Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 18

Regional Studies

ISSN: 0034-3404 (Print) 1360-0591 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cres20

Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters

Edward J. Malecki

To cite this article: Edward J. Malecki (2012) Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters, Regional
Studies, 46:8, 1023-1039, DOI: 10.1080/00343404.2011.607806
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2011.607806

Published online: 28 Oct 2011.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 3873

View related articles

Citing articles: 53 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=cres20
Regional Studies, Vol. 46.8, pp. 1023–1039, September 2012

Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters


EDWARD J. MALECKI
Department of Geography, The Ohio State University, 1036 Derby Hall, 154 North Oval Mall, Columbus, OH 43210-1361,
USA. Email: malecki.4@osu.edu

(Received November 2009: in revised form June 2011)

MALECKI E. J. Regional social capital: why it matters, Regional Studies. Social capital refers to a culture of interaction among people,
with productive economic outcomes. Social capital promotes regional learning both within a region and beyond, as it reinforces
openness to the ideas of others. Regional cultures vary in the degree to which people – individually and within their organizations
– trust and interact with one another, which is why regional outcomes vary. Innovation, learning and entrepreneurship – key pro-
cesses of regional development – take place largely within and among people as members of companies and territorial organiz-
ations. Innovative milieus, industrial districts and knowledge economies are among the regions with extraordinary pools of
social capital.

Social capital Learning region Innovation Learning

MALECKI E. J. 区域社会资本:有何相关性,区域研究。社会资本指一种人与人之间互动的文化,同时产生生产性经
济结果。由于强化了人与人之间理念的互通,社会资本能够促进区域内外的区域性学习。不同个体之间及其组织间
的信任与互动程度存在不同程度的差异, 这正是不同区域存在差异的原因。 作为区域发展中的核心过程,创新、学
习以及公司多出现在公司以及领域性组织成员内部及相互之间。创新、产业区以及知识经济往往存在于拥有突出社
会资本的区域。

社会资本 学习型区域 创新 学习

MALECKI E. J. L’importance du capital social régional, Regional Studies. Le capital social se rapporte à une culture d’interaction
humaine, dont les résultats économiques s’avèrent productifs. Le capital social promouvoit l’apprentissage régional à la fois au
sein de et au delà d’une région, car il renforce la notion d’ouverture pour ce qui est des idées d’autrui. Les cultures régionales
varient quant au point jusqu’auquel les individus – individuellement et dans leurs groupements – se font confiance et interagissent,
ce qui explique la variation des résultats. L’innovation, l’apprentissage et l’esprit d’entreprise – des étapes primordiaux de l’amén-
agement du territoire – ont lieu en grande partie au sein de et parmi les gens en tant que membres des entreprises et des organismes
territoriaux. Les milieux innovateurs, les districts industriels et les économies de la connaisance sont à trouver dans les régions où les
bassins de capital social sont extraordinaires.

Capital social Région d’apprentissage Innovation Apprentissage

MALECKI E. J. Regionales Sozialkapital: warum es wichtig ist, Regional Studies. Sozialkapital bezieht sich auf eine Kultur der Inter-
aktion zwischen Menschen mit produktiven wirtschaftlichen Ergebnissen. Sozialkapital fördert das regionale Lernen sowohl inner-
halb als auch außerhalb einer Region, da es eine Offenheit gegenüber den Ideen anderer verstärkt. In den regionalen Kulturen gibt
es Unterschiede hinsichtlich des Ausmaßes, in dem Menschen – einzeln und innerhalb ihrer Organisationen – einander vertrauen
und interagieren; hierin liegt der Grund, warum auch die regionalen Ergebnisse unterschiedlich ausfallen. Innovation, Lernen und
Unternehmertum – zentrale Prozesse der Regionalentwicklung – finden zum Großteil innerhalb und zwischen Menschen als Mit-
gliedern von Unternehmen und territorialen Organisationen statt. Zu den Regionen mit außergewöhnlichem Reichtum an
Sozialkapital gehören innovative Milieus, Industriebezirke und Wissenswirtschaften.

Sozialkapital Lernregion Innovation Lernen

MALECKI E. J. El capital social regional: por qué es importante, Regional Studies. El capital social se refiere a una cultura de inter-
acción entre las personas con resultados económicos productivos. El capital social fomenta el aprendizaje regional tanto dentro
como fuera de una región ya que refuerza la apertura a las ideas de otros. En las culturas regionales existen variaciones en la
medida en que las personas –individualmente y dentro de sus organizaciones– confían e interactúan entre ellas, motivo por el
cual varían los resultados regionales. La innovación, el aprendizaje y el interés empresarial –procesos clave del desarrollo regional–
tienen lugar en gran medida dentro y entre las personas como miembros de las empresas y organizaciones territoriales. Los medios
sociales innovadores, las comarcas industriales y las economías del conocimiento pertenecen a las regiones con fondos extraordi-
narios de capital social.

0034-3404 print/1360-0591 online/12/081023-17 © 2012 Regional Studies Association http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2011.607806


http://www.regionalstudies.org
1024 Edward J. Malecki

Capital social Región de aprendizaje Innovación Aprendizaje

JEL classifications: O1, O18, O31, R11

INTRODUCTION collective learning and innovation take place (FALK


and KILPATRICK , 2000; RUTTEN and BOEKEMA ,
In a knowledge-based world, knowledge transfer –
2007; WESTLUND , 2006). These are central processes
deliberate and unintended – is critical. In both formal-
in a global economy in which competition is largely
ized transfer and informal interactions, social links and
based on knowledge.
the norms and values associated with them play an
This paper begins by defining social capital, its forms
important role. ‘[G]ood social relations facilitate knowl-
and its measurement. Next, it outlines the development
edge transfers while absence of relations or bad relations
process as fundamentally about innovation and entre-
do not’ (WESTLUND , 2006, p. 91). Social capital has
preneurship. Within that process, social capital is
joined financial capital as a critical, ‘soft’ type of territor-
central to learning and knowledge creation. The
ial capital in regional development (CAMAGNI , 2008).
degree to which people interact and create knowledge
But there remain multiple understandings of what
collectively is central to the innovation process, particu-
social capital means, how it works and why it matters
larly within organizations. Power relationships, uneven-
(BHANDURI and YASUNOBU , 2009; WESTLUND and
ness and over-embeddedness of social capital can reduce
ADAM , 2010).
or limit the benefits of social capital. The paper then
COLEMAN (1988) popularized the concept of social
identifies innovative milieux as locales that are particu-
capital but also prompted much confusion.1 His defi-
larly rich in social capital. It concludes with some
nition – that social capital ‘is defined by its function’
thoughts about what is missing in research on social
and ‘inheres in the structure of relations between
capital. Future regional studies research in this arena
actors and among actors’ (p. S98) – has proven less
will be better informed by contextualizing social
than enlightening for many trying to apply it. Examples
capital and developing a more nuanced understanding
of social capital remain ‘easier to provide than one
of social capital as a process.
specific definition’ (SERAGELDIN and GROOTAERT ,
2000, p. 45).
As a metaphor, social capital is described as both a
SOCIAL CAPITAL2
glue and a lubricant. As a glue, it ‘facilitates transactions,
cooperation, and learning in an uncertain world’ The concept of social capital was first used by HANIFAN
(CAPPELLIN , 2004, p. 214; FOUNTAIN , 2001). It (1916), and it has become widespread since the 1980s
keeps cooperation together but also hinders social (FARR , 2004). It became a prominent topic in the litera-
change (PALDAM , 2000). ‘Lubricant’ is an alternative ture during the late 1980s, marked by two seminal
metaphor, implying that social capital helps to facilitate, papers by BOURDIEU (1986) and COLEMAN (1988).
or lubricate, exchanges within a group (ADAM et al., A sociological ‘invention’, social capital has remained
2005). Social capital may be ‘both glue and lubricant, of greater interest among sociologists than economists.
in that social structures are formed and bound by Sociologists tend to cite BOURDIEU (1986) as the
social capital yet social capital also facilitated the inter- seminal text. PUTNAM (1995, 2000) popularized the
actions and flows within the structure’ (ANDERSON concept for policy-makers.
and JACK , 2002, p. 206). The ‘glue’ is changeable or Applications of social capital are found throughout
organic, and can be adjusted and adapted depending the social sciences – in economic performance, health
upon circumstances. Thus, the ‘gluing’ is a continuing and well-being, crime, education, and government
process of becoming bonded, and the amount of ‘lubri- (HALPERN , 2005). The success of social capital as a
cant’ that social capital provides is dependent on the concept, according to DURLAUF and FAFCHAMPS
state of the ‘gluing’ process. More valuable than the (2005, p. 1642), may be because ‘no social science has
metaphor used, then, is the observation that ‘social managed to impose a definition of the term that captures
capital is not a “thing” but a process’ – a bridge-building what different researchers mean by it within a discipline,
process linking individuals, ‘creating a condition for the let alone across fields.’ For example,
effective exchange of information and resources’
all camps in the field of public health generally agree that
(ANDERSON and JACK , 2002, p. 207).
social capital ‘matters’ in some basic sense – unlike in say,
Social capital allows regions to begin a ‘dynamic the field of economic development, where selected critics
spiral of development’ (SWEENEY , 2001, p. 161). The paint it as a politically vapid distraction, and argue for its
web of social or network relations and the wider abandonment.
social context together shape the way in which (SZRETER and WOOLCOCK , 2004, p. 651)
Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters 1025
FISCHER (2005, p. 157) suggests that the term ‘social Social capital stands for the ability of actors to secure
capital’ is ‘unnecessary, because clearer and simpler benefits by virtue of membership in social networks or
terms – such as membership, family, sociability and other social structures.
trust – serve perfectly well.’ (PORTES , 1998, p. 6)
WESTLUND (2006) and CANNONE (2009) highlight
Social capital refers to the norms and networks that enable
the contrast between the two major proponents of the
people to act collectively.
term, Bourdieu and Coleman. Although both recognize (WOOLCOCK and NARAYAN , 2000, p. 226)
the centrality of networks and groups,
Bourdieu regards social capital as a resource that is procured Social capital is defined as social, non-formalized networks
via the links to the nodes (individual/group), whereas that are created, maintained and used by the networks’
Coleman’s standpoint is that social capital consists of the nodes/actors in order to distribute norms, values, preferences
links within and between networks/groups. and other attributes and characteristics, but which also
(WESTLUND , 2006, p. 1, emphasis in original) emerge as a result of actors sharing some of these attributes.
(WESTLUND , 2006, p. 8)
That is, to Coleman, social capital cannot be the private
property of any individual; to Bourdieu, social capital is Social capital can be envisaged as a revolving mutual fund
the sum of the resources that accrue to a group or indi- of traded and un-traded interdependencies.
vidual by virtue of possessing a durable network of insti- (ANDERSON et al., 2007, p. 265)
tutionalized relationships.3 These distinctions are
Social capital consists of social relations among agents com-
important because they focus attention on network bined with social institutions that allow for co-operation
links or relationships rather than on what is possessed and communication.
by an individual or organization. (LORENZEN , 2007, p. 801)
PUTNAM et al. (1993) explain stark differences in
development between northern and southern Italy as a Several observations emerge from these (and other) defi-
result of differences in social capital, as seen in civic nitions. First, social capital explicitly represents the
engagement. SABATINI (2008) attributes these persistent overlap between the social and economic spheres of
differences in the quality of economic development to human life. Consequently, attempts to construct econ-
an abundance of bonding social capital and low levels omic models of social capital (for example, DASGUPTA ,
of weak ties in the southern regions. NARDONE et al. 2003; GLAESER et al., 2002) are likely to miss important
(2010) document the considerable variation in types elements. ARROW (2000) notes that
and levels of social capital among communities within the essence of social networks is that they are built up for
southern Italy. PUTNAM (1995, 2000) describes the reasons other than their economic value to the participants.
decline of civic engagement in American society as … [A]ttempts to understand the microfoundations of
one of people ‘bowling alone’ rather than with others. social capital are probably doomed to fail.
This generalization must be tempered by the presence (p. 4)
of regional variations in social capital in the United GIACCARIA (2009) suggests that most attempts to
States (IYER et al., 2005; PUTNAM , 2000; RUPASINGHA understand the microfoundations resort to ‘magic’.
et al., 2006). An intriguing non-local dimension is seen Others focus on understanding the behaviour of
in lower levels of social capital in communities where groups rather than individuals (BOWLES and GINTIS ,
Wal-Mart stores are located, perhaps because these 2002). The incentives and motivations of public or
‘big box’ stores have lower need for local businesspeo- social entrepreneurs are not well understood
ple, such as bankers, lawyers and accountants (GOETZ (OSTROM , 2000), but BIRCH and WHITTAM (2008)
and RUPASINGHA , 2006). identify a number of objectives other than profit for
which social capital is an outcome.
Second, it is becoming clear that social capital is not
Definitions
the same when it is barely present and when it is found
With this background, here are a few of the many defi- in abundance. UPHOFF (2000) proposes a social capital
nitions of social capital. continuum, shown in Table 1, which explicitly recog-
nizes that the presence of social capital to different
Social capital cannot be acquired by individuals acting degrees sparks qualitatively different behaviours.
alone; it is created and transmitted through cultural
Third, although the importance of social capital for
mechanisms like tradition, religion, or historical habit,
which created shared ethical values and a common purpose. development and growth requires a focus on the group
(FUKUYAMA , 1995, pp. 26–27) rather than on the individual, it is unclear on which scale
or level of analysis we should focus. As shown in
Social capital is a self-organising system with many actors Table 2, the terminology as well as the conception of
connected in an amorphous web or network. social capital tends to change as the scale of analysis and
(WILSON , 1997, pp. 747–748) level of aggregation changes (see also TURNER , 2000).
1026 Edward J. Malecki
Table 1. The social capital continuum
Substantial social
Minimum social capital Elementary social capital capital Maximum social capital

Interests No interest in others’ welfare; Primarily interested in one’s own wel- Commitment to com- Commitment to others’ wel-
self-interest at others’ expense fare; cooperate only if it serves one’s mon enterprises fare; concern for the public
own advantage good
Values Self-aggrandizement Efficiency of cooperation Effectiveness Altruism regarded as good in
of cooperation itself
Issues Selfishness Reduction of transaction costs How to sustain collec- Self-sacrifice
tive action
Strategy Autonomy Tactical cooperation Strategic cooperation Merger of the submergence of
individual interests

Source: Based on UPHOFF (2000, pp. 224–225).

National scale studies have had a tremendous influence more substantial support necessary for enterprise
(KNACK and KEEFER , 1997), yet the community or advancement’ (TURNER , 2007, p. 415; see also
locality is more appropriate than the nation (WOOLCOCK , STORPER , 2005; KLOOSTERMAN , 2010). SVENDSEN
1998; SZRETER and WOOLCOCK , 2004). Perhaps the and SVENDSEN (2004) identify ‘the destruction of
even smaller ‘neighbourhood’ is most appropriate social capital’ as
(FORREST and KEARNS , 2001; MOULAERT and NUSS-
bridging social capital giving way to ‘bonding’ social
BAUMER , 2005; SCHUTJENS and VÖLKER , 2010).
capital … and ‘inward looking networks’. … [B]ridging
Overall, it seems that the intermediate, or meso-scale, of social capital enforces personal contact and acts as a ‘lubri-
analysis (such as firms and regions) is where the social cator’ for human co-operation, whereas bonding social
capital process affects development more directly. capital enforces distance between people and, conse-
quently, acts as a ‘super-glue’, increasing distrust and,
thus, transaction costs.
Types and forms of social capital (p. 2)
The variety of definitions and understandings of social
GROOTAERT and VAN BASTELAER (2002, p. 3)
capital has prompted the construction of typologies to
suggest that there are only two distinct types of social
delineate the distinct contexts of social capital. Among
capital: structural and cognitive. Structural social
the most widely adopted is the typology of WOOLCOCK
capital – seen in the social networks of actors – facilitates
(2004) to account for three types of relational assets that
information sharing, collective action, and decision-
people have access to in varying degrees:
making through established roles and social networks
. Bonding social capital: immediate family, friends, supplemented by precedents, rules and procedures. It
neighbours. is relatively objective and externally observable. Cogni-
. Bridging social capital: more distant colleagues and tive social capital refers to shared norms, values, atti-
associates. tudes, beliefs and trust. Like its components, it is
. Linking social capital: connections to people in pos- relatively subjective and intangible. Illustrating the lack
itions of authority. of consensus, LIAO and WELSCH (2005) add a third
type to these two: relational capital, which incorporates
The distinctions among the three types are highlighted
trust and trustfulness. These three types are used most in
in recent work. For example, the greatest constraint
business and management research, with emphasis on
on Indonesian entrepreneurs is a lack of linking social
structural social capital (LEE , 2009).
capital – that is, that able to penetrate the financial
Typologies avoid confronting the question: to what
system (TURNER , 2007). While bonding and bridging
extent is social capital ‘capital’? That is, how does it
social capital ‘support the day-to-day survival of an
accumulate? What are the rules of accumulation and
enterprise’, only linking social capital can provide ‘the
the rules of depreciation? Social capital is one of
Table 2. Social capital at different levels of aggregation several kinds of hybrid capital, which pose problems for
those who see them as identical – not merely analogous
Level Terms used for social capital – to financial capital, and reduced to a homogeneous
Nation National cultures value form (DEAN and KRETSCHMER , 2007). Its
Region Regional culture, regional mentality intangibility and irreproducibility provide a double
Local level (place) Local relations, spirit of place challenge for those who create policies to generate
Group Relations, norms, networks social capital (LUNDVALL et al., 2002). WESTLUND
Individual Behaviour, preferences, opinions, values,
attitudes
(2006) sees social capital as diversified and complex,
with resultant similarities and dissimilarities with other
Source: Adapted from WESTLUND (2006, fig. 3.1). forms of capital; he concludes that there is only a
Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters 1027
weak basis to call social capital a form of capital. GIAC- existing instruments to measure bridging social capital,
CARIA (2009), however, believes that social capital is and none (that we are aware of) that taps linking
capital in the Marxist sense of the term. social capital’ (KAWACHI et al., 2004, p. 688). Most
FISCHER (2005, p. 157), for whom social capital is a empirical work focuses on bonding social capital,
‘dreadful metaphor’, asks ‘Where can I borrow social perhaps not because it is the best proxy but because
capital? What is the going interest rate? Can I move measures of trust and of civic engagement are readily
some of my social capital off-shore?’ Yet, BOURDIEU available, and can be fine-tuned. For example, KNACK
(1986) focuses on the convertibility of social capital and KEEFER (1997) distinguish between ‘Olson-type’
into economic capital: groups, or rent-seeking organizations, and ‘Putnam-
type’ groups, which are not rent-seeking but involve
[T]here are some goods and services to which economic
social interaction that promotes trust and cooperation.
capital gives immediate access, without secondary costs;
others can be obtained only by virtue of a social capital of
‘Obtaining a single, true measure of social capital is
relationships (or social obligations) which cannot act instan- probably not possible’ (WOOLCOCK and NARAYAN ,
taneously, at the appropriate moment, unless they have 2000, p. 239). They suggest two principal reasons.
been established and maintained for a long time … i.e., at First, the most comprehensive definitions of social
the cost of an investment in sociability which is necessarily capital are multidimensional, incorporating different
long-term because the time lag is one of the factors of the levels and units of analysis. Second, the nature and
transmutation of a pure and simple debt into that recog- forms of social capital change over time, as the balance
nition of nonspecific indebtedness which is called gratitude. shifts between informal organizations and formal insti-
(p. 252) tutions. At The World Bank, which sees social capital
The greater problem of the use of metaphors to describe as the ‘missing link’ in sustainable development and
social capital is tendency to make the latter ‘magical’, part of the ‘intangible capital residual’ (WORLD BANK ,
ignoring ‘issues such as who has it, who instead has no 1997, 2006), economists recommend a shift toward
access to it, how it is reproduced and who takes advantage formal institutions (BEBBINGTON et al., 2004; STIGLITZ ,
of it’ (GIACCARIA , 2009, p. 76). Social capital also 2000).4 This is illustrated by BARTOLINI and BONATTI ’s
depreciates or decays if it is not renewed. ‘Social relation- (2008) model in which an economy tends to grow faster
ships die out if not maintained; expectations and obli- when it is relatively poorer in social capital, and more
gations wither over time; and norms depend on regular rapidly in the presence of formal institutions. Attention
communication’ (COLEMAN , 1990, p. 321). ROBISON only to formal institutions may be flawed where infor-
et al. (2002) say that decay occurs without maintenance mal institutions – such as the presence of corruption –
in the relationship; such ‘disinvestment’ in a relationship are more significant (FIDRMUC and GËRXHANI , 2008).
destroys social capital. For precisely this reason, social ANDERSON et al. (2007) suggest that the measure-
capital can disappear if it is not continually reinforced ment issue is related to the definition:
and built upon. A region rich in social capital today Unlike a normal ‘stock’ social capital is not owned but
might be social capital-poor tomorrow if it is not actively merely represents a pool of goodwill residing in a social
maintained. Attempts to measure social capital, therefore, network. … Thus, networks of connected individuals can
should recognize that it is a process, not easily measured, apply the social capital present in the network to unlock
rather than a thing which is measureable. or gain access to other resources. Seen this way social
capital is more akin to a key, rather than the resource itself.
Can social capital be measured? (p. 264)
Social capital is difficult to measure directly; for empiri- Accordingly, LANDRY et al. (2002) attempt to measure
cal purposes the use of proxy indicators is necessary. social capital through five forms of structural social
Years of education and work experience are common capital and one form of cognitive social capital (reciprocal
proxies for human capital. No such consensus exists trust). They find that firms’ decisions to innovate and to
for the study of social capital, and the search for the introduce radical innovations are more likely among
best proxy indicator continues (GROOTAERT and VAN firms whose social capital (in the form of participation
BASTELAER , 2002). Among the most common proxies assets and relational assets) is greater (see also
are responses to surveys, such as the General Social CARMONA -LAVADO et al., 2010; HAUSER et al., 2007).
Survey in the United States, Eurobarometer surveys, Among communities, SVENDSEN and SORENSEN
the European Values Survey, and the World Values (2007) show how social, organizational and cultural
Survey, concerning generalized trust (‘Most people capital – all forms of intangible capital – account for
can be trusted’ or ‘Most people are honest’), and mem- differences in community economic performance. The
bership in voluntary organizations (ranging from most explicit statement of this idea is that of social
churches to labour unions) and other questions (WES- capital as a regional resource – a dynamic, innovative
TLUND and ADAM , 2010). capability (PIHKALA et al., 2007). As a regional resource,
A degree of consensus has emerged around Wool- ‘social capital is not owned socially, it is simply (re)pro-
cock’s three forms of social capital, but ‘there are few duced socially’ (GIACCARIA , 2009, p. 75).
1028 Edward J. Malecki
Because social capital is difficult to see and measure, process of interaction’ (LUNDVALL and CHRISTENSEN ,
measures vary widely (WESTLUND and ADAM , 2010). 2004, p. 5, emphasis in original).
Some believe that qualitative techniques are necessary Firms invest in social links with suppliers, demanding
for measurement (ANDERSON et al., 2007; FALK and and collaborating customers, and research and develop-
KILPATRICK , 2000; STABER , 2007). In part because ment partners. To validate and critique the ‘proliferating
social capital ‘is not as easy to find, see, and measure as rivers of knowledge’ requires reliance on social capital,
is physical capital’, OSTROM (2000, p. 180) believes via formal or informal networks (SCHULLER , 2006).
that it ‘may be almost invisible’ unless researchers These network ties provide several benefits, such as
faster access to information and knowledge, lower infor-
inquire about the ways in which individuals organize
mation and knowledge costs, and increased quantity and
themselves and the rights and duties that guide their be-
havior – sometimes with little conscious thought. Even
quality of information and knowledge (WESTLUND and
when asked, local residents may not fully describe the NILSSON , 2005). These, in turn, result in faster inno-
rules they use. vation processes, a higher quality of innovations and
increased innovation potential (KOKA and PRESCOTT ,
Recent research has attempted to detect individual 2002). This is seen also at the regional level (FROMHOLD -
differences via factor analysis and has used cluster analysis EISEBITH , 2004).
to detect groups of people and types of social capital, Geography influences social capital in that
which are personal rather than organizational in origin
(KALLIO et al., 2010; PIHKALA et al., 2007). while not all types of social relations are subject to distance
costs, the interdependencies of different types of social
relations make dense combinations of them dependent
upon geographic proximity.
DEVELOPMENT AS INNOVATION AND (LORENZEN , 2007, p. 805)
ENTREPRENEURSHIP: THE ROLE OF The advantage of proximity – and of urban agglomera-
SOCIAL CAPITAL tion – is the potential for frequent as well as unplanned
The development process is fundamentally about inno- interactions (STORPER and VENABLES , 2004). At a col-
vation and entrepreneurship – that is, creating new lective level, all firms can potentially benefit from proxi-
products, new firms and new industries (CAPPELLIN , mity. However, firms and inter-firm relations vary
2003; MALECKI , 1997). Innovation – change rather considerably, and this results means that agglomeration
than stability – is increasingly necessary in a knowledge and clustering do not guarantee interaction (OINAS ,
economy, and ‘only the territorial production systems 2002); nor do they guarantee that learning can occur.
which are able to learn how to adapt continuously to Learning is an interactive, socially embedded, and localized
the new conditions imposed by globalisation will process, and therefore requires an analytical framework
remain competitive’ (MAILLAT , 2001, p. 137). In broader than that offered by economics alone
this sense, regional social capital is what transforms (LUNDVALL et al., 2002). LORENZEN (2007) cites the
technology into regional economic development ‘shared social codebooks’ in a place that provide ‘cogni-
through regional innovation networks (RUTTEN and tive co-ordination’ which in turn facilitates learning.
BOEKEMA , 2007). However, because of both uncertainty Knowledge and learning embedded in social capital are
and inability to control networks, top-down planning is largely localized and do not ‘travel’ well because they
not effective (GUTH , 2005). At the regional scale, it is are bound historically to local circumstances, involving
even more unlikely that knowledge and innovation unique bonds and accumulated routines:
capabilities can be created by decree, since few, if any, The formal and informal networks between people in a
regions have sufficient top-down power. common location, which have often been developed
The primary relevance of social capital to the process through long-term interaction, and the resulting evolution
of economic growth derives from its presence in interac- of local institutions form part of the social capital surround-
tive learning (FALK and KILPATRICK , 2000; LUNDVALL ing innovation processes.
et al., 2002). Social capital, along with interaction, net- (MALMBERG et al., 1996, p. 92)
working, cooperation and spatial proximity, are
‘elements of collective learning processes promoting Localized learning has become a focal issue for
the innovativeness and competitiveness of firms, research, because whether – and where – it takes place
regions, and nations’ (ASHEIM et al., 2007, p. 657). Inno- opens opportunities for dealing with change, inno-
vative learning is about finding, assembling and absorbing vation, and disruptive innovation. An important comp-
relevant knowledge from many sources to create new lement to the focus on localized learning is what might
combinations. Innovation ‘is a process where the be called dispersed learning (AMIN and COHENDET ,
outcome is highly dependent upon interaction and com- 1999). Small and medium-size enterprises (SMEs), as
munication between people’ in which actors operate ‘in they internationalize, gradually extend the geographical
a context where the resources they need to mobilize scope, from a local or regional to an international level,
are shared with others and actually change in the very of those relationships of trust and collaboration that
Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters 1029
were originally common only within their local clusters functions within and among organizations and groups
(CAPPELLIN , 2004). – at the meso-scale (FALK and KILPATRICK , 2000;
As firms stretch their boundaries to include a wider SEPPÄNEN et al., 2007). Trustful relations tend to be
array of sources of knowledge, this must include both self-reinforcing and thereby strengthen cooperation.
sources in close proximity, or local sources, and those Mistrust, on the other hand, tends to cycle in a negative
located anywhere else – that is, non-local sources direction, which weakens relationships and cooperation
(OINAS and LAGENDIJK , 2005; WOOLCOCK , 1998). (FOUNTAIN , 2001). Research inspired by PUTNAM
Areas and their populations must be receptive to new (1995, 2000) and KNACK and KEEFER (1997) has
ideas from new sources. Horizontal networks within focused on macro-scale and society-wide conditions,
the community need to be complemented by vertical using survey data on trust and cultural characteristics.
networks (or pipelines) to other places (FLORA and However, it is difficult to translate or generalize across
FLORA , 1993). This necessity of both local ‘buzz’ and spatial scales, because trust is context dependent and
‘pipelines’ to global knowledge has been emphasized sector dependent and, most importantly, an economic
recently by BATHELT et al. (2004) and ASHEIM et al. benefit is more likely to arise from social capital in econ-
(2007). Access to technology and knowledge embedded omic and business networks rather than social networks
in other milieux is particularly difficult to obtain (WESTLUND and ADAM , 2010).
(MALMBERG et al., 1996); to do so it is critical to Business reliability, or competence trust, concerns tech-
‘anchor’ projects, that is, to create a milieu that is both nical and managerial competence to carry out a task,
locally autonomous as a dynamic knowledge-rich such as accepting goods from a supplier without inspect-
locale and capable of existing within a network of ing them (SAKO , 1992). Competence trust exceeds
distant interactions, ‘on the map’ in certain specific contractual trust, the mutual expectation that promises
areas (CREVOISIER and JEANNERAT , 2009). In some made are kept, which is the trust typically described
fields, venture capitalists provide international social by economists. Indeed, trustworthiness is considered a
capital to complement the local social capital of innova- source of competitive advantage (BARNEY and
tive regions (MÄKELÄ and MAULA , 2008). HANSEN , 1994) and contributing to social capital
The economic focus on formal institutions and on (BOWEY and EASTON , 2007).
minimizing transaction costs tends to detract from atten- A third, higher-level trust, goodwill trust, refers to
tion to learning and innovation and to relational capital mutual expectations of open commitment, seen in a will-
(LUNDVALL , 2006; SAKO , 1998). Relational capital ingness to do more than is formally expected, such as
sharing of non-routine information (GELSING , 1992;
is defined as all relationships – market relationships, power
SAKO , 1992). Higher-level types of trust are the basis of
relationships and cooperation – established between firms,
institutions and people, which stem from a strong sense of
Uphoff’s substantial and maximum social capital (Table
belonging and a highly developed capacity of cooperation 1). Note that such trust is not the civic engagement
typical of culturally similar people and institutions. trust of Putnam, nor the general trust found in popu-
(CAPELLO and FAGGIAN , 2005, p. 77; CAMAGNI , 2008) lations, but a relation-specific trust found in contexts of col-
lective innovative learning. Like social capital, such trust
It has similarities to the substantial social capital found in is more a property of collective units and relationships
Table 1 (UPHOFF , 2000). than of isolated individuals (BLOMQVIST , 1997). Collab-
Social capital, however, does not develop automati- oration for learning and innovation are facilitated by a
cally from interactions. Instead, it takes time for trust richer set of relationships, which enhance the volume,
and credibility to form (MAC KINNON et al., 2004). diversity and richness of information exchanged (KOKA
MASKELL (2000) suggests the benefits of investment in and PRESCOTT , 2002). Continuous interaction
the time-consuming process of social capital accumu- between firms offers the opportunity for innovation as
lation. Partners save search costs by staying in contact well as the existence of a known and predictable environ-
with one another and, through repetitive knowledge ment in which innovation can be realised (EASTON ,
exchanges, they benefit from lower costs and increased 1992). The relation-specific skills between firms formed
quality of the knowledge transmitted. The relation- through this process are a form of social capital in
specific sunk costs support a continuous stream of which both parties invest and from which both benefit
innovation. (PATCHELL and HAYTER , 1995). For example, innova-
tive firms tend to make greater use of collaboration and
information exchange, be involved in higher trust
Trust as a meso-scale concept
relationships, and make greater use of non-local net-
Trust is central to the concept of social capital (DAS- works (COOKE et al., 2005). The problem lies in how
GUPTA , 2000; GLAESER et al., 2002; OSTROM and such trust between actors in the business and economic
AHN , 2003; PALDAM , 2000). A large literature has sphere is related to generalized trust within larger popu-
grown around the concept of trust (see the reviews by lations (WESTLUND and ADAM , 2010).
MURPHY , 2006; and RING , 1997).5 Trust is not only The concept of relational capital would seem to focus
an individual or micro-scale phenomenon, but also it attention at the micro scale – that is, on people, rather
1030 Edward J. Malecki
than on groups or organizations, including firms. Territories as well as firms, then, have absorptive
However, because people and interpersonal interaction capacity. GIULIANI (2002) describes cluster absorptive
are the basic building blocks of networks, different and capacity as a function of three components: the knowl-
possibly conflicting goals arise in an individual’s knowl- edge bases of firms, the intra-cluster knowledge system
edge networks: personal interests, project goals and the and the extra-cluster knowledge system. While a few
firm’s aims (GRABHER and IBERT , 2006). From the per- firms may be isolated from the networks in the cluster,
spective of two companies attempting to learn from each most firms play one of three roles: absorbers of knowl-
other within a strategic alliance, KALE et al. (2000) suggest edge, mutual exchangers, or technological gatekeepers,
a typical conclusion: the trust and respect necessary for transferring knowledge from external sources to local
learning to take place emerge from relations among the firms (GIULIANI and BELL , 2005; MORRISON , 2008;
individuals in the firms. This suggests, in turn, that it is WINK , 2008). Gatekeepers or brokers, filling structural
a significant challenge for companies to learn deeply holes in a social network, provide links to new ideas
from external sources. After acquiring knowledge, it is and encourage creativity (BURT , 2000, 2004). Gate-
absorbed through the complex and time-consuming keepers act as the ‘network go-between’ who ‘primes’
spiral of knowledge acquisition proposed by NONAKA the relationship between newly introduced actors by
and TAKEUCHI (1995).
setting expectations for trust and reciprocity and by equip-
Trust emerges at the meso-scale through face-to-face
ping it with resources that are ‘rolled over’ from the go-
encounters and on the basis of group memberships or between’s existing embedded tie to one of the new
other characteristics associated with trustworthy individ- network partners.
uals (such as race, religion or social class) (MURPHY , (UZZI , 1996, p. 694)
2006). Moreover, building trust requires time, effort
and the right spaces for interaction (LAZARIC et al., Among the important gatekeepers who bridge a struc-
2008). This is a large challenge when trying to create, tural hole between two unconnected people are social
from the top down, relationships within which learning entrepreneurs or community entrepreneurs (BIRCH
and innovation can take place, such as global teams and and WHITTAM , 2008; JOHANNISSON and NILSSON ,
strategic alliances. 1989). Within a community or locality, people vary
greatly in their skills and personalities – independent of
the organizations in which they work – and these indi-
Absorptive capacity vidual variations in turn give rise to three forms of
As the highest-level capability, learning allows a firm to social capital: organizational bonding social capital,
adapt to changed circumstances in its competitive regional bridging social capital and personal creative
environment. Learning has attained new significance social capital. Organizational bonding social capital is
through the concept of absorptive capacity: the firm’s beneficial in the assimilation and transformation of
ability to evaluate potential knowledge, assimilate it, knowledge. Regional bridging social capital helps in
and apply it (COHEN and LEVINTHAL , 1990). Learning the acquisition of diverse knowledge. Personal creative
is specific to each firm–firm dyad and the relationship social capital describes the personal will to take risks
between their knowledge-processing systems (LANE and continue positively after mistakes. Of the various
and LUBATKIN , 1998). As the relationship grows, and types of social capital, PIHKALA et al. (2007) suggest that
absorptive capacity increases, absorption mechanisms creative social capital is most needed in regional develop-
become more diverse. Firms with high absorptive ment. All types are needed to generate a regional absorp-
capacity extend learning to all kinds of knowledge and tive capacity (KALLIO et al., 2010).
many sources, but especially personal contacts, which CAPELLO (1999, p. 357) notes that the internal
enhance the exchange of tacit knowledge capacity of each firm to exploit collective learning is
(MANGEMATIN and NESTA , 1999). RUSH et al. (2007) one of the preconditions for collective learning to take
have devised an operational measure of absorptive place in a milieu; the second is the strategy of each
capacity, resulting in four types of firms: unaware, firm, which depends on the nature of the innovation
reactive, strategic, and creative. and the size of the firm. Not only knowledge, but also
Rather than micro- (individual) or macro- the scope of competition must be global (MOROSINI ,
(national or societal) scale, social capital is primarily 2004). Global competition and awareness, combined
a meso-scale process, centred in communities and with strong local knowledge integration, together
organizations and comprised of intermediaries, stimulate higher economic performance of industrial
knowledge brokers and institutions (FALK and KILPA- clusters (GIULIANI , 2002).
TRICK , 2000; GUTH , 2005; MURPHY , 2006). At this WESTLUND (2006) compares biotechnology firms in
level, non-proprietary and intangible assets are shared Sweden, Japan and California. He finds that the stron-
among a group of firms. Through knowledge extern- gest social capital of Japanese firms is internal to the
alities and untraded interdependencies, these higher- firms – to a large degree, an intentional product of
order capabilities become sticky, enhancing absorptive efforts to build ‘knowledge-creating companies’
capacity (FOSS , 1996). (NONAKA and TAKEUCHI , 1995; NONAKA and
Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters 1031
TOYAMA , 2005). In California and Sweden, by contrast, formation and success of SMEs is well established
firms use the region as a spatial counterpart to Japanese (JOHANNISSON , 2000; MALECKI and TOOTLE , 1996).
firms’ corporate internalization. Only in California, At a regional, collective level, the characteristic of asso-
however, did interactions within the regional environ- ciationalism captures the fact that networking is
ment include both high enterprise-internal social common between and among institutions as well as
capital as well as diversified networks, perhaps drawing firms and individuals (ANDERSON and JACK , 2002;
upon Silicon Valley’s ‘peculiar’ social capital (COHEN COOKE and MORGAN , 1998). Social capital and asso-
and FIELDS , 1999). GREUNZ (2005) draws a similar con- ciationalism do not emerge by themselves everywhere.
clusion within Europe: social capital appears to be at Instead, an animateur or a community entrepreneur is
work in the successful regions, with private–private needed to catalyse local capabilities (MORGAN , 1997).
and private–public cooperation. Particularly useful research in this regard is the work
of the Lahti Unit in Finland, which has aimed to
measure regional capabilities for a visionary new
Social capital within organizations
regional development (HARMAAKORPI and UOTILA ,
Social capital is not only a territorial process and attri- 2006; KALLIO et al., 2010; PIHKALA et al., 2007;
bute; it also is ‘created’ within firms, both large corpor- TURA and HARMAAKORPI , 2005). This work corre-
ations and SMEs. Firms are another meso-scale entity sponds generally to the steps recommended by
between individuals and nations. Companies devote COOKE (2003) for regional technology foresight and
considerable effort to optimizing interactions and trust the creation of a regional innovation and learning
among workers at dispersed locations and, perhaps a system (RILS); see also BENNEWORTH (2007).
more difficult challenge, between workers in different PIHKALA et al. (2007), for example, who find that
companies in alliances. In effect, within organizations, several types of social capital characterize the perceptions
social capital can be interpreted in the context of cor- of regional development in the region, and that ‘creative
porate culture (CHUNG and GIBBONS , 1997). Thus, social capital’ is most related to visionary thinking.
social capital, like trustworthiness, can be seen as a stra- Indeed, social capital is a capability-like resource rather
tegic resource – not uniformly available, mobile, or than an asset, such as physical capital (KALLIO et al.,
easily traded or imitated (OLIVER , 1996). 2010). The combination of various types of social
Just as collective knowledge in a firm is greater than capital, cemented by leadership, is perhaps most com-
the sum of the individual knowledge possessed by the monly noted in rural regions (FLORA and FLORA ,
firm’s employees (NAHAPIET and GHOSHAL , 1998), 1993; HORLINGS , 2010).
social capital benefits the firm collectively more than it
does individual employees (LEANA and VAN BUREN ,
1999). Through its employment practices, especially
stable employment relationships and investment in SOME LIMITATIONS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL
training and learning, firms can manage organizational The importance of social bonds, in comparison with
social capital. As a result, social capital is exchanged their absence, appears at first glance without question.
and combined to create new knowledge, or intellectual However, the benefits from social capital are likely to
capital, from which the firm as well as the individual be unequally distributed and even exclusionary
benefits. In this view, the co-evolution of social and (FAFCHAMPS , 2006). More generally, focus on the
intellectual capital underpins organizational advantage benefits of social capital ignores the unequal power
(NAHAPIET and GHOSHAL , 1998). held by the actors in a network (GRABHER , 2006).
SMEs ‘cannot function’ without social capital Power may result more from weak ties than from
(COOKE , 2007). COOKE et al. (2005) show that social strong ties (GRANOVETTER , 1973). Issues such as who
capital within and among small firms affects their per- has social capital and who does not – central to BOUR-
formance, even if effects of regional social capital are dif- DIEU (1986) – greatly affect the process and the outcome
ficult to discern. Because of its benefits, the ‘use of social of community planning and governance (GIACCARIA ,
capital by SMEs is, effectively, ubiquitous … a kind of 2009; TAYLOR , 2000). Strong ties can
entry-ticket to doing business’ (COOKE , 2007, p. 173).
In other words, SMEs rely on cooperation as a learning separate excluded people further from the society around
process, and their networks reinforce one another, them. … The tragedy for today’s excluded communities
building the absorptive capacity of firms (BOUGRAIN is that they neither have the strong ties of the past nor
the weaker ties that are an essential ‘currency’ in today’s
and HAUDEVILLE , 2002).
society.
These findings reinforce the long-standing empirical (TAYLOR , 2000, p. 1027)
observation: that social networks evolve into business-
focused networks, whereby firm formation takes Too much bonding social capital becomes negative,
place, and then into strategic networks, which allow creating conformity rather than variety, and restricting
firms to innovate and to thrive by their links to other both business initiative and individual freedom.
organizations. The importance of networks to the Notably, social capital may restrict entrepreneurial
1032 Edward J. Malecki
initiative: ‘entrepreneurship-inhibiting social capital’ is labour market, the presence of cultural and organiz-
distinct from ‘entrepreneurship-facilitating social ational proximity, the presence of strong and stable
capital’ (WESTLUND and BOLTON , 2003). Innovation innovative synergies among local actors and labour
is stifled in some companies and places with ‘high’ force, and exploitation of collective learning
social capital, because they are less open to newcomers (CAMAGNI , 1991, CAPELLO , 1999). These conditions
and especially to innovative collaborations (FLORIDA are not found everywhere, and may be called knowledge
et al., 2002). Bonding social capital is potentially unhelp- economies (COOKE , 2002; CREVOISIER , 2004). Most
ful, leading to exclusion of outsiders, excess claims on importantly, today’s ‘combinatorial knowledge
group members, restrictions on individual freedoms, dynamics’ develop and operate across multiple
and lowering norms (PORTES , 1998). locations and across scales in ways that require various
Social capital also can be a liability if too dependent types of links (CREVOISIER and JEANNERAT , 2009;
on a core network player or if over-embeddedness MALECKI , 2011).
characterizes the network (UZZI , 1997). TURA and In short, an innovative milieu reinforces and extends
HARMAAKORPI (2005) identify two ‘lock-ins’ of the benefits from social capital for actors within the
social capital: the closure of the network and collective milieu. FROMHOLD -EISEBITH (2004) finds that the
blindness. The first is a particularly negative feature in a innovative (or creative) milieu is more useful for effect-
knowledge economy, where ideas from outside the firm ing change, whereas social capital is more about stable
or the region are essential. Collective blindness is diffi- and stabilizing relationships. Thus, milieu relationships
cult to combat without the infusion of new knowledge and social capital relationships fulfil different tasks. The
flows from new sources. That is, the shared values and milieu mainly enables the move from invention to inno-
common purpose of a group can reinforce existing vation, from idea to commercialization, and from
activities and close it off from new ideas. business plan to new enterprise. Social capital helps
Entrepreneurs’ network ties tend to be homo- companies to obtain other kinds of support and to
geneous rather than diverse, and to favour local over master management challenges, to become and stay
distant ties. This means that entrepreneurs face limited profitable (FROMHOLD -EISEBITH , 2005; PARTANEN
access to new resources and knowledge. The benefits et al., 2008). ‘Through the combinations of economic
of social capital are seen in entrepreneurs who are able and social relationships in the network, the information
to develop broader, more diverse networks. Weak, becomes rich, redundant and cheap’ (HERTZ ,
distant ties provide access to new information or 1992, p. 110).
resources (KIM and ALDRICH , 2005). For example, In innovative milieux and industrial districts, econ-
access to resources, such as financing, connections, tech- omic space becomes a ‘relational space’, a field of inter-
nology, market information and gossip, may provide the actions, synergies and collective social actions that
incentive for having relationships (BOWEY and stimulate innovative capability and local economic
EASTON , 2007). Thus, investment by SMEs in social development (CAMAGNI , 1991). Trust and the embedd-
capital ‘may be purely manipulative’ (COOKE , 2007). edness of economic relationships into the ‘deeper social
If decisions are made purely for emotional or familial fabric’ or the communal, noneconomic institutions of
reasons, businesses can fail (SPENCE et al., 2003). the local area distinguish industrial districts from other
localized agglomerations of firms (HARRISON , 1992).
Three paradigms are at work in an innovative milieu
(CREVOISIER , 2004). First, the technological paradigm
THE INNOVATIVE MILIEU: OPTIMAL
stresses innovation, learning and know-how as the
SOCIAL CAPITAL
most important competitive advantages. Second, the
Perhaps the ideal examples of localized learning systems organizational paradigm emphasizes the role of net-
are innovative milieux and industrial districts. In these works, competition, and rules of cooperation, as well
places, associationalism is high, involving knowledge as relational capital. Third, the territorial paradigm
sharing among firms, among institutions, and between accounts for the role of proximity and distance and stres-
institutions and firms (CAPELLO , 1999; COOKE and ses the fact that competition occurs between regions.
MORGAN , 1998; HARRISON , 1992; INKPEN and ‘Relational capital’ rather than social capital is the pre-
TSANG , 2005; POMA and SACCEHETTI , 2004). In ferred term in research on industrial districts
short, each such milieu has a unique, optimum combi- (CAMAGNI , 2008; CAPELLO and FAGGIAN , 2005;
nation of the various component parts or types of MOLINA -MORALES and MARTINEZ -FERNANDEZ ,
social capital.6 A firm in such a locale can become 2006). The ‘industrial district stands out in every
endowed with high-order capabilities, which are at respect as a highly integrated texture encompassing all
the meso-level, neither within the firm alone nor network strands; it appears to be a self-organizing
generally available at the national or macro level arena for entrepreneurship’ (JOHANNISSON et al.,
(FOSS , 1996). 1994, p. 351). Others similarly identify a ‘district
An innovative milieu is characterized by several fea- effect’ – the benefit from location within an industrial
tures: stable inter-SME linkages and a stable local district (BECCHETTI et al., 2007).7
Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters 1033
The additive beneficial effect of the milieu consists of network specific, it also connects with institutions and
the complex combination of bonding and bridging networks elsewhere.
social capital which take on different meanings across Methodologically, new methods are required that
scales (WESTLUND et al., 2010). It is the optimal combi- take account of the processes of social capital – when,
nation of local and non-local links and, more specifi- why and how social capital is built and exchanged.
cally, links to key innovative centres elsewhere, that ‘Ordinary’ business purposes are certainly different
provide an innovative milieu with its competitiveness from the pursuit of innovation, for which fewer, more
(CREVOISIER and JEANNERAT , 2009). knowledgeable partners are needed (GIULIANI , 2007).
To distinguish these situations, richer and more detailed
research – mainly qualitative in nature – is needed
(ANDERSON et al., 2007; STABER , 2007). This may
CONCLUSIONS
tend to ensure that social capital is likely to remain
The paper ends by emphasizing a few key points. First, within the domain of regional studies, as opposed to
social capital is a concept that embodies how people regional science (MC CANN , 2007). Regional research
function productively with other people, primarily and other interdisciplinary fields need more concepts
locally but also at a distance. Non-local ties are at least such as social capital to bridge and link, rather than to
as important as local ones. Second, social capital is part bond, the like-minded more strongly.
of a region’s ‘collective personality’, out of which inno-
vation takes place (WESTLUND and BOLTON , 2003).
Third, social capital is central to the development of Acknowledgments – Earlier versions of this paper were
presented at the ‘The Learning Region Comes of Age?’
regions; while hard to identify and challenging to
seminar held at Tilburg University, Tilburg, the Netherlands,
measure, its effects are visible in many ways. Across- in June 2007; and at the North American Meetings of the
the-board policies will not work, since both public Regional Science Association, Savannah, GA, USA, in
intervention and public–private cooperation are November 2007. Thanks are extended to Frans Boekema
needed to stimulate network formation through the and Roel Rutten for prompting the author to undertake
building up of social capital in each region (ASHEIM , this research. The author is grateful for the comments of
2007). ‘Local circumstances are the only meaningful James Baginski, Roberta Capello and two anonymous
point of departure’ (MORGAN , 2004, p. 18). Social reviewers. However, all remaining errors are the author’s
capital and networks open to new members and new alone.
ideas are necessary for entrepreneurial social infrastructure,
which converts social capital into organizational forms
that facilitate collective action (FLORA , 1998; FLORA NOTES
and FLORA , 1993). These are similar to four meta-pro-
cesses that CAMAGNI (1995) suggests must take place in 1. Following COLEMAN (1988), KEELEY (2007, pp. 105–
less-favoured regions: the involvement of local 106) maintains that human capital and social capital ‘are
resources, the creation of synergies among local actors inextricably linked … social capital promotes the develop-
and factors, a link-up with external energies, and a con- ment of human capital and human capital promotes the
tinued process of innovation. development of social capital, although the mechanics of
The research reviewed here reinforces the idea that the process are complex.’ In chicken-and-egg fashion,
social capital can be created and that it matters for devel- social capital forms human capital through improved edu-
cation and health; human capital forms social capital as
opment. LORENZEN (2007, p. 813) recommends
education boosts civic and social engagement.
‘inspiring and forcing regions with a low stock of 2. It is not claimed that this is a comprehensive review. There
social capital to invest in it.’ Social capital appears to is no way to review the entire field on social capital, a
facilitate the visionary capability of a group and its phrase found in 4637 articles in March 2011, according
ability for collective learning (HARMAAKORPI and to ISI’s Social Science Citation Index (SSCI). To this
UOTILA , 2006). As a regional personality trait, number must be added hundreds of books and chapters
however, it is difficult if not impossible to imitate one not searchable in the SSCI. The website Social Capital
region’s social capital process in other places. Social Gateway (SABATINI , 2011) is a useful resource.
capital is a unique, locally specific process. 3. HOLT (2008) extends Bourdieu’s individual focus to
Perhaps most ignored in discussions of innovative embodied and internalized social capital, and the various
milieux and social capital, in their focus on the local starting points of individuals depending on their gender,
race, sexuality and disability. Similarly, WARR (2006)
or regional level, is attention to the global level. It is
suggests that building social capital in circumstances of dis-
understood that the global economy is global, but that advantage is a particular challenge and must be a socially
does not always translate into how to bring the global transformative ‘art’. MILES and TULLY (2007) see a role
sphere into the local region in a real manner, employing for regional development agencies in the distressed com-
both local buzz and global pipelines (HASSINK , 2007). munities in which many such individuals live.
Future research on social capital should acknowledge 4. In general, although The World Bank lent a great deal of
that although it tends to be locally, industry and visibility to the concept of social capital, its predominant
1034 Edward J. Malecki
focus is on minimal social capital, in UPHOFF ’s (2000) 6. The author thanks an anonymous reviewer for suggesting
typology, emphasizing social capital that can be replaced this interpretation.
by institutions. For critiques of The World Bank’s role, 7. ‘Relational capital’ rather than social capital is the preferred
see FINE (1999, 2007). term in research on industrial districts (CAMAGNI , 2008;
5. The literatures on trust and social capital appear to have CAPELLO and FAGGIAN , 2005; MOLINA -MORALES and
developed largely independently; few works on one MARTINEZ -FERNANDEZ , 2006).
topic cite work on the other.

REFERENCES
ADAM F., MAKAROVIÈ M., RONÈEVIÆ B. and TOMŠIÈ M. (2005) The Challenges of Sustained Development: The Role of Socio-Cultural
Factors in East–Central Europe. Central European University Press, Budapest.
AMIN A. and COHENDET P. (1999) Learning and adaptation in decentralised business networks, Environment and Planning D: Society
and Space 17, 87–104.
ANDERSON A. R. and JACK S. L. (2002) The articulation of social capital in entrepreneurial networks: a glue or a lubricant?, Entre-
preneurship and Regional Development 14, 193–210.
ANDERSON A., PARK J. and JACK S. (2007) Entrepreneurial social capital: conceptualizing social capital in new high-tech firms, Inter-
national Small Business Journal 25, 245–272.
ARROW K. J. (2000) Observations on social capital, in DASGUPTA P. and SERAGELDIN I. (Eds) Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective,
pp. 3–5. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
ASHEIM B. T. (2007) The learning firm in the learning region: innovating through cooperation and social capital building, in
LANDABASO M., KUKLINSKI A. and ROMÁN C. (Eds) Europe – Reflections on Social Capital, Innovation and Regional Development,
pp. 193–202. Wyz˙sza Szkoła Biznesu National-Louis University, Nowy Scz.
ASHEIM B., COENEN L. and VANG J. (2007) Face-to-face, buzz, and knowledge bases: sociospatial implications for learning, inno-
vation, and innovation policy, Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 25, 655–670.
BARNEY J. B. and HANSEN M. H. (1994) Trustworthiness as a source of competitive advantage, Strategic Management Journal 15
[Special Issue], 175–190.
BARTOLINI S. and BONATTI L. (2008) Endogenous growth, decline in social capital and expansion of market activities, Journal of
Economic Behavior and Organization 67, 917–926.
BATHELT H., MALMBERG A. and MASKELL P. (2004) Clusters and knowledge: local buzz, global pipelines and the process of knowl-
edge creation, Progress in Human Geography 28, 31–56.
BEBBINGTON A., GUGGENHEIM S., OLSON E. and WOOLCOCK M. (2004) Exploring social capital debates at The World Bank, Journal
of Development Studies 40, 33–64.
BECCHETTI L., DE PANIZZA A. and OROPALLO F. (2007) Role of industrial district externalities in export and value-added perform-
ance: evidence from the population of Italian firms, Regional Studies 41, 601–621.
BENNEWORTH P. (2007) Leading Innovation: Building Effective Regional Coalitions for Innovation. National Endowment for Science,
Technology and the Arts (NESTA), London.
BHANDURI H. and YASUNOBU K. (2009) What is social capital? A comprehensive review of the concept, Asian Journal of Social Science
37, 480–510.
BIRCH K. and WHITTAM G. (2008) The third sector and the regional development of social capital, Regional Studies 42, 437–450.
BLOMQVIST K. (1997) The many faces of trust, Scandinavian Journal of Management 13, 271–286.
BOUGRAIN F. and HAUDEVILLE B. (2002) Innovation, collaboration and SMEs internal research capacities, Research Policy 31,
735–747.
BOURDIEU P. (1986) The forms of capital, in RICHARDSON J. G. (Ed.) Handbook of Theory and Research for the Sociology of Education,
pp. 241–258. Greenwood, New York, NY.
BOWEY J. L. and EASTON G. (2007) Entrepreneurial social capital unplugged: an activity-based analysis, International Small Business
Journal 25, 273–306.
BOWLES S. and GINTIS H. (2002) Social capital and community governance, Economic Journal 112(November), F419–F436.
BURT R. S. (2000) The network structure of social capital, in SUTTON R. and STAW B. (Eds) Research in Organizational Behavior,
Vol. 22, pp. 345–423. Elsevier, Amsterdam.
BURT R. S. (2004) Structural holes and good ideas, American Journal of Sociology 110, 349–399.
CAMAGNI R. (1991) Local ‘milieu’, uncertainty and innovation networks: towards a new dynamic theory of economic space, in
CAMAGNI R. (Ed.) Innovation Networks: Spatial Perspectives, pp. 121–144. Belhaven, London.
CAMAGNI R. P. (1995) The concept of innovative milieu and its relevance for public policies in European lagging regions, Papers in
Regional Science 74, 317–340.
CAMAGNI R. (2008) Regional competitiveness: towards a concept of territorial capital, in CAPELLO R., CAMAGNI R., CHIZZOLINI B.
and FRATESI U. (Eds) Modelling Regional Scenarios for the Enlarged Europe: European Competitiveness and Global Strategies, pp. 33–47.
Springer, Berlin.
CANNONE M. (2009) Searching for social capital, in HÄKLI J. and MINCA C. (Eds) Social Capital and Urban Networks of Trust, pp. 37–
65. Ashgate, Aldershot.
CAPELLO R. (1999) Spatial transfer of knowledge in high technology milieux: learning versus collective learning processes, Regional
Studies 33, 353–365.
Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters 1035
CAPELLO R. and FAGGIAN A. (2005) Collective learning and relational capital in local innovation processes, Regional Studies 39,
75–87.
CAPPELLIN R. (2003) Territorial knowledge management: toward a metrics of the cognitive dimension of agglomeration econom-
ies, International Journal of Technology Management 26, 303–325.
CAPPELLIN R. (2004) International knowledge and innovation networks for European integration, cohesion, and enlargement,
International Social Science Journal 56, 207–225.
CARMONA-LAVADO A., CUEVAS-RODRIGUEZ G. and CABELLO-MEDINA C. (2010) Social and organizational capital: building the
context for innovation, Industrial Marketing Management 39, 681–690.
CHUNG L. H. and GIBBONS P. T. (1997) Corporate entrepreneurship: the roles of ideology and social capital, Group and Organization
Management 22, 10–30.
COHEN S. S. and FIELDS G. (1999) Social capital and capital gains in Silicon Valley, California Management Review 41(2), 108–130.
COHEN W. M. and LEVINTHAL D. A. (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation, Administrative
Science Quarterly 35, 128–152.
COLEMAN J. (1988) Social capital in the creation of human capital, American Journal of Sociology 94, S95–S120; repr. in DASGUPTA
P. and SERAGELDIN I. (Eds) (2000) Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective, pp. 13–39. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
COLEMAN J. S. (1990) Foundations of Social Theory. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
COOKE P. (2002) Knowledge Economies: Clusters, Learning and Cooperative Advantage. Routledge, London.
COOKE P. (2003) Economic globalisation and its future challenges for regional development, International Journal of Technology Man-
agement 26, 401–420.
COOKE P. (2007) Social capital, embeddedness, and regional innovation, in LANDABASO M., KUKLINSKI A. and ROMÁN C. (Eds)
Europe – Reflections on Social Capital, Innovation and Regional Development, pp. 162–175. Wyz˙sza Szkoła Biznesu National-
Louis University, Nowy Scz.
COOKE P., CLIFTON N. and OLEAGA M. (2005) Social capital, firm embeddedness and regional development, Regional Studies 39,
1065–1077.
COOKE P. and MORGAN K. (1998) The Associational Economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
CREVOISIER O. (2004) The innovative milieus approach: toward a territorialized understanding of the economy?, Economic Geogra-
phy 80, 367–379.
CREVOISIER O. and JEANNERAT H. (2009) Territorial knowledge dynamics: from the proximity paradigm to multi-location milieus,
European Planning Studies 17, 1223–1241.
DASGUPTA P. (2000) Economic progress and the idea of social capital, in DASGUPTA P. and SERAGELDIN I. (Eds) Social Capital:
A Multifaceted Perspective, pp. 325–424. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
DASGUPTA P. (2003) Economics of social capital, Economic Record 81(Suppl.), S2–S21.
DEAN A. and KRETSCHMER M. (2007) Can ideas be capital? Factors of production in the postindustrial economy: a review and
critique, Academy of Management Review 32, 573–594.
DURLAUF S. N. and FAFCHAMPS M. (2005) Social capital, in AGHION P. and DURLAUF S. N. (Eds) Handbook of Economic Growth,
Vol. 1B, pp. 1639–1699. Elsevier, Amsterdam.
EASTON G. (1992) Industrial networks: a review, in AXELSSON B. and EASTON G. (Eds) Industrial Networks: A New View of Reality,
pp. 3–27. Routledge, London.
FAFCHAMPS M. (2006) Development and social capital, Journal of Development Studies 42, 1180–1198.
FALK I. and KILPATRICK S. (2000) What is social capital? A study of interaction in a rural community, Sociologia Ruralis 40, 87–110.
FARR J. (2004) Social capital: a conceptual history, Political Theory 32, 6–33.
FIDRMUC J. and GËRXHANI K. (2008) Mind the gap! Social capital, East and West, Journal of Comparative Economics 36, 264–286.
FINE B. (1999) The developmental state is dead – long live social capital?, Development and Change 30, 1–19.
FINE B. (2007) Eleven hypotheses on the conceptual history of social capital: a response to James Farr, Political Theory 35, 47–53.
FISCHER C. S. (2005) Bowling alone: what’s the score?, Social Networks 27, 155–167.
FLORA C. B. and FLORA J. L. (1993) Entrepreneurial social infrastructure: a necessary ingredient, Annals of the American Academy of
Political and Social Science 529, 48–58.
FLORA J. L. (1998) Social capital and communities of place, Rural Sociology 63, 481–506.
FLORIDA R., CUSHING R. and GATES G. (2002) When social capital stifles innovation, Harvard Business Review 80(8), 20.
FORREST R. and KEARNS A. (2001) Social cohesion, social capital and the neighbourhood, Urban Studies 38, 2125–2143.
FOSS N. J. (1996) Higher-order industrial capabilities and competitive advantage, Journal of Industry Studies 3(1), 1–20.
FOUNTAIN J. E. (2001) Building the Virtual State: Information Technology and Institutional Change. Brookings Institution Press,
Washington, DC.
FROMHOLD-EISEBITH M. (2004) Innovative milieu and social capital – complementary or redundant concepts of collaboration-
based regional development?, European Planning Studies 12, 747–765.
FROMHOLD-EISEBITH M. (2005) Concepts of regional collaboration as points of entry into regional institutional analyses, in LE
HERON R. and HARRINGTON J. W. (Eds) New Economic Spaces: New Economic Geographies, pp. 165–176. Ashgate, Aldershot.
FUKUYAMA F. (1995) Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. Free Press, New York, NY.
GELSING L. (1992) Innovation and the development of industrial networks, in LUNDVALL B.-A. (Ed.) National Systems of Innovation,
pp. 116–128. Pinter, London.
GIACCARIA P. (2009) The ‘magic and loss’ of social capital and local development, in HÄKLI J. and MINCA C. (Eds) Social Capital and
Urban Networks of Trust, pp. 67–90. Ashgate, Aldershot.
1036 Edward J. Malecki
GIULIANI E. (2002) Cluster absorptive capacity: why do some clusters forge ahead and others lag behind?, European Urban and
Regional Studies 12, 269–288.
GIULIANI E. (2007) The selective nature of knowledge networks in clusters: evidence from the wine industry, Journal of Economic
Geography 7, 139–168.
GIULIANI E. and BELL M. (2005) The micro-determinants of meso-level learning and innovation: evidence from a Chilean wine
cluster, Research Policy 34, 47–68.
GLAESER E. L., LAIBSON D. and SACERDOTE B. (2002) An economic approach to social capital, Economic Journal 112(November),
F437–F458.
GOETZ S. J. and RUPASINGHA A. (2006) Wal-Mart and social capital, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 88, 1304–1310.
GRABHER G. (2006) Trading routes, bypasses, and risky intersections: mapping the travels of ‘networks’ between economic soci-
ology and economic geography, Progress in Human Geography 30, 163–189.
GRABHER G. and IBERT O. (2006) Bad company? The ambiguity of personal knowledge networks, Journal of Economic Geography 6,
251–271.
GRANOVETTER M. (1973) The strength of weak ties, American Journal of Sociology 78, 1360–1380.
GREUNZ L. (2005) Intra- and inter-regional knowledge spillovers: evidence from European regions, European Planning Studies 13,
449–473.
GROOTAERT C. and VAN BASTELAER T. (2002) Introduction and overview, in GROOTAERT C. and VAN BASTELAER T. (Eds) The Role
of Social Capital in Development: An Empirical Assessment, pp. 1–10. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
GUTH M. (2005) Innovation, social inclusion and coherent regional development: a new diamond for a socially inclusive inno-
vation policy in regions, European Planning Studies 13, 333–348.
HALPERN D. (2005) Social Capital. Polity, Cambridge.
HANIFAN L. J. (1916) The rural school community center, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 67, 130–138.
HARMAAKORPI V. and UOTILA T. (2006) Building regional visionary capability. Futures research in resource-based regional devel-
opment, Technological Forecasting and Social Change 73, 778–792.
HARRISON B. (1992) Industrial districts: old wine in new bottles?, Regional Studies 26, 469–483.
HASSINK R. (2007) The learning region: a constructive critique, in RUTTEN R. and BOEKEMA F. (Eds) The Learning Region: Foun-
dations, State of the Art, Future, pp. 252–271. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
HAUSER C., TAPPEINER G. and WALDE J. (2007) The learning region: the impact of social capital and weak ties on innovation,
Regional Studies 41, 75–88.
HERTZ S. (1992) Towards more integrated industrial systems, in AXELSSON B. and EASTON G. (Eds) Industrial Networks: A New View
of Reality, pp. 105–128. Routledge, London.
HOLT L. (2008) Embodied social capital and geographic perspectives: performing the habitus, Progress in Human Geography 32,
227–246.
HORLINGS I. (2010) How to generate sustainable European rural regions: the role of social capital, leadership and policy arrange-
ments, Regions 280, 8–12.
INKPEN A. C. and TSANG E. W. K. (2005) Social capital, networks, and knowledge transfer, Academy of Management Review 30,
146–165.
IYER S., KITSON M. and TOH B. (2005) Social capital, economic growth and regional development, Regional Studies 39, 1015–1040.
JOHANNISSON B. (2000) Networking and entrepreneurial growth, in SEXTON D. L. and LANDSTRÖM H. (Eds) The Blackwell Handbook
of Entrepreneurship, pp. 368–386. Blackwell, Oxford.
JOHANNISSON B., ALEXANDERSON O., NOWICKI K. and SENNESETH K. (1994) Beyond anarchy and organization: entrepreneurs in
contextual networks, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 6, 329–356.
JOHANNISSON B. and NILSSON A. (1989) Community entrepreneurs: networking for local development, Entrepreneurship and
Regional Development 1, 3–19.
KALE P., SINGH H. and PERLMUTTER H. (2000) Learning and protection assets in strategic alliances: relational capital, Strategic Man-
agement Journal 21, 217–237.
KALLIO A., HARMAAKORPI V. and PIHKALA T. (2010) Absorptive capacity and social capital in regional innovation systems: the case
of the Lahti region in Finland, Urban Studies 47, 303–319.
KAWACHI I., KIM D., COUTTS A. and SUBRAMANIAN S. V. (2004) Health by association? Social capital, social theory, and the political
economy of public health – Commentary: Reconciling the three accounts of social capital, International Journal of Epidemiology
33, 682–690.
KEELEY B. (2007) Human Capital: How What You Know Shapes Your Life. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Develop-
ment (OECD), Paris.
KIM P. H. and ALDRICH H. E. (2005) Social capital and entrepreneurship, Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship 1(2), 55–104.
KLOOSTERMAN R. C. (2010) Matching opportunities with resources: a framework for analysing (migrant) entrepreneurship from a
mixed embeddedness perspective, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 22, 25–45.
KNACK S. and KEEFER P. (1997) Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation, Quarterly Journal of
Economics 112, 1251–1288.
KOKA B. R. and PRESCOTT J. E. (2002) Strategic alliances as social capital: a multidimensional view, Strategic Management Journal 23,
795–816.
LANDRY R., AMARA N. and LAMARI M. (2002) Does social capital determine innovation? To what extent?, Technological Forecasting
and Social Change 69, 681–701.
Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters 1037
LANE P. J. and LUBATKIN M. (1998) Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning, Strategic Management Journal 19,
461–477.
LAZARIC N., LONGHI C. and THOMAS C. (2008) Gatekeepers of knowledge versus platforms of knowledge: from potential to rea-
lized absorptive capacity, Regional Studies 42, 837–852.
LEANA C. R. and VAN BUREN H. J. (1999) Organizational social capital and employment practices, Academy of Management Review
24, 538–555.
LEE R. (2009) Social capital and business and management: setting a research agenda, International Journal of Management Reviews 11,
247–273.
LIAO J. and WELSCH H. (2005) Roles of social capital in venture creation: key dimensions and research implications, Journal of Small
Business Management 43, 345–362.
LORENZEN M. (2007) Social capital and localised learning: proximity and place in technological and institutional dynamics, Urban
Studies 44, 799–817.
LUNDVALL B.-Å. (2006) Interactive learning, social capital, and economic performance, in KAHIN B. and FORAY D. (Eds) Advancing
Knowledge and the Knowledge Economy, pp. 63–74. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
LUNDVALL B.-Å. and CHRISTENSEN J. L. (2004) Introduction: Product innovation – on why and how it matters for firms and the
economy, in CHRISTENSEN J. L. and LUNDVALL B.-Å. (Eds) Product Innovation, Interactive Learning and Economic Performance, pp. 1–
18. Elsevier, Amsterdam.
LUNDVALL B.-Å., JOHNSON B., ANDERSEN E. S. and DALUM B. (2002) National systems of production, innovation and competence
building, Research Policy 31, 213–231.
MACKINNON D., CHAPMAN K. and CUMBERS A. (2004) Networking, trust and embeddedness amongst SMEs in the Aberdeen oil
complex, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 16, 87–106.
MAILLAT D. (2001) Territory and innovation: the role of the milieu, in SWEENEY G. (Ed.) Innovation, Economic Progress and the
Quality of Life, pp. 137–143. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
MÄKELÄ M. M. and MAULA M. V. J. (2008) Attracting cross-border venture capital: the role of a local investor, Entrepreneurship and
Regional Development 20, 237–257.
MALECKI E. J. (1997) Technology and Economic Development, 2nd edn. Addison Wesley Longman, London.
MALECKI E. J. (2011) Connecting local entrepreneurial ecosystems to global innovation networks: open innovation, double net-
works and knowledge integration, International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Innovation Management 14, 36–59.
MALECKI E. J. and TOOTLE D. M. (1996) The role of networks in small firm competitiveness, International Journal of Technology Man-
agement 11, 43–57.
MALMBERG A., SÖLVELL Ö. and ZANDER I. (1996) Spatial clustering, local accumulation of knowledge and firm competitiveness,
Geografiska Annaler, Series B: Human Geography, 78B, pp. 85–97.
MANGEMATIN V. and NESTA L. (1999) What kind of knowledge can a firm absorb?, International Journal of Technology Management 18,
149–172.
MASKELL P. (2000) Social capital, innovation, and competitiveness, in BARON S., FIELD J. and SCHULLER T. (Eds) Social Capital:
Critical Perspectives, pp. 111–123. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
MCCANN P. (2007) Observational equivalence? Regional studies and regional science, Regional Studies 41, 1209–1221.
MILES N. and TULLY J. (2007) Regional development agency policy to tackle economic exclusion? The role of social capital in
distressed communities, Regional Studies 41, 855–866.
MOLINA-MORALES F. X. and MARTINEZ-FERNANDEZ M. T. (2006) Industrial districts: something more than a neighbourhood,
Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 18, 503–524.
MORGAN K. (1997) The learning region: institutions, innovation and regional renewal, Regional Studies 31, 491–503.
MORGAN K. (2004) The exaggerated death of geography: learning, proximity and territorial innovation systems, Journal of Economic
Geography 4, 3–21.
MOROSINI P. (2004) Industrial clusters, knowledge integration and performance, World Development 32, 305–326.
MORRISON A. (2008) Gatekeepers of knowledge within industrial districts: who they are, how they interact, Regional Studies 42,
817–835.
MOULAERT F. and NUSSBAUMER J. (2005) Defining the social economy and its governance at the neighbourhood level: a meth-
odological reflection, Urban Studies 42, 2071–2088.
MURPHY J. T. (2006) Building trust in economic space, Progress in Human Geography 30, 427–450.
NAHAPIET J. and GHOSHAL S. (1998) Social capital, intellectual capital, and the organizational advantage, Academy of Management
Review 23, 242–266.
NARDONE G., SISTO R. and LOPOLITO A. (2010) Social capital in the LEADER Initiative: a methodological approach, Journal of
Rural Studies 26, 63–72.
NONAKA I. and TAKEUCHI H. (1995) The Knowledge-Creating Company: How Japanese Companies Create the Dynamics of Innovation.
Oxford University Press, Oxford.
NONAKA I. and TOYAMA R. (2005) The theory of the knowledge-creating firm: subjectivity, objectivity and synthesis, Industrial and
Corporate Change 14, 419–436.
OINAS P. (2002) Competition and collaboration in interconnected places: towards a research agenda, Geografiska Annaler: Series B:
Human Geography 84B, 65–76.
OINAS P. and LAGENDIJK A. (2005) Towards understanding proximity, distance and diversity in economic interaction and local
development, in LAGENDIJK A. and OINAS P. (Eds) Proximity, Distance and Diversity, pp. 307–331. Ashgate, Aldershot.
1038 Edward J. Malecki
OLIVER C. (1996) The institutional embeddedness of economic activity, in BAUM J. A. C. and DUTTON J. E. (Eds) Advances in Stra-
tegic Management, Vol. 13, pp. 163–186. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT.
OSTROM E. (2000) Social capital: a fad or a fundamental concept?, in DASGUPTA P. and SERAGELDIN I. (Eds) Social Capital: A Multi-
faceted Perspective, pp. 172–214. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
OSTROM E. and AHN T. K. (2003) Introduction, in OSTROM E. and AHN T. K. (Eds) Foundations of Social Capital, pp. xi–xxxix.
Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
PALDAM M. (2000) Social capital: one or many? Definition and measurement, Journal of Economic Surveys 14, 629–653.
PARTANEN J., MÖLLER K., WESTERLUND M., RAJALA R. and RAJALA A. (2008) Social capital in the growth of science-and-
technology-based SMEs, Industrial Marketing Management 37, 513–522.
PATCHELL J. and HAYTER R. (1995) Skill formation and Japanese production systems, Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie
86, 339–356.
PIHKALA T., HARMAAKORPI V. and PEKKARINEN S. (2007) The role of dynamic capabilities and social capital in breaking socio-
institutional inertia in regional development, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 31, 836–852.
POMA L. and SACCHETTI S. (2004) Knowledge life cycles inside local economic systems, in COOKE P. and PICCALUGA A. (Eds)
Regional Economies as Knowledge Laboratories, pp. 93–116. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
PORTES A. (1998) Social capital: its origins and applications in modern sociology, Annual Review of Sociology 24, 1–24.
PUTNAM R. D. (1995) Bowling alone: America’s declining social capital, Journal of Democracy 6(1), 65–78.
PUTNAM R. D. (2000) Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Survival of American Community. Simon & Schuster, New York, NY.
PUTNAM R. D., LEONARDI R. and NANETTI R. Y. (1993) Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton
University Press, Princeton, NJ.
RING P. S. (1997) Processes facilitating reliance on trust in inter-organizational networks, in EBERS M. (Ed.) The Formation of Inter-
Organizational Links, pp. 113–145. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
ROBISON L. J., SCHMID A. A. and SILES M. E. (2002) Is social capital really capital?, Review of Social Economy 60, 1–21.
RUPASINGHA A., GOETZ S. J. and FRESHWATER D. (2006) The production of social capital in US counties, Journal of Socio-Economics
35, 83–101.
RUSH H., BESSANT J. and HOBDAY M. (2007) Assessing the technological capabilities of firms: developing a policy tool, R&D Man-
agement 37, 221–236.
RUTTEN R. and BOEKEMA F. (2007) Regional social capital: embeddedness, innovation networks and regional economic develop-
ment, Technological Forecasting and Social Change 74, 1834–1846.
SABATINI F. (2008) Social capital and the quality of economic development, Kyklos 61, 466–499.
SABATINI F. (2011) Social Capital Gateway (available at: http://www.socialcapitalgateway.org/).
SAKO M. (1992) Prices, Quality, and Trust: Inter-firm Relations in Britain and Japan. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
SAKO M. (1998) Does trust improve business performance?, in LANE C. and BACHMANN R. (Eds) Trust Within and Between Organ-
izations, pp. 88–117. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
SCHULLER T. (2006) Social capital, networks, and communities of knowledge, in KAHIN B. and FORAY D. (Eds) Advancing Knowl-
edge and the Knowledge Economy, pp. 75–89. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
SCHUTJENS V. and VÖLKER B. (2010) Space and social capital: the degree of locality in entrepreneurs’ contacts and its consequences
for firm success, European Planning Studies 18, 941–963.
SEPPÄNEN R., BLOMQVIST K. and SUNDQVIST S. (2007) Measuring inter-organizational trust: a critical review of the empirical
research in 1990–2003, Industrial Marketing Management 36, 249–265.
SERAGELDIN I. and GROOTAERT C. (2000) Defining social capital: an integrating view, in DASGUPTA P. and SERAGELDIN I. (Eds) Social
Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective, pp. 40–58. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
SPENCE L. J., SCHMIDPETER R. and HABISCH A. (2003) Assessing social capital: small and medium sized enterprises in Germany and
the U.K, Journal of Business Ethics 47, 17–29.
STABER U. (2007) Contextualizing research on social capital in regional clusters, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
31, 505–521.
STIGLITZ J. E. (2000) Formal and informal institutions, in DASGUPTA P. and SERAGELDIN I. (Eds) Social Capital: A Multifaceted
Perspective, pp. 59–68. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
STORPER M. (2005) Society, community, and economic development, Studies in Comparative International Development 39(4),
30–57.
STORPER M. and VENABLES A. J. (2004) Buzz: face-to-face contact and the urban economy, Journal of Economic Geography 4,
351–370.
SVENDSEN G. L. H. and SORENSEN J. F. L. (2007) There’s more to the picture than meets the eye: measuring tangible and intangible
capital in two marginal communities in rural Denmark, Journal of Rural Studies 23, 453–471.
SVENDSEN G. L. H. and SVENDSEN G. T. (2004) The Creation and Destruction of Social Capital: Entrepreneurship, Co-operative Movements
and Institutions. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
SWEENEY G. (2001) Social capital: the core factor in economic resurgence, in SWEENEY G. (Ed.) Innovation, Economic Progress and the
Quality of Life, pp. 144–163. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
SZRETER S. and WOOLCOCK M. (2004) Health by association? Social capital, social theory, and the political economy of public
health, International Journal of Epidemiology 33, 650–667.
TAYLOR M. (2000) Communities in the lead: power, organisational capacity and social capital, Urban Studies 37, 1019–1035.
TURA T. and HARMAAKORPI V. (2005) Social capital in building regional innovative capability, Regional Studies 39, 1111–1125.
Regional Social Capital: Why it Matters 1039
TURNER J. H. (2000) The formation of social capital, in DASGUPTA P. and SERAGELDIN I. (Eds) Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspec-
tive, pp. 94–146. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
TURNER S. (2007) Small-scale enterprise livelihoods and social capital in eastern Indonesia: ethnic embeddedness and exclusion,
Professional Geographer 59, 407–420.
UPHOFF N. (2000) Understanding social capital: learning from the analysis and experience of participation, in DASGUPTA P. and
SERAGELDIN I. (Eds) Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective, pp. 215–249. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
UZZI B. (1996) The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations: the network
effect, American Sociological Review 61, 674–698.
UZZI B. (1997) Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: the paradox of embeddedness, Administrative Science Quar-
terly 42(1), 35–67.
WARR D. J. (2006) Gender, class, and the art and craft of social capital, Sociological Quarterly 47, 497–520.
WESTLUND H. (2006) Social Capital in the Knowledge Economy: Theory and Empirics. Springer, Berlin.
WESTLUND H. and ADAM F. (2010) Social capital and economic performance: a meta-analysis of 65 studies, European Planning
Studies 18, 893–919.
WESTLUND H. and BOLTON R. (2003) Local social capital and entrepreneurship, Small Business Economics 21, 77–113.
WESTLUND H. and NILSSON E. (2005) Measuring enterprises’ investments in social capital: a pilot study, Regional Studies 39,
1079–1094.
WESTLUND H., RUTTEN R. and BOEKEMA F. (2010) Social capital, distance, borders and levels of space: conclusions and further
issues, European Planning Studies 18, 965–970.
WILSON P. A. (1997) Building social capital: a learning agenda for the twenty-first century, Urban Studies 34, 745–760.
WINK R. (2008) Gatekeepers and proximity in science-driven sectors in Europe and Asia: the case of human embryonic stem cell
research, Regional Studies 42, 777–791.
WOOLCOCK M. (1998) Social capital and economic development: toward a theoretical synthesis and policy framework, Theory and
Society 27, 151–208.
WOOLCOCK M. (2004) Why and how planners should take social capital seriously, Journal of the American Planning Association 70,
183–189.
WOOLCOCK M. and NARAYAN D. (2000) Social capital: implications for development theory, research, and policy, World Bank
Research Observer 15, 225–249.
WORLD BANK (1997) Expanding the Measure of Wealth: Indicators of Environmentally Sustainable Development. The World Bank,
Washington, DC.
WORLD BANK (2006) Where Is the Wealth of Nations? Measuring Capital for the XXI Century. The World Bank, Washington, DC.

You might also like