Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

Game analysis of price competition

among telecommunications operators in


India
Received (in revised form): 13th October, 2010

Niranjan Varma*
is pursuing his masters in telecommunications at the Indian Institute of Technology-Delhi. He studied for his bachelor’s degree in
engineering at Jawaharlal Nehru Technological University-Hyderabad. His areas of interest include telecommunication networks, wireless
communications and telecom markets.

Seema Sharma
is an assistant professor in the area of economics and statistical analysis. She has a PhD from IIT Delhi. The major area of her research
centres on productivity and efficiency analysis. She has published her research in national and international refereed Journals of high
repute. She has participated and presented her research in many national and international conferences in India and abroad and has
travelled widely to countries such as USA, Japan, France, Australia, Thailand and the Czech Republic.

*Bharti School of Telecommunications, IIT Delhi, New Delhi, India


Tel: +91 9810894657; E-mail: varma.niranjan@gmail.com

Abstract After liberalisation of the telecommunications (telecoms) sector in India, there has been
a continuous decrease in telecoms tariffs in the country. In this paper, the authors perform a game
analysis of price competition in the Indian telecoms market. Apart from discussing the effect of
price reduction by operators on the industry, the paper also attempts to determine the equilibrium
price at which the market will stabilise giving sustainable profits to telecoms operators. The
authors consider the cases of rational competition and vicious competition in their analysis.

KEYWORDS: telecoms operators, revenue, growth, price war, game analysis, Nash equilibrium
JEL CLASSICIATION: L96

PRINCIPAL MANAGEMENT was to provide access to all people for certain


IMPLICATIONS basic telecoms services at affordable and
The history of the telecommunications reasonable prices.2
(telecoms) industry in India starts way back in To provide an effective regulatory
1851. The Department of Telecom was framework and adequate safeguards to ensure
constituted in 1985, but there was no significant fair competition and protection of consumer
development in the industry until liberalisation interests, the Telecom Regulatory Authority of
of the telecoms sector in 1994.1 In the pre- India (TRAI) was constituted in 1997. The first
liberalisation scenario, telephone density was 0.8 tariff regulation was issued in 1998 by TRAI.3
per 100 persons compared to the world average The Government recognised that the result of
of 10.0 per 100 persons. In 1994, the the liberalisation thus far had not been entirely
Government announced its National Telecom satisfactory. In 1999, a new National Telecom
Policy (NTP), which defined certain important Policy was introduced with the main objectives
objectives, like availability of telephony on of achieving efficiency and transparency in
demand, provision of world class services at spectrum management, and protecting the
reasonable prices, ensuring India’s emergence as defence and security interests of the country,
a major manufacturing base of telecoms thereby enabling Indian telecoms companies to
equipment and universal availability of basic become truly global players.4
telecoms services to all villages. The major goal The tariff decline started with the

352 Journal of Telecommunications Management Vol. 3, 4 352–359 # Henry Stewart Publications 1754–1662 (2011)
Game analysis of price competition among telecoms operators in India

notification of the Telecommunication Tariff years, India reached 600 million subscribers
Order (TTO) in 1999 by the regulator and (including wireless and wireline) in 2010.6
continued thereafter. A few years ago a local Greater demand for better services and speed
call from a mobile cost around Rs15 per have made the market more competitive. As a
minute and calls received by mobile subscribers result, tariffs have been falling continuously
cost about the same. Today it costs less than 50 across the board, making Indian tariffs one of
paise per minute for outgoing calls with the lowest in the world. Going forward, the
absolutely no charge for incoming calls. The sector is likely to achieve larger growth rates
major drivers for this fall in telecoms prices with a whole range of new services expected
have been liberalisation, globalisation, new over the next few years with the coming of
players, new technologies and services, and 3G.
lower equipment costs. Liberalisation and The total subscriber base (both wireless and
globalisation are creating new types of telecoms wireline) of the telecoms sector in India during
players, which are investing hugely and the financial year 2009–10 crossed the 600
changing their strategies as the market evolves. million mark. The telecoms industry notched
With advancements in technology, switching up 38,520 crores of rupees in revenues during
and transmission equipment costs are decreasing the quarter ending 31st December, 2009,
considerably and more capacity and bandwidth helped by a recovery in mobile and landline
are available at lower costs.5 services.7 The growth in the subscriber base in
The rest of this paper is organised as follows. the Indian telecoms sector is shown in Figure 1,
The next section presents a discussion on which clearly illustrates the rapid rate of
revenue and growth of the telecoms industry in subscriber growth.
India. It also discusses trends in average revenue ARPUs have been decreasing over the last
per user (ARPU) and comparisons with global few quarters with a sharp decline in tariffs
markets. A cost analysis of the Indian telecoms despite the increase in minutes of usage per user
industry and drivers for low prices in the per month.8 It can be observed from Table 1
industry are discussed in the third section. A that the revenue of the telecoms industry was
model for analysing price competition in the growing over the last few quarters, but it
market is given in the fourth section, together almost stabilised in the last three quarters even
with a discussion of the marginal costs involved when subscriber additions were significant.
in the Indian telecoms industry. Finally, the This is due to sharp declines in ARPUs and
study is concluded in the fifth section. tariffs in the telecoms sector. Table 1 presents
the revenue of the telecoms industry and
ARPUs in India over the last few quarters.9
THE TELECOMS INDUSTRY IN
INDIA: REVENUE AND GROWTH Comparison with global markets
PERFORMANCE In India, telecoms tariffs are the lowest in the
The telecoms sector is one of the fastest world and ARPUs are declining.10 Despite low
growing sectors in India and the fastest ARPUs, the telecoms operators in India are
growing telecoms market in the world, with a getting very good gross revenues compared to
compound annual growth of 34 per cent over their counterparts in Europe and other parts of
the last decade. This impressive rate is a result the world due to their huge subscriber base and
of India’s economic growth and liberalisation the growth in that subscriber base. But, at the
policy since 1991 and the fundamental, present rate of growth in teledensity and
structural and institutional reforms during that decline in ARPUs, the industry cannot be
period. Today, India has nearly 490 million sustained if tariffs continue to go down at the
subscribers and, with an annual addition of present rate. Telecoms tariffs in various
more than 125 million over the last couple of countries are presented in Table 2.

# Henry Stewart Publications 1754–1662 (2011) Vol. 3, 4 352–359 Journal of Telecommunications Management 353
Varma and Sharma

Figure 1: The growth of the Indian subscriber base, 1999–09 (in millions)
Source: Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI), Government of India ‘Annual Report 2008–09’, 2009, New Delhi.

Table 1: ARPU and revenue of the telecoms industry Table 2: Telecoms tariffs in various countries

Quarter Revenue ARPU (Rs) Country Tariff (US$)


(Rs cr7)
Belgium 0.23
Oct–Dec 2009 14,090.63 155.60 Italy 0.22
Jul–Sep 2009 14,311.14 173.66 UK 0.19
Apr–Jun 2009 14,540.94 191.28 France 0.17
Jan–Mar 2009 14,197.06 207.87 Brazil 0.16
Oct–Dec 2008 13,696.50 221.84 Philippines 0.11
Jul–Sep 2008 12,323.04 226.71 Taiwan 0.11
Apr–Jun 2008 12,027.33 246.71 Argentina 0.11
Jan–Mar 2008 11,454.41 253.44 Malaysia 0.09
Oct–Dec 2007 10,346.62 267.91 Hong Kong 0.05
Jul–Sep 2007 9,496.56 280.53 Thailand 0.05
Apr–Jun 2007 9,013.80 308.07 China 0.03
Jan–Mar 2007 7,627.34 301.38 India 0.02
Oct–Dec 2006 6,974.32 315.93
Jul–Sep 2006 6,330.27 335.46 Source: BSNL, Government of India (2008) ‘Growth of Telecom
Apr–Jun 2006 5,620.59 346.59 Sector in India’, TDSAT, Chennai
Jan–Mar 2006 4,942.12 356.21

Source: Cellular Operators Association of India (COAI) ‘ARPU


Revenue Analysis Report’, Q1 2006 to Q4 2009, New Delhi
related to the licence fee, infrastructure
deployment and real estate costs. Marginal costs
COST ANALYSIS OF THE INDIAN refer to spectrum charges, interconnection
TELECOMS SECTOR charges and termination charges. Three
The costs involved in the telecoms industry can approaches are followed to evaluate these costs,
be broadly classified as fixed costs and marginal namely, top-down methodology, bottom-up
costs. Fixed costs refer to the costs that are methodology and outside-in methodology.

354 Journal of Telecommunications Management Vol. 3, 4 352–359 # Henry Stewart Publications 1754–1662 (2011)
Game analysis of price competition among telecoms operators in India

After evaluating the costs involved, pricing of assuming that the services provided by all
the services is done by four methodologies, telecoms operators are identical and consumers
namely, discretionary price setting, are sensitive to prices. So only the telecoms
benchmarking, rate of return and price cap.11 operator whose price is low can sell its
The top-down model is based on an products. Let pi, pj, pk, . . . be the prices of
operator’s accounts, taking into consideration telecoms operators I, J, K, . . . nth, respectively,
the service costs incurred in the previous year. and also assume that the product demand of
The bottom-up model estimates the cost that a operator I is a – pi when operator I has the
hypothetical reasonably efficient operator lowest price in the market compared to all
would incur providing the same services as the other players in the market; the product
incumbent. The outside-in approach uses demand of telecoms operator I is (a – pi)/n
‘proxy’ estimates from outside sources vis-a`-vis when all operators are pricing their products at
establishing cost benchmarks and a range of the same price; and the product demand of
costs for services or facilities. operator I is zero when its price is greater than
In the discretionary price setting, strong that of any other operator, as shown below.
focus is on social objectives, usually prevalent 8
in government-operated telecoms networks. In <ða  pi Þ; if pi < pj ; pi < pk ; :::pi < pn
benchmarking, prices are set by comparison qi ðpi ; pj ; pk Þ ða  pi Þ=n; if pi ¼ pj ¼ pk :::pn
:
with similar countries, eg those with similar 0; if pi > pj or pi > pk ; :::pi > pn
national/geographic characteristics, similar
(1)
markets etc. In the rate of return approach, the
operator is allowed to make a certain return on Where a is a constant much greater than the
investment. In the price cap approach, revenue costs, and a – pi denotes that the higher the prices
received from a ‘basket of services’ is regulated. of operator I, the lower its product demand and
In India, the pricing policy is not discretionary hence the lower the number of subscribers for its
for the players because TRAI adopted the price product. The same assumptions are applicable to
cap pricing methodology.12 In price capping, J, K, . . . nth.13
the prices of services like local calls, subscriber
trunk dialling (STD) calls, short messaging Price war in the telecoms sector
service (SMS) and packet data are not regulated Due to intense competitive rivalry, a price war
individually. They are viewed as a basket of leads to a multilateral series of price reductions.
services and the operator has to submit a report One operator lowers its prices, then others
on the price packages provided in order to gain lower their prices to match. If one operator
approval from the regulator. reduces its price again, a new round of
reductions starts. In the short term, price wars
MODEL OF TELECOMS MARKET are good for consumers but often they are not
In this section, price competition in the Indian good for the operating companies involved.
telecoms industry is modelled mathematically Today, there are 11 telecoms operators in
and a game analysis is applied to determine the India and there is no limit to the number of
effects on revenue and product demand of a operators per circle. New telecoms operators
telecoms operator reducing its prices. The Nash with deep pockets are very enthusiastic in the
equilibrium is obtained for the cases of rational Indian telecoms industry and are ready to bear
competition and vicious competition. initial loses in order to become established in
the market. With falling ARPUs and declining
Mathematical modelling for price tariffs the industry will not be able to provide
competition analysis services if the costs involved are not considered
Suppose there are n operators providing when setting prices, even though the 3G
services, namely I, J, K, . . . nth operator, auctioning process is at the penultimate stage

# Henry Stewart Publications 1754–1662 (2011) Vol. 3, 4 352–359 Journal of Telecommunications Management 355
Varma and Sharma

and huge money is being invested to acquire ða  c2 Þ2


ui ¼ uj ¼ uk ¼ ::: ¼  c1 ¼
spectrum.14 If operators lose their revenue at 4n
this stage due to vicious competition in the a2 ac2 c22
 þ  c1 (5)
telecoms sector, the industry’s growth will be 4n 2n 4n
slowed down. In such a case, it is necessary to This is the revenue function of each operator.
discuss price competition among telecoms Now suppose operator I reduces its prices, ie,
operators. pi<pj<pk ...) set pi ¼ na, then the revenue
According to the characteristic that the cost function of operator I is:
of a communications enterprise has a larger
proportion of fixed costs and a smaller u’i(pi, pj, pk ...)=qi(pi, pj, pk ...)(pi – c2) – c1
proportion of marginal costs, it is assumed that ðn  1Þa2
the prices of all the operators are the same, ¼  c1 (6)
n2
namely, the fixed cost is c1, and the marginal
cost is c2. The revenue functions of the three Comparing (5) and (6), because it was assumed
enterprises are: that a is much greater than costs u’i(pi, pj, pk ...)>
ui(pi, pj, pk ...) (actually it is true for all n > 4/3)
ui(pi, pj, pk, ...)=qi(pi, pj, pk, ...)(pi – c2) – c1 and: q’i ¼ ðn1Þan > q1 ¼ ac 2n . Here it can also be
2

uj(pi, pj, pk, ...)=qi(pi, pj, pk, ...)(pj – c2) – c1 (2) observed that the new revenue of the operator
uk(pi, pj, pk, ...)=qi(pi, pj, pk, ...)(pk – c2) – c1 includes extra revenue of ac2/2n which may be
... interpreted as revenue from new customers who
joined the operator after it reduced its prices.
According to the price competition model, From the above analysis it can be observed
when, the revenue functions of telecoms that, by decreasing the price of services, an
operators I, J, K, . . . nth are (from (1)): operator can increase its subscriber base and
revenue. The same analysis can be applied to
a  pi
ui(pi, pj, pi, ...)= (pi – c2) – c1 any number of operators. Hence operators
n decrease their prices to increase their market
a  pj
uj(pi, pj, pi, ...)= (pj – c2) – c1 (3) share and revenue. Since the market was
n considered to be price sensitive, if one operator
a  pk
uk(pi, pj, pi, ...)= (pk – c2) – c1 reduces its prices others will lose their
. . .. n customers and, in order to hold onto their
market share, they also need to reduce their
It is known that, for the revenue function to be prices. This leads to a price war in the market.
maximum, its first order derivative is zero. The above analysis could be extended to more
Taking the partial derivatives of (3) with than three players. Here the authors made an
respect to their prices and equating to zero15 assumption that the market was completely
obtains: price sensitive, whereas in a real-life scenario it
@ui 1 would not be the case.
= ða  2pi þ c2 Þ  c1 The above analysis can be appreciated by
@pi n
observing the trends of subscriber base growth
@uj 1 and revenue growth in the telecoms industry
= ða  2pj þ c2 Þ  c1 (4)
@pj n over the last decade when telecoms tariffs are
@uk 1 reduced by operators to increase their revenue
= ða  2pk þ c2 Þ  c1 and subscriber base. The cumulative growth of
@pk n
the industry in terms of revenue can be
Solving these equations: pi=pj=pk= ...=aþc
2 ,
2
observed in Table 1 when tariffs are reduced.
ac2
qi=qj=qk= ...= 2n and the value of the The impact on the subscriber base also can be
revenue functions of I, J and K are: observed in Figure 1.

356 Journal of Telecommunications Management Vol. 3, 4 352–359 # Henry Stewart Publications 1754–1662 (2011)
Game analysis of price competition among telecoms operators in India

Nash equilibrium qi...), where operator L has the least product


The price war will continue until one of the demand ql.
operators encounters a price below which it Discussing the above process step-wise, four
cannot sell its products without making losses. steps are encountered:
At this price, the price war will end and prices
in the market will come to an equilibrium . Step 1: Operator I reduces its prices to
point. In game theory, the Nash increase its revenue and product demand.
equilibrium16,17 is a solution concept for a . Step 2: Other operators also reduce their
game involving two or more players in which prices to match the prices of I if they are
each player is assumed to know the equilibrium more than c2+c1 / ql, where ql is the product
strategies of the other players, and no player demand of the operator having least product
has anything to gain by changing only their demand.
own strategy unilaterally. If each player has . Step 3: If the prices of operator I are greater
chosen a strategy and no player can benefit by than c2+c1 / ql, then repeat steps 1 and 2.
changing their strategy while the other players . Step 4: If the prices of operator I are equal to
keep theirs unchanged, then the current set of c2+c1 / ql, the price war ends and the Nash
strategy choices and the corresponding payoffs equilibrium is (c2+c1 / ql, c2+c1 / ql, c2+c1 /
constitute the Nash equilibrium. The Nash qi...).
equilibrium concept is used to analyse the
outcome of the strategic interaction of several If price competition does not end at the above
decision makers. In other words, it is a way of point, the market enters into vicious
predicting what will happen if several people competition. In vicious competition, when a
or several institutions are making decisions at telecoms operator’s profits are zero, it will
the same time, and if the decision of each one reduce its prices further, in order to explore the
depends on the decisions of the others. market,18 but only to such a level where it can
To obtain the Nash equilibrium two market cover at least its marginal costs, c2. Although its
situations have to be studied, namely, rational prices cannot cover fixed costs, the operator
competition and vicious competition. In can cover marginal costs and still explore the
rational competition, analysing from the market. This is the case where an operator has
perspective of profitability, price competition been providing services for a long time and has
will end when one of the operator’s profits is already recovered its capital investment. So, the
zero. Operator I can reduce its prices to a level, Nash equilibrium in this case is: c2, c2, c2...).
c2+c1 / qi, at which point the profits of operator To get a numerical insight of the results
I are zero. Suppose there is some other derived above, suppose there are two operators
operator, say L, which has less product demand in the market with fixed and marginal costs
than operator I. While I is reducing its prices to involving Rs100 and Rs0.5, respectively.
increase its revenue, at some point prices will Suppose that the first operator has a product
reach a level where operator L is making zero demand of 200 minutes of usage and the second
profit due to its low product demand. Then L operator has a product demand of 100 minutes
has no advantage from price competition. At of usage. Then, from the above analysis, it can
this point, because L will make a loss if it be observed that the equilibrium price in
further reduces its prices, it will not reduce its rational competition is (0.5+100/100, 0.5+
prices below the level c2+c1 / ql and even I 100/100), ie (1.5, 1.5), and in vicious
would like to maintain profitability. Without competition the equilibrium price is (0.5, 0.5).
loss of generality, the same theory can be Here notice that in rational competition the
extended to all other players in the market. first operator is making a profit and the second
Thus the price war comes to an end with the operator is just able to sustain itself in the
equilibrium price: (c2+c1 / ql, c2+c1 / ql, c2+c1 / market, but in vicious competition neither of

# Henry Stewart Publications 1754–1662 (2011) Vol. 3, 4 352–359 Journal of Telecommunications Management 357
Varma and Sharma

the operators is making a profit. For example, compensated by huge additions to the
suppose that a new operator with deep pockets subscriber base. In India, teledensity has reached
enters the competition and decreases the price a level of more than 52 per cent and the
below the existing market price to build a remaining untapped market lies in rural areas.
subscriber base. If the equilibrium prices Until now, revenues have been growing
derived above are not considered, due to the rapidly due to significant additions to the
price war in the market, all the operators will subscriber base and good ARPUs. But the
have to incur losses and the industry will suffer revenues of telecoms operators during recent
in the long run. quarters were almost stabilising, despite huge
additions to the subscriber base, due to a sharp
Indian market fall in tariffs. With the current growth rates in
In India, marginal costs at present comprise a the subscriber base, the market will saturate in
spectrum fee of 2 paise per minute, an the near future and tariffs also will reach an
interconnection fee to be paid by the operator equilibrium level.
to the backbone network of 13 paise per From this analysis, the authors found that,
minute, and a termination fee to be paid by the when a telecoms operator reduces its price, its
operator to another operator if a call is made market share will be larger and even its profits
from its network to another network of 20 will increase. This is the reason for price wars
paise per minute.19 By considering the above between telecoms operators. In rational
costs involved, the marginal cost is 2 paise for competition, the price reaches equilibrium at
local calls within the same network, 15 paise the zero margin level of an operator whose
for local calls to other networks, 22 paise for product demand is the lowest. In the case of
STD calls within the same network and 37 vicious competition, the equilibrium price of a
paise for STD calls to other networks. These service is its marginal cost.
charges include the spectrum fee,
interconnection charge and termination charge. Acknowledgments
Operators can provide lower prices than these The authors gratefully acknowledge the
if they can negotiate interconnection charges to support offered by the Department of
a lower level. Management Studies and Bharti School of
From the results derived in the above Telecommunications, Technology and
section, it can be observed that the tariff Management, IIT Delhi.
prevailing in the Indian market — around 60
paise/minute — is fairly above the marginal References
cost level and therefore there is rational 1 Telecom India Daily (2006) ‘Indian Telecom History’, Vol.
competition. It should be noted also that 1, Telecom India Online, New Delhi, available at:
www.telecomindiaonline.com/indiantelecomhistory.pdf
telecoms operators can sustain vicious
(accessed 18th January, 2011)
competition only after recovering their capital 2 India-gii (1997) ‘Telecom pricing’, consultation paper on
investment, otherwise they will run into losses concepts, principles and methodologies, New Delhi,
in the long run. Hence, TRAI has to keep a available at: http://members.tripod.com/india_gii/ (accessed
18th January, 2011).
vigilant eye on competition in the market as 3 Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI) (1998)
operators have invested heavily in acquiring 3G ‘Telecom Tariff Order’, TRAI, New Delhi.
spectrum recently and new operators are 4 The Government of India (1999) ‘New Telecom Policy’,
New Delhi.
entering the market. 5 Misra, N. (2008) ‘Tariff trends in Indian telecom’, world
connect, India, Vol. 6, pp. 7–8.
CONCLUSIONS 6 Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI) (2010)
‘Telecom subscribers growth for the month of March’, 26th
The telecoms industry in India is rapidly
April, TRAI, New Delhi.
growing in terms of subscribers and revenue. 7 See: http://www.ibef.org/industry/telecommunications.aspx
But the sector is losing ARPU and this is being (accessed 4th May, 2010).

358 Journal of Telecommunications Management Vol. 3, 4 352–359 # Henry Stewart Publications 1754–1662 (2011)
Game analysis of price competition among telecoms operators in India

8 Government of India (2008) ‘Telecom Development in Engineering, 26th-27th December, 2009, Xi’an, China, pp.
India’, Bharath Sanchar Nigam Limited, 3rd August, 102–105.
Chennai. 14 Thomas, P. and Kalyan, P. (2009) ‘Bids for 3G irrational’,
9 Cellular Operators Association in India (2009) ‘ARPU- Economic Times, 26th April.
REVENUE Analysis’, COAI, New Delhi, December. 15 Cheng and Tang, ref. 13 above.
10 Government of India, ref. 8 above. 16 Felegyhazi, M. and Hubaux, J.-P. (2007) ‘Game Theory in
11 Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI) (2008) Wireless Networks: A Tutorial’, Laboratoire d’Informatique
‘Consultation Paper on Review of Interconnection Usage Algorithmique: Fondements et Applications, Paris, June.
Charge (IUC)’, TRAI, New Delhi, 31st December. 17 Ferguson, T. S. (2003) ‘Game Theory’, University of
12 Ibid. California, Los Angeles, CA.
13 Cheng, Z. and Tang, S. (2009) ‘Game analysis of price 18 Qu, Z. and Sun, T. (2001) ‘Telecom price control and
competition and cooperation of telecom operators’, in innovation’, World Telecommunications, Vol. 7, pp. 25–27.
proceedings of the International Conference on Information 19 Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI) (2008),
Management, Innovation Management and Industrial course lecture at IIT Delhi by a TRAI expert.

# Henry Stewart Publications 1754–1662 (2011) Vol. 3, 4 352–359 Journal of Telecommunications Management 359
Copyright of Journal of Telecommunications Management is the property of Henry Stewart Publications LLP
and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright
holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.

You might also like