Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 69

Principles of Economics, 8e ISE Robert

H. Frank
Visit to download the full and correct content document:
https://ebookmeta.com/product/principles-of-economics-8e-ise-robert-h-frank/
More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant
download maybe you interests ...

Principles of Macroeconomics, 8e ISE Robert H. Frank

https://ebookmeta.com/product/principles-of-
macroeconomics-8e-ise-robert-h-frank/

Principles of Microeconomics, 8e ISE Robert H. Frank

https://ebookmeta.com/product/principles-of-
microeconomics-8e-ise-robert-h-frank/

Principles of Economics, A Streamlined Approach, 4e ISE


Robert H. Frank

https://ebookmeta.com/product/principles-of-economics-a-
streamlined-approach-4e-ise-robert-h-frank/

Principles of Microeconomics: A Streamlined Approach,


4e ISE Robert H. Frank

https://ebookmeta.com/product/principles-of-microeconomics-a-
streamlined-approach-4e-ise-robert-h-frank/
Principles of Macroeconomics: A Streamlined Approach,
4e ISE Robert H. Frank

https://ebookmeta.com/product/principles-of-macroeconomics-a-
streamlined-approach-4e-ise-robert-h-frank/

ISE Principles of Biology 3rd Edition Robert Brooker

https://ebookmeta.com/product/ise-principles-of-biology-3rd-
edition-robert-brooker/

Economics for Healthcare Managers Robert H. Lee

https://ebookmeta.com/product/economics-for-healthcare-managers-
robert-h-lee/

Financial Markets and Institutions, 8e ISE Anthony


Saunders

https://ebookmeta.com/product/financial-markets-and-
institutions-8e-ise-anthony-saunders/

ISE Labor Economics (ISE HED IRWIN ECONOMICS) 8th


Edition George J. Borjas

https://ebookmeta.com/product/ise-labor-economics-ise-hed-irwin-
economics-8th-edition-george-j-borjas/
This International Student Edition is for use outside of the U.S.

PRINCIPLES OF

ECONOMICS
FRANK • BERNANKE • ANTONOVICS • HEFFETZ

EIGHTH EDITION
PRINCIPLES OF
ECONOMICS
Eighth Edition

ROBERT H. FRANK
Cornell University

BEN S. BERNANKE
Brookings Institution [affiliated]
Former Chair, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

KATE ANTONOVICS
University of California, San Diego

ORI HEFFETZ
Cornell University and the Hebrew University of Jerusalem
PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS
Published by McGraw Hill LLC, 1325 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10121. Copyright ©2022
by McGraw Hill LLC. All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. No part of this
­publication may be reproduced or distributed in any form or by any means, or stored in a database or
retrieval system, without the prior written consent of McGraw Hill LLC, including, but not limited to,
in any network or other electronic storage or transmission, or broadcast for distance learning.
Some ancillaries, including electronic and print components, may not be available to customers outside
the United States.
This book is printed on acid-free paper.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 LWI 24 23 22 21 20
ISBN 978-1-266-05230-9
MHID 1-266-05230-5
Cover Image: Shutterstock/photoff

All credits appearing on page or at the end of the book are considered to be an extension of the
copyright page.
The Internet addresses listed in the text were accurate at the time of publication. The inclusion of a website
does not indicate an endorsement by the authors or McGraw Hill LLC, and McGraw Hill LLC does not
guarantee the accuracy of the information presented at these sites.

mheducation.com/highered
D E D I C AT I O N

For Ellen
R. H. F.

For Anna
B. S. B.

For Fiona and Henry


K. A.

For Katrina, Eleanor, Daniel, and Amalia


O. H.
ABO U T T H E AUTHOR S

ROBERT H. FRANK BEN S. BERNANKE


Robert H. Frank is the H. J. Professor Bernanke received his
Louis Professor of Management B.A. in economics from Harvard
and Professor of Economics, University in 1975 and his Ph.D.
emeritus, at Cornell’s Johnson in economics from MIT in 1979.
School of Management, where He taught at the Stanford
he taught from 1972 to 2020. Graduate School of Business
After receiving his B.S. from from 1979 to 1985 and moved to
Georgia Tech in 1966, he taught Princeton University in 1985,
math and science for two years where he was named the Howard
as a Peace Corps Volunteer in Harrison and Gabrielle Snyder
Courtesy of Robert H. Frank rural Nepal. He received his Courtesy of Ben S. Bernanke Beck Professor of Economics
M.A. in statistics in 1971 and and Public Affairs and where he
his Ph.D. in economics in 1972 from The University of California served as chair of the Economics Department. Professor Bernanke
at Berkeley. He also holds honorary doctorate degrees from the is currently a Distinguished Fellow in Residence with the Economic
University of St. Gallen and Dalhousie University. During leaves Studies Program at the Brookings Institution.
of absence from ­Cornell, he has served as chief economist for Professor Bernanke was sworn in on February 1, 2006, as
the Civil Aeronautics Board (1978–1980), a Fellow at the Center chair and a member of the Board of Governors of the Federal
for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences (1992–1993), Reserve System; his second term expired January 31, 2014.
Professor of American Civilization at l’Ecole des Hautes Etudes ­Professor Bernanke also served as chair of the Federal Open
en Sciences Sociales in Paris (2000–2001), and the Peter and Market Committee, the Fed’s principal monetary policymaking
Charlotte Schoenfeld Visiting Faculty Fellow at the NYU Stern body. Professor Bernanke was also chair of the President’s
School of Business in 2008–2009. His papers have appeared in Council of Economic Advisers from June 2005 to January 2006.
the American Economic Review, Econometrica, the Journal of Polit- Professor Bernanke’s intermediate textbook, with Andrew
ical Economy, and other leading professional journals, and for Abel and Dean Croushore, Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
more than two decades, his economics columns appeared regu- (Addison-Wesley, 2017), is a best seller in its field. He has
larly in The New York Times. authored numerous scholarly publications in macroeconomics,
Professor Frank is the author of a best-selling interme- macroeconomic history, and finance. He has done significant
diate economics textbook—Microeconomics and Behavior, research on the causes of the Great Depression, the role of
Tenth ­Edition (McGraw Hill, 2021). His research has focused financial markets and institutions in the business cycle, and
on rivalry and cooperation in economic and social behavior. measurement of the effects of monetary policy on the economy.
His books on these themes include Choosing the Right Pond Professor Bernanke has held a Guggenheim Fellowship and
(Oxford, 1985), Passions Within Reason (W. W. Norton, a Sloan Fellowship, and he is a Fellow of the Econometric
1988), What Price the Moral High Ground? (Princeton, 2004), Society and of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences. He
Falling Behind (University of California Press, 2007), The served as the director of the Monetary Economics Program of
Economic Naturalist (Basic Books, 2007), The Economic the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) and as a
Naturalist’s Field Guide (Basic Books, 2009), The Darwin member of the NBER’s Business Cycle Dating Committee. From
Economy (Princeton, 2011), Success and Luck (Princeton, 2001 to 2004 he served as editor of the American ­Economic
2016), and Under the Influence (Princeton, 2020), which have Review, and as president of the American Economic Association
been translated into 24 languages. The Winner-Take-All Society in 2019. Professor Bernanke’s work with civic and professional
(The Free Press, 1995), co-authored with Philip Cook, groups includes having served two terms as a member of the
received a Critic’s Choice Award, was named a Notable Book Montgomery Township (New Jersey) Board of ­Education.
of the Year by The New York Times, and was included in
BusinessWeek’s list of the 10 best books of 1995. Luxury Fever KATE ANTONOVICS
(The Free Press, 1999) was named to the Knight-Ridder Best
Books list for 1999. Professor Antonovics received
Professor Frank is a co-recipient of the 2004 Leontief her B.A. from Brown Univer-
Prize for Advancing the Frontiers of Economic Thought. sity in 1993 and her Ph.D. in
He was awarded the Johnson School’s Stephen Russell economics from the University
Distinguished Teaching Award in 2004, 2010, 2012, and of Wisconsin in 2000. Shortly
2018, and the School’s Apple Distinguished Teaching Award thereafter, she joined the fac-
in 2005. His introductory microeconomics course has ulty in the Economics Depart-
graduated more than 7,000 enthusiastic economic natural- ment at the University of
ists over the years. Courtesy of Kate Antonovics
California, San Diego. Professor

iv
PR EFAC E

Antonovics is also currently serving as the Provost of UC San


Diego’s Seventh College.
FOCUSED ON SEVEN CORE
Professor Antonovics is known for her excellence in teach- PRINCIPLES TO PRODUCE
ing and her innovative use of technology in the classroom. Her
popular introductory-level microeconomics courses have regu-
ECONOMIC NATURALISTS
larly enrolled over 900 students each fall. She also teaches labor THROUGH ACTIVE LEARNING
economics at both the undergraduate and graduate level. She
Our eighth edition arrives in the midst of some of the
has received numerous teaching awards, including the UCSD
most dramatic upheavals ever witnessed, both in the
Department of Economics award for Best Undergraduate
Teaching, the UCSD Academic Senate Distinguished Teaching economy generally and in higher education in particular.
Award, and the UCSD Chancellor’s Associates Faculty The COVID-19 pandemic has produced levels of unem-
Excellence Award in Undergraduate Teaching. ployment not seen since the Great Depression and has
Professor Antonovics’s research has focused on racial dis- created dramatic changes in the ways we teach across
crimination, gender discrimination, affirmative action, intergen- educational institutions at every level.
erational income mobility, learning, and wage dynamics. Her These developments have reinforced our confidence
papers have appeared in the American Economic Review, the in the instructional philosophy that motivated us to pro-
Review of Economics and Statistics, the Journal of Labor Economics, duce our first edition—the need to strip away clutter and
and the Journal of Human Resources. She is a member of both focus more intensively on central concepts. This
the American Economic Association and the Society of Labor
approach, we believe, is especially well suited for the
Economists.
new environment.
In earlier editions, we noted that although many
ORI HEFFETZ millions of dollars are spent each year on introductory
economics instruction in American colleges and univer-
Professor Heffetz received his
sities, the return on this investment has been disturb-
B.A. in physics and philosophy
ingly low. Studies have shown, for example, that several
from Tel Aviv University in 1999
and his Ph.D. in economics months after having taken a principles of economics
from Princeton University in course, former students are no better able to answer
2005. He is an Associate simple economics questions than others who never even
Professor of Economics at the took the course. Most students, it seems, leave our intro-
Samuel Curtis Johnson Graduate ductory courses without having learned even the most
School of Management at important basic economic principles. Such dismal per-
Cornell University, and at the formance, never defensible, has become even more dif-
Courtesy of Ori Heffetz
Economics Department at the ficult to justify in the face of looming resource shortages
Hebrew University of Jerusalem. in higher education.
Bringing the real world into the classroom, Professor
The problem, in our view, has almost always been
Heffetz has created a unique macroeconomics course that
that courses try to teach students far too much. In the
introduces basic concepts and tools from economic theory and
applies them to current news and global events. His popular process, really important ideas get little more coverage
classes are taken by hundreds of students every year on than minor ones, and everything ends up going by in
Cornell’s Ithaca and New York City campuses and via live a blur. The human brain tends to ignore new informa-
videoconferencing in dozens of cities across the United States, tion unless it comes up repeatedly. That’s hardly sur-
Canada, and Latin America. prising, since only a tiny fraction of the terabytes of
Professor Heffetz’s research studies the social and cultural information that bombard us each day is likely to be
aspects of economic behavior, focusing on the mechanisms that relevant for anything we care about. Only when some-
drive consumers’ choices and on the links between economic thing comes up a third or fourth time does the brain
choices, individual well-being, and policymaking. He has pub- start laying down new circuits for dealing with it. Yet
lished scholarly work on household consumption patterns, indi-
when planning their lectures, many instructors ask
vidual economic decision making, and survey methodology and
themselves, “How much can I cover today?” And
measurement. He was a visiting researcher at the Bank of Israel
during 2011, is currently a Research Associate at the National because modern electronic media enable them to click
Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), and serves on the through upwards of 100 PowerPoint slides in an hour,
editorial board of Social Choice and Welfare. they feel they better serve their students when they put
more information before them. But that’s not the way

v
vi PREFACE

learning works. Professors should instead be asking, “How Learning economics is like learning a language. In each case,
much can my students absorb?” there is no substitution for actually speaking. By inducing
Our approach to this text was inspired by our conviction students to speak economics, The Economic Naturalist exam-
that students will learn far more if we attempt to cover much ples serve this purpose.
less. Our basic premise is that a small number of basic prin- For those who would like to learn more about the role
ciples do most of the heavy lifting in economics, and that if of examples in learning economics, Bob Frank’s lecture on
we focus narrowly and repeatedly on those principles, stu- this topic is posted on YouTube’s “Authors@Google” series
dents can actually master them in just a single semester. The (www.youtube.com/watch?v=QalNVxeIKEE), or search
enthusiastic reactions of users of previous editions of our “Authors@Google Robert Frank”.
textbook affirm the validity of this premise. Avoiding exces-
sive reliance on formal mathematical derivations, we present
concepts intuitively through examples drawn from familiar KEY THEMES AND FEATURES
contexts. We rely throughout on a well-articulated list of Emphasis on Seven Core Principles
seven Core Principles, which we reinforce repeatedly by illus- Because a few Core Principles do most of the work in eco-
trating and applying each principle in numerous contexts. nomics, focusing almost exclusively on these principles
We ask students periodically to apply these principles them- ensures that students leave the course with a deep mastery
selves to answer related questions, exercises, and problems. of them. In contrast, traditional encyclopedic texts so over-
Another distinguishing feature of this text is its explicit whelm students with detail that they often leave the course
recognition of the pedagogical challenge posed by the broad with little useful working knowledge at all.
variance in students’ quantitative backgrounds and in
instructor preferences about the optimal level of mathemat- 1. The Scarcity Principle: Although we have boundless
ical detail for the course. We confront this challenge by needs and wants, the resources available to us are lim-
relegating more detailed mathematical treatment of selected ited. So having more of one good thing usually means
topics to chapter appendices. For example, Chapter 5, having less of another.
Demand, emphasizes the key intuition that underpins utility 2. The Cost-Benefit Principle: An individual (or a firm or
maximization, and relegates the formal presentation of indif- a society) should take an action if, and only if, the extra
ference curves and budget constraints to the appendix, benefits from taking the action are at least as great as
allowing instructors the freedom to choose the approach the extra costs.
that best suits their needs. Similarly, Chapter 25, Spending
and Output in the Short Run, uses diagrams and numerical 3. The Incentive Principle: A person (or a firm or a society)
examples to convey the main ideas behind the basic Keynes- is more likely to take an action if its benefit rises, and less
ian model (the “Keynesian cross”), saving a more general likely to take it if its cost rises. In short, incentives matter.
algebraic analysis to Appendix A and a derivation of the 4. The Principle of Comparative Advantage: Everyone does
multiplier formula to Appendix B—again providing flexibility best when each concentrates on the activity for which
to instructors. Many adopters have cited this additional flex- his or her opportunity cost is lowest.
ibility as a reason for having chosen our book.
Throughout the body of the text, however, our principal 5. The Principle of Increasing Opportunity Cost: In expand-
focus is not on quantitative detail, but rather on students to ing the production of any good, first employ those
become “economic naturalists,” people who employ basic resources with the lowest opportunity cost, and only after-
economic principles to understand and explain what they ward turn to resources with higher opportunity costs.
observe in the world around them. An economic naturalist 6. The Efficiency Principle: Efficiency is an important
understands, for example, that infant safety seats are required social goal because when the economic pie grows larger,
in cars but not in airplanes because the marginal cost of space everyone can have a larger slice.
to accommodate these seats is typically zero in cars but often
hundreds of dollars in airplanes. Scores of such examples are 7. The Equilibrium Principle: A market in equilibrium leaves
sprinkled throughout the book. Each one, we believe, poses no unexploited opportunities for individuals but may not
a question that should make any curious person eager to learn exploit all gains achievable through collective action.
the answer. These examples stimulate interest while teaching
students to see each feature of their economic landscape as Economic Naturalism
the reflection of one or more of the Core Principles. Students Our ultimate goal is to produce economic naturalists—people
talk about these examples with their friends and families. who see each human action as the result of an implicit or
PREFACE vii

explicit cost-benefit calculation. The economic naturalist Ori Heffetz utilize learning glass technology to provide
sees mundane details of ordinary existence in a new light students with an overview of important economic concepts.
and becomes actively engaged in the attempt to understand Perfect for an introduction to basic concepts before coming
them. Some representative examples: to class, or as a quick review, these videos, with accompa-
nying questions, can be assigned within Connect or used as
In Micro:
part of classroom discussion.
• Why do movie theaters offer discount tickets to students? Both The Economic Naturalist and Learning Glass
videos and accompanying multiple-choice questions that test
• Why do we often see convenience stores located on
students’ understanding of the principles illustrated in the
adjacent street corners?
videos have become valued tools for instructors who incor-
• Why do supermarket checkout lines all tend to be porate elements of the flipped-classroom approach in their
roughly the same length? teaching, or those who are relying more heavily on other
forms of remote learning.
In Macro:
• Why does the average Argentine hold more U.S. dollars Modern Microeconomics
than the average U.S. citizen? Economic surplus is more fully developed here than in any
other text. This concept underlies the argument for eco-
• Why does news of inflation hurt the stock market?
nomic efficiency as an important social goal. Rather than
• Why do almost all countries provide free public ­education? speak of trade-offs between efficiency and other goals, we
Economic Naturalist Video Series: We are very excited to stress that maximizing economic surplus facilitates the
offer an expanded video series based on Economic Naturalist achievement of all goals.
examples. A series of videos covering some of our favorite One of the biggest hurdles to the fruitful application of
micro- and macro-focused examples can be used as part of cost-benefit thinking is to recognize and measure the relevant
classroom presentations or assigned for homework along costs and benefits. Common decision pitfalls identified by
with accompanying questions within McGraw Hill ­Connect®. 2002 Nobel laureate Daniel Kahneman and others—such as
These fascinating, fun, and thought-provoking applications the tendency to ignore implicit costs, the tendency not to
of economics in everyday life encourage students to think ignore sunk costs, and the tendency to confuse average and
like an economist. Refer to the distinguishing features pages marginal costs and benefits—are introduced in Chapter 1,
of the preface for additional information. You can view one Thinking Like an Economist, and discussed repeatedly in
of these dynamic videos here: http://econeveryday.com/why- subsequent chapters.
do-cooked-rotisserie-chickens-cost-less-than-fresh-uncooked- There is perhaps no more exciting toolkit for the eco-
chickens/. nomic naturalist than a few principles of elementary game
theory. In Chapter 9, Games and Strategic Behavior, we show
how these principles enable students to answer a variety of
Active Learning Stressed strategic questions that arise in the marketplace and every-
The only way to learn to hit an overhead smash in tennis is day life. In new Chapter 10, An Introduction to Behavioral
through repeated practice. The same is true for learning Economics, we survey many of the most exciting develop-
economics. Accordingly, we consistently introduce new ments in what has become the economics profession’s most
ideas in the context of simple examples and then follow vibrant new field. We believe that the insights of Nobel
them with applications showing how they work in familiar ­laureate Ronald Coase are indispensable for understanding
settings. At frequent intervals, we pose self-tests that both a host of familiar laws, customs, and social norms. In
test and reinforce the understanding of these ideas. The end- Chapter 11, Externalities, Property Rights, and the Environ-
of-chapter questions and problems are carefully crafted to ment, we show how such devices function to minimize mis-
help students internalize and extend basic concepts and are allocations that result from externalities.
available within Connect as assignable content so that
instructors can require students to engage with this material. Modern Macroeconomics
Experience with earlier editions confirms that this approach Both the Great Recession and the COVID-19 pandemic have
really does prepare students to apply basic economic prin- renewed interest in cyclical fluctuations without ­challenging
ciples to solve economic puzzles drawn from the real world. the importance of such long-run issues as growth, productiv-
Learning Glass Lecture Videos: A collection of brief instruc- ity, the evolution of real wages, and capital formation. Our
tional videos featuring the authors Kate Antonovics and treatment of these issues is organized as follows:
viii PREFACE

• A five-chapter treatment of long-run issues, followed by Chapter 2


a modern treatment of short-term fluctuations and stabi- • Updated student-centered examples, such as interior
lization policy, emphasizes the important distinction designer Kelly Wearstler
between short- and long-run behavior of the economy. • Updated section on comparative advantage and out-
• Designed to allow for flexible treatment of topics, these sourcing, including updates related to the United States-
chapters are written so that short-run material Mexico-Canada Agreement
(Chapters 24–27) can be used before long-run material • New end-of-chapter problem related to outsourcing
(Chapters 19–23) with no loss of continuity. Chapter 3
• The analysis of aggregate demand and aggregate supply • Updated student-centered examples, such as digital
relates output to inflation, rather than to the price level, versus print ads and Marvel Studio films
sidestepping the necessity of a separate derivation of • New Economic Naturalist, “Why was there a shortage
the link between the output gap and inflation. The dis- of toilet paper during the COVID-19 pandemic?”
cussion of monetary policy has two parts. It starts with
• Three new end-of-chapter questions that reinforce the
a standard supply and demand analysis of the market
chapter’s learning objectives, including a question
for money that is centered on the short-run interest
related to the drop in crude oil prices during the coro-
rate. It then introduces the new tools of monetary pol-
navirus pandemic
icy, such as quantitative easing and forward guidance,
that have been so important since 2008, and that again Chapter 4
took center stage in the 2020 response to the pandemic. • Minor updates only
• This book places a heavy emphasis on globalization, Chapter 5
starting with an analysis of its effects on real wage • Updated student-centered examples, such as LeBron
inequality and progressing to such issues as the costs James
and benefits of—and the likely winners and losers from— • New Economic Naturalist, “Why would Jeff Bezos
trade, the causes and effects of protectionism, the role live in a smaller house in Manhattan than in Medina,
of capital flows in domestic capital formation, the link Washington?”
between exchange rates and monetary policy, and the Chapter 6
sources of speculative attacks on currencies.
• Minor updates only
Chapter 7
CHANGES IN THE EIGHTH EDITION • Minor updates only
Changes Common to All Chapters Chapter 8
In all chapters, the narrative has been tightened. Many of • Updated student-centered examples, such as Instagram,
the examples have been updated, with a focus on student- electric scooter rentals, iTunes, HBO, Netflix, and cable
centered examples that connect to current topics such as Internet
the COVID-19 pandemic and the rise of the gig economy. • Updated end-of-chapter problems
The examples, self-tests, and end-of-chapter material
from the previous edition have been redesigned to provide Chapter 9
more clarity and ease of use. Data have been updated • Updated student-centered examples, such as the Ford
throughout. Mustang and Chevrolet Camaro
Chapter 10
Chapter-by-Chapter Changes • New Economic Naturalist, “Why have attempts to pri-
vatize Social Security proved so politically unpopular in
Chapter 1
the United States?”
• Updated student-centered examples, such as Netflix,
wireless keyboards, dogwalking, and Jeff Bezos • New Economic Naturalist, “If prosperous voters would
be happier if they spent less on positional goods and
• New and updated end-of-chapter problems that rein- lived in environments with more generously funded
force the chapter’s learning objectives public sectors, why haven’t they elected politicians who
• Updated appendix on working with equations, graphs, would deliver what they want?”
and tables based on electric scooter rentals • Updated the discussion of relative position
PREFACE ix

Chapter 11 Chapter 19
• Updated student-centered examples, such as roommate • Updated examples, data, and figures
conflicts
Chapter 20
• Updated information on carbon taxes, including men- • Clarification throughout the chapter of the difference
tion of the Paris Agreement between trends in average incomes and trends in income
• Updated end-of-chapter questions inequality
Chapter 12 • Updated discussion of globalization that now includes
• Updated student-centered examples, such as the gig recent developments, including the political opposition
economy and apps like Uber and Lyft to the Trans-Pacific Partnership trade agreement and
the Trump administration’s resistance to increased eco-
• Updated discussion of the Affordable Care Act
nomic integration of the U.S. with China
Chapter 13
• New Economic Naturalist, “Can technology hurt
• Updated student-centered examples, such as Serena
­workers?,” that includes what was previously a para-
Williams and Taylor Swift
graph on workers’ resistance to new technology (with
• Updated discussion of welfare benefits and in-kind anecdotes on Ned Ludd and the tale of John Henry);
transfers the new EN highlights workers’ concerns about auto-
mation, robotics, and artificial intelligence (AI)
• New end-of-chapter question related to income redistri-
bution • New Economic Naturalist, “How did the COVID-19
Chapter 14 pandemic affect the demand for U.S. jobs,” that dis-
• Updated student-centered examples, such as video cusses the different effects the epidemic is having on
streaming services like Netflix different jobs in different sectors

Chapter 15 • New discussion of European labor markets that high-


• Revised Economic Naturalist that discusses the lights the deregulation in southern Europe following the
U.S.-China trade war that started in 2018, highlighting global financial crisis and that, on some metrics,
that there is more to trade than the exchange of goods Europe’s labor market does better than the U.S. labor
and services and its supply and demand analysis in this market
chapter; also covers issues such as intellectual property
Chapter 21
and national security
• Updates related to the COVID-19 economic downturn
Chapter 16 that include the discussion of U.S. household saving
• Updated discussion of growth that reflects higher Internet early in the chapter and the discussion of the U.S. gov-
and cell phone penetration ernment deficit later in the chapter
• Updated discussion of recessions and expansions that • New Economic Naturalist, “Why have real interest rates
mentions the COVID-19 economic disruptions declined globally in recent decades?,” that discusses the
Chapter 17 combination of higher global saving and lower global
• Updated discussion of the correlation between per cap- investment that helps explain the downward trend in
ita GDP and health outcomes such as life expectancy real interest rates
that now mentions that within high-income countries,
Chapter 22
the relationship can even reverse, with examples of data
from the U.S., Canada, and Japan • New discussion of the Fed’s role in stabilizing financial
markets and as lender of last resort, which took center
Chapter 18 stage in recent episodes of financial panic; the discus-
• Updated discussion of the development of real wages sion covers Section 13(3) landing during the 2008 and
for production workers and for highly paid baseball 2020 crises
players over time that is now linked together, in the
context of a new discussion about increasing wage Chapter 23
inequalities between the highest- and lowest-paid U.S. • Updates related to recent U.S.-China trade frictions, in
workers the discussion of the saving rate and the trade deficit
x PREFACE

• Updates related to the COVID-19 pandemic and finan- A NOTE ON THE WRITING
cial markets
OF THIS EDITION
Chapter 24 Ben Bernanke was sworn in on February 1, 2006, as chair
• Updates related to the COVID-19 downturn and a member of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, a position to which he was reappointed
• Revised Economic Naturalist 24.3 that includes discus- in January 2010. From June 2005 until January 2006, he
sion of the gig economy in the context of the natural served as chair of the President’s Council of Economic
rate of unemployment in the U.S. Advisers. These positions have allowed him to play an
active role in making U.S. economic policy, but the rules
Chapter 25
of government service have restricted his ability to partic-
• Revised Economic Naturalist 25.5 that discusses the ipate in the preparation of previous editions. Since his
U.S. government’s response to the COVID-19 pandemic second term as chair of the Federal Reserve has com-
and covers details of the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and pleted, we are happy that Ben is actively involved in the
Economic Security (CARES) Act of 2020 and their revision of the macro portion of this edition.
economic rationale

• Other COVID-19-related updates


ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Chapter 26 Our thanks first and foremost go to our portfolio director,
• Updates related to COVID-19: in the context of banks’ Anke Weekes, and our product developer, Christina
excess reserves, in the context of the Fed’s quick cuts Kouvelis. Anke encouraged us to think deeply about how to
of the federal funds rate, in the context of quantitative improve the book and helped us transform our ideas into
easing (QE) and the Fed’s special landing in 2020, and concrete changes. Christina shepherded us through the revi-
in the context of the Fed’s return to forward guidance sion process with intelligence, sound advice, and good
in 2020; the chapter highlights the unprecedented speed humor. We are grateful as well to the production team,
and severity of the pandemic’s economic hit, and there- whose professionalism (and patience) was outstanding:
fore the unprecedented speed and size of the policy Christine Vaughan, content project manager; Keri Johnson,
response assessment project manager; Matt Diamond, lead designer;
and all of those who worked on the production team to turn
• Revisions throughout the chapter that reflect recent our manuscript into the text you see now. Finally, we also
developments in thinking about QE, forward guid- thank Bobby Pearson, marketing manager, for getting our
ance, and other methods; when introduced in 2008, message into the wider world.
these methods were viewed as “unconventional” Special thanks to Per Norander, University of North
and “temporary”; the chapter now observes that Carolina at Charlotte, for his energy, creativity, and help in
such methods are increasingly recognized as a “new refining the assessment material in Connect; Sukanya
normal” Kemp, University of Akron, for her detailed accuracy check
of the learning glass and economic naturalist videos; Alvin
Chapter 27
Angeles and team at the University of California, San Diego,
• Updates to The Economic Naturalist 27.5, “Can infla-
for their efforts in the production and editing of the learning
tion be too low?,” to cover the Fed’s unprecedented
glass videos; and Kevin Bertotti and the team at ITVK for
response to COVID-19
their creativity in transforming Economic Naturalist exam-
Chapter 28 ples into dynamic and engaging video vignettes.
Finally, our sincere thanks to the following teachers
• New The Economic Naturalist 28.2, “What is a safe
and colleagues, whose thorough reviews and thoughtful
haven currency?,” (such as the U.S. dollar, the Swiss
suggestions led to innumerable substantive improvements to
franc, and the Japanese yen), and how they tend to
Principles of Economics, 8/e.
appreciate in periods of uncertainty; includes specific
examples from the 2008 global financial crisis and the
2020 global coronavirus crisis Mark Abajian, San Diego Mesa College
Richard Agesa, Marshall University
• Updated The Economic Naturalist 28.4 that covers the
IMF’s COVID-19-related landing in early 2020 Seemi Ahmad, Dutchess Community College
PREFACE xi

Donald L. Alexander, Western Michigan University Derek Johnson, University of Connecticut


Jason Aimone, Baylor University Sukanya Kemp, University of Akron
Chris Azevedo, University of Central Missouri Brian Kench, University of Tampa
Narine Badasyan, Murray State University Fredric R. Kolb, University of Wisconsin–Eau Claire
Sigridur Benediktsdottir, Yale University Daniel D. Kuester, Kansas State University
Robert Blewett, St. Lawrence University Valerie Lacarte, American University
Brian C. Brush, Marquette University Donald J. Liu, University of Minnesota–Twin Cities
Christopher Burkart, University of West Florida Brian Lynch, Lake Land College
Colleen Callahan, American University Christine Malakar, Lorain Community College
Giuliana Campanelli Andreopoulos, William Paterson Ida Mirzaie, The Ohio State University
University Thuy Lan Nguyen, Santa Clara University
J. Lon Carlson, Illinois State University Jelena Nikolic, Northeastern University
David Chaplin, Northwest Nazarene University Anthony A. Noce, State University of New York
Monica Cherry, Saint John Fisher College (SUNY)–Plattsburgh
Joni Charles, Texas State University Diego Nocetti, Clarkson University
Anoshua Chaudhuri, San Francisco State University Stephanie Owings, Fort Lewis College
Nan-Ting Chou, University of Louisville Dishant Pandya, Spalding University
Maria Luisa Corton, University of South Florida– Martin Pereyra, University of Missouri
St. Petersburg Tony Pizelo, Northwest University
Manabendra Dasgupta, University of Alabama Ratha Ramoo, Diablo Valley College
at Birmingham
Thomas Rhoads, Towson University
Craig Dorsey, College of DuPage
Bill Robinson, University of Nevada–Las Vegas
Dennis Edwards, Coastal Carolina University
Brian Rosario, University of California–Davis
Tracie Edwards, University of Missouri–St. Louis
Elyce Rotella, Indiana University
Roger Frantz, San Diego State University
Jeffrey Rubin, Rutgers University
Mark Frascatore, Clarkson University
Naveen Sarna, Northern Virginia Community College
Amanda Freeman, Kansas State University
Henry Schneider, Queen’s University
Greg George, Macon State College
Sumati Srinivas, Radford University
Seth Gershenson, Michigan State University
Thomas Stevens, University of Massachusetts
Amy D. Gibson, Christopher Newport University
Carolyn Fabian Stumph, Indiana University and
Rajeev Goel, Illinois State University Purdue University–Fort Wayne
Mehdi Haririan, Bloomsburg University of Pennsylvania Albert Sumell, Youngstown State University
Susan He, Washington State University Markland Tuttle, Sam Houston State University
John Hejkal, University of Iowa David Vera, California State University–Fresno
Kuang-Chung Hsu, Kishwaukee College Nancy Virts, California State University–Northridge
Greg Hunter, California State University–Pomona Gilbert J. Werema, Texas Woman’s University
Nick Huntington-Klein, California State University–Fullerton Elizabeth Wheaton, Southern Methodist University
Andres Jauregui, Columbus State University Amanda Wilsker, Georgia Gwinnett College
David W. Johnson, University of Wisconsin–Madison William C. Wood, James Madison University
D IST IN G UI S HI N G F EATUR ES

ECONOMIC
NATURALIST
EXAMPLES
Each Economic Natural-
ist example starts with a
question to spark curios-
ity and interest in learn-
ing an answer. These
examples fuel interest
while teaching students
to see ­economics in the
world around them. Videos of
select and new Economic ­Naturalist
examples are denoted in the margin
of the material to which they per-
tain and they are housed within
Connect. A full list of ­Economic
Naturalist examples and videos can
be found in the following pages.

4 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

NUMBERED EXAMPLES
EXA MPL E 1.1 Comparing Costs and Benefits
Throughout the text, numbered and titled Should you walk downtown to save $10 on a $25 wireless keyboard?
examples are referenced and called out to fur- Imagine you are about to buy a $25 wireless keyboard at the nearby campus store
when a friend tells you that the same keyboard is on sale at a downtown store for
ther illustrate concepts. Our engaging questions only $15. If the downtown store is a 30-minute walk away, where should you buy
the keyboard?
and examples from everyday life highlight how Cost-Benefit
The Cost-Benefit Principle tells us that you should buy it downtown if the benefit
of doing so exceeds the cost. The benefit of taking any action is the dollar value
each human
32
action is the result of an implicit
CHAPTER 2 COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE
of everything you gain by taking it. Here, the benefit of buying downtown is exactly
$10, because that’s the amount you’ll save on the price of the keyboard. The cost
or explicit cost-benefit calculation. of taking any action is the dollar value of everything you give up by taking it. Here,
The alternative to a system in which everyone is a the cost of buying downtown is the dollar value you assign to the time and trouble
jack-of-all-trades is one in which people specialize in par- it takes to make the trip. But how do we estimate that value?
ticular goods and services and then satisfy their needs by One way is to perform the following hypothetical auction. Imagine that a stranger
has offered to pay you to do an errand that involves the same walk downtown
trading among themselves. Economic systems based on (perhaps to drop off a package for her at the post office). If she offered you a pay-
specialization and the exchange of goods and services are ment of, say, $1,000, would you accept? If so, we know that your cost of walking
generally far more productive than those with little spe- downtown and back must be less than $1,000. Now imagine her offer being reduced
Courtesy of Robert H. Frank

cialization. Our task in this chapter is to investigate why in small increments until you finally refuse the last offer. For example, if you’d agree
this is so. to walk downtown and back for $9 but not for $8.99, then your cost of making
the trip is $9. In this case, you should buy the keyboard downtown because the
As this chapter will show, the reason that specializa-
$10 you’ll save (your benefit) is greater than your $9 cost of making the trip.
tion is so productive is comparative advantage. Roughly, But suppose your cost of making the trip had been greater than $10. In that
a person has a comparative advantage at producing a case, your best bet would have been to buy the keyboard from the nearby cam-
particular good or service (say, haircuts) if that person pus store. Confronted with this choice, different people may choose differently,
is relatively more efficient at producing haircuts than at Did this man perform most of his depending on how costly they think it is to make the trip downtown. But although
own services because he was there is no uniquely correct choice, most people who are asked what they would
producing other goods or services. We will see that we
poor, or was he poor because do in this situation say they would buy the keyboard downtown.
can all have more of every good and service if each of us he performed most of his own
specializes in the activities at which we have a compara- services?
tive advantage.
ECONOMIC SURPLUS
This chapter also will introduce the production possibilities curve, which is a graphical
method of describing the combinations of goods and services that an economy can pro- Suppose that in Example 1.1 your “cost” of making the trip downtown was $9. Compared
duce. This tool will allow us to see more clearly how specialization enhances the produc-to the alternative of buying the keyboard at the campus store, buying it downtown
economic surplus the resulted in an economic surplus of $1, the difference between the benefit of making the
tive capacity of even the simplest economy. trip and its cost. In general, your goal as an economic decision maker is to choose those
benefit of taking an action
minus its cost
Cost-Benefit
CORE PRINCIPLES
actions that generate the largest possible economic surplus. This means taking all actions
that yield a positive total economic surplus, which is just another way of restating the Cost-
EXCHANGE AND OPPORTUNITY COST Benefit Principle.

There are seven Core Principles that we


Note that the fact that your best choice was to buy the keyboard downtown doesn’t imply
The Scarcity Principle (see Chapter 1, Thinking Like an Economist) reminds us that the that you enjoy making the trip, any more than choosing a large class means that you prefer
Scarcity
opportunity cost of spending more time on any one activity is having less time available large classes to small ones. It simply means that the trip is less unpleasant than the prospect
focus on to ensure student mastery.
of paying $10 extra for the keyboard. Once again, you’ve faced a trade-off. In this case, the
to spend on others. As the following example makes clear, this principle helps explain choice was between a cheaper keyboard and the free time gained by avoiding the trip.
why everyone can do better by concentrating on those activities at which he or she per- Throughout the text, these principles
forms best relative to others. OPPORTUNITY COST
areauction
Of course, your mental called out
could have and
produced areoutcome.
a different denoted
Suppose, for by an

EXAMPLE 2 .1 Scarcity Principle iconday. Orin the margin.


watching one ofAgain, theon seven
example, that the time required for the trip is the only time you have left to study for a
difficult test the next suppose you are your favorite shows
opportunity cost the value Netflix, or that you are tired and would love a short nap. In such cases, we say that the
of what must be forgone to opportunity cost ofCore
making thePrinciples are:
trip—that is, the value scarcity,
of what cost-benefit,
you must sacrifice to walk
Should Kelly Wearstler design her own web page?undertake an activity downtown and back—is high and you are more likely to decide against making the trip.
Kelly Wearstler is among the most famous and influential interior designers in the incentive, comparative advantage, increas-
United States today. She has received numerous accolades for her commercial
and residential design work, has completed projects for top celebrities such as
ing opportunity cost, efficiency, and equi-
Cameron Diaz, Gwen Stefani, and Ben Stiller, and boasts more than 700,000 librium.
followers on Instagram. fra32893_ch01_001-030.indd 4 7/20/20 10:21 AM

Although Kelly devotes most of her time and talent to interior design, she
is well equipped to do a broad range of other design work. Suppose Kelly
xii could design her own web page in 300 hours, half the time it would take any
other web designer. Does that mean that Kelly should design her own web
page?
Suppose that on the strength of her talents as an interior designer, Kelly earns
ages

more than $1 million a year, implying that the opportunity cost of any time she
reservation price must be only $2.
CHAPTER 3 SUPPLY AND DEMAND We defined the demand curve for any good as a schedule telling how much of it
consumers wish to purchase at various prices. This is called the horizontal interpretation
of the demand curve. Using the horizontal interpretation, we start with price on the
DISTINGUISHING
vertical axis and read the corresponding quantity horizontal axis. Thus,xiii
demanded on theFEATURES
URE 3.9 Supply
at a price of $4 per slice, the demand curve in Figure 3.1 tells us that the quantity of
Controls in the Pizza
pizza demanded will be 8,000 slices per day.
et. 4
The demand curve also can be interpreted in a second way, which is to start with
ce ceiling below the
quantity on the horizontal axis and then read the marginal buyer’s reservation price on

Price ($/slice)
brium price of pizza 3 Excess demand = 8,000
d result in excess slices/day the vertical axis. Thus, when the quantity of pizza sold is 8,000 slices per day, the demand
and for pizza. Price ceiling = 2 curve in Figure 3.1 tells us that the marginal buyer’s reservation price is $4 per slice. This
second way of reading the demand curve is called the vertical interpretation.
Demand
SELF-TESTS
SELF-TEST 3.1
These self-test questions 0 in the 8body 12 of16the chapter
In Figure 3.1, what is the marginal buyer’s reservation price when the quantity
Quantity (1,000s of slices/day)
enable students to determine whether the preced- of pizza sold is 10,000 slices per day? For the same demand curve, what will
ing material has been understood and reinforce be the quantity of pizza demanded at a price of $2.50 per slice?
The very idea of not being able to buy a pizza seems absurd, yet precisely such things
understanding before reading further. Detailed
happen routinely in markets in which prices are held below the equilibrium levels. For
answers to the
example, prior self-test
to the questions
collapse of communist are found itatwasthe
governments, consideredTHE SUPPLY
normal in CURVE
end
thoseof each for
countries chapter.
people to stand in line for hours to buy bread and other basic goods,
supply curve a graph or In the market for pizza, the supply curve is a simple schedule or graph that tells us,
while the politically connected had first choice of those goods that were available.
schedule showing the for each possible price, the total number of slices that all pizza vendors would be
quantity of a good that sellers willing to sell at that price. What does the supply curve of pizza look like? The answer
wish to sell at each price R to
E Cthis
RECAP
A Pquestion is based on the logical assumption that suppliers should be willing to
MARKET EQUILIBRIUM sell additional slices as long as the price they receive is sufficient to cover their oppor-
Sprinkled
tunity cost of supplying throughout
them. Thus, each could
if what someone chapter
earn are Recap
by selling boxes
a slice of
Market equilibrium, the situation in which all buyers and sellers are satisfied
pizza is insufficientthat underscore
to compensate and
her for summarize
what the
she could have importance
earned if she had of the
spent
with their respective quantities at the market price, occurs at the intersection
of the supply and demand curves. The corresponding price and quantity are
her time and invested her moneymaterial
preceding in some other
and way,
keyshe will not takeaways.
concept sell that slice. Oth-
called the equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity. erwise, she will.
Unless prevented by regulation, prices and quantities are driven toward Just as buyers differ with respect to the amounts they are willing to pay for pizza,
their equilibrium values by the actions of buyers and sellers. If thesellers price also
is differ with respect to their opportunity cost of supplying pizza. For those with
initially too high, so that there is excess supply, frustrated sellers willlimited
cut theireducation and work experience, the opportunity cost of selling pizza is relatively
price in order to sell more. If the price is initially too low, so thatlow there is
(because such individuals typically do not have a lot of high-paying alternatives). For
excess demand, competition among buyers drives the price upward. others,This
the opportunity cost of selling pizza is of moderate value, and for still others—like
process continues until equilibrium is reached. rock stars and professional athletes—it is prohibitively high. In part because of these dif-
ferences in opportunity cost among people, the daily supply curve of pizza will be
upward-sloping with respect to price. As an illustration, see Figure 3.2, which shows a
hypothetical supply curve for pizza in the Chicago market on a given day.
PREDICTING AND EXPLAINING CHANGES IN
PRICES AND
WORKED QUANTITIES
PROBLEM VIDEOS
If we know how the factors that govern supply and demand curves are changing, we can
Brief videos predictions
make informed work through
about how end-of-chapter problems
prices and the corresponding quantities will change.
toButaid in describing
when studentchanging
understanding
circumstances ofincore economic
the marketplace, we must take care to
recognize some important terminological distinctions.60For example, we must distinguish
e in the quantity
concepts and offer assistance with more
fra32893_ch03_055-088.indd
challeng-
between the meanings of the seemingly similar expressions change in the quantity demanded
8/4/20 10:07 AM

nded a movement ing


and material. The When
change in demand. videos are ofavailable
we speak a “change inas thehints
quantity demanded,” this
the demand curve that means the
within change in the quantity that people wish to buy that occurs in response to a
Connect.
in response to a change in price. For instance, Figure 3.10(a) depicts an increase in the quantity demanded
e in price that occurs in response to a reduction in the price of tuna. When the price falls from $2
to $1 per can, the quantity demanded rises from 8,000 to 10,000 cans per day. By contrast,
e in demand a shift of
when we speak of a “change in demand,” this means a shift in the entire demand curve.
tire demand curve
For example, Figure 3.10(b) depicts an increase in demand, meaning that at every price
the quantity demanded is higher than before. In summary, a “change in the quantity
demanded” refers to a movement along the demand curve and a “change in demand”
means a shift of the entire curve.

LEARNING GLASS VIDEOS


Dozens of lecture videos featuring authors Kate
88.indd 68 8/4/20 10:07 AM
Antonovics and Ori Heffetz utilize learning glass
technology to provide you with an overview of
important concepts. These videos can be accessed
as resources within SmartBook® or as assignable
content via McGraw Hill Connect®
ECONOMIC NATURALIST VIDEO SERIES

Asymmetric Information: Why do “almost new” used cars sell Money and Its Uses: Is there such a thing as private, or
for so much less than brand new ones? ­communicably traded, money?
Behavioral Economics: Why do real estate agents often show Monopolistic Competition: Why do we often see convenience
clients two nearly identical houses, even though one is both stores located on adjacent street corners?
cheaper and in better condition than the other? Prisoner’s Dilemma: Why do people shout at parties?
Commercial Banking: Why can it be more expensive to Production Costs: Why are brown eggs more expensive than
­transfer funds between banks electronically than it is to white ones?
send a check through the mail? Saving: Why do American households save so little while
Comparative Advantage: iPhones: Designed in California, but ­Chinese households save so much?
assembled in China Sources of Increasing Inequality: Why have the salaries of
Cost Benefit 1: Why does the light come on when you open top earners been growing so much faster than everyone
the refrigerator door but not when you open the freezer? else’s?
Cost Benefit 2: Why are child safety seats required in auto- Supply and Demand: Why are rotisserie chickens less
mobiles but not in airplanes? ­expensive than fresh chickens?
Discount Pricing: Why might an appliance retailer hammer Tariffs: Why do consumers in the United States often pay
dents into the sides of its stoves and refrigerators? more than double the world price for sugar?
Economy Strength and Currency Value: Does a strong The Demand for Money: Why does the average Argentine
­currency imply a strong economy? ­citizen hold more U.S. dollars than the average U.S. citizen?
Elasticity: Why do people buy the same amount of salt as The Invisible Hand: Why do supermarket checkout lines all
before even when the price of salt doubles? tend to be roughly the same length?
Human Capital: Why do almost all countries provide free The Law of Demand: Why are smaller automobile engines
­education? more common in Europe than in the United States?
Incentive Problems and Inefficiency: Why does the practice The Optimal Amount of Information: Why might a patient
of check splitting cause people to spend more at restaurants? be more likely to receive an expensive magnetic resonance
Inflation and Cost of Living: Do official inflation figures ­imaging (MRI) exam for a sore knee if covered under a con-
overstate actual increases in our living costs? ventional health insurance rather than a health maintenance
Inflation: Can inflation be too low? organization (HMO) plan?
Marginal Product of Labor: Why do female models earn so The Tragedy of the Commons and Property Rights: Why
much more than male models? do blackberries in public parks get picked before they’re
Menu Costs: Will new technologies eliminate menu costs? ­completely ripe?

xiv
E CO N O M I C N ATUR A LI ST EXA MP LE S

1.1 Why do many hardware manufacturers include more than 9.1 Why are cartel agreements notoriously unstable?
$1,000 worth of “free” software with a computer selling 9.2 How did Congress unwittingly solve the television
for only slightly more than that? advertising dilemma confronting cigarette producers?
1.2 Why don’t auto manufacturers make cars without 9.3 Why do people shout at parties?
­heaters? 9.4 Why do we often see convenience stores located on
1.3 Why do the keypad buttons on drive-up automated teller adjacent street corners?
machines have Braille dots? 10.1 Why did the American Olympic swimmer Shirley
2.1 Where have all the .400 hitters gone? Babashoff, who set one world record and six national
2.2 What happened to the U.S. lead in the television market? records at the 1976 Olympics, refuse to appear on the
2.3 If trade among nations is so beneficial, why are free- cover of Sports Illustrated?
trade agreements so controversial? 10.2 Why would people pay thousands of dollars to attend a
2.4 Is PBS economics reporter Paul Solman’s job a likely weight-loss camp that will feed them only 1,500 calories
candidate for outsourcing? per day?
3.1 When the federal government implements a large pay 10.3 Why was Obamacare difficult to enact and harder still to
increase for its employees, why do rents for apartments repeal?
located near Washington Metro stations go up relative to 10.4 Why have attempts to privatize Social Security proved so
rents for apartments located far away from Metro stations? politically unpopular in the United States?
3.2 Why do major term papers go through so many more 10.5 If prosperous voters would be happier if they spent less
revisions today than in the 1970s? on positional goods and lived in environments with more
3.3 Why do the prices of some goods, like airline tickets to generously funded public sectors, why haven’t they
Europe, go up during the months of heaviest elected politicians who would deliver what they want?
consumption, while others, like sweet corn, go down? 11.1 What is the purpose of free speech laws?
3.4 Why was there a shortage of toilet paper during the 11.2 Why do many states have laws requiring students to be
COVID-19 pandemic? vaccinated against childhood illnesses?
4.1 Will a higher tax on cigarettes curb teenage smoking? 11.3 Why does the government subsidize private property
4.2 Why was the luxury tax on yachts such a disaster? owners to plant trees on their hillsides?
4.3 Why are gasoline prices so much more volatile than car
11.4 Why do blackberries in public parks get picked too soon?
prices?
11.5 Why are shared milkshakes consumed too quickly?
5.1 Why does California experience chronic water shortages?
11.6 Why do football players take anabolic steroids?
5.2 Why would Jeff Bezos live in a smaller house in
12.1 Why is finding a knowledgeable salesclerk often difficult?
Manhattan than in Medina, Washington?
5.3 Why did people turn to four-cylinder cars in the 1970s, 12.2 Why did Rivergate Books, the last bookstore in
only to shift back to six- and eight-cylinder cars in the Lambertville, New Jersey, go out of business?
1990s? 12.3 Why do firms insert the phrase “As advertised on TV”
5.4 Why are automobile engines smaller in England than in when they advertise their products in magazines and
the United States? social media?
5.5 Why are waiting lines longer in poorer neighborhoods? 12.4 Why do many companies care so much about elite
6.1 When recycling is left to private market forces, why are educational credentials?
many more aluminum beverage containers recycled than 12.5 Why do many clients seem to prefer lawyers who wear
glass ones? expensive suits?
7.1 Why do supermarket checkout lines all tend to be 12.6 Why do males under 25 years of age pay more than
roughly the same length? other drivers for auto insurance?
7.2 Are there “too many” smart people working as corporate 12.7 Why do opponents of the death penalty often remain
earnings forecasters? silent?
8.1 Why does Intel sell the overwhelming majority of all 12.8 Why do proponents of legalized drugs remain silent?
microprocessors used in personal computers? 13.1 If unionized firms have to pay more, how do they
8.2 Why do many movie theaters offer discount tickets to manage to survive in the face of competition from their
students? nonunionized counterparts?
8.3 Why might an appliance retailer instruct its clerks to 13.2 Why do some ad copywriters earn more than others?
hammer dents into the sides of its stoves and 13.3 Why does Taylor Swift earn many millions more than
refrigerators? singers with only slightly less talent?
xv
xvi ECONOMIC NATURALIST EXAMPLES

14.1 Why don’t most married couples contribute equally to 24.1 Do economic fluctuations affect presidential elections?
joint purchases? 24.2 How was the 2007 recession called?
14.2 Why do television networks favor NFL Sunday Night 24.3 Why has the natural rate of unemployment in the United
Football over Masterpiece? States declined?
14.3 Why does check-splitting make the total restaurant bill 24.4 Why did the Federal Reserve act to slow down the
higher? economy in 1999 and 2000?
14.4 Why do legislators often support one another’s pork 25.1 Will new technologies eliminate menu costs?
barrel spending programs? 25.2 How did the decline in U.S. stock market values from
15.1 What is the China trade shock? 2000–2002 affect consumption spending?
15.2 Why did the U.S. start a Trade War with China? 25.3 What caused the 2007–2009 recession in the United
15.3 What is fast track authority? States?
17.1 Can nominal and real GDP ever move in different 25.4 Does military spending stimulate the economy?
directions? 25.5 Why did the federal government temporarily cut taxes in
17.2 Why do people work fewer hours today than their great- 2001, 2009, and 2020?
grandparents did? 26.1 Why does the average Argentine hold more U.S. dollars
17.3 Why do far fewer children complete high school in poor than the average U.S. citizen?
countries than in rich countries? 26.2 How did the Fed respond to recession and the terrorist
18.1 Every few years, there is a well-publicized battle in attacks in 2001?
Congress over whether the minimum wage should be 26.3 Why did the Fed raise interest rates 17 times in a row
raised. Why do these heated legislative debates recur so between 2004 and 2006?
regularly? 26.4 Why does news of inflation hurt the stock market?
19.1 Why did West Germany and Japan recover so 26.5 Should the Federal Reserve respond to changes in asset
successfully from the devastation of World War II? prices?
19.2 Why did U.S. labor productivity grow so rapidly in the 26.6 What is the Taylor rule?
late 1990s? 27.1 How did inflation get started in the United States in the
19.3 Why did medieval China stagnate economically? 1960s?
19.4 Why do almost all countries provide free public education? 27.2 Why did oil price increases cause U.S. inflation to
20.1 Can new technology hurt workers? escalate in the 1970s but not in the 2000s and 2010s?
20.2 How did the COVID-19 pandemic affect the demand for 27.3 Why was the United States able to experience rapid
U.S. jobs? growth and low inflation in the latter part of the 1990s?
21.1 How did many American households increase their 27.4 How was inflation conquered in the 1980s?
wealth in the 1990s and 2000s while saving very little? 27.5 Can inflation be too low?
21.2 Why do Chinese households save so much? 28.1 Does a strong currency imply a strong economy?
21.3 Why do U.S. households save so little? 28.2 What is a safe haven currency?
21.4 Why have real interest rates declined globally in recent 28.3 Why did the dollar appreciate nearly 50 percent in the
decades? first half of the 1980s and nearly 40 percent in the
22.1 From Ithaca Hours to Bitcoin: what is private money, second half of the 1990s?
communally created money, and open-source money? 28.4 What were the causes and consequences of the East
22.2 Why did the banking panics of 1930–1933 reduce the Asian ­crisis of 1997–1998?
national money supply? 28.5 What is the IMF, and how has its mission evolved over
23.1 What happens to national economies during banking the years?
crises? 28.6 How did policy mistakes contribute to the Great
23.2 Why did the U.S. stock market rise sharply and fall Depression?
sharply in the 1990s and again in the 2000s? 28.7 Why have 19 European countries adopted a common
23.3 Why is the U.S. trade deficit so large? currency?
SUP P LE M E N TS

The following ancillaries are available for quick download Customizable Micro Lecture Notes
and convenient access via the Instructor Resource material One of the biggest hurdles to an instructor considering
available through McGraw Hill Connect®. changing textbooks is the prospect of having to prepare new
lecture notes and slides. For the microeconomics chapters,
Solutions Manual this hurdle no longer exists. A full set of lecture notes for
Prepared by the authors with assistance from Per Norander, Principles of Microeconomics, prepared by Bob Frank for
University of North Carolina at Charlotte, this manual pro- his award-winning introductory microeconomics course at
vides detailed answers to the end-of-chapter review questions Cornell University, is available as Microsoft Word files that
and problems. instructors are welcome to customize as they see fit. The
challenge for any instructor is to reinforce the lessons of the
text in lectures without generating student unrest by merely
Test Bank repeating what’s in the book. These lecture notes address
The test bank has been carefully revised and reviewed for that challenge by constructing examples that run parallel to
accuracy. Thousands of questions have been categorized by those presented in the book, yet are different from them in
chapter learning objectives, AACSB learning categories, interesting contextual ways.
Bloom’s Taxonomy objectives, and level of difficulty.
Writing Assignment
Test Builder in Connect Available within McGraw Hill Connect® and McGraw Hill
Available within Connect, Test Builder is a cloud-based tool Connect® Master, the Writing Assignment tool delivers a
that enables instructors to format tests that can be printed learning experience to help students improve their written
or administered within an LMS. Test Builder offers a mod- communication skills and conceptual understanding. As an
ern, streamlined interface for easy content configuration instructor you can assign, monitor, grade, and provide feed-
that matches course needs, without requiring a download. back on writing more efficiently and effectively.
Test Builder allows you to:
• access all test bank content from a particular title. Remote Proctoring & Browser-Locking
• easily pinpoint the most relevant content through robust Capabilities
filtering options.
• manipulate the order of questions or scramble questions
and/or answers.
New remote proctoring and browser-locking capabilities,
• pin questions to a specific location within a test. hosted by Proctorio within Connect, provide control of the
• determine your preferred treatment of algorithmic assessment environment by enabling security options and
­questions. verifying the identity of the student.
Seamlessly integrated within Connect, these services
• choose the layout and spacing. allow instructors to control students’ assessment experience
• add instructions and configure default settings. by restricting browser activity, recording students’ activity,
and verifying students are doing their own work.
Test Builder provides a secure interface for better pro- Instant and detailed reporting gives instructors an at-a-
tection of content and allows for just-in-time updates to flow glance view of potential academic integrity concerns,
directly into assessments. thereby avoiding personal bias and supporting evidence-based
claims.
PowerPoints
Presentation slides contain a detailed, chapter-by-chapter FOR MORE INFORMATION ABOUT CONNECT AND
review of the important ideas presented in the textbook, ITS AVAILABLE RESOURCES, REFER TO THE PAGES
accompanied by animated graphs and slide notes. You THAT FOLLOW.
can edit, print, or rearrange the slides to fit the needs of
your course.

xvii
Connect Economics
Asset Alignment with
Bloom’s Taxonomy
Principles of Economics, 8e

We Take Students Higher

As a learning science company we create content that supports higher order thinking skills. Within
Connect®, we tag assessments accordingly so you can filter your search, assign it, and receive reporting
on it. These content asset types can be associated with one or more levels of Bloom’s Taxonomy.

The chart below shows a few of the key assignable economics assets with McGraw Hill Connect
aligned with Bloom’s Taxonomy. Take your students higher by assigning a variety of applications,
moving them from simple memorization to concept application.

Econ
ECON Application- Writing
Interactive Everyday
SmartBook 2.0 Adaptive Videos Exercises Based Assignment
Graphs Current
Math Prep Activities Plus
Events Blog*


Thinking Skills
Higher Order

CREATE

EVALUATE
✓ ✓ ✓
ANALYZE
✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓
APPLY
✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓
UNDERSTAND
✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓
Thinking Skills
Lower Order

REMEMBER
✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓
* Outside of Connect.
SmartBook 2.0
Adaptively aids students to study more efficiently by highlighting where in the chapter
to focus, asking review questions and pointing them to passages in the text until they
understand. Assignable and assessable.

ECON Adaptive Math Prep


Math preparedness assignments help students refresh important prerequisite topics
necessary to be successful in economics. New Adaptive Math Prep Tool provides students
just-in-time math remediation that are prerequisite to success in Principles of Economics
courses and adapt to each student.

Videos
Worked examples and real-world application videos help students learn economics.
Learning Glass videos reinforcing challenging topics featuring the authors and innovative
learning glass technology. Economic Naturalist videos bring examples to life showing
interesting applications of economic concepts. Worked Problem videos work through
select end-of-chapter questions for extra help and guidance through challenging material.

Exercises
Exercises with algorithmic variations provide ample opportunities for students to practice
and hone quantitative skills. Graphing Exercises provide opportunities for students to draw,
interact with, manipulate, and analyze graphs.

Interactive Graphs
Interactive Graphs provide visual displays of real data and economic concepts for students
to manipulate. All graphs are accompanied by assignable assessment questions and
feedback to guide students through the experience of learning to read and interpret graphs
and data.

Application-Based Activities
Immersive real-life scenarios engage students and put them in the role of everyday
economists. Students practice their economic thinking and problem-solving skills as they
apply course concepts and see the implications of their decisions as they go. Each activity
is designed as a 15-minute experience, unless students eagerly replay for a better outcome.

ECON Everyday Current Events Blog*


Our Econ Everyday blog saves instructors time bringing current, student-centered content
into their course all semester long. Short articles, written for principles-level students, is
tagged by topic to bring currency into your course. We also provide discussion questions to
help you drive the conversation forward. Visit www.econeveryday.com and subscribe for
updates. (*Outside of Connect.)

Writing Assignment Plus


Writing Assignment Plus delivers a learning experience that helps students improve their
written communication skills and conceptual understanding. Faculty can assign, monitor,
grade, and provide feedback on writing projects efficiently. Built-in grammar and writing
review helps students improve writing quality while an originality check helps students
correct central plagiarism before submission. End result? Improved workplace skills of
writing in critical thinking.

For more information, please visit: www.mheducation.com/highered/economics


Instructors:
Instructors:Student
Instructors:
Instructors: StudentSuccess
Student
Student SuccessStarts
Success
Success Startswith
Starts
Starts withYou
with
with You
You
You
Tools
Tools
Tools
Tools
Want
Want
to
tototo
Want
Wanttoto
prebuilt
enhance
enhance
enhance
enhance
to build
to build
build
build
prebuilt your
course?
your
your
your
your
youryour
your
course?
unique
own
Easy.
unique
unique
unique
ownown
own
Easy.
voice
voice
voice
voice
course?
course?
course?
Wantcourse?
Want
No problem.
NoNo
to make
to
No problem.
problem.
problem.
make
changes
Prefer
Prefer
Prefer
changes
to use
Prefer
toto
to use
use
throughout use
throughout
our our
our
the
turnkey,
our
turnkey,
turnkey,
turnkey,
semester?
the semester?
65%
65%
65%
Less
Less
Time
Time
prebuilt
prebuilt
Sure.
Sure.
Andcourse?
course?
And
you’ll Easy.
Easy.
you’ll
save Want
save Want
time toto
time
withmake
make
with changes
changes
Connect’s
Connect’s throughout
throughout
auto-grading
auto-grading the
too. the
semester?
too. semester? Less
LessTime
Time
Grading
Grading
Sure.
Sure.
AndAndyou’ll
you’ll
save
savetime
timewith
with
Connect’s
Connect’s
auto-grading
auto-grading too.
too.
Grading
Grading

Study
Study
made
made
personal
personal
Study
Studymade
madepersonal
personal
Incorporate
Incorporate
adaptive
adaptive
study study
resources
resourceslike like
Incorporate
Incorporate
SmartBook® adaptive
SmartBook®adaptive
2.0 2.0 study
intointo study
your yourresources
resources
course
course like
andand
helplike
help
youryour
SmartBook®
SmartBook®
students
students 2.0
2.0
into
be better into
be better your
your
prepared course
preparedcourse
in less and
and
in lesshelp
time. help
time. your
Learnyour
Learn
students
students
moremore be
aboutbebetter
aboutbetter
the the prepared
prepared
powerful
powerful in in
less
less
personalized time.
personalizedtime. Learn
Learn
learning
learning
more
moreabout
about
experience the
experiencethe
powerful
powerful
available
available personalized
personalized
in SmartBook
in SmartBook 2.0 learning
atlearning
2.0 at
experience
experienceavailable
availablein in
SmartBook
SmartBook 2.0
www.mheducation.com/highered/connect/smartbook2.0
www.mheducation.com/highered/connect/smartbookatat
www.mheducation.com/highered/connect/smartbook
www.mheducation.com/highered/connect/smartbook

Laptop: McGraw-Hill;
Laptop: McGraw-Hill;
Woman/dog:
Woman/dog:
George Doyle/Getty
George Doyle/Getty
Images Images
Laptop:
Laptop:
McGraw-Hill;
McGraw Hill;
oman/dog:
Woman/dog:
George
George
Doyle/Getty
Doyle/Getty
Images
Images

Affordable
Affordable
solutions,
solutions, Solutions
Solutions
for
for
Affordable
Affordablesolutions,
solutions, Solutions
Solutionsfor
for
added
addedvalue
value your
your
challenges
challenges
added
added value
value your
yourchallenges
challenges
MakeMake
technology
technology work work
for you
for you
withwith A product
A productisn’tisn’t
a solution.
a solution. RealReal
Make
Make
LMSLMS technology
technology
integration
integration work
work
for single forfor
for singleyouyou
sign-onwith
with
sign-on
access,
access, A A
product
product
solutions
solutionsisn’t
isn’t
are are a solution.
a solution.
affordable,
affordable, RealReal
reliable,
reliable,
LMS
LMS
mobileintegration
integration
mobileaccess
access for
to theforsingle
single
to the
digitalsign-on
sign-on
digital access,
textbook, access,
textbook, solutions
solutions
andand come are
come areaffordable,
affordable,
withwith
training
training reliable,
andand reliable,
mobile
mobile
and and access
reports access
reports tototo
the
to quickly thedigital
quicklydigital
show textbook,
show textbook,
you you
howhow andand
ongoingcome
come
ongoing with
with
support training
training
support
when whenand
you and you
need need
and
and
each reports
eachreports
of your toto
of yourquickly
quickly
students
studentsshow
show
is doing. you
you
is doing.how
Andhow
And
withwith ongoing
ongoing
it andit and support
howhow support
you you when
when
wantwant you
it. Visityou need
need
it. Visit
www. www.
each
each
our ourof of
your
Inclusive yourstudents
Inclusive students
AccessAccess is is
doing.
program doing.
program And
And
youyou with
can with
can it and
it andhowhow youyou
supportateverystep.comwant
want
supportateverystep.com it. it.
Visit
Visitwww.
www.
for videos
for videos
our
our
Inclusive
provideInclusive
provide Access
all theseAccess
all these program
program
toolstools
at a at you
you
discount can
can
a discount
to to supportateverystep.com
andsupportateverystep.com
and
resources
resourcesbothbothyou you forfor
and videos
and
yourvideos
your
provide
provide
youryour allall
students.these
these
students.
Ask tools
tools
yourat
Ask at
youra discount
aMcGraw-Hill
discount
McGraw-Hill toto andand resources
students resources
students
can can both
both
use use youyou
throughout and
throughoutand your
your
the the
your
yourstudents.
students.
representative
representative AskAsk
for moreyour
your
for moreMcGraw-g
McGraw
information. Hill
information. students
students
semester. can
semester. can use
usethroughout
throughout thethe
representative
representative forformoremore information.
information. semester.
semester.

Padlock:Padlock:
Jobalou/Getty
Jobalou/Getty
Images Images Checkmark:
Checkmark:
Jobalou/Getty
Jobalou/Getty
Images Images
Padlock:
Padlock:
Jobalou/Getty
Jobalou/Getty
Images
Images Checkmark:
Checkmark:
Jobalou/Getty
Jobalou/Getty
Images
Images
Instructors:
Instructors:
Students:
Instructors: Student
Student
Success
Success
Get Learning
StudentLearning
Success Starts
that
thatStarts
Fitswith
Starts
Fits withYou
You
with
You You
You
Tools
Tools
Tools
Want
Want
to
to to
enhance
enhance
Effective
enhance
Effective
Want
to build
to build
to course?
prebuilt build
prebuilt
your
tools
your
Connect
course?
your
yourforunique
youryour
Connect
ownown
own
Easy.
unique
unique voice
efficient
efficient
isEasy.
course?
designed
course?
WantWant
voice
studying
voice
studying
course?
No problem.
to
to
to make
to
No problem.
make
Nomake
make
Prefer
you more
problem.
you
changes
more
Prefer
Prefer
changes
to useto use
productive
to usethe
productive
throughout
throughout
our our
turnkey,
turnkey,
with
with
the
simple,flexible,
oursemester?
turnkey,
simple,
semester?
flexible,intuitive
Less
intuitivetools
LessTime
toolsthat
Time
65%
65%
thatmaximize
maximize
prebuilt
Sure.
Sure.
And your
course?
your
And study
Easy.
study
you’ll
you’ll
save time
Want
save
time and
time
with meet
to with
make your
Connect’s individual
changes
individual
Connect’s
auto-grading learning
throughout
auto-grading the
learning
too. needs.
semester?
needs.
too. Get
Get learningLess
learning that Timefor you with Connect.
works
that works
Grading
Grading
for you with Connect.
Sure. And you’ll save time with Connect’s auto-grading too.
Grading

Study
Study anytime, anywhere anywhere “I“Ireally
reallyliked
likedthis
this
Download
Download the free ReadAnywhere app Study
ReadAnywhere app andStudy
Study
and made
made
access
access made
your
your personal
personal
app—itmade
app—it
personal madeititeasy
easy
online eBook or SmartBook 2.0 assignments
online eBook or SmartBook 2.0 assignments when it’swhen adaptive
Incorporate it’s adaptive
Incorporate study
study totostudy
resources study
resources whenyou
when
like like you
convenient,
convenient, even if you’re offline. And Incorporate
since
offline. And since the app adaptive
the app2.0 2.0 study resources
don't like
have your
SmartBook®
SmartBook®
SmartBook® 2.0
intointo
into
your
your
your
course
course
don't
courseand andhave
help help yourtext-
your
your text-
automatically syncs with your eBook
automatically eBook and
and SmartBook
SmartBook
students
students 2.0
2.0better
be better
be prepared
prepared
inbookinand
less lesshelp
time. time.your
Learn
ininfront Learn
ofofyou.”
assignments in Connect, all of your
assignments students
your work
work is
more be
is available
available
more
about better
about
the the prepared
powerful
powerful in book
less
personalized time.
personalized
front
Learn
learning
learning
you.”
every time
every time you open it. Find out
out more atmore
more at about available
experience the available
experience powerful personalized
in SmartBook
in SmartBook 2.0 learning
2.0
at at
www.mheducation.com/readanywhere experience available in - -Jordan
SmartBook 2.0 Cunningham,
Jordan atCunningham,
www.mheducation.com/readanywherewww.mheducation.com/highered/connect/smartbook
www.mheducation.com/highered/connect/smartbook
Eastern
Eastern
www.mheducation.com/highered/connect/smartbook Washington
WashingtonUniversity
University

Laptop: McGraw-Hill;
Laptop: McGraw-Hill;
Woman/dog:
Woman/dog:
George Doyle/Getty
George Doyle/Getty
Images Images
Laptop: McGraw-Hill; Woman/dog: George Doyle/Getty Images

Everything
Everything you you need
needin inone
oneplace
place
Affordable
Affordable
solutions,
solutions,
Your
Your Connect Solutions
Connect course Solutions
has for
haseverything forneed—whether
you need—whetherreading
readingonon
Affordable solutions, your
your digital
digital eBook
Solutions
course
or completing for
everything you
assignments
assignmentsfor
forclass,
class,Connect
Connectmakes
added
addedvalue
value eBookyour
oryour challenges
challenges
completing makes
added value it easy to get youryour
it easy to get your work challenges
done.
work done.

Make Make technology


technology work work
for you
for you
withwith A product
A product isn’tisn’t
a solution.
a solution.RealReal
Make
LMSLMS technology
integration
integration
Calendar:
work
for single
for
owattaphotos/Getty
for you
single
Images sign-onwith
sign-on
access,
access, A product
solutions
solutions isn’t
are are a solution.
affordable,
affordable, Real
reliable,
reliable,
LMS
mobile integration
mobile access for
to the single
Calendar: owattaphotos/Getty Images
access to thedigital sign-on
digital access,
textbook,
textbook, solutions
andand come are
come affordable,
withwith training
training reliable,
andand
mobile
andand access
reports reports totothe
to quickly digital
quickly show textbook,
showyouyou
howhow and
ongoingcomesupport
ongoing with training
support when andyou
when
you need need
and
each
each
Learning for
Learning
each
of
for everyone
reports
everyone
of your
your
to
of your quickly
students
students
students show
is doing.
is doing.
you
is doing.how
AndAnd
And
withwith
with
ongoing
it and
it and
it and support
howhow
how
you you
you
when
wantwant
want
you
it. Visit
it.
need
it. Visit
Visit
www.
www.
www.
our our InclusiveInclusive Access Access programprogramyouyou
can can supportateverystep.com
supportateverystep.com for videos
for videos
our
provide Inclusive
McGraw
provide all Access
Hill
these
all works
thesetools program
directly
tools
at a at you
with
discount
a can
Accessibility
discount
to to supportateverystep.com
Services
and and
resourcesresources both both
you you
andforand
videos
your your
provide McGraw-Hill
all these works
tools directly
at with Accessibility Services
a discount
Departments
yourDepartments
your
students.
students. Ask andAsk
your faculty
your to meetto
McGraw-Hill
McGraw-Hillthe learning needsand resources
students
students can canboth
use use you
throughout and your
throughout the the
your and faculty to meet the learning needs
ofstudents.
representativeall students.
representative Ask
for your
Please
more
for McGraw-Hill
more contact
information. your Accessibility students
information. semester.
semester. can use throughout the
of all students.
representative Pleaseinformation.
for more contact your Accessibility semester.
Services Office and ask them to email
Services Office and ask them to email
accessibility@mheducation.com, or visit
accessibility@mheducation.com, or visit
www.mheducation.com/about/accessibility
Padlock:Padlock:
Jobalou/Getty
Jobalou/Getty
Images Images Checkmark:
Checkmark:
Jobalou/Getty
Jobalou/Getty
Images Images
Padlock:www.mheducation.com/about/accessibility
for more information.
Jobalou/Getty Images Checkmark: Jobalou/Getty Images

for more information.

Top: Jenner Images/Getty Images, Left: Hero Images/Getty Images, Right: Hero Images/Getty Images
Top: Jenner Images/Getty Images, Left: Hero Images/Getty Images, Right: Hero Images/Getty Images
C O MPA R I S O N G U IDE F OR F RANK , BE RNANKE,
A N TO N OV I C S , AND HE F F E T Z PRODUC TS
Principles of Economics provides enhanced coverage, offers more topics, and more mathematical rigor. Principles of Economics: A Streamlined
Approach is a stripped down version of the big book featuring core content with a less is more approach. See which product is right for you!

Comparison Guide
Principles of Economics, 8th edition Principles of Economics: A Streamlined Approach, 4th edition
Econ Micro Macro Streamlined Streamlined Streamlined
Chapter Title 8e 8e 8e Chapter Title 4e Econ 4e Micro 4e Macro
Thinking Like an Economist 1 1 1 Thinking Like An Economist 1 1 1
Comparative Advantage 2 2 2
Supply and Demand 3 3 3 Supply and Demand 2 2 2
Elasticity 4 4
Demand and Elasticity 3 3
Demand 5 5
Perfectly Competitive Supply 6 6 Perfectly Competitive Supply 4 4
Efficiency, Exchange, and 7 7 Efficiency, Exchange, and 5 5
the Invisible Hand in Action the Invisible Hand in Action
Monopoly, Oligopoly, and 8 8 Monopoly, Oligopoly, and 6 6
Monopolistic Competition Monopolistic Competition
Games and Strategic 9 9 Games and Strategic 7 7
Behavior Behavior
An Introduction to 10 10 An Introduction to Behavioral 8 8
Behavioral Economics Economics (NEW)
Externalities, Property 11 11 Externalities and Property 9 9
Rights, and the Environment Rights
The Economics of Information 12 12
Using Economics to Make
Labor Markets, Poverty, and 13 13 10 10
Better Policy Decisions
Income Distribution
Public Goods and Tax Policy 14 14
International Trade and 15 15 16 International Trade and 11 11 12
Trade Policy Trade Policy
Macroeconomics: The Bird’s- 16 4 Macroeconomics: The Bird’s 12 3
Eye View of the Economy Eye View of the Economy
Measuring Economic Activity: 17 5
Measuring Economic Activity:
GDP and Unemployment
GDP, Unemployment, and 13 4
Measuring the Price Level 18 6
Inflation
and Inflation
Economic Growth, Produc- 19 7 Economic Growth, Produc- 14 5
tivity, and Living Standards tivity, and Living Standards
The Labor Market: Workers, 20 8 The Labor Market: Workers, 15 6
Wages, and Unemployment Wages, and Unemployment
Saving and Capital Formation 21 9 Saving and Capital Formation 16 7
Money, Prices, and the 22 10
Money, The Federal
Federal Reserve
Reserve, and Global 17 8
Financial Markets and 23 11
Financial Markets
International Capital Flows
Short-Term Economic Fluc- 24 12
tuations: An Introduction Short-Term Economic Fluc-
18 9
Spending and Output in the 25 13 tuations and Fiscal Policy
Short Run
Stabilizing the Economy: 26 14 Stabilizing the Economy: 19 10
The Role of the Fed The Role of the Fed
Aggregate Demand, Aggre- 27 15 Aggregate Demand, Aggre- 20 11
gate Supply, and Inflation gate Supply, and Inflation
Exchange Rates and the 28 17 Exchange Rates and the 21 13
Open Economy Open Economy

xxii
BRIE F CON TENTS

PART 1 Introduction PART 6 Macroeconomic: Issues and Data

1 Thinking Like an Economist 1 16 Macroeconomics: The Bird’s-Eye View of


the Economy 423
2 Comparative Advantage 31
17 Measuring Economic Activity: GDP and
3 Supply and Demand 55 Unemployment 441

18 Measuring the Price Level and


PART 2 Competition and the Invisible Inflation 471
Hand

4 Elasticity 89 PART 7 The Economy in the Long Run


5 Demand 115 19 Economic Growth, Productivity, and Living
Standards 497
6 Perfectly Competitive Supply 151
20 The Labor Market: Workers, Wages, and
7 Efficiency, Exchange, and the Invisible Hand
Unemployment 525
in Action 175
21 Saving and Capital Formation 553

PART 3 Market Imperfections 22 Money, Prices, and the Federal


Reserve 583
8 Monopoly, Oligopoly, and Monopolistic
Competition 205 23 Financial Markets and International Capital
Flows 605
9 Games and Strategic Behavior 239

10 An Introduction to Behavioral
Economics 265 PART 8 The Economy in the Short Run

24 Short-Term Economic Fluctuations: An


11 Externalities, Property Rights, and the
Introduction 629
Environment 293
25 Spending and Output in the Short Run 649

PART 4 Economics of Public Policy 26 Stabilizing the Economy: The Role of the
Fed 687
12 The Economics of Information 325
27 Aggregate Demand, Aggregate Supply, and
13 Labor Markets, Poverty, and Income
Inflation 727
Distribution 349

14 Public Goods and Tax Policy 373


PART 9 The International Economy

28 Exchange Rates and the Open


PART 5 International Trade
Economy 765
15 International Trade and Trade Policy 397

xxiii
C ON T E N TS

PART I Introduction Summary 51 • Core Principles 51


• Key Terms 51 • Review Questions 52
Chapter 1 Thinking Like an Economist 1 • Problems 52 • Answers to Self-Tests 53
Economics: Studying Choice in a World of Scarcity 2
Chapter 3 Supply and Demand 55
Applying the Cost-Benefit Principle 3
Economic Surplus 4 What, How, and for Whom? Central Planning
Opportunity Cost 4 versus the Market 57
The Role of Economic Models 5 Buyers and Sellers in Markets 58
Three Important Decision Pitfalls 6 The Demand Curve 59
Pitfall 1: Measuring Costs and Benefits as The Supply Curve 60
Proportions rather than Absolute Dollar Market Equilibrium 62
Amounts 6 Rent Controls Reconsidered 65
Pitfall 2: Ignoring Implicit Costs 7 Pizza Price Controls? 67
Pitfall 3: Failing to Think at the Margin 8 Predicting and Explaining Changes in Prices
Normative Economics versus Positive Economics 13 and Quantities 68
Economics: Micro and Macro 13 Shifts in Demand 69
The Approach of This Text 14 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.1 71
Economic Naturalism 14 Shifts in the Supply Curve 72
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 1.1 15 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.2 75
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 1.2 15 Four Simple Rules 75
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 1.3 16 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.3 78
Summary 17 • Core Principles 17 • Key Terms 17 Efficiency and Equilibrium 78
• Review Questions 18 • Problems 18 • Answers to Cash on the Table 79
Self-Tests 19 • Appendix: Working with Equations, Smart for One, Dumb for All 80
Graphs, and Tables 20 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.4 81
Summary 82 • Core Principles 83
Chapter 2 Comparative Advantage 31 • Key Terms 83 • Review Questions 83
Exchange and Opportunity Cost 32 • Problems 83 • Answers to Self-Tests 85
The Principle of Comparative Advantage 33 • Appendix: The Algebra of Supply and Demand 86
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 2.1 35
Sources of Comparative Advantage 36 PART 2 Competition and the Invisible Hand
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 2.2 36
Comparative Advantage and Production Possibilities 37 Chapter 4 Elasticity 89
The Production Possibilities Curve 37 Price Elasticity of Demand 90
How Individual Productivity Affects the Slope and Price Elasticity Defined 90
Position of the PPC 40 Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand 92
The Gains from Specialization and Exchange 41 Substitution Possibilities 92
A Production Possibilities Curve for a Many-Person Budget Share 92
Economy 43 Time 92
A Note on the Logic of the Fruit Picker’s Rule 44 Some Representative Elasticity Estimates 93
Factors That Shift the Economy’s Production Using Price Elasticity of Demand 94
Possibilities Curve 45 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 4.1 94
Why Have Some Countries Been Slow to Specialize? 46 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 4.2 94
Can We Have Too Much Specialization? 47 A Graphical Interpretation of Price Elasticity 95
Comparative Advantage and Outsourcing 48 Price Elasticity Changes along a Straight-Line
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 2.3 48 Demand Curve 97
Outsourcing 48 Two Special Cases 98
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 2.4 49 Elasticity and Total Expenditure 99
xxiv
CONTENTS xxv

Income Elasticity and Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand 103 A Graphical Approach to Profit Maximization 161
The Price Elasticity of Supply 104 Price = Marginal Cost: The Maximum-Profit
Determinants of Supply Elasticity 106 Condition 163
Flexibility of Inputs 107 The “Law” of Supply 164
Mobility of Inputs 107 Determinants of Supply Revisited 166
Ability to Produce Substitute Inputs 107 Technology 166
Time 107 Input Prices 166
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 4.3 108 The Number of Suppliers 166
Unique and Essential Inputs: The Ultimate Expectations 166
Supply Bottleneck 110 Changes in Prices of Other Products 166
Summary 110 • Key Terms 111 • Review Applying the Theory of Supply 167
Questions 111 • Problems 112 • Answers to THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 6.1 167
Self-Tests 113 • Appendix: The Midpoint Formula 114 Supply and Producer Surplus 170
Calculating Producer Surplus 170
Chapter 5 Demand 115 Summary 171 • Key Terms 172 • Review Questions 172
The Law of Demand 116 • Problems 172 • Answers to Self-Tests 174
The Origins of Demand 116
Needs versus Wants 117 Chapter 7 Efficiency, Exchange, and the Invisible
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 5.1 117 Hand in Action 175
Translating Wants into Demand 118 The Central Role of Economic Profit 176
Measuring Wants: The Concept of Utility 118 Three Types of Profit 176
Allocating a Fixed Income between Two Goods 121 The Invisible Hand Theory 179
The Rational Spending Rule 125 Two Functions of Price 179
Income and Substitution Effects Revisited 125 Responses to Profits and Losses 179
Applying the Rational Spending Rule 127 The Importance of Free Entry and Exit 185
Substitution at Work 127 Economic Rent versus Economic Profit 186
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 5.2 128 The Invisible Hand in Action 188
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 5.3 128 The Invisible Hand at the Supermarket and on the
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 5.4 129 Freeway 188
The Importance of Income Differences 129 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 7.1 188
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 5.5 130 The Invisible Hand and Cost-Saving Innovations 188
Individual and Market Demand Curves 130 The Distinction between an Equilibrium and a
Horizontal Addition 130 Social Optimum 189
Demand and Consumer Surplus 132 Smart for One, Dumb for All 190
Calculating Consumer Surplus 132 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 7.2 190
Summary 135 • Key Terms 135 • Review Market Equilibrium and Efficiency 191
Questions 135 • Problems 135 • Answers to Efficiency Is Not the Only Goal 193
Self-Tests 137 • Appendix: Indifference Curves 138 Why Efficiency Should Be the First Goal 194
The Cost of Preventing Price Adjustments 195
Chapter 6 Perfectly Competitive Supply 151 Price Ceilings 195
Thinking about Supply: The Importance of Price Subsidies 198
Opportunity Cost 152 Summary 200 • Key Terms 201 • Review Questions 201
Individual and Market Supply Curves 154 • Problems 201 • Answers to Self-Tests 203
Profit-Maximizing Firms in Perfectly Competitive Markets 155
Profit Maximization 155 PART 3 Market Imperfections
The Demand Curve Facing a Perfectly
Competitive Firm 156 Chapter 8 Monopoly, Oligopoly, and
Production in the Short Run 157 Monopolistic Competition 205
Some Important Cost Concepts 158 Perfect and Imperfect Competition 206
Choosing Output to Maximize Profit 159 Different Forms of Imperfect Competition 206
A Note on the Firm’s Shutdown Condition 160 Monopolistic Competition 206
Average Variable Cost and Average Total Cost 161 Oligopoly 207
xxvi CONTENTS

The Essential Difference between Perfectly and THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 9.4 254
Imperfectly Competitive Firms 208 Commitment Problems 256
Five Sources of Market Power 209 Solving Commitment Problems with Psychological
Exclusive Control over Important Inputs 209 Incentives 258
Patents and Copyrights 209 Are People Fundamentally Selfish? 259
Government Licenses or Franchises 209 Preferences as Solutions to Commitment
Economies of Scale and Natural Monopolies 210 Problems 259
Network Economies 210 Summary 260 • Key Terms 260 • Review
Economies of Scale and the Importance of Questions 261 • Problems 261 • Answers to
Start-Up Costs 211 Self-Tests 264
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 8.1 213
Profit Maximization for the Monopolist 214 Chapter 10 An Introduction to Behavioral
Marginal Revenue for the Monopolist 214 Economics 265
The Monopolist’s Profit-Maximizing Judgmental Heuristics or Rules of Thumb 267
Decision Rule 216 Availability 267
Being a Monopolist Doesn’t Guarantee Representativeness 267
an Economic Profit 218 Regression to the Mean 268
Why the Invisible Hand Breaks Down under THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 10.1 269
Monopoly 218 Anchoring and Adjustment 269
Using Discounts to Expand the Market 220 Misinterpretation of Contextual Clues 270
Price Discrimination Defined 220 The Psychophysics of Perception 270
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 8.2 221 The Difficulty of Actually Deciding 271
How Price Discrimination Affects Output 221 Impulse-Control Problems 272
The Hurdle Method of Price Discrimination 224 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 10.2 273
Is Price Discrimination a Bad Thing? 226 Loss Aversion and Status Quo Bias 275
Examples of Price Discrimination 227 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 10.3 276
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 8.3 228 Beyond Narrow Self-Interest 277
Public Policy toward Natural Monopoly 228 The Present-Aim Standard of Rationality 278
State Ownership and Management 229 The Adaptive Rationality Standard 278
State Regulation of Private Monopolies 229 Concerns about Fairness 281
Exclusive Contracting for Natural Monopoly 230 Concerns about Relative Position 282
Vigorous Enforcement of Antitrust Laws 230 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 10.4 285
Summary 232 • Key Terms 232 • Review THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 10.5 286
Questions 233 • Problems 233 • Answers to Summary 289 • Key Terms 290 • Review
Self-Tests 235 • Appendix: The Algebra of Questions 290 • Problems 290 • Answers to
Monopoly Profit Maximization 236 Self-Tests 291

Chapter 9 Games and Strategic Behavior 239 Chapter 11 Externalities, Property Rights,
Using Game Theory to Analyze Strategic Decisions 240 and the Environment 293
The Three Elements of a Game 240 External Costs and Benefits 294
Nash Equilibrium 242 How Externalities Affect Resource Allocation 294
The Prisoner’s Dilemma 244 How Do Externalities Affect Supply
The Original Prisoner’s Dilemma 244 and Demand? 295
The Economics of Cartels 245 The Coase Theorem 297
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 9.1 245 Remedies for Externalities 302
Tit-for-Tat and the Repeated Prisoner’s Laws and Regulations 302
Dilemma 247 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 11.1 303
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 9.2 248 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 11.2 303
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 9.3 249 The Optimal Amount of Negative Externalities
Games in Which Timing Matters 250 Is Not Zero 304
Credible Threats and Promises 252 Compensatory Taxes and Subsidies 304
Monopolistic Competition When Location Matters 254 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 11.3 306
CONTENTS xxvii

Property Rights and the Tragedy of the Commons 306 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 12.3 336
The Problem of Unpriced Resources 306 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 12.4 337
The Effect of Private Ownership 309 Conspicuous Consumption as a Signal
When Private Ownership Is Impractical 310 of Ability 337
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 11.4 310 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 12.5 338
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 11.5 310 Statistical Discrimination 339
Harvesting Timber on Remote Public Land 311 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 12.6 339
Harvesting Whales in International Waters 311 Disappearing Political Discourse 340
Controlling Multinational Environmental THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 12.7 340
Pollution 311 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 12.8 342
Positional Externalities 311 Insurance 343
Payoffs That Depend on Relative Adverse Selection 343
Performance 312 Moral Hazard 344
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 11.6 312 The Problem with Health Care Provision through
Positional Arms Races and Positional Arms Private Insurance 344
Control Agreements 313 The Affordable Care Act of 2010 345
Campaign Spending Limits 313 Summary 346 • Key Terms 347
Roster Limits 314 • Review Questions 347 • Problems 347
Arbitration Agreements 314 • Answers to Self-Tests 348
Mandatory Starting Dates for Kindergarten 314
Chapter 13 Labor Markets, Poverty, and
Social Norms as Positional Arms Control
Income Distribution 349
Agreements 314
Nerd Norms 314 The Economic Value of Work 350
Fashion Norms 314 The Equilibrium Wage and Employment Levels 353
Norms of Taste 315 The Demand Curve for Labor 353
Norms against Vanity 315 The Supply Curve of Labor 353
Using Price Incentives in Environmental Market Shifts 354
Regulation 316 Explaining Differences in Earnings 355
Taxing Pollution 316 Human Capital Theory 355
Auctioning Pollution Permits 318 Labor Unions 355
Climate Change and Carbon Taxes 319 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 13.1 357
Summary 321 • Key Terms 322 • Review Compensating Wage Differentials 357
Questions 322 • Problems 322 • Answers to THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 13.2 358
Self-Tests 324 Discrimination in the Labor Market 358
Discrimination by Employers 358
Discrimination by Others 359
PART 4 Economics of Public Policy Other Sources of the Wage Gap 359
Winner-Take-All Markets 360
Chapter 12 The Economics of Information 325 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 13.3 360
How the Middleman Adds Value 326 Recent Trends in Inequality 361
The Optimal Amount of Information 328 Is Income Inequality a Moral Problem? 362
The Cost-Benefit Test 328 Methods of Income Redistribution 363
The Free-Rider Problem 328 Welfare Payments and In-Kind Transfers 364
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 12.1 329 Means-Tested Benefit Programs 364
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 12.2 329 The Negative Income Tax 365
Two Guidelines for Rational Search 330 Minimum Wages 365
The Gamble Inherent in Search 331 The Earned-Income Tax Credit 366
The Commitment Problem When Search Is Costly 332 Public Employment for the Poor 368
Asymmetric Information 333 A Combination of Methods 369
The Lemons Model 333 Summary 370 • Key Terms 370 • Review
The Credibility Problem in Trading 335 Questions 370 • Problems 371 • Answers to
The Costly-to-Fake Principle 336 Self-Tests 372
xxviii CONTENTS

Chapter 14 Public Goods and Tax Policy 373 Summary 418 • Key Terms 419 • Review
Government Provision of Public Goods 374 Questions 419 • Problems 420 • Answers to
Public Goods versus Private Goods 374 Self-Tests 421 • Chapter 15 Appendix: An Algebraic
Paying for Public Goods 376 Approach to Trade Analysis (included at the back of the book)
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 14.1 378
The Optimal Quantity of a Public Good 379
The Demand Curve for a Public Good 379 PART 6 Macroeconomic: Issues and Data
Private Provision of Public Goods 380
Chapter 16 Macroeconomics: The Bird’s-Eye View
Funding by Donation 381
of the Economy 423
Development of New Means to Exclude
Nonpayers 381 The Major Macroeconomic Issues 425
Private Contracting 381 Economic Growth and Living Standards 425
Sale of By-Products 381 Productivity 427
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 14.2 381 Recessions and Expansions 428
Laws, Regulations, and the Question of Unemployment 428
Centralization 384 Inflation 430
Externalities and Property Rights 384 Economic Interdependence among Nations 431
Local, State, or Federal? 384 Macroeconomic Policy 432
Sources of Inefficiency in the Political Process 385 Types of Macroeconomic Policy 432
Pork Barrel Legislation 385 Positive versus Normative Analyses of
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 14.3 386 Macroeconomic Policy 433
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 14.4 386 Aggregation 434
Rent-Seeking 387 Studying Macroeconomics: A Preview 437
Starve the Government? 389 Summary 438 • Key Terms 438 • Review
What Should We Tax? 390 Questions 438 • Problems 439 • Answers to
Summary 392 • Key Terms 392 • Review Self-Tests 439
Questions 393 • Problems 393 • Answers to
Chapter 17 Measuring Economic Activity:
Self-Tests 395
GDP and Unemployment 441
Gross Domestic Product: Measuring the
PART 5 International Trade Nation’s Output 442
Market Value 443
Chapter 15 International Trade and Final Goods and Services 445
Trade Policy 397 Produced in a Country during a Given
Comparative Advantage as a Basis for Trade 398 Period 448
Production and Consumption Possibilities and Methods for Measuring GDP 449
the Benefits of Trade 399 The Expenditure Method for Measuring GDP 449
The Two-Worker Production Possibilities GDP and the Incomes of Capital and Labor 452
Curve 399 Nominal GDP versus Real GDP 455
The Many-Worker Production Possibilities THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 17.1 457
Curve 402 Real GDP and Economic Well-Being 457
Consumption Possibilities with and without Why Real GDP Isn’t the Same as Economic
International Trade 404 Well-Being 458
A Supply and Demand Perspective on Trade 407 Leisure Time 458
Winners and Losers from Trade 410 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 17.2 458
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 15.1 410 Nonmarket Economic Activities 459
Protectionist Policies: Tariffs and Quotas 412 Environmental Quality and Resource Depletion 459
Tariffs 412 Quality of Life 459
Quotas 414 Poverty and Economic Inequality 460
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 15.2 416 But GDP Is Related to Economic Well-Being 460
The Inefficiency of Protectionism 417 Availability of Goods and Services 460
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 15.3 417 Health and Education 461
CONTENTS xxix

THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 17.3 462 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 19.2 511
Unemployment and the Unemployment Rate 463 Entrepreneurship and Management 512
Measuring Unemployment 463 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 19.3 513
The Costs of Unemployment 465 The Political and Legal Environment 513
The Duration of Unemployment 466 The Costs of Economic Growth 515
The Unemployment Rate versus “True” Promoting Economic Growth 515
Unemployment 466 Policies to Increase Human Capital 516
Summary 467 • Key Terms 468 • Review THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 19.4 516
Questions 468 • Problems 468 • Answers to Policies That Promote Saving and
Self-Tests 470 Investment 516
Policies That Support Research and
Chapter 18 Measuring the Price Level Development 517
and Inflation 471 The Legal and Political Framework 517
The Consumer Price Index and Inflation 472 The Poorest Countries: A Special Case? 517
Inflation 475 Are There Limits to Growth? 518
Adjusting for Inflation 476 Summary 520 • Key Terms 521 • Review
Deflating a Nominal Quantity 476 Questions 521 • Problems 521 • Answers to
Indexing to Maintain Buying Power 479 Self-Tests 523
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 18.1 480
Chapter 20 The Labor Market: Workers, Wages,
Does the CPI Measure “True” Inflation? 481
and Unemployment 525
The Costs of Inflation: Not What You Think 483
Five Important Labor Market Trends 526
The True Costs of Inflation 484
Trends in Real Wages 526
“Noise” in the Price System 484
Trends in Employment and
Distortions of the Tax System 485
Unemployment 527
“Shoe-Leather” Costs 486
Supply and Demand in the Labor Market 528
Unexpected Redistributions of Wealth 486
Wages and the Demand for Labor 528
Interference with Long-Term Planning 487
Shifts in the Demand for Labor 530
Hyperinflation 487
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 20.1 534
Inflation and Interest Rates 489
The Supply of Labor 534
Inflation and the Real Interest Rate 489
Shifts in the Supply of Labor 536
The Fisher Effect 492
Explaining the Trends in Real Wages
Summary 493 • Key Terms 493 • Review
and Employment 536
Questions 494 • Problems 494 • Answers to
Large Increases in Real Wages in
Self-Tests 495
Industrialized Countries 537
Real Wage Growth in the United States Has
PART 7 The Economy in the Long Run Stagnated since the Early 1970s, while Employment
Growth Has Been Rapid 537
Chapter 19 Economic Growth, Productivity, Increasing Wage Inequality: The Effects of
and Living Standards 497 Globalization and Technological Change 539
The Remarkable Rise in Living Standards: Globalization 539
The Record 499 Technological Change 541
Why “Small” Differences in Growth Rates THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 20.2 543
Matter 501 Unemployment 544
Why Nations Become Rich: The Crucial Role of Average Types of Unemployment and Their Costs 545
Labor Productivity 503 Frictional Unemployment 545
The Determinants of Average Labor Productivity 505 Structural Unemployment 546
Human Capital 505 Cyclical Unemployment 546
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 19.1 506 Impediments to Full Employment 546
Physical Capital 507 Summary 549 • Key Terms 549 • Review
Land and Other Natural Resources 509 Questions 550 • Problems 550 • Answers to
Technology 510 Self-Tests 551
xxx CONTENTS

Chapter 21 Saving and Capital Formation 553 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 23.1 608
Saving and Wealth 554 Bonds and Stocks 608
Stocks and Flows 555 Bonds 609
Capital Gains and Losses 556 Stocks 610
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 21.1 557 Bond Markets, Stock Markets, and the Allocation
Why Do People Save? 559 of Savings 613
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 21.2 559 The Informational Role of Bond and
Saving and the Real Interest Rate 560 Stock Markets 613
Saving, Self-Control, and Demonstration Effects 562 Risk Sharing and Diversification 614
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 21.3 563 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 23.2 615
National Saving and Its Components 565 International Capital Flows 616
The Measurement of National Saving 565 Capital Flows and the Balance of Trade 617
Private and Public Components of The Determinants of International
National Saving 567 Capital Flows 619
Public Saving and the Government Budget 568 Saving, Investment, and Capital Inflows 620
Is Low Household Saving a Problem? 570 The Saving Rate and the Trade Deficit 622
Investment and Capital Formation 571 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 23.3 623
Saving, Investment, and Financial Markets 573 Summary 625 • Key Terms 625 • Review
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 21.4 576 Questions 625 • Problems 626 • Answers to
Summary 578 • Key Terms 578 • Review Self-Tests 627
Questions 579 • Problems 579 • Answers to
Self-Tests 580
PART 8 The Economy in the Short Run
Chapter 22 Money, Prices, and Chapter 24 Short-Term Economic Fluctuations:
the Federal Reserve 583 An Introduction 629
Money and Its Uses 584 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 24.1 630
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 22.1 585 Recessions and Expansions 631
Measuring Money 586 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 24.2 633
Commercial Banks and the Creation of Money 587 Some Facts about Short-Term Economic
The Money Supply with Both Currency and Fluctuations 634
Deposits 590 Output Gaps and Cyclical Unemployment 637
The Federal Reserve System 592 Potential Output 637
The History and Structure of the Federal The Output Gap 638
Reserve System 593 The Natural Rate of Unemployment and
Controlling the Money Supply: Open-Market Cyclical Unemployment 639
Operations 593 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 24.3 640
The Fed’s Role in Stabilizing Financial Markets: Okun’s Law 642
Banking Panics 595 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 24.4 643
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 22.2 595 Why Do Short-Term Fluctuations Occur? A Preview
Money and Prices 598 and a Tale 644
Velocity 598 Alice’s Ice Cream Store: A Tale about Short-Run
Money and Inflation in the Long Run 599 Fluctuations 645
Summary 601 • Key Terms 602 • Review Summary 646 • Key Terms 647 • Review
Questions 602 • Problems 602 • Answers to Questions 647 • Problems 647 • Answers to
Self-Tests 603 Self-Tests 648

Chapter 23 Financial Markets and International Chapter 25 Spending and Output in the
Capital Flows 605 Short Run 649
The Financial System and the Allocation of Saving The Keynesian Model’s Crucial Assumption: Firms Meet
to Productive Uses 606 Demand at Preset Prices 651
The Banking System 607 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 25.1 652
CONTENTS xxxi

Planned Aggregate Expenditure 653 Affecting Bank Reserves through Discount


Planned Spending versus Actual Spending 653 Window Lending 702
Consumer Spending and the Economy 655 Setting and Changing Reserve Requirements 702
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 25.2 656 Excess Reserves: The Norm since 2008 703
Planned Aggregate Expenditure and Output 657 Do Interest Rates Always Move
Short-Run Equilibrium Output 660 Together? 704
Finding Short-Run Equilibrium Output: Numerical The Zero Lower Bound and the Need for
Approach 661 “Unconventional” Monetary Policy 705
Finding Short-Run Equilibrium Output: Graphical Quantitative Easing 705
Approach 662 Forward Guidance 705
Planned Spending and the Output Gap 664 Interest on Reserves and the New Tools of
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 25.3 666 Monetary Policy 706
The Multiplier 667 The Effects of Federal Reserve Actions on the
Stabilizing Planned Spending: The Role of Fiscal Economy 708
Policy 668 Planned Aggregate Expenditure and the Real
Government Purchases and Planned Interest Rate 708
Spending 668 The Fed Fights a Recession 711
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 25.4 670 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 26.2 712
Taxes, Transfers, and Aggregate Spending 671 The Fed Fights Inflation 713
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 25.5 673 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 26.3 714
Fiscal Policy as a Stabilization Tool: Three THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 26.4 715
Qualifications 674 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 26.5 715
Fiscal Policy and the Supply Side 675 The Feds Policy Reaction Function 717
The Problem of Deficits 675 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 26.6 717
The Relative Inflexibility of Fiscal Policy 675 Monetary Policymaking: Art or Science? 720
Summary 676 • Key Terms 677 • Review Summary 720 • Key Terms 722 • Review
Questions 678 • Problems 678 • Answers to Questions 722 • Problems 722 • Answers to
Self-Tests 679 • Appendix A: An Algebraic Self-Tests 724 • Appendix: Monetary Policy
Solution of the Basic Keynesian Model 681 • Appendix B: in the Basic Keynesian Model 725
The Multiplier in the Basic Keynesian Model 684
Chapter 27 Aggregate Demand, Aggregate
Chapter 26 Stabilizing the Economy: The Role of Supply, and Inflation 727
the Fed 687 Inflation, Spending, and Output: The Aggregate
The Federal Reserve and Interest Rates: Demand Curve 728
The Basic Model 688 Inflation, the Fed, and Why the AD Curve Slopes
The Demand for Money 689 Downward 729
Macroeconomic Factors That Affect the Demand Other Reasons for the Downward Slope of
for Money 692 the AD Curve 730
The Money Demand Curve 693 Factors That Shift the Aggregate Demand
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 26.1 694 Curve 730
The Supply of Money and Money Market Changes in Spending 731
Equilibrium 696 Changes in the Fed’s Policy Reaction Function 732
How the Fed Controls the Nominal Shifts of the AD Curve versus Movements along
Interest Rate 697 the AD Curve 732
The Role of the Federal Funds Rate in Inflation and Aggregate Supply 734
Monetary Policy 699 Inflation Inertia 735
Can the Fed Control the Real Interest Rate? 700 Inflation Expectations 735
The Federal Reserve and Interest Rates: Long-Term Wage and Price Contracts 736
A Closer Look 701 The Output Gap and Inflation 737
Can the Fed Fully Control the Money Supply? 701 No Output Gap: Y = Y* 738
Affecting Bank Reserves through Open-Market Expansionary Gap: Y > Y* 738
Operations 702 Recessionary Gap: Y < Y* 738
xxxii CONTENTS

The Aggregate Demand–Aggregate Supply The Determination of the Exchange Rate in the
Diagram 739 Short Run 776
The Self-Correcting Economy 741 The Foreign Exchange Market: A Supply and
Sources of Inflation 742 Demand Analysis 777
Excessive Aggregate Spending 742 The Supply of Dollars 777
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 27.1 744 The Demand for Dollars 778
Inflation Shocks 745 The Equilibrium Value of the Dollar 778
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 27.2 746 Changes in the Supply of Dollars 779
Shocks to Potential Output 748 Changes in the Demand for
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 27.3 749 Dollars 780
Controlling Inflation 751 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 28.2 780
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 27.4 753 Monetary Policy and the Exchange Rate 781
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 27.5 754 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 28.3 782
Summary 756 • Key Terms 757 • Review The Exchange Rate as a Tool of Monetary
Questions 757 • Problems 758 • Answer to Policy 783
Self-Test 759 • Appendix: The Algebra of Fixed Exchange Rates 783
Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply 762 How to Fix an Exchange Rate 784
Speculative Attacks 787
Monetary Policy and the Fixed Exchange
PART 9 The International Economy
Rate 788
Chapter 28 Exchange Rates and the Open THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 28.4 789
Economy 765 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 28.5 790
Exchange Rates 767 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 28.6 790
Nominal Exchange Rates 767 Should Exchange Rates Be Fixed or
Flexible versus Fixed Exchange Rates 769 Flexible? 792
The Real Exchange Rate 769 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 28.7 793
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 28.1 772 Summary 794 • Key Terms 795 • Review
The Determination of the Exchange Rate in the Questions 795 • Problems 796 • Answers to
Long Run 773 Self-Tests 797
A Simple Theory of Exchange Rates: Purchasing
Glossary G-1
Power Parity (PPP) 773
Shortcomings of the PPP Theory 775 Index I-1
CHAPTER
1
Thinking Like
an Economist

LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After reading this chapter,
you should be able to:

LO1 E
 xplain and apply the
Scarcity Principle,
which says that having
more of any good
thing necessarily
requires having less
of something else.

LO2 E
 xplain and apply the
Cost-Benefit Principle,
which says that an

Nick Dolding/Cultura/Corbis
action should be taken
if, but only if, its benefit
is at least as great as
its cost.

LO3 D
 iscuss three important
pitfalls that occur when
People often make bad decisions because they fail to compare the relevant costs applying the Cost-
and benefits. Benefit Principle
inconsistently.

LO4 E
 xplain and apply the
ow many students are in your introductory economics class? Some classes have
H
Incentive Principle,
just 20 or so. Others average 35, 100, or 200 students. At some schools, introduc- which says that if you
tory economics classes may have as many as 2,000 students. What size is best? want to predict people’s
If cost were no object, the best size might be a single student. Think about it: the behavior, a good place
whole course, all term long, with just you and your professor! Everything could be custom-­ to start is by examining
tailored to your own background and ability. You could cover the material at just the right their incentives.
pace. The tutorial format also would promote close communication and personal trust
between you and your professor. And your grade would depend more heavily on what you
actually learned than on your luck when taking multiple-choice exams. Let’s suppose, for
the sake of discussion, that students have been shown to learn best in the tutorial format.
Why, then, do so many introductory classes still have hundreds of students? The
simple reason is that costs do matter. They matter not just to the university administrators
who must build classrooms and pay faculty salaries, but also to you. The direct cost of
providing you with your own personal introductory economics course might easily top
$50,000. Someone has to pay these costs. In private universities, a large share of the cost
would be recovered directly from higher tuition payments. In state universities, the burden
1
2 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

would be split between higher tuition payments and higher tax payments. But, in either
case, the course would be unaffordable for most students.
With larger classes, of course, the cost per student goes down. For example, an intro-
ductory economics course with 300 students might cost as little as $200 per student. But
a class that large could easily compromise the quality of the learning environment. Com-
pared to the custom tutorial format, however, it would be dramatically more affordable.
In choosing what size introductory economics course to offer, then, university admin-
istrators confront a classic economic trade-off. In making the class larger, they risk low-
ering the quality of instruction—a bad thing. At the same time, they reduce costs and
hence the tuition students must pay—a good thing.
In this chapter, we’ll introduce three simple principles that will help you understand
and explain patterns of behavior you observe in the world around you. These principles
also will help you avoid three pitfalls that plague decision makers in everyday life.

ECONOMICS: STUDYING CHOICE


IN A WORLD OF SCARCITY
Even in rich societies like the United States, scarcity is a fundamental fact of life. There
is never enough time, money, or energy to do everything we want to do or have everything
we’d like to have. Economics is the study of how people make choices under conditions
of scarcity and of the results of those choices for society.
In the class-size example just discussed, a motivated economics student might defi-
nitely prefer to be in a class of 20 rather than a class of 100, everything else being
Are small classes “better” than
equal. But other things, of course, are not equal. Students can enjoy the benefits of
large ones?
having smaller classes, but only at the price of having less money for other activities.
economics the study of how The student’s choice inevitably will come down to the relative importance of competing
people make choices under activities.
conditions of scarcity and of That such trade-offs are widespread and important is one of the core principles of
the results of those choices economics. We call it the Scarcity Principle because the simple fact of scarcity makes
for society trade-offs necessary. Another name for the scarcity principle is the No-Free-Lunch Principle
(which comes from the observation that even lunches that are given to you are never
really free—somebody, somehow, always has to pay for them).

The Scarcity Principle (also called the No-Free-Lunch Principle): Although we


Scarcity
have boundless needs and wants, the resources available to us are limited. So
having more of one good thing usually means having less of another.

Inherent in the idea of a trade-off is the fact that choice involves compromise between
competing interests. Economists resolve such trade-offs by using cost-benefit analysis,
which is based on the disarmingly simple principle that an action should be taken if, and
only if, its benefits exceed its costs. We call this statement the Cost-Benefit Principle, and
it, too, is one of the core principles of economics:

The Cost-Benefit Principle: An individual (or a firm or a society) should take an


Cost-Benefit
action if, and only if, the extra benefits from taking the action are at least as great
as the extra costs.

With the Cost-Benefit Principle in mind, let’s think about our class-size question
again. Imagine that classrooms come in only two sizes—100-seat lecture halls and 20-seat
classrooms—and that your university currently offers introductory economics courses to
classes of 100 students. Question: Should administrators reduce the class size to 20 stu-
dents? Answer: Reduce if, and only if, the value of the improvement in instruction out-
weighs its additional cost.
This rule sounds simple. But to apply it we need some way to measure the rele-
vant costs and benefits, a task that’s often difficult in practice. If we make a few
Applying the Cost-Benefit Principle 3

simplifying assumptions, however, we can see how the analysis might work. On the
cost side, the primary expense of reducing class size from 100 to 20 is that we’ll
now need five professors instead of just one. We’ll also need five smaller classrooms
rather than a single big one, and this too may add slightly to the expense of the
move. Let’s suppose that classes with 20 cost $1,000 per student more than those
with 100. Should administrators switch to the smaller class size? If they apply the
Cost-Benefit Principle, they will realize that doing so makes sense only if the value of
Cost-Benefit
attending the smaller class is at least $1,000 per student greater than the value of
attending the larger class.
Would you (or your family) be willing to pay an extra $1,000 for a smaller class? If
not, and if other students feel the same way, then sticking with the larger class size makes
sense. But if you and others would be willing to pay the extra tuition, then reducing the
class size makes good economic sense.
Notice that the “best” class size, from an economic point of view, will generally not be the
same as the “best” size from the point of view of an educational psychologist. That’s because
the economic definition of “best” takes into account both the benefits and the costs of
different class sizes. The psychologist ignores costs and looks only at the learning benefits
of different class sizes.
In practice, of course, different people feel differently about the value of smaller
classes. People with high incomes, for example, tend to be willing to pay more for
the advantage. That helps explain why average class size is smaller, and tuition
higher, at private schools whose students come predominantly from high-income
families.
The cost-benefit framework for thinking about the class-size problem also suggests a
possible reason for the gradual increase in average class size that has been taking place
in American colleges and universities. During the last 30 years, professors’ salaries have
risen sharply, making smaller classes more costly. During the same period, median family
income—and hence the willingness to pay for smaller classes—has remained roughly con-
stant. When the cost of offering smaller classes goes up but willingness to pay for smaller
classes does not, universities shift to larger class sizes.
Scarcity and the trade-offs that result also apply to resources other than money. Jeff
Chip Somodevilla/Getty Images
Bezos is one of the richest people on Earth. His wealth is estimated at more than $180
billion. That’s more than the combined wealth of the poorest 54 percent of Americans.
Bezos could buy more houses, cars, vacations, and other consumer goods than he could
possibly use. Yet he, like the rest of us, has only 24 hours each day and a limited amount
of energy. So even he confronts trade-offs. Any activity he pursues—whether it be build-
ing his business empire or redecorating his mansion—uses up time and energy that he
could otherwise spend on other things. Indeed, someone once calculated that the value If Jeff Bezos saw a $100 bill
of Bezos’s time is so great that pausing to pick up a $100 bill from the sidewalk simply lying on the sidewalk, would it
wouldn’t be worth his while. be worth his time to pick it up?

APPLYING THE COST-BENEFIT PRINCIPLE


In studying choice under scarcity, we’ll usually begin with the premise that people are
rational, which means they have well-defined goals and try to fulfill them as best they rational person someone
can. The Cost-Benefit Principle is a fundamental tool for the study of how rational people with well-defined goals who
make choices. tries to fulfill those goals as
As in the class-size example, often the only real difficulty in applying the cost-­benefit best he or she can
rule is to come up with reasonable measures of the relevant benefits and costs. Only in
rare instances will exact dollar measures be conveniently available. But the cost-benefit
framework can lend structure to your thinking even when no relevant market data are
available.
To illustrate how we proceed in such cases, the following example asks you to decide
whether to perform an action whose cost is described only in vague, qualitative terms.
4 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

E XA MP LE 1.1 Comparing Costs and Benefits


Should you walk downtown to save $10 on a $25 wireless keyboard?
Imagine you are about to buy a $25 wireless keyboard at the nearby campus store
when a friend tells you that the same keyboard is on sale at a downtown store for
only $15. If the downtown store is a 30-minute walk away, where should you buy
the keyboard?

The Cost-Benefit Principle tells us that you should buy it downtown if the b ­ enefit
Cost-Benefit
of doing so exceeds the cost. The benefit of taking any action is the dollar value
of everything you gain by taking it. Here, the benefit of buying downtown is exactly
$10, because that’s the amount you’ll save on the price of the keyboard. The cost
of taking any action is the dollar value of everything you give up by taking it. Here,
the cost of buying downtown is the dollar value you assign to the time and trouble
it takes to make the trip. But how do we estimate that value?
One way is to perform the following hypothetical auction. Imagine that a stranger
has offered to pay you to do an errand that involves the same walk downtown
(perhaps to drop off a package for her at the post office). If she offered you a pay-
ment of, say, $1,000, would you accept? If so, we know that your cost of walking
downtown and back must be less than $1,000. Now imagine her offer being reduced
in small increments until you finally refuse the last offer. For example, if you’d agree
to walk downtown and back for $9 but not for $8.99, then your cost of making
the trip is $9. In this case, you should buy the keyboard downtown because the
$10 you’ll save (your benefit) is greater than your $9 cost of making the trip.
But suppose your cost of making the trip had been greater than $10. In that
case, your best bet would have been to buy the keyboard from the nearby cam-
pus store. Confronted with this choice, different people may choose differently,
depending on how costly they think it is to make the trip downtown. But although
there is no uniquely correct choice, most people who are asked what they would
do in this situation say they would buy the keyboard downtown.

ECONOMIC SURPLUS
Suppose that in Example 1.1 your “cost” of making the trip downtown was $9. Compared
to the alternative of buying the keyboard at the campus store, buying it downtown
economic surplus the resulted in an economic surplus of $1, the difference between the benefit of making the
benefit of taking an action trip and its cost. In general, your goal as an economic decision maker is to choose those
minus its cost actions that generate the largest possible economic surplus. This means taking all actions
that yield a positive total economic surplus, which is just another way of restating the Cost-­
Cost-Benefit
Benefit Principle.
Note that the fact that your best choice was to buy the keyboard downtown doesn’t imply
that you enjoy making the trip, any more than choosing a large class means that you prefer
large classes to small ones. It simply means that the trip is less unpleasant than the prospect
of paying $10 extra for the keyboard. Once again, you’ve faced a trade-off. In this case, the
choice was between a cheaper keyboard and the free time gained by avoiding the trip.

OPPORTUNITY COST
Of course, your mental auction could have produced a different outcome. Suppose, for
example, that the time required for the trip is the only time you have left to study for a
difficult test the next day. Or suppose you are watching one of your favorite shows on
opportunity cost the value Netflix, or that you are tired and would love a short nap. In such cases, we say that the
of what must be forgone to opportunity cost of making the trip—that is, the value of what you must sacrifice to walk
undertake an activity downtown and back—is high and you are more likely to decide against making the trip.
Applying the Cost-Benefit Principle 5

Strictly speaking, your opportunity cost of engaging in an activity is the value of


everything you must sacrifice to engage in it. For instance, if seeing a movie requires not
only that you buy a $10 ticket, but also that you give up a $20 dogwalking job that you
would have been willing to do for free, then the opportunity cost of seeing the film is $30.
Under this definition, all costs—both implicit and explicit—are opportunity costs.
Unless otherwise stated, we will adhere to this strict definition.
We must warn you, however, that some economists use the term opportunity cost to
refer only to the implicit value of opportunities forgone. Thus, in the example just dis-
cussed, these economists wouldn’t include the $10 ticket price when calculating the oppor-
tunity cost of seeing the film. But virtually all economists would agree that your
opportunity cost of not doing the dogwalking job is $20.
In the previous example, if watching another hour of your favorite show on Netflix
is the most valuable opportunity that conflicts with the trip downtown, the opportunity
cost of making the trip is the dollar value you place on pursuing that opportunity. It is
the largest amount you’d be willing to pay to avoid watching your show at another time.
Note that the opportunity cost of making the trip is not the combined value of all possi-
ble activities you could have pursued, but only the value of your best alternative—the one
you would have chosen had you not made the trip.
Throughout the text we’ll pose self-tests like the one that follows. You’ll find that
pausing to answer them will help you to master key concepts in economics. Because
doing these self-tests isn’t very costly (indeed, many students report that they’re actu-
ally fun), the Cost-Benefit Principle indicates that it’s well worth your while to do
Cost-Benefit
them.

SELF-TEST 1.1
You would again save $10 by buying the wireless keyboard downtown rather
than at the campus store, but your cost of making the trip is now $12, not $9.
By how much would your economic surplus be smaller if you bought the
keyboard downtown rather than at the campus store?

THE ROLE OF ECONOMIC MODELS


Economists use the Cost-Benefit Principle as an abstract model of how an idealized
rational individual would choose among competing alternatives. (By “abstract model” we
mean a simplified description that captures the essential elements of a situation and allows
us to analyze them in a logical way.) A computer model of a complex phenomenon like
climate change, which must ignore many details and includes only the major forces at
work, is an example of an abstract model.
Noneconomists are sometimes harshly critical of the economist’s cost-benefit model
on the grounds that people in the real world never conduct hypothetical mental auctions
before deciding whether to make trips downtown. But this criticism betrays a fundamen-
tal misunderstanding of how abstract models can help explain and predict human behav-
ior. Economists know perfectly well that people don’t conduct hypothetical mental
auctions when they make simple decisions. All the Cost-Benefit Principle really says is
that a rational decision is one that is explicitly or implicitly based on a weighing of costs
and benefits.
Most of us make sensible decisions most of the time, without being consciously aware
that we are weighing costs and benefits, just as most people ride a bike without being
consciously aware of what keeps them from falling. Through trial and error, we gradually
learn what kinds of choices tend to work best in different contexts, just as bicycle riders
internalize the relevant laws of physics, usually without being conscious of them.
Even so, learning the explicit principles of cost-benefit analysis can help us make
better decisions, just as knowing about physics can help in learning to ride a bicycle. For
instance, when a young economist was teaching his oldest son to ride a bike, he followed
6 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

the time-honored tradition of running alongside the bike and holding onto his son, then
giving him a push and hoping for the best. After several hours and painfully skinned
elbows and knees, his son finally got it. A year later, someone pointed out that the trick
to riding a bike is to turn slightly in whichever direction the bike is leaning. Of course!
The economist passed this information along to his second son, who learned to ride
almost instantly. Just as knowing a little physics can help you learn to ride a bike, know-
ing a little economics can help you make better decisions.

RECAP
COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS
Scarcity is a basic fact of economic life. Because of it, having more of one
good thing almost always means having less of another (the scarcity princi-
ple). The Cost-Benefit Principle holds that an individual (or a firm or a society)
should take an action if, and only if, the extra benefit from taking the action
is at least as great as the extra cost. The benefit of taking any action minus
the cost of taking the action is called the economic surplus from that action.
Hence, the Cost-Benefit Principle suggests that we take only those actions
that create additional economic surplus.

THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS1


Rational people will apply the Cost-Benefit Principle most of the time, although prob-
ably in an intuitive and approximate way, rather than through explicit and precise cal-
culation. Knowing that rational people tend to compare costs and benefits enables
economists to predict their likely behavior. As noted earlier, for example, we can predict
that students from wealthy families are more likely than others to attend colleges that
offer small classes. (Again, while the cost of small classes is the same for all families,
their benefit, as measured by what people are willing to pay for them, tends to be higher
for wealthier families.)
Yet researchers have identified situations in which people tend to apply the Cost-­
Benefit Principle inconsistently. In these situations, the Cost-Benefit Principle may not
predict behavior accurately. But it proves helpful in another way, by identifying specific
strategies for avoiding bad decisions.

PITFALL 1: MEASURING COSTS AND BENEFITS AS PROPORTIONS


RATHER THAN ABSOLUTE DOLLAR AMOUNTS
As the next example makes clear, even people who seem to know they should weigh the
pros and cons of the actions they are contemplating sometimes don’t have a clear sense
of how to measure the relevant costs and benefits.

E XA MP LE 1.2 Comparing Costs and Benefits

Should you walk downtown to save $10 on a $2,020 laptop


computer?
You are about to buy a $2,020 laptop computer at the nearby campus store when
a friend tells you that the same computer is on sale at a downtown store for only
$2,010. If the downtown store is half an hour’s walk away, where should you buy
the computer?
1
The examples in this section are inspired by the pioneering research of Daniel Kahneman and the late Amos
Tversky. Kahneman was awarded the 2002 Nobel Prize in Economics for his efforts to integrate insights from
psychology into economics. You can read more about this work in Kahneman’s brilliant 2011 book, Thinking
Fast and Slow (New York: Macmillan).
THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS 7

Assuming that the laptop is light enough to carry without effort, the ­structure
of this example is exactly the same as that of Example 1.1. The only difference is
that the price of the laptop is dramatically higher than the price of the wireless
keyboard. As before, the benefit of buying downtown is the dollar amount you’ll
save, namely, $10. And because it’s exactly the same trip, its cost also must be
the same as before. So if you are perfectly rational, you should make the same
decision in both cases. Yet when people are asked what they would do in these
situations, the overwhelming majority say they’d walk downtown to buy the key-
board but would buy the laptop at the campus store. When asked to explain, most
of them say something like, “The trip was worth it for the keyboard because you
save 40 percent, but not worth it for the laptop because you save only $10 out
of $2,020.”
This is faulty reasoning. The benefit of the trip downtown is not the propor-
tion you save on the original price. Rather, it is the absolute dollar amount you
save. The benefit of walking downtown to buy the laptop is $10, exactly the
same as for the wireless keyboard. And because the cost of the trip must also
be the same in both cases, the economic surplus from making both trips must
be exactly the same. That means that a rational decision maker would make the
same decision in both cases. Yet, as noted, most people choose differently.

The pattern of faulty reasoning in the decision just discussed is one of several decision
pitfalls to which people are often prone. In the discussion that follows, we will identify
two additional decision pitfalls. In some cases, people ignore costs or benefits that they
ought to take into account. On other occasions they are influenced by costs or benefits
that are irrelevant.

SELF-TEST 1.2
Which is more valuable: saving $100 on a $2,000 plane ticket to Tokyo or
saving $90 on a $200 plane ticket to Chicago?

PITFALL 2: IGNORING IMPLICIT COSTS


Sherlock Holmes, Arthur Conan Doyle’s legendary detective, was successful because he
saw details that most others overlooked. In Silver Blaze, Holmes is called on to investigate
the theft of an expensive racehorse from its stable. A Scotland Yard inspector assigned
to the case asks Holmes whether some particular aspect of the crime requires further
study. “Yes,” Holmes replies, and describes “the curious incident of the dog in the night-
time.” “The dog did nothing in the nighttime,”2 responds the puzzled inspector. But, as
Holmes realized, that was precisely the problem! The watchdog’s failure to bark when
Silver Blaze was stolen meant that the watchdog knew the thief. This clue ultimately
proved the key to unraveling the mystery.
Just as we often don’t notice when a dog fails to bark, many of us tend to overlook
the implicit value of activities that fail to happen. As discussed earlier, however, intelligent
decisions require taking the value of forgone opportunities properly into account.
The opportunity cost of an activity, once again, is the value of all that must be forgone
in order to engage in that activity. If buying a wireless keyboard downtown means not
watching another hour of your favorite show on Netflix, then the value to you of watching
the show is an implicit cost of the trip. Many people make bad decisions because they
tend to ignore the value of such forgone opportunities. To avoid overlooking implicit costs,
economists often translate questions like “Should I walk downtown?” into ones like
“Should I walk downtown or watch another hour of my favorite show?” Implicit costs are like dogs
that fail to bark in the night.
2
Arthur Conan Doyle, “The Adventure of Silver Blaze,” The Memoirs of Sherlock Holmes (London: George Many of us tend to overlook
Newnes Ltd., 1893). activities that fail to happen.
8 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

E XA MP LE 1.3 Implicit Cost


Should you use your frequent-flyer coupon to fly to Cancun for spring
break?
With spring break only a week away, you are still undecided about whether to go
to Cancun with a group of classmates at the University of Iowa. The round-trip
airfare from Cedar Rapids is $500, but you have a frequent-flyer coupon you could
use for the trip. All other relevant costs for the vacation week at the beach total
exactly $1,000. The most you would be willing to pay for the Cancun vacation is
$1,350. That amount is your benefit of taking the vacation. Your only alternative
use for your frequent-flyer coupon is for a trip to Boston the weekend after spring
break to attend your brother’s wedding. (Your coupon expires shortly thereafter.)
If the Cedar Rapids–Boston round-trip airfare is $400, should you use your
­frequent-flyer coupon to fly to Cancun for spring break?
Cost-Benefit The Cost-Benefit Principle tells us that you should go to Cancun if the bene-
fits of the trip exceed its costs. If not for the complication of the frequent-flyer
coupon, solving this problem would be a straightforward matter of comparing your
benefit from the week at the beach to the sum of all relevant costs. And because
your airfare and other costs would add up to $1,500, or $150 more than your
benefit from the trip, you would not go to Cancun.
But what about the possibility of using your frequent-flyer coupon to make
Bkindler/E+/Getty Images

the trip? Using it for that purpose might make the flight to Cancun seem free,
suggesting you’d reap an economic surplus of $350 by making the trip. But doing
so also would mean you’d have to fork over $400 for your airfare to Boston. So
the implicit cost of using your coupon to go to Cancun is really $400. If you use
it for that purpose, the trip still ends up being a loser because the cost of the
Is your flight to Cancun “free”
vacation, $1,400, exceeds the benefit by $50. In cases like these, you’re much
if you travel on a frequent-flyer more likely to decide sensibly if you ask yourself, “Should I use my frequent-flyer
coupon? coupon for this trip or save it for an upcoming trip?”

We cannot emphasize strongly enough that the key to using the Cost-Benefit
Principle correctly lies in recognizing precisely what taking a given action prevents
us from doing. Self-Test 1.3 illustrates this point by modifying the details of Example 1.3
slightly.

SELF-TEST 1.3
Refer to given information in Example 1.3, but this time your frequent-flyer
coupon expires in a week, so your only chance to use it will be for the C
­ ancun
trip. Should you use your coupon?

PITFALL 3: FAILING TO THINK AT THE MARGIN


When deciding whether to take an action, the only relevant costs and benefits are those
that would occur as a result of taking the action. Sometimes people are influenced by
costs they ought to ignore. Other times they compare the wrong costs and benefits. The
only costs that should influence a decision about whether to take an action are those we can
sunk cost a cost that is avoid by not taking the action. Similarly, the only benefits we should consider are those that
beyond recovery at the would not occur unless the action were taken. As a practical matter, however, many decision
moment a decision must makers appear to be influenced by costs or benefits that would have occurred no matter
be made what. Thus, people are often influenced by sunk costs—costs that are beyond recovery at the
THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS 9

moment a decision is made. For example, money spent on a nontransferable, nonrefundable


airline ticket is a sunk cost.
As the following example illustrates, sunk costs must be borne whether or not an action
is taken, so they are irrelevant to the decision of whether to take the action.

E XA MP LE 1 .4 Sunk Cost

How much should you eat at an all-you-can-eat restaurant?


Sangam, an Indian restaurant in Philadelphia, offers an all-you-can-eat lunch
­buffet for $10. Customers pay $10 at the door, and no matter how many times
they refill their plates, there is no additional charge. One day, as a goodwill ges-
ture, the owner of the restaurant tells 20 randomly selected guests that they can
eat at the all-you-can-eat buffet for free. The remaining guests pay the usual
price. If all diners are rational, will those who are able to eat at the buffet for
free consume a different amount of food, on average, than those who have to
pay $10 for the buffet?

Having eaten their first helping, diners in each group confront the following
question: “Should I go back for another helping?” For rational diners, if the ben-
efit of doing so exceeds the cost, the answer is yes; otherwise it is no. Note that
at the moment of decision, the $10 charge for the lunch is a sunk cost. Those
who paid it have no way to recover it. Thus, for both groups, the (extra) cost of
another helping is exactly zero. And because the people who received the free
lunch were chosen at random, there’s no reason their appetites or incomes should
be any different from those of other diners. The benefit of another helping thus
should be the same, on average, for people in both groups. And because their
respective costs and benefits are the same, the two groups should eat the same
number of helpings, on average.
Psychologists and economists have experimental evidence, however, that
people in such groups do not eat similar amounts.3 In particular, those who have
to pay for the all-you-can-eat buffet tend to eat substantially more than those for
whom the buffet is free. People in the former group somehow seem determined
to “get their money’s worth.” Their implicit goal is apparently to minimize the
average cost per bite of the food they eat. Yet minimizing average cost is not a
particularly sensible objective. The irony is that diners who are determined to get
their money’s worth usually end up eating too much.

The fact that the cost-benefit criterion failed the test of prediction in Example 1.4
does nothing to invalidate its advice about what people should do. If you are letting sunk
costs influence your decisions, you can do better by changing your behavior.
In addition to paying attention to costs and benefits that should be ignored, people
often use incorrect measures of the relevant costs and benefits. This error often occurs
marginal cost the increase
when we must choose the extent to which an activity should be pursued (as opposed to
in total cost that results from
choosing whether to pursue it at all). We can apply the Cost-Benefit Principle in such
carrying out one additional
situations by repeatedly asking the question, “Should I increase the level at which I am
unit of an activity
currently pursuing the activity?”
In attempting to answer this question, the focus should always be on the benefit and marginal benefit the
cost of an additional unit of activity. To emphasize this focus, economists refer to the cost increase in total benefit that
of an additional unit of activity as its marginal cost. Similarly, the benefit of an additional results from carrying out one
unit of the activity is its marginal benefit. additional unit of an activity

3
See, for example, Richard Thaler, “Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice,” Journal of Economic Behavior
and Organization 1, no. 1 (1980).
10 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

When the problem is to discover the proper level for an activity, the cost-benefit rule
is to keep increasing the level as long as the marginal benefit of the activity exceeds its
marginal cost. As the following example illustrates, however, people often fail to apply
this rule correctly.

E XA MP LE 1.5 Focusing on Marginal Costs and Benefits


Should SpaceX expand its launch program from four launches per
year to five?
SpaceX accountants have estimated that the gains from the company’s jumbo
rocket launch program are currently $24 billion a year (an average of $6 billion
per launch) and that its costs are currently $20 billion a year (an average
$5 billion per launch). On the basis of these estimates, they have recommended
that the company should increase its number of launches. Should SpaceX CEO
Elon Musk follow their advice?

To discover whether the advice makes economic sense, we must compare


the marginal cost of a launch to its marginal benefit. The accountants’ estimates,
average cost the total cost however, tell us only the average cost and average benefit of the program. These
of undertaking n units of an are, respectively, the total cost of the program divided by the number of launches
activity divided by n and the total benefit divided by the number of launches.
Knowing the average benefit and average cost per launch for all rockets
average benefit the total
launched thus far is simply not useful for deciding whether to expand the program.
benefit of undertaking n units
Of course, the average cost of the launches undertaken so far might be the same
of an activity divided by n
as the cost of adding another launch. But it also might be either higher or lower
than the marginal cost of a launch. The same holds true regarding average and
marginal benefits.
Suppose, for the sake of discussion, that the benefit of an additional launch is
in fact the same as the average benefit per launch thus far, $6 billion. Should
SpaceX add another launch? Not if the cost of adding the fifth launch would be
more than $6 billion. And the fact that the average cost per launch is only $5 billion
simply does not tell us anything about the marginal cost of the fifth launch.
Suppose, for example, that the relationship between the number of rockets
launched and the total cost of the program is as described in Table 1.1. The aver-
age cost per launch (third column) when there are four launches would then be
$20 billion/4 = $5 billion per launch, just as the accountants reported. But note
in the second column of the table that adding a fifth launch would raise costs
from $20 billion to $32 billion, making the marginal cost of the fifth launch
$12 billion. So if the benefit of an additional launch is $6 billion, increasing the
number of launches from four to five would make absolutely no economic sense.

TABLE 1.1
How Total Cost Varies with the Number of Launches
Number of Total cost Average cost
launches ($ billions) ($ billion/launch)
0 0 0
1 3 3
2 7 3.5
3 12 4
4 20 5
5 32 6.4
THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS 11

The following example illustrates how to apply the Cost-Benefit Principle correctly in
this case.

E XA MP LE 1 .6 Focusing on Marginal Costs and Benefits

How many rockets should SpaceX launch?


SpaceX must decide how many rockets to launch. The benefit of each launch is
estimated to be $6 billion, and the total cost of the program again depends on the
number of launches as shown in Table 1.1. How many rockets should SpaceX launch?

SpaceX should continue to launch its jumbo rockets as long as the marginal
benefit of the program exceeds its marginal cost. In this example, the marginal
benefit is constant at $6 billion per launch, regardless of the number of rockets
launched. SpaceX should thus keep launching rockets as long as the marginal
cost per launch is less than or equal to $6 billion.
Applying the definition of marginal cost to the total cost entries in the second
column of Table 1.1 yields the marginal cost values in the third column of Table 1.2.
(Because marginal cost is the change in total cost that results when we change
the number of launches by one, we place each marginal cost entry midway
between the rows showing the corresponding total cost entries.) Thus, for exam-
ple, the marginal cost of increasing the number of launches from one to two is
$4 billion, the difference between the $7 billion total cost of two launches and
the $3 billion total cost of one launch.

TABLE 1.2
How Marginal Cost Varies with the Number of Launches
Number of Total cost Marginal cost
launches ($ billions) ($ billion/launch)
0 0
3
1 3
4
2 7
5
3 12
8
4 20
12
5 32

As we see from a comparison of the $6 billion marginal benefit per launch


with the marginal cost entries in the third column of Table 1.2, the first three
launches satisfy the cost-benefit test, but the fourth and fifth launches do not.
SpaceX should thus launch three rockets.

SELF-TEST 1.4
If the marginal benefit of each launch had been not $6 billion but $9 billion,
how many rockets should SpaceX have launched?

The cost-benefit framework emphasizes that the only relevant costs and benefits in
deciding whether to pursue an activity further are marginal costs and benefits—measures
that correspond to the increment of activity under consideration. In many contexts, ­however,
12 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

people seem more inclined to compare the average cost and benefit of the activity. As
Example 1.5 made clear, increasing the level of an activity may not be justified, even though
its average benefit at the current level is significantly greater than its average cost.

SELF-TEST 1.5
Should a basketball team’s best player take all the team’s shots?
A professional basketball team has a new assistant coach. The assistant
notices that one player scores on a higher percentage of her shots than other
players. Based on this information, the assistant suggests to the head coach
that the star player should take all the shots. That way, the assistant reasons,
the team will score more points and win more games.
On hearing this suggestion, the head coach fires her assistant for incom-
petence. What was wrong with the assistant’s idea?

RECAP
THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS
1. The pitfall of measuring costs or benefits proportionally. Many decision
makers treat a change in cost or benefit as insignificant if it constitutes
only a small proportion of the original amount. Absolute dollar amounts,
not proportions, should be employed to measure costs and benefits.
2. The pitfall of ignoring implicit costs. When performing a cost-benefit
analysis of an action, it is important to account for all relevant costs,
including the implicit value of alternatives that must be forgone in order
to carry out the action. A resource (such as a frequent-flyer coupon) may
have a high implicit cost, even if you originally got it “for free,” if its best
alternative use has high value. The identical resource may have a low
implicit cost, however, if it has no good alternative uses.
3. The pitfall of failing to think at the margin. When deciding whether to
perform an action, the only costs and benefits that are relevant are those
that would result from taking the action. It is important to ignore sunk
costs—those costs that cannot be avoided even if the action isn’t taken.
Even though a ticket to a concert may have cost you $100, if you’ve
already bought it and cannot sell it to anyone else, the $100 is a sunk
cost and shouldn’t influence your decision about whether to go to the
concert. It’s also important not to confuse average costs and benefits
with marginal costs and benefits. Decision makers often have ready
information about the total cost and benefit of an activity, and from these
it’s simple to compute the activity’s average cost and benefit. A common
mistake is to conclude that an activity should be increased if its average
benefit exceeds its average cost. The Cost-Benefit Principle tells us that
the level of an activity should be increased if, and only if, its marginal
benefit exceeds its marginal cost.

Some costs and benefits, especially marginal costs and benefits and implicit costs,
are important for decision making, while others, like sunk costs and average costs and
benefits, are essentially irrelevant. This conclusion is implicit in our original statement
of the Cost-Benefit Principle (an action should be taken if, and only if, the extra ben-
Cost-Benefit
efits of taking it exceed the extra costs). When we encounter additional examples of
decision pitfalls, we will flag them by inserting the icon for the Cost-Benefit Principle
as shown here.
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
The Project Gutenberg eBook of Michael Field
This ebook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United
States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with
almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away
or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License
included with this ebook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you
are not located in the United States, you will have to check the
laws of the country where you are located before using this
eBook.

Title: Michael Field

Author: Mary Sturgeon

Release date: May 31, 2022 [eBook #68213]

Language: English

Original publication: United Kingdom: George G. Harrap & Co,


1922

Credits: Chuck Greif and the Online Distributed Proofreading


Team at http://www.pgdp.net (This file was produced
from images available at The Internet Archive)

*** START OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK MICHAEL


FIELD ***
THE HARRAP LIBRARY

1. EMERSON’S ESSAYS
First Series
2. EMERSON’S ESSAYS
Second Series
3. THE POETRY OF EARTH
A Nature Anthology
4. PARADISE LOST
John Milton
5. THE ESSAYS OF ELIA
Charles Lamb
6. THE THOUGHTS OF MARCUS AURELIUS
ANTONINUS
George Long
7. REPRESENTATIVE MEN
R. W. Emerson
8. ENGLISH TRAITS
R. W. Emerson
9. LAST ESSAYS OF ELIA
Charles Lamb
10. PARADISE REGAINED AND MINOR POEMS
John Milton
11. SARTOR RESARTUS
Thomas Carlyle
12. THE BOOK OF EPICTETUS
The Enchiridion, with Chapters from the Discourses,
etc. Translated by Elizabeth Carter. Edited by T. W.
Rolleston.
13. THE CONDUCT OF LIFE
R. W. Emerson
14. NATURE: ADDRESSES AND LECTURES
R. W. Emerson
15. THE ENGLISH HUMOURISTS OF THE
EIGHTEENTH CENTURY
W. M. Thackeray
16. DAY-DREAMS OF A SCHOOLMASTER
D’Arcy W. Thompson
17. ON HEROES AND HERO-WORSHIP
Thomas Carlyle
18. TALES IN PROSE AND VERSE
Bret Harte
19. LEAVES OF GRASS
Walt Whitman
20. HAZLITT’S ESSAYS
21. KARMA AND OTHER ESSAYS
Lafcadio Hearn
22. THE GOLDEN BOOK OF ENGLISH SONNETS
Edited by William Robertson
Further volumes will be announced later

MICHAEL FIELD
BY MARY STURGEON

“ ... the two friends ...


Who sought perfection and achieved far more.”
Gordon Bottomley
Katharine Bradley
and
Edith Cooper
The latter from a miniature
by Mr Charles Ricketts in
the Fitzwilliam Museum, Cambridge

MICHAEL
FIELD
BY MARY STURGEON

AUTHOR OF “STUDIES OF CONTEMPORARY


POETS” “WESTMINSTER ABBEY” ETC.

LONDON: GEORGE G.
HARRAP & CO. LTD.
2-3 PORTSMOUTH ST. KINGSWAY
& AT CALCUTTA AND SYDNEY

First published March 1922

Printed in Great Britain at The Ballantyne Press by


Spottiswoode, Ballantyne & Co. Ltd.
Colchester, London & Eton
PREFACE

S OME years ago the writer of this book discovered to herself the work of
Michael Field, with fresh delight at every step of her adventure through
the lyrics, the tragedies, and later devotional poems. But she was
amazed to find that no one seemed to have heard about this large body of
fine poetry; and she longed to spread the news, even before the further
knowledge was gained that the life of Michael Field had itself been epical
in romance and heroism. Then the theme was irresistible.
But although it has been a joy to try to retrieve something of this life and
work from the limbo into which it appeared to be slipping, the matter may
wear anything but a joyful aspect to all the long-suffering ones who were
ruthlessly laid under tribute. The author remembers guiltily the many
friends of the poets whom she has harried, and kindly library staffs (in
particular at the Bodleian) who gave generous and patient help. To each one
she offers sincere gratitude; and though it is impossible to name them all,
she desires especially to record her debt to Mr Sturge Moore and Miss
Fortey; Father Vincent McNabb, Mrs Berenson, and Mr Charles Ricketts;
Dr Grenfell, Sir Herbert Warren, and Mr and Mrs Algernon Warren; Miss S.
J. Tanner, Mr Havelock Ellis and Miss Louie Ellis; the Misses Sturge;
Professor F. Brooks and the Rev. C. L. Bradley; Professor and Mrs William
Rothenstein; Mr Gordon Bottomley and Mr Arthur Symons—;who will all
understand her regret that this book is so unworthy a tribute to their friend
and that the scheme of it, designed primarily to introduce the poetry of
Michael Field, rendered impossible a fuller use of the material for a Life
which they supplied.
To the courtesy of Mr Sydney C. Cockerell, the Director of the
Fitzwilliam Museum, Cambridge, the author owes the copy of Edith
Cooper’s portrait. This portrait is a miniature set in a jewelled pendant (both
drawing and setting the work of Mr Charles Ricketts) which was
bequeathed to the Fitzwilliam Museum on the death of Katharine Bradley.
Warm thanks are also tendered to the publishers who have kindly given
permission to use extracts from the poets’ works, including Messrs G. Bell
and Sons, the Vale Press, the Poetry Bookshop (for Borgia, Queen
Mariamne, Deirdre, and In the Name of Time); to Mr T. Fisher Unwin,
Messrs Sands and Company, and Mr Eveleigh Nash; and to Mr Heinemann
for Mr Arthur Symons’s poem At Fontainebleau.
A Bibliography is appended of all the Michael Field books which have
been published to date; but there still remain some unpublished MSS.
MARY STURGEON
Oxford
November 1921
CONTENTS
I. BIOGRAPHICAL 13
II. THE LYRICS 65
III. THE TRAGEDIES—;I 114
IV. THE TRAGEDIES—;II 162
V. THE TRAGEDIES—;III 197
BIBLIOGRAPHY 245

Yea, gold is son of Zeus: no rust


Its timeless light can stain;
The worm that brings man’s flesh to dust
Assaults its strength in vain:
More gold than gold the love I sing,
A hard, inviolable thing.

Men say the passions should grow old


With waning years; my heart
Is incorruptible as gold,
’Tis my immortal part:
Nor is there any god can lay
On love the finger of decay.
Long Ago, XXXVI
I. BIOGRAPHICAL

O NE evening, probably in the spring of 1885, Browning was at a


dinner-party given by Stopford Brooke. He had recently met for the
first time two quiet ladies who had come up to the metropolis from
Bristol to visit art galleries and talk business with publishers, and he
suddenly announced to the company in a lull of conversation, “I have found
a new poet.” But others of the party had made a similar discovery: it had
jumped to the eye of the intelligent about a year before, when a tragedy
called Callirrhoë had been published; and several voices cried
simultaneously to the challenge, “Michael Field!”
Only Browning, however, and a few intimate friends of the poets, knew
that Michael Field was not a man, but two women, Katharine Bradley and
Edith Cooper. They were an aunt and niece, and came of a Derbyshire
family settled at Ashbourne. Joseph Bradley, its representative there in
1749, with his son and grandson after him, were merchants of substance
and culture. They were men of intellect as well as business men, and seem
to have possessed between them all the elements which ultimately became
concentrated in our two poets. There is evidence of a leaning to philosophy,
a feeling for the arts, an interest in drama; and, more significant still, there
is one Charles Bradley who was “a prolific and meditative writer both of
prose and song.”
Katharine Harris Bradley, the elder of the two poets, was born at
Birmingham on October 27, 1846. Her grandfather had migrated there from
Ashbourne in 1810, and her father, Charles Bradley, was a tobacco-
manufacturer of that city. He had married in 1834 a Miss Emma Harris of
Birmingham, and, in the simpler fashion of those times, he and his wife
were living in a house adjoining their place of business in the old quarter of
the town. There, at 10 Digbeth, Katharine was born, The only other child of
the union was a daughter who was eleven years old at Katharine’s birth. She
was named Emma, and was of first importance in the lives of the Michael
Fields. For, being a thoughtful creature, of rare sweetness and strength of
character, she largely shaped the life of the little sister who was so much
younger than herself; and, still more vital fact, she afterward became the
mother of our second poet. She married, about 1860, James Robert Cooper,
and went with him to live at Kenilworth. Her daughter, Edith Emma
Cooper, was born there, at their house in the High Street, on January 12,
1862.
Both poets, therefore, took their origin in the heart of a Midland city and
came of merchant stock. These facts may have larger significance than their
bearing on environment and nurture, though that was important. But
regarded more widely, they seem to relate Michael Field and her fine
contribution to English literature to that movement in our modern
civilization which, in the last two or three generations, has drawn commerce
into intimate connexion with our art and letters. Such names as Horniman,
Fry, Beecham (and there are others of similar import) suggest at once
drama, art, music. They are associated in one’s mind with new impulse,
energy, initiative, and above all with disinterested service of the arts; and
they are connected chiefly with Midland towns. In like manner Michael
Field, with her gift of tragic vision sublimated from fierce Derbyshire
elements, may be seen spending a strenuous life and a moderate fortune,
without reward or encouragement, to enrich English poetry.
Neither poet ever attended school, or swotted to gain certificates; which
is probably one reason why they both became highly educated and cultured
people. When Katharine was two years old her father died from cancer—;a
disease which afterward carried off her mother, and from which both our
poets died. Mrs Bradley removed to a suburb of Birmingham, and was
careful to provide that the lessons which she gave her little girls should be
supplemented, as the need arose, by other and more advanced teaching. But
the children were allowed to follow their bent, and authority took the form
of a wise and kindly directing influence. We hear in those early days of
eager studies in French, painting, and Italian. We hear, too, of friendships
with a group of lively cousins. One of them remembers Katharine’s vivid
childhood, and speaks of her as a gay and frolicsome creature, highly
imaginative and emotional, with whom he used to act and recite. She
adored poetry, would write even her letters in rhyme, and had, as a small
child, a particular fondness for Scott’s Lady of the Lake. And she joined
with the greatest delight in the dramatic ventures which the group from time
to time attempted, such as the representation at Christmas of the passage of
the Old Year and the coming of the New.
It is probable that such conditions were ideally suited to a child of great
natural gifts and buoyant temperament. Katharine evidently thrived under
them both in mind and body; and by the time of her sister’s marriage to Mr
Cooper she was not only the healthy, happy, and well-developed young
animal who was the potential of all she afterward became, but she had
already embarked upon the classics and was beginning to interest herself in
German language and literature. Thus it happened that when, about 1861,
she and her mother made their home with the Coopers at Kenilworth,
Katharine became the natural companion of the little Edith, born in the
following year, when Katharine was sixteen. But she was, from the first,
much more than that. Mrs Cooper remained an invalid for life after the birth
of her second daughter, Amy, and Katharine fostered Edith as a mother. She
lavished on her an eager and rather imperious affection. She led her, as the
child grew old enough, along the paths that she herself had adventurously
gone, and although Edith was always shyer and more hesitating than
Katharine, poetic genius was dormant in her too, only waiting to be
stimulated by Katharine’s exuberance and led by her audacity. Edith,
stepping delicately, followed the daring lead of her elder with a steadiness
of mental power which was her proper gift; and she reaped from
Katharine’s educational harvest (won in all sorts of fields, from literatures
ancient and modern, from the Collège de France, Newnham, University
College, Bristol, and numerous private tutors) fruits more solid and mature
than even Katharine herself.
When the poets removed to Stoke Bishop, Bristol, in 1878 it was with
intellectual appetites still unsatisfied, and determined to pursue at
University College their beloved classics and philosophy. They were
already, in the opinion of a scholar who knew them at that time, fair
latinists: they possessed considerable German and French, and some Italian,
while Edith’s enthusiasm for philosophy was balanced by Katharine’s for
Greek. Edith, docile in so much else, yet “could not be coaxed on” in
Greek; not even later, when Browning, who used to speak affectionately of
her as “our little Francesca,” one day gently pressed her hand and said “in
honied accents, ‘Do learn Greek.’ ” What could a young poet do,
overwhelmed by the courtly old master’s flattery, except promise softly, “I
will try”? But it is not recorded that the effort took her very far. Katharine
the Dionysian (always a little over-zealous for her divinities, whether
Thracian or Hebrew) did not cease from coaxing; and perhaps did not
perceive, for she could be obtuse now and then, how radical was Edith’s
austere latinity. A poem of this period, addressed by Katharine to Edith, and
called An Invitation, throws a gleam on their student days. Through it one
sees as in morning sunlight their strenuous happy existence, their eager
welcome to the best that life could offer, and their fortunate freedom to
grasp it, whether it were in books or art, in sunny aspects or beautiful new
Morris designs and textures. For they were, from the first, artists in life.

Come and sing, my room is south;


Come with thy sun-governed mouth,
Thou wilt never suffer drouth,
Long as dwelling
In my chamber of the south.

Three stanzas describe the woodbine and the myrtles outside the window,
and the cushioned settee inside. Then:
Books I have of long ago
And to-day; I shall not know
Some, unless thou read them, so
Their excelling
Music needs thy voice’s flow:

Campion, with a noble ring


Of choice spirits; count this wing
Sacred! All the songs I sing
Welling, welling
From Elizabethan spring.

French, that corner of primrose!


Flaubert, Verlaine, with all those
Precious, little things in prose,
Bliss-compelling,
Howsoe’er the story goes:

All the Latins thou dost prize!


Cynthia’s lover by thee lies;
Note Catullus, type and size
Least repelling
To thy weariable eyes.

And for Greek! Too sluggishly


Thou dost toil; but Sappho, see!
And the dear Anthology
For thy spelling.
Come, it shall be well with thee.

It is clear from all the testimony that Katharine and Edith were
extremely serious persons in those first years at Stoke Bishop, a fact which
seems to have borne rather hard on the young men of their acquaintance.
Thus, a member of their college, launching a small conversational craft with
a light phrase, might have his barque swamped by the inquiry of one who
really wanted to know: “Which do you truly think is the greater poem, the
Iliad or the Odyssey?” It was an era when Higher Education and Women’s
Rights and Anti-Vivisection were being indignantly championed, and when
‘æsthetic dress’ was being very consciously worn—;all by the same kind of
people. Katharine and Edith were of that kind. They joined the debating
society of the college and plunged into the questions of the moment. They
spoke eloquently in favour of the suffrage for women, and were deeply
interested in ethical matters. They were devotees of reason, and would
subscribe to no creed. Katharine was a prime mover of the Anti-Vivisection
Society in Clifton, and was its secretary till 1887. She was, too, in
correspondence with Ruskin, was strongly influenced by him in moral and
artistic questions, and was a companion of the Guild of St George—;though
that was as far as she ever went in Ruskinian economics. Both of the friends
adored pictures, worked at water-colour drawing, wore wonderful flowing
garments in ‘art’ colours, and dressed their hair in a loose knot at the nape
of the neck.
But more than all that, they were already dedicated to poetry, and sworn
in fellowship. That was in secret, however. Student friends might guess,
thrillingly, but no one had yet been told that Katharine had published in
1875 a volume of lyrics which she signed as Arran Leigh, nor that Edith
had timidly produced for her fellow’s inspection, as the experiment of a girl
of sixteen, several scenes of a powerful tragedy; nor that the two of them
together were at that moment working on their Bellerophôn (with the
accent, please), which they published in 1881, signed “Arran and Isla
Leigh.” But such portentous facts kept them very grave; and their solemnity
naturally provoked the mirth of the irreverent, especially of undergraduate
friends down from Oxford, who knew something on their own account
about æsthetic crazes and the leaders of them. Thus a certain Herbert
Warren came down during one vacation and poked bracing fun at them. The
story makes one suppose that he must have disliked the colour blue in
women and the colour green in every one—;possibly because he was then
in his own salad days. For when somebody mischievously asked him in
Katharine’s presence, “Who are this æsthetic crowd?” he promptly replied,
“They’re people as green as their dresses.”
But their women friends were more favourably impressed. To them the
two eager girls who walked over the downs for lectures every morning were
persons of a certain distinction who, despite careless hair and untidy feet,
could be “perfectly fascinating.” Their manner of speech had been shaped
by old books, and was a little archaic. Later it became a “mighty jargon,”
understood only of the initiate. Their style of dress was daringly clinging
and graceful in an age of ugly protuberances. And though these things
might suggest a pose to the satirical, they were very attractive to the
ingenuous, who saw them simply as the naïve signs they were of budding
individuality. Their friendship, too, was clearly on the grand scale and in the
romantic manner. They were, indeed, absorbed in each other to an extent
which exasperated those who would have liked to engage the affections of
one or the other in another direction. Yet they were companionable souls in
a sympathetic circle, Katharine with abounding vitality and love of fun and
keen joy in life, expansive and forthcoming despite an occasional
haughtiness of manner; and Edith lighting up more slowly, to a rarer, finer,
more delicate exaltation.
Yet, in spite of many friends and a genuine interest in affairs, one
perceives that they constantly gave a sense of seclusion from life, of natures
set a little way apart. It was an impression conveyed unwittingly, and in
spite of themselves; and one is reminded by it of their sonnet called The
Poet, written, I believe, about this time, but not published until 1907, in
Wild Honey:

Within his eyes are hung lamps of the sanctuary:


A wind, from whence none knows, can set in sway
And spill their light by fits; but yet their ray
Returns, deep-boled, to its obscurity.

The world as from a dullard turns annoyed


To stir the days with show or deeds or voices;
But if one spies him justly one rejoices,
With silence that the careful lips avoid.

He is a plan, a work of some strange passion


Life has conceived apart from Time’s harsh drill,
A thing it hides and cherishes to fashion

At odd bright moments to its secret will:


Holy and foolish, ever set apart,
He waits the leisure of his god’s free heart.
Consciously or not, the poem is a portrait. More than one touch is
recognizable, and there can be no doubt that the opening lines give a
glimpse of Edith. They suggest for this reason that the sonnet was written
by Katharine; and if that is so, her use of the word dullard sweetly turns the
edge of the complaint of critical friends that Katharine could be thoroughly
stupid. Of course she could!—;why not? though, to be sure, it was very
provoking of her. Returning, however, to the resemblance to Edith. She had
never the good health of Katharine, and her beauty, which was of the large,
regular, blonde type, suffered in consequence. One of her friends says: “She
was as if touched by a cloud—;crystalline and fragile as flowers that love
the shade.” All who knew her speak of the extraordinary look of vision in
her eyes: time after time one hears of the ‘inspiration’ in her face, which is
visible in no matter how poor a photograph or hasty a sketch. Katharine had
intensity of another kind: warm, rich, glowing, a lyric and almost bacchic
expression. But in Edith there was “a Tuscan quality of refinement, the
outward expression of an inward beauty of thought.”
One cannot but associate those “lamps of the sanctuary” with the psychic
power which Edith undoubtedly possessed. An incident attested by their
cousin, Professor F. Brooks, may be given to illustrate this. It was
occasioned by the death of Edith’s father in the Alps. He and his younger
daughter Amy were there on holiday in 1897, and had planned to climb the
Riffelalp. They wrote of their plan to Katharine and Edith, who received the
letter at home in England on the day that the ascent was being made. Edith
read the letter and passed it to Katharine with the remark: “If they go to the
Riffelalp they will go to their doom.” And, probably about the time she was
speaking, Mr Cooper met his death, for he was lost in the ascent, and his
body was not recovered for many months.
That is only one of several psychic experiences which incontestably
occurred to Edith Cooper, the most impressive being the vision which
appeared to her as her mother was dying. Edith, who was helping to nurse
her mother, had gone into another room to rest, as it was not believed that
the end was near. She afterward told her friend Miss Helen Sturge that in
the moment of death her mother’s spirit passed through the room and
lingered for an instant beside the bed on which Edith was lying. The event
is recorded explicitly in a poem published in Underneath the Bough (first
edition):
When thou to death, fond one, wouldst fain be starting,
I did not pray
That thou shouldst stay;
Alone I lay
And dreamed and wept and watched thee on thy way.

But now thou dost return, yea, after parting,


And me embrace,
Our souls enlace;
Ask thou no grace;
Thou shalt be aye confinèd to this place.

Alone, alone I lie. Ah! bitter smarting!


Thou to the last
Didst cling, kiss fast,
Yet art thou past
Beyond me, in the hollow of a blast.

* * *
‘Michael Field’ did not come into existence until the publication of
Callirrhoë in 1884. The poets put behind them, as experimental work, the
two volumes which they had already published, and began afresh, changing
their pen-names the better to close the past. The pseudonym under which
they now hid themselves was chosen somewhat arbitrarily, ‘Michael’
because they liked the name and its associations, ‘Field’ because it went
well with ‘Michael.’ But it is true also that they had a great admiration for
the work of William Michael Rossetti, whom, Katharine says in one of her
letters, they regarded as “a kind of god-father”; and it is true, too, that
‘Field’ had been an old nickname of Edith. Their family indulged freely in
pet names, and Edith was teased by a nurse, from her boyish appearance
during a fever in Dresden, as the “little Heinrich.” Thenceforth she became
Henry for Katharine, and Katharine was Michael to her and to their
intimates.
Callirrhoë was well received, and went to a second edition in November
of the same year. It is amusing now to read the praises that were lavished
upon ‘Mr Field’ upon his first appearance. Thus the Saturday Review talked

You might also like