Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

European Management Journal Vol. 17, No. 6, pp.

645–654, 1999
Pergamon  1999 Published by Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
PII: S0263-2373(99)00055-9 0263-2373/99 $20.00

A Conceptual Framework
for Understanding the
Outsourcing Decision
AIDAN VINING, Simon Fraser University, Vancouver
STEVEN GLOBERMAN, Western Washington University, USA

Outsourcing is an increasingly important initiative


being pursued by corporations in North America
and Europe in pursuit of improved efficiency. This
paper provides a conceptual framework to assist
managers in identifying and implementing out-
sourcing decisions. In particular, the framework
suggests a way for managers to identify the pre-
and post-contractual risks associated with outsourc-
ing decisions along with strategies that can be
implemented in the pre-contractual stage in order
to mitigate those risks. Empirical findings from the
‘transactions cost’ literature are referenced to illus-
trate elements of our conceptual framework.  1999
Published by Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights
reserved

Introduction

Firms as diverse as Nike, Sun Microsystems, Mattel,


Calvin Klein and DuPont now engage in extensive
outsourcing. Outsourcing has grown rapidly during
the 1990s (Bryce and Useem, 1998). Some firms out-
source the core of their primary activities on the
value chain so extensively that they do not engage in
‘production’ as it has been traditionally understood
(Tisdale, 1994; Tempest, 1996). Other firms, in con-
trast, are extensively outsourcing
secondary activities of their
value chains, such as infor-
mation technology, account-
ing systems and distribution
(Cross, 1995; Johnson and
Schneider, 1995; Lacity
and Willcocks, 1998).1 Yet
many firms appear to
have only a vague
understanding as to the
risks and benefits of

European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999 645


A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING THE OUTSOURCING DECISION

outsourcing, apart from a general idea that it will assess ex ante the potential governance costs that arise
save resources and allow them to focus on core com- with outsourcing? How, and under what circum-
petencies (Smith et al., 1998). stances, can governance costs be reduced? The frame-
work identifies alternative instruments that are more
The implicit rationale for any form of outsourcing or less effective depending upon the relevant circum-
strategy is that ‘vertical integration is the organiza- stances, and provides a basis for meaningfully cate-
tion form not of first but of last resort — to be gorizing them.4
adopted when all else fails. Try markets, try long-
term contracts and other hybrid modes, and revert to
hierarchy only for compelling reasons’ (Williamson,
1991, p. 75). Yet extensive or intensive outsourcing The Costs of Outsourcing
involves significant risks that must be managed. An
outsourcing firm is inevitably placing at least part of Three types of costs are relevant in the choice
its destiny in the hands of other firms that are seeking between internal production and outsourcing: pro-
to maximize their profits. Thus, in spite of the fact duction costs, bargaining costs, and opportunism
that outsourcing is often described as a ‘strategic costs, with the latter two being costs of governance.
alliance’, the parties to the outsourcing contract have Production costs are either the costs of internal pro-
potentially conflicting interests (Lacity and duction or the direct purchase price. Bargaining costs
Hirschheim, 1995)2. In order to outsource intelli- include the following kinds of costs: (1) costs arising
gently the firm must know both the benefits and risks from negotiating contract details per se; (2) the costs
of outsourcing and the specific determinants of con- of negotiating changes to the contract in the post-con-
flict. But to fundamentally understand those risks tract stage when unforeseen circumstances arise; (3)
and benefits, the firm must have a clear conceptual the costs of monitoring whether performance is being
framework of the outsourcing decision. adhered to by the other party, and (4) the costs of
disputes which arise if neither party wishes to utilize
The paper proceeds as follows: first, we present an pre-agreed-to resolution mechanisms, especially
efficiency framework for assessing outsourcing costs ‘contract breaking’ mechanisms. While only the first
and benefits from the firm’s perspective; second, we bargaining cost is experienced at the time of con-
identify the specific costs associated with outsourc- tracting (the others are experienced subsequent to
ing; third, we delineate three major determinants of outsourcing), virtually all of these bargaining costs
outsourcing costs: product/activity complexity, con- can be anticipated and dealt with at the time of con-
testability and asset specificity; fourth, we present tracting.
four archetypal outsourcing situations and suggest
appropriate strategies for each; fifth, we present con- Bargaining costs arise when both parties are acting
clusions. with self-interest, but in good faith (Williamson,
1985). The incremental bargaining costs of outsourc-
ing are relevant because an advantage of ‘internaliz-
ing’ the activity is that the distribution of costs across
An Efficiency Perspective on the corporation do not need to be bargained. How-
ever, bargaining within organizations — for example
Outsourcing over wages, bonuses or internal transfer prices — can
also be costly (Miller, 1992; Alles et al., 1998); thus it
A firm must confront several issues, if outsourcing is is incremental bargaining costs of outsourcing that
to save resources. First, the purpose of outsourcing are relevant (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972).
must be clear; second, a framework must be
developed, and third, it must be shown that such a ‘Opportunism’ is any behavior by a party to a trans-
framework can be applied to a real (and potentially action designed to change the agreed terms of a
complex) firm’s outsourcing problems. The strategic transaction to be more in its favor. Opportunism
objective of outsourcing decisionmakers should be to costs arise when at least one party acts self-interest-
minimize the total costs of ‘receiving’ any given edly, but in bad faith. Opportunism is more likely in
quantity and quality of outsourced good or activity. outsourcing contexts than in transactions within
Costs, in turn, consist of expenditures for good itself organizations, since the distribution of profit is more
and the costs associated with ‘governing’ the out- relevant in dealings between organizations.
sourcing transaction. The evidence suggests that Additionally, employees within organizations have
there is often (but not always) potential for outsourc- better and more numerous opportunities to ‘pay
ing to lower the purchase price of the good (by taking back’ (and, therefore, discourage) opportunistic fel-
advantage of contractees’ lower costs, to be discussed low employees (Axelrod, 1984). Opportunism, how-
below). However, these direct purchase savings may ever, can also occur within organizations (Alles et al.,
be more than offset by increases in governance costs.3 1998). Therefore, again it is incremental opportunism
costs, which are relevant. Opportunism is usually
The major purpose here is to suggest a framework to considered to be more likely after the outsourcing
address two fundamental issues: How can the firm contract has taken place, but some behaviors prior to

646 European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999


A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING THE OUTSOURCING DECISION

contracting also have ‘opportunism-like’ character- created by production unit managers (Reichelstein,
istics (Klein et al., 1978). 1995). Second, because the production unit does not
have sufficient incentives to achieve minimum pro-
Although analytically it is possible to make a clear duction costs that are technically feasible and allows
distinction between bargaining and opportunism production costs to ‘drift’ upwards — this syndrome
costs, in practice, they are difficult to distinguish — can be caused by either managers or employees or both
it is almost always in the interest of opportunistic (Leibenstein, 1976; Button and Weyman-Jones, 1994).
suppliers to claim that their behavior results from an
unexpected change in circumstances (i.e. Market competition is normally the crucial driver in
uncertainty). Frequently, the outsourcing firm cannot forcing down production costs to their lowest level.
tell whether this claim is genuine or not. The inability Profit-maximizing firms in a competitive market will
to distinguish between legitimate bargaining and be forced to price at the lowest possible marginal
opportunism itself raises outsourcing costs cost, thus eliminating inefficient practices. Internal
(Akerlof, 1970). production units are not normally subject to this
same level of competition. (Although firms can simu-
Production costs are directly generated by the late such competition by forcing different internal
opportunity costs of the resources — land, labor and units to bid against each other for production rights.)
capital — actually used to produce the good. Pro- This rationale for outsourcing is probably now a
duction costs may be lower with outsourcing for a more important reason for outsourcing than mini-
number of reasons. mum efficient scale issues, especially for larger,
bureaucratized (and unionized) firms.
First, in-house production of the good or activity
often entails production at too low levels to be Third, firms can experience diseconomies of scope in
efficient; that is, to achieve minimum efficient scale management of multiple firm activities or disecon-
(McFetridge and Smith, 1998; Lyons, 1995). Many omies of scale in producing a single activity (Graves
goods and services for which the organization has and Langowitz, 1993; Zanger, 1994). If this is the case
low unit demand exhibit significant cost ‘lumpiness’, they may wish to concentrate on core competencies
holding quality constant (Loh and Venkatraman, and outsource other activities (Prahalad and Hamel,
1992; McFarlan and Nolan, 1995). An independent 1990; Cross, 1995; McFarlan and Nolan, 1995).
producer selling to multiple (outsourcing) buyers can
achieve quality-adjusted minimum efficient scale. Fourth, internal production of an input may generate
significant organizational negative externalities (or
The firm should conceive production costs broadly more accurately ‘internalities’, as they are internal to
and dynamically — the most significant economies the organization) that can be reduced or eliminated
of scale may be in intangible factors such as adminis- by outsourcing. (Conversely, as discussed below,
trative and information systems, knowledge and outsourcing can also generate negative externalities
learning, access to capital markets and marketing for the outsourcing firm.) Internal production of an
(Muris et al., 1992). For example, a major rationale for input, for example, may require a distinct corporate
the significant degree of outsourcing of information culture that is dysfunctional for the rest of the organi-
systems is the inability of firms to achieve minimum zation (Camerer and Vepsalainen, 1988).
efficient scale in either installing, updating or manag-
ing these systems (McLellan, 1993). There is evidence from a variety of sources that out-
sourcing can lower production costs. However, rela-
Of course, it is impossible to design firms to take tively little of this empirical evidence comes from
advantage of economies of scale for all inputs — contexts where firms outsource to other firms. It is
large pharmaceutical firms do not manufacture their difficult to measure production cost savings (Bryce
own computers. Many inputs are inevitably out- and Useem, 1998). Certainly firms believe that out-
sourced. In practice, inputs that can be bought in sourcing can lower production costs. Ang (1998)
competitive ‘spot’ markets — ‘of-the-shelf’ pur- found that a large sample of banks that outsource
chases — raise few outsourcing issues. primarily considered production cost savings in their
decisions. There is some evidence to suggest that this
Second, there is a tendency for internal production finding is generalizable (Walker and Weber, 1987;
units to act like monopolists (Crozier, 1964; Alles et Lyons, 1995; Benson and Ieronimo, 1996; Saunders et
al., 1998). Monopoly blunts efficiency incentives in al., 1997). However, perhaps the best empirical evi-
two ways: first, it reduces comparative performance dence comes from outsourcing by government to
benchmarks for internal customers and, second, the private suppliers. Empirical studies tend to find in
good is less likely to be efficiently priced in the firm’s this outsourcing context that production cost savings
internal ‘market’, thereby obscuring the efficiency of are in the 20–30 per cent range, especially if competi-
the internal supply unit. Inefficient internal prices can tive bidding is used (Hensher, 1988; Walsh, 1991;
arise for two reasons. First, because the internal pro- Szymanski and Wilkins, 1993; Domberger and Hall,
duction unit is an efficient low cost producer, but 1996). A recent summary of outsourcing by the 66
prices monopolistically — this problem is usually largest cities in the US suggests that the annual cost

European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999 647


A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING THE OUTSOURCING DECISION

savings were between 16 and 20 per cent; respon- The degree of product/activity complexity largely
dents also estimated that outsourcing improved ser- determines: (1) the uncertainty surrounding the con-
vice quality by between 24 and 27 per cent (Dilger et tract (this effects both contracting parties equally)
al., 1997). which raises the probability that bounded rationality
will come into play (Williamson, 1985); (2) the poten-
However, studies that have examined the relative tial for information asymmetry (the probability that
production costs of internal provision versus out- one party to the contract will have information that
sourcing have not included bargaining and oppor- the other party does not have); and (3) the probability
tunism costs, which a priori might be expected to be that there will be externalities that will affect the
higher with outsourcing. Additionally, some forms of firm’s other activities. Complex goods involve uncer-
outsourcing can be expected to raise production tainty about the nature and costs of the production
costs, for example if cost-plus contracts are used process itself. They also face more environmental
(Spann, 1974; McAfee and McMillan, 1988; Ulset, uncertainty because complex goods are more likely
1996). to be affected by unforeseen changes in the task
environment (Van den Ven et al., 1989; Collingridge,
In summary, the firm should seek the regime that 1992). Greater uncertainty raises bargaining costs,
minimizes the sum of its production, bargaining and both during contract negotiations and post-contract.
opportunism costs. Ideally, strategic managers then
compare the estimated costs with the costs of intern- Information asymmetry occurs when one party has
alization, that is, the cost of the firm producing the relevant information that the other party does not.
good itself. While information asymmetry does not always raise
costs, usually it does, especially if a contract involves
post-experience goods. High task complexity raises
the probability that there will be information asym-
The Determinants of Outsourcing Costs metry, because it implies specialized knowledge or
assets whose characteristics are only initially known
to contractees or other experts. Information asym-
Three major factors are likely to determine the sum of metry, thus, raises the probability that a party to the
bargaining and opportunism costs: product/activity transaction can behave opportunistically. Opportun-
complexity, contestability, and asset specificity. We ism arising from information asymmetry can occur
discuss each of these in turn. either at the contract negotiation stage (typically
when there is information asymmetry and low
contestability) or at the post-contract stage, but is
Product/Activity Complexity most likely to be significant post-contract. Either con-
tractor or contractee may generate these costs.
Product (service) or activity complexity largely
defines the degree of difficulty in specifying and Higher task complexity also increases the potential
monitoring the terms and conditions of a transaction for production externalities, that is the potential for
(‘activity’ simply refers to outsourced inputs that can- serious disruption to the rest of the firm if the out-
not usefully be described as goods or services). sourced service is withdrawn or degraded
Goods, services or activities can be approximately (Globerman, 1995).
divided into search goods, experience goods and
post-experience goods (Vining and Weimer, 1988). A Thus, from the outsourcing firm’s standpoint,
good is a search good if its price-performance product/activity complexity raises costs both
(quality) characteristics are known before the ‘out- because there is substantial uncertainty surrounding
sourcing’ decision is made. Indeed, such decisions the transaction, and because contractees often have
are normally not even thought of as outsourcing — more information about attributes of the relevant
the purchase of ballpoint pens is simply purchasing transactions. The associated concern is that it may be
or procurement. A good is an experience good if its very difficult for contractors to ensure that the quality
price-performance characteristics are approximately of services provided is appropriately high. The
known almost immediately after purchase. For empirical evidence supports the idea that product
example, assessing the quality of food served by a complexity raises the probability of internalization.
contractee is relatively easy at the time of consump- Masten (1984), for example, found that more complex
tion. A good is a post-experience good if its price- components for the aerospace industry were more
performance characteristics cannot be assessed for a likely to be produced internally than to be out-
considerable time (if ever, when full revelation is sourced. Jensen and Rothwell (1998) found that
dependent on contingent events) after the outsourc- nuclear power plants were less likely to outsource
ing decision. Measuring the price-performance ‘production-critical’ activities that are complex and
characteristics of a complex good such as R&D is dif- where the quality is more difficult to assess before a
ficult (Ulset, 1996; Tapon and Cadsby, 1996). Unique problem occurs (see also Anderson and Schmittlein,
and/or new (to the outsourcing firm) goods are 1984; Anderson, 1985; Tapon and Cadsby, 1996;
almost always complex. Ulset, 1996).

648 European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999


A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING THE OUTSOURCING DECISION

Contestability are soliciting ‘unreasonably low’ bids and/or are


arbitrarily requiring rebids at lower-than-originally
A contestable market is one where only a few firms agreed to prices, a competitive market may not
are immediately available to provide any given ser- emerge. Similarly some outsourcing firms dampen
vice, but many other firms would quickly become competition by encouraging excessive specialization
available if the price paid by the outsourcing firm by suppliers. This reduces outsourcing firms’ switch-
exceeded the average cost incurred by contractees. ing capacity in the face of unsatisfactory perform-
For example, the markets for basic accounting and ance. Contractees will, in turn, incorporate the
payroll services are highly contestable as many firms increased risk in higher prices for their services. This
have the basic capabilities to supply such services, latter point underscores the need for firms to think
even if they are not currently doing so. The degree broadly about the cost consequences of specific out-
of contestability may, in some cases, be more sourcing strategies. Short-run cost savings, and even
important than the number of firms actually provid- improvements in quality, associated with economies
ing a given service (Baumol et al., 1982). of specialization, may be achieved at the expense of
higher long-run costs.
In some circumstances the market for the service in
question may be competitive — there may be a con- In contrast, in many cases it is possible for outsourc-
siderable number of firms in the relevant (usually ing firms to deliberately enhance competition by
geographic) market producing the service, or a very expanding the size of the relevant geographic market.
close substitute. In this case, potential entry by new This is certainly an important impetus for the explos-
suppliers may offer little additional discipline on the ive growth of cross-national outsourcing (Feenstra,
behavior of incumbent potential contractees. 1998). Such a strategy is less feasible if contestability
problems are not so much the result of sunk cost
The degree to which the activity being outsourced is investments, per se, but of the geographical specificity
contestable affects opportunism costs. If the market of the relevant assets.
for the activity is contestable, opportunism is reduced
at the contract stage and, potentially, at the post-con- Another potential approach to mitigating compe-
tract stage. Low contestability raises different issues tition problems is for the outsourcing firm to own the
in the contract and post-contract phases. During con- (sunk cost) assets and for contractees to own only
tract negotiations, a potential contractee in a market relatively fungible assets. Thus, the outsourcing firm
with limited contestability is tempted to offer services retains formal ownership of relatively specialized
at a price above marginal cost (or average cost in cir- and expensive equipment, which is leased to contrac-
cumstances where average cost is declining for the tees. In this way, the need for potential new suppliers
demanded good). This higher price can be thought to make large sunk-cost investments can be mitigated
of as a bargaining cost, because it is part of the out- and contestability enhanced.
sourcing ‘toll’.
Finally, contestability is also a function of the capa-
At the post-contract stage low contestability increases bility of the firm to bring the service back in-house
the risks of opportunism (and associated costs) facing (‘backsourcing’). In order to effectively outsource,
the other party for two reasons. First, because a con- firms must retain a ‘core’ employee capacity anyway.
tractee cannot be quickly replaced (temporal If this capacity can be readily expanded because there
specificity). Second, because there is a heightened are trained specialists available, the outsourcing firm
risk of ‘contract breach externalities’. This risk is can credibly threaten backsourcing. There is evidence
especially relevant when the contractee provides ser- that more firms are actually engaging in backsourc-
vices that are related to a network of some kind ing (Delaney, 1999).
within the outsourcing firm. For example, a con-
tractee firm carrying out payroll operations may thre- In sum, neither economies-of-scale or the need for
aten to withdraw service, jeopardizing the payment sunk-cost investments are the main barriers to con-
of all payroll paychecks. This could effectively shut testability. In particular, if either outsourcing firms or
down the firm. Contexts where firms fear breach contractees are mobile, small numbers of competitors
externalities are often defined as ‘strategic’ systems. need not eliminate competition. If they are not
However, firms do not eliminate these externality mobile, the problem is better evaluated as one of geo-
problems by producing the good or activity them- graphic asset specificity. Indeed, for the remainder
selves. As the FedEx strike graphically illustrated, of this paper, we assume that contestability can be
employees can also opportunistically hold-up achieved in all cases.
employers by withdrawing essential services (passive
breach) or by picketing and various forms of sab-
otage (active breach). Asset Specificity
The evidence suggests that some firms have uninten- An asset is ‘specific’ if it makes a necessary contri-
tionally contributed to contestability problems. If bution to the production of a good and it has much
potential suppliers perceive that outsourcing firms lower value in alternative uses (Klein et al., 1978).

European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999 649


A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING THE OUTSOURCING DECISION

There are various kinds of specificity including agers this advice may seem abstract, but recent evi-
physical asset specificity, location specificity, human dence from an extensive survey of information
asset specificity, dedicated assets (Williamson, 1985, technology outsourcing suggests that detailed con-
p. 55) and temporal specificity (Masten et al., 1991, tract specification is the leading predictor of out-
p. 9; Pirrong, 1993). Whatever the form of asset speci- sourcing firm satisfaction (Lacity and Willcocks,
ficity, the issue is basically the same: contracts which 1998).
require either party to employ assets (usually capital
assets, but in some circumstances human capital
assets) that have little or no alternative use, that is,
are ‘sunk’, raise the potential for opportunism. The Outsourcing Situations and Some
contracting party who commits assets is vulnerable Possible Strategies
to hold-up (Shelanski and Klein, 1995; Ulset, 1996).
No matter what prices are agreed to in the con-
tracting stage, the other party can behave opportun- We now apply the framework to various combi-
nations of product complexity and asset specificity
istically by reneging and offering lower prices that
only cover incremental costs.5 (remembering that contestability problems can be
treated as being ultimately co-extensive with asset
Extensive evidence suggests that asset specificity specificity problems). We consider possible combi-
nations of these two characteristics with the goal of
reduces the degree of outsourcing (e.g. Globerman,
1980; Monteverde and Teece, 1982; Stuckey, 1983; illustrating the conceptual framework rather than
providing a definitive guide to all outsourcing
Masten, 1984; Anderson and Schmittlein, 1984; And-
erson, 1985; Globerman and Schwindt, 1986; Hennart, issues.6
1988; Lieberman, 1991; Hallwood, 1990; Lyons, 1995;
Zaheer and Venkatraman, 1995; Jensen and Rothwell,
1998; Ang, 1998). Intermediate levels of asset speci- Low Product/Activity Complexity and Low Asset
ficity, when not leading to complete internalization, Specificity
lead to long-term exclusive contracts (e.g. Joskow,
1987; Goldberg and Erickson, 1987; Crocker and This combination provides the clearest case for out-
Masten, 1988; DeCanio and Frech, 1993; Pirrong, sourcing. It encompasses many standard products,
1993). services and activities required by the firm. Out-
sourcing offers the potential for lower production
Although bargaining and opportunism costs can costs for the good or activity, as well as minimal bar-
occur during contracting (period 1) or post-contrac- gaining and opportunism costs. Low product com-
tually (period 2), it is feasible for the outsourcing firm plexity implies that the outsourcing firm has, or can
to address both these costs at the contracting stage easily acquire, sufficient knowledge and information
(that is, in period 1). The parties are then in a multi- to specify contract terms precisely (as there is low
period game (Rasmussen, 1994). The outsourcing uncertainty about price-performance characteristics
‘player’ can anticipate what the optimal strategy in and no information asymmetry). With low asset
each period of the game will be for the contractee specificity (and resulting high contestability), inef-
player and by backward induction identify its own ficient or opportunistic contractees can be quickly
optimal strategy in each period. For example, sup- replaced.
pose the outsourcing firm is playing a game where
contestability is high in period 1, but is expected to
be low in any subsequent periods. Outsourcing firms, Low Product/Activity Complexity and High Asset
therefore, should be able to predict that a contractee Specificity
will behave opportunistically or generate bargaining
costs in some subsequent period. The outsourcing Given low complexity, problems associated with
firm should, therefore, incorporate this expectation high asset specificity almost certainly involve high
into its period 1 strategy. The optimal result is an temporal or locational specificity. There are likely to
initial contract that anticipates and addresses all be few efficiency costs arising from high physical
potential opportunism costs and bargaining costs. asset specificity if the outsourcing firm makes the rel-
evant specific investments itself as, given this owner-
The practical value of this ‘game’ analogy is that out- ship, it is not costly to replace the contractee (given
sourcing firms can use it to formulate consistent high contestability). There are likely to be problems,
expectations about future outsourcing issues and however, if the contractee makes the investment.
plan accordingly. In order to do so, however, out- Once the investment is sunk, a contractee is vulner-
sourcing firms must think through the factors influ- able to opportunistic hold-up by the outsourcing
encing opportunism and bargaining costs as well as firm, which could demand that the contractee deliver
strategies to minimize costs. Thus, it is useful to dis- the good at marginal cost. Given that all potential
tinguish between ex ante mechanisms and ex post contractees can deduce this as a possible ex post out-
mechanisms, emphasizing that in the case of the lat- come, they will compensate ex ante. They can com-
ter it is only the ‘trigger’ that is ex post. To some man- pensate in one of two possible ways: either by raising

650 European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999


A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING THE OUTSOURCING DECISION

the bid price or by utilizing a higher cost production ing after the fact about whether the specifications
technology that requires less physical asset speci- were satisfied, and if not, whether the contractee
ficity. Either strategy ultimately raises the outsourc- acted incompetently or negligently. However, in this
ing firm’s costs. situation opportunism should not be a significant
problem, since low asset specificity implies high con-
One way to avoid these problems is for the outsourc- testability, suggesting that switching costs will be
ing firm to own the specific asset and to rent it or low for both parties. Opportunistic behavior once
lease it to the contractee. However, leasing specific identified can be easily countered by contract termin-
assets is not costless. The outsourcing firm is now ation.
outsourcing two activities — the original outsourced
service and the lease contract (Hensher, 1988). Lease
contracts can also generate opportunistic behavior, High Product/Activity Complexity and High Asset
including the potential for the lessee to overutilize Specificity
and run down the leased assets. Including ‘reason-
able usage and maintenance’ clauses can mitigate this The important difference between this situation and
problem in lease agreements. But this form of out- the second case descibed above is that reliance upon
sourcing, then, requires detailed specification of both arbitration or other third-party contract enforcement
contracts, adding to costs. procedures is more problematic because it is more
difficult for a judging third party to identify whether
Temporal asset specificity raises several problems contract breach has occurred. This type of problem
(Masten et al., 1991). The first arises if the contractee has been discussed in the industrial organization
fails to provide contracted performance. The out- literature. The basic solution suggested is that out-
sourcing firm’s usual insurance against the opportun- sourcing firms provide contractees with an incentive
istic exercise of contract breach is an action in tort. (‘economic rent’) which contractees can expect to
However, this is less desirable than having a contract earn indefinitely in the absence of a verified contract
which mitigates incentives for contractee breach. The breach. The potential loss of these rents harmonizes
outsourcing firm can, for example, write a contract the incentives of contractees with those of outsourc-
that contains provisions that backloads payment ing firms.
(contract completion bonuses) and requires perform-
ance bonding. Table 1 summarizes the relevant issues for each of
the four cases described. The table focuses on two
The second possible problem arises if the outsourcing issues: the dominant problem(s) to be expected and
firm wishes to terminate because of unsatisfactory the general strategic solution. The table identifies dif-
performance, but needs to maintain service until a ferent environmental contexts and alternative instru-
replacement contractee is in place. The risk is that in ments to modify each context; however, the overall
an ‘endgame’ situation such as this the contractee framework emphasizes the following steps:
will act opportunistically. The most obvious way for
an outsourcing firm to mitigate this risk is to demand 1. Formulate consistent expectations about the
bonding from a winning bidder plus a contract agree- uncertainties surrounding the potential trans-
ment that specifies timely arbitration of the firm’s actions at all stages of contract formulation and
claim for the bond because of unsatisfactory con- implementation;
tractee performance (Eaton and White, 1982). 2. Identify the potential opportunism at different
stages of contract formulation and implemen-
tation, including the underlying sources: con-
High Product/Activity Complexity and Low Asset testability, complexity and/or asset specificity.
Specificity 3. Identify contract provisions to attenuate the
This configuration perhaps best characterizes the opportunism and assess the consequences of the
supply of a wide range of services or activities poten- preferred strategies for the overall efficiency of
tially outsourcable to professionals. It should be kept outsourcing versus internal production.
in mind, however, when assessing potential out- 4. Implement the relevant strategies prior to the
sourcing problems that firms’ employment contracts initiation of outsourcing.
with professional employees are not very different
from those with formally outsourced professionals.
Basically the same issues arise under either arrange-
ment (Garen, 1998; James, 1998). The main problem is
high bargaining costs owing to honest disagreements Conclusions
surrounding ex ante specifications, or ex post perform-
ance in relationship to ex ante specifications. In parti- There is increasing interest in outsourcing among
cular, disagreements can arise because ex ante speci- firms in a wide range of industries. In this paper, we
fications are sometimes costly and difficult to write, suggest that the broad problems associated with out-
and (therefore) the parties often have difficulty agree- sourcing can be mitigated by contractual and related

European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999 651


A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING THE OUTSOURCING DECISION

Table 1 A Summary of Outsourcing States

Case Product/activity Asset specificity Dominant problem(s) Solution(s)


complexity

1 Low Low Few Rely primarily on contestability via contract


termination (i,e, increase potential suppliers)
2 Low High Hold-up For physical assets, outsourcing firm owns
and leases assets; for temporal specificity,
backloaded payments, bonuses and bonding.
Use of quick arbitration
3 High Low Honest disagreements about Where possible mutually agreed upon practice
quality and other performance guidelines
attributes
4 High High Opportunism by contractee Harmonize outsourcing firm and contractee
incentives through ‘rent-creation’

strategies on the part of the outsourcing. We propose mation in internal management communication. Journal
a simple framework that relates some alternative of Economic Behavior and Organization 36(3), 295–317.
Anderson, E. (1985) The salesperson as outside agent or
strategies for archetypal problem situations sur- employee: a transaction cost analysis. Marketing Science
rounding outsourcing. This framework does not deal 4(3), 234–254.
with all strategic outsourcing issues. The outsourcing Anderson, E. and Schmittlein, D. (1984) Integration of the
also has to develop information strategies so that it salesforce: an empirical investigation. Rand Journal of Eco-
nomics 15(3), 385–395.
can continue to learn — about changing costs and
Ang, S. (1998) Production and transaction economies and IS
other relevant factors (Cross, 1995). outsourcing: a study of the U.S. banking industry. MIS
Quarterly 22(4), 535, 552.
Axelrod, R. (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation. Basic Books,
New York.
Acknowledgements Baumol, W., Panzar, J. and Willig, R. (1982) Contestable Markets
and the Theory of Industry Structure. Harcourt, Brace, Jov-
The authors would like to thank Betty Chung for word-pro-
anovich, New York.
cessing assistance.
Benson, J. and Ieronimo, N. (1996) Outsourcing decisions: evi-
dence from Australia-based enterprises. International Lab-
our Review 135, 59–73.
Bryce, D. and Useem, M. (1998) The impact of corporate out-
Notes sourcing on company value. European Management Jour-
1. This is not to argue that the value chain is the only way of nal 16(6), 635–643.
conceptualizing the context of outsourcing. For a broader Button, K. and Weyman-Jones, T. (1994) X-efficiency and tech-
framework that expands to include ‘shops’ and ‘networks’ nical efficiency. Public Choice 80, 83–104.
as well as ‘chains’, see Stabell and Fjeldstad (1998). Camerer, C. and Vepsalainen, A. (1988) The economic
2. Tapon (1989) argues that pharmaceutical firms are more efficiency of corporate culture. Strategic Management Jour-
willing to outsource R&D to university laboratories nal 9(Special issue), 115–126.
because the latter are non-profit organizations and, there- Coles, J. and Hesterly, W. (1988) The impact of firm-specific
fore, less likely to have a financial conflict of interest with assets and the interaction of uncertainty: an examination
for-profit pharmaceutical firms. of make or buy decisions in public and private hospitals.
3. For an estimation of these ‘organization costs’ see Masten Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 36, 383–409.
et al. (1991, p. 28). Collingridge, D. (1992) The Management of Scale: Organizations,
4. This framework was originally discussed in Globerman Big Decisions, Big Mistakes. Routledge, New York.
and Vining (1996). Crocker, K. and Masten, S. (1988) Mitigating contractual haz-
5. As Pirrong (1993) notes, sunk costs can generate oppor- ards: unilateral options and contract length. Rand Journal
tunism even where no contract has been signed, if a party of Economics 19(3), 327–343.
has committed resources whose values would be reduced Cross, J. (1995) IT outsourcing: British Petroleum’s competi-
if the transaction were not consummated. tive approach. Harvard Business Review 73(3), 94–103.
6. Coles and Hesterly (1988) provide evidence that ‘trans- Crozier, M. (1964) The Bureaucratic Phenomenon. University of
actional uncertainty’ (complexity) interacts with asset Chicago Press, Chicago.
specificity to determine the propensity of private hospitals DeCanio, S. and Frech, H. (1993) Vertical contracts: a natural
to internalize services. experiment in natural gas pipeline regulation. Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149, 370–392.
Delaney, K. (1999) Outsourcing takes a back seat to backsourc-
ing. Toronto Globe and Mail, May 17.
References Dilger, R., Moffitt, R. and Struyk, L. (1997) Privatization of
municipal services in America’s largest population cities.
Akerlof, G. (1970) The market for lemons: quality, uncertainty Public Administration Review 57(1), 21–26.
and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics Domberger, S. and Hall, C. (1996) Contracting for public ser-
84(3), 488–500. vices: a review of the Antipodean experience. Public
Alchian, A. and Demsetz, H. (1972) Production, information Administration 74, 129–148.
costs, and economic organization. American Economic Eaton, C. and White, W. (1982) Agent compensation and the
Review 62(5), 777–795. limits of bonding. Economic Inquiry 20(3), 330–343.
Alles, M., Newman, P. and Noel, J. (1998) The value of infor- Feenstra, R. (1998) Integration of trade and disintegration of

652 European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999


A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING THE OUTSOURCING DECISION

production in the global economy. Journal of Economic McFarlan, F. and Nolan, R. (1995) How to manage an IS out-
Perspective 12(4), 31–51. sourcing alliance. Sloan Management Review 36(2), 9–23.
Garen, J. (1998) Self-employment, pay systems, and the theory McFetridge, D. and Smith, D. (1998) The Economics of Vertical
of the firm: an empirical analysis. Journal of Economic Disintegration. The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C.
Behavior and Organization 36(2), 257–274. McLellan, K. (1993) Achieving competitive advantage by out-
Globerman, S. (1980) Markets, hierarchies and innovation. sourcing a core skill: the potential strategic benefits avail-
Journal of Economic Issues 14, 977–998. able from information technology outsourcing in the
Globerman, S. (1995) A policy analysis of foreign ownership financial sector. ASAC Conference, June, Lake Louise,
restrictions in telecommunications. Telecommunications Alberta.
Policy 19(1), 21–28. Miller, G. (1992) Managerial Dilemmas. Cambridge University
Globerman, S. and Schwindt, R. (1986) The organization of Press, New York.
vertically related transactions in the Canadian forest pro- Monteverde, K. and Teece, D. (1982) Supplier switching costs
duct industries. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organiza- and vertical integration in the automobile industry. Bell
tion 7(2), 199–212. Journal of Economics 13, 206–213.
Globerman, S. and Vining, A. (1996) A framework for evaluat- Muris, T., Scheffman, D. and Spiller, P. (1992) Strategy and
ing the government contracting-out decision with an transaction costs: the organization of distribution in the
application to information technology. Public Adminis- carbonated soft drink industry. Journal of Economics and
tration Review 56(6), 577–586. Management Strategy 1, 83–128.
Goldberg, V. and Erickson, J. (1987) Quantity and price adjust- Pirrong, S. (1993) Contracting practices in bulk shipping mar-
ment in long-term contracts: a case study of petroleum kets: a transactions cost explanation. Journal of Law and
coke. Journal of Law and Economics 30(2), 369–398. Economics 36(1), 913–937.
Graves, S. and Langowitz, N. (1993) Innovative productivity Prahalad, C. and Hamel, G. (1990) The core competence of the
and returns to scale in the pharmaceutical industry. Stra- corporation. Harvard Business Review 68(3), 79–93.
tegic Management Journal 14(8), 593–605. Rasmussen, E. (1994) Games and Information, 2nd ed.
Hallwood, P. (1990) Transaction Costs and Trade Between Multi- Blackwell, Cambridge, MA.
national Corporations. Unwin Hyman, Boston. Reichelstein, S. (1995) Reliance investment under negotiated
Hennart, J.F. (1988) Upstream vertical integration in the transfer pricing: an efficiency result. The Accounting
aluminum and tin industries. Journal of Economic Behavior Review 70(2), 275–291.
and Organization 9(3), 281–299. Saunders, C., Gebelt, M. and Hu, Q. (1997) Achieving success
Hensher, D. (1988) Some thoughts on competitive tendering in information systems outsourcing. California Manage-
in local bus operations. Transport Reviews 8(4), 363–372. ment Review 39, 63–79.
James, H. (1998) Are employment and managerial control Shelanski, H. and Klein, P. (1995) Empirical research in trans-
equivalent? Evidence from an electronics producer. Jour- action cost economics: a review and assessment. The Jour-
nal of Economic Behavior and Organization 36, 447–471. nal of Law, Economics and Organization 11(2), 335–361.
Jensen, J. and Rothwell, G. (1998) Transaction costs, regu- Smith, M., Mitra, S. and Narasimhan, S. (1998) Information
lation, and subcontracting at nuclear power plants. Jour- system outsourcing: a study of pre-event firm character-
nal of Economic Behavior and Organization 36(3), 369–381. istics. Journal of Management Information Systems 15(2),
Johnson, J. and Schneider, K. (1995) Outsourcing in distri- 60–92.
bution: the growing importance of transportation brok- Spann, R. (1974) Rate of return regulation in production: an
ers. Business Horizons 38(6), 40–49. empirical test of the Averch and Johnson thesis. Bell Jour-
Joskow, P. (1987) Contract duration and relationship-specific nal of Economics and Management 5(1), 38–54.
investments: empirical evidence from coal markets. Stabell, C. and Fjeldstad, O. (1998) Configuring value for com-
American Economic Review 77(1), 168–185. petitive advantage: on chains, shops, and networks. Stra-
Klein, B., Crawford, R. and Alchian, A. (1978) Vertical inte- tegic Management Journal 19(5), 413–437.
Stuckey, J. (1983) Vertical Integration and Joint Ventures in the
gration, appropriable rents and the competitive con-
Aluminum Industry. Harvard University Press, Cam-
tracting process. Journal of Law and Economics 21(2),
bridge, MA.
297–326.
Szymanski, S. and Wilkins, S. (1993) Cheap rubbish? Competi-
Lacity, M. and Hirschheim, R. (1995) The information systems
tive tendering and contracting out in the refuse collec-
outsourcing bandwagon. Sloan Management Review 35(1),
tion — 1981–1988. Fiscal Studies 14(3), 109–130.
73–86.
Tapon, F. (1989) A transaction costs analysis of innovations
Lacity, M. and Willcocks, L. (1998) An empirical investigation in the organization of pharmaceutical R&D. Journal of
of information technology sourcing practices: lessons Economic Behavior and Organization 12(2), 197–213.
from experience. MIS Quarterly 22(3), 363–409. Tapon, F. and Cadsby, C. (1996) The optimal organization of
Leibenstein, H. (1976) Beyond Economic Man. Harvard Univer- research: evidence from eight case studies of pharma-
sity Press, Cambridge, MA. ceutical firms. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organiza-
Lieberman, M. (1991) Determinants of vertical integration: an tion 31(1), 381–399.
empirical test. Journal of Industrial Economics 39(5), 451– Tempest, R. (1996) Barbie and the world economy. Los Angeles
466. Times, September 22, pp. A1 and A12.
Loh, L. and Venkatraman, N. (1992) Determinants of infor- Tisdale, S. (1994) Shoe and tell. The New Republic, September
mation technology outsourcing: a cross-sectional analy- 12, pp. 10–11.
sis. Journal of Management Information Systems 9(1), 7–24. Ulset, S. (1996) R&D outsourcing and contractual governance:
Lyons, B. (1995) Specific investment, economies of scale, and an empirical study of commercial R&D projects. Journal
the make-or-buy decision: a test of transaction cost of Economic Behavior and Organization 30(1), 63–82.
theory. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization Van den Ven, A., Angle, H. and Poole, M. (1989) Research on
26(3), 431–443. the Management of Innovation. Harper and Row, New
Masten, S. (1984) The organization of production: evidence York.
from the aerospace industry. Journal of Law and Economics Vining, A. and Weimer, D. (1988) Information asymmetry fav-
27(2), 402–417. oring sellers: a policy framework. Policy Sciences 21(4),
Masten, S., Meeham, J. and Snyder, E. (1991) The costs of 281–303.
organization. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization Walker, G. and Weber, D. (1987) Supplier competition, uncer-
7(1), 1–25. tainty, and make-or-buy decisions. Academy of Manage-
McAfee, R.P. and McMillan, J. (1988) Incentives in Government ment Journal 30(3), 589–596.
Contracting. University of Toronto Press, Toronto, Onta- Walsh, K. (1991) Competitive Tendering for Local Authority Ser-
rio. vices: Initial Experiences. HMSO, London.

European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999 653


A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING THE OUTSOURCING DECISION

Williamson, O. (1985) The Economic Institution of Capitalism. role of trust in economic exchange. Strategic Management
The Free Press, New York. Journal 16(5), 373–392.
Williamson, O. (1991) Strategizing, economizing and econ- Zanger, T. (1994) Understanding organizational diseconomies
omic organization. Strategic Management Journal of scale in R&D: agency problems and the allocation of
12(Special issue), 75–94. engineering talent, ideas, and effort by firm size. Manage-
Zaheer, A. and Venkatraman, N. (1995) Relational governance ment Science 40, 708–729.
as an interorganizational strategy: an empirical test of the

AIDAN VINING, Faculty STEVEN GLOBERMAN,


of Business Administration, Western Washington Uni-
Simon Fraser University at versity, College of Business
Harbour Centre, 2400-515 and Economics, Bellingham,
West Hastings Street, Van- Washington 98225-9170,
couver, British Columbia, USA. E-mail: steven.glober-
Canada V6B 5K3. man@wwu.edu

Aidan Vining is the CNABS Steven Globerman is the


Professor of Business and Ross Distinguished Pro-
Government Relations in fessor of Canada – US Busi-
the Faculty of Business, ness and Economic
Simon Fraser University, Vancouver. Recent articles Relations and Director of the Center for International
have appeared in the Journal of Risk and Insurance, Business at Western Washington University’s College
The Journal of Policy Analysis and Management of Business and Economics in Bellingham, Wash-
and International Business Review. He has recently ington. He has published on a wide range of topics in
co-authored the 3rd edition of Policy Analysis: Con- industrial economics, international business and public
cepts and Practice (Prentice-Hall, NJ, 1999). policy and served as a consultant to numerous compa-
nies and government agencies in both North America
and Europe.

654 European Management Journal Vol 17 No 6 December 1999

You might also like