The main consideration, while assessing the combination of Sierra and Novak, should be

that if after the combination, Novak increases its subscription prices, would it still hold the same

market share as earlier. 149 The consumers, will in such a scenario shift to other OTT platforms and

thus Novak will lose its market share to these OTT platforms. There are readily available

substitutes which can be easily accessed by the consumers. Therefore, in the relevant market,

Novak will still not be in a dominant position even after its combination with Sierra.

[¶ 76.] It is thus submitted that the Combination does not significantly impede effective

competition in the relevant market. The Combination does not prevent any other OTT platform

from doing business and does not make them dependent on Novak. In the case of Airtours v

Commission, the Court while overruling the decision of Commission held that the merger was not

making any other firm dependent on the Combination.150 Similarly, the Combination in no way

hinders the ability of Bart or any other company to do business in the OTT sector. They are in no

147
Memorandum ¶2
148 Facts on Record, ¶ 34
149 European Commission, ‘Guidelines on the Assessment of Horizontal Mergers under the

Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings’, OJ C-31 (2004)


150 Airtours (n 4)

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 27


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

way prevented from forming agreements and offering lucrative offers to consumers.

[III.] THE COMBINATION DOES NOT CAUSE AAEC IN THE MARKET

[¶ 77.] The Combination does not aggravate the already existing circumstances in the OTT market

because firstly [A], the combination does not create further barriers to entry in the market.

Secondly [B], countervailing buyer power already exists in the market.

A. The combination does not create further barriers to entry in the market

[¶ 78.] It is submitted that the Combination does not aggravate entry barriers in the OTT market

under Section 20(4)(b) of the Act. 151 One of the important factors while assessing any combination

is to check whether the combination is creating barriers for entry to the new players or expansion

for the current players in the market. 152 The assessment for entry barriers include: absolute

advantages, intrinsic or structural advantages, economies of scale, and strategic advantages.

[¶ 79.] It is conceded that there already exist many technological difficulties in entering the OTT

market.153 The Combination does not create any new type of difficulty. Novak would not have an

absolute advantage as other companies always have an option to reach out to consumers and to

offer them more lucrative deals. Further, the OTT platforms are mainly technology-driven systems

and this form of barrier always exists in this market. The Combination is not adding anything in

this regard. Further, concerning economies of scale, new companies can easily establish their

business at lower levels and are free to grow them. Therefore, the Combination is not adding

anything new to the same.

151
Section 20(4)(b), The Competition Act, 2002, § 20(4)(b).
152
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development ‘Merger Remedies’ (OECD, 2003)
< https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/34305995.pdf>
153 Hedda Berto, ‘Sharing is caring – An Examination of the Essential Facilities Doctrine and its

Applicability to Big Data’ (2020), <http://www.diva-


portal.se/smash/get/diva2:1435499/FULLTEXT01.pdf>

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 28


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

B. Countervailing buyer power exists in the market

[¶ 80.] It is further submitted that there exists countervailing power in the market and the

Combination does not violate Section 20(4)(d) of the Act. 154 Countervailing buyer power exists

in a market where a consumer is able to use its negotiating strength particularly to constrain the

ability of the Combination to increase prices. 155 Where the consumers can exercise their

negotiating power or have alternatives, there is a countervailing power in the market.

[¶ 81.] There exist other platforms such as Bart where consumers can switch, and other OTT

platforms that prevent Novak from raising price or to exercise any unreasonable power in the

market. Further, due to digitalization, a large population is shifting online. 156 The pace of evolution

of digital markets and the dependency on them is increasing at a faster pace, making the buyers

more impowered. Therefore, it is highly unlikely that consumers would have to pay higher prices

as an effect of this Combination, unlike the cases where combinations have reduced countervailing

power in the market. 157 This gives immense countervailing power in the hands of the buyer.

Therefore, the Combination does not violate Section 20(4)(d) of the Act.

[¶ 82.] It is submitted that the Combination would not violate other factors under Section 20(4) of

the Act. The Combination does not have a capacity to increase the prices or profit margins

significantly due to the availability of substitutes, and therefore, it does not violate Section 20(4)e

of the Act. It is further submitted that the extent of effective competition is likely to sustain in the

market and it aids in the growth of innovation and technology. Therefore, the Combination does

not cause adverse impact on the effective competition in the market, and thus, it should be allowed.

154
The Competition Act 2002, § 20(4)(d),
155
Whish (n 4) p. 940
156 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, ‘The Evolving Concept of Market

Power in the Digital Economy’, (OECD Competition Policy Roundtable Background Note, 2022)
157 Federal Trade Commission v Staples 970 F. Supp. 1066 (D.D.C. 1997); Dr Pepper/Seven-Up

Companies v Federal Trade Commission 991 F.2d 859 (D.C. Cir. 1993).

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 29


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

[IV.] THE COMBINATION CAN BE OBJECTIVELY JUSTIFIED BASED ON EFFICIENCIES

ARISING FROM IT

[¶ 83.] It is submitted that competitive markets have higher efficiency providing maximum

satisfaction attainable by the society. And the Combination of Novak and Sierra would further

lead to efficiency in the market. There are no adverse effects on competition in the market due to

the Combination. Nonetheless, the efficiency that the Combination would brought into the market

would counteract the effects on competition and potential harm, if any, to consumers that would

otherwise have occurred.

[¶ 84.] The efficiency in the market is measured is mainly measured from two factors; 158 firstly,

the Combination may increase the speed of an innovative product reaching the market. Secondly,

the Combination would incentivise investment that ultimately benefits consumers. Both the

factors are being fulfilled here. The acquisition of Sierra having around 5% market share would

help in providing more attractive offers to the increased consumer base. This would help Novak

to diversify it’s services to consumers by providing more time-related data and information. This

aids in nature and extent of innovation in the market, which is one of the factors while assessing

the Combination.159

[¶ 85.] It is submitted that the BCLT has to look at privacy concerns not in isolation as the BCLT

is not empowered to do the same. 160 The BCLT is empowered to look at privacy issues only while

determining the test of ‘significantly impede effective competition’. It was established above that

the Combination does not impede the competition in the market in any way. Just looking at the

privacy would not serve the purpose here.

158
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, ‘Start-ups, Killer Acquisitions and
Merger Control’, (OECD, 2020) <https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/start-ups-killer-
acquisitions-and-merger-control-2020.pdf>
159 The Competition Act, 2002, s 20(4)(l),.
160 Ben Holles de Peyer, ‘EU Merger Control and Big Data’ (2018) 13(4) Journal of Competition

Law and Economics p. 767-790;

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 30


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE APELLANT [WRITTEN ARGUMENTS]

[¶ 86.] If the BCLT were to begin evaluating privacy that are not linked to competition in the

merger control processes, i.e. freestanding privacy concerns, this could move the attention of

antitrust law away from efficiency. No personal data of consumers are being asked and whatever

data is required, it is required while and for using the platform. The same is utilized to provide

real-time information to consumers for providing them the best experience. The Combination

would solely further the same objective. Therefore, it is submitted that the Combination is

increasing efficiency in the market and counteracting the potential harm, if any, to consumers.

THE FIFTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2024 31


WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS ON BEHALF OF THE PETITIONER [PRAYER]

PRAYER

Whereof in the light of the issues raised, arguments advanced, and authorities cited, it is most

humbly prayed that this Honorable Tribunal may be pleased to adjudge and declare that:

I. Novak has not violated § 3 of the Act

II. Novak has not violated § 4 of the Act

III. Mr. Samesh Rippy does not have locus to challenge the order of the CCB dated May 26,

2023 within the meaning of § 53B of the Act

IV. The Sierra Acquisition does not cause AAEC in the market in light of various factors listed

under § 20(4) of the Act

And pass any order that it may deem fit in light of equity, fairness, and good conscience.

For this act of kindness, the appellants shall duty-hound forever pray.

ON BEHALF OF NOVAK, CCB.

029-A

COUNSEL FOR NOVAK, CCB.

THE THIRTEENTH NLU ANTITRUST LAW MOOT COURT COMPETITION, 2022 PAGE | 32

You might also like