Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 30

Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies

ISSN: 0007-4918 (Print) 1472-7234 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cbie20

Survey of Recent Developments

Armida S. Alisjahbana & Chris Manning

To cite this article: Armida S. Alisjahbana & Chris Manning (2002) Survey of
Recent Developments, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 38:3, 277-305, DOI:
10.1080/00074910215539

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/00074910215539

Published online: 17 Jun 2010.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 90

View related articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=cbie20
Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 38, No. 3, 2002: 277–305

SURVEY OF RECENT DEVELOPMENTS

Armida S. Alisjahbana
Padjadjaran University, Bandung

Chris Manning*
Australian National University

SUMMARY
The Indonesian economy continued to for 2002, and the fire sale of IBRA debts
stabilise in 2002, and to recover in the added another Rp 23 trillion to the pub-
second and third quarters of the year lic coffers. Although investment still
from poorer performance in the previ- remained flat, there had also been some
ous year. Confidence was helped by a important signs of credit expansion for
successful MPR session in August, small and medium enterprises. Some
which completed the round of consti- breakthroughs were achieved in the
tutional reforms begun several years private sector, such as a resolution in
earlier, including provision for direct the long-standing Kalimantan Prima
election of the president and vice presi- Coal dispute on divestment of its ma-
dent and a new bicameral elected jority shareholding, and a favourable
national assembly. Sadly, just when court rulin g in the M an ulife case
macroeconomic conditions seemed (Athukorala 2002: 145 and 147–8).
more favourable than for some time, the At the same time, recovery in both
tragic events in Bali in October threw a domestic demand and exports was halt-
cloud over growth prospects for the fi- ing. International confidence was not
nal quarter and the coming year. helped by National Planning Agency
All the indicators of macroeconomic head Kwik Kian Gie’s continuing focus
performance had turned around by on early ‘graduation’ from the IMF pro-
August–September. The exchange rate gram. Asset sales were delayed because
had appreciated significantly, year-on- of haggling over the disposal of a 51%
year inflation was down from 15% in share in Bank Niaga and there were signs
February to 10% by August, and nomi- of spreading agricultural protection,
nal interest rates had fallen. These de- much of it in the form of NTBs. There
velopm ents supported much more were strong indications that labour regu-
favourable budget outcomes for 2002. lation and associated unrest were begin-
The assumptions for the proposed 2003 ning to affect the investment climate.
budget appeared generally plausible, Labour-intensive manufacturing exports
although the 5% growth target seemed suffered in particular, raising much con-
a little too optimistic, the more so in the cern about job creation. The crisis over
wake of the Bali bombings. Divestment repatriation of large numbers of overseas
of shares from both Telkom and Indosat workers from Malaysia from early 2002
appeared to have secured the govern- did not help the labour market, especially
ment’s budget target from IBRA sales in Eastern Indonesia.

ISSN 0007-4918 print/ISSN 1472-7234 online/02/030277-29 © 2002 Indonesia Project ANU


278 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

POLITICAL DEVELOPMENTS through to a second round. Teams on


The August MPR (People’s Consultative one ticket must gain at least 20% of the
Council) meeting marked the fourth and votes in half of the country’s provinces,
final round of constitutional amend- requiring the candidates to cultivate
ments begun under former President support in the majority of outer island
Habibie. 1 The amendments passed allow provinces. The reform ensures that the
the public direct control over the election strongest presidential–vice-presidential
of the president, and take away the teams will probably consist of coalition
MPR’s authority to elect the president candidates from the major parties.
and the president’s direct accountability In practice, the completion of the
to the MPR (with the accountability round of constitutional amendments
speech to the MPR now replaced by an reaffirms the unitary structure of the
annual report). The two main amend- state with ‘federal’ arrangements, in-
ments on the election of the president and cluding the creation of two new special
the composition and role of the MPR autonomous regions in Aceh and Papua.
were passed with relatively little oppo- The bicameral system to replace the cur-
sition, after extensive negotiation among rent MPR will consist of an elected DPR
the major parties. A constitutional com- (Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat, People’s
mission was to be set up through an MPR Representative Council) chamber and a
committee over the next six months, with second elected chamber to represent re-
a more limited agenda than initially en- gional interests, the DPD (Dewan
visaged of ‘synchronising’ and improv- Perwakilan Daerah or Council of Re-
ing the amendments already passed. The gional Representatives). Interest group
push by several of the Muslim-oriented representatives will disappear from the
parties for introduction of syariat law MPR in 2004, bringing about the historic
through revision of article 29 was de- removal of the 38 armed forces (TNI)
feated. However, the MPR meeting also representatives, who would have re-
saw the creation of two independent ju- tained their seats until 2009 under a
dicial bodies, a Constitutional Court and previous decree.2
an independent Judicial Commission The MPR also took the bold step of
with responsibility for supreme court mandating an ‘aspirational’ 20% alloca-
appointments and judicial ethics issues. tion for education from central and dis-
The passing of the two amendments trict budgets and a stipulation that the
is critical for planning of the 2004 elec- social welfare system should be ex-
tion. They include provisions for direct tended to ‘all the people’, although it
election of the president and vice presi- was not clear how either objective might
dent, and for the restructuring of the be achieved in practice.
MPR, for the first time since it was in- Two other political events in Septem-
augurated in 1960, into a fully elected ber portrayed the government in a less
bicameral assembly comprising parlia- favourable light with pro-democracy
ment and a regional representative forces. The first was the decision of
council. A two-stage process of presi- Akbar Tanjung (with implicit presiden-
dential election was approved which tial support) not to step down from any
sets out a ‘packet’ system whereby par- of his present positions, including as
ties nominate ‘tickets’ of presidential chairman of the DPR, while he appeals
and vice-presidential candidates. If no against the three-year gaol term handed
ticket gains the necessary majority sup- down early in the month for embezzle-
port, the two highest ranking tickets go ment of Bulog funds. Not long after the
Survey of Recent Developments 279

Akbar ruling, the controversial Jakarta Q4 2001 figure of just 1.6% (table 1). This
governor, General (ret.) Soetiyoso, was growth was mainly supported by con-
voted in for a second term by the pro- sumption spending, with private and
vincial assembly, with Megawati’s government consumption increasing by
blessing and amidst huge demonstra- 6.4% and 9.4%, respectively, even
tions. The election was marked by well though total consumption growth fell
documented claims of substantial vote back slightly during the first half. Sec-
buying of councillors in the regional as- ond quarter investment was 3.7% lower
sembly (DPRD) (JP, 5/9/02). 3 This than in 2001, although this rate of de-
came on top of a detailed account of cline was less severe than in the two pre-
spending sprees by DPR members from vious quarters. Exports continued to fall
huge increases in salaries and other at a significant rate, while imports
emoluments in various regions across slumped dramatically in each of the last
the country at a time of fiscal belt-tight- three quarters.
ening (Tempo, English Edition, 1–7 Given the continued decline in invest-
October 2002). ment and exports, the contribution of
At the time of writing, it was still too private consumptiongrowth to economic
early to assess the political and economic recovery is important, since it accounts
fallout from the huge bomb blast that for more than 70% of GDP (DRI 2002).
claimed the lives of over 180 people, the The continued healthy growth in private
majority of them foreigners, in Kuta, Bali consumption may reflect perceptions of
on 12 October. Despite earlier official de- reduced risk relating to economic and
nials, the country has now been tragi- political conditions and, in particular,
cally given notice that it is well and truly increasing confidence engendered by
on the international terrorist map. The strengthening of the rupiah. The rise in
tragedy is likely to affect the Balinese net exports during the last year (with
economy severely, especially through imports declining much more than ex-
dire consequences for tourism in the ports) reflects the expected reallocation
immediate future. It is also likely to pose of productive resources from non-
a further disincentive to foreign invest- tradable goods and services to tradables
ment throughout Indonesia (and the re- as a result of the large real depreciation
gion), though early falls in the exchange of the rupiah from mid 1997. The persis-
rate and the stock exchange, while no- tent decline in investment is due mainly
ticeable, were not as large as some had to continued lack of business confi-
feared. This domestic shock occurred at dence—especially among foreign inves-
a time of heightened fears of a down- tors; the adverse impact of the global
turn in the international economy in the economic slowdown on investment in
wake of the US stock market decline, export-oriented industries; the existence
and in light of the pending US, and pos- of significantexcess capacity in the manu-
sibly UN-supported, attack on Iraq. facturing sector; and poor profit perfor-
mances in the corporate sector
MACROECONOMIC (Athukorala 2002; ADB 2002: 7).
PERFORMANCE On the output side, relatively strong
Regained Growth Momentum? growth in the second quarter was
The upward trend in GDP growth that helped considerably by an impressive
began in Q1 2002 continued, with GDP turnaround in the agriculture sector,
expanding in the second quarter of 2002 which registered 6.3% year-on-year
by 3.5% year-on-year, well up from the growth after modest declines in the pre-
280 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

TABLE 1 GDP Growth, Year-on-Year


(1993 prices, %)

Mar-01 Jun-01 Sep-01 Dec-01 Mar-02 Jun-02

GDP 4.8 3.8 3.1 1.6 2.2 3.5


Expenditure
Private consumption 4.0 4.7 5.8 9.2 7.1 6.4
Government consumption 6.0 4.2 11.9 11.0 8.8 9.4
Investment 18.9 7.7 –0.8 –7.1 –6.9 –3.7
Exports 18.4 8.0 –2.6 –12.9 –5.2 –7.1
Imports 50.7 37.2 –3.7 –29.8 –25.7 –21.6
Sector
Agriculture, livestock, forestry
& fisheries 3.7 1.7 –0.4 –2.8 –1.4 6.3
Mining & quarrying 6.8 –0.3 –2.4 –5.9 -2.3 1.8
Manufacturing 4.2 4.8 4.7 3.6 3.7 2.5
Electricity, gas & water supply 7.3 9.9 8.9 7.6 7.9 4.7
Construction 6.2 5.7 3.5 0.7 1.7 2.4
Trade, hotels & restaurants 6.8 5.5 5.7 2.6 3.4 3.7
Transport & communications 6.4 7.0 7.6 8.9 8.4 8.2
Finance, rental & business services 3.9 3.4 2.7 2.0 2.7 2.6
Other services 1.3 1.6 2.3 2.7 1.5 0.4

Source: CEIC Asia Database.

ceding three quarters. The manufactur- outperform Malaysia until Q2 2002 (fig-
ing and construction sectors grew ure 1). It has been argued that this was
relatively slowly, by 2.5% and 2.4% re- because Indonesia was not affected as
spectively, while transport and commu- severely by the slump in the electronics
nications continued to outperform other export market, on which it is less depen-
sectors, with growth of 8.2%. The steady dent than countries such as Malaysia
decline in manufacturing growth (from and Korea (Pangestu and Goeltom
4.7% year-on-year in Q3 2001) provides 2001). Nevertheless, Indonesia’s growth
some cause for concern, but all in all it rate declined during 2001 and, notwith-
appears that GDP growth for 2002 is standing recent acceleration, it had
likely to be in the range 3.5–3.8% in the fallen behind all the other countries in
absence of any expectation of resurgence this group by mid 2002.
in exports or investment.
In longer-term perspective, GDP re- Financial Indicators
bounded relatively slowly from the peak Exchange Rate. The rupiah appreciated
of the crisis in 1998, only beginning to strongly between February and May
grow moderately during the latter part 2002, but weakened a little from mid year
of 1999. Somewhat surprisingly, Indo- to around Rp 9,000/$ in September (fig-
nesia’s growth compared favourably ure 2). (The October bombings in Bali
with that of the other Asian crisis coun- had had surprisingly little impact on the
tries from late 2000 until the third quar- currency at the time of writing.) Overall
ter of 2001, and Indonesia continued to it appreciated by some 15.4% against the
Survey of Recent Developments 281

FIGURE 1 Comparative GDP Growth, Year-on-Year


(1993 prices, %)
16

Indonesia Malaysia
12
Philippines Korea
Thailand

-4
Q1 2000 Q1 2001 Q1 2002

Source: Asia Recovery Information Center Database, www.aric.adb.org.

FIGURE 2 Exchange Rates and Share Pricesa


(December 1999 = 100)
100

80

60

$/Rp
40 Yen/Rp
CSPI

20

0
Sep-01 Dec-01 Mar-02 Jun-02 Sep-02
a
CSPI = Composite Share Price Index.

Source: CEIC Asia Database.


282 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

dollar and 6.8% against the yen during strengthening during this period, dol-
the first three quarters of 2002—one of lar values were still 23% above their end
the stronger performances across the re- 2001 levels. Part of the explanation for
gion. The strengthening of the currency the decline in rupiah share prices may
has also been accompanied by a reduc- be overall weakness in industrial coun-
tion in its volatility compared with the try and regional stock markets, but the
previous year (Bank Indonesia 2002). decline in money growth relative to the
Among other things, these positive de- earlier period is also likely to have con-
velopments presumably reflect both in- tributed.
ternational and domestic responses to Base Money. Base money increased by
Indonesia’s perceived commitment to 21% in the year to November 2001, 4 and
more prudent macroeconomic manage- stood at Rp 127.8 trillion at year end,
ment (LPEM–FEUI 2002), including bet- well above the current LOI (letter of in-
ter control of monetary growth. tent to the IMF) indicative target of Rp
Risk. Short-term risk indicators such 120.6 trillion. Bank Indonesia (BI) finally
as the swap premium and covered inter- responded at around this time to the
est rate differentials declined during persistent increase in inflation since
2002. The one-month swap premium fell about March 2000 by tightening mon-
significantly from 16.7% at the end of etary policy (figure 3). Whereas base
2001 to 12.2% by the end of August 2002, money growth of around 20% p.a. had
suggesting that market players were be- been the norm since mid 2000, the
coming less concerned about weakening growth rate was far slower in 2002, and
of the rupiah in the near future. Likewise, was running at 7.5% year-on-year by
the covered interest rate differential (the September—having fallen to as low as
excess of the dollar interest rate over the 4.9% in August. In contrast with most
rupiah interest rate adjusted for the swap of the post-crisis period (Deuster 2002:
premium) narrowed from 0.83% to 0.50% 25), the volume of base money was well
during this period, suggesting a modest below LOI indicative targets after April
decline in market assessments of other 2002, amounting to Rp 123.9 trillion at
kinds of risk relating to Indonesia. the end of September, whereas the in-
Stock Market. The rebound on the dicative target was Rp 128.2 trillion.
Jakarta Stock Exchange since late 2001 Inflation. Inflationary pressure re-
peaked in April 2002 (figure 2). Al- ceded significantly after February (fig-
though this partly reflected the general ure 3), with the year-on-year rate falling
upward trend as global and regional from 15.1% to 10.5% in September;
share prices recovered after the terror- prices were virtually constant during
ist attacks on the US on 11 September, March and April, and subsequent
the surge in Indonesian share prices was monthly increases have been relatively
especially strong, with a gain of 33% in small. While many commentators seek-
local currency terms and 60% in dollar ing to explain changes in inflation look
values (ADB 2002). Presumably this was to seasonal factors, wage and salary in-
partly attributable to renewed investor creases, exchange rate changes and in-
interest in Indonesian shares as politi- creases in administered prices for
cal uncertainties receded. Share prices commodities such as fuel, it is hard to
began to slide back in May, however, ignore the fact that base money growth
and by September most of the rupiah was far lower in 2002 than in 2001.
gains since the end of 2001 had been Interest Rates. The second quarter of
wiped out; nonetheless, given rupiah 2002 saw a continuation of the decline
Survey of Recent Developments 283

FIGURE 3 Base Money Growth, Inflation and Interest Rates


(% p.a.)
25

20

15

10

-5
Jan-00 Jul-00 Jan-01 Jul-01 Jan-02 Jul-02

Base money growth Inflation


Interbank 1-month Interbank real

Source: CEIC Asia Database.

in nominal interest rates that had been flation—appears to be largely unrespon-


apparent since January (figure 3). The sive to the conduct of monetary policy,
nominal 3-month SBI (Bank Indonesia having remained fairly consistent at
Certificate) rate (not shown) fell by 3.3 around 4–5% p.a. since late 2000. 6 Ar-
percentage points during the period guably it is real rather than nominal
January–September. 5 Bank lending rates rates that are of most fundamental con-
dropped relatively little during this pe- cern to economic actors.7
riod, but average deposit rates fell some-
what more, resulting in a much needed Balance of Payments
increase in the banks’ net lending mar- Although total exports stabilised in Q1
gins. The declining interest rate trend 2002, non-oil and gas exports and total
reflects the impact on expectations of imports both declined slightly, continu-
falling inflation and rupiah appreciation ing the slide that began in Q3 2000
over this period: that is, nominal rates (table 2). The trade balance increased
adjusted downwards as expectations of marginally over the previous quarter, as
inflation and depreciation were revised did the current account surplus. The capi-
to lower levels. It is interesting to note tal account was still in deficit in Q1 2002,
that the real interest rate—represented reflecting a continued and significant net
in figure 3 by the 1-month interbank call outflow of private capital; net official
rate adjusted for contemporaneous in- capital inflow also remained negative.
284 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

TABLE 2 Balance of Payments


($ billion)

2000 2001 2002


Total Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Total Q1

Exports 65.41 15.40 15.00 14.23 12.73 57.36 12.74


Non-oil & gas 50.34 11.62 11.67 11.31 10.20 44.81 10.12
Oil & gas 15.07 3.78 3.33 2.92 2.53 12.56 2.62
Oil 7.95 2.08 1.95 1.55 1.35 6.92 1.42
LNG & LPG 7.11 1.71 1.38 1.37 1.18 5.64 1.20
Imports –40.37 –9.22 –9.51 –8.59 –7.35 –34.67 –7.20
Merchandise trade
balance 25.04 6.18 5.49 5.64 5.38 22.69 5.54
Services –17.05 –4.12 –4.15 –3.28 –4.24 –15.80 –4.26
Current account 7.99 2.06 1.34 2.36 1.14 6.90 1.28
Official capital 3.22 –0.14 –0.24 –0.20 –0.17 –0.74 –0.35
Inflows 7.49 1.40 1.16 1.40 1.79 5.74 1.36
CGI 2.42 0.53 0.41 0.38 0.65 1.96 0.35
Non-CGI 5.07 0.87 0.75 1.02 1.14 3.78 1.01
Debt repayments –4.27 –1.53 –1.40 –1.59 –1.95 –6.48 –1.71
Private capital –9.99 –3.11 –2.47 –2.50 –0.18 –8.25 –1.08
Direct investment –4.55 –2.24 –1.90 –1.11 –0.62 –5.88 –2.24
Other –5.44 –0.87 –0.57 –1.39 0.45 –2.38 1.16
Capital account –6.77 –3.25 –2.71 –2.70 –0.34 –8.99 –1.42
Overall balance 5.04 –0.72 –0.04 0.32 –0.94 –1.38 –0.01
Capital & current
account, net 1.22 –1.19 –1.37 –0.34 0.80 –2.09 –0.14
Errors & omissions 3.82 0.46 1.33 0.66 –1.74 0.71 0.13

Source: Bank Indonesia, http://www.bi.go.id.

The net outflow of private capital in the investor interest in the Jakarta Stock Ex-
form of direct investment was as high change, and IBRA (Indonesian Bank Re-
in Q1 2002 as in any quarter since the structuring Agency) asset sales (CSIS
start of the crisis, providing a strong in- 2002). Note, however, that these balance
dication that investor confidence in of payments data are by now quite old;
Indonesia’s prospects, far from improv- the recent figures from the stock ex-
ing, has continued to weaken. change discussed above suggest that the
There was, however, a significant in- desire to invest in Indonesian stocks has
crease in other private capital flow (i.e. declined significantly in recent months.
portfolio investment), which had been
positive since Q4 2001. The factors un- THE FISCAL SITUATION
derlying this surge in portfolio invest- The 2002 Budget
ment are difficult to ascertain, but may At the time of writing, the budget for
include the return of Indonesian citi- 2002 appeared to be reasonably well on
zens’ savings from offshore accounts as track. Tax revenue for January–August
political conditions stabilised, renewed was 58.4% of the budgeted amount for
Survey of Recent Developments 285

the year, suggesting that the overall tar- amounts from privatisation (Rp 6.5 tril-
get is within reach—even though re- lion) and asset sales (Rp 35.3 trillion)
vised GDP growth estimates of 3.2–3.8% than suggested by table 3. Assuming the
for 2002 are a little lower than the bud- deficit comes in on target, this would
get assumption of 4% (table 3). The 9% permit some net redemption of govern-
inflation rate assumed in the budget was ment bonds outstanding.
well within reach at its September level
of 10.5%. Rupiah appreciation had not The Draft 2003 Budget
been sufficient at the time of writing to The 2003 draft budget presented by
achieve the average exchange rate of President Megawati to parliament in
Rp 9,000/$ assumed in the budget, but August 2002—surprisingly far in ad-
the actual outcome should not be far vance of the start of the fiscal year in
away from this.8 The decline in SBI in- January 2003, and thus running the risk
terest rates reduced interest payments of being overtaken within the next few
on the government’s domestic debt, but months by unforeseen events such as the
it was not until September that the Bali bomb attacks—was based on three
3-month SBI rate fell to 14%—the aver- broad objectives: consolidating the bud-
age rate assumed in the budget. Thus in get, stimulating the economy, and
the absence of debt rescheduling, debt achieving fiscal sustainability. The bud-
interest outlays can be expected to ex- get deficit was targeted at 1.3% of GDP,
ceed budgeted levels. On the other hand, significantly lower than for 2002. Its key
the assumed average oil price of $22/ economic assumptions (table 3) were
barrel will be exceeded, as oil has risen that:
dramatically in price since March: it was • GDP growth would increase to 5%
$28/barrel in August, and with the (by comparison with the 3.2–3.8% now
threat of war in Iraq there was the pros- expected in 2002);
pect of even further increases in the near • inflation would fall to 8% from its
future. Oil production is expected to August 2002 level of 10% (a surpris-
average 1.2 million barrels/day, some- ingly unambitious target, given the
what less than the budget assumption ease with which the rate had already
of 1.3 million barrels/day, but the im- been reduced from over 15% in Feb-
pact of this on oil revenue will be more ruary);
than offset by the higher price. • the 3-month SBI interest rate would
The planned budget deficit of 2.5% of fall to 13% from its August level of
GDP is believed to be within reach, 14.9%;
thanks to the increase in oil prices and • the average exchange rate would be
to the rescheduling of some interest pay- Rp 8,700/$, roughly the same as its
ments falling due in 2002 as agreed in August level;
the Paris Club negotiations in April. Fi- • oil production would remain
nancing of the deficit relies heavily on around its average 2002 level of 1.2
privatisation and IBRA asset sales. Pri- million barrels/day; and
vatisation proceeds and IBRA asset sales • the oil price would fall to $20.50/bar-
for the first half of 2002 were Rp 2.1 tril- rel from the $28/barrel figure recorded
lion and Rp 23.1 trillion respectively, in August (seemingly highly conser-
already well in excess of the aggregate vative, but the difficulty of predicting
Rp 23.5 trillion required from these world oil prices probably justifies such
sources to finance the deficit. The gov- an approach—even if the level of pre-
ernment actually hopes to obtain greater cision here is spurious).
286 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

TABLE 3 Budgets for 2002 and 2003


(Rp trillion)

2002 2003 Real


Change
Revised % of % of Approved % of % of (%)a
Total GDP Total GDP

TOTAL REVENUE 301.9 100.0 17.6 327.8 100.0 16.8 0.5


Tax revenue 219.6 72.7 12.8 260.8 79.5 13.3 10.0
Domestic taxes 207.0 68.6 12.1 246.5 75.2 12.6 10.3
Income tax 104.5 34.6 6.1 124.7 38.0 6.4 10.5
(of which non-oil & gas) (88.8) (29.4) (5.2) (112.2) (34.2) (5.7) (16.9)
Value added tax 70.1 23.2 4.1 82.1 25.1 0.5 8.5
Land & building taxes 8.1 2.7 0.5 9.9 3.0 1.5 18.6
Excise & other 24.4 8.1 1.4 29.8 9.1 6.2 13.2
International trade taxes 12.6 4.2 0.7 14.3 4.3 0.7 4.8
Non-tax revenue 82.3 27.3 4.8 67.0 20.5 3.4 –24.6
Natural resources 63.2 20.9 3.7 49.6 15.1 2.5 –27.4
Profit transfers from SOEs 10.4 3.4 0.6 8.5 2.6 0.4 –24.2
Other non-tax revenues 8.7 2.9 0.5 9.0 2.7 0.5 –4.5

TOTAL EXPENDITURE 344.0 100.0 20.1 354.2 100.0 18.1 –4.7


Central government expenditure 246.1 71.5 14.3 241.0 68.0 12.3 –9.3
Routine expenditure 193.8 56.3 11.3 186.5 52.6 9.5 –10.9
Personnel 41.3 12.0 2.4 51.9 14.7 2.7 16.4
Goods & services 12.9 3.8 0.8 15.4 4.3 0.8 10.4
Interest payments 88.5 25.7 5.2 80.9 22.8 4.1 –15.4
Domestic debt 59.5 17.3 3.5 55.1 15.6 2.8 –14.3
Foreign debt 29.0 8.4 1.7 25.8 7.3 1.3 –17.6
Subsidies 41.6 12.1 2.4 25.4 7.2 1.3 –43.5
Fuel 30.4 8.8 1.8 13.6 3.8 0.7 –58.6
Non-fuel 11.2 3.3 0.7 11.8 3.3 0.6 –2.4
Other 9.5 2.8 0.6 12.8 3.6 0.7 25.2
Development expenditure 52.3 15.2 3.0 54.5 15.4 2.8 –3.5
Rupiah financing 26.5 7.7 1.5 36.2 10.2 1.9 26.6
Project financing 25.8 7.5 1.5 18.3 5.2 0.9 –34.4

Funding of regional governments 97.9 28.5 5.7 113.2 32.0 5.8 7.1
Equalisation funds 94.5 27.5 5.5 103.6 29.2 5.3 1.5
Revenue sharing 24.6 7.2 1.4 25.9 7.3 1.3 –2.7
General allocation fund (DAU) 69.1 20.1 4.0 75.4 21.3 3.9 1.1
Specific allocation fund (DAK) 0.8 0.2 0.0 2.3 0.7 0.1 169.0
Special autonomy funds 3.4 1.0 0.2 9.6 2.7 0.5 162.1

OVERALL BALANCE –42.1 –12.2 –2.5 –26.3 –7.4 –1.3 –42.1


Survey of Recent Developments 287

TABLE 3 (continued) Budgets for 2002 and 2003


(Rp trillion)

2002 2003 Real


Change
Revised % of % of Approved % of % of (%)a
Total GDP Total GDP

FINANCING 42.1 100.0 2.5 26.3 100.0 1.3 –42.1


Domestic financing 23.5 55.9 1.4 16.9 64.3 0.9 –33.4
Use of bank deposits 0.0 0.0 0.0 8.5 32.3 0.4
Other 23.5 55.9 1.4 8.4 31.9 0.4 –66.9
Privatisation 4.0 9.5 0.2 8.0 30.4 0.4 85.2
Asset sales 19.5 46.4 1.1 12.0 45.6 0.6 –43.0
Government bonds (net) 0.0 0.0 0.0 –11.6 –44.1 –0.6
Foreign financing (net) 18.6 44.1 1.1 9.4 35.7 0.5 –53.1
Foreign financing (gross) 35.4 84.1 2.1 26.1 99.2 1.3 –31.7
Program loans b 9.5 22.7 0.6 7.8 29.7 0.4 –24.2
Project loans 25.8 61.4 1.5 18.3 69.6 0.9 –34.4
Debt payment –16.8 –39.9 –1.0 –16.7 –63.5 –0.9 –8.0
Maturity –44.0 –104.6 –2.6 –42.8 –162.7 –2.2 –9.9
Rescheduling 27.2 64.7 1.6 26.1 99.2 1.3 –11.2
Principal 20.1 47.8 1.2 19.8 75.3 1.0 –8.8
Interest 7.1 16.9 0.4 6.3 24.0 0.3 –17.8

ASSUMPTIONS
GDP growth (%) 4.0 5.0
Inflation rate (%) 9.0 8.0
Interest rate (3-month SBI, %) 14.0 13.0
Exchange rate (Rp/$) 9,000 8,700
Oil production (mbcd)c 1.3 1.2
Oil price ($/barrel) 22.0 20.5

a
Change in 2003 relative to 2002, % in real terms.
b
In the revised 2002 budget, program loans were merged with Paris Club III rescheduling
of Rp 36.8 trillion, because at the time the budget was formulated the amount of debt
rescheduled was not yet clear.
c
Million barrels of crude oil per day.

Source: Republic of Indonesia, Nota Keuangan dan Rancangan Anggaran Pendapatan dan Belanja
Negara 2003 [Financial Notes and Draft State Budget 2003].
288 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

The assumption of 5% GDP growth by 50%. This reduction is made possible


was perceived to be reasonable, if some- by a further major cut (39%, or 44% in
what optimistic. It relied, for example, real terms) in subsidies—most notably
on assumptions of investment and ex- on fuel prices—and by reduced debt ser-
port growth in excess of 6% and 5% re- vicing costs. Fuel subsidies are to be
spectively, which would represent a slashed to Rp 13.6 trillion, down from
considerable improvement on 2002. 9 The Rp 30.4 trillion in 2002, while electricity
blow to investor confidence and to tour- tariffs will be raised on average by 6%
ism exports resulting from the Bali each quarter. Some non-fuel subsidies
bombings makes it highly unlikely that will be retained, however, including the
these growth rates will be achieved. The fertiliser subsidy, food subsidies for
targeted deficit of 1.3% of GDP has been poverty alleviation, and interest subsi-
criticised by some as failing to provide dies in certain lending programs; the
an adequate stimulus to economic re- total amount involved is Rp 11.8 trillion.
covery, but this view assumes that the The cost of foreign debt servicing is ex-
continued existence of unused produc- pected to decline as a result of both the
tion capacity results simply from a lack Paris Club rescheduling and rupiah ap-
of aggregate demand—ignoring such preciation. At the same time, the domes-
crucial matters as the enormous prob- tic debt servicing cost is projected to fall
lem of widespread corporate defaults, with declines in the SBI interest rate, and
the continued ill health of the banking as a result of some redemptions of the
system, the lack of strong leadership and government’s bank recapitalisation
consistent policy making on the part of bonds.
the government, and the ever more ob- Development expenditure is also ex-
vious inadequacies of the legal system. pected to decline in real terms and as a
The planned reduction of the deficit at percentage of GDP. There is a projected
least signals the government’s intention shift in development spending toward
to consolidate its position and put the greater reliance on rupiah financing and
budget on a more sustainable path. correspondingly less on project (aid) fi-
Revenue is expected to increase by nancing. The decline in development
8.5% from the budgeted amount in 2002, spending must be interpreted carefully,
which would amount to a negligible in light of structural changes to the bud-
change in real terms: hence the projected get resulting from the decentralisation
slight decline in revenue relative to of public services to local government
GDP. Most of the increase is to be gen- level: total funding of local government
erated from individual and corporate accounts for about 30% of the central
income tax, value added tax and the ex- government budget. Nevertheless,
cise on cigarette sales. Income tax rev- funding of local government through
enue increases are to be achieved by the equalisation process is to increase
extending coverage of persons and firms only by about 1.5% in real terms.
that have thus far evaded their obliga- Roughly two-thirds (Rp 16.9 trillion)
tions as tax payers. of the deficit financing requirement is to
Central government expenditure is be met from domestic sources, the re-
projected to decline significantly by vir- mainder from net new foreign borrow-
tue of a large cut in routine expendi- ing. The target for privatisation proceeds
ture—despite plans to increase salaries is Rp 8 trillion—twice the budgeted
of civil servants, police and military per- amount in 2002—which seems very op-
sonnel by 10% and teachers’ allowances timistic considering the slow progress so
Survey of Recent Developments 289

far on this front. IBRA asset sales are ex- the government has been concentrating
pected to bring in another Rp 12 trillion. on lengthening the maturity structure
Whether IBRA can meet this target re- of some of the existing bonds so as to
mains to be seen, since it has limited as- push principal repayments further into
sets for disposal after recent large sales. the future. Agreement has been reached
If these figures (and all the other budget with the four state-owned banks (Bank
items) were to be realised, the govern- Mandiri, Bank BNI, Bank Rakyat Indo-
ment would be able to redeem some nesia and Bank Tabungan Negara) to
Rp 11.6 trillion of existing bank recapi- ‘re-profile’ some Rp 175 trillion of their
talisation bonds. Provided any shortfall holdings of government bonds (table 4).
in privatisation and asset sales does not The maturity dates of fixed rate bonds,
exceed this amount in aggregate, the bud- originally between 2004 and 2009, are
get deficit for 2003 can still be financed, now to be extended to between 2010
but correspondingly smaller amounts of and 2013 (Kompas, 21/9/02), while
bonds will be able to be redeemed. those of variable rate bonds are to be
extended from between 2004 and 2009
The Burden of Government Debt to between 2014 and 2020. Despite a
As of September 2002, total government perception to the contrary on the part
domestic debt outstanding was Rp 656 of some observers, the debt re-profil-
trillion. The bulk of it (Rp 427 trillion) ing exercise has not involved any
comprised bonds issued to recapitalise switching of bonds from fixed to vari-
banks that became insolvent during the able interest rates. Since the interest
banking sector crisis of 1997/98, while rates on these bonds are below market
additional bonds worth Rp 218 trillion levels (McLeod 2000: 27–9) the banks
were issued to Bank Indonesia in settle- that hold them are effectively subsidis-
ment of liquidity support provided to ing the government, and the size of the
troubled banks during the course of the subsidy increases with any extension of
crisis. 10 Interest payments on these the maturity structure. Presumably for
bonds are now imposing a heavy bur- this reason, the agreement provides for
den on the budget: in 2002, for example, additional interest payments to the four
about Rp 59.5 trillion, or 20% of total banks amounting to a total of Rp 824
revenue, is accounted for by interest billion each year until 2010 in return for
payments on domestic debt. On the ba- delaying the repayment of principal
sis of the maturity structure of these (Kompas, 21/9/02).
bonds as originally issued, principal re- Besides domestic debt, the total
payments begin to become significant in amount of government external debt
2003, but jump to a much higher level outstanding was $73.5 billion (as of July
in 2004 and continue to increase in each 2002), and the cash outflows associated
of the next three years (Deuster 2002: 31). with this also constitute a heavy drain
This would imply much greater annual on budgetary resources. In the 2002
debt service burdens than in 2002; in budget, total principal and interest
2004, for example, principal and inter- originally due on this debt was
est payments together would exceed Rp 43.9 trillion, but the government has
Rp 100 trillion. reduced the actual amount to Rp 16.7
One response to this cash flow prob- trillion by negotiating through the Paris
lem is to roll over the bonds as they Club the rescheduling of some Rp 20.2
mature (i.e. to issue replacement bonds) trillion of principal and Rp 7.1 trillion
as in the budget for 2002, 11 but recently of interest falling due this year.
290 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

TABLE 4 Domestic Government Debt Reprofiling


(Rp trillion)

Bank Rate Total Reprofiled Unchanged

Mandiri Fixed 47.0 34.8 12.3


Variable 89.9 69.6 20.3
Total 137.0 104.4 32.6
BNI Fixed 33.1 24.7 8.5
Variable 19.3 16.2 3.1
Total 52.4 40.8 11.6
BRI Fixed 22.0 16.8 5.2
Variable 6.5 3.6 2.9
Total 28.5 20.4 8.1
BTN Fixed 1.2 0.0 1.2
Variable 12.6 9.0 3.6
Total 13.7 9.0 4.7
Total fixed 103.3 76.2 27.1
Total variable 128.4 98.4 30.0
Grand total 231.6 174.6 57.0

Source: Ministry of Finance, cited in Kompas, 21/9/02.

Of course rescheduling foreign debt Various measures are available for re-
and lengthening the maturity profile of ducing the total amount of bonds out-
bonds issued domestically does nothing standing, such as selling assets to finance
more than ease the government’s cur- the redemption of bonds, and allowing
rent cash flow difficulties—in effect, recapitalised banks to swap bonds for
shifting the burden of dealing with the assets (such as bank loans) now held by
amortisation of these borrowings to fu- IBRA.13 Little is gained by such measures,
ture governments. Thus an even greater as they all involve the loss of revenues
problem will arise with the 2004 bud- generated by the assets in question, leav-
get, for example. ing the budget deficit largely unchanged.
There does not appear to be an easy An alternative approach involving the
solution to the budget debt servicing use of accumulated budget surpluses
problem. In the absence of any other (sisa anggaran lebih) held as deposits at
new source of financing, and given lim- BI to redeem bonds would have the ef-
its on the extent to which spending can fect of expanding base money, and it
be reduced further, external financing would be necessary for BI to sterilise the
and rescheduling of existing debt is still inflationary impact by issuing new SBIs;
a possibility in the near future.12 In the given that BI is part of the public sector,
medium term, however, the important total public sector debt would therefore
question is whether the government will be unchanged. This latter observation is
continue to be able to persuade its ex- also relevant to a recent agreement on the
ternal creditors to delay the repayment sharing of banking crisis costs by the gov-
of its borrowings. ernment and BI (box 1).14
Survey of Recent Developments 291

BOX 1 SMOKE AND MIRRORS: SHARING THE COST OF THE BANKING C RISIS?
Much was made recently of a new agreement (still to be ratified by the DPR
at the time of writing) regarding some Rp 218 trillion in bonds issued by the
government to BI to compensate the latter for last-resort loans it extended to
troubled banks at the height of the financial crisis (Bantuan Likuiditas Bank
Indonesia, BLBI), most of which have not been repaid (Kenward 2002: 22–3).
The purpose of this agreement was to create the impression that the cost of
these defaults was now to be shared between the government and BI, rather
than being carried by the government alone (in implicit recognition of BI’s
failure to exercise sufficient care in providing these loans in the first place).
This was to be effected by transforming some Rp 159 trillion of these bonds
into ‘Capital Maintenance Notes’ (CMNs) that have no maturity date and
pay no interest (i.e. into zero interest consols).a
Clearly these new instruments are worthless, since their present value
(calculated by discounting their nominal amounts over an infinitely long
period of time at any positive interest rate) is zero. That being the case, the
effect is to ‘charge’ BI an amount of Rp 159 trillion for its presumed incom-
petence as lender of last resort; apparently this is sufficient to satisfy those
on the government side who wish to see BI carry some of the cost of what
they see as its past mistakes. By carrying the CMNs at their face value rather
than their true value, however, BI will be spared the embarrassment of rec-
ognising this loss and writing down the value of its equity commensurately
in its financial statements.
The agreement also requires, however, that these CMNs be redeemed by
the government over time by means of forgoing dividends that would oth-
erwise accrue to it from BI’s operating profits. Thus if BI were to make a
profit of Rp 159 trillion this year it could notionally pay this amount to the
government as a dividend, whereupon the government could notionally
use this revenue to redeem all the outstanding CMNs. BI would still be
saved from the need to recognise a loss of Rp 159 trillion on its lending
activities, by being able to portray this transaction as a dividend payment.
At the other extreme, if it failed ever to earn any profit in the future, it would
simply continue to carry Rp 159 trillion of CMNs in its balance sheet indefi-
nitely, again avoiding the need for any embarrassing financial disclosures.
All of this financial ‘smoke-and-mirrors’ is of little or no consequence to
the government’s financial position or to economic recovery. Both BI and
the government are part of the public sector, and changing the terms of the
financial transactions between them has no impact on the financial position
of the public sector overall: any gain to one side is matched by an equal loss
to the other. There is an intangible cost, however, in the form of yet another
setback to the ideal of encouraging transparency in the public sector.
a
This formalises what has been actual practice: to date the government has not paid
any interest on its debt to BI.
292 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

FIGURE 4 Motor Car, Motor Cycle and Cement Sales


(January 2002 = 100)
150

125

100

75

50 Motor cars
Motor cycles
Cement
25

0
Jan-01 Apr-01 Jul-01 Oct-01 Jan-02 Apr-02 Jul-02

Source: PEG–Bappenas, Real Sector Indicators (unpublished data).

THE REAL SECTOR: Nevertheless, even though the value of


TRADE AND INVESTMENT domestic approvals plunged 70% over
Although growth had been expected to the same period, the downward trends
remain strong for the rest of 2002, inter- in total gross fixed capital formation
national developments and the fallout and import of capital goods seem to
from the Bali tragedy now cast doubt on have bottomed out in the December
this prognosis, and even more so for quarter. Growth in the domestic com-
growth targets and macroeconomic sta- ponent of fixed capital formation also
bility in 2003. Domestic consumption remained positive in each quarter since
was not as robust in the first half of 2002 mid 2001. Additionally, reports from BI
as 12 months ago. Key indicators ce- of an increase in credit from the bank-
ment, motor car and motor cycle sales ing sector and of some 51% of all new
increased in this period, but were still credit going to small and medium en-
barely above figures recorded in the first terprises (SMEs) through to May 2002
half of last year, following a deep trough (Kompas, 18/7/02) offer further hope
around puasa and lebaran (the fasting for continued recovery in 2002, al-
month and the holiday following it) in though the potential disincentive for
late 2001 (figure 4). the banks to lend to SMEs following
Investment signals were mixed. For- official approval for a haircut on past
eign investment approvals remained loans is not encouraging. 15
low in the first half of 2002. Both the Exports recovered somewhat in 2002
number of projects (506) and the value after a bumpy last two quarters in 2001.
of investment approvals (just over $2.5 Although they were some 7% lower
billion) were significantly down com- overall (and 3% in the case of non-oil
pared with the same period in 2001. and gas exports) in the first half of 2002
Survey of Recent Developments 293

FIGURE 5 Value of Oil and Non-oil Exports


($ billion)
6

3
Total
Non-oil
2 Oil

0
Jan-01 Jul-01 Jan-02 Jul-02

Source: BPS (Central Statistics Agency), Indikator Ekonomi, various issues.

than in the same period in 2001, they wear industry was facing major prob-
had bounced back following the steep lems as Nike and Reebok closed facto-
decline in the second half of 2001, when ries in Indonesia in the first half of 2002
orders fell off sharply in response to the (FEER, 12/9/02: 47–9). Furniture and
11 September attacks and associated timber sales also declined in this pe-
political unrest in Indonesia. Overall, riod, and were some 10% below the
non-oil and gas exports rose by 3.6% in previous quarter.
the first half of 2002 compared with the The appreciation of the exchange rate
second half of the previous year, with in the first two quarters of 2002 prob-
machinery and appliances registering ably played some role in the slowdown
particularly robust growth (figure 5 in these exports, although regulated in-
and table 5). 16 creases in labour costs were now squeez-
Nevertheless, the trend in several ing key labour-intensive industries (see
labour-intensive exports that had below). Further, firm surveys found that
played a key role in job expansion non-labour costs of special concern to
before the crisis was particularly wor- exporters included the high luxury tax
rying. Garments had not recovered fol- on imported goods, especially electron-
lowing the sharp (15% ) decline in ics, the high cost and inefficiency of port
exports in the second half of 2001. Com- services, the ban imposed on bonded
petition from China was already begin- warehouses for the purchase of locally
ning to hurt the textile and garment made materials, and delays in rebates
industries, with lower unit labour costs to exporters through Bintek (Badan
resulting from higher productivity rela- Informasi dan Teknologi Keuangan, the
tive to wage rates in Chinese industry Financial Information and Technology
(James, Ray and Minor 2002). The foot- Agency).17
294 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

TABLE 5 Principal Non-oil Exports, 2001 and 2002


($ million)

Product and 2001 2002 2002 S1


SITC Code Compared with:
S1 S2 S1 2001 S1 2001 S2
(% ) (% )

Machine/electricity equipment (85) 3,198 2,716 2,976 –6.9 9.6


Timber, timber products (44) 1,649 1,705 1,531 –7.2 –10.2
Machinery/mechanical machinery (84) 1,422 1,303 1,496 5.2 14.8
Garments (excl. knitted ware) (62) 1,511 1,272 1,297 –14.2 2.0
Appliances/household lighting (94) 775 676 849 9.5 25.6
Synthetic filaments (54) 585 571 533 –8.9 –6.7
Organic chemicals (29) 488 538 528 8.2 –1.9
Man-made staple fibres (55) 468 414 456 –2.6 10.1
Cotton (52) 390 354 340 –12.8 –4.0
Copper (74) 199 221 210 5.5 –5.0
Subtotal 10,685 9,770 10,216 –4.4 4.6
Other 11,670 11,229 11,529 –1.2 2.7
Total 22,355 20,999 21,745 –2.7 3.6

Source: BPS (adapted from CSIS 2002).

Smuggling and Trade Restrictions At the same time, a raft of regulations


Reports of widespread smuggling con- have been introduced in an attempt to
tinued to dominate public discussion of limit smuggling and overcome prob-
trade policy in the first half of 2002. Fol- lems of under-invoicing of imports.
lowing the furore over a smuggled con- Over 3,800 importers in eight key sec-
signment of luxury cars earlier in the tors have been registered with the trade
year, extensive smuggling of electron- and industry ministry, which threatened
ics products and used clothing contin- to withdraw licences for non-reporting.
ued to receive media attention (JP, The customs service announced in Oc-
18/7/02). This revived once again the tober that 10 large, reputable importers
debate over whether Indonesia should would receive favourable treatment
reintroduce a Pre-Shipment Inspection from the service (Kompas, 2/10/01).
Authority (PSI). 18 Both trade and indus- Many of the reforms to agricultural
try minister Rini Suwandi and IMF rep- trade outlined in the initial MOU
resentatives have spoken in favour of (memorandum of understanding) with
reintroduction of PSI and they have the IMF in 1998 are being dismantled.
received strong support from some pro- Import of some commodities for domes-
ducer groups. Finance minister Boedi- tic processing, notably cloves and raw
ono has been more cautious, arguing sugar, has been restricted to registered
that the reintroduction of PSI will only domestic producers. The Ministry of
delay long overdue reforms to the cus- Trade and Industry appointed three
toms service. state plantations as registered sugar
Survey of Recent Developments 295

importers, setting a minimum price to farmer interests, most notably a


(Rp 3,100) well above the current fob 5–20% export tax on cocoa, a move
price at which they can bring in sugar strongly criticised by the Executive Di-
(JP, 24/9/02). 19 Some key items such as rector of the Indonesian Cocoa Associa-
rice and wheat flour have been moved tion (Askindo) (JP, 12/10/02).
from the ‘green’ to the more intrusive Tariffs on Rice. There has been con-
‘red’ customs lane for special attention siderable controversy over the effects of
on the part of officials, causing major projected increases in the rice tariff. The
delays and some cancellation of import supporters of greater protection argue
consignments. that Indonesia is merely adapting to
As reported in the previous survey what is a very uneven playing field in
(Athukorala 2000: 157–8), calls for in- agricultural trade. On the other hand,
creased agricultural protection have critics of a more interventionist ap-
been associated with complaints that proach have pointed out that Indonesian
local producers can no longer compete rice prices are now already significantly
with lower than normal international above world prices, thus artificially dis-
prices of some commodities (sugar and torting incentives in favour of rice
cloves in particular). 20 Low (5%) anti- against potentially more profitable
dumping duties were proposed by the crops, farm and non-farm activities
Ministry of Industry and Trade on (Bappenas et al. 2002; Timmer 2002).
wheat flour in July, despite earlier as- They also argue that higher rice prices
surances from the minister that there tend to hurt rather than help the poor,
was no case against dumping in this in- most of whom are net consumers of rice.
dustry. A much stronger push for new The special rice subsidy (OPK), recently
tariffs on key agricultural commodities increased in value to a smaller number
(rice, sugar, corn and soy bean) was of households, tends to cushion the im-
made by the agriculture minister, pact of higher prices on the poor, al-
Bungaran Saragih (Kompas, 11/6/02). though it has been estimated that only
He formed a team to investigate tariffs around half receive relatively meagre
on these commodities in late June. In support. However, a further increase in
September, he announced a proposed the tariff will reduce benefits from the
increase in the tariff on rice from Rp 430 subsidy.
to Rp 753/kg to accompany an increase Critics of the push towards more
in the farmers’ floor price of around protection in rice also draw two impor-
15%, from Rp 1,519 to Rp 1,745/kg of tant contrasts with the early period
unhusked rice (gabah).21 when Bulog held a monopoly over the
The Ministry of Agriculture has also import of rice. In the period of heavy
recommended a fertiliser subsidy of Bulog intervention in the 1980s and
Rp 1.2–1.5 trillion, which is projected 1990s, domestic prices tracked interna-
to reduce urea and other fertiliser prices tional prices quite closely in a volatile
by some 15–20%, and the Ministry of world rice market. Currently, all indi-
Trade and Industry has banned a re- cations are that world prices will re-
ported small increase in price by the main low for some time, with higher
state-owned producer, PN Pusri levels of per capita production in many
(Kompas, 9/10/02). Other regulations countries. Major exporters (Vietnam
proposed by the trade and industry and Thailand) hold large stocks of rice,
ministry are also potentially damaging and countries like India also play a role
296 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

in the international trade from time to be the conflict between the entrenched
time. Secondly, insofar as rice produc- interests of the sugar mill lobby and
ers were protected in earlier periods, those of both consumers and potential
the trade-off was substantial gains in producers of agro-processed commodi-
production through the rice intensifi- ties, who use sugar as an input. As agri-
cation and extensification programs, cultural researchers have long pointed
which are unlikely to be repeated. out, increased protection of sugar and
While few would deny that in- sugar factories is likely to be at the ex-
creased protection of rice farmers is pense of many rice sector farmers (and
likely to slow the longer-term transfer workers) on Java, who thrive under
of farmers into higher value added similar agronomic conditions.
crops, the impact of increased protec- Nevertheless, on the positive side,
tion on the poor appears to be less prior to this year the government had
clearcut. A CGE (Computable General moved cautiously on agricultural pro-
Equilibrium) model to simulate the ef- tection, despite quite intense lobbying
fects on the poor of an increase in the from farmer groups and from some re-
tariff from 25% to 45% found that gions. The Ministry of Trade and Indus-
higher tariffs do increase the incidence try strongly rejected the East Java
of poverty (Warr 2002). But the impact attempt to impose an import ban for that
was quite small. The results imply that province in early July, and it appears
the effects on the poor alone are not that after a month of experimenting with
enough to drop proposals for greater such a ban the East Java governor was
protection. The analysis predicts that having second thoughts on whether this
the main beneficiaries of the policy are was an effective policy to raise farmgate
likely to be farm labouring households, rice prices (Bisnis Indonesia, 9/7/02 and
through more employment and higher 8/8/02). The Minister of Finance is said
wages from increased production. The to have rejected proposals for an anti-
net positive impact on poverty occurs dumping tariff on wheat flour. There
mainly because these households have have not been strong signs of a grow-
the highest incidence of poverty among in g protectionist mood spr ead ing
socio-economic groups identified in the from agriculture to other areas of the
model. economy (despite pressures from pro-
These results are a welcome reminder ducers and sections of the DPR), al-
that the distributional impact and ad- though a recent proposal for a tariff on
justment costs of market-oriented poli- garments is a worrying development.
cies are not always clearcut, despite
potential longer-term economic benefits. Failing Infrastructure?
The proponents of reform must do more The Case of Electricity Supply23
than merely assert that poverty allevia- One major obstacle to new investment
tion is served by less protection if they and increased production has been the
are to convince a sceptical public, and slowdown in construction of new infra-
gullible politicians, that the interests of structure and the maintenance of exist-
well organised producer groups are nec- ing road, port, telecommunications and
essarily against those of the poor in pub- electricity networks. Fortunately, the
lic policy.22 country had invested heavily in physi-
The longer-term costs of more protec- cal infrastructure during the Soeharto
tion would seem much higher in the case era, and hence existing networks were
of sugar. The main issue still appears to better placed than in many countries
Survey of Recent Developments 297

suffering economic crises (e.g. Eastern of the electricity production process,


Europe or the Philippines in the 1980s much of which would almost certainly
and 1990s). have to come from overseas private
Five years on the cracks are beginning sources. Because of uncertainty, large in-
to appear, owing to a lack of public and vestors will probably require a sover-
private investment. This was vividly eign, not a PLN, guarantee (after having
brought home to national capital resi- had their fingers burnt from unpaid
dents and businesses when Jakarta and debts arising out of the rupiah depre-
surrounding areas suffered a five-hour ciation of 1998–99); the government is
total blackout on Thursday, 12 Septem- loath to offer such guarantees, given
ber (McBeth 2002). The immediate cause the precedent it would set for other
of the blackout was a break in nearby public–private sector deals. Gas may be
transmission lines. But the underlying an option in the medium term. But even
problem relates to funding cutbacks and here, the country will need large invest-
financial difficulties suffered by the State ments, and a capacity to deal with asso-
Electricity Company, PLN, in the wake ciated legal and security issues.
of the crisis.
The main challenge appears to be LABOUR POLICY:
medium term rather than immediate. REGULATION OUT OF CONTROL
For the present, the power needs of the Labour policy issues remained in the
country are being met by a combination spotlight in the latter half of 2002, in
of public and private (captive) suppli- the context of layoffs in key labour-
ers, with some two-thirds of total capa- intensive industries, discussed above,
city (33,000 megawatts) being supplied and associated fears of mountin g
by the public sector. Moreover, the gov- unemployment. 24 Three interrelated
ernment has moved to raise electricity policy issues dominated public discus-
prices from the highly subsidised levels sion: (i) the employment impact of large
of the past, and recently passed a new increases in minimum wages in Janu-
law paving the way for privatisation of ary; (ii) opposition from employers and
PLN by 2007, allowing greater flexibil- unions to the drafts of two new acts
ity in pricing and investment. (A short- (undang-undang) regulating labour pro-
term effect was the release of urgently tection and the settlement of industrial
needed aid for power.) Current capacity disputes; and (iii) labour unrest, espe-
still seems capable of coping with cur- cially associated with layoffs in the
rent demand—although there are some modern sector. There remains a funda-
tricky transmission issues to be dealt mental disconnect between the advo-
with—and there remains a breathing cacy of labour rights campaigners, on
space to increase generation, transmis- the one hand, and the complaints of
sion and distribution if investments (and business groups about labour regula-
decisions) are forthcoming in the imme- tion and unrest on the other. The former
diate future. fail to address the argument that labour
Nevertheless, the country will need regulation jeopardises employment,
around 2,000 megawatts of new gener- while the employers’ case is not helped
ating capacity per annum if investment by often exaggerated claims about the
picks up and the country begins to meet impact of some regulations, such as
economic growth targets of 5% or more. multiple unionism at the plant level,
New investment needs would then be and the disruption caused by a more
around $2 billion per annum in all stages militant union movement.
298 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

The flight of capital from labour- clearly suggest otherwise (JP, 31/8/02).
intensive industries has been high- Although probably overstating the case,
lighted by the exit of foreign investors the footwear manufacturer and associa-
(especially Koreans) and domestic firms tion head, Anton Supit, reports that
from the garments and footwear indus- some 200,000 workers lost jobs in the in-
tries. During the June visit of his foreign dustry over the past two years (AWSJ,
minister, Badawi, the Malaysian ambas- 13/8/02). It is a similar story in gar-
sador also announced that Indonesia ments. Great River, one of the country’s
was pricing itself out of export-oriented largest exporters, reportedly shed some
labour-intensive industries. The Korean 5,000 of its 15,000 workers in the past
Chamber of Commerce reported that 36 two years.
companies in garments, footwear and In the five years 1996–2001, at a time
toy making had closed down in the pre- of increasing strains in the labour mar-
vious 12 months (JP, 23/8/02). Even ket, small and cottage firms absorbed
though the number of workers affected almost 80% of employment growth in
is still a small proportion of the 500,000 manufacturing. In contrast, the number
reported to be employed in Korean of jobs in large and medium firms grew
companies, the closure of several high hardly at all, after increasing at slightly
profile Nike and Reebok contractors re- less than 10% per annum and account-
sulted in labour protests. ing for more than half the new jobs
Once the largest exporter of Nike created in the sector in the decade
footwear in the world, with 38% of the 1986–96. 25
market in 1996, Indonesia has now
slipped behind China, and many inves- Minimum Wages: Employment
tors have set up in Vietnam, whose share Considerations on the Back Burner
of exports of Nike products rose from The Korean Chamber of Commerce re-
2% in 1996 to 16% in 2001–02 (Dhume ported four labour-related problems in
and Tkacik 2002). Nike and Reebok have Indonesia (JP, 23/8/02): ‘irrational’
been at pains to stress that they are com- wage policies (minimum wages and ex-
mitted to Indonesia, yet their actions cessive overtime premiums); low labour

FIGURE 6a Real Minimum Wages in Major FIGURE 6b Minimum Wages in Major


Industrial Centres, 1992–2002 Industrial Centres in Dollar Terms, 1992–2002
(Rp, 1996 prices) ($, current prices)
250 70

60
200
50
150 40

100 30

Jakarta 20 Jakarta
50 Bandung Bandung
Surabaya 10
Surabaya
0 0
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 1992 1995 1998 2001

Sources: Unpublished data, Ministry of Manpower and Transmigration; BPS, Indikator


Kesejahteraan Buruh [Labour Welfare Indicators], various issues.
Survey of Recent Developments 299

productivity; strikes; and poor law en- gotiation, to have increased nationwide
forcement. The term ‘irrational’ presum- by around twice the CPI (consumer price
ably refers to regulated wages having index) over the past two years (table 6). 26
risen by nearly 40% (25% in real terms) Despite the reports of business stress,
in the Greater Region of Jakarta and in there was every indication that some
Surabaya in the past two years. Al- provinces were planning to raise mini-
though they had fallen precipitously mum wages by similar amounts in 2003.
during the crisis along with average The Jakarta (Special Capital Region,
wages, real minimum wages (MW) in DKI) government had already decided
major industrial areas had returned to to expand the basic needs index from 43
10–30% above pre-crisis levels in real to 55 items, including the purchase of a
rupiah terms, and in 2002 were close to range of consumer durables, seen as
pre-crisis levels in dollar terms at an needs ‘fitting’ (layak) for the consump-
exchange rate of Rp 9000/$ (figures 6a tion standards of Jakarta workers.27 The
and 6b). Indonesia’s competitive advan- DKI Wages Council came up with a fig-
tage from the crisis-induced deprecia- ure of Rp 700,000 as the value of the
tion had largely been eroded. KHM in October 2002, to be used as a
The term ‘irrational’ might also have standard for minimum wage increases,
been used to describe adjustments based implying, potentially, a rise of 18% in
on a measure of basic needs, the mini- January 2003 (Kompas, 11/10/02). The
mum physical needs index or KHM association of employers, Apindo, has
(Kebutuhan Hidup Minimum). On av- argued for no increase in the present
erage, the needs index has, implausibly, difficult economic circumstances, a sug-
been estimated by provincial wage gestion met by a not so gentle reminder
councils, often through a process of ne- from the Minister of Manpower, and

TABLE 6 Nominal Values and Estimates of the Real Value of Minimum Wages, 1996–2002

Nominal Value of Minimum Index Real Minimum


Minimum KHM Wage as % (1998 = 100) Wage
Wage of KHM (1998 Prices)
(Rp ‘000) (Rp ‘000 KHM a CPIb Deflated by
per month) a KHM CPI

Apr-96 122 132 0.92 0.52 0.48 234 257


Jan-99 180 253 0.71 1.00 1.00 180 180
Jan-00 225 266 0.85 1.05 1.02 214 220
Jan-01 307 343 0.90 1.36 1.12 226 275
Jan-02 363 422 0.86 1.67 1.26 218 289

a
The minimum wage each year takes into account estimates of the KHM (minimum physical
needs) index in October–December of the preceding year, and estimated changes in the
KHM in the preceding 12 months. The estimates of the national KHM are unweighted
averages of the provincial KHM estimates.
b
Index of the CPI for December in the preceding year.

Source: Ministry of Manpower and Transmigration, unpublished data, and BPS, Indikator
Hidup Pekerja, various issues.
300 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

head of the largest union, that a freeze (with unions arguing that the new draft
on nominal wages ‘could’ result in in- law offers less protection than the old
dustrial action. 1964 law), changes to the wording of
Compliance with MW had increased severance pay conditions, 28 and condi-
considerably by 2000 in large and me- tions governing the right to strike.29 Op-
dium firms, establishing the minimum position to the sister Settlement of
as the standard entry-level wage for Labour Disputes Act arises mainly
new, less skilled workers (SMERU 2001). from the proposed replacement of the
However, MW also feed into overtime present labour disputes councils with
rates, already generous by international a labour court (to be staffed by one
standards, and the cost of severance pay, regular and two ad hoc judges at dis-
which had been increased and broad- trict level) which unions argue would
ened to cover a wider range of workers put them at a disadvantage in disputes
through the controversial Ministerial vis-à-vis wealthier employers.
Decree 150 passed in 2000 (Dick 2001: Employers, for their part, were most
29). Rising wage costs have contributed opposed to proposed clauses that allow
not only to significant job losses in the payments for striking workers (breaking
modern sector but also to a widening with the internationally accepted prin-
wage gap between the protected and ciple of ‘no work, no pay’); prescribe three
unprotected wage sectors, and to crowd- months long-service leave; and prohibit
ing and lower earnings in the informal night work for pregnant women.
sector (SMERU 2001; Bird and Manning In part, over-regulation and, implic-
2002). itly, rent seeking by the ministry con-
tribute to conflicts between the unions
Labour Legislation: and employers. Further, most of the
Still an Unfinished Agenda 60-plus new unions have an interest in
The Korean Chamber of Commerce opposing acts proposed by a man-
complaints about legal uncertainty (JP, power minister who is still head of the
23/8/02) relate primarily to the unre- largest union, SPSI (Serikat Pekerja
conciled tug-of-war between workers Seluruh Indonesia), their major com-
and employers over new labour legisla- petitor, and the only registered union
tion. As a result of this conflict, the pass- for private sector workers for most of
ing of two proposed labour acts (a the New Order period. More funda-
combined version of which was shelved mentally, there is widespread belief
in 1998) has been repeatedly delayed. among unions and civil society groups
Seemingly close to a final reading in the that it is now labour’s turn to gain a
DPR, the passing of both acts was post- fairer share of the pie.
poned yet again at the end of Septem- Few commentators have been pre-
ber (JP, 28/9/02). pared to face up to the genuine dilemma
The extraordinarily detailed Labour of how to extend labour protection while
Protection Act, drafted by the Ministry at the same time encouraging employ-
of Manpower and Transmigration, cov- ment. Simplistic interventions by some
ers severance pay, minimum wage influential commentators have not
regulation, training, collective bargain- helped to clarify the potential costs of
ing and a raft of labour conditions. labour regulation.30 The Minister of
Union opposition relates to articles on Trade and Industry, Rini Suwandi, has
employment of contract workers, insuf- publicly drawn attention to the poten-
ficient protection against dismissal tial costs of labour unrest over the new
Survey of Recent Developments 301

labour acts and minimum wages (JP, of departure and return for migrants in
7/7/02; 24/8/02). But, while the gov- East Malaysia, where the number of
ernment has stressed the importance of stranded returning migrants is reported
employment for welfare and social sta- to have swelled to 30,000 in early Sep-
bility, there has been little evidence of tember.34
efforts to reconcile the pursuit of this Because of this crisis, the Malaysian
objective with the costs to employers of government extended the amnesty, and
increasing labour regulation. in mid August it repealed the ban on
hiring new Indonesian workers owing
Migrant Labour to labour shortages on many construc-
The management of migrant workers tion projects in the vicinity of Kuala
emerged as a major national issue with Lumpur, including work on the new
the forced repatriation from Malaysia national capital at Putrajaya (FEER,
of some 400, 000 illegal Indonesian 12/9/02).
workers beginning early in 2002, cul- The crisis on Nunukan, and especially
minating in a minor crisis as migrants the clause in the new Malaysian law re-
flooded exit points to Indonesia in lated to caning of offenders, brought
July–September. 31 Illegal labour migra- strong reactions from Indonesian lead-
tion has been spurred by large wage ers (JP, 30/8/02). In late August anti-
differentials between the two countries Malaysian demonstrations erupted in
(which widened with the large rupiah Jakarta, Malaysian visitors were de-
depreciation during the economic cri- tained in North Sumatra and the Malay-
sis), combined with the Malaysian sian government advised its citizens not
policy of long turning a blind eye to il- to travel to Indonesia.
legal immigration as it sought cheap The labour market effect of return
labour in declining industries, con- migration has not been as large as is of-
struction and services.32 ten claimed, because the total number
Why did the migrant worker crisis of some 400,000 return migrants (by late
occur? Following a series of half-hearted September), many with considerable
crackdowns in the 1990s, the Malaysian savings, is still equivalent to only
government announced a ban on the around 5% of all unemployed. How-
hire of any new Indonesian workers, ever, it is likely to be significant in ma-
and the planned reduction of the num- jor sending areas in Eastern Indonesia,
ber of legally approved workers by 50% where the loss of income from remit-
in early 2002. 33 In March, it announced tances will probably have a large indi-
an amnesty to facilitate the repatriation rect effect on incomes.
of illegal workers by a 31 July deadline. Unfortunately, it seems unlikely that
A new law provided for up to six-month improvements will occur in the admin-
gaol terms for illegal workers and their istrative framework, given the speed of
employers, including the possibility of the Malaysian government’s reversal of
caning (cambuk) and a potential fine of its original ban, and the seeming inabil-
up to RM 10,000. ity of the Indonesian government to de-
By the deadline, only around 250,000 velop a clear policy response. Many
illegal migrants were reported to have private organisations, including now
returned to Indonesia (Kompas 31/7/02; over 400 officially approved recruiting
7/8/02; 10/9/02) , and a migrant– agents, and numerous government of-
refugee crisis emerged on the island of ficials in the Ministry of Manpower and
Nunukan in East Kalimantan, the point the immigration service, have long stood
302 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

to gain from rents earned from the place- disposal of IBRA-controlled assets. The
ment of workers abroad.35 A former retiring Head of the World Bank Mis-
head of the Labour Recruiting Agency sion, Mark Baird, in noting that cor-
Association (Apjati) argued that if Indo- ruption was now more harmful to
nesia wanted to clean up the labour mi- development than in the past, listed
gration process the government would five daunting medium-term challenges:
need to ‘replace the entire Ministry of to improve tax and customs adminis-
Manpower and Transmigration admin- tration; to achieve a better balance in
istration involved with overseas work- labour policies; to contain the prolifera-
ers’ (Kompas, 23/9/02). tion of regulations in the regions; to
Noting widespread reports of collu- speed up asset sales and privatisation;
sion between officials and labour re- and to improve the regulatory frame-
cruiting agencies to profit from labour work for investment, especially in in-
migration, human rights observers have frastructure (JP, 5/9/02).
recommended that Indonesia establish In challenging the sceptics, a more
an independent body to administer all optimistic view would give the present
aspects of the process, as in the Philip- administration credit for providing
pines. At the same time, however, the greater political stability, essential for
current high degree of regulation of re- renewed and sustained investment. It
cruiting, departure and placement will would note that President Megawati has
need significant reassessment if mi- backed her finance minister in pursuing
grants are to be protected from rent seek- reforms to get the budget back on track
ers on both sides of the border. and restore macroeconomic stability,
and in rejecting an early exit from the
PROGNOSIS IMF special support program. Despite
As Indonesia moves closer to the gen- accusations of being a centralist at heart
eral election in 2004, the government and too close to the military, she has re-
faces a major challenge to stall back- affirmed her support for the major re-
tracking on key reforms and to sustain forms of the previous post-Soeharto
newly gained macroeconomic balance governments, especially decentralisa -
in the wake of the Bali bombings and tion and the special autonomy laws for
predicted political unrest over the fall- Papua and Aceh, and has overseen the
out from Bali. Will Indonesia now settle important constitutional amendments at
into a ‘Philippines’ pattern, with an ex- the August MPR meeting.
tended period of slow and unsteady In the light of the Bali tragedy, the first
economic growth and small improve- hurdle is surely to maintain macro-
ment in living standards? Or, despite economic stability and resist mounting
sometimes messy and unpredictable pressures for special privileges and pro-
political outcomes, can it return to the tection, with an eye to realising a cred-
‘East Asian’ model of rapid economic, ible economic growth rate for 2003. The
employment and productivity growth, pattern of growth also matters: it should
and sustained improvements in living support many more ‘better’ jobs, to con-
standards? tribute to rising living standards, and
Sceptics, probably in the majority, greater resolve is surely needed in
point to the absence of strong leader- microeconomic areas such as trade and
ship in providing backing for reform, labour policy to achieve such an out-
privatisation, bank restructuring and come.
Survey of Recent Developments 303

NOTES
* Chris Manning was employed with the 12 Another option that has captured atten-
Partnership for Economic Growth (PEG) tion recently is the proposal to issue Trea-
– Bappenas (USAID) at the time of writ- sury bills (‘T-bills’) with short maturities.
ing. He wishes to thank colleagues at This would achieve nothing, however,
PEG for support in preparing the Survey. other than to put a new label on a por-
1 See The Van Zorge Report, 2–9 September tion of the government’s debt. Debt is
2002 (including a long interview with debt, regardless of whether it is called
Jacob Tobing, the Head of the Ad Hoc bonds, borrowings or T-bills.
Drafting Committee). 13 In the case of asset for bond swaps, it is
2 The role of the DPD, essentially, will be unclear why this method would be pre-
to review the basic legislative framework ferred to open auctions of IBRA’s loan
of regional government and consider portfolio. The danger of nego tiated
budget issues for the regions. swaps is that the implicit prices of the
3 An unsuccessful PDI-P (Indonesian bonds and assets in question will be dis-
Democratic Party of Struggle) candidate torted away from true market values in
reported to the press on the day after the a manner that is not transparent to the
election that he had paid Rp 200 million general public.
($22,200) each to 40 councillors. 14 The government also holds deposits with
4 The December figures are heavily dis- commercial banks, the average amount
torted by seasonal factors. of which roughly doubled between 1999
5 The interbank rate shown in figure 3 and 2001 to around Rp 40 trillion. These
closely tracks the policy determined SBI could be run down significantly without
rate. increasing base money, but the scope for
6 The temporary dip in the first half of 2002 this is small in comparison with the vol-
would appear to reflect the delay in ad- ume of bonds outstanding.
justment of inflationary expectations to 15 The details of a limited haircut approved
the tightening of monetary policy that in a presidential decree in late July are to
occurred around the beginning of 2002. be worked out jointly by the Minister of
7 It is clear from figure 3 that BI puts most Finance and the Minister of State Enter-
emphasis on controlling nominal inter- prises for SMEs.
est rates rather than money growth, even 16 Growth in exports tapered off in July and
though all the LOIs to the IMF contain August 2002, however, falling by 3.5%
money growth targets but not interest from their June level, largely as a result
rate targets. of slower growth in non-oil and gas
8 At the time of writing it was too soon to exports.
tell whether the bombing outrage in Bali 17 Based on a report on visits by PEG–
would significantly affect the average Bappenas consultants to large export
exchange rate for calendar year 2002. companies in the first half of 2002. One
9 A Ministry of Finance analysis breaks major electronics manufacturer reported
down the 5% target growth for 2003 into that close to 100% of all more advanced
the following components: private con- technology goods destined for the do-
sumption, 6.38%; government consump- mestic market (eg. DVDs, VCDs, cell
tion, 7.07%; investment, 6.24%; exports, phones and higher quality consumer
5.38%; and imports 10.86%. durables) were being smuggled into the
10 See Deuster (2002) for details of total ex- country, often by major exporters.
ternal and domestic debt and the matu- 18 See Athukorala (2002: 146) on the earlier
rity profile of domestic debt outstanding. PSI system.
11 The 2002 budget allowed for bond re- 19 The Minister of Agriculture favours sub-
demptions amounting to Rp 3.9 trillion sidies rather than higher tariffs, arguing
to be financed by new issues in the same that they will provide greater assistance
amount. to farmers.
304 Armida S. Alisjahbana and Chris Manning

20 Thanks are due to valuable comments costs of high minimum wages. For ex-
from Steve Marks and Peter Rosner on ample, the ILO director in Jakarta re-
this issue. ceived front-page billing in the Jakarta
21 One proposal supported by Bulog is a Post (24/8/02), for gratuitously point-
quota–tariff scheme (Tabor, Sawit and ing out that labour problems were not the
Dillon 2002). ‘major’ problem for foreign investors.
22 Despite the CGE study’s value in exam- 31 The total number of migrant workers in
ining general equilibrium effects, the va- Malaysia was estimated at around two
lidity of assumptions on the importance million in early 2002, around 70% of
of rice consumption in budgets of the whom were Indonesians and 60% of
poor is unclear, and one might question these illegal. About two-thirds of Indo-
the low rate of substitutability between nesians worked in West Malaysia and a
imported and domestically consumed further one-third in East Malaysia, most
rice implied in the model. of the latter group being from Eastern In-
23 The authors are especially grateful to Pe- donesia.
ter McCawley for material on the elec- 32 Legal workers generally earned RM 500–
tricity industry. 1,000 (Rp 1.1–2.3 million) a month in
24 See especially The Van Zorge Report, 14–21 early 2002, 3–5 times what many could
August 2002: 4–16. earn in mostly uncertain jobs in Indo-
25 Based on data from the BPS industrial nesia, and illegal unskille d workers
surveys. earned around RM 300–600.
26 According to official guidelines, the 33 The introduction of the new policy was
KHM is only one of six factors to be taken followed by migrant worker riots after a
into account in adju sting minimum raid on a factory and the arrest of 16 In-
wages, yet the other five are largely ne- donesian workers in January–February
glected in the calculation. 2002.
27 In fact, owing to disagreements among 34 Over 3,000 people were reported to be
the parties on price increases, the Jakarta suffering health problems and 64 deaths
government side-stepped the issue of had been reported to the end of August,
determining the KHM in 2001 for wage around one-third as many as died in the
adjustments in 2002, and instead used an Bali bombings.
estimate of per capita income to set mini- 35 Migration is highly regulated, permitting
mum wages in January 2002. rents to be extracted from the companies
28 The new severance pay regulations (re- and the authorities at various stages: re-
flected in articles 145–166 in the act) not cruiting companies hav e to obtain
only increased the level of payments to employment orders from overseas com-
some workers but also explicitly set these panies, and then recruit potential work-
payments as a ‘minimum’, contributing ers, prepare and equip them, and arrange
to claims for higher severance pay. for their travel to overseas destinations.
29 See especially reports in JP, 7/7/02; and In most cases, the companies make an
Kompas 8/8/02; 9/9/02. advance to the workers (of Rp 3–6 million
30 Chatib Basri and Moh. Ikhsa n (JP, or RM 1,500–2,500), to be deducted later
15/8/02; Kompas, 8/8/02) have been al- from their wages. All contracts are re-
most lone voices drawing attention to the newable after two years.
Survey of Recent Developments 305

REFERENCES
ADB (Asian Development Bank) (2002), Asia Kenw ard, Lloyd R. (2002) , Kemana
Economic Monitor: July 2002 Update, Manila. Indonesia’s Financial Sector?, Partnership
Athukorala, Prema-chandra (2002), ‘Survey for Economic Growth – Bappenas, Jakarta,
of Recent Developments’, Bulletin of Indo- July (mimeo).
nesian Economic Studies 38 (2): 141–62. LPEM–FEUI (Lembaga Penyelidikan Eko-
Bank Indonesia (2002), Monthly Report: Eco- nomi dan Masyarakat Fakultas Ekonomi
nomic, Monetary and Banking, Jakarta, Universit as Indonesia) (2002), Macro-
June (mimeo). economic Review, August.
Bappenas, Ministry of Agriculture, USAID McBeth, J. (2002), ‘Electricity: Indonesia
and DAI Food Policy Advisory Team Blacks Out’, Far Eastern Economic Review,
(2002), ‘An Approach to Macro Food 3 October: 56–9.
Policy’, Working Paper No. 4, DAI Jakarta. McLeod, Ross H. (2000), ‘Survey of Recent
Bird, K., and C. Manning (2002), The Impact Developments’, Bulletin of Indonesian Eco-
of Minimum Wages on Employment and nomic Studies 36 (2): 5–41.
Earnings in the Informal Sector, Paper Pang estu, Mari, and Miranda Swaray
presented at the 8th East Asian Economic Goeltom (2001), ‘Survey of Recent Devel-
Association Conference, Kuala Lumpur, opments’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic
November. Studies 37 (2): 141–71.
CSIS (Centre for Strategic and International SMERU (Social Monitoring and Early Re-
Studies) (2002), Economic and Political sponse Unit) (2001), Wage and Employ-
Developments in Indonesia, Jakarta, Sep- ment Effects of Minimum Wage Policy in
tember (mimeo). the Indonesian Urban Labor Market, Re-
Deuster, Paul R (2002), ‘Survey of Recent search Report, Jakarta.
Developments’, Bulletin of Indonesian Eco- Tabor, S.R., M. Husein Sawit and H.S. Dillon
nomic Studies 38 (1): 5–37. (2002), Indonesian Rice Policy and the
Dhume, S., and M. Tkacik (2002), ‘Just Quit Choice of a Trade Regime for Rice in In-
It’, Far Eastern Economic Review, 12 Sep- donesia, Paper presented at the Workshop
tember: 47–9. ‘Kebijakan Pengelolaan Impor Beras dan
Dick, H.W. (2001), ‘Survey of Recent Devel- Pilihan Regim Perdagangan di Indonesia’
opments’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic [Rice Import Management Policy and the
Studies 37 (1): 7–41. Choice of a Trade Regime in Indonesia],
DRI (Danareksa Research Institute) (2002), Bulog, Jakarta, 11 March.
Quarterly Report, Jakar ta, August Timmer, C.P. (2002), Food Security and Rice
(mimeo). Policy in Indonesia: The Economics and
James, W.E., D.J. Ray and P.J. Minor (2002), Politics of the Food Price Dilemma, Un-
‘Indonesia’s Textile and Apparel Indus- published paper, Graduate School of In-
try: Meeting the Challenges of the Chang- ternational Relations and Pacific Studies,
ing International Trade Environment ’, University of San Diego, California, La
Working Paper Series 2002–20, August, Jolla CA.
International Center for the Study of East Warr, P. (2002), Poverty and Food Policy in
Asian Development, Kitakyushu. Indonesia, Draft report, SMERU, Jakarta.

You might also like