Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 42

Introduction to Stochastic Finance

Jia-An Yan
Visit to download the full and correct content document:
https://textbookfull.com/product/introduction-to-stochastic-finance-jia-an-yan/
More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant
download maybe you interests ...

Stochastic Finance An Introduction with Examples 1st


Edition Turner

https://textbookfull.com/product/stochastic-finance-an-
introduction-with-examples-1st-edition-turner/

Introduction to Stochastic Processes 1st Edition Tapas


Kumar Chandra

https://textbookfull.com/product/introduction-to-stochastic-
processes-1st-edition-tapas-kumar-chandra/

Stochastic Calculus An Introduction Through Theory and


Exercises 1st Edition Paolo Baldi

https://textbookfull.com/product/stochastic-calculus-an-
introduction-through-theory-and-exercises-1st-edition-paolo-
baldi/

Accounting and Finance: An Introduction 8th Edition


Eddie Mclaney

https://textbookfull.com/product/accounting-and-finance-an-
introduction-8th-edition-eddie-mclaney/
Numerical Partial Differential Equations in Finance
Explained: An Introduction to Computational Finance 1st
Edition Karel In 'T Hout (Auth.)

https://textbookfull.com/product/numerical-partial-differential-
equations-in-finance-explained-an-introduction-to-computational-
finance-1st-edition-karel-in-t-hout-auth/

Healthcare Finance: An Introduction to Accounting and


Financial Management, Sixth Edition Louis C. Gapenski

https://textbookfull.com/product/healthcare-finance-an-
introduction-to-accounting-and-financial-management-sixth-
edition-louis-c-gapenski/

Stochastic Processes and Calculus An Elementary


Introduction with Applications 1st Edition Uwe Hassler

https://textbookfull.com/product/stochastic-processes-and-
calculus-an-elementary-introduction-with-applications-1st-
edition-uwe-hassler/

Gapenski's healthcare finance : an introduction to


accounting and financial management Seventh Edition
Kristin Leanne Reiter

https://textbookfull.com/product/gapenskis-healthcare-finance-an-
introduction-to-accounting-and-financial-management-seventh-
edition-kristin-leanne-reiter/

Mathematics of Finance An Intuitive Introduction


Undergraduate Texts in Mathematics Saari

https://textbookfull.com/product/mathematics-of-finance-an-
intuitive-introduction-undergraduate-texts-in-mathematics-saari/
Universitext

Jia-An Yan

Introduction
to Stochastic
Finance
Universitext
Universitext

Series editors
Sheldon Axler
San Francisco State University
Carles Casacuberta
Universitat de Barcelona
Angus MacIntyre
Queen Mary, University of London
Kenneth Ribet
University of California, Berkeley
Claude Sabbah
École polytechnique, CNRS, Université Paris-Saclay, Palaiseau
Endre Süli
University of Oxford
Wojbor A. Woyczyński
Case Western Reserve University

Universitext is a series of textbooks that presents material from a wide variety


of mathematical disciplines at master’s level and beyond. The books, often well
class-tested by their author, may have an informal, personal even experimental
approach to their subject matter. Some of the most successful and established books
in the series have evolved through several editions, always following the evolution
of teaching curricula, to very polished texts.

Thus as research topics trickle down into graduate-level teaching, first textbooks
written for new, cutting-edge courses may make their way into Universitext.

More information about this series at http://www.springer.com/series/223


Jia-An Yan

Introduction to Stochastic
Finance

123
Jia-An Yan
Academy of Mathematics and System Science
Chineses Academy of Sciences
Beijing, China

ISSN 0172-5939 ISSN 2191-6675 (electronic)


Universitext
ISBN 978-981-13-1656-2 ISBN 978-981-13-1657-9 (eBook)
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-1657-9

Library of Congress Control Number: 2018952344

Mathematics Subject Classification: 91Gxx, 60Gxx, 60Hxx

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. and Science Press 2018


This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of
the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation,
broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information
storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology
now known or hereafter developed.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication
does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant
protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
The publisher, the authors, and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book
are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or
the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any
errors or omissions that may have been made. The publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional
claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This Springer imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.
The registered company address is: 152 Beach Road, #21-01/04 Gateway East, Singapore 189721,
Singapore
Preface

The history of financial mathematics can be traced back to the French mathemati-
cian Louis Bachelier’s doctoral dissertation “Théorie de la speculation” in 1900
Bachelier (1900). Bachelier’s work, however, was not known to most economists
until Paul A. Samuelson mentioned it in an article of 1965. In 1969 and 1971,
Robert C. Merton studied the optimal portfolio problem in continuous-time using
the stochastic dynamic programming method. In 1973, Fischer Black and Myron
S. Scholes used stochastic analysis, in particular, Kiyosi Itô’s formula, to derive
the famous Black-Scholes formula for option pricing. Almost at the same time,
Merton (1973a) improved the Black-Scholes model and developed an idea of using
options to evaluate a company’s debt in the so-called contingent claims analysis.
Harrison and Kreps (1979) proposed a martingale method to characterize a no-
arbitrage market and the use of equivalent martingale measure on options pricing
and hedging, which had profound influence on the subsequent development of
financial mathematics. Since 1970s, in order to study the pricing of interest rate
derivatives, many scholars have proposed several interest rate term structure models,
including Vasicek, CIR, HJM, and BGM models, which could reflect the market
trend of the future spot rate.
For more than half a century, many scholars worked research on theory and
applications of financial mathematics (also known as mathematical finance) and
published many books in the area. Financial mathematics not only has a direct
impact on the innovation of financial instruments and on the efficient functioning
of financial markets but also is widely used in investment decisions, valuation of
research and development projects, and in risk management.
This book is intended to give a systematic introduction to the basic theory of
financial mathematics, with an emphasis on applications of martingale methods in
pricing and hedging of contingent claims, interest rate term structure models, and
expected utility maximization problems. The book consists of 14 chapters. Chap-
ter 1 introduces the basic theory of probability and discrete time martingales, which
is specially designed for readers who do not have much knowledge of probability
theory. In Chap. 2, we introduce the theory of discrete time portfolio selection (i.e.,
Harry M. Markowitz’s mean-variance analysis), the capital asset pricing model

v
vi Preface

(CAPM), the arbitrage pricing theory (APT), and the multistage mean-variance
analysis. The basic idea of expected utility theory and the consumption-based
asset pricing model are also sketched in this chapter. In Chap. 3, we introduce
discrete time financial markets and martingale characterization of arbitrage-free
markets and present the martingale method for the expected utility maximization
and the risk-neutral pricing principle for European contingent claims. Chapter 4
systematically presents Itô’s theory of stochastic analysis (including Itô’s integral
and Itô’s formula, Girsanov’s theorem, and the martingale representation theorem)
which is the theoretical basis of the martingale method in financial mathematics.
This chapter can be used separately as a concise text for postgraduates in probability
studying Itô’s theory of stochastic analysis. In Chap. 5, for the Black-Scholes
model, we introduce the martingale method for pricing and hedging European
contingent claims and derive the Black-Scholes formula for pricing European
options. The pricing of American options is also briefly discussed. In addition,
some examples are given to illustrate applications of the martingale method, and
several modifications of the Black-Scholes model are presented. In Chap. 6, we
introduce several commonly used exotic options: barrier options, Asian options,
lookback options, and reset options. The pricing and hedging of these exotic options
are investigated with the martingale method and partial differential equations.
Chapter 7 presents Itô process and diffusion process models. The martingale method
of contingent claim pricing is presented in detail, including an introduction of
time and scale transformation to give some explicit formulas for option pricing.
Chapter 8 introduces the bond market and interest rate term structure models,
including a variety of single-factor short-term interest rate model, HJM model,
and BGM Model, and studies the pricing of interest rate derivatives. Chapter 9
introduces optimal investment portfolios and investment-consumption strategies
for diffusion process models. Within L2 -allowable trading strategies, the risk-
mean portfolio selection problem, expected utility maximization problem, and
the selection of portfolio strategy with consumption are investigated. Chapter 10
introduces the general theory of static risk measures, which includes consistent
risk measures, convex risk measures, comonotonically sub-additive risk measures,
comonotonically convex risk measure, and a variety of distribution invariant risk
measures, as well as their characterizations and representations. In Chap. 11, after
a brief overview of semimartingales and stochastic calculus, we introduce some
basic concepts and results on markets of semimartingale model and give numeraire-
free characterizations of attainable contingent claims. In Chap. 12, we give a
survey on convex duality theory for optimal investment and present a numeraire-
free and original probability-based framework for financial markets. The expected
utility maximization and valuation problems in a general semimartingale setting are
studied in Chap. 13. For a market driven by a Lévy process, the optimal portfolio and
the related martingale measure are worked out explicitly for some particular types of
utility function. Finally, in Chap. 14, we introduce the “optimal growth portfolios”
in markets of semimartingale model and work out their expressions in a geometric
Lévy process model and a jump-diffusion-like process model.
Preface vii

I have taught from the manuscript of this book in an introductory course of


mathematical finance for my former graduate students. Thanks to them for reporting
misprints and errors. I am grateful to Prof. Jianming Xia for contributing to the
writing of Sect. 9.2 of Chap. 9; to Dr. Yongsheng Song for his PhD thesis, which is
the basic material for Chap. 10 of the book; and to Dr. Jun Yan for typographical
and grammatical suggestions.

Beijing, China Jia-An Yan


May, 2018
Contents

1 Foundation of Probability Theory and Discrete-Time


Martingales . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
1.1 Basic Concepts of Probability Theory. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
1.1.1 Events and Probability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
1.1.2 Independence, 0-1 Law, and Borel-Cantelli Lemma . . . . . . 3
1.1.3 Integrals, (Mathematical) Expectations of Random
Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.1.4 Convergence Theorems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.2 Conditional Mathematical Expectation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
1.2.1 Definition and Basic Properties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
1.2.2 Convergence Theorems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.2.3 Two Theorems About Conditional Expectation . . . . . . . . . . . 15
1.3 Duals of Spaces L∞ (, F) and L∞ (, F, m) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
1.4 Family of Uniformly Integrable Random Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
1.5 Discrete Time Martingales . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
1.5.1 Basic Definitions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
1.5.2 Basic Theorems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
1.5.3 Martingale Transforms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
1.5.4 Snell Envelop . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
1.6 Markov Sequences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31
2 Portfolio Selection Theory in Discrete-Time . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.1 Mean-Variance Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34
2.1.1 Mean-Variance Frontier Portfolios Without
Risk-Free Asset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
2.1.2 Revised Formulations of Mean-Variance Analysis
Without Risk-Free Asset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38
2.1.3 Mean-Variance Frontier Portfolios with Risk-Free
Asset. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
2.1.4 Mean-Variance Utility Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45

ix
x Contents

2.2 Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47


2.2.1 Market Competitive Equilibrium and Market Portfolio . . 47
2.2.2 CAPM with Risk-Free Asset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
2.2.3 CAPM Without Risk-Free Asset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
2.2.4 Equilibrium Pricing Using CAPM . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
2.3 Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
2.4 Mean-Semivariance Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
2.5 Multistage Mean-Variance Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58
2.6 Expected Utility Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
2.6.1 Utility Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
2.6.2 Arrow-Pratt’s Risk Aversion Functions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
2.6.3 Comparison of Risk Aversion Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
2.6.4 Preference Defined by Stochastic Orders. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
2.6.5 Maximization of Expected Utility and Initial Price
of Risky Asset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
2.7 Consumption-Based Asset Pricing Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72
3 Financial Markets in Discrete Time . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
3.1 Basic Concepts of Financial Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
3.1.1 Numeraire . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
3.1.2 Pricing and Hedging . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
3.1.3 Put-Call Parity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
3.1.4 Intrinsic Value and Time Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
3.1.5 Bid-Ask Spread . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
3.1.6 Efficient Market Hypothesis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
3.2 Binomial Tree Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
3.2.1 The One-Period Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
3.2.2 The Multistage Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
3.2.3 The Approximately Continuous Trading Case . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
3.3 The General Discrete-Time Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83
3.3.1 The Basic Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83
3.3.2 Arbitrage, Admissible, and Allowable Strategies . . . . . . . . . 85
3.4 Martingale Characterization of No-Arbitrage Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86
3.4.1 The Finite Market Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86
3.4.2 The General Case: Dalang-Morton-Willinger Theorem . . 87
3.5 Pricing of European Contingent Claims. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
3.6 Maximization of Expected Utility and Option Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
3.6.1 General Utility Function Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
3.6.2 HARA Utility Functions and Their Duality Case . . . . . . . . . 94
3.6.3 Utility Function-Based Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
3.6.4 Market Equilibrium Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
3.7 American Contingent Claims Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103
3.7.1 Super-Hedging Strategies in Complete Markets . . . . . . . . . . 103
3.7.2 Arbitrage-Free Pricing in Complete Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104
3.7.3 Arbitrage-Free Pricing in Non-complete Markets . . . . . . . . 105
Contents xi

4 Martingale Theory and Itô Stochastic Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107


4.1 Continuous Time Stochastic Processes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107
4.1.1 Basic Concepts of Stochastic Processes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107
4.1.2 Poisson and Compound Poisson Processes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108
4.1.3 Markov Processes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110
4.1.4 Brownian Motion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
4.1.5 Stopping Times, Martingales, Local Martingales . . . . . . . . . 114
4.1.6 Finite Variation Processes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115
4.1.7 Doob-Meyer Decomposition of Local Submartingales . . . 116
4.1.8 Quadratic Variation Processes of Semimartingales . . . . . . . 119
4.2 Stochastic Integrals w.t.t. Brownian Motion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
4.2.1 Wiener Integrals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
4.2.2 Itô Stochastic Integrals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125
4.3 Itô’s Formula and Girsanov’s Theorem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130
4.3.1 Itô’s Formula . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
4.3.2 Lévy’s Martingale Characterization of Brownian
Motion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133
4.3.3 Reflection Principle of Brownian Motion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134
4.3.4 Stochastic Exponentials and Novikov Theorem . . . . . . . . . . 134
4.3.5 Girsanov’s Theorem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136
4.4 Martingale Representation Theorem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137
4.5 Itô Stochastic Differential Equations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140
4.5.1 Existence and Uniqueness of Solutions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140
4.5.2 Examples . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
4.6 Itô Diffusion Processes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147
4.7 Feynman-Kac Formula . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148
4.8 Snell Envelop (Continuous Time Case) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149
5 The Black-Scholes Model and Its Modifications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
5.1 Martingale Method for Option Pricing and Hedging . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
5.1.1 The Black-Scholes Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
5.1.2 Equivalent Martingale Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155
5.1.3 Pricing and Hedging of European Contingent Claims . . . . 157
5.1.4 Pricing of American Contingent Claims. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160
5.2 Some Examples of Option Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
5.2.1 Options on a Stock with Proportional Dividends . . . . . . . . . 162
5.2.2 Foreign Currency Option . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 163
5.2.3 Compound Option . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164
5.2.4 Chooser Option . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165
5.3 Practical Uses of the Black-Scholes Formulas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
5.3.1 Historical and Implied Volatilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
5.3.2 Delta Hedging and Analyses of Option Price
Sensitivities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
xii Contents

5.4 Capturing Biases in Black-Scholes Formulas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168


5.4.1 CEV Model and Level-Dependent Volatility Model . . . . . . 168
5.4.2 Stochastic Volatility Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 170
5.4.3 SABR Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 172
5.4.4 Variance-Gamma (VG) Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 172
5.4.5 GARCH Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174
6 Pricing and Hedging of Exotic Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175
6.1 Running Extremum of Brownian Motion with Drift . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175
6.2 Barrier Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
6.2.1 Single-Barrier Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
6.2.2 Double-Barrier Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180
6.3 Asian Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180
6.3.1 Geometric Average Asian Options. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181
6.3.2 Arithmetic Average Asian Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183
6.4 Lookback Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 189
6.4.1 Lookback Strike Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 190
6.4.2 Lookback Rate Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 192
6.5 Reset Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193
7 Itô Process and Diffusion Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195
7.1 Itô Process Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195
7.1.1 Self-Financing Trading Strategies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195
7.1.2 Equivalent Martingale Measures and No Arbitrage. . . . . . . 197
7.1.3 Pricing and Hedging of European Contingent Claims . . . . 201
7.1.4 Change of Numeraire . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 203
7.1.5 Arbitrage Pricing Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 205
7.2 PDE Approach to Option Pricing. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 208
7.3 Probabilistic Methods for Option Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 209
7.3.1 Time and Scale Changes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 209
7.3.2 Option Pricing in Merton’s Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 210
7.3.3 General Nonlinear Reduction Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 211
7.3.4 Option Pricing Under the CEV Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 212
7.4 Pricing American Contingent Claims . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 214
8 Term Structure Models for Interest Rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 217
8.1 The Bond Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 218
8.1.1 Basic Concepts. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 218
8.1.2 Bond Price Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 219
8.2 Short Rate Models. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 220
8.2.1 One-Factor Models and Affine Term Structures . . . . . . . . . . 221
8.2.2 Functional Approach to One-Factor Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 225
8.2.3 Multifactor Short Rate Models. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 229
8.2.4 Forward Rate Models: The HJM Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 231
8.3 Forward Price and Futures Price. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 234
8.3.1 Forward Price . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 234
8.3.2 Futures Price . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 235
Contents xiii

8.4 Pricing Interest Rate Derivatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 236


8.4.1 PDE Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 236
8.4.2 Forward Measure Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 239
8.4.3 Changing Numeraire Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 239
8.5 The Flesaker-Hughston Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 242
8.6 BGM Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 244
9 Optimal Investment-Consumption Strategies in Diffusion Models . . . 247
9.1 Market Models and Investment-Consumption Strategies . . . . . . . . . . 247
9.2 Expected Utility Maximization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 250
9.3 Mean-Risk Portfolio Selection. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 258
9.3.1 General Framework for Mean-Risk Models. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 258
9.3.2 Weighted Mean-Variance Model. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 259
10 Static Risk Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 263
10.1 Coherent Risk Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 263
10.1.1 Monetary Risk Measures and Coherent Risk Measures . . 264
10.1.2 Representation of Coherent Risk Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 266
10.2 Co-monotonic Subadditive Risk Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 268
10.2.1 Representation: The Model-Free Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 269
10.2.2 Representation: The Model-Dependent Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . 272
10.3 Convex Risk Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 274
10.3.1 Representation: The Model-Free Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 274
10.3.2 Representation: The Model-Dependent Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . 275
10.4 Co-monotonic Convex Risk Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 276
10.4.1 The Model-Free Case. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 276
10.4.2 The Model-Dependent Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 278
10.5 Law-Invariant Risk Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 280
10.5.1 Law-Invariant Coherent Risk Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 280
10.5.2 Law-Invariant Convex Risk Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 285
10.5.3 Some Results About Stochastic Orders and Quantiles. . . . 286
10.5.4 Law-Invariant Co-monotonic Subadditive Risk
Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 288
10.5.5 Law-Invariant Co-monotonic Convex Risk Measures . . . . 298
11 Stochastic Calculus and Semimartingale Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 307
11.1 Semimartingales and Stochastic Calculus. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 308
11.1.1 Doob-Meyer’s Decomposition of Supermartingales . . . . . . 308
11.1.2 Local Martingales and Semimartingales . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 310
11.1.3 Stochastic Integrals w.r.t. Local Martingales . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 311
11.1.4 Stochastic Integrals w.r.t. Semimartingales . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 313
11.1.5 Itô’s Formula and Doléans Exponential Formula . . . . . . . . . 314
11.2 Semimartingale Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 315
11.2.1 Basic Concepts and Notations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 316
11.2.2 Vector Stochastic Integrals w.r.t. Semimartingales. . . . . . . . 318
11.2.3 Optional Decomposition Theorem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 319
xiv Contents

11.3 Superhedging . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 321


11.4 Fair Prices and Attainable Claims . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 322
12 Optimal Investment in Incomplete Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 327
12.1 Convex Duality on Utility Maximization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 328
12.1.1 The Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 328
12.1.2 Complete Market Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 329
12.1.3 Incomplete Market Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 330
12.1.4 Results of Kramkov and Schachermayer . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 332
12.2 A Numeraire-Free Framework. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 334
12.2.1 Martingale Deflators and Superhedging . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 335
12.2.2 Reformulation of Theorem 12.1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 337
12.3 Utility-Based Approaches to Option Pricing. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 338
12.3.1 Minimax Martingale Deflator Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 338
12.3.2 Marginal Utility-Based Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 340
13 Martingale Method for Utility Maximization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 343
13.1 Expected Utility Maximization and Valuation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 344
13.1.1 Expected Utility Maximization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 344
13.1.2 Utility-Based Valuation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 346
13.2 Minimum Relative Entropy and Maximum Hellinger Integral. . . . . 348
13.2.1 HARA Utility Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 348
13.2.2 Another Type of Utility Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 350
13.2.3 Utility Function W0 (x) = −e−x . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 351
13.3 Market Driven by a Lévy Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 352
13.3.1 The Market Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 352
13.3.2 Results for HARA Utility Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 354
13.3.3 Results for Utility Functions of the Form Wγ (γ < 0) . . . 359
13.3.4 Results for Utility Function W0 (x) = −e−x . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 359
14 Optimal Growth Portfolios and Option Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 365
14.1 Optimal Growth Portfolio . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 365
14.1.1 Optimal Growth Strategy. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 366
14.1.2 A Geometric Lévy Process Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 367
14.1.3 A Jump-Diffusion-Like Process Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 373
14.2 Pricing in a Geometric Lévy Process Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 377
14.3 Other Approaches to Option Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 383
14.3.1 The Föllmer-Schwarzer Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 383
14.3.2 The Davis’ Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 383
14.3.3 Esscher Transform Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 384

References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 387

Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 397
Chapter 1
Foundation of Probability Theory
and Discrete-Time Martingales

Gambling with dice was very popular in medieval Europe. The study of problems
involving probability associated with gambling led to the development of proba-
bility theory. However, it was not until the early twentieth century that probability
theory was considered as a branch of mathematics. The mathematical foundation
of modern probability theory was laid by Andrei N. Kolmogorov in 1933. He
adopted Lebesgue’s framework of measure theory and created an axiomatic system
for probability theory. This chapter introduces some basic concepts and results
of modern probability theory, highlights the results related to the conditional
mathematical expectation, and then introduces discrete-time martingale theory,
including the martingale transform and the Snell envelope. We assume that the
reader has basic knowledge of measure theory.

1.1 Basic Concepts of Probability Theory

1.1.1 Events and Probability

Consider a trial or random experiment. Let  be the collection of all possible


outcomes of the trial, called sample space. If the number of outcomes of the trial is
finite or countable, we can use combinatorial mathematics to study issues related to
probability. However, if the number of outcomes of the trial is uncountably infinite,
we may not be able to consider a single outcome of the trial because the probability
of its appearance may be zero. Hence, we need to study issues related to probability
under the framework of measure theory.
In measure theory, we use  to represent a space, i.e., a predefined biggest set
for a study. Its elements are denoted by ω; ω ∈ A or ω ∈
/ A stands for the fact that ω
belongs to A or does not belong to A, respectively. The set which does not contain
any element is called an empty set and is denoted by ∅. We use A ⊃ B or B ⊂ A to

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. and Science Press 2018 1


J.-A. Yan, Introduction to Stochastic Finance, Universitext,
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-1657-9_1
2 1 Foundation of Probability Theory and Discrete-Time Martingales

express that B is a subset of A and use

A∩B, A∪B, A\B, A B

to express the intersection, union, difference, and symmetric difference of A and B,


respectively. That is:
A ∩ B = {ω : ω ∈ A and ω ∈ B}, A ∪ B = {ω : ω ∈ A or ω ∈ B},
A \ B = {ω : ω ∈ A and ω ∈
/ B}, A B = (A \ B) ∪ (B \ A).

Sometimes we also use AB to represent A ∩ B. We use Ac to express  \ A and


call Ac the complement of A (in ). Consequently, it holds that A \ B = A ∩ B c . If
A ∩ B = ∅, we say that A and B are disjoint. Clearly, A ∩ Ac= ∅, A ∪ A c = .

Let {Aλ , λ ∈ } be a family of subsets of . We use Aλ and Aλ to


λ∈ λ∈
express their union and intersection, respectively. Assume that {An , n1} (denoted
also as (An )) is a finite or countable sequence of subsets of
. If (An ) are mutually

disjoint (i.e., n = m ⇒ An ∩ Am = ∅), we usually use An to express An . If
 n n
An = , we say that {An , n1} is a partition of .
n
For any sequence (An ) of subsets, set
 ∞
∞  ∞ 
 ∞
lim sup An = Ak , lim inf An = Ak ,
n→∞ n→∞
n=1 k=n n=1 k=n

and call them the upper limit and lower limit of (An ). Obviously,
lim inf An ⊂ lim sup An .
n→∞ n→∞

If lim inf An = lim sup An , we say that the limit of (An ) exists, and we denote its
n→∞ n→∞
same upper and lower limit by lim An and call it the limit of (An ).
n→∞
A family of subsets of  is called a set class. A set class C is called an algebra,
if  ∈ C, ∅ ∈ C, and C is closed under finite intersection and complement (thereby,
C is closed under finite union and under difference). We call C a σ -algebra, if  ∈
C, ∅ ∈ C, and C are closed under countable intersection and complement (thereby,
C is closed under the countable union and the difference). The smallest σ -algebra
containing a set class C is called a σ -algebra generated by C, denoted by σ (C).
Let F be a σ -algebra on . We call ordered couple (, F) a measurable space,
and an element of F an F-measurable set. Let μ be a function defined on F with
values in R+ = [0, ∞]. If μ(∅) = 0 and μ is countably additive or σ -additive,
namely,
∀n1 , An ∈ F ; ∀n = m , An ∩ Am = ∅
∞ ∞
 
⇒μ An = μ(An ),
n=1 n=1
1.1 Basic Concepts of Probability Theory 3

then we call μ a measure on  (or (, F)). If μ() < ∞, we call μ a finite
measure. If there is a countable measurable division (Ai )i1 of , such that for any
Ai , μ(Ai ) < ∞, we call μ a σ -finite measure. If μ() = 1, we call μ a probability
measure and call the ordered triple (, F, μ) a probability space. Usually, we use
P to denote a probability measure.
Let (, F, P) be a probability space. If A ∈ F, and P(A) = 0, we call A a null
set. If all subsets of any P-null set belong to F, F is said to be complete w.r.t. P,
and we call (, F, P) a complete probability space.
Let (, F, P) be a probability space. Set

N = {N ⊂  : there exists A ∈ F, P(A) = 0, such that N ⊂ A},

F = {B ∪ N : B ∈ F, N ∈ N },

P(B ∪ N) = P(B), B ∈ F, N ∈ N .

Then (, F, P) is a complete probability space, which is the smallest complete


probability space containing (, F, P). We call (, F , P) the completion of
(, F, P) and call F the completion of F w.r.t. P.

1.1.2 Independence, 0-1 Law, and Borel-Cantelli Lemma

Let (, F, P) be a probability space. If A ∈ F, we call A an event. The sample


space  itself is called the inevitable event. An event A happens if the outcome ω
of the trial is an element of A. Let A and B be two events. If P(AB) = P(A)P(B),
events A and B are called independent. An event class (At , t ∈ T ) is called an
independent class, if for any finite subset S of T , we have

P As = P(As ).
s∈S s∈S

In this case we say that the events in this event class are mutually independent. This
mutual independence is much stronger than pairwise independence.
Two event classes A and B are called independent if any event A ∈ A and any
event B ∈ B are independent. More generally, let (Ct , t ∈ T ) be a family of event
classes. If for any event At from each event class Ct , event class (At , t ∈ T ) is an
independent event class, then we call this family an independent family and say that
the event classes in this family are mutually independent.
It is easy to prove the following result.
Extension theorem of independent class Let (Ct , t ∈ T ) be an independent class.
If each Ct is a π class (i.e., closed under intersection), then (σ (Ct ), t ∈ T ) is also an
independent class, where σ (Ct ) is the σ -algebra generated by event class Ct .
1.2 Conditional Mathematical Expectation 15

Theorem 1.7 (Monotone convergence theorem) Let (Xn ) be a sequence of ran-


dom variables whose conditional expectations w.r.t. G exist. If Xn ↑ X a.s. and
E[X1 − | G] < ∞ a.s., then the conditional expectation of X w.r.t. G exists and
E[Xn | G] ↑ E[X| G] a.s.
Theorem 1.8 (Fatou’s lemma) Let (Xn ) be a sequence of random variables
whose conditional expectations w.r.t. G exist.
(1) If there exists a random variable Y such that E[Y − | G] < ∞ a.s., and for each
n1, Xn Y a.s., then the conditional expectation of lim inf Xn w.r.t. G exists,
n→∞
and we have:

E[lim inf Xn | G] lim inf E[Xn | G];


n→∞ n→∞

(2) If there exists a random variable Y , such that E[Y + | G] < ∞ a.s., and for each
n1, Xn Y a.s., then the conditional expectation of lim sup Xn w.r.t. G exists,
n→∞
and we have

E[lim sup Xn | G] lim sup E[Xn | G].


n→∞ n→∞

a.s.
Theorem 1.9 (Dominated convergence theorem) Assume Xn −→ X (respec-
p
tively, Xn → X). If there exists a nonnegative random variable Y , such that |Xn |Y
a.s., then X is integrable, and we have lim E[Xn | G] = E[X| G] a.s. (respectively,
n→∞
p
E[Xn | G] −→ E[X| G]).

1.2.3 Two Theorems About Conditional Expectation

In this book we will often utilize the following two theorems about conditional
expectations.
Theorem 1.10 Let (, F, P) be a probability space, G be a sub-σ -algebra of F,
X be a Rm -valued G-measurable random variable, and Y be a Rn -valued random
variable. If Y and G are independent (i.e., σ (Y ) and G are independent), then for
any nonnegative Borel function g(x, y) on Rm × Rn , it holds

E[g(X, Y ) | G] = E[g(x, Y )]|x=X . (1.5)

Proof In order to prove (1.5), we need only to prove that for any nonnegative G-
measurable random variable Z,

E[g(X, Y )Z] = E[f (X)Z],


Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
*****

Päivällisen jälkeen loiottiin kalliolla ja luettiin Kiven Veljeksistä


parhaita paikkoja. Julistettiin tarinakilpailu, johon kaikki saisivat ottaa
osaa, ja yhdessä arvosteltaisiin tulokset.

Jallun tarina julistettiin voittaneeksi kilpailun ja tästä hyvästynyt


Jallu lupasi laittaa oikein suussa sulavan illallisen.

Illalla saivat Jaakko ja Mikko laskea pitkän siiman ja pohtia


uudelleen suunnitelmaansa kepposta.

— Mitäs, jos vene menisi niin kauaksi, etteivät sitä pojat tavoita ja
jäädään niin neuvoin kaikki saareen, sanoi Jaakko.

— No ei se mitään. Kylläpähän tulevat hakemaan, kun ei kotiin


kuulu ja ahvenia ongitaan muonaksi, sanoi Mikko.

— Niinpä sitten olkoon päätetty, julisti Jaakko. — Ennen uintia


jätetään venhe hyvin vähän kiinni kallion laitaan, ja toinen käy sitten
sopivassa tilaisuudessa irroittamassa sen ja antamassa sille
alkuvauhtia.

Yöksi rakensivat pojat kalliolle hongan pölkyistä nuotion, ja tyveniä


vesiä katsellen ja käen kukuntaa kuunnellen nukuttiin.

Aamupäivä meni pitkäsiimaa kokiessa, ja kun se antoi runsaan


saaliin, suoritettiin intiaanitanssi kalliolla kalastuksen kunniaksi.
Sopisi ylpeillä äideille ja siskoille hyvin onnistuneesta kalaretkestä.

Eilen toimittamatta jäänyt tervaaminen suoritettiin nyt hehkuvassa


auringon paahteessa, kun terva oli ensin padassa lämmitetty.
— Hii, miten se kutittaa ihoa, sanoi Mikko.

— Kas, miten hyvin se menee nahkaan, ihaili Jaakko ja Jallu.


Olisipa nyt kelvannut näyttää ihoaan kotijoukoille.

— Nyt on parasta hiukan liotella ihoaan, koskapa sitä niin hirveästi


kuumottaa, sanoi Jallu. — Murjaanit järveen!

Jaakon ja Mikon sydän takoi kiivaammin, mutta koetettiin olla


huolettoman näköisiä kaikesta. Tuuli oli hyvä ja mantereeseen päin
lähtisi vene viilettämään, ja kun se oli toisella puolella saarta, kuin
poikien majapaikka, eivät Lassi ja Jallu tietäisi mitään, ennenkuin
venhe olisi jo kaukana.

Kevyt venhe jo viiletti kaukana, kun Lassi sen huomasi.

— Voi turkkilainen, kun venhe on karannut! huudahti hän, — Kuka


peikkolainen sen kytki niin huonosti.

— No voi sun saksan sakilainen! kivahti Jallukin, ja pojat hokivat


sitä samaa kuin toisetkin.

— Lähtään uimaan ja otetaan se kiinni, sanoi Jallu ja alkoi jo


vedellä voimakkain ottein selälle.

— Ei sitä tavoita enää minkäänlainen uimari, julisti Lassi. — Nyt


on vain otettava selvää, kuka venheen on kytkenyt niin huonosti, että
se pääsi karkaamaan. Ja sen minä sanon, että sen ilkimyksen korvat
kuumenevat.

Tutkittiin asiata ja tulos oli Lassille masentava. Hän oli viimeksi


käynyt veneellä viemässä rantarisuun lisää männynhavuja.
— No koska minä olen joutunut syylliseksi, niin jokainen teistä saa
livauttaa minua korvalle, mutta tehkää se kepeällä kädellä, koskapa
teitä on niin kovin monta rankaisijaa.

— Täysi satsi Lassille, ei siinä auta puolustelu, huusi Jallu.

— Mikä mies se semmoinen on, joka pyrkii syntejään pakoon.


Korvat tänne!

— Ei muuta kuin pieni livaus vain, oli Mikon ja Jaakon


mielipiteenä. —
Onhan tässä otettava huomioon lieventävät asianhaarat.

Ja sen sijaan kuin Jallu antoi navakan tillikan Lassille, hipaisivat


toiset pojat Lassin korvalehteä hieman vain sormen päillään.

Lassilla oli kiivas luonto, jota hän ei osannut vielä kylliksi hillitä, ja
nyt se kuohahti siitä, että Jallu tahtoi kovempaa rangaistusta hänelle
kuin toiset.

— Sinä olet sakin jukuripää ja sinua on pehmitettävä, sanoi hän, ja


pian kieriskelivät pojat kalliolla ja kanervikossa ankarassa
sylirysyssä.

— Tämän piti nyt tulla meidän tähtemme, sanoi Jaakko.

— Ei se pahaa tee Jallulle pieni kuranssaus, sanoi Mikko. — Mitäs


ei tyytynyt toisten päätökseen.

Kun nujellus lakkasi, katseltiin mustelmia ja naarmuja, joita oli


saatu kanervikossa.

— Tunnustatko saaneesi hassausta ansiosta? kysyi Lassi Jallulta.


— Kyl-lä. Samallahan sitä sait sinäkin, mutta sinun kauemmin
tervassa ollut pintasi kesti risujen raapaisuja paremmin kuin minun,
sanoi Jallu.

— Mutta mitäs tästä. Pääasia on se, että nyt olemme kuin hiiret
loukussa. Sinne meni vielä meidän riitatoverien vaatteet. Kuka
käskikin meidän niitä venheeseen riisumaan. Se oli noloa, se…

— Nyt on jo vene rannalla, sanoi Jaakko, joka oli sen kulkua


seurannut.

— Ja pysyy siellä. Saamme odottaa, kunnes tulevat sydän


kurkussa meitä katselemaan, arveli Mikko.

— Katsotaanpa, mitä meille jäi, sanoi Lassi.

— Pata jäi ja onget, kahvipannu ja sokerit meni veneen mukana,


ilmoitti
Jaakko, joka oli jo tehnyt tutkimuksen.

— Jäiköhän lierotuohinen edes?

— On jäänyt varmasti. Pistin sen kallion koloon, sanoi Jallu. —


Mitäs muuta kuin onkimaan ja ahvenia pataan.

— Tulikin pahuuksenmoinen nälkä siinä tappeluksessa, sanoi


Lassi.

— Eihän vain liene siinä nujakassa aapeluksemme, Seitsemät


Veljekset, hävinnyt? kysyi Jallu.

— Minä nostin kirjan puuhun, sanoi Jaakko.


Päivä paistoi ja kallio poltteli jalkapohjia. Veneen menetys ei
surettanut liioin. Ainahan keinoja löytyi, kunhan vain aurinko paistoi
ja ruoka riitti. Ja sitä taas sai, kun vain heitti siiman kalliolta veteen.
Ahvenet hyppivät ihan maan ja veden rajassa.

*****

Jallu oli mennyt veljensä kanssa puita noutamaan nuotioon ja


Lassi kyykötti kallion reunalla odotellen ahventa onkeen. Jaakko oli
onkineen vähän matkan päässä. Hän nauroi.

— Mitä hörötät? kysyi Lassi.

— Sitä, kun sinulla ei ole vaatteita ja saat yöllä paahtaa itseäsi


kuin neekeri nuotiossa.

— Täälläpä ei ensi yötä ollakaan, sanoi Lassi.

— Mikäs auttaa?

— Sepähän nähdään.

Lassi oli löytänyt saaresta muutamia kuivia hirsiä, joista saisi


lautan, kun olisi millä se sitoa kokoon. Sitä hän nyt mietti siinä
seuratessaan kylläistä ahventa, joka repi syöttiä, mutta ei haukannut
sitä rohkeammin.

Olisipa vain köyttä, jolla solmiaisi puut yhteen ja sitten vielä purje.
Poikien paidoista ja housuista ei sitä taitaisi saada kokoon.

— Mustikoita, hei pojat! kuului toisten huuto metsästä.

Pojat jättivät onkensa ja juoksivat viidakkoon. Mustikat olivat


kesän ensimmäisiä heille ja halulla käytiin niihin käsiksi. Siinä
vierähtivät tunnit huomaamatta ja päivä alkoi olla illoillaan, kun pojat
palasivat kalliolle. Koetettiin onkia, mutta ahven ei syönyt enää.

— Oikeastaan me emme mitään päivällistä tarvitsekaan, kun


jokaisen maaru on mustikoita täysi, arveli Jallu.

— Mutta kotiin paluuta meidän olisi pohdittava ankarasti, sanoi


Lassi.
— Minulla olisi hyvä keino, mutta siinä on yksi niksi.

— Mikä, sanohan?

— Ei ole köyttä. Saaren rannalla on ainakin kahdeksan vankkaa


hirttä, ja niistä me voisimme laittaa lautan, kun olisi vain nuoraa.

— Sitä me saamme Koivunvesoista vaikka kuinka… voimme niillä


kyllä sitoa lautan kokoon, sanoi Mikko ja kimpaisi metsään vitsaksia
noutamaan.

— No nyt ei siis puutu muuta kuin kiireesti lautan tekoon, sanoi


Lassi. — Sattui vielä niin mainiosti, että puut ovat mantereen
puoleisella rannalla. Ei muuta kuin heti purjetta laskemaan.

Puut olivat raskaita ja vaivoin saatiin ne vieritetyksi veteen. Kun


lautta oli valmis, aleni jo aurinkokin kaukaisen rannan taakse ja tuuli
laimeni.

— Näyttää siltä, että yöksi tulee aivan tyyni, mutta voimmehan


soutaa lauttaa maihin, sanoi Jallu.

— Tahi odottaa aamua, jolloin tuuli kantaa meitä soutamattakin,


arveli
Lassi.
— Millä me soudamme, kun ei ole airoja. Ja sitäpaitsi me
palellumme lautalle, kun ei ole vaatteita, sanoi Jallu. Parasta, kun
viritämme nuotion ja odotamme aamua.

— Mutta minulla on niin turkkilaisen nälkä, eikä ole enää


leipääkään, sanoi Lassi. — Kyllä me lämmintä saamme, kun
melomme oikein vahvasti seipäillä.

Mikko oli taas kähminyt verkkomökille ja toi nyt sieltä vanhan


sarkapalton, joka kai oli Lassin ja Jaakon isältä joskus sinne jäänyt
kalamatkoilla oltaessa. Toinenkin, vielä kuluneempi vanha takki löytyi
ja Mikko palasi meluten saaliineen.

— Nyt ei ole enää muusta puutetta kuin tuulesta, riemuittiin.

Sitä odotellen tehtiin nuotio ja jokainen sai nyt koettaa parastaan


tärinäin kertomisessa, että aika paremmin kuluisi.

Lassi oli huomannut eteläisellä ilmanrannalla pilven kasvavan ja


piti sitä silmällä. Kohta alkoikin haapa kalliolla hiljaa humista ja
veden pintaan syntyi tummia juovia. Pilvikin etelän taivaalla kasvoi
kasvamistaan ja siellä välähti joskus salama.

— Tuliko lautta hyvin kiinni? kysyi Lassi pojilta.

— Tuli varmasti.

Pian alkoivat laineet lipattaa kallion laitaan ja pojat tunsivat


selvästi tuulen kiihtyvän.

Nyt lautta irti ja mars matkalle! komensi Lassi. — Tulee pian sade
ja silloin ei ole täällä kovinkaan hauskat olot.
Lautta kannatti hyvin. Melottiin tuulen avuksi sauvoimilla, ja lautta
eteni rannasta paremmin kuin olisi osattu odottaakaan.

— Tämäpä on suurenmoista! kehasivat pojat. Sarkaviitasta


laitettiin vielä purje, ja se lisäsi vauhtia. Jallu sai väliin lainata Lassille
takkiressuaan ja onneksi oli tuulikin lämmintä ja se kiihtyi joka hetki.
Laineet keinuttelivat jo lauttaa, niin että oli varottava siltä syvyyteen
suistumasta.

Ukkonenkin jyrähteli jo ja salamat valaisivat tummentuvaa


taivasta. Vakavina katselivat pojat mantereen rantaa ja vuoroin
taakseen, jossa taivas yhä synkkeni. Ulappa kuohui jo
valkopäälaineissa ja poikien täytyi laskeutua polvilleen lautalle
pysyäkseen sillä. Sitäpaitsi täytyi Lassin ja Jallun meloa voimiensa
takaa estääkseen kylmää, joka tahtoi väkisinkin puistatella ruumista.

Jyrisi yhä ankarammin, ja Mikko alkoi vetistellä, mutta ei sanonut


mitään. Häntä vaivasi se, että oli näin aiheuttanut Jaakon kanssa
heille kaikille yhteisen kärsimyksen. Olisi jo pitänyt tunnustaa, mutta
Mikko pelkäsi, että hänet heitettäisiin Jaakon kanssa uimaan.

Jaakko oli kovin kalpea. Hän ei miettinyt muuta, kuin että rannalle
päästyä on heti tunnustettava asia pojille, vaikkakin he kuinkakin
peittoaisivat. Ei mitenkään voisi jättää tunnustamatta. Ja nyt kun sen
tekisi, olisi kuranssauskin ehkä lievempi, kun pojat olivat väsyneitä.

Ranta oli enää vain noin puolen kilometrin päässä, kun jyrähti
entisiä ankarammin ja sadepilvi puhkesi. Vettä tuli, niin että romisi.

Pojat luulivat nyt jo voivansa loppumatkan uidakin hätätilassa ja se


antoi jälleen varmuuden tunnetta.
— Jopa nyt aivan kaatamalla sataa, sanoi Jallu ja vilu tärisytti
pojan leukoja.

— Antaa tulla vain!

— No kyllä minun puolesta vaikka seipäitä. Siinä tämä poika


kestää, missä toinenkin, kehaisi Jallu.

Lautta alkoi kolista rantakivillä ja odottamatta sen kokonaan


rannalle ajautumista pojat kahlasivat maalle. Ei siitä ollutkaan pitkä
matka veneelle, joka oli heiltä karannut. Se vedettiin kiireesti maalle
ja sitten hurjaa juoksua kotiin. Vaahtopäälaineissa ei viitsitty enää
lähteä venhettä, soutamaan.

Vasta puolitiessä kotimatkaa huomasivat pojat, että heidän


vaatteensa olivat unohtuneet venheeseen.

— Jääkööt!

Peräkkäin paineltiin rantaa pitkin ja pellon poikki oikaistiin suoraan


saunaan.

Se oli illalla lämminnyt ja kiuas pohisi vielä, kun sitä vesitti.

— Hei pojat! Nyt otetaan oikein mustalaisen löylyt sen retken


kunniaksi!

Jaakko ja Mikko tekivät tunnustusta. Kovin heitä vapisutti.

— Sitä jo ajattelinkin, sanoi Lassi. — Kylläpä siitä vielä nahkanne


kuumenee.

— Mutta rankaisu pitää toimittaa ihmisiksi, tokaisi Mikko. — Mitäs


kiusasitte minua saaressa.
Lassi mietti, että vähällä taitavat pojat siitä päästä, kun kerran
hyvin oli seikkailusta selvitty. Ja olihan ollut oikeastaan hauskakin se
lauttakyyti. Seikkailua!

Saunan ovi avattiin ja äidin pää pisti oviaukosta esiin.

— Ovatpahan toki vielä hengissä, sanoi hän. — Minä olen jo ollut


niin levoton teidän tähtenne. Tulkaa sitten lapsikullat syömään, kun
joudutte.

Lassin olisi tehnyt mieli selvittää matkansa seikkailu äidille, mutta


se jäi seuraavaan päivään. Nyt nautittiin löylystä, joka teki kovin
hyvää tervaiselle iholle.
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK POIKIEN KIRJA
***

Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.

Creating the works from print editions not protected by U.S.


copyright law means that no one owns a United States copyright in
these works, so the Foundation (and you!) can copy and distribute it
in the United States without permission and without paying copyright
royalties. Special rules, set forth in the General Terms of Use part of
this license, apply to copying and distributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works to protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG™ concept
and trademark. Project Gutenberg is a registered trademark, and
may not be used if you charge for an eBook, except by following the
terms of the trademark license, including paying royalties for use of
the Project Gutenberg trademark. If you do not charge anything for
copies of this eBook, complying with the trademark license is very
easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose such as
creation of derivative works, reports, performances and research.
Project Gutenberg eBooks may be modified and printed and given
away—you may do practically ANYTHING in the United States with
eBooks not protected by U.S. copyright law. Redistribution is subject
to the trademark license, especially commercial redistribution.

START: FULL LICENSE


THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE
PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK

To protect the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting the free


distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work (or
any other work associated in any way with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg”), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full
Project Gutenberg™ License available with this file or online at
www.gutenberg.org/license.

Section 1. General Terms of Use and


Redistributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works
1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg™
electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree
to and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property
(trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all
the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or
destroy all copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in your
possession. If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a
Project Gutenberg™ electronic work and you do not agree to be
bound by the terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from
the person or entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in
paragraph 1.E.8.

1.B. “Project Gutenberg” is a registered trademark. It may only be


used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people
who agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a
few things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg™ electronic
works even without complying with the full terms of this agreement.
See paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with
Project Gutenberg™ electronic works if you follow the terms of this
agreement and help preserve free future access to Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works. See paragraph 1.E below.
1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation (“the
Foundation” or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the
collection of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works. Nearly all the
individual works in the collection are in the public domain in the
United States. If an individual work is unprotected by copyright law in
the United States and you are located in the United States, we do
not claim a right to prevent you from copying, distributing,
performing, displaying or creating derivative works based on the
work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg are removed. Of
course, we hope that you will support the Project Gutenberg™
mission of promoting free access to electronic works by freely
sharing Project Gutenberg™ works in compliance with the terms of
this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg™ name
associated with the work. You can easily comply with the terms of
this agreement by keeping this work in the same format with its
attached full Project Gutenberg™ License when you share it without
charge with others.

1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the terms
of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.

1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg:

1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other


immediate access to, the full Project Gutenberg™ License must
appear prominently whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg™
work (any work on which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” appears, or
with which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” is associated) is
accessed, displayed, performed, viewed, copied or distributed:
This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United
States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with
almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away
or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License
included with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you
are not located in the United States, you will have to check the
laws of the country where you are located before using this
eBook.

1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is derived


from texts not protected by U.S. copyright law (does not contain a
notice indicating that it is posted with permission of the copyright
holder), the work can be copied and distributed to anyone in the
United States without paying any fees or charges. If you are
redistributing or providing access to a work with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg” associated with or appearing on the work, you must
comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1 through
1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the Project
Gutenberg™ trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is posted


with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution
must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any
additional terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms
will be linked to the Project Gutenberg™ License for all works posted
with the permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning of
this work.

1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project


Gutenberg™ License terms from this work, or any files containing a
part of this work or any other work associated with Project
Gutenberg™.

1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this


electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without
prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with
active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project
Gutenberg™ License.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense
to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means
of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original “Plain
Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must include the
full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.

1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying,


performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg™ works
unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing


access to or distributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works
provided that:

• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from
the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”

• You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who


notifies you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt that
s/he does not agree to the terms of the full Project Gutenberg™
License. You must require such a user to return or destroy all
copies of the works possessed in a physical medium and
discontinue all use of and all access to other copies of Project
Gutenberg™ works.

• You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of


any money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in
the electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90
days of receipt of the work.

• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.

1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg™


electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set
forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the manager of
the Project Gutenberg™ trademark. Contact the Foundation as set
forth in Section 3 below.

1.F.

1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend


considerable effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe
and proofread works not protected by U.S. copyright law in creating
the Project Gutenberg™ collection. Despite these efforts, Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works, and the medium on which they may
be stored, may contain “Defects,” such as, but not limited to,
incomplete, inaccurate or corrupt data, transcription errors, a
copyright or other intellectual property infringement, a defective or
damaged disk or other medium, a computer virus, or computer
codes that damage or cannot be read by your equipment.

1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except


for the “Right of Replacement or Refund” described in paragraph
1.F.3, the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner
of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark, and any other party
distributing a Project Gutenberg™ electronic work under this
agreement, disclaim all liability to you for damages, costs and
expenses, including legal fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO
REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT LIABILITY, BREACH OF
WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE
PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH 1.F.3. YOU AGREE THAT THE
FOUNDATION, THE TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY
DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE LIABLE
TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL,
PUNITIVE OR INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE
NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH DAMAGE.

1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you


discover a defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it,
you can receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by
sending a written explanation to the person you received the work
from. If you received the work on a physical medium, you must
return the medium with your written explanation. The person or entity
that provided you with the defective work may elect to provide a
replacement copy in lieu of a refund. If you received the work
electronically, the person or entity providing it to you may choose to
give you a second opportunity to receive the work electronically in
lieu of a refund. If the second copy is also defective, you may
demand a refund in writing without further opportunities to fix the
problem.

1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth in
paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.

1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied


warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages.
If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the
law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be
interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted
by the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any
provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions.

1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the


Foundation, the trademark owner, any agent or employee of the
Foundation, anyone providing copies of Project Gutenberg™
electronic works in accordance with this agreement, and any
volunteers associated with the production, promotion and distribution
of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works, harmless from all liability,
costs and expenses, including legal fees, that arise directly or
indirectly from any of the following which you do or cause to occur:
(a) distribution of this or any Project Gutenberg™ work, (b)
alteration, modification, or additions or deletions to any Project
Gutenberg™ work, and (c) any Defect you cause.

Section 2. Information about the Mission of


Project Gutenberg™
Project Gutenberg™ is synonymous with the free distribution of
electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of
computers including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers.
It exists because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and
donations from people in all walks of life.

Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the


assistance they need are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg™’s
goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg™ collection will
remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a
secure and permanent future for Project Gutenberg™ and future
generations. To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation and how your efforts and donations can help,
see Sections 3 and 4 and the Foundation information page at
www.gutenberg.org.
Section 3. Information about the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation
The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non-profit
501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the
state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal
Revenue Service. The Foundation’s EIN or federal tax identification
number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg
Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent
permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state’s laws.

The Foundation’s business office is located at 809 North 1500 West,


Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887. Email contact links and up
to date contact information can be found at the Foundation’s website
and official page at www.gutenberg.org/contact

Section 4. Information about Donations to


the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation
Project Gutenberg™ depends upon and cannot survive without
widespread public support and donations to carry out its mission of
increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can
be freely distributed in machine-readable form accessible by the
widest array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small
donations ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax
exempt status with the IRS.

The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating


charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United
States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a
considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and
keep up with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in
locations where we have not received written confirmation of

You might also like