Karki SexPreferenceValue 1988

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

Sex Preference and the Value of Sons and Daughters in Nepal

Author(s): Yagya B. Karki


Source: Studies in Family Planning , May - Jun., 1988, Vol. 19, No. 3 (May - Jun., 1988),
pp. 169-178
Published by: Population Council

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1966752

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

Population Council is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
Studies in Family Planning

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Sex Preference and the Value of Sons
and Daughters in Nepal

Yagya B. Karki

Sex preference and the specific value of sons and daughters to parents in Nepal are examnined
using rural and urban survey data fromn 1979. Ideal family size among all respondents zvas, onl
average, thlree children, with two sons and one daughter the preferred sex coinpositionl for about
90 percent of all respondents. Among those who reported current contraceptive use, the mean
number of living sons was hiigher than the mean number of living daughters for all respondenits.
Most couples have at least one son before they adopt contraception; respondents hlad, on average,
three to four births before adopting contraception. Sons are preferred to daughters by Nepalese
parents mainly for socioeconomic and religious reasons, as opposed to the economnic reasons
reported elsewhlere in many developing societies. The findings indicate that the economic inotive
for hlaving bothi sons and daughters may be weakening in Nepal, but that a preference for sons
does exist. (STUDIES IN FAMILY PLANNING 1988; 19, 3:169-178)

Sex preferences, and preference for sons in particular, behavior, however, was insignificant. Also, because the
as a major determinant of family size, have been well study was exploratory and the data analyzed were not
documented in several Asian societies.' The Value of collected specifically to examine son preference and fer-
Children (VOC) study on six countries in Asia and the tility behavior, it was not possible to look at the impact
Pacific, for example, reports that family size is influenced of son preference on fertility.
by son preference (Arnold et al., 1975). This report cites, A number of studies conducted in India do look at
among other factors, continuity of the family name, re- son preference and fertility. In some Indian communities
ligious rituals, and ancestor worship as important rea- sons are highly prized; the birth of a son may be an oc-
sons for wanting sons in Taiwan, South Korea, and casion for celebration, whereas a new daughter is almost
Thailand. In addition to wanting sons for economic rea- cause for commiseration (Gideon, 1962). Furthermore,
sons, the rural respondents in Thailand also cited reli- when times are difficult, male children are given better
gious reasons for wanting sons. However, the VOC treatment than female children; mostly boys attend
studies concentrated only on urban and semi-urban schools, and boys are better fed and better clothed. De-
areas, although the latter were reported as rural areas spite this, not much evidence exists of any influence on
(Ware, 1978). Also, although these studies document son fertility in societies that favor male children (Cassen,
preference, they do not explain much about how such 1980).
attitudes and beliefs actually affect fertility behavior. One way to look at the impact of son preference
A few studies, in addition to documenting the im- on fertility would be to examine birth order data by sex
portance of son preference, try to show its impact on of children, for couples of completed fertility. If son
fertility. A cross-cultural comparative study (Freedman preference has any influence on fertility, couples who
and Coombs, 1974) on son preference based on second- have sons first would be expected to curtail childbearing
ary data shows stated attitudes that indicate a clear pref- sooner than those who have daughters first. One study
erence for sons in Korea and Taiwan, and to a lesser de- that carried out work along these lines in India, however,
gree in India. The impact of this attitude on fertility found no such effect (Repetto, 1972). In a nationwide
sample of about 25,000 couples in India in 1970, the ma-
jority wanted children of both sexes but expressed a
Yagya B. Karki, Ph.D. is Director, Worldview International modest preference for sons (ORG, 1971). The parity pro-
Foundation/Nepal, P.O. Box 2912, Tangal, Kathmandu, gression ratios (the probability of going on to parity x +
Nepal. At the time this paper was written, he was a 1 from x) of these couples were little influenced by the
consultant in demography at the National Commission on sex of children already born, although it was found that
Population, His Majesty's Government of Nepal, couples who had only daughters were the least likely to
Kathmandu. want no more children and wanted the largest number

Volume 19 Number 3 May/June 1988 169

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
of additional children, particularly sons (Sharma and curity for parents, let alone for economic prosperity. This
Jain, 1974). Overall, the analysis shows that ideals about study casts doubts on the view that sons represent "poor
the desirability of sons do not greatly affect reproductive man's capital."
performance, but among contraceptive users, particu- Nag et al. (1978), analyzing time budget data on the
larly acceptors of terminal methods, some direct corre- activities of children aged six years and over from villages
lation is seen between the number of surviving sons and in Java and Nepal, report that children are economically
family planning acceptance (Sharma and Jain, 1974: 96). useful. However, Vlassoff (1979) has come up with evi-
Apparently, the effect of son preference on fertility dence from a village in Maharastra State, India that eco-
can be observed only when a high level of contraceptive nomic costs outweigh the benefits of children up to age
practice exists. This was the case, for instance, in South 16. Still, he says, children are expected to work because:
Korea, where the effect of son preference showed up (a) it serves to strengthen the bond between parents and
only after the third birth (Park, 1978), when parents be- children; (b) it provides a release of energy in an envi-
gan to practice contraception. Similar findings have been ronment where recreational facilities for children are al-
reported in Taiwan (Heer and Wu, 1974). most nonexistent; and finally, (c) it fosters the learning
The Nepal Fertility Survey (Nepal FP/MCH Project, of agricultural skills through a period of lengthy ap-
1977) has produced a few tables that show a strong in- prenticeship.
fluence of son preference on the number of children de-
sired. For example, it was found that women with one
son and one daughter were almost three times more likely
to want no more children as compared with women who Study Objectives
had two living daughters and no son (27.4 percent vs.
Using primary data from the West Central hills of Nepal
10.0 percent). However, this study lacks adequate in-
and employing both qualitative and quantitative meth-
formation to explain why son preference appears to be
ods, the questions addressed in this study are:
so strong in the analysis. Besides, the study was not de-
signed specifically to explore sex preference in Nepal. 1 What sex do the respondents prefer their child(ren)
to be?
2 How strong is sex preference?
3 What are the most important utilities of sons and
Utility of Children daughters to parents?
A population prefers one sex to the other generally be- 4 Does stated sex preference show up in actual be-
cause of some definite "utilities" associated with the havior? For example, how-if at all-does it affect
preferred sex. These utilities, however, vary from one fertility and contraceptive practice?
society to another and also within different segments of
It is hoped that the findings will add substantially
the same society. In the context of the Hindu society of
to the already existing knowledge of social demography
India, Mamdani (1973) writes that the first duty of a mar-
in general and to Nepalese demography in particular.
ried woman is to become a mother; her dharma (duty) is
This study is of great import to the latter, because con-
to bear children, particularly sons. Mamdani appears to
tinuing and rapid population growth in Nepal2 is already
overlook the noneconomic value of sons because, in his
having serious deleterious effects on the ecological, so-
study, the ultimate goal of having sons is to acquire eco-
cial, and economic environment. The problems are par-
nomic prosperity. This is illustrated in the following re-
ticularly severe in the hills, where traditional farming
marks made by an elderly farmer to Mamdani:
practice is forcing peasants to work increasingly steeper
You were trying to convince me in 1960 that I should not slopes that are often unfit for sustained farming, even
have any more sons. Now, you see, I have six sons and with the elaborate terracing practiced there. An increas-
two daughters and I sit at home in leisure. They are grown ing demand for fodder and fuelwood is diminishing the
up and they bring me money (1973: 109).
supply of ground-holding trees, causing frequent land-
It may be that wealthy people, particularly those with slides that, in turn, destroy lives, homes, and crops
land, want many children for economic reasons. Pun- throughout the hills (Eckholm, 1976). Such deteriorating
jab-the state that Mamdani studied-is the richest one conditions of the hills are forcing people to outmigrate
in India. Mamdani's quotation certainly does not speak continuously.
for the vast majority of poor Indians, though, because it
is very unlikely that their children will be as economically
rewarding as the children of Mamdani's well-off farmer.
Data and Methods
A recent study (Vlassoff and Vlassoff, 1980) of Mahar-
ashtra villages, where 87 percent of the villagers depend The data come from two sample surveys conducted in
on farming for their livelihood, has produced evidence Gorkha and Pokhara in 1979. Both Gorkha, a rural dis-
that having sons was no guarantee even for old age se- trict, and Pokhara, a town, lie in the West Central mid-

170 Studies in Family Planning

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
hills area of Nepal. The questionnaire used in the surveys formation was collected on a total of 1,863 individuals
consisted of three main parts. Part 1 comprised census- constituting about 5 percent of the total population of
type questions; Part 2 elicited information on fertility and the town.
on infant and child mortality from 15-49-year-old ever- In Pokhara, a census-type questionnaire was ad-
married women; and Part 3 focused on the Value of Chil- ministered to 291 households containing 343 ever-mar-
dren items, such as advantages and disadvantages of ried women aged 15-49, and from these, 188 wives were
having children, ideal and desired family sizes, satis- interviewed for the VOC information. Only 50 percent
faction from having children, birth control information, of husbands were administered the VOC questionnaire
perceived economic values and costs of children, and in the town. The response rate was 93 percent for wives
information on the socioeconomic background of re- and 91 percent for husbands. Interviews in both areas
spondents.3 Well trained interviewers were employed were completed, on average, in 52 minutes.
to administer the questionnaire. In the rural area, only
males conducted the interviews, as it was not possible
to recruit a sufficient number of females, partly because
The Setting
the job involved spending nights away from home. The
Nepal Fertility Survey (Nepal FP/MCH Project, 1977) also Based primarily on subsistence agriculture, Gorkha is
employed only male interviewers in the hills. Altogether, typical, in many respects, of the mid-hills area of Nepal.
3 supervisors and 18 interviewers worked for two and a In Pokhara, about one-half of the population lives on
half months in the rural area. In the urban area, four trade and commerce and the other half on farming. The
females interviewed the wives, and three males-in- villagers in Gorkha produce two crops a year on dry land
cluding one supervisor-interviewed the husbands. and normally one crop a year on irrigated land. They
In Gorkha, out of 47 village panchayats (a politico- depend entirely on the monsoon rains for irrigation.
administrative unit roughly equivalent to a county in In the Gorkha sample almost every family had some
Great Britain), five were selected on the basis of proba- land to work, the average being 1.4 acres per household,
bilities proportional to size. Nine village panchayats were whereas the corresponding figure for the urban area was
not included in the sample universe because of difficult 0.4. However, in Pokhara about 57 percent of the people
access, as they were above 10,000 feet in altitude. Census- interviewed reported nonagricultural occupations as
type information was collected for every second house- opposed to only 2 percent in the rural areas.
hold, which produced a population of 11,542 individuals Bullocks provide the main motive power for culti-
representing 7 percent of the total population of 164,858 vation. Apart from plowing, all other work needed for
of the sampled universe. Part 2 of the questionnaire was farming is done by human beings. Without human labor,
administered to ever-married women aged 15-49 in every which includes the work of men, women, and children,
household, while Part 3 was administered to wives aged the rural economy cannot be sustained. In addition to
15-39 with at least one living child and whose husbands land, the villagers also own animals; the mean number
were at home at the time of the survey. Consequently, of cattle, which includes cows, oxen, and buffalo, is about
of the total 1,909 sampled households only 669 house- six per family, and the mean number of goats and sheep
holds had women eligible for Part 3 of the questionnaire per family is about three.
and, of these, 683 wives were successfully interviewed. The household is the primary unit of production for
Only 15-39-year-old women were interviewed, because the family's own consumption. In most villages, paid
this is the age when both partners are most sexually active labor is scarce. Instead, mostly reciprocal labor arrange-
and also when they give the most attention to the values ments (parma) and communal activities are practiced in
and costs of bearing and rearing children. In addition to the hills, with the result that very little individual wealth
the wives, 216 rural husbands from every third house- is accumulated.These arrangements are tantamount to
hold were interviewed. The response rate among the a form of communal insurance against a single household
wives was 99 percent and among their husbands it was being left destitute as a result of a natural disaster (for
98 percent. example, a landslide), and also enable poor families to
Pokhara town, comprising 16 wards, had a total conduct such events as weddings and funerals. The
population of 36,189 in 1979. For sampling purposes, goods required for running the local economy are man-
wards 1, 2, 3, 4, 9, and 12 were classed as highly urban- ufactured by the household itself through cloth weaving,
ized, and the other ten wards were classed as less ur- house building, and the manufacture of rice stalk mats,
banized. Ward 3 was sampled from the highly urbanized bamboo baskets, winnowing fans, and the like, activities
groups, and wards 11, 13, and 16 from the less urbanized that usually take place when the agricultural season is
group, on the basis of probabilities proportional size. The over or slow.
survey questionnaire was administered to every second Just as in many other less developed countries, sig-
household in ward 3, but in order to make the sample nificant migration takes place from the hills to other areas
sizes of the two groups uniform the wards from the less for employment. Many adult males seek employment
urbanized area were stratified. Thus, demographic in- outside the country, leaving their families to work land

Volume 19 Number 3 May/June 1988 171

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
on their own. This is common even in the urban areas. the Nepalese women interviewed did not want to discuss
About 31 percent of 15-49-year-old rural married women their sexual behavior in any context. Campbell et al.
reported that their husbands were away from home at (1979) and Bennett (1976) make special reference to the
the time of the survey; the corresponding figure for the Bahun-Chhetri community, who are orthodox Hindu.
urban area was 20 percent. However, this outlet for the One of the main problems is that the whole idea of family
burgeoning population is narrowing both in India and planning is a very sensitive matter in Nepalese society,
South East Asia. Since the majority of the migrants come particularly among women. It is said that when a woman
from the hills, the dwindling employment opportunities talks openly about family planning, she is seen as morally
outside Nepal have important implications for the hills degraded, and her fidelity to her husband becomes sus-
population. pect.
According to the present survey, about 15 percent Campbell et al. (1979) argued that one reason for
of rural and 55 percent of urban respondents were lit- such a low level of family planning knowledge among
erate. The national literacy rate for Nepal around 1979 the NFS informants was that the interviewers were
was 19 percent (World Bank, 1981). The rural district un- males. Interestingly, however, the degree of complete-
der study had no electricity at the time of the survey, but ness of reporting on current contraceptive use was no
a road joined its district headquarters (located about 1,200 better among urban as compared to rural wives in the
meters above sea level) with the main roadway, which present study, even though urban wives were inter-
passed along its southern border. It also had 10 high viewed by females.
schools, 170 primary schools, and 2 hospitals. Most Nepalese society is male-dominated and wives
modern amenities are foreign to the villagers of Gorkha. hardly ever become involved in matters outside the
Pokhara, on the other hand, is the location of one of five home. Moreover, since revealing information about
regional headquarters of the Western Development Re- family planning is likely to make most wives anxious
gion in Nepal. It is probably the second most important about their relationship with their husbands, they do
valley in Nepal attracting foreign tourists. not usually talk about it openly unless they obtain their
The total fertility rate (TFR) in 1979 was higher in husband's consent. It is also reported by Campbell et al.
the rural area (6.4) than in the urban area (4.3) (Karki, (1979) that most women would not want to talk about
1982). Using the Nepal Fertility Survey data, the national family planning in the presence of others, particularly
TFR was found to be 6.3 in 1976 (Goldman et al., 1979). the elderly members of the family, to whom they must
As expected, the infant mortality rate (IMR) was higher pay respect. In view of such constraints, every effort was
in the rural area (130 per 1,000 live births) than in the made in the present study to interview each person alone.
urban area (60 per 1,000) (Karki, 1982). Urban-rural Also, the respondents were told that the present study
mortality statistics are not available but the national IMR had nothing to do with the government's family planning
in 1976 was 134 per 1,000 live births (Central Bureau of program in Kathmandu. Yet, the interviewers got the
Statistics, 1978). impression that the respondents, particularly the wives,
Almost no one in the rural population, if the statistics did not want to talk about family planning.
are taken at face value, practices contraception; only 15
percent reported having ever heard of family planning
in the rural area, though nearly 60 percent knew about
Results
family planning in the urban area. Current contraceptive
use was, however, low in both areas: about 29 percent
(N = 27) of the husbands and only 11 percent (N = 20) of Sex Preference
the wives reported current contraceptive use in the urban
The questionnaire contained both open-ended and
area. The corresponding figures were 7 percent for hus-
structured questions on sex preference. The set of open-
bands (N = 15) and 7 percent for wives (N = 48) in the
ended questions was on ideal family size and compo-
rural area (Karki, 1982). The extent to which the urban
wives were reluctant to reveal contraceptive use appears
quite considerable, and it is probable that the rural wives
were equally if not more reluctant to discuss their con- Table 1 Response to an open-ended question about ideal

traceptive behavior. It may be that the husbands were family size and composition

also concealing information about their contraceptive Wives' response Husbands' response

use. All of the respondents may have been similarly hes- Variable Rural Urban Rural Urban
itant to discuss their knowledge of family planning. Desired (mean)
Since in the Nepalese Hindu society extramarital sex Family size 3.2 2.9 3.2 3.2
Number of sons 2.0 1.7 2.1 1.9
is very uncommon, it follows that when husbands are Number of daughtersa 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.3
practicing contraception, their wives must also be doing Numberof respondents 683 188 216 92

so. Since so many more husbands than wives reported aThose who did not want any daughters included 43 rural wives and 3 urban
current contraceptive use, it is plausible to assume that wives, and 13 rural husbands and 6 urban husbands.

172 Studies in Family Planning

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 2 Preferred sex of children and family composition The set of structured questions required respondents
among Nepalese couples to choose their ideal combination of sexes if they could
Percent of responses
have only three children. When asked what their first
Wives Husbands
choice was, respondents indicated a strong preference
for sons (Table 2), with about 90 percent of all respon-
Sex composition Rural Urban Rural Urban
dents choosing two boys and one girl. Respondents were
First choice
Three girlsa 0 1 0 0 then asked to choose the next best combination, and the
One boy, two girls 5 1 3 7
majority selected one boy and two girls. Finally, those
Two boys, one girl 86 98 89 93
Three boysa 9 1 8 0 respondents who had not already chosen either three
Total percent 100 100 100 100 sons or three daughters as their optimal family compo-
(Number of respondents) (683) (188) (216) (92)
sition were asked to choose between the two. As ex-
Second choice
Three girlsa 1 1 0 0 pected, the overwhelming majority chose all sons. This
One boy, two girls 50 68 55 66
clearly indicates a strong preference for sons, a preference
Two boys, one girl 5 1 3 7
Three boysa 44 31 42 26 that persists even when the respondents are broken
No response 1 0 0 0
down by rural and urban areas and by sex.
Total percent 100 100 100 100
(Number of respondents) (620) (186) (198) (92)
For comparisons with other Asian societies, the re-
Third choice sponses shown in Table 2 are again classified, in Table
Three girls 2 2 3 9
3, by sex bias scales (Coombs et al., 1975), ranging from
Three boys 96 97 96 88
No response 1 1 2 3 one (girl preference) to seven (boy preference). The other
Total percent 100 100 100 100 societies included in Table 3 are Taiwan, South Korea,
(Number of respondents) (340) (127) (115) (67)
and the Philippines (Coombs and Sun, 1978). The strong
Note: Percentages may not sum to 100 because of rounding. son preference in Nepal is very much on a par with that
aNot asked further.
in Taiwan and in South Korea. The Philippines offers a
marked contrast, where as much girl as boy preference
is found.
sition. The respondents were asked what their ideal Table 3 shows that husbands express no preference
family size and sex composition would be if they could for girls at all, whereas some wives, albeit a very small
start their family building all over again. The mean ideal proportion, do indicate some preference for girls. The
size is about three (Table 1). Preference for sons over rural respondents appear to show stronger son prefer-
daughters is slightly stronger among the rural respon- ence (IS6-7 = 48 percent) than their urban counterparts
dents, but the mean number of sons desired in both (IS6-7 =29 percent). If son preference affects fertility,
groups is about two, and the mean number of daughters then it is likely that the rural population will ultimately
desired is about one. have larger families than the urban ones.

Table 3 Sex bias distribution among Nepalese couples

Coombs IS scalea

Girl preference Balance Boy preference Total

Respondents ISi IS2 IS3 IS4 IS5 IS6 IS7 % N


Wives
Rural 0 1 c 5 45 39 10 100 659
Urban c c 0 2 66 31 c 100 186
Allb c 1 C 4 50 37 8 100 845
Husbands
Rural 0 0 0 4 49 38 8 100 213
Urban 0 0 0 7 68 25 0 100 87
Allb 0 0 0 5 54 35 6 100 300
Rural husbands
andwives 0 c c 5 46 39 9 100 872
Urban husbands
and wives c c 0 4 66 29 c 100 273
All respondentsb c c c 5 51 36 7 100 1,145
Taiwan 0 0 1 11 54 32 2 100 5,463
Korea 0 1 0 4 4 49 5 100 d
Philippines 5 8 24 33 20 7 3 100 d

Note: Total percent may not add to 100 because of roundi


aThe Coombs IS preference for sex of children scale rang
with IS4 indicating a clear preference for balance of s
to give unbiased population estimates. cLess than 0.5 percent. dNot available.
Source: C.H. Coombs, L.C. Coombs, and G.H. McCleland, "Preference scales for number and sex of children," Population Studies
29,2 (1975):273-298; L.C. Coombs and T.H. Sun, "Family composition preference in a developing culture: The case of Taiwan,"
Population Studies 32,1 (1978):43-64.

Volume 19 Number 3 May/June 1988 173

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Reasons for Wanting Sons and Daughters Karki, 1982: 73). Thus, the old age security value of sons
(socioeconomic) and the religious value (noneconomic)
The analysis so far demonstrates that all respondents
appear to be the most important dimensions of the value
have a preference for sons, but that few would be satisfied
of children in the mid-hills populations of Nepal. The
with sons alone. In order, therefore, to examine desired
old age security value of sons also was seen in a study
family composition further, separate open-ended ques-
conducted in the neighborhood of Kathmandu city, al-
tions were asked on reasons for wanting sons and
though only a minority felt that sons provide adequate
daughters. This was done after the respondents had in-
security for old age (Schuler and Goldstein, 1986).
dicated the sex composition of their ideal family.

Reasons for Wanting Daughters


Reasons for Wanting Sons
About 5 percent of all respondents did not want any
All respondents who wanted at least one son in their
daughters (see Table 1, note a) in their ideal family. The
ideal family were asked to give at least two reasons for
rest were asked, "For you, what are the most important
wanting sons. The question was, "For you, what are the
reasons for wanting a daughter?" (The interviewers were
most important reasons for wanting a son?" (Interview-
instructed to probe for two reasons.)
ers were instructed to probe for two reasons.) The first
In their study on the work activities of children in a
reasons given are shown in Table 4. The responses have
village in Nepal, Nag et al. (1978) reported that girls are
been broadly divided into economic, socioeconomic, and
more useful than boys in the household and familial
sociopsychological and cultural reasons. The old age se-
work. While this may be true, the reasons for wanting
curity value of children has been categorized as socio-
daughters given as first responses to an open-ended
economic because help in old age can be both economic
question (shown in Table 5) do not appear to support
and social. For poor parents, help from children is pri-
the high economic value of daughters. The second re-
marily economic. For parents who are not constrained
sponses, not shown, do not indicate the economic im-
financially, though, help in old age is noneconomic, often
portance of daughters either (Karki, 1982: 76). Both the
taking the form of companionship, for example, or emo-
first and second responses suggest the importance of
tional support. The reasons given for wanting sons in
noneconomic reasons for wanting daughters. This pat-
Table 4 are primarily noneconomic for the rural respon-
tern is much more pronounced among rural than urban
dents, but the urban respondents more often gave so-
respondents. It is only the urban wives who realize the
cioeconomic reasons, particularly the old age value of
practical utility of girls, although slightly more urban than
sons. In the rural area, the religious value of sons was
rural husbands mentioned this reason for wanting girls,
emphasized more, which is not surprising because re-
as well.
ligion has a great influence on the traditional way of life
A very high proportion of rural respondents stressed
in the rural population. With increasing urbanization,
the religious value of daughters. The birth of a daughter,
the religious influence may gradually erode.
in some Nepalese communities, is hailed as an event that
Nearly 90 percent of the respondents gave a second
will bring prosperity (Thapa, 1980), and some religious
reason for wanting sons. The second responses, not
occasions require the presence of females. For instance,
shown in the table, reverse the picture because the re-
Tihar, the second most important festival of the Hindus,
spondents who gave a noneconomic reason first for
requires the presence of one's sisters to make it a happy
wanting sons gave a socioeconomic reason second (see

Table 4 First responses to an open-ended question on the


reasons for wanting sons Table 5 First responses to an open-ended question on the
reasons for wanting daughters
Percent
Percent
Wives Husbands
Wives Husbands
Response Rural Urban Rural Urban
Response Rural Urban Rural Urban
Economic reasons 10 5 11 10
Practical help 3 2 4 2 Economic reasons 10 44 16 17
Inherit family debts and assets 4 2 4 8 Practical help 10 44 16 17
Sons earn income 3 1 3 0 Socioeconomic reasons 3 6 2 2
Socioeconomic reasons 24 47 18 47 Old age security 3 6 2 2
Old age security 24 47 18 47 Sociopsychological and
Sociopsychological and cultural reasons 86 51 81 80
cultural reasons 67 48 71 43 For religious occasions 53 25 52 37
Religious ritual reasons 60 47 64 27 Avoid loneliness 13 19 12 26
Family continuity 5 1 6 13 Make relatives 19 7 15 17
Happiness/satisfaction 1 0 1 2 Othera 1 0 2 0
Social status/sons' achievements 1 0 0 1 Total 100 100 100 100
Total 100 100 100 100 (Number of respondents)3)(63) (175) (201n) (86)
(Number of respondents) (683) (188) (216) (92)
Note: Total percents may not add to 100 due to rounding.
Note: Total percents may not add to 100 due to rounding. 'NO specific reason for wanting girls; just want girls.

174 Studies in Family Planning

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 6 Respondents who want no more children, by number of living children and living sons

Wives Husbands

Rural Urban Rural Urban


No. of No. of % want % want % want % want
living living No. of no more No. of no more No. of no more No. of no more
children sons all wives children all wives children all husbands children all husbands children
1 0 73 8.2 28 7.1 30 3.3 10 10.0
1 75 20.0 23 4.3 29 3.4 9 0.0
Total 148 14.2 51 5.9 59 3.4 19 5.3
2 0 26 15.4 8 37.5 4 25.0 0 0.0
1 81 82.7 39 61.5 22 77.3 18 44.4
2 35 74.3 13 84.6 10 50.0 4 100.0
Total 142 68.3 60 63.3 36 63.9 22 54.5
3 0 14 7.1 4 50.0 6 16.7 3 0.0
1 57 86.0 12 75.0 15 93.3 7 100.0
2 65 96.9 19 94.7 19 100.0 14 92.9
3 23 95.7 0 0.0 7 85.7 0 0.0
Total 159 84.9 35 82.9 47 85.1 24 83.3
4or
more 0 3 33.3 1 100.0 0 0.0 1 100.0
1 40 95.0 5 80.0 13 100.0 3 66.7
2 69 98.6 17 100.0 23 95.7 11 100.0
3 66 100.0 11 100.0 18 100.0 6 100.0
4or
more 56 98.2 8 100.0 20 100.0 6 100.0
Total 234 97.4 42 97.6 74 98.6 27 96.3
Total 683 70.4 188 59.0 216 63.9 92 64.1

occasion. The sisters ceremonially offer Tiko (a mark on parents earn religious merit when they perform Kanya-
the forehead) to one another and garlands to their broth- daan (give a virgin daughter to a boy in another family).
ers, and daan (gifts) are exchanged (Department of Tour- This is probably one reason for early and universal female
ism, 1980). If there are no sisters in the family, the broth- marriage in Nepal.
ers request women or girls from the neighborhood to
put Tiko on their foreheads and receive a benediction,
Effect of Current Sex Composition of
but that kind of arrangement is not really satisfactory.
Children on Fertility
There are probably more festivals in Nepal than
anywhere else in the world (Anderson, 1971), and for The effect of sex preference on fertility is examined by
proper observation of almost all of them the presence of considering the percent of respondents who said that
a young unmarried girl is necessary. On such occasions, they want no more children (Table 6). In Nepal, 60-70
by offering Tiko and some daan in the form of metal (par- percent of respondents wanted no more children, and
ticularly copper coins) to a young unmarried girl, a per- the percent wanting no more children increases with the
son is believed to earn punya (religious merit) for the next number of living children. Within each living children
life. Parents in the neighborhood of Kathmandu city also group, the sex composition of the family influences future
stress that they are supposed to support their daughters childbearing desires. For instance, among respondents
and receive nothing but love and religious merit in return with two living children, the proportion wanting no more
(Schuler and Goldstein, 1986: 68). children among those who have one son is two to three
The perception that daughters are valuable for avoid- times higher than the proportion among those with no
ing loneliness is stronger among urban as compared to sons. In larger families, the differences are even greater.
rural parents. More urban than rural respondents men- In the group of respondents with three children, over
tioned this as a value of daughters. Girls, it is felt, are five times as many of those with one son want no more
more playful and enjoyable as children than boys. children as compared with women who have no sons.
Another important reason given for wanting daugh- Furthermore, respondents with two or more living sons
ters is that they increase the size of the extended family are much more likely to want no more children than those
by adding relatives. The urban wives seem to attach less with one son. Despite small numbers, these relationships
importance to this than the rural wives, but a slightly generally hold for respondents of both sexes and in both
greater proportion of urban as compared to rural hus- areas (Table 6).
bands feel that this is an important reason for having
daughters. Relatives can also be added to the family
Effect of Son Preference on Contraception
through sons, but in the Hindu society of the Nepalese,
gaining relatives through daughters has a more signif- The effect of son preference on contraceptive use is in-
icant connotation. According to the Hindu scriptures, vestigated by considering the timing of first use and the

Volume 19 Number 3 May/June 1988 175

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 7 Parity at first contraceptive use among Nepalese Table 8 Respondents who reported having living sons when
couples they first practiced contraception

Percent responding Percent

Number of live births prior Wives Husbands Number of Wives Husbands


to contraceptive use Rural Urban Rural Urban living sons Rural Urban Rural Urban

1 10 5 13 4 0 2 0 0 0
2 13 15 13 26 1 30 35 47 44
3 21 45 7 44 2 35 55 13 48
4 15 25 20 15 3 17 10 7 7
5 15 10 13 7 4ormore 17 0 33 0
6+ 27 0 33 4 Total percent 100 100 100 100
Total percent 100 100 100 100
Total number of respondents 48 20 15 27
Total number of respondents 48 20 15 27 Mean number of living sons 2.2 1.8 2.4 1.6
Mean number of live births
before adopting contraception 4.1 3.2 4.3 3.1 Note: Total percents may not add to 100 due to rounding.

Note: Total percents may not add to 100 due to rounding.

variations in percent users. Despite the fact that the in-


formation on contraception may be biased, as discussed Table 9 Respondents who reported having living daughters
earlier, it seems worthwhile to investigate when a couple when they first practiced contraception
first practices contraception and whether their decision Percent
is influenced by family size composition. Nepalese cou-
ples generally believe that family planning should begin Number of Wives Husbands
living daughters Rural Urban Rural Urban
only after they achieve their desired family size and sex
0 21 10 13 11
composition. 1 25 50 27 48
2 30 30 40 33
To most, family planning means stopping child-
3 21 10 7 4
bearing completely rather than spacing births. This is 4ormore 4 0 13 4

probably why people who are using birth control before Total percent 100 100 100 100

their first birth may be especially reluctant to admit it. Total number of respondents 48 20 15 27
Mean number of living daughters 1.7 1.4 1.9 1.4
No respondents reported using any form of birth control
before the birth of a first child (Table 7). In addition, the Note: Total percents may not add to 100 due to rounding.

Table 10 Respondents who ever practiced contraception, by number of living children


and living sons

Husbands who ever used


Wives who ever used contraceptives contraceptives
Number of Number of Rural Urban Rural Urban
living children living sons N % N % N % N %
1 0 73 1.4 28 0.0 30 0.0 10 0.0
1 75 5.3 23 4.4 29 6.9 9 11.1
Total 148 3.4 51 2.0 59 3.4 19 5.3
2 0 26 0.0 8 0.0 4 0.0 0 0.0
1 81 3.7 39 7.7 22 9.1 18 33.3
2 35 14.3 13 7.7 10 0.0 4 50.0
Total 142 5.6 60 6.7 36 5.6 22 36.4
3 0 14 0.0 4 0.0 6 0.0 3 0.0
1 57 7.0 12 16.7 15 6.7 7 71.4
2 65 6.2 19 31.6 19 0.0 14 42.9
3 23 4.4 0 0.0 7 0.0 0 0.0
Total 159 5.7 35 22.9 47 2.1 24 45.8
4or
more 0 3 0.0 1 0.0 0 0.0 1 0.0
1 40 7.5 5 20.0 13 15.4 3 0.0
2 69 11.6 17 23.5 23 8.7 1 1 45.5
3 66 10.6 11 18.2 18 5.6 6 33.3
4 or
more 56 14.3 8 0.0 20 25.0 6 0.0
Total 234 11.1 42 16.6 74 13.5 27 25.9
Total 683 7.0 188 10.6 216 6.9 92 29.4

Note: The denominators used to calculate

176 Studies in Family Planning

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
rural respondents had, on average, approximately four primarily for religious occasions and not for econom-
births before adopting contraception. Urban couples had ic benefits. This was more strongly expressed in the ru-
about three births before beginning family planning. ral area.
The family sex composition among the respondents The economic motive to have many children may be
who ever practiced birth control reveals that most couples changing even in the rural areas of Nepal. The existence
have at least one living son (Table 8) before practicing of such a pattern is supported by the family size data:
birth control. Some respondents in both rural and urban both the mean ideal family size of about three and the
areas had practiced birth control without having a living mean desired family size (includes number of living chil-
daughter (Table 9) but only one had done so without dren, current pregnancy, and number of additional chil-
having a living son. Despite the small numbers the pat- dren wanted) of about four are low for a population that,
tern is similar to that in a sample of 214 women studied for the most part, does not practice contraception. Also,
in a Pokhara sterilization camp (Miller and Joshi, 1974). the reasons expressed for wanting sons and daughters
From this analysis, it appears that it would be quite dif- support the suggestion that the economic motive for
ficult, if not impossible, to persuade most couples to having children may be weakening.
adopt family planning if they did not already have living The author's own observation of the deteriorating
sons. hills environment and the perceived economic costs of
The data presented so far do not reflect the extent raising children was articulated by the respondents
of contraceptive use and how it is affected by the number (Karki, 1982: Chapter 5), who spoke in support of a shift
and sex composition of living children. This is done by toward smaller family size. The economic situation of
considering the percent of respondents who practice the people in the hills has, unfortunately, become worse
contraception (Table 10). A small proportion of Nepalese in recent years. Due to the recession of the forests every
couples practice contraception, and because of the small year, it takes markedly longer to fetch wood and water.
numbers involved, there is no clear pattern. However, Also, the villagers now feel the shortage of good agri-
respondents without a living son do not practice con- cultural land. The very high rise in the value of land has
traception at all, except for one woman in the rural area, made its purchase by villagers practically impossible be-
which might be a reporting error. Apparently, even those cause of its prohibitive cost. Those families who had good
respondents who have one child start thinking about land are now only moderately well off, because as gen-
birth control measures, if the child is a son. erations mature, inheritance customs continually divide
large estates between several sons; thus, more sons
means less land for each. Many villagers, therefore, link
the poverty of the people to large family size.
Summary and Discussion
Family size preferences and the decision to practice
This small-scale study and a large nationally represen- contraception are both affected by son preference-that
tative sample survey have indicated strong evidence of is, the desire to have at least one living son. The pro-
son preference in Nepalese society. The young couples portion of couples with at least one living son who desire
(i.e., female respondents aged 15-39) in Nepal do not, additional children is very low compared to their coun-
however, seem to desire many (i.e., more than three) terparts with no son. Also, virtually no couples without
sons, even though they value them very highly. They sons, in both the urban and in the rural samples, were
do not want only sons, either. Their ideal family size is practicing contraception. Among those who reported
three, and their ideal sex composition of children is two current contraceptive use, the mean number of living
sons and one daughter. Most desire at least one living sons was higher than the mean number of living daugh-
child of each sex. ters.
Nepalese parents prefer sons to daughters because Although Nepalese couples express a strong desire
of their culture and the various roles that sons play in for sons and their intentions with regard to future family
their family life. It is only one's own son who can perform building are affected accordingly, such a phenomenon
death and post-death rituals to ensure that the gate of still does not account for low contraceptive use because,
heaven will be opened for parents. In addition, sons even among those who have two or more sons, the pro-
continue the family name and provide support in old portion practicing contraception is much smaller than
age. For these and other reasons, it is not surprising to the proportion wanting no more children. A large gap
often hear people say, "Let it be late, but let it be a son. " exists between the desire to cease childbearing and any
When respondents were asked what their ideal action to realize that goal. Moreover, the percent of cou-
family size and sex composition would be if they were ples who do not have a son decreases quite rapidly as
to start their family life all over again, about 6 percent the number of living children increases. Thus, only 10
of rural and 3 percent of urban couples did not want percent of respondents with three children have no sons.
any girls at all. The rest, however, who wanted at least It is this small group whose contraceptive and fertility
one girl in their ideal family, said that they wanted girls behavior would be affected by the lack of a son.

Volume 19 Number 3 May/June 1988 177

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Notes Eckholm, E.P. 1976. Losing Ground: Environmental Stress and World Food
Prospects. New York; W. W. Norton Company.
This paper is based on the author's Ph.D. thesis in demography, "Fer-
Freedman, R. and L.C. Coombs. 1974. Cross-Cultuiral Comparisons: Data
tility and the Value of Children: A Study of Rural and Urban Populations
oni Two Factors in Fertility Behavior. New York: The Population Coun-
in Nepal" (Karki, 1982). Research costs were covered by a generous
cil.
grant from the Ford Foundation. The financial support is gratefully
acknowledged. The author is grateful to the late Professor D.V. Glass Gideon, H. 1962. "A baby is born in the Punjab.'' American Anthropologist
64.
of the London School of Economics, who was his supervisor initially,
for providing much encouragement and support during the planning Goldman, Noreen, Ansley J. Coale, and Maine Weinstein. 1979. "The
of the project. The author also wishes to thank the referees and members quality of data in the Nepal Fertility Survey." WFS Scientific Reports.
of the Editorial Committee of Sttudies in Family Planniing for their helpful No. 6. Voorburg: International Statistical Institute.
comments.
Heer, D. and H. Wu. 1974. "The effect of infant and child mortality
An earlier version of this paper was presented in a lecture to the
and preference for sons upon fertility and family planning behavior
staff of the Centre for Population Studies, London School of Hygiene and attitudes in Taiwan." In Population and Social Change in South
and Tropical Medicine, February 1982.
East Asia. Ed. J.F. Kanter. Lexington: Lexington Books.
1 For a review of the literature on preference for sons around the world,
Karki, Y.B. 1982. "Fertility and the value of children: A study of rural
see Williamson (1976). and urban populations in Nepal." Ph.D. thesis, London School of
2 The population of Nepal has grown from 8.3 million in 1952/54 to Economics.
9.4 million in 1961, 11.6 million in 1971, and 15.0 million in 1981. Mamdani, M. 1973. The Myth of Population Control: Familly Caste and Class
The average annual rates of growth in percentages are 1.6, 2.1, and in an Indian Village. New York: Monthly Review Press.
2.7 during the 1952/54-61, 1961-71, and 1971-81 census periods, re-
Miller, R. and P. L. Joshi. 1974. Laparoscopic Sterilization in Camp Setting:
spectively. See Central Bureau of Statistics (1985).
The Nepal Experience. Washington, DC: Agency for International
3 For more, see Chapter 3 in Karki (1982). Development.
4 See Chapter 5 in Karki (1982). Nag, M., B. White, and R.C. Peet. 1978. "An anthropological approach
to the study of the economic value of children in Java and Nepal."
Cuirrenit Anthropology 19: 293-306.
Nepal Family Planning/Maternal-Child Health (FP/MCH) Project. 1977.
Nepal Fertility Survey,. First Report (1976). Kathmandu: Ministry of
References Health.

Anderson, Mary M. 1971. The Festivals of Nepal. London. Operations Research Group (ORG). 1971. An All-India Survey of Fanily
Planning Practices. Baroda: ORG.
Arnold, F., R. Bulatao, C. Buripakdi, B.J. Chung, J.T. Fawcett, T. Iritani,
S.J. Lee, and T.S. Wu. 1975. The Value of Children: A Cross-National Park, Chai Bin. 1978. The Fourth Korean Child: The Effect of Son Preference
Study. Voltum2e 1, Introduction and Comparative Analysis. Honolulu: on Subsequent Fertility. Report No. 87. Honolulu: East-West Pop-
East-West Population Institute. ulation Institute.

Bennett, Lynn. 1976. "Sex and motherhood among the Brahmans and Repetto, R. 1972. "Son preference and fertility behavior in developing
countries." Studies in Famiilly Planning 3, 4: 70-76.
Chhetris of East Central Nepal." Journal of the Institutte of Nepal anid
Asian Studies (Special issue). Contributions to Nepalese Studies, Schuler, Sidney Ruth and Melvyn C. Goldstein. 1986. "Family planning
Volume 3. Kathmandu: Tribhuban University. in Nepal from the user's and nonuser's perspectives." Studies in
Campbell, J. Gabriel, Ramesh Shrestha, and Linda Stone. 1979. T/le Family Platnning 17, 2: 66-77.
Use and Misuse of Social Science Research in Nepal. Kathmandu: Sharma, D.V.N. and A.K. Jain. 1974. "Preference about sex of children
Research Centre for Nepal and Asian Studies, Tribhuban University. and use of contraception among women wanting no more children
Cassen, R.H. 1980. India: Population, Economny, Society. New York: in India." Dem1ography India 3, 1: 81-104.
Holmes and Meier. Thapa, Dhruba B.S. 1980. "Law and population." In Population of Nepal.
Country Monograph Series, No. 6. Bangkok: Economic and Social
Central Bureau of Statistics. 1978. The Demtiographic Samriple Suirvelj of Nepal.
Kathmandu: National Planning Commission Secretariat, His Maj- Commission for Asia and the Pacific, United Nations.
esty's Government of Nepal. Vlassoff, M. 1979. 1980. "Labor demand and economic utility of chil-
. 1985. Intercemisal Changes of Somne Key Censtis Variables, Nepal, dren's case study in rural India." Population Studies 33, 3: 415-428.
1952/54-1981. Kathmandu: His Majesty's Government of Nepal. Vlassoff, M. and C. Vlassoff. 1980. "Old age security and the utility
Coombs, C.H., L.C. Coombs, and G.H. McCleland. 1975. "Preference of children in rural India." Population Studies 34, 3: 487-499.
scales for number and sex of children." Population Studies 29, 2: 273- Ware, Helen. 1978. The Economic Value of Children in Asia and Africa:
298.
Comparative Perspective. Papers of the East-West Population Institute,
Coombs, L.C. and T.H. Sun. 1978. "Family composition preference in No. 50. Honolulu: East-West Population Institute.
a developing culture: The case of Taiwan." Population Studies 32, 1:
Williamson, Nancy E. 1976. Sons or Daughters: A Cross-Cultural Survey,
43-64.
of Parental Preferences. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.
Department of Tourism. 1980. Nepal: Pacific Travel News. Kathmandu: World Bank. 1981. World Development Report, 1981. Washington, DC:
His Majesty's Government of Nepal. World Bank.

178 Studies in Family Planning

This content downloaded from


103.173.2.149 on Sat, 11 May 2024 01:48:49 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like