1 s2.0 S0957417423021085 Main

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Expert Systems With Applications


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/eswa

Decision-making in a low-carbon supply chain considering consumers’


fairness concerns✩
Haohao Song a , Ying Wang a ,∗, Xiangyu Mao a , Chunyang Wang b
a
College of Economics and Management, Nanjing University of Aeronautics and Astronautics, Nanjing, Jiangsu, China
b
Nanjing Institute of Space Management, Nanjing, Jiangsu, China

ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

Keywords: The purpose of our study is to discuss the impact of consumers’ market distribution and consumers’ fairness
Low-carbon supply chain management concerns on the decisions of supply chain participants. Based on utility theory, we innovatively incorporate
Stackelberg game consumers’ fairness concerns as a significant factor into the game model and focus on the impact of the
Heterogeneous preferences
utility gap between products on consumers’ purchasing willingness. In this paper, we establish a two-echelon
Consumers’ market distribution
supply chain consisting of one traditional manufacturer, one low-carbon manufacturer, and one retailer, and
Consumers’ fairness concerns
comparatively analyze the equilibrium results under the initial state and consumers’ fairness concerns. The
results show that the presence of consumers’ fairness concerns results in the higher wholesale price, higher
retail price, and larger profit of low-carbon products yet leads to a decline in traditional products’ pricing
and profit, and the impacts on the low-carbon manufacturer are more significant than on the traditional
manufacturer. A reduction appears in the retailer’s profit since consumers’ fairness concerns decrease the
retailer’s ability to differential pricing. Additionally, the impacts of consumers’ fairness concerns on the game
equilibrium are also affected by consumers’ market distribution and low-carbon manufacturers’ technical
efficiency, and the impacts are more pronounced in an environment where low-carbon manufacturers’ R&D
investments are more efficient. Furthermore, in a market dominated by low-carbon preferred consumers, low-
carbon manufacturers are always more profitable than traditional manufacturers, while in a market dominated
by traditionally preferred consumers, low-carbon manufacturers are only able to achieve higher profits than
traditional manufacturers when R&D is quite efficient and consumers’ fairness concerns are relatively strong.

1. Introduction 2021; Liang & Futou, 2020). For instance, in an effort to reduce
environmental pollution from exhaust emissions, Toyota has introduced
With the rapid development of industrial technology recently, the Prius, a greener alternative to the regular model (Zhang, Yu, Tan,
global warming becomes increasingly serious (Xia, Lu, & Wang, 2023; Yin and Randhir, 2021). Similarly, Haier also has proposed a four-
Zhao et al., 2021). To mitigate the global greenhouse effect, countries stage green strategy, which is committed to advancing the low-carbon
around the world have reached a consensus on emission reduction upgrade of China’s household electrical appliances (Huang, Zhang, Ren,
and pledged to promote low-carbon development (Gregory, 2022; Luo, & Zhou, 2019). It is undeniable that low-carbon technology investment
Zhou, Song, & Fan, 2022; Zhang, Ma, Si, Liu and Liao, 2021). Under is an important approach to decarbonizing the final product of the
this circumstance, consumers are more conscious of environmental supply chain, however, due to the high cost of pollution control, the
protection when purchasing a product, thereby products’ green perfor- uncertainty of R&D results, and the probability of positive externalities,
mance become a critical factor that significantly influences consumers’ it may inhibit channel members’ motivation to conduct low-carbon
purchasing willingness in addition to product quality and price (Li,
R&D independently (Hong, Cao, Gong, & Chen, 2021; Jiang, Wang,
Meng, Li, & Du, 2022; Zhang, Xin et al., 2021). Manufacturers, as the
Cao, & Fan, 2021; Shi, Liu, Du, & Cheng, 2023). Thus, in order to
main upstream participants in the supply chain, are taking action to
better demonstrate the impact of consumers’ preference for low-carbon
improve products’ green level as well as to enhance their corporate
products on supply chain members, our study constructs a two-stage
images (Heydari, Govindan, & Basiri, 2021; Li, Cui, Li, Xu and Xu,

✩ Our study is supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 71873064) and Social Science Fund Project of Jiangsu Province (Grant
No. 21EYB008).
∗ Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: haohaosong@nuaa.edu.cn (H. Song), yingwang@nuaa.edu.cn (Y. Wang), maoxiangyu@nuaa.edu.cn (X. Mao), mengnjc@hotmail.com
(C. Wang).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa.2023.121606
Received 28 September 2022; Received in revised form 18 August 2023; Accepted 11 September 2023
Available online 20 September 2023
0957-4174/© 2023 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

with both traditional and low-carbon manufacturers and comparatively (1) How do consumers’ low-carbon preferences, market distribution,
analyzes the different influences of consumers’ low-carbon preferences and low-carbon manufacturers’ R&D efficiency influence the decision-
on both parties. making of supply chain participants in the initial status? (2) Compared
Although products with green performance can make consumers with the initial status, how does consumers’ fairness concern affect
reap more benefits than traditional products, these products usually game equilibrium, and how does it affect equilibrium results in dif-
are more expensive, which requires consumers to have a higher ability ferent market environments? (3) What market environments are more
to pay (Lin, Fan, Tan, & Zhu, 2021; Xu, Jing, Shen, Zhou, & Zhao, favorable for manufacturers to conduct low-carbon investments? In
2023). Moreover, many low-carbon products need corresponding sup- consequence, we conduct a two-echelon supply chain consisting of
porting facilities to use, resulting in the existing traditional equipment one traditional manufacturer, one low-carbon manufacturer, and one
becoming sunk costs, which also makes consumers more cautious when retailer in a market composed of traditionally preferred consumers and
choosing to purchase low-carbon products (Li, Hu, Shi and Wang, 2021; low-carbon preferred consumers, where manufacturers are the leader
Wang, Fan, Shen, & Jin, 2020). Based on these reasons, it is difficult in the chain and there is a Cournot competition between two manufac-
for all consumers to immediately transform from traditionally preferred turers. In our study, we incorporate consumers’ market distribution and
consumers to low-carbon preferred consumers, and the coexistence of fairness concerns as significant factors into the game model and then
low-carbon preferred consumers and traditionally preferred consumers discuss the game equilibrium in initial status and consumers’ fairness
will be a common phenomenon in the market (Liu & Xiao, 2020; concerns. A comparison between the outcomes in the different market
Pal, Sarkar, & Sarkar, 2023). Hence, the distribution of consumers environments will also be conducted. Based on the above analysis, we
with different preferences in the market becomes a crucial factor, will provide some advice for the manufacturers and the retailer.
and supply chain participants may take different actions in two cases The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2,
where low-carbon preferred consumers account for the majority and we will briefly review the related literature. In Section 3, our research
traditionally preferred consumers account for the majority. However, describes the problem and derives the manufacturer’s optimal strategies
the existing research tends to assume that all consumers in the whole in the initial status and under consumers’ fairness concerns, respec-
market will purchase green products (Chen, Su, Wu, & Zhou, 2022; tively. In Section 4, we compare the game equilibrium results between
Wang et al., 2020), or just analyzes whether consumers will purchase initial status and consumers’ fairness concerns. Numerical analysis is
green products or traditional products based on the Hotelling model conducted to validate the propositions and obtain some interesting
(Gan, Li, Wang, Zhang, & Huang, 2021; Liu, Liu, Wang, Cui, & Han, results in Section 5. The conclusions and management insights are
2021). Different from these studies, our paper sets up the market summarized in Section 6.
with both traditionally preferred consumers and low-carbon preferred
consumers, and investigates the decision-making behaviors of supply 2. Literature review
chain participants under different market distributions.
Additionally, due to the development of information technology, Our study is highly related to the issue of enterprises’ low-carbon
consumers can easily obtain information on products’ price, quality, efforts, consumers’ heterogeneous preferences, and consumers’ fairness
and green performance, which makes it a common phenomenon that concerns in the supply chain. Thereby, we will briefly review relevant
consumers will compare the purchasing effectiveness of homogeneous literature on low-carbon supply chain management, supply chains with
products (Gu, Yang, & Huo, 2021; Ma, Hu, & Yao, 2021). Given consumer heterogeneous preferences, and supply chains with fairness
the mismatch of greenness and price between products, consumers’ concerns in the following.
fairness concern about products’ utility difference is emerging as a
non-negligible issue in achieving internal consistency and integral de- 2.1. Low-carbon supply chain management
carbonization of the supply chain (Li & Jain, 2016; Ren, Wang, Zeng,
& Yuan, 2022; Xu et al., 2021). As a matter of fact, supply chain With consumers’ awareness of environmental protection under the
members’ fairness concerns are not something new. For now, although circumstance of global warming, low-carbon transformation and up-
peer-induced fairness concerns among peers and distributional fair- grading of supply chains are extremely urgent (Kang & Tan, 2023;
ness concerns between upstream and downstream enterprises have Mirzaee, Samarghandi, & Willoughby, 2023). For now, a large amount
been widely explored by scholars (Jian, Li, Zhang, & Su, 2021; Liu, of literature has examined the role of supply chain members’ actions in
Wang, Shen, Yan, & Wei, 2018; Zhong & Sun, 2022), only a small pollution control (Song, Wang, Yang, Duan, & Liu, 2020), green produc-
portion of literature touch upon the impacts of consumers’ fairness tion (Liu et al., 2022), and low-carbon technology investment (Chen,
concern in the supply chain (Jiang, Ji, Wu, & Lu, 2023; Zhang, He, Wang, & Zhou, 2019) on supply chain decarbonization. Wu, Zhang,
& Zhang, 2022). Essentially, although low-carbon preferred consumers and Chen (2021) discovered that the enterprises’ economic perfor-
are willing to purchase green products at a higher price than traditional mance was mainly determined by the level of their green contribution,
products, however, their purchasing desire will shrink significantly while the R&D efficiency, spillover effect, and power relationship with
when the utility of a green product is lower than that of a traditional supply chain partners were essential influencing factors for the level
product (Alderighi, Nava, Calabrese, Christille, & Salvemini, 2022; of their green contribution. In reality, due to the requirements of
Huang, Zhang, & Fan, 2022; Zhang & Zheng, 2022). Therefore, our large capital and sophisticated talents in low-carbon strategies, it is
paper includes consumer fairness concern about the utility differences risky for enterprises to bear the cost of low-carbon efforts alone.
between purchasing traditional and low-carbon products as a signifi- Hence, channel members’ cooperation in low-carbon investments grad-
cant influencing factor and discusses its impact on channel members’ ually becomes a common phenomenon. Yu, Wang and Liu (2022)
decision-making by comparing the equilibrium results. concluded that vertical collaboration among supply chain members
Given that both consumers’ market distribution and fairness con- would reduce carbon emission rates and product prices, while horizon-
cerns have a significant impact on channel members’ decision-making, tal collaboration among manufacturers would reduce retailers’ profits
while few existing literature combines these two factors to analyze and customers’ benefits. Wang, Yu, Jin, and Mao (2021) constructed a
low-carbon supply chain issues, our study includes consumers’ market low-carbon supply chain consisting of a dominant retailer and a small
distribution and fairness concerns as important parameters for supply and medium-sized manufacturer and suggested that the coordination
chain participants’ decision-making. In this paper, consumers are di- contract between the manufacturer and retailer could achieve mutual
vided into traditionally preferred consumers and low-carbon preferred benefits for both. Additionally, government policy implementation is
consumers and their purchasing preferences are assumed not to change another important driving force for supply chain low-carbon upgrading.
easily. Our research is designed to answer the following questions: Wang et al. (2021) excavated the carbon emissions reduction decision

2
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

of the construction supply chain under government subsidies and found preferences in product channels and characteristics will affect supply
the carbon emission reduction and the market demand could reach the chain enterprises’ strategies. However, these studies only consider the
optimal value for all channel members under the decentralized deci- impact of consumers’ preferential behavior in product heterogeneity
sion. Long et al. (2022) respectively constructed a Stackelberg game on the supply chain. In fact, when consumers purchase products, they
model dominated by the manufacturer and retailer under government not only have heterogeneous preference behavior but also fairness
subsidies and found that the increase of government price subsidies was concern behavior of comparing the purchasing utility of different prod-
beneficial to market demand and social welfare, and the effect was ucts, both of which will affect the channel members’ decisions, yet
more significant when consumers’ green preferences were large. Wu the latter is rarely considered in the above literature. Therefore, this
and Kung (2020) demonstrated that the government could use a carbon paper will further explore the impact of consumers’ fairness concerns
tax to encourage traditional supply chains to upgrade their carbon regarding the utility gap between traditional and low-carbon products
technologies as well as to encourage financial institutions to provide on supply chain members’ decisions. A joint impact of consumers’ low-
preferential loans to supply chains whose carbon technologies were carbon preference and fairness concern on the game equilibrium will
at a disadvantage in the market. Chen et al. (2022) constructed a tri- be discussed and a comparison of the magnitude of these two factors’
partite supply chain composed of the government, manufacturers, and influence on the equilibrium will simultaneously be conducted.
retailers, and discussed the equilibrium results under the government
objectives of social welfare maximization and utility maximization. 2.3. Supply chain with fairness concerns
Their results showed that the government objective of utility maxi-
mization benefited more consumer groups than that of social welfare Fair and reasonable benefit distribution is an essential founda-
maximization. From the abovementioned literature, it is obvious that tion for supply chain participants to achieve long-term and stable
corporate low-carbon effort is a crucial incentive for low-carbonization coordination (Adhikari & Bisi, 2020; Feng, Li, Zhou, & Wu, 2022;
throughout the supply chain. Our study also aims to analyze the impact Pan, Cui, Xing, & Lu, 2020). As a member of the supply chain, each
of enterprises’ low-carbon efforts on channel members’ decisions. In participant is concerned not only with its revenue but also with the
contrast to the previously mentioned literature, we divide consumers gap between its revenue and that of other participants. In view of
in the market into traditionally preferred consumers and low-carbon the fact that channel members were concerned about the fairness of
preferred consumers, and further explore the impacts of consumers’ income distribution, Cui, Raju, and Zhang (2007) initially introduced
low-carbon preference on the equilibrium results under different mar- fairness concerns into a supply chain model and explored the impact
ket distributions of consumers, so as to expand the research in this of fairness concerns on channel members’ pricing. After that, a large
field. number of scholars have conducted research on the issue of partici-
pants’ fairness concerns in supply chains (Sharma, Dwivedi, & Singh,
2.2. Supply chain with consumer heterogeneous preference 2019; Zhong & Sun, 2022). At this stage, the existing literature about
fairness concerns mainly concentrates on distributional fairness con-
In the context of the information age, consumer demands for prod- cerns between upstream and downstream participants and peer-induced
ucts are becoming more diversified and personalized, which has forced fairness concerns among peers. Regarding the issue of distributional
supply chain participants to take consumer heterogeneous preferences fairness concerns, Jian et al. (2021) constructed a Stackelberg game
into consideration when they make strategic decisions (Jang & Choi, model with a fairness-concerned manufacturer and analyzed the game
2021; Tang, Wang, & Zhou, 2020; Wang & Hou, 2020). The devel- equilibrium under centralized and decentralized decision-making. The
opment of information technology has made the coexistence of on- results suggested that the manufacturer’s fairness concern was detri-
line chains and offline chains become a common phenomenon, thus mental to the environmental performance and may lead to a waste
some scholars have examined the impact of consumer heterogeneity of resources. Similarly, Sarkar and Bhala (2021) demonstrated that
in channel preferences on supply chain participants’ decision-making. a constant wholesale price contract could coordinate a decentralized
Liu, Li, Ren, and Forrest (2020) introduced the different levels for channel in a manufacturer-dominated supply chain when the retailer’s
consumer preference of network channels into dual-channel supply dominance inequality aversion was strong enough. Their research ar-
chain decisions and discovered that consumers’ network preferences gued that the collection rate of channel partners was higher and both
had significant effects on enterprises’ optimal pricing, demand, and parties were richer under the manufacturer collection model. Regarding
profitability. Zhang, Dai, Sun, Zhang, and Yang (2020) modeled a the issue of peer-induced fairness concerns, Pan et al. (2020) built
dual-channel supply chain consisting of multiple competing manufac- a two-echelon supply chain consisting of one dominant retailer and
turers and multiple competing retailers. They claimed that the increase two following manufacturers and believed that the increase of manu-
in raw material conversion rate always benefited all participants of facturers’ peer-induced fairness concerns was disadvantageous to the
the dual-channel supply chain. Additionally, other scholars analyzed profits of the manufacturers while was advantageous to the profits
consumers’ differential preferences for product characteristics such as of the retailer and the entire supply chain. Li, Xu, Li, Du and Ye
brand, quality, and functionality. In particular, under the circumstance (2021) also investigated the peer-induced fairness concerns in the case
of the low-carbon economy, a large body of literature lucubrated the of one re-manufacturer and two recyclers and concluded that channel
role of consumers’ low-carbon preferences in supply chain participants’ coordination could be achieved through a simple constant transfer
decisions. Cheng, Ji, Zhang, and Shi (2022) believed that the improve- price contract under certain conditions. Moreover, a few scholars have
ment of consumers’ environmental awareness had a positive impact on introduced consumers’ fairness concerns into the research on the supply
the operation of the supply chain network and could achieve synergy chain. Li and Jain (2016) studied the impact of consumers’ fairness
between economic and ecological goals under certain conditions. Sun concerns on enterprises’ behavior-based pricing (BBP) strategies, prof-
et al. (2020) constructed a Stackelberg game model dominated by its, consumer surplus, and social welfare, suggesting that implementing
the manufacturer and demonstrated that the low-carbon preference of BBP was more profitable and could improve social welfare when con-
consumers could increase channel members’ profits only when the lag sumers’ fairness concerns were strong enough. Yi, Wang, Liu, and
of emission reduction technology was relatively small. Wang and Hou Chen (2018) manifested that when consumers were extremely fairness
(2020) argued that consumers’ green preferences significantly affected concerned, it would be the optimal decision for the manufacturer to
the green level of the final product of the supply chain, which in decentralize its distribution channel downward by using agency sales,
turn contributed to the greening and upgrading of the supply chain and direct sales would be a better strategy for manufacturers when
and the improvement of social welfare. The aforementioned literature consumer fairness concerns were relatively weak. Yu, Wang, Feng, Bao
generally agrees that market distribution of consumers with different and Han (2022) found that incentives provided by manufacturers can

3
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

mitigate consumer fairness concerns for national brands and could 3.1. Initial state
effectively discourage retailers from establishing their brands under
certain conditions. Diao, Harutyunyan, and Jiang (2022) constructed Low-carbon development has become an important trend in supply
a two-stage supply chain model and analyzed the impact of consumers’ chains at this stage. As consumers’ low-carbon awareness increases,
fairness concerns on dynamic pricing strategies and channel profits of they are gradually willing to buy greener products, and manufacturers
enterprises. Their research indicated that consumers’ fairness concerns in the supply chain are increasing their R&D investment in green
could bring win-win results for manufacturers and retailers. Despite technology to improve the green level of their products. However, there
the literature on fairness concerns in supply chains being extensive, are still some consumers who prefer to purchase traditional products.
few scholars have studied the impact of consumers’ fairness concerns Hence, in this section, we will calculate the game equilibrium under the
about products’ utility on participants’ decision-making in a market initial state and analyze the impacts of different parameters on the re-
where there are both low-carbon preferred and traditionally preferred sults. In this paper, consumers are divided into two groups, traditionally
consumers. Therefore, based on consumers’ fairness concerns about preferred consumers and low-carbon preferred consumers, with tradi-
the difference in purchasing utility between traditional and low-carbon tionally preferred consumers only buying products from manufacturer
products, this paper will construct a two-echelon supply chain in a mar- 𝑀1 and low-carbon consumers buying products from manufacturer 𝑀2 .
ket environment where there is a segmentation of low-carbon preferred Although low-carbon preferred consumers and traditionally preferred
consumers and traditionally preferred consumers. In contrast to the consumers only buy corresponding products, their purchasing desire
existing literature, we will analyze the joint influence of consumers’ will still be affected by the price of alternative products, which is also in
market distribution and fairness concerns on supply chain pricing line with economic reality. Thus, we assume that the parameter price
decisions and compare the magnitude of the role of different factors of the products is 1, the price parameter of alternative products is 𝛽
in influencing the outcome of the game. (0 < 𝛽 < 1) (Pan et al., 2020; Wu & Kung, 2020), and the parameter
of consumers’ low-carbon preference is 𝛾 (𝛾 > 0) (Jian et al., 2021; Lin
et al., 2021; Wang et al., 2021). At this time, consumer demands 𝐷1 for
3. Model and analysis traditional products and consumer demand 𝐷2 for low-carbon products
respectively are:
In our work, we construct a two-echelon supply chain consisting
of one traditional manufacturer 𝑀1 , one low-carbon manufacturer 𝐷1 = 𝜃 − 𝑃1 + 𝛽𝑃2 , 𝐷2 = 1 − 𝜃 − 𝑃2 + 𝛽𝑃1 + 𝛾𝑔. (1)
𝑀2 , and one retailer 𝑅. It is assumed that there are only tradition- Thus, the profits of the manufacturer 𝑀1 , 𝑀2 , and the retailer 𝑅
ally preferred consumers and low-carbon preferred consumers in the respectively are:
whole market and consumers will not change their preferences. For
the convenience of subsequent calculation and analysis, without loss of 𝜇𝑔 2
𝜋𝑀1 = 𝑊1 𝐷1 , 𝜋𝑀2 = 𝑊2 𝐷2 − , 𝜋𝑅 = (𝑃1 − 𝑊1 )𝐷1 + (𝑃2 − 𝑊2 )𝐷2 . (2)
generality, we refer to the studies of Meng, Li, Liu, Li, and Zhang (2021) 2
and Zheng and Li (2023) and suppose that the market volume is 1. Solve the game in reverse. The specific process is shown in Ap-
2
Traditionally preferred consumers and low-carbon preferred consumers pendix A. When 𝜇 > 𝛾4 , the game equilibrium is:
respectively are 𝜃 and 1−𝜃 (0 ≤ 𝜃 ≤ 1), which is similar to the model set- 𝛾(2 − 2𝜃 + 𝛽𝜃)
tings of Zhang and Zheng (2022). Manufacturer 𝑀1 and manufacturer 𝑔= , (3)
2(4𝜇 − 𝛽 2 𝜇 − 𝛾 2 )
𝑀2 respectively produce traditional products and low-carbon products 𝜃(4𝜇 − 𝛾 2 ) + 2𝛽𝜇(1 − 𝜃) (2 − 2𝜃 + 𝛽𝜃)𝜇
𝑊1 = 2𝐷1 = , 𝑊2 = 2𝐷2 = , (4)
at unit costs 𝐶1 and 𝐶2 , and sells them to retailer 𝑅 at wholesale price 2(4𝜇 − 𝛽 2 𝜇 − 𝛾 2 ) 4𝜇 − 𝛽 2 𝜇 − 𝛾 2
𝑊1 and 𝑊2 . Then, retailer 𝑅 sells traditional products and low-carbon (2𝛽 2 − 3)𝛾 2 𝜃 + 2𝜇[6𝜃 + 𝛽(5 − 2𝛽 2 ) + 𝛽𝜃(1 + 2𝛽)(2𝛽 − 5)]
𝑃1 = , (5)
products to traditionally preferred consumers and low-carbon preferred 4(1 − 𝛽 2 )(4𝜇 − 𝛽 2 𝜇 − 𝛾 2 )
consumers, with retail prices of 𝑃1 and 𝑃2 respectively. Following He, 2𝜇[6 − 6𝜃 + 5𝛽𝜃 + 𝛽 2 (3𝜃 − 2𝛽𝜃 − 3)] − 𝛽𝛾 2 𝜃
𝑃2 = , (6)
Wang, Shi, and Liao (2021) and Jian et al. (2021), we assume that 4(1 − 𝛽 2 )(4𝜇 − 𝛽 2 𝜇 − 𝛾 2 )
the greenness of the traditional product is 𝐺 and the greenness of the [𝜃(4𝜇 − 𝛾 2 ) + 2𝛽𝜇(1 − 𝜃)]2 𝜇(4𝜇 − 𝛾 2 )(2 − 2𝜃 + 𝛽𝜃)2
𝜋𝑀1 = , 𝜋𝑀2 = , (7)
8(4𝜇 − 𝛽 2 𝜇 − 𝛾 2 )2 8(4𝜇 − 𝛽 2 𝜇 − 𝛾 2 )
low-carbon product is 𝐺 + 𝑔. To ensure that the formula has economic
4𝜇2 [2𝜃(2 − 𝛽)2 (𝛽 − 1)(𝜃 − 1) − 4 − 5𝛽 2 ] + 4𝛾 2 𝜃𝜇[3𝛽 + (2 − 𝛽)(1 − 𝛽)𝜃] − 𝛾 4 𝜃 2
significance, the green degree of traditional products should be non- 𝜋𝑅 =
16(1 − 𝛽 2 )(4𝜇 − 𝛽 2 𝜇 − 𝛾 2 )
negative, that is, 𝐺 ≥ 0, while 𝑔 > 0 indicates that low-carbon R&D
(8)
will lead to a higher green level of low-carbon products than traditional
products. In our study, we suppose that low-carbon products require To further ensure the economic significance, in the subsequent
2
additional investment 𝜇𝑔2 (𝜇 > 0) from manufacturer 𝑀2 (Jian et al., analysis of the equilibrium results and numerical simulation studies,
𝛾2
2021), which means that low-carbon products need more cost inputs we only analyze the situation when 𝑔 is positive, that is, 𝜇 > 4−𝛽 2.
and the green degree of low-carbon products is highly related to the
invested capital. Since we do not discuss the impact of low-carbon R&D Proposition 1. 𝑔, 𝑊1 , 𝑊2 , 𝐷1 , and 𝐷2 are increasing functions with
on manufacturers’ unit costs and the values and size relationship of respect to 𝛽, 𝛾 and decreasing functions with respect to 𝜇. 𝑔, 𝑊2 , and 𝐷2
𝐶1 and 𝐶2 will not affect the subsequent conclusions, to simplify the are decreasing functions with respect to 𝜃, while 𝑊1 and 𝐷1 are decreasing
derivation of the model, we assume that 𝐶1 = 𝐶2 = 0, which is similar 𝛾2 𝛾2
functions with respect to 𝜃 when 4−𝛽 2 < 𝜇 < 4−2𝛽 and increasing functions
to the research of Zhang, Yu et al. (2021). Similarly, since the follow-up 𝛾2 𝛾2
when 𝜇 > . When 𝜇 = , 𝑤1 and 𝐷1 are independent with 𝜃.
study mainly analyzes the comparative advantages of the green degree 4−2𝛽 4−2𝛽
of low-carbon products over traditional products, that is, the size of 𝑔, From Proposition 1, it is clear that an increase in the price param-
added with that the change of 𝐺 has little effect on the subsequent eter of alternative products 𝛽 and consumers’ low-carbon preference
conclusions, we also assume that 𝐺 = 0. In the following section, parameter 𝛾 will result in an increase in the product’s greenness at
we will separately discuss the results of the game equilibrium under equilibrium, as well as an increase in the wholesale price of the
the initial state and consumers’ fairness concern, and then analyze products of manufacturer 𝑀1 and 𝑀2 . It is easy to understand that
the impacts of different parameters on the equilibrium outcomes. A the increase in the price parameter of alternative products and low-
comparison of the game equilibrium between the two states will be carbon preference parameter will lead to an increase in the market
further investigated. The descriptions of different parameters are shown demand for the product, and then manufacturer 𝑀2 will have more
in Table 1. funds to invest in green R&D and thus improve the greenness level

4
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

Table 1
Description of different parameters.
Parameters Descriptions
𝛽 Parameter of alternative products’ price
𝛾 Parameter of consumers’ low-carbon preference
𝜃 Proportion of traditionally preferred consumers
𝜇 R&D parameter of low-carbon manufacturer
𝜆 Parameter of consumers’ fairness concerns on products’ utility
𝑔 Greenness of low-carbon products
𝑖, 𝑖 ∈ {1, 2} Subscript of traditional channel and low-carbon channel
𝑀𝑖 Traditional manufacturer and low-carbon manufacturer
𝑅 Retailer
𝑊𝑖 Wholesale price of traditional manufacturer and low-carbon manufacturer
𝑃𝑖 Retail price of traditional manufacturer and low-carbon manufacturer
𝐷𝑖 Demand of traditional products and low-carbon products
𝑈𝑖 Utility of traditional products and low-carbon products
𝜋𝑀1 ,𝑀2 ,𝑅 Profits of traditional manufacturer, low-carbon manufacturer, and the retailer
∗ Superscripts of fairness concerned

of low-carbon products. Benefited by the increase in the wholesale market demand for low-carbon products and further promote the in-
price of manufacturer 𝑀2 , 𝑀1 will also increase the wholesale price. crease of low-carbon products’ wholesale price, retail price, and low-
Additionally, the increase in green technology R&D parameter means carbon manufacturer’s profit. Due to the positive externalities of R&D,
that manufacturer 𝑀2 requires more R&D funds to achieve the same the traditional manufacturer obtains obvious free-rider benefits, and
R&D results, which is obviously detrimental to manufacturer 𝑀2 and thus also realizes the improvement of its profits. However, the increase
will lead to a reduction in R&D investment. This further leads to of R&D parameter is disadvantageous to the manufacturer 𝑀1 and
a reduction in the greenness of the product and inevitably leads to 𝑀2 because it puts great pressure on manufacturer 𝑀2 , which in
a reduction in the wholesale price of the manufacturer 𝑀2 . As a return leads to the decrease of R&D effects and the decrease of both
result, 𝑀1 will also reduce the wholesale price to increase its potential manufacturers’ profits. Additionally, since the functional relationships
market demand. Moreover, the higher the market share of low-carbon between the retailer’s profit and the parameters are quite complex, it
preferred consumers, the more favorable it is for the manufacturer 𝑀2 is not analyzed in detail in this section and will be further analyzed in
to increase its R&D investment and thus enhance the wholesale price of the numerical simulation section of this paper.
the products, whereas the impact of low-carbon preferred consumers’
market share on manufacturer 𝑀1 ’ wholesale pricing is uncertain. The 3.2. Fairness concern
wholesale price of 𝑀1 decreases with the increase of 𝜃 when 𝜇 is
small and increases with the increase of 𝜃 when 𝜇 is large. Obviously, With the development of information, it has become easier for
when R&D efficiency is low, manufacturer 𝑀1 can only increase its consumers to obtain information on product performance, which has
market competitiveness by reducing its wholesale price, while when led to consumers being more cautious and getting used to comparing
R&D efficiency is high, the wholesale price of 𝑀1 increases with the different products when purchasing products (Diao et al., 2022; Li
increase of market share. & Jain, 2016). In our study, traditionally preferred consumers and
low-carbon preferred consumers only buy the corresponding products,
Proposition 2. 𝑃1 and 𝑃2 are increasing functions with respect to 𝛾 and however, due to the interoperability of information, consumers also
decreasing functions with respect to 𝜇. 𝑃2 is a decreasing function with know the price of another product and will compare it with their
𝛾2
respect to 𝜃. 𝑃1 is a decreasing function with respect to 𝜃 when 4−𝛽 2 < purchases. Drawing on the research of Yi et al. (2018) and Yu, Wang,
(3−2𝛽 2 )𝛾 2 (3−2𝛽 2 )𝛾 2 Feng et al. (2022), we suppose that consumer purchasing utility is
𝜇 < 2(2𝛽 3 −3𝛽 2 −5𝛽+6)
and a increasing function when 𝜇 > 2(2𝛽 3 −3𝛽 2 −5𝛽+6)
.
affected by the greenness of the product and the price of the product.
(3−2𝛽 2 )𝛾 2
When 𝜇 = 2(2𝛽 3 −3𝛽 2 −5𝛽+6) , 𝑃1 is independent with 𝜃. Specifically, the utility of traditionally preferred consumers purchasing
a traditional product is 𝑈1 and the utility of low-carbon preferred
consumers for a low-carbon product is 𝑈2 , where 𝑈1 = 𝑣̄ − 𝑃1 and
From Proposition 2, it is clear that the retail prices of traditional
𝑈2 = 𝑣̄ − 𝑃2 + 𝑔. 𝑣̄ represents the reserved utility, which is assumed
products and low-carbon products increase with the increase of the
to be large enough. Considering that consumers will compare the pur-
alternative product price parameter and decrease with the increase
chasing utility of the two products under the information environment,
of the R&D parameter. Combined with Proposition 1, it is easy to
and combining the existing research on fairness concerns (Jian et al.,
understand that the increase of the alternative product price parameter
2021; Sarkar & Bhala, 2021; Zhong & Sun, 2022), we assume that
will significantly raise consumer demands, which leads to an increase
the parameter of consumer’s fairness concern on product utility is 𝜆
in the manufacturers’ wholesale price and in turn leads to an increase in
(𝜆 ≥ 0). In our study, we just consider the situation where traditional
the retailer’s price to the consumer. Conversely, a larger R&D parameter
products and low-carbon products coexist in the market, that is, when
will reduce R&D investment, which will lead to lower retail prices of
𝜃 −𝑃1∗ +𝛽𝑃2∗ > 𝜆(𝑈2 −𝑈1 ). Equilibrium results under consumers’ fairness
traditional products and low-carbon products.
concerns are distinguished in this paper by the superscript *. At this
point, the market demand for the two products respectively are:
Proposition 3. 𝜋𝑀1 and 𝜋𝑀2 are increasing functions with respect to 𝛽 and
𝛾 and decreasing functions with respect to 𝜇. 𝜋𝑀2 is a decreasing function 𝐷1∗ = 𝜃 −𝑃1∗ +𝛽𝑃2∗ +𝜆(𝑈1 −𝑈2 ), 𝐷2∗ = 1−𝜃 −𝑃2∗ +𝛽𝑃1∗ +𝛾𝑔 ∗ +𝜆(𝑈2 −𝑈1 ). (9)
with respect to 𝜃, while 𝜋𝑀1 is a decreasing function with respect to 𝜃 when
𝛾2 𝛾2 𝛾2 𝛾2 Obviously, when the purchasing utility of one product is greater
4−𝛽 2
<𝜇< 4−2𝛽
and a increasing function when 𝜇 > 4−2𝛽
. When 𝜇 = 4−2𝛽
, than another, the market demand for this product will increase while
𝜋𝑀1 is independent with 𝜃. the market demand for the other product will decrease, which is in line
with the economic sense. At this point, the profits of the manufacturers
and the retailer respectively are:
Understandably, the increase of alternative products’ price param-
∗ 𝜇𝑔 ∗2 ∗
eter and consumers’ low-carbon preferences will directly increase the 𝜋𝑀 = 𝑊1∗ 𝐷1∗ , 𝜋𝑀

= 𝑊2∗ 𝐷2∗ − , 𝜋𝑅 = (𝑃1∗ − 𝑊1∗ )𝐷1∗ + (𝑃2∗ − 𝑊2∗ )𝐷2∗ . (10)
1 2 2

5
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

(𝛾+𝜆)2 1 𝛾2
Similarly, solve the game in reverse. When 𝜇 > 4(1+𝜆)
, the game of traditional products in the initial state. When 2
< 𝜃 ≤ 1, if 4−𝛽 2
<
equilibrium is: 𝜇 < 𝛾2𝜃
, the wholesale price, retail price, and market demand of
2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽)
(𝛾 + 𝜆)[2(1 + 𝜆) − 𝜃(2 − 𝛽 + 𝜆)] low-carbon products are greater than those of traditional products, and if
𝑔∗ = , (11)
𝐶 𝛾2𝜃 𝛾2 𝛾 2 𝜃2
∗ 𝜇 ≥ 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽) , the opposite is true. When 12 < 𝜃 ≤ 1, if 4−𝛽 2 ≤ 4(2𝜃−1) ,
2𝐷1 (1 + 𝜆)[2𝜇(𝛽 − 𝛽𝜃 + 𝜆 + 𝜃𝜆 + 2𝜃) − (𝛾 + 𝜆)(𝛾𝜃 + 𝜆)]
𝑊1∗ = = , (12) whatever value 𝜇 takes, the profit of manufacturer 𝑀1 always is larger
1+𝜆 2𝐶 𝛾2 𝛾 2 𝜃2
2𝐷2∗ than that of 𝑀2 . If 4−𝛽 2 < 4(2𝜃−1) , the profit of manufacturer 𝑀1 is
(1 + 𝜆)𝜇[2(1 + 𝜆) − 𝜃(2 − 𝛽 + 𝜆)]
𝑊2∗ = = , (13) 𝛾 2 𝜃2
1+𝜆 𝐶 larger than that of 𝑀2 when 𝜇 > 4(2𝜃−1)
and the opposite is true when
2 2
−(𝛾 + 𝜆)(𝛾𝜃 + 𝛾)(3 − 2𝛽 − 4𝛽𝜆 + 6𝜆 + 𝜆 ) + 2𝜇𝐴 𝛾2 𝛾 2 𝜃2
𝑃1∗ = , (14) 4−𝛽 2
<𝜇≤ 4(2𝜃−1)
.
2(1 − 𝛽)(1 + 𝛽 + 2𝜆)𝐶
(1 + 𝜆)(𝛽 + 𝜆)(𝛾 + 𝜆)(𝛾𝜃 + 𝛾) + 2𝜇𝐵
𝑃2∗ =− , (15)
2(1 − 𝛽)(1 + 𝛽 + 2𝜆)𝐶
∗ (1 + 𝜆)[2𝜇(𝛽 − 𝛽𝜃 + 𝜆 + 𝜃𝜆 + 2𝜃) − (𝛾 + 𝜆)(𝛾𝜃 + 𝜆)]2
𝜋𝑀 = , (16) It can be seen that when the market share of traditionally preferred
1 2𝐶 2
2 2
𝜇[2(1 + 𝜆) − 𝜃(2 − 𝛽 + 𝜆)] [4𝜇(1 + 𝜆) − (𝛾 + 𝜆) ] consumers is less than half, the wholesale price 𝑊2 , retail price 𝑃2 of

𝜋𝑀 = . (17) low-carbon products, and the profit of manufacturer 𝑀2 are greater
2 2𝐶 2
than those of traditional products in the initial state, which indicates
In the above equation, 𝐴 = 2𝛽 3 (𝜃 − 1) + 3𝛽 2 (𝜆𝜃 − 𝜃 − 2𝜆) + 𝜃(2 + 𝜆)(3 +
that manufacturer 𝑀2 have greater market pricing bargaining power
5𝜆)+𝜆(5+10𝜆+3𝜆2 )−𝛽(𝜆2 −10𝜆−5)+5𝛽𝜃+𝛽𝜃𝜆(16+5𝜆), 𝐵 = 2𝛽 3 𝜃+3𝛽 2 (1−
when the proportion of traditionally preferred consumers is small. At
𝜃+𝜃𝜆+𝜆)+𝜃(2+𝜆)(3+5𝜆)−3(1+𝜆)(2+4𝜆+𝜆2 )+𝛽[6𝜆+𝜆2 −5𝜃−𝜃𝜆(16+5𝜆)],
this point, low-carbon products’ pricing and manufacturer 𝑀2 ’ profit
and 𝐶 = 2𝜇(2 − 𝛽 + 𝜆)(2 + 𝛽 + 3𝜆) − (𝛾 + 𝜆)[2𝛾(1 + 𝜆) + 𝜆(2 − 𝛽 + 𝜆)]. Since the
∗ is too complex, it is not listed in this part and will
will be greater than that of traditional products. On the contrary,
profit function of 𝜋𝑅
when the proportion of traditionally preferred consumers is large, the
be further analyzed in the subsequent numerical simulation section.
optimal pricing of low-carbon products will be higher than traditional
Similar to the initial state, in order to ensure practical economic sig-
products only when 𝜇 is small, i.e., when green R&D is relatively
nificance in the fairness concern section, the conclusions below are ob-
efficient. When 𝜇 is large, the optimal pricing of low-carbon products
tained on the basis that 𝑔 ∗ is positive, i.e. 𝜇 > 𝑚𝑎𝑥
2 (𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)] will be lower than those of traditional products. However, when the
{ (𝛾+𝜆)
4(1+𝜆)
, 2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)
}. When 𝛽(𝛾 + 𝜆) + 𝜆(𝛾 − 2 − 𝜆) ≥ 0, 𝜇 should proportion of traditionally preferred consumers is high, manufacturer
(𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
satisfy the condition 𝜇 > 2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)
, and when 𝛽(𝛾 + 𝜆) + 𝜆(𝛾 − 𝑀2 has less pricing power in the market, and its pricing will be greater
(𝛾+𝜆)2 than that of traditional products only when the R&D efficiency is
2 − 𝜆) < 0, 𝜇 should satisfy the condition 𝜇 > 4(1+𝜆)
.
high. When R&D efficiency is low, the optimal pricing is even lower
than that of traditional products, and conducting low-carbon R&D for
Proposition 4. 𝑔 ∗ , 𝑊2∗ , and 𝐷2∗ are increasing functions with respect
manufacturer 𝑀2 is uneconomical at this time. Therefore, in a market
to 𝛾 and decreasing functions with respect to 𝜇 and 𝜃. The functional
of mostly traditionally preferred consumers, it is not a good choice for
relationships between 𝑊1∗ , 𝐷1∗ and 𝛾, 𝜇, 𝜃 are related to the size relationship
manufacturers to invest in low-carbon R&D when green R&D efficiency
between 4𝛽𝛾𝜇 − 4𝜇𝜆(1 − 𝛽 − 𝛾) − 𝜆(𝛾 + 𝜆)2 , 𝛽(𝛾 + 𝜆) + 𝜆(𝛾 − 2 − 𝜆),
is relatively low.
2𝜇(2 − 𝛽 + 𝛾) − 𝛾(𝛾 + 𝜆) and 0, respectively.

Similar to Proposition 1, in the case of consumers being fairness- Proposition 6. When 0 ≤ 𝜃 ≤ 21 , the wholesale price, retail price, and
concerned, low-carbon products’ greenness, wholesale price, and mar- market demand of low-carbon products are larger than those of traditional
ket demand increase with the increase of alternative products’ price products under consumers’ fairness concerns. When 12 < 𝜃 ≤ 1, if
(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆) 2
parameter and decrease with the increase of R&D parameter and the
2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽+𝜆)
≤ 𝑚𝑎𝑥{ (𝛾+𝜆)
4(1+𝜆)
, (𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)
}, the wholesale price,
proportion of traditionally preferred consumers. Differently, in the case
retail price, and market demand of low-carbon products are smaller than
of consumer’s fairness concern, the functional relationships between (𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆) 2
those of traditional products; if 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽+𝜆) > 𝑚𝑎𝑥{ (𝛾+𝜆) ,
the wholesale price, market demand of traditional products and 𝛾, 𝜃, 4(1+𝜆)
2
(𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
𝜇 are more complex. When 4𝛽𝛾𝜇 − 4𝜇𝜆(1 − 𝛽 − 𝛾) − 𝜆(𝛾 + 𝜆)2 = 0, 𝑊1∗ 2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)
}, at this point, when 𝑚𝑎𝑥{ (𝛾+𝜆)
4(1+𝜆)
,
is independent with 𝛾. 𝑊1∗ is an increasing function with respect to (𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
} < 𝜇 < (𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)
, the wholesale price, retail
𝛾 when 4𝛽𝛾𝜇 − 4𝜇𝜆(1 − 𝛽 − 𝛾) − 𝜆(𝛾 + 𝜆)2 > 0 and vice versa. When 2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆) 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽+𝜆)
price, and market demand of low-carbon products are larger than those of
𝛽(𝛾 +𝜆)+𝜆(𝛾 −2−𝜆) = 0, 𝑊1∗ is independent with 𝜇. 𝑊1∗ is an increasing (𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)
traditional products, and the opposite is true when 𝜇 ≥ 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽+𝜆) .
function with respect to 𝜇 when 𝛽(𝛾 +𝜆)+𝜆(𝛾 −2−𝜆) < 0 and vice versa.
When 2𝜇(2 − 𝛽 + 𝛾) − 𝛾(𝛾 + 𝜆) = 0, 𝑊1∗ is independent with 𝜃. 𝑊1∗ is an
increasing function with respect to 𝜇 when 2𝜇(2 − 𝛽 + 𝛾) − 𝛾(𝛾 + 𝜆) > 0
and vice versa. Since the functions of 𝑔 ∗ , 𝑊1∗ , and 𝑊2∗ with respect to 𝛽
and 𝜆 are more complex, as well as the relationships between product Similar to the conclusions in Proposition 5, the wholesale price,
retail prices and profits with the parameters, we will further analyze retail price, and market demand of low-carbon products are also larger
their relationships in the numerical simulations. than those of traditional products under consumers’ fairness concerns
when the proportion of traditionally preferred consumers is less than
4. Comparative analysis half. It can be seen that consumers’ fairness concerns only affect the
values of the wholesale price, retail price, and profits of traditional and
Based on the equilibrium results of the game under the initial low carbon products while do not affect the size relationship between
state and consumers’ fairness concerns, our study further compares the them. Only when the proportion of traditionally preferred consumers
differences between the wholesale price, retail price, market demand, is more than half, consumers’ fairness concerns will have significant
and profits of manufacturers in the initial state and consumers’ fairness effects on the size relationship between these equilibrium results. Since
concern and obtains the following propositions. the expression of the functions under consumers’ fairness concerns is
relatively complex, we will further compare the relationship between
Proposition 5. When 0 ≤ 𝜃 ≤ 21 , the wholesale price, retail price, the magnitude of these equilibrium results in the numerical simulation
market demand, and profit of low-carbon products are larger than those section.

6
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

Fig. 1. Relationship between wholesale price, retail price and 𝜇, 𝜃.

5. Numerical simulation This in turn leads to the retail price of low-carbon products also being
greater than the retail price of traditional products. However, when
5.1. Initial state traditionally preferred consumers dominate the market, the pricing
power of manufacturer 𝑀2 is greatly reduced, and its market pricing
In this section, our study analyzes the functional relationship be- power is greater than that of manufacturer 𝑀1 only when its R&D
tween parameters and the game equilibrium results through numerical efficiency is quite high.
simulation, aiming to explore the mechanism of parameters’ influence Fig. 2(a) and (b) describe the relationships between the channel
on the equilibrium results. Since there is an obvious linear relationship participants’ profits and 𝜇, 𝜃. Obviously, the profits of supply chain
between the market demand and the wholesale price, only the func- participants decrease with the increase of 𝜇, which is consistent with
tional relationships between the wholesale price and parameters are the conclusion of Proposition 3. Low R&D efficiency is detrimental
analyzed in the subsequent analysis. In addition, since the equilibrium to the profits of the entire supply chain participants. Similar to the
results are basically monotonically increasing functions with respect to conclusions of Fig. 1, it can be seen that when 𝜃 = 0.4, no matter
the parameters 𝛽, and 𝛾, this paper does not make separate images how 𝜇 changes, the profit of the manufacturer 𝑀2 is always larger than
of the relationship between the parameters 𝛽, 𝛾 and the equilibrium the profit of the manufacturer 𝑀1 . And when 𝜃 = 0.6, the situation is
results in the numerical simulation section. In this part, we focus on different. At this point, When is 𝜇 small, the profit of manufacturer
the effects of parameters 𝜇 and 𝜃 on the equilibrium results. Suppose 𝑀2 is larger than that of manufacturer 𝑀1 , and when 𝜇 is large, the
that 𝛽 = 0.6, 𝛾 = 1, 𝜃1 = 0.4, 𝜃2 = 0.6, and 0.4 ≤ 𝜇 ≤ 1.6. Thereby, we conclusion is just the opposite.
can obtain the relations between the wholesale price, retail price, and
𝜇, 𝜃, which are drawn in Fig. 1. 5.2. Fairness concern
Fig. 1(a) and (b) depict the wholesale and retail prices as a function
of parameters 𝜇 and 𝜃. Overall, the wholesale and retail prices of both In this section, we discuss the effects of parameters on the equi-
traditional and low-carbon products decrease as 𝜇 increases, which librium outcomes in the case where consumers are fairness-concerned
is consistent with the conclusion of Propositions 1 and 2. Detailedly, about the product utility. Given the complexity of the functional ex-
when 𝜃 is smaller, the change in 𝜇 affects the equilibrium outcome pressions for the equilibrium outcome under fairness concerns, coupled
to a greater extent. Additionally, the change in 𝜇 has a greater effect with the main research objective of our study, we only focus on the
on the wholesale and retail price of low-carbon products than those of impacts of parameters 𝜃, 𝜇, and 𝜆 on the equilibrium outcomes in this
traditional products. It is easy to understand that manufacturer 𝑀2 , as a section. In addition, the impact of the presence of consumers’ fairness
participant in green R&D investment, is directly benefited from its R&D concerns on the equilibrium outcomes will be discussed in detail, as
efficiency. Hence, 𝜇 usually has a greater impact on manufacturer 𝑀2 well as the differences in the degree of parameters’ influence on the
than manufacturer 𝑀1 . When 𝜇 is large, it indicates that manufacturer equilibrium outcomes will also be analyzed in depth. We assume that
𝑀2 is inefficient in green R&D, which in turn leads to low product 𝛽 = 0.6, 𝛾 = 0.8, 𝜃1 = 0.4, 𝜃2 = 0.6, 0.6 ≤ 𝜇 ≤ 1.2, and 0 ≤ 𝜆 ≤ 0.5 and
greenness in equilibrium. At this point, manufacturer 𝑀2 has to reduce obtain the relationships between parameters and equilibrium outcomes,
its wholesale price to increase its competitiveness in the market. As a which is shown in Figs. 3–7.
result, manufacturer 𝑀1 will also reduce its wholesale price to compete
with manufacturer 𝑀2 , which will further lead to a lower retail price 5.2.1. Relationships between 𝑔 ∗ and 𝜃, 𝜇, 𝜆
of these two products. From Fig. 3, we can find that the greenness 𝑔 ∗ of low-carbon
Specifically, from Fig. 1(a) and (b), we can see that when 𝜃 = 0.4, products at 𝜃 = 0.4 is always larger than that at 𝜃 = 0.6. This indicates
no matter how 𝜇 changes, the wholesale and retail price of low-carbon that when low-carbon preferred consumers make up the majority of
products are always greater than those of traditional products, while the market, manufacturer 𝑀2 faces a larger potential demand and has
when 𝜃 = 0.6, the situation is quite different. At this point, when 𝜇 greater pricing power in the market than those of manufacturer 𝑀1 ,
is small, the wholesale and retail prices of low-carbon products are which causes manufacturer 𝑀2 to invest more in green R&D and thus
greater than the corresponding results of traditional products, while enhance the greenness of low-carbon products. Compared with the ini-
when 𝜇 is large, the conclusion is just the opposite. This is because tial status, it is obvious that consumers’ fairness concerns on products’
manufacturer 𝑀2 has great pricing power when the proportion of utility are beneficial for manufacturer 𝑀2 and the smaller 𝜇 is, the more
traditionally preferred consumers is small, which will inevitably lead favorable it is for 𝑔 ∗ . Specifically, 𝑔 ∗ achieves its maximum value at
it to increase its wholesale price to cover its investment in R&D costs. 𝜇 = 0.6 and 𝜆 = 0.5. In addition, Fig. 3 also shows that 𝑔 ∗ decreases

7
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

Fig. 2. Relationship between profit and 𝜇, 𝜃.

𝑊2∗ is clearly decreasing with the increase of 𝜆 while 𝑊1∗ is slightly


increasing with the increase of 𝜆, which means the presence of fairness
concerns is disadvantageous for the pricing of manufacturer 𝑀2 while
advantageous for manufacturer 𝑀1 .

5.2.3. Relationships between 𝑃 ∗ and 𝜃, 𝜇, 𝜆


Similar to the conclusions in Fig. 4, from Fig. 5(a) and (b), we can
obtain that the retail price of low-carbon products is always higher than
that of traditional products when 𝜃 = 0.4 while the size of the retail
prices of traditional products and low-carbon products is uncertain
when 𝜃 = 0.6. However, there are some conclusions that are not quite
the same as the conclusions in Fig. 4. As is shown in Fig. 5, the retail
price of traditional products is slightly increasing with the increase of 𝜆
which is different from the conclusions in its wholesale price. Although
the gap between 𝑃1∗ and 𝑃2∗ and the gap between 𝑊1∗ and 𝑊2∗ both take
Fig. 3. Impacts of 𝜃, 𝜇, and 𝜆 on the greenness. their maximum values when 𝜇 = 0.6 and 𝜆 = 0.5, the gap between 𝑃1∗
and 𝑃2∗ takes the minimum value when 𝜇 = 0.6 and 𝜆 = 0, which is
quite different from the result in Fig. 4. In addition, compared with the
with the increase of 𝜇 and increases with the increase of 𝜆, and the impact of 𝜆 on the wholesale price, the impact of 𝜆 on the retail price
effect of 𝜇 on 𝑔 ∗ is larger than that of 𝜆. Understandably, consumers’ is greater, especially at 𝜃 = 0.6, which suggests that consumers’ fairness
fairness concerns indirectly affect manufacturer 𝑀2 ’s R&D investment concerns play a more significant role in the pricing of both products for
by influencing consumers’ market demand, while R&D efficiency is the retailer 𝑅.
direct factor that is key to enhancing products’ greenness. Compared with Fig. 4(b), we can see that in the same range of values
for 𝜇 and 𝜆, the area where the retail price of traditional products is
higher than that of low-carbon products is larger than the area where
5.2.2. Relationships between 𝑊 ∗ and 𝜃, 𝜇, 𝜆
the wholesale price of traditional products is higher than that of low-
As can be seen from Fig. 4(a) and (b), the wholesale price of
carbon products. In the initial state, 𝜇 respectively takes the same value
manufacturer 𝑀2 is always greater than that of manufacturer 𝑀1 when
when the wholesale and retail prices of traditional and low-carbon
𝜃 = 0.4, while the relationship between the size of the wholesale prices
products are equal. Nevertheless, under the circumstance of consumers’
of manufacturer 𝑀1 and 𝑀2 is uncertain when 𝜃 = 0.6. As is shown in
fairness concerns, the range of 𝜇 is larger when their retail prices are
Fig. 4(a), the gap between 𝑊1∗ and 𝑊2∗ is smallest when 𝜇 = 1.2 and
equal than that when their wholesale prices are equal. It is not difficult
𝜆 = 0 and largest when 𝜇 = 0.6 and 𝜆 = 0.5. From Fig. 4(b), it can be
to understand that consumers are not only concerned about the utility
seen that the wholesale price of manufacturer 𝑀2 is greater than that
they get from the products in this situation but also about the utility
of manufacturer 𝑀1 for most of the range of values of the parameter
gap between the products. Furthermore, since the retail price of the
𝜇 and 𝜆, except when 𝜇 is relatively large and 𝜆 is relatively small.
products directly affects the utility of the product, while the wholesale
The conclusions are similar to those in Fig. 1(a) when consumers are
price indirectly affects the wholesale price of the product, it is easier to
fairness-concerned about the product’s utility. When 𝜃 = 0.4, i.e. when
explain the more pronounced effect of fairness concerns on the retail
low-carbon preferred consumers are in the majority, manufacturer 𝑀2
price than the wholesale price.
has greater market pricing power than manufacturer 𝑀1 and is always
pricing higher than manufacturer 𝑀1 . However, when traditionally
∗ and 𝜃, 𝜇, 𝜆
5.2.4. Relationships between 𝜋𝑀
preferred consumers are in the majority, the pricing market power of
manufacturer 𝑀2 sharply reduces and the wholesale price of manufac- Similarly, as is shown in Fig. 6, the profit of manufacturer 𝑀2
turer 𝑀2 will even be smaller than that of manufacturer 𝑀1 in the case is always larger than that of manufacturer 𝑀1 when 𝜃 = 0.4, while
where 𝜇 is large and 𝜆 is small. Additionally, according to Fig. 4(a) and the size of the profits of manufacturer 𝑀1 and manufacturer 𝑀2 is
(b), we can conclude that the wholesale price of manufacturer 𝑀2 is uncertain. From Fig. 6(a), we can discover that the impact of 𝜆 on
much more affected by 𝜆 than that of manufacturer 𝑀1 . Specifically, ∗
the 𝜋𝑀1 is larger than that of 𝜇 while 𝜋𝑀2∗ is more affected by 𝜇.

8
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

Fig. 4. Impacts of 𝜃, 𝜇, and 𝜆 on the wholesale price.

Fig. 5. Impacts of 𝜃, 𝜇, and 𝜆 on the retail price.

Fig. 6. Impacts of 𝜃, 𝜇, and 𝜆 on the manufacturers’ profits.

Moreover, the gap between the profits of manufacturer 𝑀1 and man- manufacturer 𝑀2 while decreasing that of manufacturer 𝑀1 , which in
ufacturer 𝑀2 takes the maximum value when 𝜇 = 0.6 and 𝜆 = 0.5. turn leads to a decrease in manufacturer 𝑀2 ’s profits and an increase
Understandably, consumers’ fairness concerns are more likely to affect in manufacturer 𝑀1 ’s profits. Additionally, compared to the wholesale
product demands, which has a greater impact on manufacturer 𝑀1 . In prices in Fig. 4(b), it is obvious that although manufacturer 𝑀2 has a
contrast, for manufacturer 𝑀2 , reducing R&D costs is a more critical higher wholesale price than manufacturer 𝑀1 , manufacturer 𝑀2 also
factor for its profitability, and thus changes in R&D parameter have a needs to bear the cost of R&D investment. Therefore, only when the
greater impact on its profitability. From Fig. 6(b), we can obtain that R&D of manufacturer 𝑀2 is more efficient and consumers’ fairness

𝜋𝑀1 ∗
and 𝜋𝑀2 both take the maximum value when 𝜇 = 0.6, and the concerns are stronger can it reap greater profits than manufacturer 𝑀1 .
difference is that 𝜋𝑀1 ∗ takes the maximum value when 𝜆 = 0 while

𝜋𝑀1 takes the maximum value when 𝜆 = 0.5. It can be seen that the ∗ and 𝜃, 𝜇, 𝜆
5.2.5. Relationships between 𝜋𝑅
improvement in R&D efficiency not only helps to boost the profit of From Fig. 7, we can clearly see that the profit of retailer 𝑅 at
𝑀2 but also the profit of 𝑀1 , which implies that there is a clear free- 𝜃 = 0.6 is always larger than that at 𝜃 = 0.4, which demonstrates that
rider effect for the traditional manufacturer. The increase in consumers’ retail 𝑅 can earn more when low-carbon preferred consumers are in
fairness concerns about product utility increases the market demand of the majority of the market. Additionally, it is obvious that when 𝜇 is

9
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

low-carbon manufacturer’s R&D efficiency and consumers’ low-carbon


preferences on the traditional manufacturer’s and retailer’s profits.
(ii) In both markets with a majority of traditionally preferred con-
sumers and a majority of low-carbon preference consumers, consumers’
fairness concerns about products’ utility can lead to an increase in
products’ greenness and a decrease in the retailer’s profit, while its
impacts on products’ pricing and manufacturers’ profitability are also
influenced by other factors. Specifically, consumer fairness concern has
a greater impact on low-carbon products’ pricing, which fall signifi-
cantly with the increase of consumers’ fairness concerns in both market
scenarios, while it has little impact on traditional products’ pricing. The
traditional manufacturer’s profit declines with the increase of consumer
fairness concerns in both scenarios. The low-carbon manufacturer’s
profit decreases with an increase in consumer fairness concerns when
its R&D investment is inefficient. And when its R&D is quite effective,
Fig. 7. Impacts of 𝜃, 𝜇, and 𝜆 on the retailer’s profit. the increase of consumer fairness concern will have little effect in
markets dominated by traditionally preferred consumers and result
in the increase of the low-carbon manufacturer’s profit in markets
relatively large, the influence of 𝜆 on the profit of retailer 𝑅 is not dominated by low-carbon consumers.
significant, however, when 𝜇 is relatively small, the profit of retailer (iii) In a situation where low-carbon consumers are in the majority,
𝑅 sharply decreases with the increase of 𝜆. When consumers’ fairness it would be advantageous for low-carbon manufacturers to invest in
concern parameter is small and R&D efficiency is high, the profit of green R&D, irrespective of fairness concerns on the part of the con-
retailer 𝑅 will be quite large. This is because a small consumers’ fairness sumers, because the wholesale price, retail price and market demand
concern parameter allows retailer 𝑅 to differentiate the retail prices of low-carbon products would be greater than that of conventional
of traditional products and low-carbon products based on consumer products, which would result in the greater profit of the low-carbon
preferences, which in turn leads to an increase in its profits. The manufacturer than that of the traditional manufacturer. While in a
increase in R&D efficiency of manufacturer 𝑀2 helps other participants market dominated by traditional consumers, although the low-carbon
throughout the supply chain, and thus also leads to an increase in the manufacturer’s wholesale price and demand may be larger than the
profit of retailer 𝑅. traditional manufacturer’s, its profit is not necessarily larger than the
traditional manufacturer’s since it needs to bear R&D investments
separately. At this point, only when R&D is relatively efficient and
6. Conclusions and management insights
consumers’ fairness concerns are relatively strong will the low-carbon
manufacturer earn more profits than the traditional manufacturer and
Considering the realistic situation that consumers are fairness- only in this situation it is favorable for it to conduct low-carbon
concerned about products’ purchasing utilities, we construct a two- investments.
echelon supply chain consisting of two competing manufacturers and
one retailer, where manufacturers are the leaders in the decision-
making sequence. Based on consumers’ utility differentiation of pur- 6.2. Management insights
chasing products in the real environment, our study creatively incorpo-
rates consumers’ fairness concern as a significant parameter in the game
The existence of consumers’ fairness concerns has non-negligible
model and discusses its impact on supply chain participants’ decisions.
impacts on supply chain participants’ decisions, while the degree of
In our study, consumers in the market are divided into traditionally pre-
the impacts also depends on consumers’ low-carbon preferences, the
ferred consumers and low-carbon preferred consumers. Then, we solve
market distribution of consumers, and the low-carbon manufacturer’s
the game equilibrium under the initial state and consumers’ fairness
R&D efficiency. In view of the fact that consumers’ concern about
concerns, respectively. Moreover, the impacts of the parameters on the
fairness is a common phenomenon in real life, combined with the above
equilibrium results are carefully discussed and a comparative analysis
research conclusions, we put forward some implications for the core
of the equilibrium results is also deeply dissected.
enterprises of the supply chain.
(i) Traditional manufacturers should take the initiative to promote
6.1. Conclusions their products decarbonization transformation. Low-carbon develop-
ment is the general trend. With the passage of time, traditionally
Based on the above study, we have obtained some interesting preferred consumers may gradually shift to low-carbon preferred con-
conclusions. sumers, and the increase in the market proportion of low-carbon pref-
(i) In the initial state, the increase in consumers’ low-carbon prefer- erence consumers will lead to a large shrinkage in profits for traditional
ence contributes to the increase in wholesale prices, retail prices, and manufacturers. The advance of low-carbon transformation and upgrad-
profits for manufacturers and retailers, while the increase in the low- ing of traditional manufacturers helps them to improve their market
carbon manufacturer’s R&D parameter leads to the opposite results. competitiveness as well as avoid being eliminated in the fierce market
Different from the monotonic relationships between the two param- competition.
eters above and the game equilibrium, although an increase in the (ii) Low-carbon manufacturers should determine whether to invest
market share of traditionally preferred consumers leads to a significant in R&D based on their low-carbon R&D efficiency as well as the market
decrease in the wholesale price, retail price, and profit of low-carbon distribution and behavioral preferences of consumers. In markets where
products, it does not necessarily lead to an increase in corresponding low-carbon consumers predominate and consumers’ low-carbon prefer-
results of traditional products, because the impacts of the traditionally ences are relatively high, low-carbon manufacturers will be under less
preferred consumers’ market proportion on the equilibrium are also pressure to conduct low-carbon R&D and their benefits from R&D will
influenced by the magnitude of the low-carbon manufacturer’s R&D be more evident. Conversely, when traditionally preferred consumers
efficiency. Additionally, there is a significant free-rider effect of the account for the majority and consumer preferences for low-carbon

10
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

products are not strong, low-carbon manufacturers will be under signif- 𝑔, 𝑊1 , and 𝑊2 into Eqs. (1) and (2), we can obtain that the game
icant pressure and it would be unwise to invest heavily in low-carbon 𝛾(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃) 𝜃(4𝜇−𝛾 2 )+2𝛽𝜇(1−𝜃)
equilibrium is: 𝑔 = 2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 ) , 𝑊1 = 2𝐷1 = 2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )
, 𝑊2 =
capital at this time. (2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)𝜇 2 2 2 )+𝛽𝜃(1+2𝛽)(2𝛽−5)]
2𝐷2 = 4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2
, 𝑃1 = (2𝛽 −3)𝛾 𝜃+2𝜇[6𝜃+𝛽(5−2𝛽
4(1−𝛽 2 )(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )
, 𝑃2 =
(iii) Supply chain participants need to remain attentive to con-
2𝜇[6−6𝜃+5𝛽𝜃+𝛽 2 (3𝜃−2𝛽𝜃−3)]−𝛽𝛾 2 𝜃 [𝜃(4𝜇−𝛾 2 )+2𝛽𝜇(1−𝜃)]2
sumers’ fairness concerns. For traditional manufacturers, consumers’ 4(1−𝛽 2 )(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )
, 𝜋 𝑀1 = 8(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2
, 𝜋𝑀2 =
fairness concerns can be detrimental by reducing their market demand, 𝜇(4𝜇−𝛾 2 )(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)2
2
8(4𝜇−𝛽 𝜇−𝛾 ) 2 , and 𝜋 𝑅 =
which may decrease their profits. In contrast, low-carbon manufactur- 4𝜇2 [2𝜃(2−𝛽)2 (𝛽−1)(𝜃−1)−4−5𝛽 2 ]+4𝛾 2 𝜃𝜇[3𝛽+(2−𝛽)(1−𝛽)𝜃]−𝛾 4 𝜃 2
ers benefit from consumers’ fairness concerns. At this point, low-carbon 16(1−𝛽 2 )(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )
.
manufacturers should increase the introduction of high-level talents Calculation process of Eqs. (11)–(17)
and actively promote the innovation of low-carbon products so as to The calculation process is similar to that of Eqs. (3)–(8). Firstly,
obtain greater benefits. Additionally, as consumers are concerned about we can obtain the Hessian matrix of 𝜋𝑅 ∗ with respect to 𝑃 ∗ and 𝑃 ∗
the utility differences between products, it will lead to a reduction ( ) 1 2
−2 − 2𝜆 2𝛽 + 2𝜆
in the retailer’s ability to differentiate pricing between traditional is . Since 𝛽 < 1, the Hessian matrix is negative
2𝛽 + 2𝜆 −2 − 2𝜆
products and low-carbon products. The excessive price gap between ∗ with respect to
definite and there is an extreme value solution of 𝜋𝑅

low-carbon products and traditional products is detrimental to retailers’ 𝛽+𝜃−𝛽𝜃+𝜆+𝑔 ∗ [𝛽𝛾+𝜆(𝛽+𝛾−1)] 𝑊
𝑃1∗ and 𝑃2∗ . Then we can obtain that 𝑃1∗ = 2(1−𝛽)(1+𝛽+2𝜆)
+ 21
long-term development. ∗ (𝛾+𝜆+𝛾𝜆−𝛽𝛾) 𝑊∗
(iv) Low-carbon manufacturers and traditional manufacturers and 𝑃2∗ = 1−𝜃+𝛽𝜃+𝜆+𝑔 + 22 . Substituting them into 𝜋𝑀 ∗ , the
2(1−𝛽)(1+𝛽+2𝜆) ( 2 )
should promote R&D collaboration to accelerate the decarbonization 𝛾+𝜆
Hessian matrix of 𝜋𝑀∗ with respect to 𝑊 ∗ and 𝑔 ∗ is −(1 + 𝜆) 2 .
and upgrading of the entire supply chain. Given that the increase in 2 2 𝛾+𝜆
−𝜇
2
consumers’ low-carbon preferences and improvement of R&D tech- 2
Hence, when 𝜇 > (𝛾+𝜆) , the Hessian matrix is negative definite. At
nology efficiency is beneficial to both low-carbon manufacturers and ∗
4(1+𝜆)
∗ ∗
𝜕𝜋𝑀1 𝜕𝜋𝑀2 𝜕𝜋𝑀2
traditional manufacturers, low-carbon manufacturers bear R&D expen- this point, let 𝜕𝑊1∗
= 0,
𝜕𝑊2∗
= 0, and
𝜕𝑔 ∗
= 0, we can obtain
ditures alone tends to result in extremely fierce competition, which is (𝛾+𝜆)[2(1+𝜆)−𝜃(2−𝛽+𝜆)] ∗ (1+𝜆)[2𝜇(𝛽−𝛽𝜃+𝜆+𝜃𝜆+2𝜃)−(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)]
that 𝑔∗= 𝐶
, 𝑊1 = 2𝐶
,
disadvantageous to both sides. Therefore, low-carbon manufacturers
and traditional manufacturers should sign cooperative contracts to and 𝑊2∗ = (1+𝜆)𝜇[2(1+𝜆)−𝜃(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
𝐶
, where 𝐶 = 2𝜇(2 − 𝛽 + 𝜆)(2 + 𝛽 + 3𝜆) −
enhance R&D investment in low-carbon technologies, with a view to (𝛾 + 𝜆)[2𝛾(1 + 𝜆) + 𝜆(2 − 𝛽 + 𝜆)]. Finally, substituting 𝑔 ∗ , 𝑊1∗ , and 𝑊2∗
achieving a win-win situation for both sides while further promoting into Eqs. (9) and (10), we can obtain that the game equilibrium is:
2𝐷∗
the low-carbon upgrade of the industrial chain. 𝑔 ∗ = (𝛾+𝜆)[2(1+𝜆)−𝜃(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
𝐶
, 𝑊1∗ = 1+𝜆1 = (1+𝜆)[2𝜇(𝛽−𝛽𝜃+𝜆+𝜃𝜆+2𝜃)−(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)]
2𝐶
,
2𝐷2∗ 2 −4𝛽𝜆+6𝜆+𝜆2 )+2𝜇𝐴
𝑊2∗ = 1+𝜆
= (1+𝜆)𝜇[2(1+𝜆)−𝜃(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
𝐶
, 𝑃1∗ = −(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝛾)(3−2𝛽
2(1−𝛽)(1+𝛽+2𝜆)𝐶
,
CRediT authorship contribution statement
(1+𝜆)[2𝜇(𝛽−𝛽𝜃+𝜆+𝜃𝜆+2𝜃)−(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)]2
𝑃2∗ = − (1+𝜆)(𝛽+𝜆)(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝛾)+2𝜇𝐵
2(1−𝛽)(1+𝛽+2𝜆)𝐶
, 𝜋 ∗
𝑀1
= 2𝐶 2
,
Haohao Song: Methodology, Software, Writing – original draft. ∗ 𝜇[2(1+𝜆)−𝜃(2−𝛽+𝜆)]2 [4𝜇(1+𝜆)−(𝛾+𝜆)2 ]
and 𝜋𝑀 = 2𝐶 2
. In the above equation, 𝐴 =
2
Ying Wang: Conceptualization, Writing – reviewing & editing. Xi- 2𝛽 3 (𝜃 − 1) + 3𝛽 2 (𝜆𝜃 − 𝜃 − 2𝜆) + 𝜃(2 + 𝜆)(3 + 5𝜆) + 𝜆(5 + 10𝜆 + 3𝜆2 ) − 𝛽(𝜆2 −
angyu Mao: Methodology, Software, Investigation. Chunyang Wang: 10𝜆 − 5) + 5𝛽𝜃 + 𝛽𝜃𝜆(16 + 5𝜆), 𝐵 = 2𝛽 3 𝜃 + 3𝛽 2 (1 − 𝜃 + 𝜃𝜆 + 𝜆) + 𝜃(2 +
Project administration, Funding acquisition. 𝜆)(3 + 5𝜆) − 3(1 + 𝜆)(2 + 4𝜆 + 𝜆2 ) + 𝛽[6𝜆 + 𝜆2 − 5𝜃 − 𝜃𝜆(16 + 5𝜆)], and
𝐶 = 2𝜇(2 − 𝛽 + 𝜆)(2 + 𝛽 + 3𝜆) − (𝛾 + 𝜆)[2𝛾(1 + 𝜆) + 𝜆(2 − 𝛽 + 𝜆)].
Declaration of competing interest

Appendix B. Proofs of propositions


We declare that we have no financial or personal relationships with
other people or organizations that can inappropriately influence our
work. There is no professional or other personal interest of any nature
or kind in any product, service, or company that could be construed as Proof of Proposition 1. Since 𝑊1 and 𝑊2 are separately twice as
influencing the position presented in, or the review of, the manuscript large as 𝐷1 and 𝐷2 , we just discuss the relationship between 𝑊1 and
entitled. 𝑊2 with each parameter in this part. Taking partial derivatives of 𝑔,
𝑊1 , and 𝑊2 with respect to 𝛾, 𝜃 and 𝜇 separately, we can obtain that
2 𝜃]𝛾𝜇−𝛾 3 𝜃 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)
Data availability
𝜕𝑔
𝜕𝛽
= [4𝛽(1−𝜃)+4𝜃+𝛽
2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2
, 𝜕𝑔
𝜕𝛾
= (4𝜇−𝛽
2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2
, 𝜕𝑔
𝜕𝜃
(𝛽−2)𝛾
= 2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 ) ,
2 )(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)𝛾 𝜕𝑊 2 2 (1−𝜃+𝛽𝜃)] 𝜕𝑊
and 𝜕𝑔
𝜕𝜇
= − (4−𝛽
2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2
; 𝜕𝛽1 = 𝜇[𝜇(4+𝛽 )(1−𝜃)+16𝛽𝜃𝜇−𝛾
(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2
, 𝜕𝛾1 =
Data will be made available on request. 𝛽𝛾𝜇(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃) 𝜕𝑊 2(2−𝛽)𝜇−𝛾 2 𝜕𝑊1 (2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)𝛽𝛾 2 𝜕𝑊2
2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2
, 𝜕𝜃1 = 2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 ) , and 𝜕𝜇
= − 2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2 ; 𝜕𝛽
=
[4𝛽(1−𝜃)+4𝜃+𝛽 2 𝜃]𝜇2 −𝛾 2 𝜃𝜇 𝜕𝑊2 2𝛾𝜇(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃) 𝜕𝑊2 (𝛽−2)𝛾 𝜕𝑊2
Appendix A. Calculation processes of equations (4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2
, 𝜕𝛾
= (4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2
, 𝜕𝜃
= 4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2
, and 𝜕𝜇
=
(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)𝛾 2 𝛾2 𝜕𝑔 𝜕𝑔
− (4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2 . Since 𝜇 > 4−𝛽 2 , it is obvious that 𝜕𝛾 > 0, 𝜕𝜃 < 0, and
Calculation process of Eqs. (3)–(8) 𝜕𝑔 𝜕𝑊 𝜕𝑊 𝜕𝑊 𝜕𝑊 𝜕𝑊
< 0; 𝜕𝛾1 > 0 and 𝜕𝜇1 < 0; 𝜕𝛾2 > 0, 𝜕𝜃2 < 0, and 𝜕𝜇2 < 0. In
Solve the game in reverse. Firstly,
( we can) obtain the Hessian matrix
𝜕𝜇
𝛾2 2 𝛽2𝛾2𝜃 𝜕𝑔
−2 2𝛽 addition, since 𝜇 > 4−𝛽 2 , we can get 4𝜃𝜇 − 𝛾 = 4−𝛽 2 > 0 thus 𝜕𝛽 > 0
of 𝜋𝑅 with respect to 𝑃1 and 𝑃2 is . Since the Hessian matrix
2𝛽 −2 𝜕𝑊2
and 𝜕𝛽 > 0. Similarly, since 𝜇(4 + 𝛽 2 )(1 − 𝜃) + 16𝛽𝜃𝜇 − 𝛾 2 (1 − 𝜃 + 𝛽𝜃) >
is negative definite, there is an extreme value solution of 𝜋𝑅 with
𝜕𝜋 𝜕𝜋 𝛽 2 𝛾 2 (2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃) 𝜕𝑊
respect to 𝑃1 and 𝑃2 . Let 𝜕𝑃𝑅 = 0 and 𝜕𝑃𝑅 = 0, then we can obtain 4𝛽 2
> 0, we can obtain 𝜕𝛽1 > 0. Differently, the relationship
1 2
𝑊 𝑊 𝛾2
that 𝑃1 = 𝛽+𝜃−𝛽𝜃+𝛽𝛾𝑔
2(1−𝛽 2 )
+ 21 and 𝑃2 = 1−𝜃+𝛽𝜃+𝛾𝑔
2(1−𝛽 2 )
+ 22 . Substituting 𝑃1 between 𝑤1 and 𝜃 is influenced by the magnitude of 𝜇. When 𝜇 = 4−2𝛽 ,
and 𝑃2 into 𝜋𝑀2 , we can obtain the Hessian matrix of 𝜋𝑀2 with respect 𝜕𝑤
( ) we can obtain 𝜕𝜃1 = 0, thereby 𝑊1 and 𝐷1 are independent with 𝜃.
𝛾
−1 𝛾2 𝛾2 𝜕𝑊1
to 𝑊2 and 𝑔 is 2 , and there is an extreme value solution When 4−𝛽 2 < 𝜇 < 4−2𝛽 , thus 𝜕𝜃
< 0, 𝑊1 and 𝐷1 are decreasing
𝛾
2
−𝜇 𝛾2
functions with respect to 𝜃, and the opposite is true when 𝜇 > 4−2𝛽 .
𝛾2
of 𝜋𝑀2 with respect to 𝑊2 and 𝑔 when 𝜇 > 4
. At this point, let
𝜕𝜋𝑀1 𝜕𝜋𝑀2 𝜕𝜋 𝛾(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)
= 0, = 0, and 𝜕𝑔𝑀2 = 0, we can obtain that 𝑔 = ,
𝜕𝑊1 𝜕𝑊2 2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 ) Proof of Proposition 2. Taking partial derivatives of 𝑃1 and 𝑃2
2
𝜃(4𝜇−𝛾 )+2𝛽𝜇(1−𝜃) (2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)𝜇 𝜕𝑃
𝑊1 = 2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )
, and 𝑊2 = 4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2
. Finally, substituting with respect to 𝛾, 𝜃, and 𝜇 separately, we can obtain that 𝜕𝛾1 =

11
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

𝛽𝛾𝜇(5−2𝛽 2 )(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃) 𝜕𝑃 2𝜇(2𝛽 3 −3𝛽 2 −5𝛽+6)−(3−2𝛽 2 )𝛾 2 𝜕𝑃 𝛾 2 𝜃2


2(1−𝛽 2 )(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )
, 𝜕𝜃1 = 4(1−𝛽 2 )(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )
, and 𝜕𝜇1 = 𝑀1 is larger than that of 𝑀2 when 𝜇 > 4(2𝜃−1)
and the opposite is true
2 2
𝛽𝛾 (2𝛽 −5)(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃) 𝜕𝑃2
2
3𝛾𝜇(2−𝛽 )(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃) 𝜕𝑃 2 𝜇(4𝛽 −6𝛽 −10𝛽+12)−𝛽𝛾 2
3 2 𝛾2 𝛾 2 𝜃2
; 𝜕𝛾 = 2(1−𝛽 2 )(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2 , 𝜕𝜃 = − 4(1−𝛽 2 )(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 ) , when 4−𝛽 2
<𝜇≤ .
4(1−𝛽 2 )(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2 4(2𝜃−1)
𝜕𝑃 3𝛾 2 (𝛽 2 −2)(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃) 𝜕𝑃1
and 𝜕𝜇2 = 4(1−𝛽 2 )(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2 . Obviously, we can obtain that 𝜕𝛾 > 0,
𝜕𝑃1 𝜕𝑃2 𝜕𝑃2
< 0, 𝜕𝛾 > 0, and 𝜕𝜇 < 0. Let 𝑓1 (𝛽) = 2𝛽 3 − 3𝛽 2 − 5𝛽 + 6, thus Proof of Proposition 6. Comparing the magnitudes of 𝑊1∗ and 𝑊2∗ , 𝐷1∗
𝜕𝜇
𝑓1′ (𝛽) = 6𝛽(𝛽 − 1) − 5 < 0. 𝑓 1 (𝛽) is monotonically decreasing in [0, 1). and 𝐷2∗ , 𝑃1∗ and 𝑃2∗ , and we can obtain that
∗ ∗ (𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)+2𝜇(1−2𝜃)(2−𝛽+𝜆)
𝜕𝑃 𝑊2 − 𝑊1 = 2𝜇(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)−(𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)] , 𝐷2∗ − 𝐷1∗ =
Since 𝑓 1 (1) = 0, 𝑓 1 (𝛽) > 0 holds in [0, 1), and then 𝜕𝜃2 < 0 holds
(1+𝜆)[(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)+2𝜇(1−2𝜃)(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
3−𝛽 2 , 𝑃2∗ − 𝑃1∗ =
in [0, 1). Furthermore, we compare the magnitudes of 2(2𝛽 3 −3𝛽 2 −5𝛽+6)
2𝜇(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)−(𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
(3+2𝛽+5𝜆)[(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)+2𝜇(1−2𝜃)(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
1 3−𝛽 2 1 𝛽(5−2𝛽 2 ) . It is clear that when 0 ≤ 𝜃 ≤
and 4−𝛽 2 . Since 2(2𝛽 3 −3𝛽 2 −5𝛽+6)
− 4−𝛽 2
= 2(2𝛽 4 +𝛽 3 −11𝛽 2 −4𝛽−12)
, we let 2𝜇(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)−(𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
1 ∗ > 𝑊 ∗ , 𝐷∗ > 𝐷∗ , and 𝑃 ∗ > 𝑃 ∗ . However, the relation-
𝑓2 (𝛽) = 2(2𝛽 4 + 𝛽 3 − 11𝛽 2 − 4𝛽 − 12). Because first-order derivative of 2
, 𝑊 2 1 2 1 2 1
𝑓2 (𝛽) is 𝑓2′ (𝛽) = 2(8𝛽 3 + 3𝛽 2 − 22𝛽 − 4) which is obviouly less than 0. ship between the magnitude of 𝑊1∗ and 𝑊2∗ , 𝐷1∗ and 𝐷2∗ , and 𝑃1∗
Along with the condition that 𝑓2 (1) = 0, we can obtain 𝑓2 (𝛽) > 0 in and 𝑃2∗ when 21 < 𝜃 ≤ 1 are is determined by the magnitude of
2 (𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
3−𝛽 2 𝛾2
[0, 1) and thus 2(2𝛽 3 −3𝛽 1 𝜕𝑃1
2 −5𝛽+6) > 4−𝛽 2 . Therefore, 𝜕𝜃 > 0 when 4−𝛽 2 <
𝑚𝑎𝑥{ (𝛾+𝜆)
4(1+𝜆)
(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)
, 2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆) } and 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽+𝜆) (𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)
. When 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽+𝜆)
2
(3−𝛽 2 )𝛾 2 (3−𝛽 2 )𝛾 2
𝜇 < and the opposite is true when 𝜇 > . ≤ 𝑚𝑎𝑥{ (𝛾+𝜆) , (𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)] }, 𝑊2∗ < 𝑊1∗ , 𝐷2∗ < 𝐷1∗ , and 𝑃2∗ <
2(2𝛽 3 −3𝛽 2 −5𝛽+6) 2(2𝛽 3 −3𝛽 2 −5𝛽+6) 4(1+𝜆) 2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)
2 )𝛾 2
When 𝜇 = 2(2𝛽 3(3−𝛽 −3𝛽 2 −5𝛽+6)
, 𝑃1 is independent with 𝜃. 𝑃1∗ always hold whatever 𝜇 takes. However, it is different when
(𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆) 2 (𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽+𝜆)
> 𝑚𝑎𝑥{ (𝛾+𝜆)
4(1+𝜆)
, 2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆) }. 𝑊2∗ > 𝑊1∗ , 𝐷2∗ > 𝐷1∗ ,
2 (𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)]
Proof of Proposition 3. Taking partial derivatives of 𝜋𝑀1 and 𝜋𝑀2 and 𝑃2 > 𝑃1 hold when 𝑚𝑎𝑥{ (𝛾+𝜆)
∗ ∗
4(1+𝜆)
, 2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆) } < 𝜇 <
𝜕𝜋𝑀
1
with respect to 𝛽, 𝛾, 𝜃, and 𝜇 separately, we can obtain that 𝜕𝛽
= (𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆) (𝛾+𝜆)(𝛾𝜃+𝜆)
and the opposite is true when 𝜇 ≥ 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽+𝜆) .
𝜕𝜋𝑀 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽+𝜆)
𝜇[𝜇(4+𝛽 2 )(1−𝜃)+16𝛽𝜃𝜇−𝛾 2 (1−𝜃+𝛽𝜃)][4𝜃𝜇+2𝛽𝜇(1−𝜃)−𝛾 2 𝜃] 1
2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )3
,
𝜕𝛾
=
𝛽𝛾𝜇(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)[4𝜃𝜇+2𝛽𝜇(1−𝜃)−𝛾 2 𝜃] 𝜕𝜋𝑀 2 ][4𝜃𝜇+2𝛽𝜇(1−𝜃)−𝛾 2 𝜃]
References
2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )3
, 𝜕𝜃 1 = [2(2−𝛽)𝜇−𝛾 4(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2
, and
𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝛽𝛾 2 (2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)[4𝜃𝜇+2𝛽𝜇(1−𝜃)−𝛾 2 𝜃] 𝜕𝜋𝑀
1 2
𝜕𝜇
= − 4(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )3
; 𝜕𝛽
= Adhikari, A., & Bisi, A. (2020). Collaboration, bargaining, and fairness concern for
𝜇(4𝜇−𝛾 2 )(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)[(4𝛽−4𝛽𝜃+4𝜃+𝛽 2 𝜃)𝜇−𝛾 2 𝜃] 𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝛾𝜇(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)2 [(4+𝛽 2 )𝜇−𝛾 2 ] a green apparel supply chain: An emerging economy perspective. Transportation
2
4(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )3
, 𝜕𝛾 = 4(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )3
, Research Part E-Logistics and Transportation Review, 135, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/
𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝜇(𝛽−2)(2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)(4𝜇−𝛾 2 ) 𝜕𝜋𝑀 (2−2𝜃+𝛽𝜃)2 [(4+𝛽 2 )𝜇−𝛾 2 ]𝛾 2
2
= , and 𝜕𝜇 2
= − . j.tre.2020.101863.
𝜕𝜃 4(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )2 8(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )3 Alderighi, M., Nava, C. R., Calabrese, M., Christille, J.-M., & Salvemini, C. B. (2022).
Similar to the process of proving Proposition 1, we can obtain that Consumer perception of price fairness and dynamic pricing: Evidence from Book-
𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝜕𝜋𝑀 ing.com. Journal of Business Research, 145, 769–783. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.
1
𝜕𝛽
> 0, 𝜕𝛾 1 > 0, 𝜕𝜇 1 < 0, 𝜕𝛽 2 > 0, 𝜕𝛾 2 > 0, 𝜕𝜇 2 < 0, and
jbusres.2022.03.017.
𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝜕𝜋𝑀 𝛾2 𝛾2 𝜕𝜋𝑀
2 1 1
𝜕𝜃
> 0. In addition, 𝜕𝜃
< 0 when 4−𝛽 2
<𝜇< 4−2𝛽
and 𝜕𝜃
≥0 Chen, S., Su, J., Wu, Y., & Zhou, F. (2022). Optimal production and subsidy
𝛾2 rate considering dynamic consumer green perception under different government
when 𝜇 ≥ 4−2𝛽
. subsidy orientations. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 168, http://dx.doi.org/10.
1016/j.cie.2022.108073.
2 Chen, X., Wang, X., & Zhou, M. (2019). Firms’ green R & D cooperation behaviour in a
Proof of Proposition 4. Since 𝑊1∗ and 𝑊2∗ are separately 1+𝜆 times
supply chain: Technological spillover, power and coordination. International Journal
as large as 𝐷1 and 𝐷2 , we just discuss the relationship between 𝑊1∗
∗ ∗
of Production Economics, 218, 118–134. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2019.04.
and 𝑊2∗ with each parameter in this part. Taking partial deriva- 033.
tives of 𝑔 ∗ , 𝑊1∗ , and 𝑊2∗ with respect to 𝛾, 𝜇 and 𝜃, separately, Cheng, P., Ji, G., Zhang, G., & Shi, Y. (2022). A closed-loop supply chain network
𝜕𝑔 ∗ 2 considering consumer’s low carbon preference and carbon tax under the cap-
we can obtain that 𝜕𝛾
= 2[(1+𝜆)(𝛾+𝜆) +(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)𝜇][2(1−𝜃)+𝜆(2−𝜃)+𝛽𝜃]
𝐶2
, and-trade regulation. Sustainable Production and Consumption, 29, 614–635. http:

𝜕𝑔 ∗ 2(𝛾+𝜆)(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)[2(1−𝜃)+𝜆(2−𝜃)+𝛽𝜃] 𝜕𝑔 ∗ (𝛾+𝜆)(2−𝛽+𝜆) 𝜕𝑊1 //dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.spc.2021.11.006.
𝜕𝜇
= − 𝐶2
, 𝜕𝜃 = − 𝐶
, 𝜕𝛾 =
Cui, T. H., Raju, J. S., & Zhang, Z. J. (2007). Fairness and channel coordina-
[4𝛽𝛾𝜇−4𝜇𝜆(1−𝛽−𝛾)−𝜆(𝛾+𝜆)2 ][2(1−𝜃)+𝜆(2−𝜃)+𝛽𝜃] 𝜕𝑊1∗
𝐶2
, 𝜕𝜇
= tion. Management Science, 53(8), 1303–1314. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1060.
2(𝛾+𝜆)[𝛽(𝛾+𝜆)+𝜆(𝛾−2−𝜆)][2(1−𝜃)+𝜆(2−𝜃)+𝛽𝜃] 𝜕𝑊1∗ 2𝜇(2−𝛽+𝜆)−𝛾(𝛾+𝜆) 𝜕𝑊2∗ 0697.
𝐶2 𝜕𝜃
, = 𝐶
, 𝜕𝛾
= Diao, W., Harutyunyan, M., & Jiang, B. (2022). Consumer fairness concerns and
2𝜇[4𝛾(1+𝜆)+𝜆(4−𝛽+3𝜆)][2(1−𝜃)+𝜆(2−𝜃)+𝛽𝜃] 𝜕𝑊2∗ dynamic pricing in a channel. Marketing Science, http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mksc.
𝐶2
, 𝜕𝜇
=
2022.1395.
𝜕𝑊 ∗
− 2(𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾(1+𝜆)+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)][2(1−𝜃)+𝜆(2−𝜃)+𝛽𝜃]
𝐶2
, 𝜕𝜇2 = − 2𝜇(2−𝛽+𝜆)
𝐶
. Since 2 − 𝛽 + Feng, Q., Li, D., Zhou, G., & Wu, Z. (2022). Fairness based unique common equilibrium
(𝛾+𝜆)[2𝛾+2𝛾𝜆+𝜆(2−𝛽+𝜆)] efficient frontier for evaluating decision-making units with fixed-sum outputs.
𝜆 > 0, 2(1 − 𝜃) + 𝜆(2 − 𝜃) + 𝛽𝜃 > 0, and 𝜇 > 2(2−𝛽+𝜆)(2+𝛽+3𝜆)
, it is Annals of Operations Research, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-05013-7.
𝜕𝑔 ∗ 𝜕𝑔 ∗ 𝜕𝑔 ∗ 𝜕𝑊2∗ 𝜕𝑊2∗ 𝜕𝑊2∗ Gan, M., Li, D., Wang, J., Zhang, J., & Huang, Q. (2021). A comparative analysis of
obvious that 𝜕𝛾
> 0, ,
𝜕𝜇 𝜕𝜃
< 0, 𝜕𝛾
> 0, and 𝜕𝜇
, 𝜕𝜃
< 0.
the competition strategy of seaports under carbon emission constraints. Journal of
Cleaner Production, 310, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.127488.
2𝜇(2−𝛽)(1−2𝜃)+𝛾 2 𝜃 Gregory, R. P. (2022). The effect of atmospheric greenhouse gases on firm value
Proof of Proposition 5. Since 𝑊2 − 𝑊1 = 2(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )
, 𝑃2 − 𝑃1 =
and firm size distribution. Journal of Cleaner Production, 358, Article 131751.
(3+2𝛽)[2𝜇(2−𝛽)(1−2𝜃)+𝛾 2 𝜃] 4𝜇(1−2𝜃)+𝛾 2 𝜃
4(1+𝛽)(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 )
, and 𝑊2 − 𝑊1 = 8(4𝜇−𝛽 2 𝜇−𝛾 2 ) , it is obvious that http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.131751.
Gu, M., Yang, L., & Huo, B. (2021). The impact of information technology usage on sup-
𝑊2 > 𝑊1 , 𝑃2 > 𝑃1 , and 𝜋𝑀2 > 𝜋𝑀1 when 0 ≤ 𝜃 ≤ 12 . If 12 < 𝜃 ≤ 1, due to
ply chain resilience and performance: An ambidexterous view. International Journal
𝛾2𝜃 2 𝛾2𝜃 𝛾2
2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽)
× 4−𝛽 𝛾2
= 2+𝛽1 > 1, we can obtain that 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽) > 4−𝛽 2. of Production Economics, 232, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2020.107956.
2(2− ) 𝜃 He, P., Wang, Z., Shi, V., & Liao, Y. (2021). The direct and cross effects in a
𝛾2𝜃
Hence, 𝑊2 < 𝑊1 and 𝑃2 < 𝑃1 when 𝜇 > 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽)
and the opposite is supply chain with consumers sensitive to both carbon emissions and delivery time.
𝛾2 𝛾2𝜃 European Journal of Operational Research, 292(1), 172–183. http://dx.doi.org/10.
true when 4−𝛽 2
<𝜇 ≤ 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽)
. To further analyze the relationship 1016/j.ejor.2020.10.031.
between the magnitude of the profits of manufacturers 𝑀1 and 𝑀2 , Heydari, J., Govindan, K., & Basiri, Z. (2021). Balancing price and green quality in
𝛾2𝜃 2 𝜃(𝜃−1) presence of consumer environmental awareness: a green supply chain coordination
we let 𝐺(𝜃) = 2(2𝜃−1)(2−𝛽) and obtain that 𝐺′ (𝜃) = 𝛾2(2𝜃−1) 2 ≤ 0. Hence, approach. International Journal of Production Research, 59(7), 1957–1975. http:
𝛾2 2 1
𝐺𝑚𝑖𝑛 (𝜃) = 𝐺(1) = 4
and 𝐺(𝜃) ∈ [ 𝛾4 , +∞). When 2
< 𝜃 ≤ 1, if //dx.doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2020.1771457.
𝛾2 𝛾 2 𝜃2 Hong, X., Cao, X., Gong, Y., & Chen, W. (2021). Quality information acquisition
4−𝛽 2
≥ 4(2𝜃−1)
, whatever value 𝜇 takes, the profit of manufacturer 𝑀1 and disclosure with green manufacturing in a closed-loop supply chain. Interna-
𝛾2 𝛾 2 𝜃2 tional Journal of Production Economics, 232, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2020.
is larger than that of 𝑀2 . If 4−𝛽 2
< 4(2𝜃−1)
, the profit of manufacturer
107997.

12
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

Huang, M., Zhang, Y., & Fan, H. (2022). Research on retail channel decisions Meng, Q., Li, M., Liu, W., Li, Z., & Zhang, J. (2021). Pricing policies of dual-
considering consumer’s fairness concern. Rairo-Operations Research, 56(1), 23–47. channel green supply chain: considering government subsidies and consumers’
http://dx.doi.org/10.1051/ro/2021171. dual preferences. Sustainable Production and Consumption, 26, 1021–1030. http:
Huang, H., Zhang, J., Ren, X., & Zhou, X. (2019). Greenness and pricing decisions of //dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.spc.2021.01.012.
cooperative supply chains considering altruistic preferences. International Journal Mirzaee, H., Samarghandi, H., & Willoughby, K. (2023). A robust optimization model
of Environmental Research and Public Health, 16(1), http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/ for green supplier selection and order allocation in a closed-loop supply chain
ijerph16010051. considering cap-and-trade mechanism. Expert Systems with Applications, 228, http:
Jang, S., & Choi, J. Y. (2021). Which consumer attributes will act crucial roles for //dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa.2023.120423.
the fast market adoption of electric vehicles?: Estimation on the asymmetrical & Pal, B., Sarkar, A., & Sarkar, B. (2023). Optimal decisions in a dual-channel competitive
heterogeneous consumer preferences on the EVs. Energy Policy, 156, Article 112469. green supply chain management under promotional effort. Expert Systems with
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2021.112469. Applications, 211, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa.2022.118315.
Jian, J., Li, B., Zhang, N., & Su, J. (2021). Decision-making and coordination of green Pan, K., Cui, Z., Xing, A., & Lu, Q. (2020). Impact of fairness concern on retailer-
closed-loop supply chain with fairness concern. Journal of Cleaner Production, 298, dominated supply chain. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 139, Article 106209.
Article 126779. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.126779. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2019.106209.
Jiang, Y., Ji, X., Wu, J., & Lu, W. (2023). Behavior-based pricing and consumer Ren, T., Wang, D., Zeng, N., & Yuan, K. (2022). Effects of fairness concerns on price
fairness concerns with green product design. Annals of Operations Research, http: and quality decisions in IT service supply chain. Computers & Industrial Engineering,
//dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10479-023-05198-5. 168, Article 108071. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2022.108071.
Jiang, X., Wang, L., Cao, B., & Fan, X. (2021). Benefit distribution and stability analysis Sarkar, S., & Bhala, S. (2021). Coordinating a closed loop supply chain with fairness
of enterprises’ technological innovation cooperation alliance. Computers & Industrial concern by a constant wholesale price contract. European Journal of Operational
Engineering, 161, Article 107637. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2021.107637. Research, 295(1), 140–156. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2021.02.052.
Kang, K., & Tan, B. Q. (2023). Carbon emission reduction investment in sustainable Sharma, A., Dwivedi, G., & Singh, A. (2019). Game-theoretic analysis of a two-echelon
supply chains under cap-and-trade regulation: An evolutionary game-theoretical supply chain with option contract under fairness concerns. Computers & Industrial
perspective. Expert Systems with Applications, 227, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa. Engineering, 137, Article 106096. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2019.106096.
2023.120335. Shi, J., Liu, D., Du, Q., & Cheng, T. C. E. (2023). The role of the procurement
Li, X., Cui, X., Li, Y., Xu, D., & Xu, F. (2021). Optimisation of reverse supply chain with commitment contract in a low-carbon supply chain with a capital-constrained
used-product collection effort under collector’s fairness concerns. International Jour- supplier. International Journal of Production Economics, 255, http://dx.doi.org/10.
nal of Production Research, 59(2), 652–663. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00207543. 1016/j.ijpe.2022.108681.
2019.1702229. Song, J., Wang, B., Yang, W., Duan, H., & Liu, X. (2020). Extracting critical supply
Li, J., Hu, Z., Shi, V., & Wang, Q. (2021). Manufacturer’s encroachment strategy with chains driving air pollution in China. Journal of Cleaner Production, 276, Article
substitutable green products. International Journal of Production Economics, 235, 124282. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.124282.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2021.108102. Sun, L., Cao, X., Alharthi, M., Zhang, J., Taghizadeh-Hesary, F., & Mohsin, M. (2020).
Li, K. J., & Jain, S. (2016). Behavior-based pricing: An analysis of the impact of Carbon emission transfer strategies in supply chain with lag time of emission
peer-induced fairness. Management Science, 62(9), 2705–2721. http://dx.doi.org/ reduction technologies and low-carbon preference of consumers. Journal of Cleaner
10.1287/mnsc.2015.2265. Production, 264, Article 121664. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.121664.
Li, J., Meng, G., Li, C., & Du, K. (2022). Tracking carbon intensity changes between Tang, S., Wang, W., & Zhou, G. (2020). Remanufacturing in a competitive market:
China and Japan: Based on the decomposition technique. Journal of Cleaner A closed-loop supply chain in a Stackelberg game framework. Expert Systems with
Production, 349, Article 131090. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.131090. Applications, 161, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa.2020.113655.
Li, F., Xu, X., Li, Z., Du, P., & Ye, J. (2021). Can low-carbon technological innovation Wang, Y., Fan, R., Shen, L., & Jin, M. (2020). Decisions and coordination of green
truly improve enterprise performance? The case of Chinese manufacturing compa- e-commerce supply chain considering green manufacturer’s fairness concerns.
nies. Journal of Cleaner Production, 293, Article 125949. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/ International Journal of Production Research, 58(24), 7471–7489. http://dx.doi.org/
j.jclepro.2021.125949. 10.1080/00207543.2020.1765040.
Liang, L., & Futou, L. (2020). Differential game modelling of joint carbon reduction Wang, Y., & Hou, G. (2020). A duopoly game with heterogeneous green supply chains
strategy and contract coordination based on low-carbon reference of consumers. in optimal price and market stability with consumer green preference. Journal of
Journal of Cleaner Production, 277, Article 123798. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j. Cleaner Production, 255, Article 120161. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.
jclepro.2020.123798. 120161.
Lin, J., Fan, R., Tan, X., & Zhu, K. (2021). Dynamic decision and coordination Wang, Y., Yu, Z., Jin, M., & Mao, J. (2021). Decisions and coordination of retailer-led
in a low-carbon supply chain considering the retailer’s social preference. Socio- low-carbon supply chain under altruistic preference. European Journal of Operational
Economic Planning Sciences, 77, Article 101010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.seps. Research, 293(3), 910–925. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2020.12.060.
2021.101010. Wu, T., & Kung, C.-C. (2020). Carbon emissions, technology upgradation and financing
Liu, Y., Li, J., Ren, W., & Forrest, J. Y.-L. (2020). Differentiated products pricing with risk of the green supply chain competition. Technological Forecasting and Social
consumer network acceptance in a dual-channel supply chain. Electronic Commerce Change, 152, Article 119884. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2019.119884.
Research and Applications, 39, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.elerap.2019.100915. Wu, Y., Zhang, X., & Chen, J. (2021). Cooperation of green R & D in supply chain with
Liu, J., Liu, Y., Wang, F., Cui, Y., & Han, L. (2021). Influence of free-market competition downstream competition. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 160, Article 107571.
and policy intervention competition on enterprise green evolution. Journal of http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2021.107571.
Cleaner Production, 325, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.129225. Xia, X., Lu, M., & Wang, W. (2023). Emission reduction and outsourcing remanufac-
Liu, Z., Qian, Q., Hu, B., Shang, W.-L., Li, L., Zhao . . ., Y., & Han, C. (2022). Govern- turing: A comparative study under carbon trading. Expert Systems with Applications,
ment regulation to promote coordinated emission reduction among enterprises in 227, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa.2023.120317.
the green supply chain based on evolutionary game analysis. Resources Conservation Xu, X., Gong, Z., Guo, W., Wu, Z., Herrera-Viedma, E., & Cabrerizo, F. J. (2021).
and Recycling, 182, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2022.106290. Optimization consensus modeling of a closed-loop carbon quota trading mechanism
Liu, W., Wang, D., Shen, X., Yan, X., & Wei, W. (2018). The impacts of distributional regarding revenue and fairness. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 161, Article
and peer-induced fairness concerns on the decision-making of order allocation 107611. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2021.107611.
in logistics service supply chain. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Xu, C., Jing, Y., Shen, B., Zhou, Y., & Zhao, Q. Q. (2023). Cost-sharing contract
Transportation Review, 116, 102–122. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2018.05.006. design between manufacturer and dealership considering the customer low-carbon
Liu, Y., & Xiao, T. (2020). Pricing and collection rate decisions and reverse channel preferences. Expert Systems with Applications, 213, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa.
choice in a socially responsible supply chain with green consumers. Ieee Transactions 2022.118877.
on Engineering Management, 67(2), 483–495. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/tem.2018. Yi, Z., Wang, Y., Liu, Y., & Chen, Y.-J. (2018). The impact of consumer fairness seeking
2887118. on distribution channel selection: Direct selling vs. agent selling. Production and
Long, Q., Tao, X., Chen, Y., Chen, Y., Xu, L., Zhang, S., & Zhang, J. (2022). Exploring Operations Management, 27(6), 1148–1167. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/poms.12861.
combined effects of dominance structure, green sensitivity, and green preference Yu, W., Wang, Y., Feng, W., Bao, L., & Han, R. (2022). Low carbon strategy
on manufacturing closed-loop supply chains. International Journal of Production analysis with two competing supply chain considering carbon taxation. Computers
Economics, 251, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2022.108537. & Industrial Engineering, 169, Article 108203. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2022.
Luo, R., Zhou, L., Song, Y., & Fan, T. (2022). Evaluating the impact of carbon tax policy 108203.
on manufacturing and remanufacturing decisions in a closed-loop supply chain. Yu, N., Wang, S., & Liu, Z. (2022). Managing brand competition with consumer fairness
International Journal of Production Economics, 245, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe. concern via manufacturer incentive. European Journal of Operational Research,
2022.108408. 300(2), 661–675. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2021.08.026.
Ma, D., Hu, J., & Yao, F. (2021). Big data empowering low-carbon smart tourism Zhang, G., Dai, G., Sun, H., Zhang, G., & Yang, Z. (2020). Equilibrium in supply
study on low-carbon tourism O2O supply chain considering consumer behaviors chain network with competition and service level between channels considering
and corporate altruistic preferences. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 153, Article consumers’ channel preferences. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, 57,
107061. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2020.107061. Article 102199. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2020.102199.

13
H. Song et al. Expert Systems With Applications 237 (2024) 121606

Zhang, J., He, X., & Zhang, Y. (2022). Peer-induced fairness and personalized pricing Zhang, Q., & Zheng, Y. (2022). Pricing strategies for bundled products considering
in a channel. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 73(8), 1812–1827. http: consumers’ green preference. Journal of Cleaner Production, 344, Article 130962.
//dx.doi.org/10.1080/01605682.2021.1940327. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.130962.
Zhang, R., Ma, W., Si, H., Liu, J., & Liao, L. (2021). Cooperative game analysis Zhao, L., Oleson, K., Bou-Zeid, E., Krayenhoff, E. S., Bray, A., Zhu ., Q., & Oppen-
of coordination mechanisms under fairness concerns of a green retailer. Journal heimer, M. (2021). Global multi-model projections of local urban climates. Nature
of Retailing and Consumer Services, 59, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2020. Climate Change, 11(2), http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/s41558-020-00958-8.
102361. Zheng, X.-X., & Li, D.-F. (2023). A new biform game-based investment incentive
Zhang, B., Xin, Q., Tang, M., Niu, N., Du, H., Chang, X., & Wang, Z. (2021). Revenue mechanism for eco-efficient innovation in supply chain. International Journal of
allocation for interfirm collaboration on carbon emission reduction: complete Production Economics, 258, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2023.108795.
information in a big data context. Annals of Operations Research, http://dx.doi.org/ Zhong, Y., & Sun, H. (2022). Game theoretic analysis of prices and low-carbon strategy
10.1007/s10479-021-04017-z. considering dual-fairness concerns and different competitive behaviours. Computers
Zhang, C., Yu, N., Tan, D., Yin, X., & Randhir, T. O. (2021). Value creation mechanism & Industrial Engineering, 169, Article 108195. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2022.
through carbon asset for the sustainability of the automobile sector. Sustainable 108195.
Development, 29(6), 1173–1189. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/sd.2216.

14

You might also like