Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 38

Microeconomics Canadian 14th Edition

Mcconnell Solutions Manual


Visit to download the full and correct content document: https://testbankdeal.com/dow
nload/microeconomics-canadian-14th-edition-mcconnell-solutions-manual/
More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant
download maybe you interests ...

Microeconomics Canadian 14th Edition Mcconnell Test


Bank

https://testbankdeal.com/product/microeconomics-canadian-14th-
edition-mcconnell-test-bank/

Microeconomics Canadian 15th Edition McConnell


Solutions Manual

https://testbankdeal.com/product/microeconomics-canadian-15th-
edition-mcconnell-solutions-manual/

Macroeconomics Canadian 14th Edition Mcconnell


Solutions Manual

https://testbankdeal.com/product/macroeconomics-canadian-14th-
edition-mcconnell-solutions-manual/

Microeconomics Canadian 15th Edition McConnell Test


Bank

https://testbankdeal.com/product/microeconomics-canadian-15th-
edition-mcconnell-test-bank/
Microeconomics 13th Edition Mcconnell Solutions Manual

https://testbankdeal.com/product/microeconomics-13th-edition-
mcconnell-solutions-manual/

Microeconomics 21st Edition McConnell Solutions Manual

https://testbankdeal.com/product/microeconomics-21st-edition-
mcconnell-solutions-manual/

Microeconomics 20th Edition McConnell Solutions Manual

https://testbankdeal.com/product/microeconomics-20th-edition-
mcconnell-solutions-manual/

Microeconomics Canadian 14th Edition Ragan Solutions


Manual

https://testbankdeal.com/product/microeconomics-canadian-14th-
edition-ragan-solutions-manual/

Macroeconomics Canadian 14th Edition Mcconnell Test


Bank

https://testbankdeal.com/product/macroeconomics-canadian-14th-
edition-mcconnell-test-bank/
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

McConnell Brue Flynn Barbiero 14ce

DISCUSSION QUESTIONS

1. Complete the following table and answer the questions below: LO7.1

a. At which rate is total utility increasing: a constant rate, a decreasing rate, or an increasing rate?
How do you know?
b. “A rational consumer will purchase only 1 unit of the product represented by these data since
that amount maximizes marginal utility.” Do you agree? Explain why or why not.
c. “It is possible that a rational consumer will not purchase any units of the product represented
by these data.” Do you agree? Explain why or why not.

Answer: Missing total utility data, top – bottom: 18; 33. The missing total utility for the second
unity can be found by adding the marginal utility (change in utility) to the total utility for the
first unit. By consuming the second unit, 8 more units of utils are added; thus total utility is 18
(= 10 + 8). Missing marginal utility data, top – bottom: 7; 5; 1. The missing marginal utility
values are found by subtracting the total utility for the previous unit consumed from the total
utility of the unit with the missing value (the change in utility). The marginal utility for the third
unit is 7, which equals 25 (total utility for the third unit) minus 18 (total utility for the second
unit).
a. A decreasing rate; because marginal utility is declining.
b. Disagree. The marginal utility of a unit beyond the first may be sufficiently great
(relative to product price) to make it a worthwhile purchase. Consumers are interested
in maximizing total utility, not marginal utility.
c. Agree. This product’s price could be so high relative to the first unit’s marginal utility
that the consumer would buy none of it.

7-1
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

2. Mrs. Simpson buys loaves of bread and quarts of milk each week at prices of $1 and 80 cents,
respectively. At present she is buying these products in amounts such that the marginal utilities
from the last units purchased of the two products are 80 and 70 utils, respectively. Is she buying
the utility-maximizing combination of bread and milk? If not, how should she reallocate her
expenditures between the two goods? LO7.2

Answer: Mrs. Wilson is not buying the utility-maximizing combination of bread and milk
because the marginal utility per cent spent on each good is not equal. The marginal
utility per cent of bread is 0.8 (= 80 utils/100 cents); the utility per cent of milk is 0.875
(= 70 utils/80 cents). Mrs. Wilson should buy more milk and less bread.

3. How can time be incorporated into the theory of consumer behaviour? Explain the following
comment: “Want to make millions of dollars? Devise a product that saves Americans lots of
time.” LO7.2

Answer: Time is money. This expression is a time-saving way of making the point that
for a person who can make so much per hour, every hour spent not working is so much
money not made. A person can be said to “consume” a ball game or an evening at the
theater. If the ball game costs $10 and the theater $20, at first sight one could say the ball
game is a better deal. But if the person makes $20 an hour and is forgoing this in taking
the time off, then we must take into account the time spent at the ball game or at the
theater. If the ball game goes into extra innings and takes 4 hours, then its total cost is
$90 (= $10 + $80). If the theater takes 3 hours, its total cost is $80 (= $20 + $60).
Assuming the marginal utility of the ball game and attending the theater are the same, the
theory of consumer behaviour (with time taken into account) would therefore have this
consumer going to the theater.

4. Explain what is meant by the following statements:LO7.2


a. Before economic growth, there were too few goods; after growth, there is too little time.
b. It is irrational for an individual to take the time to be completely rational in economic decision
making.
c. Telling your spouse where you would like to go out to eat for your birthday makes sense in
terms of utility maximization.

Answer:
a. Before economic growth, most people lived at the subsistence level. By practically
anyone’s definition, this implies “too few goods.” After economic growth, goods are
in relative abundance. To make (or consume) more takes time, but the relative
abundance of goods means that there are already many goods to enjoy. So, now there
is a clash between the use of time to make more goods and the use of time to relax and
enjoy the goods one already has. There just isn’t enough time.

7-2
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

b. To be completely rational in economic decision making, provided one does not take
time into consideration, one has to take account of every factor. This would take a
great deal of time. One could not, for example, make any purchase without first
searching the classifieds to see whether a better deal could be had, rather than simply
heading for the nearest store. However, this would be most irrational, for time does
have value. While making an extensive search before making any deal, one would be
forgoing the income to make this or any deal. For every penny saved to make the
perfect deal, one would be losing dollars in income because of the time spent in
making the perfect deal.
c. There is little time sacrificed in making a request to your spouse for the restaurant
where you eat on your birthday. If you eat there, the benefit will likely exceed the
cost. It also reduces the probability of eating at a restaurant where the market value
(purchase price) exceeds the utility to the recipient.

5. In the last decade or so there has been a dramatic expansion of small retail convenience stores
(such as Mac’s, 7 Eleven, Becker’s, etc.), although their prices are generally much higher than
prices in large supermarkets. What explains the success of the convenience stores? LO7.2

Answer: These stores are selling convenience as well as the goods that are purchased
there. Because of their small size and convenient locations, they save busy consumers
time. In an era when most consumers are working at least 40 hours per week, their time
is valuable, and when only a few items are needed, the time saved must be worth the
additional cost one pays for shopping at these convenience stores. (You seldom, if ever,
see anyone buying a week’s worth of groceries at such shops.)

6. Many apartment-complex owners are installing water meters for each apartment and billing the
occupants according to the amount of water they use. This is in contrast to the former procedure
of having a central meter for the entire complex and dividing up the collective water expense as
part of the rent. Where individual meters have been installed, water usage has declined 10 to 40
percent. Explain that drop, referring to price and marginal utility. LO7.3

Answer: The way we pay for a good or service can significantly alter the amount
purchased. An individual living in an apartment complex who paid a share of the water
expense measured by a central meter would have little incentive to conserve. Individual
restraint would not have much impact on the total amount of water used.
Suppose there were 10 apartments in the complex; each apartment would be billed for
one-tenth of the cost of the water. A single gallon of water would carry a price equal to
one-tenth the amount charged by the water district. The very low price per gallon would
encourage the use of water until the marginal utility of an additional gallon was
correspondingly low. If the tenants paid separately for their own water, the full market
price of water would be considered when making their consumption choices.

7-3
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

7. Using the utility-maximization rule as your point of reference, explain the income and
substitution effects of an increase in the price of product B, with no change in the price of product
A. LO7.4

Answer: The utility-maximization rule compares the marginal utilities per dollar of goods
under consideration (in this case A and B). An increase in the price of product B would
reduce the marginal utility per dollar of B. This would discourage consumption of B, and
with a pure income effect, would not alter consumption of A. If the increased price of B
caused the marginal utility per dollar of the last unit of B to fall below the MU/$ of the
next unit of A, we would expect the consumer to substitute A for B in consumption
(substitution effect).

8. ADVANCED ANAYLSIS A “mathematically fair bet” is one in which the amount won will
on average equal the amount bet, for example when a gambler bets, say, $100 for a 10 percent
chance to win $1,000 ($100 = .10 x $1,000). Assuming diminishing marginal utility of dollars,
explain why this is not a fair bet in terms of utility. Why is it even a less fair bet when the
“house” takes a cut of each dollar bet? So is gambling irrational? LO7.4

Answer: Because the marginal utility of money diminishes the more you have, the utility
of the $100 used to make the bet is greater than the $900 that you might gain ($1,000 -
$100) if you win the bet.
It is even less of a “fair bet’ when the “house” takes its cut, because the $100 bet has the
possibility of yielding less than $900 in winnings.
Is gambling irrational? Maybe. The activity of gambling may provide enough extra utility
to offset the poor utility odds of winning.

The LAST WORD In what way is criminal behaviour similar to consumer behaviour? Why do
most people obtain goods via legal behaviour as opposed to illegal behaviour? What are society's
main options for reducing illegal behaviour?

Answer:
Both the lawful consumer and the criminal try to maximize their total utility. (Answers
may vary.)
Most people choose legal behaviour because they see the price of illegal behaviour to be
greater than the marginal benefit. The costs include guilt, direct costs (supplies and
tools), loss of freedom, and the forgone income earned through legal behaviour.
Society's main option to reduce illegal behaviour is to increase the cost of engaging in it.
They can do this many ways. Guilt costs can be increased through family, educational,
and religious efforts. They can get better locks and alarms forcing the criminal to spend
more money on better tools. They can provide higher incomes for legal behaviour,
increasing the opportunity cost. They can increase policing to make it more likely the
criminal will be caught.

7-4
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

REVIEW QUESTIONS

1. True or false. The law of diminishing marginal utility predicts the consumption behaviour of
addicts quite well. LO7.1

Answer: false.
The law of diminishing marginal utility does not predict the consumption behaviour of
addicts well at all. That is because the law predicts that, other things equal, successive
units will be less and less valuable to a person. Thus, people should not keep on
consuming additional units relentlessly. But an alcoholic, for instance, will often purse a
15th drink on a given day with as much intensity as he pursued his first drink that day.
And a gambling addict will often bet his final dollar with as much alacrity as he bet his
first. Those suffering from addiction appear to behave as if the marginal utility of the
drug or behaviour to which they are addicted remains high no matter how much of the
drug or behaviour they engage in.

2. Frank spends $75 on 10 magazines and 25 newspapers. The magazines cost $5 each and the
newspapers cost $2.50 each. Suppose that his MU from the final magazine is 10 utils while his
MU from the final newspaper is also 10 utils. According to the utility-maximizing rule, Frank
should: LO7.2
a. Reallocate spending from magazines to newspapers.
b. Reallocate spending from newspapers to magazines.
c. Be satisfied because he is already maximizing his total utility.
d. None of the above.

Answer: a, reallocate spending from magazines to newspapers

Frank is not currently maximizing the utility that he could get from his $75 budget and
should reallocate spending from magazines to newspaper in order to increase the total
utility that he receives from his budget.
This can be seen by examining the MU per dollar that he is currently getting from the last
magazine and the last newspaper. The MU per dollar from the last magazine is 10/$5 = 2
utils per dollar. The MU per dollar from the last newspaper is 10/$2.50 = 4 utils per
dollar. Thus, Frank could gain more total utils if he spent less on newspapers and more
on dollars.
As an example, imagine that Frank cut his purchases of magazines by one, reducing them
from 10 purchased to only 9 purchased. That would free up $5 that he could spend on
newspapers. Since newspapers cost $2.50 each, he could purchase two newspapers.
Now, look at what happens to his total utility as he makes that change in consumption.
He will lose 10 utils by consuming one fewer magazine (because the MU of magazines is
10). But he will gain more than 10 utils by consuming two additional newspapers
(because the MU of an additional newspaper is 10 utils and he will be consuming two
additional newspapers). Thus, by reallocating his spending from the product with the
lower MU per dollar to the product with the higher MU per dollar, Frank will be able to
increase the total utility that he receives from his budget.

7-5
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

3. Demand curves slope downward because, other things held equal, LO7.3
a. An increase in a product’s price lowers MU.
b. A decrease in a product’s price lowers MU.
c. A decrease in a product’s price raises MU per dollar and makes consumers wish to purchase
more units.
d. An increase in a product’s price raises MU per dollar and makes consumers wish to purchase
more units.

Answer: c, A decrease in a product’s price raises MU per dollar and makes consumers
wish to purchase more units.
Rational consumers decide how to spend their limited budgets by comparing the marginal
utilities per dollar that they can get from various products. If the prices of all other
products stay the same while the price of product X falls, then the MU per dollar of
money spent on product X will increase. That will mean that any money spent
purchasing units of product X will get the consumer more MU than previously. Thus,
consumers interested in getting as much utility as possible when spending their limited
budges will want to spend more of their limited budgets on product X. This behaviour
explains the downward slope of demand curves because a decrease in the price of product
X leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of product X.

4. Jermaine spends his money on cucumbers and lettuce. If the price of cucumbers falls, the MU
per dollar of cucumbers will ______________ and Jermaine will _______________ cucumbers
for lettuce. LO7.4
a. Fall; substitute
b. Rise; substitute
c. Fall; supply
d. Rise; demand

Answer: b, rise; substitute


When the price of cucumbers falls, the MU per dollar of cucumbers will rise. As a result,
each dollar spent on cucumbers will now bring more marginal utility than it did
previously. Cucumbers thus become relatively more attractive than they were previously
and so Jermaine will switch, or substitute, some of his spending away from lettuce and
towards cucumbers in order to maximize his utility given the new, lower price of
cucumbers.

5. Tammy spends her money on lemonade and iced tea. If the price of lemonade falls, it is as
though her income __________________. LO7.4
a. increases
b. decreases
c. stays the same

7-6
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

Answer: a, increases.
A person’s income is not same thing as their budget. Rather, their income is the amount
of goods and services that they can purchase with their budget. Thus, when the price of
something that they purchase falls, their income rises because they can now purchase
more goods and services than they did before.
Consider the following example. Suppose that Tammy originally has a $6 budget and
maximizes utility by purchasing 2 glasses of lemonade for $2 each and 2 glasses of iced
tea for $1 each. So her income of goods and services is 2 glasses of lemonade and 2
glasses of iced tea. Then suppose that the price of iced tea falls in half, to only $1 per
glass. Her budget of $6 remains unchanged, but she will now be able to purchase more
total items and thereby enjoy a higher income due to the lower price of lemonade.
This can be seen most directly by noting that her old income of 2 glasses of lemonade
and 2 glasses of iced tea will now only cost $4—which means that she has $2 left over to
increase her consumption of either iced tea or lemonade. The price reduction allows her
to consume more overall, which is the same as saying that her income of goods and
services has increased.

PROBLEMS

1. Mylie’s total utility from singing the same song over and over is 50 utils after one repetition,
90 utils after two repetitions, 70 utils after three repetitions, 20 utils after four repetitions, -50
utils after five repetitions, and -200 utils after six repetitions. Write down her marginal utility for
each repetition. Once Mylie’s total utility begins to decrease, does each additional singing of the
song hurt more than the previous one or less than the previous one? LO7.1

Answers: 50, 40, -20, -50, -70, -150; More than the previous one.

Feedback: Consider the following values: Mylie’s total utility from singing the same
song over and over is 50 utils after one repetition, 90 utils after two repetitions, 70 utils
after three repetitions, 20 utils after four repetitions, -50 utils after five repetitions, and -
200 utils after six repetitions.
Mylie's marginal utility can be found by calculating the change in total utility as she sings
the song one more time. The utility from singing the song the first time is 50, which is the
total utility of singing the song the first time, 50, minus the total utility of not singing the
song at all, 0. The utility from singing the song the second time is 40, which is the total
utility from singing the song the second time, 90, minus the total utility from singing the
song the first time, 50. Apply the same procedure to following repetitions of the song.
The marginal utility of the third time is -20 (= 70 - 90). The fourth time, -50 (= 20 - 70),
the fifth time, -70 (= -50 - 20). The sixth time, -150 (= -200 - (-50) = -200 + 50).
Once Mylie's total utility begins to decrease, each additional song hurts more than the
previous one because she is becoming worse in terms of utility (which is a measure of
individual welfare). As we can see above, after the second repetition, Mylie is actually
worse off. Also, the decline in utility increases after the second repetition.

7-7
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

2. John likes Coca-Cola. After consuming one Coke, John has a total utility of 10 utils. After two
Cokes, he has a total utility of 25 utils. After three Cokes, he has a total utility of 50 utils. Does
John show diminishing marginal utility for Coke or does he show increasing marginal utility for
Coke? Suppose that John has $3 in his pocket. If Cokes cost $1 each and John is willing to spend
one of his dollars on purchasing a first can of Coke, would he spend his second dollar on a Coke,
too? What about the third dollar? If John’s marginal utility for Coke keeps on increasing no
matter how many Cokes he drinks, would it be fair to say that he is addicted to Coke? LO7.1

Answers: Increasing; Yes; Yes.

Feedback: Consider the following values: After consuming one Coke, John has a total
utility of 10 utils. After two Cokes, he has a total utility of 25 utils. After three Cokes, he
has a total utility of 50 utils. Also, assume John has $3 in his pocket and Cokes cost $1
each.
John's marginal utility equals the change in total utility as he consumes an additional unit.
Thus, his marginal utility from the first Coke is 10 (= 10 - 0), his second Coke is 15 (= 25
- 10), and his third Coke is 25 (= 50 -25). Since his marginal utility is increasing at an
increasing rate he shows increasing marginal utility for Coke.
If John consumes the first can of Coke, we know that his marginal utility per dollar was
sufficient to induce the purchase. Since his marginal utility increases as he consumes
more Coke, his marginal utility per dollar will also increase (price does not change). This
implies that he will purchase the second Coke because it provides even more marginal
utility per dollar than the first Coke did. The same is true for the third can of Coke. He
will spend his entire income on Coke, thus it is fair to say he is addicted to Coke.

3. Suppose that Omar’s marginal utility for cups of coffee is constant at 1.5 utils per cup, no
matter how many cups he drinks. On the other hand, his marginal utility per doughnut is 10 for
the first doughnut he eats, 9 for the second he eats, 8 for the third he eats, and so on (that is,
declining by 1 util per additional doughnut). In addition, suppose that coffee costs $1 per cup,
doughnuts cost $1 each, and Omar has a budget that he can spend only on doughnuts, coffee, or
both. How big would that budget have to be before he would spend a dollar buying a first cup of
coffee? LO7.2

Answer: $10.

7-8
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

Feedback: Consider the following example: Suppose that Omar’s marginal utility for
cups of coffee is constant at 1.5 utils per cup, no matter how many cups he drinks. On the
other hand, his marginal utility per doughnut is 10 for the first doughnut he eats, 9 for the
second he eats, 8 for the third he eats, and so on (that is, declining by 1 util per additional
doughnut). In addition, suppose that coffee costs $1 per cup, doughnuts cost $1 each, and
Omar has a budget that he can spend only on doughnuts and/or coffee.
To answer this question, we first need to calculate the marginal utility per dollar for
doughnuts. Recall that the marginal utility per dollar for a good is the marginal utility
divided by the price of the good (=MU/P). For the first doughnut we have 10 (=10/$1),
the second doughnut 9 (=9/$1), third 8, fourth 7, fifth 6, sixth 5, seventh 4, eighth 3, ninth
2, and tenth 1.
The marginal utility per dollar for every cup of coffee is 1.5 (=1.5/$1).
To determine how big the budget would have to be before John would spend a dollar
buying his first cup of coffee, we compare the marginal utility per dollar values. John will
purchase the first doughnut before he buys a cup of coffee because the marginal utility
per dollar for the doughnut is greater than the marginal utility per dollar for the cup of
coffee (10>1.5). The same is true for the second through the ninth doughnut. This implies
John will buy 9 doughnuts at the price of $1 before he buys his first cup of coffee.
Therefore his budget will need to $10 before he buys his first cup of coffee, $9 on the
doughnuts and $1 for the cup of coffee.

4. Columns 1 through 4 in the table below show the marginal utility, measured in utils, that
Ricardo would get by purchasing various amounts of products A, B, C, and D. Column 5 shows
the marginal utility Ricardo gets from saving. Assume that the prices of A, B, C, and D are,
respectively, $18, $6, $4, and $24 and that Ricardo has an income of $106. LO7.2

a. What quantities of A, B, C, and D will Ricardo purchase in maximizing his utility?


b. How many dollars will Ricardo choose to save?
c. Check your answers by substituting them into the algebraic statement of the utility-maximizing
rule (verify that all of the income has been exhausted between the various goods and savings).

7-9
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

Answer: (a) 4 units of good A, 3 units of good B, 3 units of good C, zero units of good D; (b)
$4; (c) $106 (= $18x4 + $6x3 +$4x3 + $24x0 + $4)

Feedback: Consider the following information and use the table above: the prices of A,
B, C, and D are, respectively, $18, $6, $4, and $24 and Ricardo has an income of $106.

The first step is to convert the marginal utility values into marginal utility per dollar
values. Recall this is MU/P.

Marginal Marginal Marginal Marginal Marginal Marginal Marginal Marginal units


Utility Utility Utility Utility Utility Utility Utility Utility
per dollar per dollar per dollar per dollar per dollar per dollar per dollar per dollar
unit 1 unit 2 unit 3 unit 4 unit 5 unit 6 unit 7 unit 8
Column 1 4.00 3.00 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 0.83 0.67 4
Good A
Column 2 4.00 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.17 0.83 0.33 0.17 3
Good B
Column 3 3.75 3.00 2.00 1.75 1.25 1.00 0.88 0.75 3
Good C
Column 4 1.50 1.25 1.00 0.75 0.54 0.29 0.17 0.08 0
Good D
Column 5 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0.50 0.25 0.13 4
Saving

The table above reads across rows (for example, the first row labeled 'Column 1-Good A'
is marginal utility per dollar for good A). The columns represent the marginal utility per
dollar for the different goods for each unit consumed and saving (for example, column 1
'Marginal Utility per dollar unit 1' tells us the marginal utility per dollar for the first unit
of every good and savings). This will makes the comparison a little easier.

To determine the optimal amount of goods that Ricardo will purchase, we choose the
goods with the highest marginal utility per dollar as we move from left to right. We
continue to do this until income is exhausted. We see that the first unit of savings ($1)
provides $5.00 worth of utility per dollar, so Ricardo makes this choice. Next he
purchases one unit of good A and good B with a marginal utility per dollar of 4 He will
also save the second dollar (an additional $1) because the marginal utility per dollar is 4.
The next decision leads Ricardo to purchase the first unit of good C with a marginal
utility per dollar of 3. Then he moves on to purchase the second unit of good A, the
second unit of good B, and he saves an additional dollar because the marginal utility per
dollar is 3for these goods. After these purchases, he has an income left of $53. Since he
has income left, he continues to buy more goods using the approach above.

In conclusion, Ricardo will consume 4 units of good A, 3 units of good B, 3 units of good
C, zero units of good D, and saves $4. This will exhaust his income $106 (= $18 x 4 + $6
x 3 +$4 x 3 + $24 x 0 + $4).

7-10
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

5. You are choosing between two goods, X and Y, and your marginal utility from each is as
shown in the table below. If your income is $9 and the prices of X and Y are $2 and $1,
respectively, what quantities of each will you purchase to maximize utility? What total utility will
you realize? Assume that, other things remaining unchanged, the price of X falls to $1. What
quantities of X and Y will you now purchase? Using the two prices and quantities for X, derive a
demand schedule (prices and quantities demanded table) for X. LO7.3

Answer: X = 2 units, Y = 5 units; total utility = 48; X = 4, Y = 5; Demand schedule =


Price Demanded Quantity Demanded
2 2
1 4

Feedback: Consider the following table and information as an example:

Your income is $9 and the prices of X and Y are $2 and $1, respectively.

The first step is to convert the marginal utility values into marginal utility per dollar
values. Recall this is MU/P. See the table below.

7-11
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

Marginal Marginal Marginal Marginal Marginal Marginal Units


Utility Utility Utility Utility Utility Utility
per per per per per per
dollar dollar dollar dollar dollar dollar
unit 1 unit 2 unit 3 unit 4 unit 5 unit 6
Good Y 8.00 7.00 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 5
(first price)
Good X 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.50 1.00 2
(first price)
Good Y 8.00 7.00 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 5
(second
price)
Good X 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 4
(second
price)

The first two rows define the marginal utility per dollar for goods X and Y when the price
of good X is $2 and the price of Good Y is $1. Each column is the marginal utility for the
unit consumed (Marginal utility per dollar for unit 1 is for the first unit consumed,
Marginal utility per dollar for unit 2 is for the second unit consumed, etc...).
To determine the optimal number of goods to purchase we choose the goods with the
highest marginal utility per dollar as we move from left to right. We continue to do this
until income is exhausted.
First, we only consider the first two rows for Goods X and Y for the first price of good X
(price of X is $2). We purchase the first unit of good Y with a marginal utility per dollar
of 8. Next we purchase the second unit of good Y with a marginal utility per dollar of 7.
Followed by the third unit of good Y with a marginal utility per dollar of 6. Continuing
on, we purchase the fourth and fifth unit of Good Y and the first and second unit of good
X 5and4marginal utility per dollar). Thus, we purchase 5 units of good Y and 2 units of
good X. The total cost is $9 (= $5 x 5 + $2 x 2), which exhausts income.
The total utility is then found by adding up the marginal utility values for the goods
consumed using the values in the original table. The total utility from good Y is 30 (=8 +
7 + 6 + 5 + 4) and the total utility from good X is 18 (=10 + 8). The sum of these two
values is the total utility, which equals 48 (=30 + 18).
Now we consider the case where the price of good X falls to $1.
Here, we only consider the last two rows for Goods X and Y for the second price of good
X. Here our first purchase is the first unit of good X with a marginal utility per dollar of
10. Next we purchase the second unit of good X and the first unit of good Y with a
marginal utility per dollar of 8.00. We continue this process until income is exhausted.
The optimal consumption level for good X is 4 and for good Y is 5.
This gives us the ordered pairs for good X: (P = 2, Q = 2) and (P = 1, Q = 4). We can use
these ordered pairs to graph the demand schedule (not required).

7-12
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

6. ADVANCED ANAYLSIS Let MUA = z = 10 - x and MUB = z = 21 - 2y, where z is marginal


utility per dollar measured in utils, x is the amount spent on product A, and y is the amount spent
on product B. Assume that the consumer has $10 to spend on A and B—that is, x + y = 10. How
is the $10 best allocated between A and B? How much utility will the marginal dollar yield?
LO7.3

Answer: $7 on good B; $3 on good A; MUA = 7, MUB = 7.

Feedback: To solve this system of equations we set the MUA=MUB. This is required if
we are maximizing utility. This leaves with only x and y to solve for using the
individual's budget constraint.
Consider the following equations: Let MUA = z = 10 - x and MUB = z = 21 - 2y, where z
is marginal utility per dollar measured in utils, x is the amount spent on product A, and y
is the amount spent on product B. Also, assume that the consumer has $10 to spend on A
and B—that is, x + y = 10.
We know from our optimization rule that MUA=MUB, which implies 10 - x = 21 - 2y. Or,
after some rearranging, 2y - x = 11. Combining this equation with our budget constraint,
x + y =10, we have two equations and two unknowns (x and y).

Use the budget constraint to solve x, or x = 10 - y. Substitute x from this equation into
our optimality rule (2y - x = 11), which gives us 2y - (10 -y) = 11. Again after some
rearranging, we have 2y - 10 + y = 11, or 3y = 21. Thus, we spend $7 on good B. Using
our budget constraint 9x + y =10), this implies we spend $3 on good A.
To check our answer, substitute these values into the marginal utility equations: MUA=
10 - x, or MUA = 10 -3 = 7 and MUB = 21 - 2y = 21 -2x7 = 7. Thus, MUA=MUB., and the
marginal dollar will yield 7 utils.

7-13
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 07 - Consumer Choice and Utility Maximization

7. Suppose that with a budget of $100, Deborah spends $60 on sushi and $40 on bagels when
sushi costs $2 per piece and bagels cost $2 per bagel. But then, after the price of bagels falls to $1
per bagel, she spends $50 on sushi and $50 on bagels. How many pieces of sushi and how many
bagels did Deborah consume before the price change? At the new prices, how much money
would it have cost Deborah to buy those same quantities (the ones that she consumed before the
price change)? Given that it used to take Deborah’s entire $100 to buy those quantities, how big is
the income effect caused by the reduction in the price of bagels? LO7.4

Answers: 30 pieces of sushi and 20 bagels; $80 (= (30 x $2) + (20 x $1)); $20.

Feedback: Consider the following values as an example. Suppose that with a budget of
$100, Deborah spends $60 on sushi and $40 on bagels when sushi costs $2 per piece and
bagels cost $2 per bagel. But then, after the price of bagels falls to $1 per bagel, she
spends $50 on sushi and $50 on bagels.
This implies that Deborah bought 30 pieces of Sushi (=$60/$2) and she bought 20 bagels
(=$40/2) before the price change.
If Deborah purchased the same quantities of Sushi and bagels with the new prices it
would only cost her $80. She still spends $60 on Sushi because the price hasn't changed
(still $2) and she was consuming 30 pieces. However, the cost of the 20 bagels has fallen
to $20 because the price of the bagel is only $1 now.
This implies Deborah has an additional $20 to spend as a result of the price decrease on
bagels (= $100 (original cost) - $80 (new cost)).

7-14
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written
consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
The Project Gutenberg eBook of Royal fruit
gelatin suggestions
This ebook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United
States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with
almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away
or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License
included with this ebook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you
are not located in the United States, you will have to check the
laws of the country where you are located before using this
eBook.

Title: Royal fruit gelatin suggestions

Creator: Royal Baking Powder Company

Release date: September 17, 2023 [eBook #71670]

Language: English

Original publication: United States: Royal Baking Powder Co,


1926

Credits: Lisa Corcoran, Stephen Hutcheson, Bob Taylor and the


Online Distributed Proofreading Team at
https://www.pgdp.net

*** START OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK ROYAL


FRUIT GELATIN SUGGESTIONS ***
Royal
Fruit
Gelatin
Suggestions
Made by the Makers of Royal Baking Powder
189,000 women asked for
it in 7 weeks
Sent all the way to New York for
this new delicious dessert, the
minute they read about it
Now they write
From Oklahoma—“We served raspberry
for dinner and we were more than delighted.
It is delicious. Royal Fruit Gelatin has
completely won our hearts.”
In Massachusetts they say—“It is delicious
and all that you claim for it, and I shall
certainly use it after this.”
“Your gelatin is better than any other
brand. The orange gelatin was especially
good and the flavor exactly like the fresh
fruit. If I had held an orange in one hand and
the opened box of gelatin in the other, it
would have been hard to tell by smell which
was which,” writes an enthusiast in
Pennsylvania.
They love it in Ohio!—“I am writing to
express my satisfaction with the real fruit
flavor, and to say it is the finest thing in the
gelatin line I have ever had. The children are
saying ‘please get some more!’ Where can I
buy it?”
In New York State—“I found Royal Gelatin
far superior to the brand I have been using,
as it is tastier and lends itself well to the
adding of fruit,” writes one delighted woman.

*Now you can buy it everywhere....

Copyright, 1926, by Royal Baking Powder Co. Printed in U. S. A.


A Revelation
in
Flavors
T HE fresh, fragrant aroma, that greets you the
moment you open the package—how
delicious it is—how different from any gelatin you
have ever bought before. You recognize its
distinction with the first whiff—it’s the very aroma
of the sun-ripened fresh fruits themselves.
Pour a little of it into your hand. Note the rich heaviness of the
delicate fruit-flavored crystals. Empty the package into a bowl, and
pour on the boiling water—Ah! Just smell the rich fragrance! Like
ripe fruit, warm with sunshine and drenched with dew.
Taste these new gelatins carefully—roll them
on your tongue. There is no strange flavor—no
“manufactured” taste at all. Not the faintest trace
of “gummy” taste or “gluey” smell. The pure
gelatin that carries these fresh fruit flavors does
not alter their delicacy, their aroma, in any way.
For no synthetics or artificial flavorings are used.
And pure, perfect gelatin of itself is neutral to
taste and smell.

Real fruit flavors made from


fresh fruits
Royal Raspberry—ripe, luscious, melting, like the very berries
from whose juice its flavor comes.
Royal Strawberry—hold it to the light! It’s the real strawberry
shade—gleaming, perfect. And its flavor—straight from the juice of
that most perfect fruit.
Sniff the cherry-ripe fragrance that rises as you melt the crystals of
Royal Cherry—gleaming, dancing under the leaves, playing hide and
seek with the sunshine ... that’s the way the juice from which this
flavor is made is ripened and sweetened.
Royal Orange with its golden beauty—Royal Lemon, clear,
translucent, pure ... with the delicious flavor and fragrance only the
fruits themselves can give—how delectable they are.

And for health....


Famous food specialists everywhere
recommend gelatin as an integral part of a
balanced diet. As a source of protein, a
principle of growth, an active aid to
digestion, it has its established place.
It is especially desirable for children—
and how they love it! While to the
housewife, it is a delicious dessert that
may be made in a minute—yet capable of
so many toothsome changes that “time
cannot stale its infinite variety.” Nor
(blessed thought!) in spite of its charm to a
sweet tooth, is it fattening at all!
Of course you want the very purest gelatin in the world! On
general principles, and because it’s so invaluable for children. You
know you can trust Royal Fruit Flavored Gelatin quality ... because
for years you have used Royal Baking Powder, and know its
superlative standard. Royal Fruit Flavored Gelatin is made by the
same standards of quality and purity.
You’ll be delighted with its delicate texture, smooth, tender, firm,
and, with its lovely color, as appetizing to look at, as to taste. And
then it’s so quick! Hundreds of delighted women have written to tell
us that it sets more quickly than any other gelatin they have ever
used. For making whipped desserts, they tell us it is wonderful. “It
whips just like cream” “and so easily and quickly.”
You’ll notice, and enjoy, the difference too!

With confidence....
We introduce Royal Fruit Flavored Gelatin to our Royal Baking
Powder friends with complete confidence, and especial pride. We
are sure that the same discriminating taste that insists upon
consistent perfection, will give it the sure and lasting welcome that
Royal Baking Powder has always received.
The Package, The Utensils and
Just How to Get Perfect Results

E ACH package of Royal Fruit Flavored Gelatin weighs 3¼ ozs.


and measures ½ cup or 8 tablespoons.
Each package of 3¼ ozs. calls for two cups or one pint water or
other liquid and makes over one pint jelly, or sufficient to serve six
persons.
In order to save time and shorten the cooling process, one cup
boiling water is used to dissolve the gelatin and one cup cold water
or other liquid to cool it, but if preferred, the two cups boiling water
can be added at once.
If you desire to use a portion of a package at any time, dissolve
two level tablespoons Royal Fruit Flavored Gelatin in ½ cup boiling
water and this amount can be moulded in a custard cup and is
sufficient for one large serving.
When a portion of a package of Royal Fruit Flavored Gelatin is left,
close tightly as possible and keep in a dry place until ready to use.

Utensils for Measuring, Dissolving,


Moulding and Chilling Royal
Fruit Flavored Gelatins
Kettle for boiling water
Bowl for holding the Gelatin
Measuring cup
Spoon for stirring
Mould or bowl or cup for setting the Gelatin

I N MEASURING the liquid it is important to use the standard


measuring cup holding ½ pint or its equivalent, as the consistency
of the finished Gelatin depends upon the amount of water or other
liquids used.
Stir the mixture well after boiling water is added so all will be
dissolved. Then add cold water.
For Whipped Desserts the rotary egg beater is best and saves
much time.

Moulds

T HERE are on the market, tin, aluminum and china moulds in


varying shapes and sizes. If there is no mould at hand, ordinary
bowls, custard cups or even plain cups can be used very
successfully for moulding Royal Fruit Flavored Gelatins.

Chilling

T HE quickest way to chill Royal Fruit Flavored Gelatins is in the


ice box. To shorten the stiffening process still further, set mould
in pan filled with cracked ice, rock salt and water.
In cold weather, the mould, covered, can be placed on outside
window sill. Royal Fruit Flavored Gelatins chilled in this way will
stiffen in a remarkably short time; in some cases in one-half to three-
quarters of an hour.

Removing Gelatin From Moulds

D IP mould very quickly into bowl or pan of hot water. Loosen


carefully from sides of mould with a knife; place plate or serving
dish over top and quickly turn upside down. The mould can then be
lifted carefully without spoiling the shape or design.

How Served

R OYAL
Flavored
Fruit

Gelatins are
complete in
themselves and
really do not require
any garnishings.
However, they are
delicious served with
whipped or plain
cream, custard,
marshmallow or fruit
sauces, recipes for
which are included in
this booklet.
Royal Lemon
You’ll find Royal Lemon delightful
in its refreshing deliciousness.

Orange Lemon Jelly


1 package Royal Orange Gelatin
1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
2 cups boiling water
2 cups cold water

P UT Royal Lemon and Orange Gelatins into large bowl. Mix well;
add boiling water and stir until dissolved; add cold water. Pour
into moulds; chill until firm and serve plain or with sliced fruit.
Bananas are very good. Serves 12.

Cider Jelly
1 package Royal Orange or Lemon Gelatin
⅛ teaspoon salt
2 cups sweet cider

H EAT 1 cup cider to boiling. Pour over Royal Orange or Lemon


Gelatin and salt; stir until dissolved. Add 1 cup cold cider. Pour
into moulds and chill until firm. As a relish, serve plain. As a dessert,
serve plain or with whipped cream. Serves 6.

Coffee Jelly
1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
1 cup boiling water
1¼ cups strong coffee

D ISSOLVE Royal Lemon Gelatin in boiling water. Add coffee


which has been very carefully strained from any coffee grounds.
Pour into mould; chill until firm. Serve with sweetened whipped
cream. Serves 6.

Jellied Custard

Tomato Jelly Salad


1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
1⅔ cups strained tomato juice
¼ cup vinegar
1 teaspoon salt
⅛ teaspoon pepper
⅛ teaspoon cloves
1 teaspoon onion juice
¼ teaspoon paprika

H EAT tomato juice to boiling, and pour over Royal Lemon Gelatin.
Stir until thoroughly dissolved; add vinegar and seasonings.
Pour into moulds. Serve with mayonnaise on lettuce leaves. Serves
6.

Orange Charlotte Russe


1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
2 cups boiling water
½ teaspoon salt
1 cup orange juice
Sections of pulp from 2 oranges well drained from juice
1 cup cream, whipped

D ISSOLVE Royal Lemon Gelatin and salt in boiling water. Add


orange juice. Cool by setting bowl in pan of very cold water until
mixture begins to thicken. Beat with egg beater until light and frothy.
Fold in whipped cream and sections of orange pulp free from any
skin. Place in mould and chill thoroughly.
If desired, the mould may be decorated with the orange sections,
instead of moulding them in the dessert. Serves 10.

Jellied Custard
1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
1 cup boiling water
1 egg
¼ cup sugar
¼ teaspoon salt
2 cups milk

M AKE a soft custard of the last four ingredients as follows:—Beat


egg slightly, add sugar and salt; mix well. Pour on milk and
cook in double boiler stirring until it thickens sufficiently to coat the
spoon. Cool.
Dissolve Royal Lemon Gelatin in boiling water. Cool; when it
begins to thicken, add the custard; pour into moulds. Chill until firm.
Serve with Fruit Sauce.
For variation, add ½ cup any preserved fruit with the custard,
using the syrup drained from the fruit as a sauce. Serves 12.

Apricot Whip
1 package Royal Lemon or Orange Gelatin
1 cup boiling water
⅛ teaspoon salt
¾ cup apricot pulp
½ cup apricot juice

D ISSOLVE Royal Gelatin in boiling water; add salt, apricot pulp


and juice and chill by setting in cracked ice or very cold water.
When almost set, beat with egg beater until stiff enough to hold its
shape. Pile lightly in sherbet glasses lined with lady fingers or in
small moulds and chill until firm.
Canned, sweetened, fresh or stewed apricots may be used.
Serves 6.

Sunshine Salad
1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
1 cup boiling water
1 cup canned grated pineapple well drained from juice
1 cup cold water
1 cup grated carrot

D ISSOLVE Royal Lemon Gelatin in boiling water; add cold water.


Chill until it begins to thicken. Add grated carrot and pineapple.
Chill in small moulds until firm. Serve on lettuce with mayonnaise.
This is particularly good for children. Serves 6.

Pineapple Marshmallow Jelly


1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
1 package Royal Cherry Gelatin
2 cups boiling water
2 cups cold water
6 slices canned pineapple, diced
12 marshmallows, cut in small pieces

D ISSOLVE Royal Lemon and Cherry Gelatins in boiling water;


add cold water and cool; add fruit, drained from juice, and
marshmallows. Chill, stirring occasionally while thickening to prevent
fruit from settling. When set, serve in sherbet glasses. Serves 12.
Pineapple Bavarian Cream
1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
1 cup boiling water
⅛ teaspoon salt
1 cup canned pineapple juice
1 cup grated pineapple
1 cup cream, whipped

D ISSOLVE Royal Lemon Gelatin in boiling water; add salt and


pineapple juice. Set in pan of cracked ice or very cold water and
chill until mixture begins to thicken. Beat with egg beater until very
frothy. Fold in grated pineapple and whipped cream. Blend well;
place in moulds and chill. Serves 10.

Jellied Fudgy Apples


½ cup sugar
1 cup water
6 apples—peeled and cored
1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
1 cup cold water
1 cup brown sugar
1 tablespoon butter
¼ cup milk

B OIL together sugar and water for about 10 minutes. Add apples
and cook until tender but not broken. When done, drain and
arrange in one large or six small moulds. Measure boiling syrup, add
boiling water to make one cup. Pour over Royal Lemon Gelatin and
stir until dissolved. Add one cup cold water. Cool. Prepare fudge by
boiling together brown sugar, butter and milk to 238° F., or until a soft
ball forms when tested in cold water. Fill centers of apples with fudge
mixture. When it has cooled, pour gelatin mixture over apples to fill
mould. Chill until firm. Serve with Whipped Cream.
½ cup chopped walnuts or pecans may be added to fudge mixture
if desired. Serves 6.

Cherry Angelica
1 package Royal Lemon Gelatin
1 cup boiling water
1 cup cold water
10 maraschino cherries, chopped fine
⅔ cup angelica, chopped fine

D ISSOLVE Royal Lemon Gelatin in boiling water; add cold water.


Chill; when mixture begins to thicken, stir in cherries and
angelica. Pour into moulds and chill until firm or line the moulds as
follows:—Set moulds in pan of cracked ice. Pour in small amount of
cold but still liquid Royal Gelatin. Tip and turn moulds to coat entire
surface with the mixture. Arrange on this very thin strips of angelica
and bits of cherries to form a design. Add remainder of gelatin
mixture, carefully so design will not be disturbed. When all is added,
chill until firm. Serves 6.

Pineapple Marshmallow Jelly


Royal Orange
And in Royal Orange you will find
an ideal flavor with which to serve
fresh fruits.

Apricot Fruit Mould


1 package Royal Orange Gelatin
1¾ cups apricot juice
½ cup water
½ cup canned apricots, sliced
½ cup canned cherries, halved and stoned

H EAT apricot juice to boiling. Pour over Royal Orange Gelatin


and stir until dissolved. Add water. Chill until mixture begins to
thicken, then fold in fruit well drained from juice. Pour into one large
or eight small moulds and chill until firm. Serve with cream. Serves 8.

Rhubarb Royal
1 package Royal Orange Gelatin
1 cup boiling water
1 lb rhubarb
1½ cups cold water
½ cup sugar

W ASH rhubarb and cut into 1-inch pieces. Do not remove the
skin. Place in shallow pan. Add ½ cup cold water to sugar and
pour over rhubarb. Bake in slow oven (250° F.) until tender but
unbroken. Baste occasionally with the syrup in the pan. Dissolve
Royal Orange Gelatin in boiling water; add 1 cup cold water. Chill.
Just as it begins to thicken fill eight small moulds ½ full, arrange
rhubarb pieces on it and fill moulds with remainder of the gelatin.
Chill until firm. Serve plain or with cream. Serves 8.

You might also like