Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 39

Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 21, Number 4 —Fall 2007—Pages 91–114

Personnel Economics: The Economist’s


View of Human Resources

Edward P. Lazear and Kathryn L. Shaw

P ersonnel economics drills deeply into the firm to study human resource
management practices like compensation, hiring practices, training, and
teamwork. Many questions are asked: Why should pay vary across workers
within firms—and how “compressed” should pay be within firms? Should firms pay
workers for their performance on the job or for their skills or hours of work? How
are pay and promotions structured across jobs to induce optimal effort from
employees? Why do firms use teams and how are teams used most effectively? How
should all these human resource management practices, from incentive pay to
teamwork, be combined within firms? Personnel economists offer new tools to
analyze these questions—and new answers as well.
In the not-too-distant past, the typical textbook on human resources manage-
ment would often eschew generalization, arguing that each situation is different.
The economist’s approach is the opposite. Rather than thinking of each human
resources event as separate and institutionally driven, economists place a premium
on identifying the underlying general principles, and on using specific institutional
details to identify the causal sources of the general principles. Four primary
building blocks from economics form the foundation of personnel economics:
First, personnel economics assumes that both the worker and the firm are rational
maximizing agents, seeking utility and profits. Of course, the economic approach

y Edward P. Lazear is on leave as Jack Steele Parker Professor of Economics and Human
Resources Management, Graduate School of Business, and Morris A. Cox Senior Fellow,
Hoover Institution, both at Stanford University, Stanford, California. Since February 2006,
he has been Chairman of the President’s Council of Economic Advisers, Washington, D.C.
Kathryn Shaw is Ernest Arbuckle Professor of Economics, Graduate School of Business,
Stanford University, Stanford, California.
92 Journal of Economic Perspectives

allows for constraints or imperfections, such as imperfect information and trans-


action costs, and permits an individual’s utility to be influenced by a variety of
factors such as personal identity, competition, and peer pressure. Second, person-
nel economists assume that labor markets and product markets must reach some
price– quantity equilibrium, which provides discipline for our models. Third, effi-
ciency is a central concept of personnel economics. In the many circumstances in
which inefficiencies arise, the economist pushes the analysis to another level by
asking where equilibrating market forces might have failed, and asking what actions
firms and/or workers might take to reduce the inefficiency. Fourth, personnel
economists emphasize the use of econometrics and experimental design to identify
underlying causal relationships. For example, some firms observe that if the firm
moves to piece rate pay, productivity rises. However, it turns out that piece rate pay
induces the most productive workers to join the firm, as well as changing the
productivity of existing workers.
During the last 25 years, as personnel economics has emerged as a field,
human resources practices have systematically changed. For example, compensa-
tion now varies much more highly across individuals. In 1974, the 90th percentile of
wage earners received about 1.9 times the hourly wage of the 50th percentile, but
this multiple has risen steadily over the last three decades and has now reached
about 2.3. Meanwhile the ratio of the hourly wage paid to the 50th percentile of
wage earners compared to the 10th percentile rose somewhat from about 1.9 in
1974 to 2.1 over the next three decades, but since then has sagged back to a ratio
of about 2.0. In other words, wage inequality has risen markedly mainly because the
upper tail of high earners has grown (Autor, Katz, and Kearney, 2006, forthcom-
ing). This rising variance of pay has occurred within occupations and across
occupations. The variance of pay has also risen within firms and across firms.
The rising variance of pay across individuals surely reflects changing demand
for skills, but also is likely to reflect changes in human resource practices. Com-
pensation has shifted towards pay-for-performance. The proportion of employees’
pay that comes from bonuses rather than from base salary has increased. Table 1A
shows that the share of large firms that have more than 20 percent of their
workforce working with some form of individual incentives, like a performance
bonus, has grown from 38 percent to 67 percent. The percent of firms using any
form of “gain-sharing” or group-based incentives has grown from 26 percent to
53 percent.
Teamwork has become prevalent in many firms. Firms reported pronounced
increases in teamwork since the 1980s, as shown in Table 1B. From 1987 to 1996,
the share of large firms that have more than 20 percent of their workers in
problem-solving teams rose from 37 percent to 66 percent. The percent of large
firms with workers in self-managed work teams rose from 27 percent to 78 percent.
Team use seems to have reached a plateau in the later 1990s, but it’s a high-
level plateau.
Personnel economics is aimed at modeling firms’ use of optimal management
Edward P. Lazear and Kathryn L. Shaw 93

Table 1
Human Resource Management Practices in Large Firms

A: Incentive Pay

% of firms with. . .

individual more than 20% of


incentives, like employees having more than 20% of more than 20% of
performance individual employees having skill-based employees having
bonuses incentives gainsharing gainsharing pay skill-based pay

1987 83 38 26 7 40 15
1990 90 45 39 11 51 17
1993 90 50 42 16 60 23
1996 91 57 45 19 72 22
1999 93 67 53 24 72 26

B: Teamwork

% of firms with. . .

20% or more 20% or more in more than 20%


employees in self-managed self-managed given team-
teams teams teams teams building skills

1987 70 37 27 7 54
1990 86 51 47 10 55
1993 91 65 62 20 75
1996 94 66 78 32 78
1999 84 61 72 28 76

Source: Lawler, Mohrman, and Benson (2001), Lawler, Mohrman, and Ledford (1995).

practices that have contributed to these trends. In what follows, we examine topics
that have become fixtures of personnel economics and attempt to demonstrate
how the notions of maximization, equilibrium, efficiency, and econometric
modeling have enabled economists to further the understanding of human
resources management.

Promotions and Raises

In many large corporations with hierarchical management structures,


wages show discrete jumps between levels of the hierarchy, rather than contin-
uous increases. For example, Jack Welch left General Electric in 2001, when he
earned $4 million in base pay as chief executive officer. He was succeeded by
Jeffrey Immelt, who earned $2.75 million in base pay in his first year as chief
executive officer. But in the previous year, Immelt had been a vice president
94 Journal of Economic Perspectives

earning $1 million (General Electric Corporation, 2001). Why did Immelt’s value
to the company more than double from one day to the next? The annual reports
of public companies are rife with comparable examples in which a job promotion
at the upper executive levels brings a very large salary increase.
In standard human capital theory, wages are determined by skills, and no
conceivable story would allow Immelt’s skills to increase dramatically a few minutes
before he was promoted. Yet this flies in the face of common patterns of managerial
compensation. It appears that jobs themselves—particularly high-level manage-
ment jobs—play a large role in determining the wages of the jobholder. When
Immelt took the top job at General Electric, reports stated that “the Welch protégé
won a valuable prize” and Welch agreed that “He got a hellava raise, I’ll tell you
that” (“GE’s Talent Agency,” Time, December 3, 2000). Analogously standard
notions of competition do not seem to work in this context either. Why didn’t the
other strong candidates for the chief executive officer job offer to work for wages
much lower than those currently being paid to Immelt, bidding down his wage to
close to his previous level?
Something else must be going on. Tournament theory, as it has come to be
called, provides an integrated theory of compensation at different levels of the
hierarchy (Lazear and Rosen, 1981; Green and Stokey, 1983; Nalebuff and Stiglitz,
1983). It addresses how pay raises are associated with promotions and argues that
these compensation levels are not necessarily linked with a naive notion of pro-
ductivity. However, productivity in a broader sense does influence compensation
and is in part determined by it, through an incentive structure. At its heart,
tournament theory makes the point that promotions are a relative gain. Individuals
are promoted not on the basis of their absolute performance, but on the basis of
their relative position in the organization. Furthermore, the compensation at one
level does not necessarily serve to motivate individuals currently working at that
level, but instead motivates all of those below that level who strive to be promoted.
The theory reconciles directly the initial puzzle that individuals are promoted to
jobs and then receive wages associated with those jobs that seem out of line with
their previously recognized skill levels.
Tournament theory begins with the notion that prizes are fixed in advance. In
other words, wages are associated, to a first approximation, with jobs rather than
with the individual who holds the job. A vice president who is promoted to
president receives the salary of a president— even when that salary is considerably
different from the salary previously received. Winning that salary depends on
relative performance. Individuals are promoted not because they are good, but
because they are better than others within the relevant group. Promotion is a
statement about relative position within the firm, not necessarily about absolute
performance. The best worker receives the promotion even if many of the other
workers are excellent.
The larger the pay spread between promotions, the larger the incentive to put
forth effort. Consider a tennis match where winner and loser both receive the same
Personnel Economics: The Economist’s View of Human Resources 95

prize. There is no doubt that individuals generally prefer to win, because pride and
other factors may be involved. But winning becomes more important if the winner’s
prize is significantly larger than the loser’s prize. In tennis, players may practice
harder, forego other competitions, or just focus more on winning when the prize
difference is greater. Similarly, in a corporate hierarchy, a large difference between
the salary of the president and the vice president makes vice presidents more
interested in becoming president, and they put forth considerable effort to get to
that job. Similarly, at lower levels of the hierarchy, newly minted MBAs, lawyers, and
assistant professors work extremely hard so that they can be promoted, or make
partner, or obtain tenure. Accounting firms, law firms, and large corporations all
motivate their managerial employees at least in part by the hope of promotion.
The tournament model also sets limits on the size of pay spreads. Very large
pay spreads induce high effort, but they also create a work environment in the firm
that is not very pleasant. If individuals are working at a very high level of intensity—
say, 80 –90 hours a week—it will be necessary to compensate those employees at a
very high level. At some point, the additional cost to sustain that level of effort will
not be justified by the output. In addition, individuals who are competing with one
another can either seek to outperform others, or they can contribute to the failure
of others. Such incentives can result in collusion (Dye, 1984) or in sabotage
(Lazear, 1989). Thus, pay structure must strike a balance between providing
incentives for effort and reducing the adverse consequences associated with this
kind of industrial politics.
Outsiders can change the nature of internal tournaments. If workers must
compete not only with their coworkers, but also potentially with those employed in
other firms, incentives are diluted. Chan (1996) argues that this is why firms tend
to give preference to insiders over outsiders. Outsiders are hired only when they are
substantially better than insiders. The evidence is that those hired from the outside
move on a faster track than the typical insider at the same position.
Of course, chief executive officers currently receive a significant portion of
their compensation in the form of bonuses or stock and stock options. When Jack
Welch retired as chief executive office of General Electric in 2001, his annual bonus
was $12.5 million. During Immelt’s first year as chief executive officer, his bonus
was $3.5 million. This pattern is consistent with tournament theory because for
chief executive officers who are already at the top rung of the hierarchical ladder,
relative compensation cannot serve as their motivation. Because the output of a
chief executive officer is the profitability of the firm, stock and stock options are a
reasonable metric of their output: in effect, chief executive officers switch from
tournament-like pay to piece rate pay (Rosen, 1986).
Tournament theory has significant empirical support. The structure of wages
within firms and their patterns of promotion are generally consistent with tourna-
ment theory (DeVaro, 2006; Eriksson, 1999). The structure of prizes does seem to
have a direct effect on the level of effort or resources devoted to an activity. For
example, Knoeber and Thurman (1994) show that the size of the spread affects
96 Journal of Economic Perspectives

output in the broiler chicken industry. Ehrenberg and Bognanno (1990) were
among the first to show that effort was responsive to prizes by looking at the scores
that golfers obtained in contests. In experimental work, subjects behave almost
exactly as tournament theory would suggest (Falk and Fehr, 2006). Drago and
Garvey (1998) use a sample of Australian firms to show that when promotion
incentives are strong, individuals put more effort into their jobs (as measured by
absenteeism), but are also less likely to work cooperatively.
For explaining the large discrete jumps in compensation that accompany
major promotions, tournament theory is pretty much the only game in town. It has
stood the test of empirical evidence, it has not been displaced by other theories,
and it is consistent with common sense and standard business vernacular. Indeed,
the competition for the job of chief executive officer at General Electric largely
came down to three individuals: Jeffrey Immelt, Bob Nardelli, and Jim McNerney.
When Immelt got the job, Nardelli went to Home Depot and McNerney to 3M.
When asked later about the competition for the General Electric top job, Bob
Nardelli said “Look, you don’t get to these jobs without being competitive. Any
CEO will harbor that competitive spirit. It’s not against Jeff [Immelt] or Jim
[McNerney]. You want to win. You don’t want to win at their expense, you just want
to win” (USA Today, 2007). This language certainly sounds like someone who
recognizes his own participation in a competitive tournament.

Choice of Compensation Structure and the Hiring and Retention


of Employees

In some firms, most workers are paid a salary. In other firms, bonuses or
performance pay are a big portion of compensation. A survey done by Payscale.com
looked at median salary and bonuses for a sample of occupations in a major
metropolitan area. The median bonus for administrative assistants, social workers,
and nurses is a small percentage of total compensation—less than 2 percent. The
median bonus of a salesperson is $30,000 for nonpharmaceutical sales and almost
$40,000 for pharmaceutical sales. The median salaries of these types of salespersons
are $44,000 and $58,500, respectively, roughly on par with the median registered
nurse’s salary. For salespersons, bonuses make up over 40 percent of total compen-
sation. Pay on the basis of output also extends to much more highly paid jobs, such
as investment bankers, who are paid for the performance of the merger they just
achieved, or hedge fund managers, who are paid for the performance of the fund
they manage. For executive-level positions such as senior vice presidents and chief
executive officers, the portion of compensation paid in bonuses is even larger, and
in fact bonuses often far exceed base salary.
Why do some jobs pay workers an hourly wage or salary and other jobs pay
based on the workers’ performance? Clearly, part of the answer lies in our exam-
Edward P. Lazear and Kathryn L. Shaw 97

Figure 1
Paying for Input versus Paying for Output
(# of people at each wage and output level)

wage 2 ⫽ q ⫺ (measurement costs)


f (q ), f (wage)

q ⫽ output

Output, wage wage 1 ⫽ mean(q )

Note: Without measuring individual output (q), the firm pays wage1 , which is the mean of output across
all workers. After incurring fixed measurement costs, the firm pays all individuals the distribution of
wages labeled wage2. If the firm does not bear these measurement costs, the best workers in area A will
leave the firm for other firms that do measure their individual output.

ples: it is easier, or less costly, to measure the output of salespeople than nurses.
While the cost of measuring output is important in our model, we will tie it to other
key features of employment that build on the concepts of equilibrating markets and
rational decision makers. We will also suggest answers to some important broader
questions: How should firms structure pay for optimal retention of workers? How
should firms avoid losing “star” workers?
Assume that workers in an occupation, such as a portfolio manager at a hedge
fund, have output, q, that varies across workers in the occupation in a typical
bell-curve-shaped distribution shown in Figure 1. Each individual’s output is ini-
tially unknown to the firm, because output is costly to measure. However, the firm
can measure each individual’s output at some cost. The firm has two options. First,
the firm can forego measurement, in which case no measurement cost is incurred
and no information about worker ability is ever revealed. A firm of this sort pays a
straight salary, which must equal the average output. Second, the firm can measure
the output of the employees and pay workers according to their individual output,
which is “pay for performance.” In this case, the distribution of pay matches the
distribution of output, minus the measurement costs.
The question is whether the firm should pay a straight salary—pay all workers
on the basis of input and ignore individual variations in output— or pay on the basis
of measured individual output. Thus, workers will be willing to come to a piece rate
firm if and only if their expected pay in a setting of piece rates with measurement
exceeds their pay in a setting of salary without measurement. The key is for a firm
98 Journal of Economic Perspectives

to choose the human resources practices—pay-for-performance versus salary—


based on the firm’s ability to attract the “right” workers for the firm. This model
provides several important results.
A first implication of this model is that firms will pay for performance when it
is cheaper to measure performance. When measurement costs are low, good
workers will demand that their output be measured. For example, hedge fund
trading is cheap to measure—success is readily quantifiable and relatively near
term—so if one firm pays all traders the same mean wage, the best traders will leave
to work for a firm that does pay for their performance (or will start their own firm).
In Figure 1, the best workers, in area A, will leave the hedge fund firm if the firm
pays an average wage rather than using pay for performance. In contrast, in
commercial banking, it takes years for portfolios to mature, so firms pay average
wages for input, such as hours at the loan desk.1 This model is about self-selection,
or “fit.” Those people who have the skills for hedge fund trading, such as working
under pressure to perform, will gravitate towards this occupation when it does pay
for performance. In contrast, individuals who excel at working with loan customers
will head towards commercial banking. In this case, the firm pays a salary and then
must screen using interviews, experience, and education as signals of talent. Alter-
natively, if the costs of firing are low, firms will hire a range of workers in the full
distribution of Figure 1, then fire for poor performance (Lazear, 1986). Ultimately,
one advantage of pay based on measured output is that individuals who are not well
suited to the required tasks are provided information that allows them to engage in
an alternative activity.
The lower the cost of measuring output, the greater the likelihood that pay is
a function of output. If we look at pay by occupation, we see that pay for output
does rise with our general notion of the ease of measuring output. Empirical
research confirms this: Brown (1990) and Drago and Heywood (1995) show that
piece rates are less common when monitoring costs are higher, a finding in line
with the theoretical prediction. (However, Brown (1992) shows that salaried work-
ers whose salaries are tied to supervisor ratings, do not earn more than their
unsupervised colleagues, in contrast to the theoretical prediction.) We would also
expect that, if the cost of measuring output is decreasing over time— due to
information technologies, for example—then more firms should pay for perfor-
mance. Anecdotal evidence suggests that these patterns hold true, although more
systematic analysis remains to be done (Andersson, Freedman, Haltiwanger, Lane,
and Shaw, 2006).
A second implication of this model is that firms are more likely to pay for
performance as the worker’s alternative wage offers approach the value at the

1
There are other dimensions of output, such as client relations and business development. Sometimes,
compensation schemes build in bonuses for superior performance along these dimensions. Further-
more, revenue is not profit, so incentives are sometimes made product-specific to prevent salespeople
from selling high-price, low-margin goods.
Personnel Economics: The Economist’s View of Human Resources 99

current firm. When a worker has alternative high-paying jobs, it is important for the
firm to pay the worker for what they produce or the firm will lose the worker. One
example is job-hopping in Silicon Valley (Fallick, Fleischman, and Rebitzer, forth-
coming). In the earlier years, computer programming skills would often be firm-
specific (as for Oracle or Microsoft). As Silicon Valley developed, and markets
thickened, many firms could now make use of what were once firm-specific skills,
and mobility rose. More mobility is consistent with fewer firm-specific skills. It also
implies that wages should be more variable across workers in the new environment.
This insight has implications for attracting and retaining workers. Workers
with firm-specific human capital will find that current productivity is likely to be
much greater than their alternative productivity in another job, and so they are less
likely to be paid on the basis of output. Being paid for individual performance is
also more likely to occur when a worker is young, before a great deal of specific
human capital is acquired. Thus, the best time to sort workers is when they are
young. As a corollary, senior people in the firm are less likely to be measured.
Tenure reviews and decisions to promote to partner take place early in careers for
this reason.
Third, as the lower tail in the distribution of worker quality like Figure 1 gets
larger, performance pay is more likely to be optimal. A larger lower tail means that
the value of weeding out low quality workers rises.
Thus far, we have emphasized how the choice between pay for performance
and salary leads to selection and sorting among workers. Conversely, we have
ignored the possibility that paying for performance can induce people to work
harder. Naturally, economists have also emphasized that some people are likely to
work harder when there are tangible rewards. Workers with a high disutility of
effort relative to their output will avoid firms that pay for performance. Workers are
heterogeneous—those who value intrinsic internal motivation more than extrinsic
rewards will gravitate towards jobs with salary or wage-based pay: not everyone
would enjoy the risk and rewards and work environment of being a hedge fund
manager. This feature could be added to the model above, and it would introduce
additional issues that we will not expand upon here. Nonetheless, we can look in
the data to see if pay-for-performance raises output.
The likelihood that pay-for-performance will encourage more effort raises
some questions about identifying causal relationships carefully. For example, hedge
fund managers earn more than do commercial bankers. Since hedge fund man-
agers have a larger portion of income paid in incentive pay, an unwary human
resources person might conclude that paying for output makes workers more
productive. However, putting in place an output-based pay plan for commercial
bankers might well provide only very limited results.
Why might this be the case? First, it takes time for those who are best at selling
loans to switch to those jobs. Thus, productivity gains from moving to a commission-
based system for loan officers may be smaller in the short run than in the long run.
Second, measuring the performance of commercial bankers may prove tricky. For
100 Journal of Economic Perspectives

example, a bank that sets pay based on the number of loans may find that the rate
of loan defaults increases. If a number of those defaults happen only several years
into the future, the commercial bank may find itself better off just paying salary.
Third, loan officers may never be as productive as investment bankers, because
successful investment bankers produce a higher dollar value-added (or productiv-
ity) per unit of effort than do commercial bankers. In keeping with the higher
productivity of investment banking, the firm must hire more highly talented people
as investment bankers, and pay them more. If a human resources manager does not
consider such selection effects, the gains from implementing an incentive pay
program may be much lower than expected.
What do the data tell us? Performance pay is used to induce selection by
workers into the right jobs. For example, Lazear (2000) provides an example of
a firm that installs windshields: individual workers drive their trucks to custom-
ers with damaged windshields and install new windshields. When the firm
switches from hourly pay to piece rate pay, the average daily productivity goes
from two windshields to three. Some of the increase would be due to the
rewards for performance. About half probably comes from selecting workers
who can respond to those incentives (by exerting more effort) and about half
from selecting workers who can respond to those incentives with high effort or
talent.
Numerous other studies find performance gains and selection effects from
performance pay. Other evidence exists on how workers respond when presented
with varying compensation schemes. Asch (1990) presents evidence that Navy
recruiters vary their recruitment effort in response to incentives. Using data on
jockeys, Fernie and Metcalf (1999) show that incentive contracts generate superior
performance to other, noncontingent payment systems. Using an experiment in a
tree-planting firm, Shearer (2004) shows a productivity gain of around 20 percent
when worker compensation was switched from a fixed wage to a piece rate system.
Freeman and Kleiner (2005) do find that productivity falls when switching from
piece rates to salary pay, but profitability rises because performance pay under-
mines other goals, such as lowering inventories. Similarly, Lo, Ghosh, and Lafon-
taine (2006) show that salesmen of industrial products are offered contracts with
piece rate pay in part to increase personal performance and in part to induce the
selection of salespeople who respond well to that type of contract. In a survey of
firms across industries, Parent (1999) documents the existence of an incentive
effect whereby men who are paid a piece rate are induced to work harder/more
efficiently.
Thus, personnel economics provides implications for the structure of pay
across occupations and experience levels. The choice between pay-for-performance
and salary is determined by concerns of economic efficiency in different employ-
ment settings, including the level of measurement costs and the value of screening
out workers to specific employers.
Edward P. Lazear and Kathryn L. Shaw 101

Pay Compression

Another element of the choice of compensation is whether, within a firm, the


firm’s pattern of pay for individuals should have less variance than does individual
performance. No systematic data exists on individual output, so no one knows
whether pay is generally more compressed than output within firms.2 Nevertheless,
managers and human resource professionals within firms do have a sense that pay
is more compressed than output, and often ask the question, how compressed
should pay be?
The often-stated objective of a more compressed pay structure is to make pay
more equitable. People do seem to value equity or fairness in pay (Baron and
Kreps, 1999). However, fairness is a slippery concept. Is it fair to pay all workers the
same amount, or does fairness require that workers are paid in proportion to their
output? What if output results from inherent differences in ability rather than
choice about effort? If endowed ability is viewed as luck, should firms ignore these
differences? If some firms did ignore differences in innate ability, what would
happen in a competitive market where other firms that do pay on the basis of ability
attract the most able workers and thereby lower costs relative to the compressed
wage firms?
There are a number of reasons to believe that some degree of pay compression
is an efficient market outcome. For example, perhaps a greater degree of equity or
fairness produces higher productivity, perhaps through greater teamwork. This
trade-off will vary across firms. For example, in firms with more team-based work,
pay should be more compressed for numerous reasons: equity is more relevant in
close comparisons, and individual output that would attract an outside wage offer
is more difficult to disentangle from group results.
In the tournaments model above, workers may distinguish themselves not only
by making themselves look good, but also by making their rivals look bad. When pay
or other forms of rewards are based on relative performance, cooperation is
discouraged as workers try to outshine their competition. To reduce the incentives
to undermine coworkers, pay compression becomes part of optimal contracts. In
general, pay compression reduces the incentives to engage in sabotage or other
noncooperative behavior that is induced by the prisoner’s-dilemma-style payoff
structure (Lazear, 1989).
A related idea involves pay compression that results because workers try to
influence their superiors (Milgrom, 1988; Prendergast, 1993). As the gains from

2
The evidence on this is sketchy because pay and productivity are rarely measured in the same data set.
The theory and popular literature on this are somewhat schizophrenic. In one paper, Frank (1985)
argues that pay is compressed relative to productivity. Years later, Frank (1996) argues that pay is spread
out too much because of the winner-take-all nature of pay in some occupations. In one dataset that has
productivity and wage data, the variance in productivity is smaller than the variance in pay (Lazear,
1999b).
102 Journal of Economic Perspectives

appearing better than another in the firm increase, the incentives to lobby one’s
boss become greater. Pay compression serves to mitigate these effects.
Finally, pay may be compressed because it is efficient to have the firm insure
workers against uncertain outcomes, like bad luck on the job or bad luck when sales
fall due to market conditions. One difficulty with this kind of insurance is that it is
subject to severe moral hazard problems. If workers know that they will be insured
against low productivity outcomes, incentives to put forth effort are reduced.
It is difficult to test whether firms are compressing pay relative to output. If
some firms compress pay, high-ability workers should leave those firms. Eventually,
firms with compressed pay will be comprised entirely of “average” or below-average
workers. In Lazear and Shaw (forthcoming), we don’t find that that mobility rates
are higher for high-wage people in firms with more compressed pay. But again, the
data we have does not measure ability, so firms with compressed pay may already
lack high-ability workers.

Hedonic Wage Analysis and Nonmonetary Job Attributes

Money isn’t everything. Employees care about more than pay. When asked,
employees state that they care about flexible hours of work, comfortable working
conditions, colleagues whom they enjoy, projects on which they enjoy working, and
bosses who provide recognition and mentoring. Employees also care about the
nonwage benefits, such as health insurance and pensions. However, preferences for
these benefits vary across workers: older workers are more likely to care about
pension benefits or high-quality health insurance than younger ones. The question
is, should the firm offer more pensions, or more health insurance, or flexible
hours? How do benefits affect the amount of base pay offered? The hedonic model
of compensation provides a structure for firms to use in answering these questions.
Benefits are often costly. This fact is obvious in the case of pensions and health
insurance, but even nonmonetary benefits, such as flexible work hours, can
increase coordination costs for the firm. These benefits can also have productivity-
enhancing effects: for example, pensions may cause productivity to rise as workers
invest in more human capital and have a longer time horizon at the firm (Lazear,
1979), or flexibility may increase productivity as workers choose when best to work.
However, the hedonic model tends to focus on the cost side of benefits, or at
least to assume that productivity enhancements from benefits do not totally out-
weigh the costs. In this setting, a trade-off arises—if the firm offers more benefits,
it must offer less pay. How should a firm strike the right balance between wages
and benefits?
The key insight of the hedonic model is that a firm should offer the package
of pay and benefits that will attract the workers it desires. The interaction between
workers’ preferences, the firm’s cost structure, and the firm’s desire to attract
employees will determine how many benefits to offer.
Personnel Economics: The Economist’s View of Human Resources 103

The first and perhaps most obvious prediction of the hedonic model is that
there is a negative trade-off between wages and “positive” job attributes, attributes
like status or flexibility in hours of work.
A second key prediction of the hedonic model is that each firm offers the
benefits that will attract the types of workers that the firm values the most. Consider
an example from the software industry. SAS is a firm that produces statistical
software licensed to big corporations, and their product’s value comes from its very
high re-licensing rate from its existing customers. Therefore, SAS wants software
programmers who serve customers well by designing product upgrades that suit
customer needs. To attract such programmers, SAS offers pension benefits and
other family-friendly benefits. In contrast, the typical firm in Silicon Valley is less
likely to provide pension benefits. These other software firms value software pro-
grammers who are younger and have the latest programming skills in new tech-
nologies. In turn, these young workers prefer high pay (and risky stock options)
and state-of-the art programming projects over pensions.
A market equilibrium sorts workers to their optimal match or “fit” with firms.
The firms that value loyalty among workers, like SAS, will offer pension benefits,
and the workers who want stable long-term jobs will choose these firms and will give
up some base salary to get the pension. The firms that value the skills of a young
mobile workforce will not offer pensions, and the young workers will choose the
high pay and stock options of these firms. The model tells us both how much the
firm should offer in benefits and why they should offer particular benefits to attract
certain types of workers.
Does the data support these two predictions of the model? At first glance, the
data does not support the prediction that wages and benefits are negatively corre-
lated. In fact, if we look at typical job attributes, such as pensions, health insurance,
or safe working conditions, there is a positive correlation between these benefits
and pay. As shown in Table 2, the percentage of individuals covered by employ-
ment-based health insurance rises with family income. However, simple correla-
tions are not a fair test of the hedonic model. Simple correlations always produce
an upward bias (or positive trade-off) because in the cross-sectional sample under-
lying these correlations a person’s ability is not observed. People of higher ability
will get both higher base pay and higher benefits than people of lower ability. A
college-educated worker typically has both higher pay and benefits than a high-
school educated worker, so as base pay rises, benefits rise. Since worker ability
differences cannot be measured solely by education, cross-sectional regressions
always suffer from an omitted ability bias that produces the positive pay– benefit
correlation.
As a thought exercise, consider the sort of data needed to test for a negative
trade-off between benefits and pay. Collect data on one person’s job offers after
they have gone to a broad range of firms that offer different pay packages, and see
if a negative trade-off exists in their job offers. The closest we can come to this
thought experiment is to follow individuals over time as they change jobs and see
104 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Table 2
Percentage of Individuals Covered by Employment-Based Health Insurance
(by family income)

Covered by employment-based As a percent


Family income Total health care of total

Whites
All Whites 240,909 147,367 0.61
⬍$25,000 52,424 11,996 0.23
$25,000–$49,000 59,753 32,561 0.54
$50,000–$74,999 46,360 34,111 0.74
$75,000 or more 82,372 68,699 0.83
Blacks
All Blacks 36,965 18,003 0.49
⬍$25,000 14,578 3,156 0.22
$25,000–$49,000 9,944 5,483 0.55
$50,000–$74,999 5,844 4,042 0.69
$75,000 or more 6,599 5,322 0.81

Source: U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey, 2006, Annual Social and Economic Supplement.

if there is a negative trade-off in pay packages. Studies of this type do find a small
negative trade-off (Brown, 1980). However, this approach does not fully solve the
selection problem: after all, individuals do not choose their new jobs randomly. The
average software programmer in Silicon Valley who knows his pay– benefits prefer-
ences will not move to SAS; thus, we never estimate the true trade-off. Of course,
that is the point of the model: benefits are used to cause workers to select the firm
that values them the most.
This point leads to the test of our second prediction: do firms use benefits to
encourage workers to sort to the firm that values them the most? The evidence
shows workers sorting to firms based on benefits. Oyer (forthcoming) shows that
workers match to the firms that offer the benefits each worker values. Stern (2004)
looks at the pay of scientists and finds support for both predictions of the model.
High-quality scientists often take cuts in pay in order to work on good projects, and
firms offer them the projects and pay packages they desire.
After the basic theory of the hedonic model was developed by Rosen (1974; see
also Thaler and Rosen, 1976), empirical methods essential for addressing selection
issues evolved, allowing for new tests of the model. Methods for thinking experi-
mentally using nonexperimental data improved our understanding of the hedonic
model itself as well as the tests of it (Epple, 1987).
Viewing seeming nonmonetary attributes of the job as having trade-offs that
can be monetized is a major breakthrough, because it means that any model in
personnel economics can be applied to nonmonetary rewards just as well as to
monetary incentives. For example, the tournaments model above, which dis-
cusses motivation in terms of prizes that take the form of higher salaries, can
Edward P. Lazear and Kathryn L. Shaw 105

also be interpreted to refer to prizes that take the form of status or prestige, not
money.
Hedonic analysis as done by economists is very different from approaches
taken by other human resources scholars. The hedonic notion that everything can
be monetized is anathema to the approach taken by industrial psychologists.
Instead, those fields tend not to think in terms of trade-offs, but in terms of status
or identity associated with positions (March, 1999). In these status or identity
models, an individual may demand a particular feature of a job because it is
consistent with his identity. Economists certainly introduce concepts of identity as
well, but identity is added to an equilibrium model of rational decision making (see
the next subsection on teams below).
Personnel economists explicitly think in terms of substitution and trade-offs,
and firms have begun to do so as well. For example, for many years, most firms have
had a benefits department that is distinct from the compensation department.
Firms had thought in terms of providing some market level of each job attribute,
rather than thinking in terms of a total package of utility for pay and for benefits.
As firms have moved towards an emphasis on human resources as a strategic
decision, these trade-offs are increasingly recognized. Simple evidence of this
change is that workers are now given choices: flex benefits plans allow them to
purchase different amounts of health care versus pay. The hedonic model also tells
us that employees will not be offered the full range of choices. If the firm feels it
has the right range of pension–pay packages to attract the workers it desires, it will
not give workers additional choices.
In the personnel economics model, the provision of benefits and nonmonetary
job attributes has little to do with identity or other external factors; instead, it is
motivated by rational behavior and efficiency as firms seek out the kinds of workers
they desire.

Team Production

Teamwork has increasingly become a way of life in many firms. From 1987 to
1996, for example, the share of large firms that have more than 20 percent of their
workers in problem-solving teams rose from 37 percent to 66 percent, as shown
earlier in Table 1. The percent of large firms with workers in self-managed work
teams rose from 27 percent to 78 percent. Team use seems to have hit a plateau in
the 1990s; but it’s a high plateau.
Why do so many workplaces now use teams? Teams can be time consuming to
organize and coordinate, and the apparent slow progress of teams is nearly pro-
verbial. Moreover, managers and team members always worry about the free-rider
problem—that indolent individuals will free-ride on the effort of a few team
members. So why do firms use teams? How should teams be managed? And what
types of firms are likely to gain the most from teams?
106 Journal of Economic Perspectives

One reason firms use teams is that team production can be more productive
than individuals working alone. For example, suppose that the goal is to develop a
new product. How should workers be organized to achieve this objective? In Figure
2, two different situations are depicted. Suppose that two skills, design and opera-
tions, are needed to produce a product. A point in the space reflects the amount
of knowledge that an individual has in each of the two required skills.
In Figure 2A (the left-hand panel), individual 2 is strong on operation skills,
but relatively weak on design skills. Individual 3 is strong on design, but weak on
operations. If person 2 needs to think about design, person 3 is a good person to
ask. If person 3 needs to think about operations, then person 2 is a good person to
ask. If skills are distributed as in the left-hand panel, then team communication
seems best because each person has an absolute advantage in one of the two skills.
With teams, it is as if each member has access the good operations skills of
person 2 and the good design skills of person 3, rather than only their own
individual endowment of these skills. Note also that individual 1 has no area of
greatest expertise, but may be sufficiently cheap to make hiring this person
worthwhile.
Suppose instead that the situation is that shown in Figure 2B. Now, person 4
has an absolute advantage in both design and operations. If person 2 has a question
about design, person 4 is a better resource than person 3. If person 3 has a question
about operations, person 4 is a better resource than person 2. This setting is
better-suited to a hierarchical organization, where person 4 is the supervisor to
whom all go to consult.
When does the firm choose the Team versus Hierarchy? If individuals like type
4, who possess an absolute advantage in both skills, are more expensive because
they are rare, firms will choose teams. Which firm types are likely to be willing to
pay for the one-dimensional experts shown in the left-hand panel? Maybe new
technologies would more likely be associated with firms consisting of teams of
experts, because in new technologies, rapid evolution of information makes it
difficult for any one person to have an absolute advantage in everything. As
technologies mature, very talented individuals may, over time, acquire knowledge
in a multitude of skills, making a hierarchical structure more natural. It is also true
that new technologies are associated with firms that introduce teamwork (Bartel,
Ichniowski, and Shaw, forthcoming; Bloom and Van Reenen, 2007).
The model of teamwork introduces the importance of complementarity
between the skills of different workers. When the design expert works with the
operations expert, they produce a new product design that is better than the two
individuals could have produced working independently. In other words, workers’
inputs interact multiplicatively, so that each worker’s marginal product is enhanced
by combining effort with another worker who has different skills.
The figure emphasizes several features of team interaction that may be central
to creating value in teamwork: Lazear (1999a) provides more detail. The first
feature, which is especially clear in Figure2A, is “disjointness:” that is, the gains
Personnel Economics: The Economist’s View of Human Resources 107

Figure 2
When to Use Teams

A: Team of Experts B: Hierarchy of Generalists


4
skill D3
Design skills

Design skills
3 3
skill D2 skill D2

1 2 1 2
skill D1 skill D1

skill 01 skill 02 skill 01 skill 02 skill 03


Operations skills Operations skills

from team interaction are greater when individuals have different skills or different
information. The second feature is relevance: that is, the skills of team members
should not only be nonoverlapping, but also relevant. Third, teamwork requires
communication, which can involve both common jargon and personal knowledge
of each other. Communication costs are likely reduced over time as individuals
learn to speak each others’ languages.
Fourth, firms that need to solve complex problems quickly should use teams;
firms that need to check decisions should be more hierarchical. Consider an
example. Coke has invested heavily in its brand value and the shape of its tradi-
tional bottle. Any design alteration by a product design team should be checked
very carefully, by many bosses up the hierarchy, before any new design could be
launched. The example illustrates that team-based decision making is too costly
when the bad decisions of team members can have very negative consequences for
the firm. A generalist, such as person 4, will typically cost more than individual
experts. Generalists, who can check the designs of experts, should be hired as well
when the value to the firm is high. In contrast, a new firm, with no brand value, can
risk letting the team of experts decide, because the risk of making a poor decision
is less costly to the firm.
A variety of empirical evidence shows that teamwork can be more productive,
for reasons based in the sources of productivity described above. The model of
worker complementarity within teams is supported in Hamilton, Nickerson, and
Owan (2003), which found that adoption of teams in a garment factory increased
productivity on average by 14 percent and that more heterogeneous teams were
more productive than teams of the same ability. Communication is also very
important in teams. In a study of 700 workers in steel mills, workers in the mills with
a team-based environment reported much higher levels of communication with all
peers and supervisors than in the hierarchical mills (Ichniowski and Shaw, 2003).
Given the increased communication required for teamwork, teams are more pro-
ductive when communication costs are low. The firms that use teams the most are
108 Journal of Economic Perspectives

those that have complex problems to solve. For example, in a study of steel
production, Boning, Ichniowski, and Shaw (forthcoming) show that team systems
produce the greatest gains and are more likely to be adopted in steel mills that have
complicated problems to solve because their products are complex.
The economic approach to team configuration is motivated primarily by an
emphasis on complementarity of skills. Although other disciplines have loosely
defined notions of complementary skills, the rigorous definitions of absolute and
comparative advantage in economics provide specific implications. For example, it
is not sufficient that one member has absolute advantage in a certain skill. It is
necessary to understand the equilibrium wage differentials across individuals of
different types to know whether one form of organization like hierarchy dominates
another form like team production.
The U.S. economy has seen pronounced changes in the pricing of skills
coinciding with the rise of teamwork. Since 1987, as discussed earlier, wage inequal-
ity has risen markedly, specifically the gap between the pay of workers at the 90th
percentile of the wage distribution and the median worker has grown yearly (Autor,
Katz, and Kearney, 2006). In short, the wages of highly skilled “star” workers have
grown relative to the typical employee (Andersson, Freedman, Haltiwanger, Lane
and Shaw, 2006). Are these stars experts, like persons 2 and 3 in Figure 2, or
generalists, like person 4? Perhaps both. Experts are highly valued: the inequality
of wages has risen within very narrowly defined occupations. General skills are also
valued: the underlying skill that is rising in demand (and pay) is “cognitive
nonroutine problem solving skills” across all occupations (Autor, Levy, and Mur-
nane, 2003). We do not have national data that combines information on firms’ use
of teams and the skills and wages of their employees. The data does suggest that
firms are increasingly comprised of problem-solving experts, and firms are increas-
ingly team-based.

The Complementarity of Human Resource Management Practices


and Organizational Transformation

Firms are changing their human resources practices toward more incentive pay
and more teamwork. Yet some managers report that their experiments with new
practices have failed (for examples in the steel industry, see Ichniowski, Shaw, and
Prennushi, 1997). Are there general principles that managers can follow that are
more likely to produce successful results when they implement these practices?
When a new practice is introduced, it often requires supporting practices to be
successful. For example, teams are more productive when workers are better
trained, or are given team-based incentive pay, or are selected carefully for skills
that are complementary. If the firm does not introduce all practices, the teams may
well fail to produce higher output. Human resources practices can be comple-
Edward P. Lazear and Kathryn L. Shaw 109

ments, in the sense that doing more of one of them increases the returns to doing
more of the others. Economists and noneconomists both emphasize the value of
complementary practices (for example, Baron and Kreps, 1999; Pfeffer, 1994).
Thus, when firms consider alternative human resource management practices,
such as teamwork or incentive pay, they would be wise to consider the value of the
collective set of practices rather than the value of individual practices.
Empirical evidence supports the claim that greater value can be obtained from
introducing a set of complementary practices than from introducing individual
human resources practices. Ichniowski, Shaw, and Prennushi (1997) gather data
from four systems of human resource practices that are used in 35 steel mills. The
mills that introduce a complete system of innovative practices—such as group-based
incentive pay, teamwork, careful hiring, high communications with workers,
implicit job security, extensive training, and job flexibility—are substantially more
productive than the mills that introduce a very limited set of teams.
Many other examples of the importance of complementary practices prevail
(Roberts, 2004). Southwest Airlines uses a set of labor practices that focus on
teamwork, training, and careful hiring that seem to result in a set of satisfied
customers and fast turnaround time for planes. When traditional airlines attempt
to compete with Southwest and fail, it is most likely because large airlines cannot
introduce the entire set of practices that would mimic Southwest (O’Reilly, 1995).
Because human resources practices form complementary sets, in optimizing
production, the choices firms have before them look like a mountain range—there
are local peaks in output with valleys between them. In a traditional production
function, firms increase labor to move up the peak towards the highest output, then
hit diminishing returns to labor and slide down the side of the mountain. Instead
of choosing amounts of labor, firms are choosing sets of complementary labor
practices (Roberts, 2004). One peak in output arises when the firm chooses the
complementary set of traditional labor practices: close monitoring of workers, little
problem-solving, and workers doing their jobs alone. If the firm then introduces
teams, output may fall, as this takes time away from production but does not raise
output. The firm enters a valley, and does not get to another, perhaps higher, peak
until it combines the entire set of practices that support teams. In the real world
with adjustment costs, firms can’t always make leaps from peak to peak, and may get
trapped in a valley in the short run. Therefore, when firms change their human
resource practices, they must know their ultimate goal and take the risk of a
short-term fall in output. Moreover, individual managers cannot be given the power
to make marginal changes in human resources practices.
Returning to the evidence from the steel industry, Ichniowski and Shaw (1995)
show that steel mills rarely make big leaps to highly innovative practices, despite the
evidence that the sets of innovative practices are ultimately successful. More
broadly, Baron and Hannan (2002) follow about 200 start-up companies as they
choose their human resources practices and change their practices over time.
The evidence showing that firms form sets of complementary practices is strong
110 Journal of Economic Perspectives

and furthermore confirms that firms have difficulty leaping between these sets
(Roberts, 2004).

Conclusion

For most of the last century, personnel, later called human resources manage-
ment, was the territory of industrial psychologists and those who studied organiza-
tional behavior. But in the 1970s, economists began to bring the formalism and
rigor of economic thinking to human resources. The model for personnel eco-
nomics, the field that grew out of that endeavor, was modern finance. Finance was
historically an institutional field without much theoretical or even empirical un-
derpinning until the modern developments of scholars like Merton Miller, Harry
Markowitz, William Sharpe, Eugene Fama, Fischer Black, Myron Scholes, Robert
Merton, and many others who followed in their footsteps. These scholars trans-
formed the field of finance into a branch of economics in large part by recognizing
that a few basic principles, such as arbitrage, governed financial markets. Personnel
economics has followed a similar path and is beginning to gain the prominence
that modern finance has enjoyed.
What does personnel economics add to traditional methods of studying
human resources management? Most labor economists who taught in business
schools have traditionally encountered a disinterested audience. Traditional topics
of labor supply and demand, unemployment, and investment in education, which
are of primary concern to labor economists, are almost irrelevant to their business
students. The issues studied by human resources specialists were of interest to
economists, but the approach taken by the noneconomists lacked the formal
framework to which economists have grown accustomed. The entry of economists
into the field of human resources management was assisted by breakthroughs in
agency and contract theory, which enabled economists to tackle problems that had
evaded them in the past. Entry was further assisted by advancements in economet-
rics, including ways of addressing sample selection bias, omitted variable bias, and
endogeneity, as well as by the use of panel data, which allowed economists to
formulate and test models in a way that closely approximated experiments in the
use of alternative human resource management practices.
In providing guidance to firms in the choice of their human resource man-
agement practices, several themes have emerged. Many of the models emphasize
the importance of “fit.” Firms and workers achieve fit when a worker’s skill set,
broadly understood, is matched to the firm that values it the most. Workers, or
potential employees, have very heterogeneous skills and preferences. Because
measuring the output of individual workers is often difficult, it becomes especially
important to think about the incentives workers face. Pay for performance may not
just induce the higher effort levels, but may also induce workers to select the firm
that is the best fit for their skills, effort, and tastes. Personnel economics emphasizes
Personnel Economics: The Economist’s View of Human Resources 111

the importance of human resources practices for inducing workers’ self-sorting


to firms.
Better fit or performance is achieved when complementary people are
matched to each other within the firm, or when complementary human resources
practices are matched to each other. People are complements when the skills of
one enhance those of another within their team. Human resources practices are
complements when one practice—such as teamwork—is combined with another
practice—such as group-based incentive pay—such that together they raise output
more than would either practice independently.
Alfred Marshall’s ([1890] 1961) famous statement that it is not the economist’s
business to tell the brewer how to brew beer has not been adhered to when it comes
to personnel economics. Personnel economists, at least in their interactions with
business students and practitioners, are attempting to use the tools of economics to
understand, and even sometimes to guide, practices.

References

Akerlof, George, and Kranton, Rachel. 2000. Kearney. Forthcoming. “Trends in U.S. Wage
“Economics and Identity.” Quarterly Journal of Inequality: Re-assessing the Revisionists.” Review
Economics, 115 (August): 715–53. of Economics and Statistics.
Alchian, Armen A., and Demsetz, Harold. Autor, David H., Frank Levy, and Richard
1972. “Production, Information Costs, and Eco- Murnane. 2003. “The Skill Content of Recent
nomic Organization.” American Economic Review, Technological Change: An Empirical Explora-
62(5): 777–95. tion.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4):
Andersson, Fredrik, Matthew Freedman, 1279 –1333.
John Haltiwanger, Julia Lane, and Kathryn Baily, Martin N. 1977. “On the Theory of Lay-
Shaw. 2006. “Reaching for the Stars: Who Pays offs and Unemployment.” Econometrica 45(5):
for Talent in Innovative Industries?” National 1043– 63.
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Baron, James, and Michael Hannan. 2002.
12435. “Organizational Blueprints for Success in High-
Asch, Beth J. 1990. “Do Incentives Matter? Tech Start-Ups: Lessons from the Stanford
The Case of Navy Recruiters.” Industrial and Project on Emerging Companies.” California
Labor Relations Review, February, 43(special Management Review, Spring, 44(3): 8 –36.
issue): s89 –s106. Baron, Jim, and David Kreps. 1999. Strategic
Autor, David, Lawrence Katz, and Melissa Human Resources: Frameworks for General Managers.
Kearney. 2005. “Rising Wage Inequality: The New York: John Wiley.
Role of Composition and Prices.” National Bartel, Ann, Casey Ichniowski, and Kathryn
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Shaw. Forthcoming. “How Does Information
11628. Technology affect Productivity? Plant-Level
Autor, David, Lawrence Katz, and Melissa Comparisons of Product Innovation, Process Im-
Kearney. 2006. “The Polarization of the U.S. provement and Worker Skills.” Quarterly Journal
Labor Market.” American Economic Review Papers of Economics, November.
and Proceedings, 96(2): 189 –94. Becker, Gary. 1957. The Economics of Discrimi-
Autor, David, Lawrence Katz, and Melissa nation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
112 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Bloom, Nicholas, and John Van Reenen. 2007. the Microfoundations of a High-Technology
Forthcoming. “Measuring and Explaining Man- Cluster.” Review of Economics and Statistics.
agement Practices across Firms and Countries.” Fernie, Sue, and David Metcalf. 1999. “It’s Not
Quarterly Journal of Economics, November. What You Pay It’s the Way That You Pay It and
Boning, Brent, Ichniowski, Casey, and Shaw, That’s What Gets Results: Jockeys’ Pay and Per-
Kathryn. Forthcoming. “Opportunity Counts: formance.” Labour: Review of Labour Economics
Teams and the Effectiveness of Production and Industrial Relations, June 13(2): 385– 411.
Incentives,” Journal of Labor Economics. Frank, Robert H. 1984. “Interdependent Pref-
Brown, Charles. 1980. “Equalizing Differences erences and the Competitive Wage Structure.”
in the Labor Market.” Quarterly Journal of Econom- RAND Journal of Economics, 15(Winter): 510 –20.
ics, 94(February): 113–34. Frank, Robert H. 1985. Choosing the Right Pond:
Brown, Charles. 1990. “Firms’ Choice of Human Behavior and the Quest for Status. New
Method of Pay.” Industrial and Labor Relations York: Oxford University Press.
Review, February, 43(1): 165S–182S. Frank, Robert H. 1996. The Winner-Take-All
Brown, Charles. 1992. “Wage Levels and Society. New York: Penguin Books.
Methods of Pay.” RAND Journal of Economics, Freeman, Richard, and Morris Kleiner. 2005.
23(Autumn): 366 –75. “The Last American Shoe Manufacturer: De-
Chan, William. 1996. “External Recruitment creasing Productivity and Increasing Profits in
versus Internal Promotion.” Journal of Labor the Shift from Piece Rates to Continuous Flow
Economics, October, 14(4): 555–70. Production.” Industrial Relations, April, 44(2):
Cheung, Steven N. S. 1969. The Theory of Share 307–30.
Tenancy: With Special Application to Asian Agricul-
General Electric Corporation. 2001. Annual
ture and the First Phase of Taiwan Land Reform.
Report.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Gordon, Donald F. 1974. “A Neoclassical The-
DeVaro, Jed. 2006. “Internal Promotion Com-
ory of Keynesian Unemployment.” Economic In-
petitions in Firms.” The Rand Journal of Economics,
quiry, 12(December): 431–59.
37(3), 521– 42.
Green, Jerry R., and Nancy L. Stokey. 1983. “A
Drago Robert, and Gerald T. Garvey. 1998.
Comparison of Tournaments and Contracts.”
“Incentives for Helping on the Job: Theory and
The Journal of Political Economy, 91(3), 349 – 64.
Evidence.” Journal of Labor Economics, 16(1):1–25.
Griliches, Zvi. 1977. “Estimating the Returns
Drago, R., and Heywood, J. S. 1995. “The
to Schooling: Some Econometric Problems.”
Choice of Payment Schemes: Australian Estab-
Econometrica, 45(January): 1–22.
lishment Data.” Industrial Relations, October,
34(4): 507–31. Hamilton, Barton, Jack Nickerson, and Hideo
Dye, Ronald A. 1984.”The Trouble with Tour- Owan. 2003. “Team Incentives and Worker Het-
naments.” Economic Inquiry, 22(1), 147–9. erogeneity: An Empirical Analysis of the Impact
Ehrenberg, Ronald G., and Michael L. Bog- of Teams on Productivity and Participation.”
nanno. 1990. “Do Tournaments Have Incentive Journal of Political Economy, June, 111(3): 465–97.
Effects?” Journal of Political Economy, 98(6): 1307– Hausman, Jerry A., and William E. Taylor.
24. 1981. “Panel Data and Unobservable Individual
Epple, Dennis. 1987. “Hedonic Prices and Im- Effects.” Econometrica, 49(November): 1377–98.
plicit Markets: Estimating Demand and Supply Heckman, James. 1979. “Sample Selection
Functions for Differentiated Products.” Journal of Bias as a Specification Error.” Econometrica,
Political Economy, 95(February): 59 – 80. 47(January): 153– 61.
Eriksson, Tor. 1999. “Executive Compensa- Ichniowski, Casey, and Kathryn Shaw. 1995.
tion and Tournament Theory: Empirical Tests “Old Dogs and New Tricks: Determinants of the
on Danish Data.” Journal of Labor Economics, Adoption of Productivity-Enhancing Work Prac-
April, 17(2): 262– 80. tices.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Micro-
Falk, Armin, and Ernst Fehr. 2006. “The economics, 1995, pp. 1– 65.
Power and Limits of Tournament Incentives: Ichniowski, Casey, and Kathryn Shaw. 2003.
The Impact of Sabotage, Social Norms and Loss “Connective Capital: Building Problem-solving
Aversion.” Unpublished paper. Networks within Firms.” Unpublished paper.
Fallick, Bruce, Charles A. Fleischman, and Ichniowski, Casey, Kathryn Shaw, and Gio-
James B. Rebitzer. Forthcoming. “Job Hopping vanna Prennushi. 1997. “The Effects of Human
in Silicon Valley: Some Evidence Concerning Resource Management Practices on Productiv-
Edward P. Lazear and Kathryn L. Shaw 113

ity: A Study of Steel Finishing Lines.” American Main, Brian G. M., Charles A. O’Reilly III, and
Economic Review, 86(3): 291–313. James Wade. 1993. “Top Executive Pay: Tourna-
Johnson, D. Gale. 1950. “Resource Allocation ment or Teamwork?” Journal of Labor Economics,
under Share Contracts.” Journal of Political Econ- October, 11(4): 606 –28.
omy, 58(2): 111–23. March, James. 1999. The Pursuit of Organiza-
Kandel, Eugene, and Edward Lazear. “Peer tional Intelligence. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publish-
Pressure and Partnerships.” 1992. Journal of ers Inc.
Political Economy, 100(August): 801– 817. Marshall, Alfred P. [1890] 1961. Principles of
Knoeber, Charles R., and Walter N. Thurman. Economics. New York: Macmillan.
1994. “Testing the Theory of Tournaments: An Milgrom, Paul R. 1988. “Employment Con-
Empirical Analysis of Broiler Production.” Jour- tracts, Influence Activities, and Efficient Organi-
nal of Labor Economics, April, 12(2): 155–79. zation Design.” Journal of Political Economy,
Lawler, Edward E., III, Susan Albers Mohr- 96(February): 42– 60.
man, and George Benson. 2001. Organizing for Milgrom, Paul, and John Roberts. 1990. “The
High Performance: Employee Involvement, TQM, Economics of Modern Manufacturing: Technol-
Reengineering, and Knowledge Management in the ogy, Strategy, and Organizations.” American
Fortune 1000. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Economic Review, June, 80(3): 511–28.
Lawler, Edward E., III, Susan Albers Mohr- Nalebuff, Barry J., and Joseph E. Stiglitz.
man, and Gerald E. Ledford Jr. 1995. Creating 1983. “Prizes and Incentives: Towards a General
High Performance Organizations: Practices and Re- Theory of Compensation and Competition.” The
sults of Employee Involvement and TQM in Fortune Bell Journal of Economics, 14(1), 21– 43.
1000 Companies. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. O’Reilly III, Charles A. 1995. “Southwest Air-
Lazear, Edward P. 1979. “Why Is There Man- lines: Using Human Resources for Competitive
datory Retirement?” Journal of Political Economy, Advantage (A).” Stanford Case No. HR-1A. Stan-
87(6), 1261– 84. ford, CA: Stanford Graduate School of Business.
Lazear, Edward P. 1986. “Salaries and Piece Oyer, Paul. 1998. “Fiscal Year Ends and Non-
Rates.” Journal of Business, 59(July): 405–31. Linear Incentive Contracts: The Effect on Busi-
Lazear, Edward P. 1989. “Pay Equality and ness Seasonality.” The Quarterly Journal of Econom-
Industrial Politics.” Journal of Political Economy, ics, 113(February): 149 – 85.
97(June): 561– 80. Oyer, Paul. Forthcoming. “Salary or Benefits?”
Lazear, Edward P. 1999a. “Globalization and Research in Labor Economics.
the Market for Teammates.” The Economic Jour- Parent, Daniel. 1999. “Methods of Pay and
nal, 109(March): C15–C40. Earnings: A Longitudinal Analysis.” Industrial
Lazear, Edward P. 1999b. “Personnel Eco- and Labor Relations Review, October, 53(1): 71–
nomics: Past Lessons and Future Directions.” 86.
Presidential Address to the Society of Labor Pfeffer, Jeffrey. 1994. Competitive Advantage
Economists, San Francisco, May 1, 1998. Journal through People. Harvard Business School Press.
of Labor Economics, April, 17(2): 199 –236. Prendergast, Canice. 1993. “The Role of Pro-
Lazear, Edward P. 2000. “Performance Pay motion in Inducing Specific Human Capital Ac-
and Productivity.” American Economic Review, quisition.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
December, 90(5): 1346 – 61. 108(2): 523–534.
Lazear, Edward P., and Sherwin Rosen. 1981. Prendergast, Canice, and Robert H. Topel.
“Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor 1996. “Favoritism in Organizations.” Journal of
Contracts.” Journal of Political Economy, October, Political Economy, October, 104(5): 958 –78.
89(5): 841– 64. Roberts, John. 2004. The Modern Firm: Organi-
Lazear, Edward, and Kathryn Shaw. Forth- zational Design for Performance and Growth. Oxford
coming. “Wage Structure, Wages, and Mobility.” University Press.
In An International Comparison of the Structure of Rosen, Sherwin. 1974. “Hedonic Prices and
Wages, ed. Edward Lazear and Kathryn Shaw. Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in
University of Chicago. Pure Competition.” Journal of Political Economy,
Lo, Desmond, Mrinal Ghosh, and Francine 82(January/February): 34 –55.
Lafontaine. 2006. “The Role of Risk, Incentives, Rosen, Sherwin. 1986. “Prizes and Incentives
and Selection in Salesforce Compensation Con- in Elimination Tournaments.” American Economic
tracts.” Unpublished paper, Ross School of Busi- Review, September, 76(4): 701–715.
ness, University of Michigan, May. Ross, Stephen A. 1973. “The Economic The-
114 Journal of Economic Perspectives

ory of Agency: The Principal’s Problem.” Ameri- chy.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management
can Economic Review, 63(2): 134 –39. Science, 6(August): 552–79.
Shearer, Bruce. 2004. “Piece Rates, Fixed Time. 2000. “GE’s Talent Agency.” December 3.
Wages and Incentives: Evidence from a Field Thaler, Richard, and Sherwin Rosen. 1976.
Experiment.” Review of Economic Studies, “The Value of Saving a Life: Evidence from the
71(April): 513–34. Labor Market.” In Household Production and Con-
Stern, Scott. 2004. “Do Scientists Pay to be sumption, ed. Nestor E. Terlecky. Studies in In-
Scientists?” Management Science, 50(June): 835– come and Wealth 40. New York: Columbia Uni-
53. versity Press (for NBER), pp. 412– 42.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1975. “Incentives, Risk, and USA Today. 2007. “Home Depot’s New CEO is
Information: Notes toward a Theory of Hierar- Also a GE Alum.” January 13.
This article has been cited by:

1. Achyuta Adhvaryu, Jean-François Gauthier, Anant Nyshadham, Jorge Tamayo. 2024. Absenteeism,
Productivity, and Relational Contracts Inside the Firm. Journal of the European Economic Association
67. . [Crossref]
2. Víctor González-Jiménez. 2024. Incentive design for reference-dependent preferences. Journal of
Economic Behavior & Organization 221, 493-518. [Crossref]
3. Mads Nordmo Arnestad, Mats Glambek, Marcus Selart. 2024. With a little profitable help from
my friends: the relational incongruence of benefiting financially from prosocially motivated favors.
Frontiers in Behavioral Economics 3. . [Crossref]
4. Tommaso Reggiani, Rainer Michael Rilke. 2024. Designing Donation Incentive Contracts for Online
Gig Workers. Journal of Business Ethics 190:3, 553-568. [Crossref]
5. Felix Kölle, Thomas Lauer. 2024. Understanding Cooperation in an Intertemporal Context.
Management Science 62. . [Crossref]
6. E. Glenn Dutcher, Regine Oexl, Dmitry Ryvkin, Timothy C. Salmon. 2024. Do competitive
bonuses ruin cooperation in heterogeneous teams?. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 62. .
[Crossref]
7. Emile Cammeraat, Lea Samek, Mariagrazia Squicciarini. 2024. Organizational Capital, Skills and
Productivity. Review of Income and Wealth 62. . [Crossref]
8. Christopher L. Brown. 2024. Team production in endogenous networks. Journal of Economic Behavior
& Organization 217, 560-580. [Crossref]
9. José Alberto Bayo Moriones, Jose E. Galdon-Sanchez, Sara Martinez-de-Morentin. 2024.
Complements or Substitutes? Examining the Relationship between Teamwork and Selection
Intensity. SSRN Electronic Journal 53. . [Crossref]
10. Yun taek Oh, Morris M. Kleiner. 2024. The Influence of Occupational Licensing on Workforce
Transitions to Retirement. SSRN Electronic Journal 74. . [Crossref]
11. Yun taek Oh, Morris M. Kleiner. 2024. The Influence of Occupational Licensing on Workforce
Transitions to Retirement. SSRN Electronic Journal 74. . [Crossref]
12. Aurelie Dariel, Nikos Nikiforakis, Simon Siegenthaler. 2024. Leadership, Inequality, and
Coordination: an Experimental Investigation. SSRN Electronic Journal 115. . [Crossref]
13. Gerd Muehlheusser, Timo Promann, Andreas Roider, Niklas Wallmeier. 2024. Honesty of Groups:
Effects of Size and Gender Composition. SSRN Electronic Journal 87. . [Crossref]
14. Sotiris Blanas. 2023. The distinct effects of information technologies and communication technologies
on skill demand. Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 128. . [Crossref]
15. Andrzej Baranski, Diogo Geraldes, Ada Kovaliukaite, James Tremewan. 2023. An Experiment on
Gender Representation in Majoritarian Bargaining. Management Science 2. . [Crossref]
16. Zhangfan Cao, William Rees, Zhifang Zhang. 2023. The effect of real earnings smoothing on
corporate labour investment. The British Accounting Review 55:6, 101178. [Crossref]
17. Julian V Johnsen, Hyejin Ku, Kjell G Salvanes. 2023. Competition and Career Advancement. Review
of Economic Studies 125. . [Crossref]
18. Diane Pelly. 2023. Worker Well-Being and Quit Intentions: Is Measuring Job Satisfaction Enough?.
Social Indicators Research 169:1-2, 397-441. [Crossref]
19. A. Baltrunaite, S. Formai, A. Linarello, S. Mocetti. 2023. Ownership, Governance, Management and
Firm Performance: Evidence from Italian Firms. Italian Economic Journal 2. . [Crossref]
20. Ahrum Choi, Woo‐Jong Lee, Yong Gyu Lee, Gaoguang Zhou. 2023. Internal Information Quality
and Corporate Employment Decisions. Australian Accounting Review 53. . [Crossref]
21. Christophe Loussouarn, Carine Franc, Yann Videau, Julien Mousquès. 2023. L’effet combiné de
l’exercice en maison de santé pluriprofessionnelle et des paiements à la coordination sur l’activité des
médecins généralistes. Revue économique Vol. 74:3, 441-470. [Crossref]
22. Nicole Maestas, Kathleen J. Mullen, David Powell, Till von Wachter, Jeffrey B. Wenger. 2023. The
Value of Working Conditions in the United States and Implications for the Structure of Wages.
American Economic Review 113:7, 2007-2047. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
23. Tobias Hiller. 2023. Training, Abilities and the Structure of Teams. Games 14:3, 44. [Crossref]
24. Darrell J. Glaser, Ahmed S. Rahman. 2023. Between the Dockyard and the Deep Blue Sea —
Retention and Personnel Economics in the Royal Navy. Labour Economics 113, 102407. [Crossref]
25. JUNG HO CHOI, BRANDON GIPPER, SARA MALIK. 2023. Financial Reporting Quality and
Wage Differentials: Evidence from Worker‐Level Data. Journal of Accounting Research 66. . [Crossref]
26. Susanna Gallani. 2023. Conduit Incentives: Eliciting Cooperation from Workers Outside of Managers’
Control. The Accounting Review 98:3, 175-202. [Crossref]
27. Lea Heursen. 2023. Does relative performance information lower group morale?. Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization 209, 547-559. [Crossref]
28. Justin Buffat, Matthias Praxmarer, Matthias Sutter. 2023. The intrinsic value of decision rights: A
replication and an extension to team decision making. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
209, 560-571. [Crossref]
29. Audinga Baltrunaite, Giulia Bovini, Sauro Mocetti. 2023. Managerial talent and managerial practices:
Are they complements?. Journal of Corporate Finance 79, 102348. [Crossref]
30. Bong-Geun Choi, Jung Ho Choi, Sara Malik. 2023. Not just for investors: The role of earnings
announcements in guiding job seekers. Journal of Accounting and Economics 65, 101588. [Crossref]
31. André Haas, Hagen Wäsche, Rita Wittelsberger, Petra Nieken, Alexander Woll. 2023. Social skills
and sports: Pupils of an elite school of sports are more competitive and cooperative. German Journal
of Exercise and Sport Research 53:1, 118-122. [Crossref]
32. Alice J. Chen, Elizabeth L. Munnich, Stephen T. Parente, Michael R. Richards. 2023. Provider turf
wars and Medicare payment rules. Journal of Public Economics 218, 104812. [Crossref]
33. Fatin Nadirah Khasni, J.S. Keshminder, Soo Cheng Chuah, T. Ramayah. 2023. A theory of planned
behaviour: perspective on rehiring ex-offenders. Management Decision 61:1, 313-338. [Crossref]
34. Lin Xu, Jingxiao Zhang, Yiying Ding, Junwei Zheng, Gangzhu Sun, Wei Zhang, Simon P. Philbin.
2023. Understanding the role of peer pressure on engineering students' learning behavior: A TPB
perspective. Frontiers in Public Health 10. . [Crossref]
35. Leena Rudanko. 2023. Firm Wages in a Frictional Labor Market. American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics 15:1, 517-550. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
36. Allison Demeritt, Karla Hoff. Lab-in-the-Field Experiments 235-259. [Crossref]
37. David Hardt, Lea Mayer, Johannes Rincke. 2023. Who Does the Talking Here? The Impact of Gender
Composition on Team Interactions. SSRN Electronic Journal 23. . [Crossref]
38. Christopher Karpowitz, Stephen D. O'Connell, Jessica Preece, Olga Stoddard. 2023. Strength in
Numbers? Gender Composition, Leadership, and Women's Influence in Teams. SSRN Electronic
Journal 8. . [Crossref]
39. John A. List, Rohen Shah. 2022. The impact of team incentives on performance in graduate school:
Evidence from two pilot RCTs. Economics Letters 221, 110894. [Crossref]
40. Lukas Kiessling, Jonas Radbruch, Sebastian Schaube. 2022. Self-Selection of Peers and Performance.
Management Science 68:11, 8184-8201. [Crossref]
41. Bo Sun, Ao Ruan, Biyu Peng, Shanshi Liu. 2022. Pay disparities within top management teams,
marketization and firms’ innovation: evidence from China. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 27:4,
715-735. [Crossref]
42. Ashwin Kambhampati, Carlos Segura‐Rodriguez. 2022. The optimal assortativity of teams inside the
firm. The RAND Journal of Economics 53:3, 484-515. [Crossref]
43. Boris Hirsch, Philipp Lentge. 2022. Non‐base compensation and the gender pay gap. LABOUR 36:3,
277-301. [Crossref]
44. Laurie Rachet-Jacquet. 2022. Do breaks from surgery improve the performance of orthopaedic
surgeons?. Journal of Health Economics 85, 102667. [Crossref]
45. Dorgyles C. M. Kouakou. 2022. Innovation, ancienneté du manager et implication des employés dans
la prise de décision au sein des entreprises d’un pays en développement. Revue économique Vol. 73:5,
781-810. [Crossref]
46. Ol'ga V. ASTAF'EVA, Denis S. KUZNETSOV, Nikita A. LYSENKO, Stanislav A. ROMANOV.
2022. A comparative analysis of human capital development in Russian and foreign companies.
Regional Economics: Theory and Practice 20:8, 1549-1566. [Crossref]
47. Anne-Sophie Larsson, Martin R. Edwards. 2022. Insider econometrics meets people analytics and
strategic human resource management. The International Journal of Human Resource Management
33:12, 2373-2419. [Crossref]
48. Karen Meng Li, Sang-Hyun Kim. 2022. Performance Feedback with Team Incentive: A Field
Experiment in Chinese Factories. Global Economic Review 51:3, 216-231. [Crossref]
49. Miriam Krueger, Guido Friebel. 2022. A Pay Change and Its Long-Term Consequences. Journal of
Labor Economics 40:3, 543-572. [Crossref]
50. Achyuta Adhvaryu, Teresa Molina, Anant Nyshadham. 2022. Expectations, Wage Hikes and Worker
Voice. The Economic Journal 132:645, 1978-1993. [Crossref]
51. Nicola Bianchi, Michela Giorcelli. 2022. The Dynamics and Spillovers of Management Interventions:
Evidence from the Training within Industry Program. Journal of Political Economy 130:6, 1630-1675.
[Crossref]
52. Phong T. H. Ngo, Jared Stanfield. 2022. Does Government Spending Crowd Out R&D Investment?
Evidence from Government-Dependent Firms and Their Peers. Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 57:3, 888-922. [Crossref]
53. Xiqian Cai, Wei Jiang, Hong Song, Huihua Xie. 2022. Pay for performance schemes and manufacturing
worker productivity: Evidence from a kinked design in China. Journal of Development Economics 156,
102840. [Crossref]
54. Mark A Chen, Hai Tran, Qinxi Wu, Evgenia Zhivotova. 2022. Are Directors Rewarded for Excellence?
Evidence from Reputation Shocks and Career Outcomes. The Review of Corporate Finance Studies
11:2, 263-313. [Crossref]
55. Sushmita Choudhury Sen. 2022. TRANSFORMING HR PRACTICES WITH BEHAVIORAL
ECONOMICS. PARIPEX INDIAN JOURNAL OF RESEARCH 108-111. [Crossref]
56. Zhongbin Wang, Luyi Yang, Shiliang Cui, Sezer Ülkü, Yong-Pin Zhou. 2022. Pooling Agents for
Customer-Intensive Services. Operations Research . [Crossref]
57. U.Jawahar Supraveen, Sayyad Saadiq Ali, K.Sharath Babu, V. Ramchander Rao, Ganga Naga Saroj
Bandi. HR Analytics - The Measurement of HR Processes using a Methodical Approach 1-4.
[Crossref]
58. Paul Turner. Complementarity and Competence-knowledge, Skills, Attitudes, and Behaviours
203-231. [Crossref]
59. Gabriel Burdin, Takao Kato. Complementarity in Employee Participation Systems 1-29. [Crossref]
60. Anna Ressi, Daniel Schaupp, Victor van Pelt. 2022. What Do You Recommend? The Effects of
Communication and Dark Personality on Misreporting in Autonomous Teams. SSRN Electronic
Journal 64. . [Crossref]
61. Zhe Li, Bo Wang. 2022. Non-CEO executives’ intra-organizational competition incentives and
corporate labor investment efficiency. SSRN Electronic Journal 66. . [Crossref]
62. Allison Demeritt, Karla Hoff. Lab-in-the-Field Experiments 1-25. [Crossref]
63. John A. List, Rohen Shah. 2022. The Impact of Team Incentives on Performance in Graduate School:
Evidence from Two Pilot Rcts. SSRN Electronic Journal 107. . [Crossref]
64. John A. List, Rohen Shah. 2022. The Impact of Team Incentives on Performance in Graduate School:
Evidence from Two Pilot Rcts. SSRN Electronic Journal 107. . [Crossref]
65. Anne M. Lillis, Mary A. Malina, Julia Mundy. 2022. The Role of Subjectivity in Mitigating Incentive
Contracting Risks. The Accounting Review 97:1, 365-388. [Crossref]
66. Francis Ezieshi Monyei, Wilfred I. Ukpere, Emmanuel Kalu Agbaeze, Solomon Omonona, Lovlyn
Ekeowa Kelvin-Iloafu, Happiness Ozioma Obi-Anike. 2021. The Impact of Succession Management
on Small and Medium Enterprises’ Sustainability in Lagos State, Nigeria. Sustainability 13:23, 13489.
[Crossref]
67. HYEJIN KO, ANDREW WEAVER. 2021. Employer Responses to Legislation Protecting Non-
Regular Workers: Evidence from South Korea. Journal of Social Policy 22, 1-25. [Crossref]
68. Bernard Sinclair-Desgagné. 2021. Green human resource management – A personnel economics
perspective. Resource and Energy Economics 66, 101261. [Crossref]
69. David J. Cooper, Krista Saral, Marie Claire Villeval. 2021. Why Join a Team?. Management Science
67:11, 6980-6997. [Crossref]
70. Felix Bolduan, Ivo Schedlinsky, Friedrich Sommer. 2021. The influence of compensation
interdependence on risk-taking: the role of mutual monitoring. Journal of Business Economics 91:8,
1125-1148. [Crossref]
71. Jordi McKenzie, Paul Crosby, Liam J. A. Lenten. 2021. It takes two, baby! Feature artist collaborations
and streaming demand for music. Journal of Cultural Economics 45:3, 385-408. [Crossref]
72. Tyler F. Thomas, Todd A. Thornock. 2021. How Incomplete Information of Team Member
Contributions Affects Subsequent Contributions: The Moderating Role of Social Value Orientation.
Journal of Management Accounting Research 33:3, 145-161. [Crossref]
73. Philip Brookins, Paan Jindapon. 2021. Risk preference heterogeneity in group contests. Journal of
Mathematical Economics 95, 102499. [Crossref]
74. Ting Chen, Ji Yeon Hong. 2021. Rivals within: political factions, loyalty, and elite competition under
authoritarianism. Political Science Research and Methods 9:3, 599-614. [Crossref]
75. Ji‐Hung Choi, Hannah Oh, John Bae, Sang‐Joon Kim. 2021. Affirmative action and team
performance: An agency theoretic perspective. Managerial and Decision Economics 42:5, 1183-1193.
[Crossref]
76. Shahid Karim, Kong Xiang, Abdul Hameed. 2021. Investigating social development inequality among
steel industry workers in Pakistan: A contribution to social development policies. PLOS ONE 16:6,
e0253082. [Crossref]
77. Jonathan Cribb, Carl Emmerson. 2021. What Can We Learn About Automatic Enrollment Into
Pensions From Small Employers?. National Tax Journal 74:2, 377-404. [Crossref]
78. Sarthak Gaurav. 2021. Dynamic Inconsistency and Incentive Design: Insights from Behavioural
Economics for HR Managers. NHRD Network Journal 14:2, 193-205. [Crossref]
79. Matthew G. Springer, Lori L. Taylor. 2021. Compensation and Composition: Does Strategic
Compensation Affect Workforce Composition?. Journal of Education Human Resources 39:2, 101-164.
[Crossref]
80. Prithwiraj (Raj) Choudhury, Cirrus Foroughi, Barbara Larson. 2021. Work‐from‐anywhere : The
productivity effects of geographic flexibility. Strategic Management Journal 42:4, 655-683. [Crossref]
81. Hee-Yeon Sunwoo, Justin Law, Woo-Jong Lee, Seungbin Oh. 2021. The Importance of
Organizational Context for the Relation Between Human Capital Investment and Firm Performance:
Evidence From Labor Unions. Journal of Management Accounting Research 33:1, 197-217. [Crossref]
82. Christophe Loussouarn, Carine Franc, Yann Videau, Julien Mousquès. 2021. Can General Practitioners
Be More Productive? The Impact of Teamwork and Cooperation with Nurses on GP Activities. Health
Economics 30:3, 680-698. [Crossref]
83. Brice Corgnet, Brian Gunia, Roberto Hernán González. 2021. Harnessing the power of social
incentives to curb shirking in teams. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 30:1, 139-167.
[Crossref]
84. Anh Thuy Tu, Truong Xuan Pham. Vietnam’s National Human Resource Development Strategy in
Response to Industry 4.0: An Analysis from a Labor Market Perspective 69-96. [Crossref]
85. Heather Sarsons, Klarita Gërxhani, Ernesto Reuben, Arthur Schram. 2021. Gender Differences in
Recognition for Group Work. Journal of Political Economy 129:1, 101-147. [Crossref]
86. Ben Weidmann, David J. Deming. 2021. Team Players: How Social Skills Improve Team Performance.
Econometrica 89:6, 2637-2657. [Crossref]
87. Marcel ILIE, Augustin Semenescu. 2021. PERFORMANCE ENHANCEMENT OF MULTI-
DISCIPLINARY R&D TEAM THROUGH PROJECT MANAGEMENT. ANNALS OF THE
ACADEMY OF ROMANIAN SCIENTISTS Series on ENGINEERING SCIENCES 13:1, 59-66.
[Crossref]
88. Seth Carnahan, Jose Uribe, John Meluso, Jesse Austin-Breneman. 2021. Do Employee Absences Help
Managers Evaluate Individual Contributions to Team Production? Evidence from Plant Productivity
Data. SSRN Electronic Journal 109. . [Crossref]
89. Sule Alan, Gozde Corekcioglu, Matthias Sutter. 2021. Improving Workplace Climate in Large
Corporations: A Clustered Randomized Intervention. SSRN Electronic Journal 105. . [Crossref]
90. Sule Alan, Gozde Corekcioglu, Matthias Sutter. 2021. Improving Workplace Climate in Large
Corporations: A Clustered Randomized Intervention. SSRN Electronic Journal 105. . [Crossref]
91. Shan Aman-Rana, Clement Minaudier, Brais Alvarez Pereira, Shamyla Chaudry. 2021. Gender and
Choice over Co-workers: Experimental Evidence. SSRN Electronic Journal 66. . [Crossref]
92. Patrick J. Ferguson. 2021. Do managers distinguish between effects of luck and effort on employees'
performance outcomes? Evidence from a high-stakes field setting. SSRN Electronic Journal 100. .
[Crossref]
93. Ina Ganguli, Ricardo Hausmann, Martina Viarengo. 2021. Gender Differences in Professional Career
Dynamics: New Evidence from a Global Law Firm. Economica 88:349, 105-128. [Crossref]
94. Harvey Upton. 2021. Implicit incentives and delegation in teams. SSRN Electronic Journal 29. .
[Crossref]
95. Diogo Geraldes, Andrzej Baranski, Ada Kovaliukaite, James Tremewan. 2021. An Experiment on
Gender Representation in Majoritarian Bargaining. SSRN Electronic Journal 21. . [Crossref]
96. Zhangfan Cao, William Rees. 2020. Do employee-friendly firms invest more efficiently? Evidence
from labor investment efficiency. Journal of Corporate Finance 65, 101744. [Crossref]
97. Gabriele Chierchia, Fabio Tufano, Giorgio Coricelli. 2020. The differential impact of friendship on
cooperative and competitive coordination. Theory and Decision 89:4, 423-452. [Crossref]
98. Lorenzo Caliendo, Giordano Mion, Luca David Opromolla, Esteban Rossi-Hansberg. 2020.
Productivity and Organization in Portuguese Firms. Journal of Political Economy 128:11, 4211-4257.
[Crossref]
99. Yi-Yi Chen. 2020. Intergroup competition with an endogenously determined prize level. Journal of
Economic Behavior & Organization 178, 759-776. [Crossref]
100. Jordan Roulleau-Pasdeloup. 2020. A Puncher’s chance: Expected gain and risk taking in a market for
superstars. Labour Economics 66, 101890. [Crossref]
101. William Gilje Gjedrem, Ola Kvaløy. 2020. Relative performance feedback to teams. Labour Economics
66, 101865. [Crossref]
102. Jana Gallus, Sudeep Bhatia. 2020. Gender, power and emotions in the collaborative production of
knowledge: A large-scale analysis of Wikipedia editor conversations. Organizational Behavior and
Human Decision Processes 160, 115-130. [Crossref]
103. Alberto Bayo-Moriones, Jose E. Galdon-Sanchez, Sara Martinez-de-Morentin. 2020. Performance
appraisal: dimensions and determinants. The International Journal of Human Resource Management
31:15, 1984-2015. [Crossref]
104. Chun-Lin Kao, Ming-Yuan Chen. 2020. Employee downsizing, financial constraints, and production
efficiency of firms. International Review of Economics & Finance 68, 59-73. [Crossref]
105. Benjamin Dubrion. 2020. Partir de John R. Commons pour repenser l’analyse économique des
pratiques de GRH : fondements et implications pour l’économie. Économie et Institutions :28. .
[Crossref]
106. Raymond Fisman, Jing Shi, Yongxiang Wang, Weixing Wu. 2020. Social Ties and the Selection of
China’s Political Elite. American Economic Review 110:6, 1752-1781. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
107. Stefania Cardinaleschi, Mirella Damiani, Fabrizio Pompei. 2020. Knowledge-intensive sectors and the
role of collective performance-related pay. Industry and Innovation 27:5, 480-512. [Crossref]
108. Frauke von Bieberstein, Jonas Gehrlein, Anna Güntner. 2020. Teamwork revisited: social preferences
and knowledge acquisition in the field. Journal of Business Economics 90:4, 591-614. [Crossref]
109. Daniel Herbold, Heiner Schumacher. 2020. The agency costs of on-the-job search. Games and
Economic Behavior 121, 435-452. [Crossref]
110. Nana Adrian, Marc Möller. 2020. Self‐managed work teams: An efficiency‐rationale for pay
compression. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 29:2, 315-334. [Crossref]
111. Chenyang Xu, Klaas van’t Veld. 2020. Team Inspection in the Management of Common-Pool
Resources When Corruption is Present. Environmental and Resource Economics 75:3, 553-584.
[Crossref]
112. Niklas Lollo, Dara O’Rourke. 2020. Factory benefits to paying workers more: The critical role of
compensation systems in apparel manufacturing. PLOS ONE 15:2, e0227510. [Crossref]
113. Dorota Węziak-Białowolska, Piotr Białowolski, Eileen McNeely. 2020. The impact of workplace
harassment and domestic violence on work outcomes in the developing world. World Development
126, 104732. [Crossref]
114. Martin G. Kocher, Matthias Praxmarer, Matthias Sutter. Team Decision-Making 1-25. [Crossref]
115. Ashwin Kambhampati, Carlos Segura-Rodriguez. 2020. The Optimal Assortativity of Teams Inside
the Firm. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
116. Rahul Gupta. 2020. Does Goliath Help David? Anchor Firms and Startup Clusters. SSRN Electronic
Journal 81. . [Crossref]
117. Doruk Cetemen, Ilwoo Hwang, Ayça Kaya. 2020. Uncertainty‐driven cooperation. Theoretical
Economics 15:3, 1023-1058. [Crossref]
118. Scott M. Gilpatric, Ye Hong. 2020. Optimal Contest Design when Policing Damaging Aggressive
Behavior. SSRN Electronic Journal 2. . [Crossref]
119. Raffi E. García. 2020. Plant Behavior & Equal Pay: The Effect on Female Employment, Capital
Investments, & Productivity — A Difference-in-Discontinuities Design. SSRN Electronic Journal
94. . [Crossref]
120. Zhongbin Wang, Luyi Yang, Shiliang Cui, Sezer Ulku, Yong-Pin Zhou. 2020. Pooling Agents for
Customer-Intensive Services. SSRN Electronic Journal 59. . [Crossref]
121. Bong-Geun Choi, Jung Ho Choi, Sara Malik. 2020. Job Search with Financial Information: Theory
and Evidence. SSRN Electronic Journal 65. . [Crossref]
122. Janet Gao, Wenyu Wang, Yufeng Wu. 2020. Human Capital Portability and Worker Career Choices:
Evidence from M&A Bankers. SSRN Electronic Journal 107. . [Crossref]
123. Matthias Fahn, Hendrik Hakenes. 2019. Teamwork as a Self-Disciplining Device. American Economic
Journal: Microeconomics 11:4, 1-32. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
124. Mürüvvet Büyükboyaci, Andrea Robbett. 2019. Team formation with complementary skills. Journal
of Economics & Management Strategy 28:4, 713-733. [Crossref]
125. James Liang, Xiaoquan Wang, Hong Zhang. 2019. Promotions in the internal labor market: New
evidence from China. China Economic Review 57, 101332. [Crossref]
126. Nikos Nikiforakis, Jörg Oechssler, Anwar Shah. 2019. Managerial bonuses and subordinate
mistreatment. European Economic Review 119, 509-525. [Crossref]
127. Christophe Loussouarn, Carine Franc, Yann Videau, Julien Mousquès. 2019. Impact de
l’expérimentation de coopération entre médecin généraliste et infirmière Asalée sur l’activité des
médecins. Revue d'économie politique Vol. 129:4, 489-524. [Crossref]
128. Neil Aldrin, Andyan Pradipta Utama. 2019. Analysis of the Effect of Coaching on Teamwork
Performance. International Journal of Research in Business and Social Science (2147- 4478) 8:3, 24-32.
[Crossref]
129. Thomas J. Chemmanur, Mine Ertugrul, Karthik Krishnan. 2019. Is It the Investment Bank or the
Investment Banker? A Study of the Role of Investment Banker Human Capital in Acquisitions. Journal
of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 54:2, 587-627. [Crossref]
130. Hee-Je Bak, Do Han Kim. 2019. The unintended consequences of performance-based incentives on
inequality in scientists’ research performance. Science and Public Policy 46:2, 219-231. [Crossref]
131. Ning Gong, Bruce D Grundy. 2019. Can Socially Responsible Firms Survive Competition? An
Analysis of Corporate Employee Matching Grant Schemes*. Review of Finance 23:1, 199-243.
[Crossref]
132. Chenyang Xu, Klaas van't Veld. 2019. Team Inspection in the Management of Common-Pool
Resources when Corruption is Present. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
133. Nicola Bianchi, Michela Giorcelli. 2019. Not All Management Training Is Created Equal: Evidence
from the Training Within Industry Program. SSRN Electronic Journal 113. . [Crossref]
134. Prithwiraj Choudhury, Cirrus Foroughi, Barbara Larson. 2019. Work-from-anywhere: The
Productivity Effects of Geographic Flexibility. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
135. Bernard Sinclair-Desgagne. 2019. Climate Change and Human Resource Management. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
136. Achyuta Adhvaryu, Vittorio Bassi, Anant Nyshadham, Jorge A. Tamayo. 2019. No Line Left Behind:
Assortative Matching Inside the Firm. SSRN Electronic Journal 67. . [Crossref]
137. Pablo Munoz, Mounu Prem. 2019. Productivity and Sectoral Allocation: The Labor Market of School
Principals. SSRN Electronic Journal 25. . [Crossref]
138. Jung Ho Choi, Brandon Gipper, Sara Malik. 2019. Financial Reporting Quality, Turnover Risk, and
Wage Differentials: Evidence from Worker-level Data. SSRN Electronic Journal 67. . [Crossref]
139. Stephan Kampelmann, François Rycx, Yves Saks, Ilan Tojerow. 2018. Does education raise
productivity and wages equally? The moderating role of age and gender. IZA Journal of Labor
Economics 7:1. . [Crossref]
140. Ola Kvaløy, Klaus Mohn. 2018. Produktivitet og insentiver i offentlig sektor. Beta 32:2, 148-164.
[Crossref]
141. Thang Dang, Thai Tri Dung, Vu Thi Phuong, Tran Dinh Vinh. 2018. Human resource management
practices and firm outcomes: evidence from Vietnam. Journal of Asian Business and Economic Studies
25:2, 221-238. [Crossref]
142. Kelly E. Carter. 2018. The Effect of Labor-Management Complementarities on Production and
Efficiency When Management Is Paid but Labor Is Not Paid. Eastern Economic Journal 44:4, 535-557.
[Crossref]
143. Philip Brookins, John P. Lightle, Dmitry Ryvkin. 2018. Sorting and communication in weak-link
group contests. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 152, 64-80. [Crossref]
144. Olivier Brolis, Marie Courtois, Ginette Herman, Marthe Nyssens. 2018. Do Social Enterprises
Discriminate Less Than For-Profit Organizations? The Influence of Sector and Diversity Policies on
Managers’ Prejudice Toward Immigrants. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 47:4, 745-766.
[Crossref]
145. Bernd Frick, Robert Simmons, Friedrich Stein. 2018. The cost of shift work: Absenteeism in a
large German automobile plant. German Journal of Human Resource Management: Zeitschrift für
Personalforschung 32:3-4, 236-256. [Crossref]
146. Emanuela Ghignoni, Giuseppe Croce, Andrea Ricci. 2018. Fixed term contracts and employers' human
capital: The role of educational spillovers. Papers in Regional Science 97:2, 301-323. [Crossref]
147. Cristian Ramírez, Jorge Tarziján. 2018. Stakeholder value appropriation: The case of labor in the
worldwide mining industry. Strategic Management Journal 39:5, 1496-1525. [Crossref]
148. Herman Aguinis, Luis R. Gomez-Mejia, Geoffrey P. Martin, Harry Joo. 2018. CEO pay is indeed
decoupled from CEO performance: charting a path for the future. Management Research: Journal of
the Iberoamerican Academy of Management 16:1, 117-136. [Crossref]
149. Roy Chen, Jie Gong. 2018. Can self selection create high-performing teams?. Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization 148, 20-33. [Crossref]
150. Tanja Verheyen, Marie-Anne Guerry. 2018. Motives for (non) practicing demotion. Employee Relations
40:2, 244-263. [Crossref]
151. Catherine mname de Fontenay, Kwanghui mname Lim, Nicholas mname Snashall-Woodhams, Suren
mname Basov. 2018. Team Size, Noisy Signals, and the Career Prospects of Academic Scientists.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
152. Shusen Qi, Steven R. G. Ongena, Hua Cheng. 2018. When They Work with Women, Do Men Get
All the Credit?. SSRN Electronic Journal 23. . [Crossref]
153. Renée B. Adams, Min S. Kim. 2018. Unsuccessful Teams. SSRN Electronic Journal 30. . [Crossref]
154. André Kurmann, Erika McEntarfer. 2018. Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in the United States:
New Evidence From Worker-Firm Linked Data. SSRN Electronic Journal 60. . [Crossref]
155. Olivier Brolis, François-Xavier Devetter. 2018. La qualité d’emploi en France : cartographie et
classification des professions d’exécution. Relations industrielles / Industrial Relations 73:4, 840-877.
[Crossref]
156. Ashwin Kambhampati, Carlos Segura-Rodriguez, Peng Shao. 2018. Matching to Produce
Information. SSRN Electronic Journal 148. . [Crossref]
157. Christoph Riedl, Anita Williams Woolley. 2017. Teams vs. Crowds: A Field Test of the Relative
Contribution of Incentives, Member Ability, and Emergent Collaboration to Crowd-Based Problem
Solving Performance. Academy of Management Discoveries 3:4, 382-403. [Crossref]
158. Germán Pupato. 2017. Performance pay, trade and inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 172,
478-504. [Crossref]
159. Dov Cohen, Faith Shin, Xi Liu, Peter Ondish, Michael W. Kraus. 2017. Defining Social Class Across
Time and Between Groups. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 43:11, 1530-1545. [Crossref]
160. Felix Kölle. 2017. Affirmative action, cooperation, and the willingness to work in teams. Journal of
Economic Psychology 62, 50-62. [Crossref]
161. Ghazala Azmat, Rosa Ferrer. 2017. Gender Gaps in Performance: Evidence from Young Lawyers.
Journal of Political Economy 125:5, 1306-1355. [Crossref]
162. Kevin J. Boudreau, Tom Brady, Ina Ganguli, Patrick Gaule, Eva Guinan, Anthony Hollenberg, Karim
R. Lakhani. 2017. A Field Experiment on Search Costs and the Formation of Scientific Collaborations.
The Review of Economics and Statistics 99:4, 565-576. [Crossref]
163. Matthias Heinz, Heiner Schumacher. 2017. Signaling cooperation. European Economic Review 98,
199-216. [Crossref]
164. Roy Chen. 2017. Coordination with endogenous groups. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
141, 177-187. [Crossref]
165. Ansgar Richter, Susanne Schrader. 2017. Financial participation and recruitment and retention: causes
and consequences. The International Journal of Human Resource Management 28:11, 1563-1590.
[Crossref]
166. Heather Sarsons. 2017. Recognition for Group Work: Gender Differences in Academia. American
Economic Review 107:5, 141-145. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
167. Christian Grund, Alex Bryson, Robert Dur, Christine Harbring, Alexander K. Koch, Edward P.
Lazear. 2017. Personnel economics: A research field comes of age. German Journal of Human Resource
Management: Zeitschrift für Personalforschung 31:2, 101-107. [Crossref]
168. Akifumi Ishihara. 2017. Relational contracting and endogenous formation of teamwork. The RAND
Journal of Economics 48:2, 335-357. [Crossref]
169. Dan Goldhaber, Cyrus Grout, Nick Huntington-Klein. 2017. Screen Twice, Cut Once: Assessing
the Predictive Validity of Applicant Selection Tools. Education Finance and Policy 12:2, 197-223.
[Crossref]
170. Weerachart T. Kilenthong, Gabriel A. Madeira. 2017. Observability and endogenous organizations.
Economic Theory 63:3, 587-619. [Crossref]
171. Juan Chaparro, Eduardo Lora. 2017. Do Good Job Conditions Matter for Wages and Productivity?
Theory and Evidence from Latin America. Applied Research in Quality of Life 12:1, 153-172. [Crossref]
172. Y N Supriadi. 2017. Social Security Contribution to Productivity and Wages in Labour Organization
Perspective. IOP Conference Series: Materials Science and Engineering 180, 012020. [Crossref]
173. Ann P. Bartel, Brianna Cardiff-Hicks, Kathryn Shaw. 2017. Incentives for Lawyers. ILR Review 70:2,
336-358. [Crossref]
174. Daniel Weimar, Pamela Wicker. 2017. Moneyball Revisited. Journal of Sports Economics 18:2, 140-161.
[Crossref]
175. Werner Nienhueser. 2017. Socio-economic Research in Personnel versus Personnel Economics. Forum
for Social Economics 46:1, 104-119. [Crossref]
176. Dale Tweedie. 2017. The Normativity of Work: Retrieving a Critical Craft Norm. Critical Horizons
18:1, 66-84. [Crossref]
177. Amy Swaney. 2017. Employee Selection Practices and Performance Pay. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
178. Doruk Cetemen, Ilwoo Hwang, Ayca Kaya. 2017. Uncertainty-Driven Cooperation. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
179. Ola Andersson, Marieke Huysentruyt, Topi Miettinen, Ute Stephan. 2017. Person–Organization Fit
and Incentives: A Causal Test. Management Science 63:1, 73-96. [Crossref]
180. Ramin Baghai, Rui Silva, Luofu Ye. 2017. Bankruptcy, Team-Specific Human Capital, and
Innovation: Evidence from U.S. Inventors. SSRN Electronic Journal 56. . [Crossref]
181. Daniel H. Weinberg. 2016. Talent Recruitment and Firm Performance. Journal of Sports Economics
17:8, 832-862. [Crossref]
182. Kohei Daido, Takeshi Murooka. 2016. Team Incentives and Reference-Dependent Preferences.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 25:4, 958-989. [Crossref]
183. Jeffrey Carpenter, Peter Hans Matthews, Benjamin Tabb. 2016. Progressive taxation in a tournament
economy. Journal of Public Economics 143, 64-72. [Crossref]
184. Tanja Verheyen, Nick Deschacht, Marie-Anne Guerry. 2016. The occurrence of demotions regarding
job level, salary and job authority. Personnel Review 45:6, 1217-1239. [Crossref]
185. Karen L. Sedatole, Amy M. Swaney, Alexander Woods. 2016. The Implicit Incentive Effects of
Horizontal Monitoring and Team Member Dependence on Individual Performance. Contemporary
Accounting Research 33:3, 889-919. [Crossref]
186. Arnaldo Camuffo, Federica De Stefano. Work as Commons: Internal Labor Markets, Blended
Workforces and Management 363-382. [Crossref]
187. Gabriel Burdín. 2016. Equality Under Threat by the Talented: Evidence from Worker-Managed
Firms. The Economic Journal 126:594, 1372-1403. [Crossref]
188. Alex Gershkov, Jianpei Li, Paul Schweinzer. 2016. How to share it out: The value of information in
teams. Journal of Economic Theory 162, 261-304. [Crossref]
189. B. William Demeré, Ranjani Krishnan, Karen L. Sedatole, Alexander Woods. 2016. Do the incentive
effects of relative performance measurement vary with the ex ante probability of promotion?.
Management Accounting Research 30, 18-31. [Crossref]
190. Semih Tumen. 2016. A theory of intra-firm group design. Journal of Productivity Analysis 45:1, 89-102.
[Crossref]
191. Vishal Narayan, Vrinda Kadiyali. 2016. Repeated Interactions and Improved Outcomes: An Empirical
Analysis of Movie Production in the United States. Management Science 62:2, 591-607. [Crossref]
192. Brinja Meiseberg, Jochen Lengers, Thomas Ehrmann. 2016. The Economics of Sensationalism: The
Lack of Effect of Scandal-Reporting on Business Outcomes. Journal of Media Economics 29:1, 4-15.
[Crossref]
193. Sean Corcoran. Section I Discussion: How Do Educators Use Student Growth Measures in Practice?
153-165. [Crossref]
194. Xi Lu, Peter L. Lorentzen. 2016. Rescuing Autocracy from Itself: China's Anti-Corruption
Campaign. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
195. Ola Kvaloy. 2016. Teams in Relational Contracts. SSRN Electronic Journal 62. . [Crossref]
196. Aurélie Bonein, Isabelle Vialle. 2016. Rémunération et effort des travailleurs dans un cadre collectif.
L'Actualité économique 92:1-2, 217-247. [Crossref]
197. James D. Rodgers. Incorporating Fringe Benefits in Loss Calculations 89-115. [Crossref]
198. Shiva Sikdar. 2015. On efforts in teams with stereotypes. Economics Letters 137, 203-207. [Crossref]
199. Claudia M. Landeo, Kathryn E. Spier. 2015. Incentive contracts for teams: Experimental evidence.
Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 119, 496-511. [Crossref]
200. Xavier D’Haultfœuille, Philippe Février. 2015. Identification of mixture models using support
variations. Journal of Econometrics 189:1, 70-82. [Crossref]
201. Sascha O. Becker, Marc-Andreas Muendler. 2015. Trade and tasks: an exploration over three decades
in Germany. Economic Policy 30:84, 589-641. [Crossref]
202. Nicole C. Jones Young, Gary N. Powell. 2015. Hiring ex-offenders: A theoretical model. Human
Resource Management Review 25:3, 298-312. [Crossref]
203. Ognjen Scekic. Incentive Mechanisms for Social Computing 162-167. [Crossref]
204. Virgile Chassagnon, Benjamin Dubrion. 2015. Responsabilité sociale de l’entreprise et manipulation
des salariés au travail : un éclairage institutionnaliste à partir d’une analyse de la littérature sur les
codes de conduite. Revue de la régulation :17. . [Crossref]
205. Danny Miller, Xiaowei Xu, Vikas Mehrotra. 2015. When is human capital a valuable resource? The
performance effects of Ivy league selection among celebrated CEOs. Strategic Management Journal
36:6, 930-944. [Crossref]
206. Edoardo Della Torre, Matteo Pelagatti, Luca Solari. 2015. Internal and external equity in
compensation systems, organizational absenteeism and the role of explained inequalities. Human
Relations 68:3, 409-440. [Crossref]
207. Luisa Herbst, Kai A. Konrad, Florian Morath. 2015. Endogenous group formation in experimental
contests. European Economic Review 74, 163-189. [Crossref]
208. Margit Osterloh, Bruno S. Frey. 2015. Ranking Games. Evaluation Review 39:1, 102-129. [Crossref]
209. Tyler F. Thomas, Todd A. Thornock. 2015. Me vs. We: The Effect of Incomplete Team Member
Feedback on Cooperation of Self-Regarding Individuals. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
210. Jeremy B. Lill. 2015. When the Cat's (Far) Away: The Effect of Control Centralization and
Compensation Interdependence on Performance Misreporting. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
211. Matthias Heinz, Heiner Schumacher. 2015. Signaling Cooperation. SSRN Electronic Journal 80. .
[Crossref]
212. Katarzyna Kopycka. Personnel Strategies of Public Sector Organisations in Response to a Declining
Service Population. A Model and Empirical Evidence 191-221. [Crossref]
213. Mirella Damiani, Andrea Ricci. 2014. Managers’ education and the choice of different variable pay
schemes: Evidence from Italian firms. European Management Journal 32:6, 891-902. [Crossref]
214. Alessandro Bucciol, Nicolai J. Foss, Marco Piovesan. 2014. Pay Dispersion and Performance in Teams.
PLoS ONE 9:11, e112631. [Crossref]
215. David A. Miller, Kareen Rozen. 2014. Wasteful Sanctions, Underperformance, and Endogenous
Supervision. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 6:4, 326-361. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
216. Christian Pfeifer. 2014. Base Salaries, Bonus Payments, and Work Absence among Managers in a
German Company. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 61:5, 523-536. [Crossref]
217. Tor Eriksson, Nicolai Kristensen. 2014. Wages or Fringes? Some Evidence on Trade-Offs and Sorting.
Journal of Labor Economics 32:4, 899-928. [Crossref]
218. Richard Fabling, Arthur Grimes. 2014. The “Suite” Smell of Success. ILR Review 67:4, 1095-1126.
[Crossref]
219. Cecilia Navarra, Ermanno Tortia. 2014. Employer Moral Hazard, Wage Rigidity, and Worker
Cooperatives: A Theoretical Appraisal. Journal of Economic Issues 48:3, 707-726. [Crossref]
220. Keongtae Kim, Sunil Mithas, Jonathan Whitaker, Prasanto K. Roy. 2014. Research Note —Industry-
Specific Human Capital and Wages: Evidence from the Business Process Outsourcing Industry.
Information Systems Research 25:3, 618-638. [Crossref]
221. Thomas Armbrüster, Katharina Schüller. 2014. Strategische Orientierung und Gehaltsstrukturen von
Personalleitenden. German Journal of Human Resource Management: Zeitschrift für Personalforschung
28:3, 316-345. [Crossref]
222. Tat Y. Chan, Jia Li, Lamar Pierce. 2014. Compensation and Peer Effects in Competing Sales Teams.
Management Science 60:8, 1965-1984. [Crossref]
223. Margit Osterloh, Bruno S. Frey. Academic rankings between the “republic of science” and “new public
management” 77-103. [Crossref]
224. David A. Spencer. 2014. Conceptualising Work in Economics: Negating a Disutility. Kyklos 67:2,
280-294. [Crossref]
225. László Csaba. 2014. Developmental perspectives on Europe. Society and Economy 36:1, 21-36.
[Crossref]
226. Patrick E. Downes, Daejeong Choi. 2014. Employee reactions to pay dispersion: A typology of existing
research. Human Resource Management Review 24:1, 53-66. [Crossref]
227. Javier García-Bernal, Marisa Ramírez-Alesón. 2014. Diluting the perverse element of rational
altruism. BRQ Business Research Quarterly 17:1, 31-46. [Crossref]
228. Kevin J. Boudreau, Patrick Gaule, Karim Lakhani, Christoph Riedl, Anita Williams Woolley. 2014.
From Crowds to Collaborators: Initiating Effort & Catalyzing Interactions Among Online Creative
Workers. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
229. Dushko Josheski. 2014. Essential Themes in Personnel Economics. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
230. Daniel Herbold. 2014. A Repeated Principal-Agent Model with On-the-Job Search. SSRN Electronic
Journal 58. . [Crossref]
231. Kevin J. Boudreau, Tom Brady, Ina Ganguli, Patrick Gaule, Eva Guinan, Tony Hollenberg, Karim
Lakhani. 2014. A Field Experiment on Search Costs and the Formation of Scientific Collaborations.
SSRN Electronic Journal 34. . [Crossref]
232. Phong T. H. Ngo, Steven Roberts. 2014. Gambling for Resurrection: Value and Risk Taking in the
National Basketball Association. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
233. Matthias Fahn, Hendrik Hakenes. 2014. Teamwork as a Self-Disciplining Device. SSRN Electronic
Journal 56. . [Crossref]
234. Andrei CECHIN, Jos BIJMAN, Stefano PASCUCCI, Decio ZYLBERSZTAJN, Onno OMTA.
2013. DRIVERS OF PRO-ACTIVE MEMBER PARTICIPATION IN AGRICULTURAL
COOPERATIVES: EVIDENCE FROM BRAZIL. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 84:4,
443-468. [Crossref]
235. David A. Spencer. 2013. Barbarians at the gate: a critical appraisal of the influence of economics on
the field and practice of HRM. Human Resource Management Journal 23:4, 346-359. [Crossref]
236. Oriana Bandiera, Iwan Barankay, Imran Rasul. 2013. TEAM INCENTIVES: EVIDENCE FROM
A FIRM LEVEL EXPERIMENT. Journal of the European Economic Association 11:5, 1079-1114.
[Crossref]
237. Bruno S. Frey, Fabian Homberg, Margit Osterloh. 2013. Organizational Control Systems and Pay-
for-Performance in the Public Service. Organization Studies 34:7, 949-972. [Crossref]
238. Andrew W. Nutting. 2013. Immediate Effects of On-The-Job Training and Its Intensity. Journal of
Sports Economics 14:3, 303-320. [Crossref]
239. Ognjen Scekic, Hong-Linh Truong, Schahram Dustdar. 2013. Incentives and rewarding in social
computing. Communications of the ACM 56:6, 72-82. [Crossref]
240. Nick Vikander. 2013. Sorting and sustaining cooperation. Oxford Economic Papers 65:2, 548-566.
[Crossref]
241. Ravi Bapna, Nishtha Langer, Amit Mehra, Ram Gopal, Alok Gupta. 2013. Human Capital
Investments and Employee Performance: An Analysis of IT Services Industry. Management Science
59:3, 641-658. [Crossref]
242. Bernd J. Frick, Ute Goetzen, Robert Simmons. 2013. The Hidden Costs of High-Performance Work
Practices: Evidence from a Large German Steel Company. ILR Review 66:1, 198-224. [Crossref]
243. Akifumi Ishihara. 2013. Relational Contracting and Endogenous Formation of Teamwork. SSRN
Electronic Journal 10. . [Crossref]
244. Silvia Sacchetti, Ermanno C. Tortia. 2013. The Internal and External Governance of Cooperatives:
Membership and Consistency of Values. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
245. Daniel H. Weinberg. 2013. Talent Recruitment and Firm Performance: The Business of Major League
Sports. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
246. Daniel Herbold. 2013. Effort Incentives and On-the-Job Search: An Alternative Role for Efficiency
Wages in Employment Contracts. SSRN Electronic Journal 58. . [Crossref]
247. Lotte Bøgh Andersen, Tor Eriksson, Nicolai Kristensen, Lene Holm Pedersen. 2012. Attirer des
collaborateurs motivés par le service public. Comment définir les conditions salariales ?. Revue
Internationale des Sciences Administratives Vol. 78:4, 661-690. [Crossref]
248. Lotte Bøgh Andersen, Tor Eriksson, Nicolai Kristensen, Lene Holm Pedersen. 2012. Attracting
public service motivated employees: how to design compensation packages. International Review of
Administrative Sciences 78:4, 615-641. [Crossref]
249. Stephan Kampelmann, François Rycx. 2012. Are Occupations Paid What They are Worth? An
Econometric Study of Occupational Wage Inequality and Productivity. De Economist 160:3, 257-287.
[Crossref]
250. Katrin Burmeister-Lamp, Moren Lévesque, Christian Schade. 2012. Are entrepreneurs influenced by
risk attitude, regulatory focus or both? An experiment on entrepreneurs' time allocation. Journal of
Business Venturing 27:4, 456-476. [Crossref]
251. Tomasz Obloj, Metin Sengul. 2012. Incentive Life-cycles. Administrative Science Quarterly 57:2,
305-347. [Crossref]
252. Diemo Urbig, Utz Weitzel, Stephanie Rosenkranz, Arjen van Witteloostuijn. 2012. Exploiting
opportunities at all cost? Entrepreneurial intent and externalities. Journal of Economic Psychology 33:2,
379-393. [Crossref]
253. Ognjen Scekic, Hong-Linh Truong, Schahram Dustdar. Modeling Rewards and Incentive
Mechanisms for Social BPM 150-155. [Crossref]
254. Tor Eriksson, Marie Claire Villeval. 2012. Respect and relational contracts. Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization 81:1, 286-298. [Crossref]
255. Tor Eriksson. Progression of HR Practices in Danish Firms During Two Decades 237-266. [Crossref]
256. Tat Y. Chan, Jia Li, Lamar Pierce. 2012. Compensation and Peer Effects in Competing Sales Teams.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
257. Kohei Daido, Takeshi Murooka. 2012. Team Incentives and Reference-Dependent Preferences. SSRN
Electronic Journal 35. . [Crossref]
258. David A. Miller, Kareen Rozen. 2012. Optimally Empty Promises and Endogenous Supervision. SSRN
Electronic Journal 73. . [Crossref]
259. Alessandro Bucciol, Marco Piovesan. 2012. Pay Dispersion and Work Performance. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
260. Hein Bogaard, Jan Svejnar. 2012. Incentive Pay and Performance: Insider Econometrics in a Multi-
Unit Bank. SSRN Electronic Journal 25. . [Crossref]
261. Rosa Ferrer, Ghazala Azmat. 2012. Gender Gaps in Performance: Evidence from Young Lawyers.
SSRN Electronic Journal 3. . [Crossref]
262. Kyonghee Kim, Bok Baik, John Harry Evans, Yoshio Yanadori. 2012. White Collar Incentives. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
263. Luisa Herbst, Kai A. Konrad, Florian Morath. 2012. Endogenous Group Formation in Experimental
Contests. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
264. Richard Blaikie Fabling, Arthur Grimes, David C. Maré. 2012. Performance Pay Systems and the
Gender Wage Gap. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
265. Thomas J. Chemmanur, Mine Ertugrul, Karthik Krishnan. 2012. Is it the Investment Bank or the
Investment Banker? A Study of the Role of Investment Banker Human Capital in Acquisitions. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
266. Bruno S. Frey, Margit Osterloh. 2012. Motivation Governance. SSRN Electronic Journal 50. .
[Crossref]
267. Stephan Kampelmann, François Rycx. 2011. Wages of Occupations in Theory... and Practice. Reflets
et perspectives de la vie économique Tome L:4, 119-131. [Crossref]
268. Ann P. Bartel, Richard B. Freeman, Casey Ichniowski, Morris M. Kleiner. 2011. Can a workplace
have an attitude problem? Workplace effects on employee attitudes and organizational performance.
Labour Economics 18:4, 411-423. [Crossref]
269. Paul Osterman. 2011. Institutional Labor Economics, the New Personnel Economics, and Internal
Labor Markets: A Reconsideration. ILR Review 64:4, 637-653. [Crossref]
270. David A. Spencer. 2011. Getting personnel. Work, Employment and Society 25:1, 118-131. [Crossref]
271. Ina Krause. Neue Prozesse sozialer Schließung am deutschen Arbeitsmarkt? Betriebliche
Nutzungszusammenhänge der Beschäftigungsformen „Leiharbeit“ und „freie Mitarbeit“ 303-328.
[Crossref]
272. John A. List, Imran Rasul. Field Experiments in Labor Economics 103-228. [Crossref]
273. George Georgiadis. 2011. Projects and Team Dynamics. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
274. Isabelle Vialle, Luís P. Santos-Pinto, Jean-Louis Rulliere. 2011. Self-Confidence and Teamwork: An
Experimental Test. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
275. Bruno S. Frey, Margit Osterloh. 2011. Rankings Games. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
276. Michael Nippa. On the need to extend tournament theory through insights from status research
118-152. [Crossref]
277. Touria Jaaidane. 2010. La notion de valeur des carrières et son intérêt dans la fonction publique. Revue
française d'économie Volume XXV:3, 79-114. [Crossref]
278. Leslie McCall, Christine Percheski. 2010. Income Inequality: New Trends and Research Directions.
Annual Review of Sociology 36:1, 329-347. [Crossref]
279. Laura Langbein. 2010. Economics, Public Service Motivation, and Pay for Performance: Complements
or Substitutes?. International Public Management Journal 13:1, 9-23. [Crossref]
280. Gabriel Rossman, Nicole Esparza, Phillip Bonacich. 2010. I’d Like to Thank the Academy, Team
Spillovers, and Network Centrality. American Sociological Review 75:1, 31-51. [Crossref]
281. Ebinezer R. Florano, Julio S. Amador. 2010. Institutionalizing Reforms through the Citizen Report
Card: The Case of the Quezon City Building Permit Issuance Service. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
282. Katja Rost. 2010. The Rise in Executive Compensation - Consequence of a ‛War for Talents‛?. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
283. Tor Eriksson, Marie-Claire Villeval. 2010. Respect as an Incentive. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
284. Kathryn Shaw. 2009. Insider econometrics: A roadmap with stops along the way. Labour Economics
16:6, 607-617. [Crossref]
285. Venkat Venkatasubramanian. 2009. What is Fair Pay for Executives? An Information Theoretic
Analysis of Wage Distributions. Entropy 11:4, 766-781. [Crossref]
286. Sabrina Teyssier. 2009. Aptitude, préférences et sélection des travailleurs. Vie & sciences de l'entreprise
N° 182:2, 21-38. [Crossref]
287. Laurence J. O'Toole, Kenneth J. Meier. 2009. The Human Side of Public Organizations. The American
Review of Public Administration 39:5, 499-518. [Crossref]
288. Fredrik Andersson, Matthew Freedman, John Haltiwanger, Julia Lane, Kathryn Shaw. 2009. Reaching
for the Stars: Who Pays for Talent in Innovative Industries?. The Economic Journal 119:538, F308-
F332. [Crossref]
289. Richard M. Romano, Donald A. Dellow. 2009. Technological change, globalization, and the
community college. New Directions for Community Colleges 2009:146, 11-19. [Crossref]
290. Rachel Griffith, Andrew Neely. 2009. Performance Pay and Managerial Experience in Multitask
Teams: Evidence from within a Firm. Journal of Labor Economics 27:1, 49-82. [Crossref]
291. Douglas H. Frank, Tomasz Obloj. 2009. Ability, Adverse Learning and Agency Costs: Evidence from
Retail Banking. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
292. Tammy Schirle. 2008. Why Have the Labor Force Participation Rates of Older Men Increased since
the Mid‐1990s?. Journal of Labor Economics 26:4, 549-594. [Crossref]
293. Uschi Backes-Gellner, Donata Bessey, Kerstin Pull, Simone N. Tuor. 2008. What Behavioural
Economics Teaches Personnel Economics. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
294. James Annable. 2008. Employee On-the-Job Behavior: A Critical Survey of Economic Models. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]

You might also like