Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Case Studies on Transport Policy


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/cstp

An empirical model for setting and adjusting road-toll rates based on T


optimized equity and affordability strategies
Konstantinos Panou
Department of Shipping, Trade and Transport, University of Aegean, Korai 2A, Chios 82100, Greece

ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

Keywords: An empirical model is presented in this paper to systematically address issues related to setting tariff structures
Road tolls for road tolls in the presence of optimized equity and affordability strategies. The model is based on break-even
Tariff setting analysis to compute the minimum toll rate that could be charged per vehicle-kilometer (veh-km) in a given
Tariff adjustment policy context to cover all costs.
The model can be applied following a process comprising three steps: (a) definition of policy-focused sce-
narios—generating information on specific policies such as equity and economic affordability and allocating
them to a number of tolling objectives; (b) tariff setting—calculating the base rates from infrastructure costs
including annual maintenance costs and yearly operating costs, and allocating them into respective user-groups
and vehicle classes, namely two classes for the light vehicles and seven classes for the heavy vehicles; (c) Tariff
adjustment—laying out the toll implementation plan including recommendations on toll duration, tariff esca-
lation and tariff commercial policy.
It shows that the model is very well suited as a decision-making tool for authorities promoting tolls as it
allows for the systematic identification of tariff structures that respond in the best possible way to the policy
needs, while respecting the limitations imposed by traffic levels and possibly high maintenance & operating
costs.

1. Introduction European Bank for Reconstruction and Development as part of the


Bank’s long engagement with the road sector in the CS.
1.1. Overview The main objectives of this study were:

During the last decade a European country (hereafter called the • to assess the normative and operational aspects associated with road
Considered State—CS) had a good progress on road sector reform and tolling, in the context of the ongoing reform and the evolving road
infrastructure development absorbing a considerable amount of both infrastructure workplan of the country;
foreign and domestic financing. The rapid increase of the demand for • to assist the TA and other stakeholders at a strategic planning level
road transport made necessary the improvement of existing road in- in assessing the viability of road tolling as related to their plans for
frastructure, as well as the construction of new roads and highways future developments in the road sector, and
linking major economic and touristic centers as well as international • to pave the road to applying the user-pays principle on road users,
networks. providing recommendations for the timing and implementation of a
Taking into consideration the current process of strategic planning tolling strategy.
and infrastructure development which CS’s road transport system is
undergoing to cope with the increasing demand, and considering also To deliver to these objectives an empirical model has been devel-
the need for resource mobilization for the operation and maintenance oped with the main role to serve as a form of “screening mechanism”
of the road network, the national Transportation Agency (TA) of the CS with which a large number of possible tariff structures can be sifted
has engaged an advisory board to prepare a road tolling strategy where with relative ease by decision-makers, to ascertain an early view on
the objectives of tolling are established and potential segments suitable whether a toll project meets economic affordability and social equity
for tolling are identified. objectives, while respecting the limitations imposed by traffic levels
The financing of the CS’s Road Tolling study was endorsed by the and possibly high maintenance & operating costs.

E-mail address: panou@aegean.gr.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cstp.2020.08.006
Received 22 August 2019; Received in revised form 2 July 2020; Accepted 20 August 2020
Available online 01 September 2020
2213-624X/ © 2020 World Conference on Transport Research Society. Published by Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

This article contains an analytical discussion of this model, which but originally intended as a short-term intermediate solution. In 2004,
systematically combines information on strategic elements, i.e. infra- an electronic toll collection system replaced the vignettes for trucks
structure and specific policies, to describe aggregate influences on the over 3.5 tones, allowing them to make distance-based payments rather
tariff setting process and to identify tariff structures that respond in the than time-based. Toll rates per km to date are grouped in three vehicle
best possible way to the toll policy and operational needs. classes, according to the number of axles: 2-axle vehicles; 3-axle ve-
The analysis reflects the perspective of a Government Authority that hicles and 4- or more axle vehicles. The rates can be adapted to the
will regulate private intercity toll highways, and/or of a Highway inflation rate every year and are due to a 20% VAT.
Agency that will mobilize resources for the operation and maintenance The vignette system remains still as the charging scheme for light
of the road network (be it tolled or not). The article does not address the vehicles of up to 3.5 tones. Vignettes are offered for one year, two
pricing of decongestion tolling, which might be a subject of growing months and 10 days periods.
interest in the developed world, but comes much lower on the agenda
of developing countries where there is still lack of basic transportation 2.1.1.2. Tolls in France. In 2011, the French highway network has been
infrastructure and public transit services. With an extensive but ob- managed by sixteen private operators, two public-owned companies
solete road network in need of modernization this article does not also (ATMB, SFTRF), and one local authority corporation (CCI du Havre). Of
address any aspects related to encouraging more efficient use of existing the 12,000 km of highways in service at the 1st of January 2011,
roads or less automobile ownership, which require a well-developed 8850 km were operated by concessionaires.
infrastructure and capabilities for the effective development and In French tolls the user pays according to the distance travelled, the
adoption of public transit and sustainable mobility habits. number of axles of the used vehicle, the weight of the vehicle and its
level of emissions (e.g. ATMB Autoroutes et Tunnel du Mont Blanc). The
1.2. Disclaimer toll rate depends on construction costs, operating and infrastructure
maintenance costs, and is defined in the terms of reference of new
The study reported in this paper was supported by a grant from the concessions. In older concessions, other factors such as traffic volume,
CS’s national Transportation Agency (TA). The author served on an construction costs, or even comparisons with other road segments are
advisory board for that Agency four years ago. Although the data used taken into account.
in this research are proprietary, the findings presented in this pub- The application of class coefficients makes it possible to obtain a toll
lication have been reviewed and approved by the TA in accordance rate for each vehicle class. These class coefficients, specific for each
with its policy on objectivity in research. concessionaire, are fixed in the concession contract. They can change in
According to the relevant disclosure agreement, the data is pub- the duration of the concession within limits explicitly specified in the
lished anonymously and on an aggregated basis in this research, pro- concession agreement.
viding readers with indications of how to use road infrastructure and Concessionaires are allowed to increase toll rates every year ac-
policy related data to set tariff structures and tariff adjustment proce- cording to the consumer’s price index.
dures. It should be noted, that the data release here does not include
details of the road network or maintenance & operation costs, which are 2.1.1.3. Toll roads in the United Kingdom. In the UK, there are about
both major components of tariff setting. Neither does the disclosure forty tolled highways and road infrastructure. From those, there are six
framework extend to the traffic data which particularly influence tariff publicly owned tolls authorized by statute: for the Mersey and Tyne
setting and adjustment procedures. It accounts only for the data needed tunnels and the bridge crossings for the Severn, Humber, Itchen and
to discuss the suggested model at the level of a “screening mechanism” Cleddau—there would be ten if the Scottish government had not
as mentioned above. abolished four bridge tolls (Skye, Erskine, Forth and Tay).
There are also eight tolls authorized by Parliament that are privately
2. Background analysis owned or operated but which form part of the public highway system:
Aldwark Bridge, Clifton Suspension Bridge, Dunham Bridge, Rixton and
A review of European best-practices is presented in the following Warburton Bridge, Shrewsbury (Kingsland) Bridge, Swinford Bridge,
with the aim to capture experience in the design and implementation of Whitchurch Bridge and Witney-on-Wye Bridge. Tolls are also being
widely used road pricing systems. The cases below are not very similar charged on the M6 toll road and the Dartford Crossing. Vehicles can
to the CS but are selected as representative of certain classes of pricing either pay by cash or through a tag which opens the barrier allowing
schemes, based either on their level of technological innovation or their the vehicle to cross.
historical importance as early pioneers. Finally there is a number of private toll roads around the UK, e.g.
This Section also reflects on some major trends in setting and ad- College Road, Dulwich, Rye Road, Hoddesdon, Braunton Toll Road,
justing tariff levels through a review of recent experiences. The aim is to Barnstaple, Porlock Manor Estate, Kewstone Toll Road, Weston-super-
provide a framework that could help identify key principles that can Mare (not currently collected) and beach access roads at Kimmeridge,
serve as drivers for the estimation of toll rates in different institutional Dorset and Sandwich, Kent. A number of Forestry Commission roads are
contexts. The result of this analysis will be the basis for the model de- also tolled, e.g. Cropton, Dalby, Galloway, Hamsterley and Kielder.
velopment in Section 3.
2.1.1.4. Tolls in Spain. The first toll road infrastructure in Spain was the
2.1. A brief survey of road pricing in Europe Guadarrama tunnel, for which the concession was granted in 1960.
To date, almost 3000 km of toll highways are operated by 31 de-
2.1.1. Toll pricing signated undertakings. Toll rates are calculated according to a para-
2.1.1.1. Toll roads in Austria. Tolling for all vehicles was introduced for metric formula taking into account, among others, the construction
the first time in Austria on certain high-cost segments of highways in costs, the level of traffic and the length of the concession period.
the Austrian mountains already in the late sixties and seventies. The In the majority of cases tolls are paid at tollbooths manually or
aim was to support the financing of urgently needed high level roads automatically. To avoid stopping for paying the toll, many operators
crossing the central area of the Alps. In 1996, the Austrian parliament offer electronic toll collection capabilities. There is a single system
passed a law for future toll collection systems that extended tolling to currently in use, called the “Vía T”, which operates throughout the
the entire network of highways and express roads. Spanish highway system. At each “Vía T” lane an aerial communicates
In a first step a vignette system (based on time charges) was im- with an onboard unit, resulting in charging the appropriate amount to
plemented in 1997, because of its benefits for quick implementation, the holder’s account. Average speed at the “Vía T” lanes is limited to

1257
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

30–40 km/h for safety reasons. For all domestic HGVs an OBU is mandatory. The OBU is linked to
the vehicle tachograph for distance recording. The driver is responsible
2.1.2. HGV pricing for entering the total vehicle weight onto the OBU. All Swiss border
Several countries have introduced or are planning to introduce stations are equipped with CEN-DSRC beacons which are used by the
schemes for pricing heavy goods vehicles (HGV). In recent years there is border recognition system to record entrance and exits, as well as for
an upsurge of interest in HGV pricing schemes incorporating microwave enforcement purposes. In addition, GPS is used for monitoring purposes
short-range communications, cellular radio technology, satellite posi- (e.g., accuracy of distance recording, correctness of border recordings).
tioning, and a smart card reader. Such technology is capable of iden- DSRC (Dedicated Short-Range Communications) is a bi-directional
tifying when a vehicle enters a charging zone, applying the appropriate communication link between the OBU and the roadside equipment. A
charge, and transmitting charging data to a billing center. A desirable more thorough discussion of these technologies can be found in Chapter
feature for road user charging is that travelers should need only one set VI.
of on-board equipment for use with any local charging scheme. More
advanced technologies however such as the Automatic Number Plate 2.1.3. Areawide pricing
Recognition (ANPR) or Video Tolling system allows charging without On February 17, 2003, London introduced a 8 EUR per day con-
even requiring an on-board component (see Chapter VI for more de- gestion charge for those driving in the city center (the rate has now
tails). been increased to £11.50 per day or about 16.25 EUR). The scheme
relies on 700 video cameras which scan the rear license plates of cars
2.1.2.1. HGV pricing in Germany. Since January 1, 2005, all trucks entering the area between 07:00 and 18:00, Monday to Friday. This
exceeding 12 tons gross weight pay for each kilometer of road travelled information is matched each night against a database of drivers who
on Germany's 12,000 km highway (Autobahn) network. The toll rate is have paid the charge either by phone, via the internet or at shops and
calculated on the vehicle's environmental status (engine emission garages. Except for those with exemptions, anyone who fails to pay by
levels) and the number of axles. This distance-related highway charge midnight is fined about 150 EUR.
replaced the Euro-vignette system for traveling through Germany. While some areawide pricing schemes had to be aborted because of
The system is a dual one, comprising not only a manual booking political opposition (e.g., Austria, Hong Kong), others are working re-
option but also, for the first time ever, satellite-based automatic tolling. latively well. Singapore has led the way in restraining traffic by price
It uses a combination of satellite navigation and mobile communication since 1975. In the 1990s, three Norwegian cities—Oslo, Bergen and
technology to achieve a free flow system. Trondheim—set up pricing schemes (see more details below). Rome has
Trucks using the German Autobahn network are expected to be introduced an electronic system to control entry into its historic center.
fitted with an On Board Unit (OBU) to enable payments to be calculated San Diego, California, has adopted dynamic road pricing, using mi-
via the satellite tracking system. Currently there are about 1.8 million crowave transponders to assess congestion levels and deduct fees ac-
trucks identified under the scheme in Germany, of which some 48% cordingly.
equipped with an OBU. In Sweden, following a trial period, the parliament decided to in-
To guarantee the principle of non-discrimination, payments can also troduce a congestion tax in Stockholm from August 1, 2007. The con-
be made by manual booking at so-called toll terminals at gas stations, gestion tax is levied on Swedish-registered vehicles that enter or exit the
service areas and retail outlets, or by telephone or via the internet. So city center, Monday to Friday, between 06:30 and 18:30. During the
the dual system with automatic and manual booking alternatives en- times when the congestion tax is levied, vehicles are automatically re-
sures that all truck drivers can use the toll road system without dis- gistered at control points. Each passage entering or leaving Stockholm
crimination. It is able to handle the full tonnage booked with the is charged, depending on the time of day.
manual system if the automatic system goes down.
The scheme is raising around 3 billion EUR a year (gross amount). 2.1.3.1. Toll rings in Norway. After a long political debate, toll cordons
The revenue from electronic fee collection is about 5 times higher than have been introduced in Norway as a source of funding for urban road
the revenue gained previously from the vignettes. Most of the invest- improvements with the main objectives of easing congestion and
ment goes to the federal trunk roads sector. In keeping with the Federal improving road safety and the environment. In 1986, the Bergen toll
Government’s desire to pursue an integrated transport policy, some of it ring was opened in Norway (this was the second such ring in the world,
is also being used to upgrade railway infrastructure and waterways. The the first being in Singapore); the Oslo toll ring was opened in 1990, and
German government contracted with “Toll Collect” to operate the the Trondheim toll ring was opened in 1991. In Oslo, alternatives to toll
charging system, which is the first of its kind in the world. collection that were debated (and rejected) included: (a) an extra fuel
The effectiveness of the German toll system depends mainly on the tax earmarked for local road improvements, and (b) an extra car
number of vehicles equipped with OBU. Key features of the automatic ownership tax earmarked for local road investments. A reason for
system include: rejection was a general negative attitude to earmarking of taxes in
Norway. Establishing toll cordon in Oslo, with 19 toll plazas, was
• It recognizes a fixed toll road network (about 12,000 km of high- facilitated by the city's topography, with the fiord to the south and large
ways) and only charge tolls there. This road network may be ex- greenbelt areas to the north and to the east. With a few exceptions such
panded at any time by the way of data transfer via mobile com- as handicapped drivers, public transport, and ambulances, everybody
munication network (GSM) has to pay toll when passing in the direction of the center of Oslo.
• It is able to set environmental policy through taking the pollution Outbound traffic is not tolled. The heaviest trafficked toll plaza, serving
class into account as well as the number of axles in calculating fees about 50,000 vehicles per day, has 8 paying lanes—4 for tag users with
• It offers the technical prerequisites to introduce other fee classes, automatic vehicle identification and no speed limitation, 3 that are coin
such as the time and place of the trip operated, and 1 lane for manual services only. Operation is done by two
• It operates on a free flow system, which charges toll without causing private companies—a toll collection company, and a toll plaza
stops and traffic jams. operating company—both under contract with the Norwegian Public
Roads Administration.
2.1.2.2. HGV pricing in Switzerland. A distance-based charge collected
electronically applies to HGVs over 3.5 tons on all Swiss roads. The fee 2.1.4. Distance-related and other pricing schemes
depends on the distance driven, the total vehicle weight (e.g., tractor 2.1.4.1. The Czech Republic System. The obligation of motor vehicles
plus trailer), and the emission class. and trailer combinations, with a total weight equal to or greater than 12

1258
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

tons, to have a toll sticker affixed on the windshield was cancelled as of indicate that (i) tolling is appropriate only when traffic levels exceed
January 1, 2007, and was replaced with a distance-based toll charge 4000–5000 vehicles per day; (ii) toll rate levels should not result in
based on modern microwave technology. excessive traffic diversion—with an upper limit of acceptability con-
Vehicles that are subject to tolls must be equipped with a small sidered to be in the range of 10–15%; and (iii) under certain conditions,
electronic device—called the “Premid Onboard Unit”—which commu- toll rates can be set higher where there is no feasible alternative.
nicates with the roadside tolling equipment. A fee for the use of a Particularly at a country with middle to low average income, it is
specific road segment is charged when a toll transaction occurs; that is important to base project revenues on affordable toll rates. Although in
when a vehicle passes through a toll gantry installed on the road. At this some cases these rates might exceed short-term marginal costs they
point, an acoustic signal from the onboard unit alerts the driver that the could be set at levels considered adequate to avoid excessive traffic
toll has been recorded. The driver can use any lane without having to diversion. Moreover, the toll levels established for the various projects
reduce the vehicle speed. The tolling process is fully automatic and should be set at levels consistent with existing tolls in neighbouring
requires no intervention on the part of the driver. networks. A general rule of thumb is that tolls can be varied from 9 to
Enforcement stations are equipped with technology to check whe- 36 percent of user cost savings, with the lowest values corresponding to
ther vehicles have “Premid” units installed, whether they are installed buses and the highest to trucks.
properly, and to check toll payments. In addition to the stationary Similar approaches taken worldwide demonstrate the need for af-
gantries, there are also portable devices that can be deployed for fordable toll rates (BTRP, 2015). For instance, tolls in Brazil have been
random checks. kept at relatively low levels by international standards, at about 0.04
The toll rate depends on the number of axles and the emission class USD per veh-km, which has helped promote public acceptance of the
of the vehicle. The payable amount is calculated by multiplying the tolling programme. Another instructive example is that of Chile
applicable rate with the length of the segment. (Ortega, 2003), which has endeavored to keep tolls at levels that users
are willing to pay for improved services (i.e., about 0.025–0.030 USD
2.1.4.2. Road pricing in Finland. Finland is one of the few European per veh-km, linked to the consumer price index). By contrast, Mexico a
countries that levy no charges for road use. Road maintenance is country with comparable GDP per capita as Brazil and Chile has set tolls
financed entirely from the state budget; the taxes levied on road traffic relatively higher, in the range of 0.12–0.50 USD (Carruthers, 2014).
are fiscal and have no connection with the actual cost of road
maintenance. Because of the completely different characteristics of 2.2.1.1. Uniform toll rate issue. An important issue for tolling is whether
the Finish example, it is included here for reasons of completion. tariffs should be set by individual route or set uniformly across the
In Finland, road users are charged annual vehicle excise duty (de- network. If a toll revenue pooling system is used for the entire road
pending on the weight of their vehicle, its year of registration, the fuel it network system (e.g. France, Italy, Japan), tolls can be set at equal rates
uses and, in the case of heavy goods vehicles, its axle weight), regis- per km for all of the routes within the network, regardless of the
tration tax (based on CO2 emissions) and fuel tax (different tax on construction costs or traffic levels on the individual segment (Gómez-
gasoline and diesel). Since 2010 the annual vehicle tax for passenger Ibáñez and Meyer, 2013; Takeda, 2016; Nishida, 2015). The use of
cars is calculated entirely based on CO2 emissions. uniform toll rates allows cross-subsidizing less profitable routes with
The annual vehicle tax on diesel-powered vehicles is higher than revenues from more profitable ones. Financial viability is thus to be
gasoline-powered ones, resulting in the use of diesel fuel being more achieved for the entire network, without this meaning that individual
economical only if the vehicle’s annual mileage exceeds 27,000 km. routes or segments with positive contribution margins cannot be viable
Road traffic taxation in Finland favors frequent road users and heavy on their own. Although cross-subsidization may not necessarily require
goods traffic, and in that perspective can be seen as in conflict with the toll rates to be uniform, different levels of rates across routes or
“polluter pays” principle. segments in a relatively small network would create confusion among
The aim of road traffic taxation is to collect funds for the Treasury. users. The author advocates that charging equal levels of rates would
The significance of these taxes to the country’s economy is substantial: also be more politically acceptable.
their combined total accounts for some 10% of the State's annual rev-
enues. 2.2.1.2. Differential toll rate by vehicle categories. Toll rate setting also
There are currently judicial restrictions preventing charges from involves an issue of specifying the number of vehicle categories to be
being levied for road use. Finland’s constitution states that public ser- charged different toll rates and the rate differences across categories.
vices must be financed from tax revenues. The Act on Criteria for That issue is been thoroughly discussed in Section 4.2.2, suggesting for
Charges Payable to the State provides that charges levied for public the CS case the use of nine vehicle categories in order to enhance the
services must be based on the per unit cost of providing those services. sense of fairness among users and to be more politically acceptable.
The Public Roads Act of 2006 also bans the levying of charges on public This number of categories can be raised or decreased in special cases
roads. should technical reasons so require.

2.2. Guiding principles 2.2.1.3. Fixed or distance-based toll rate. Another issue on toll rate
setting relates to the choice of distance-based or fixed toll rates.
The profitability of a toll road project, especially in inflationary Although a distance-based toll rate system is generally more
environments, will depend much on the toll level, or increases reasonable for toll operators, as it better reflects the cost of service, it
achievable by the operators.1 Accumulated world experience suggests a involves two major problems: requirements for large capacity at exits
number of general guidelines for setting and adjusting toll rates. Sub- and possible leakage in toll collection. Since payments in a distance-
issues relate to: (a) general guidelines for toll setting; and (b) toll ad- based system should be made at exits, land and staff requirements could
justment procedures. be large,2 which has been a primary reason for the use of fixed toll rates
for highways in Greece, Japan and elsewhere (ASECAP, 2018; Nishida,
2.2.1. General guidelines for toll setting 2015). Fixed rates on the other hand are not fair to users as they usually
General principles suggested by the World Bank (World Bank, 1999) correspond to a greater, if not to the maximum distance that can be

1 2
Toll profitability in deflationary environments is more a function of the Shortcomings of distance-based toll rates can be mitigated by the in-
operator’s ability to shape demand through demand orchestration. troduction of an Electronic Toll Collection (ETC) system.

1259
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

actually travelled. facing toll road investors—that of an unpredictable revenue stream.


A well-balanced approach would be to use a “quasi distance-based” Although this approach is quite attractive from a private investor’s
toll rate system where tariff levels on each individual segment are point of view, it does have other implications, such as the fixed esca-
calculated relevant to each segment’s length. In such system, a toll lation of toll rates and the implication this might have on future road
station can be installed in the middle of each segment (on the highway users who effectively subsidize the early ones. In addition, should in-
mainline) without need for large capacity at exits. Users entering the vestors come across a windfall there are no profit sharing provisions,
highway well before the toll station and exiting long after (before making them the only beneficiaries.
running onto the next station) will assume the greater benefits. Users As suggested by the experience of the Hong Kong SAR and the
entering the highway shortly before a toll station and exiting im- Philippines approach, uncertainty over toll adjustment procedures may
mediately after will bear the greatest losses. Local traffic between two discourage the private operators and investors. Such adjustment pro-
successive toll stations can be decided whether it should be left free or cedures are best agreed unambiguously within contracts. This paper
should be tolled, depending on the congestion levels of the highway and endorses that principle, but also offers specific recommendations re-
on the existing free alternatives that affect the neighboruing commu- garding the toll rate adaptation procedure—the following points come
nities. The extent to which a “quasi distance-based” system might work from lessons learned from the various experiences outlined above. More
in favor of the toll operator or the user depends (among others) on the specifically, if the actual traffic level is more than the forecast level at a
location where tolls are installed. If they are installed on segments specified time, the Governmental agency responsible for tolls could
connecting popular travel pairs the benefit is for the provider. Failing to request either the deferral of a toll rate increase or a lowering of that
intercept such pairs would result in the advantage passing on to the level. Likewise, if the actual traffic is less than forecasted, the operator
user. could request to bring forward the timing of toll rate increases.
As part of the tolling mechanism—particularly in the developing
2.2.2. Toll adjustment procedures countries—a toll stability fund could also be established to which in-
One issue central in a toll pricing strategy, is whether toll rate ad- come above the maximum allowed is channeled, in order to offset the
justments should be left to a Governmental authority’s discretion or need for future toll increases. That would give the potential toll op-
based on a formula, usually linked to price index changes. In any case, erator the certainty that tolls can be adjusted as the need arises, while
there is a need to follow specified toll adjustment procedures once they providing for a low and stable toll regime. It also offers confidence to
have been set; uncertainty creates problems for toll road operators. To the operator—if also an equity investor—that will reap a minimum
address the issue of toll rate adjustment an overview of best practices return on his investment. A toll stability fund would also give financiers
would be helpful. (banks and other lending organizations) the assurance that the project
Toll rate adjustments are at the discretion of the Ministry of Finance will be able to service its debt requirements over the contract period.
in France, which tends to approve larger increases for less profitable toll However, there still may be a problem if the operator’s revenues fall
operators. The French approach aims to constrain unnecessarily high short due to slower than expected traffic growth. In that case, a toll
returns to private investors, but at the risk of sacrificing efficiency by increase would just suppress demand without necessarily generating
undermining incentives to make exceptional efforts to control costs or more net revenue.
improve productivity (Gómez-Ibáñez and Meyer, 2013). In Italy an
automatic toll adjustment mechanism is in force, linked to inflation, 2.3. Traffic, tariff and revenue relationships
which has been agreed upon between ANAS (the National Road
Agency) and the toll road concessionaires. This mechanism allows for As mentioned above adjusting the toll level might have profound
periodic re-evaluation of the portion of toll rates that is more likely to effects on traffic volumes and revenue toll generated, and thus on the
be affected by inflation, i.e. operation and maintenance costs. Owing to ability of a Government to attain any of these goals. The purpose of this
that, toll rates in Italy have been raised nearly every year since the early Section is to illustrate some aspects of the traffic–revenue relationship,
1970s (Takeda, 2016). Spain’s approach is also based on a formula and how the available data can be used to make preliminary tariff
linked to price inflation. It has an advantage over the previous one in setting recommendations.
that it encourages new investment, while assuming less risk of unduly The Governmental authorities promoting tolls must have obtained
returns to private investors; that is because “excess” profits are moved precise data on the potential traffic and revenue that could be expected
to a Special Reserve (Gómez-Ibáñez and Meyer, 2013). In a completely from the implementation of the tolling programme. An “investment
different approach, Japan has commissioned an advisory board to re- grade traffic and revenue study” with emphasis on commercial policy
view periodically the appropriateness of toll rates taking into account (in order to avoid unnecessary public reaction) should be duly com-
the users’ opinion. Should adjustments are deemed necessary an inter- missioned, for the toll projects shortlisted for immediate launch. One of
Ministerial body, responsible for consumer price issues, has to make the key characteristics of an investment grade traffic revenue study is
approval for changes to take effect (Nishida, 2015). that it divides users into groups based upon their perception of value of
The experience of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region time, and their likely origin and destination. This allows more precise
(SAR) presents another toll adjustment mechanism, perhaps the most estimates of the number of users and amount of revenue that they might
interesting “best practice,” at least from a private operator point of view generate on various segments of a toll road over time and, how this may
(Tam, 2009). According to that, if traffic and therefore revenue falls be affected by variations in the toll level. That data is of critical im-
below a forecast volume, it will allow the operator to transfer the pre- portance in evaluating the ability of a toll road to repay public or pri-
agreed (toll) increase date forward. Conversely, if the amount of rev- vate borrowings used to construct the toll road itself, or to provide
enue received by the operator is above the forecasted—resulting in a revenue to finance other projects or activities. It is also of fundamental
rate of return exceeding a specified range—a toll increase will be de- importance in deciding how to develop toll rate charges and subsidiary
ferred. regulations.
Another interesting example of a toll adjustment mechanism can be Prior to the availability of data from an investment grade traffic and
found in the Philippines (Planta, 1998). Here a parametric formula revenue study, there are some less precise but easier to found indicators
calculates tariff adjustments based on a long list of economic and cur- of financial viability of a toll road. One of the most important factors
rency related variables, such as prevailing local and foreign interest affecting the success of tolls is affordability of the expected users, which
rates, the consumer’s and construction materials’ price index and so on. could be expressed in terms of the economic concept of unwillingness-
The automatic fare adjustment, along with the fact that the results are to-pay. A related concept is that of Value of Time (VoT), which com-
guaranteed by the Government, alleviate one of the most common risks bines the ideas of affordability, willingness-to-pay and other factors into

1260
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

a measure of the value that any specific user group will perceive from policy.
the time savings provided by a faster travel option such as a tolled
highway. 3.1. Definition of policy-focused scenarios
When user VoT exceeds the proposed toll levels, then the user may
find the toll road to be a potentially attractive option. If the general VoT To set the overall framework in which toll rates can be designated
is below the implicit tolls, then the toll road may be unaffordable to the our model employs scenario analysis to gauge the possible future policy
user considered. In extreme cases, the average income of the user might and economic context that affect tariff setting and adjustment.
be so low that the ability to pay is called into question. In other words, (Draeger, 2010; Wiek et al., 2006; Bradfield et al., 2005; Ringland,
the toll can be set so high that the user simply cannot afford to pay it 1998). Thus, different scenarios are used which in an “IF…THEN…”
under any circumstances. proposition, provide the “IF” part.
To define the scenarios it is important to have prior identify the
2.4. Tariff setting risk specific policies that, in a given institutional context, contribute mostly
to the achievement of toll objectives. In this research, we consider
Tolls—particularly private operated options—require a high degree equity and economic affordability as the key policy variables that create
of certainty that a given toll rate will be applied for a sustained period an environment for successful tolling, facilitating the identification of
of time. Private investors expect to be repaid, either from toll revenues projects likely to be launched without major delay as they are expected
or direct Government subsidies or both. In a country where guaranteed to face barriers to implementation of low or no significance.
long term financial support to a toll project appears to be rather pro- The allocation of specific policies such as equity and affordability to
blematic, application of tolls seems to be the only method available that tolling objectives allows then for the systematic identification of tariffs
could ensure repayment of private investment. that respond in the best possible way to the policy needs, while re-
Nevertheless, tolls are almost never popular with the public, poli- specting the limitations imposed by traffic levels and possibly high
tical pressures to reduce or eliminate tolls are frequent, and as can be maintenance & operating costs. Equity and affordability implications
seen from late experience (cf. the M50 case in Ireland) might result in here are understood as follows:
outcomes that can be extremely costly to the Government.
The author advocates that parallel to the investment grade traffic 1. Equity refers to any change in the distribution of costs and benefits,
revenue study a Government willing to successfully promote tolling relative to the existing distribution, resulting from the introduction
must work on a toll regulation strategy that is: of tolls. The importance of comparing equity implications of a toll
project with alternative approaches to achieving the same objectives
• well founded in national law; is noteworthy. Alternatives may, of course, range all the way from
• sufficient to ensure that the Government has overall control of the enhancing other travel modes, to a combination of approaches, or
setting and collection of road tolls; doing nothing.
• flexible enough to facilitate the specific needs of highway operation It is also useful to understand the different perspectives of equity.
or maintenance contracts as they arise, and The so-called “horizontal equity” perspective is concerned with
• providing sufficient insulation from the rest of the political process. fairness among individuals and society groups with similar re-
sources and needs. Thus, in the case of a toll project, concerns of
3. Presentation of the model horizontal equity leads to examination of costs and benefits by
geographic area, or by users and non-users. A geographic view
At a very basic Level, the key questions toll facilitators should ad- would seek to compare benefits and payment burdens by individuals
dress are why, where, what, how, when and by whom should tolling be from different geographic locations in the region. A user versus a
applied. The first two issues are more focused on identification or non-user view would aim to estimate what benefits are received and
screening of toll opportunities and are thoroughly discussed in Panou payments made by users of the tolled facility versus those with si-
(2019); the next three issues (what, how and when) relate to tariff milar travel needs and desires who opt for alternative ways to
setting and implementation challenges and are addressed here; the last paying the toll. Since tolling typically makes the users who benefit
issue relates to toll operating entity and is not addressed in this paper. pay for most of (or more of) the costs of improvements, it is in-
The aim of this Section is to produce a model related to preliminary herently likely to be more equitable from the horizontal perspective
assessment of the tariff structure that should be applied by tolls. The than most other approaches to capacity expansion.
focus of the work has thus been to develop a tool, which seeks to The perspective on equity often referred to as “vertical equity” is the
combine information on infrastructure characteristics, traffic, user be- viewpoint concerned with differential effects on groups defined by
havior and explicit policy objectives to compute the minimum toll rate socioeconomic factors such as income and gender, or other measures
that could be charged per vehicle-kilometer (veh-km) on a given vo- of inherently advantaged or disadvantaged status. The associated
lume of traffic to cover all costs. benefit and cost assessments often turn out to be complex since one
The suggested mode builds on break-even analysis to deliver tariff must start with current travel behavior and burdens by these dif-
structures as acceptable as possible in the context of commercial and ferent segments of population and then estimate differential impacts
social considerations. It can be applied within a process comprising of pricing on these same segments.
three steps: The literature is abundant with discussions about the vertical equity
of road tolls (Manville, 2017; Schweitzer, 2009; Schweitzer and
• Definition of policy-focused scenarios, generating information on Taylor, 2008; Shaheen et al., 2019). Critics argue that tolls are re-
specific policies such as equity and economic affordability and al- gressive (they burden poorer motorists) but advocates point out that
locating them to a number of tolling objectives; such tolls are less regressive than other roadway funding sources. In
• Tariff setting, where the model is applied for each considered sce- our scenario building approach the vertical equity implications
nario to calculate base rates for low 2-axle vehicles (cars). Based on make three points. First, the net effect of tolls depends on how toll
these rates differential tariffs by vehicle category are established and revenues will be spent. If revenues are redistributed, i.e. used for the
checks are carried out to verify household affordability to tariffs and maintenance and expansion of non-tolled roads, tolls need not result
traffic to tariff sensitivity; largely in gains for higher-income groups and losses for lower-in-
• Tariff adjustment, laying out the toll implementation plan with clear come groups. Second, the net benefits are likely to be greater for
recommendations on toll duration, tariff escalation and commercial higher-income groups under any but the most progressive

1261
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

redistribution schemes. Third, even with a revenue redistribution Let n be the number of road segments for each reference scenario; Pi
scheme it is impossible to ensure that all travelers within a parti- the minimum rate that could be charged per veh-km in road segment i
cular income class are compensated. Thus, a revenue redistribution (i = 1,2,3,…,n); and Ti the number of veh-km travelled on each seg-
scheme cannot completely ensure equity. Realistically, of course, ment. Find the minimum value of Pi that maximizes the sum
very little is completely equitable. R = i Pi Ti , where R is the total toll revenue.
2. Affordability refers to people’s ability to purchase important goods Since both the Pi and Ti are strictly increasing functions, the opti-
and services. In transportation, affordability refers to people’s fi- mization problem stated above cannot be solved unless one of the two
nancial ability to access important goods and activities such as functions, or their output R is bounded from above.
medical care, basic shopping, education, work, and socializing Setting R C , where C is the total maintenance and operation cost
(Litman, 2009). of the reference network, the minimum required value Pi can be ob-
Considering transportation affordability in tolling is fundamental, as tained as follows:
it causes significant problems in communities that rely primarily on
low- to medium-income workers and lower-income households. On 1. The (Pi, Ti) pairs are firstly sorted from the smallest Pi to the largest.
those communities unaffordable tariffs imposes disproportionate Then for i = 1 we compute R = P1*T1.
financial burdens and constrains people’s mobility and opportu- 2. For i = 2 we compute again: R = P2*(T1 + T2). We repeat this step
nities. for i = 3 and until the boundary condition of equation R C is
met—N.B. for each increment of i the cumulative Ti is used instead
To operationalize the specified scenarios the following factors have of the individual value.
to be considered: 3. The value P f corresponding to the last road segment adding to the
demand needed to achieve R = C, is the minimum toll rate—-
• Network coverage—i.e. the total length (in km) of the road network hereafter called the Base Rate (BR)—that could be charged per veh-
km to cover all costs.
considered;
• Tolled projects—the length (in Km) of tolled roads in the considered It might happen that the road segments i which satisfy the condition
network;
• Base rate—corresponding to a minimum rate that could be imposed R = C are not those with the highest traffic—are certainly those with
the most veh-km. To identify the road segments with the necessary
in a typical low 2-axle vehicle class category per kilometer;
• Maintenance cost covered—by applying the base rate in the con- surplus of demand to be tolled it takes:
sidered network.
• Resorting of pairs P , T , according to the road segments’ annual
i i
The issue of scenario operationalization is more thoroughly dis- average daily traffic (AADT), from the smallest to the largest;
cussed in Section 4.1 with an application example. • obtained in theofprevious
Recalculation the total revenue R = P
step.
T , using the base rate P
f
i i
f

3.2. Tariff setting


The break-even point here defines (i) the road segments likely to be
Starting point is the calculation of veh-km travelled on each can- tolled at that rate, and (ii) is dependent on the costs sought to cover.
didate toll road of the reference network of each considered scenario.
The maintenance requirements of those networks are then assessed
assuming all activities needed to achieve and maintain a certain level of 3.3. Tariff adjustment
service for road users, including:
Tariff adjustment is necessary for cost-recovery road tolls to ensure
• Routine maintenance: Works carried out on a regular basis in order to that future toll revenues will be sufficient to retire debt, pay for the
costs of operation, maintenance and future capital improvements, and
maintain the base condition and functionality of the network—ex-
amples are verge vegetation cutting, drainage cleaning, and basic provide a reasonable return to investors. Raising debt and equity for
maintenance of traffic devices. these projects, whether for construction or for payment of any upfront
• Periodic maintenance: Works undertaken to maintain acceptable level fee, requires a reasonable adjustment procedure to assure that revenues
from tolls will be sufficient for these purposes.
of pavement condition, riding quality, road comfort and safety
through periodic interventions—examples are resealing and overlay Under public ownership, toll rate increases have rarely reflected
pavement works, which are carried out in response to measured inflation, and some have not even provided for the increasing cost of
deterioration in road condition. maintaining the toll roads. This is primarily due to the fact that there
are generally weak incentives for public operators to price roads at a
The operating costs of tolls are calculated thereafter. In the absence socially optimal level.
of previous experience from tolls in the area of interest, the calculation For congested facilities, setting maximum fixed toll rates will likely
of operating costs can be based on the cost per transaction of an be in conflict with a desire to minimize congestion through variable
Electronic Toll Collection (ETC) system—instead of the manual cost—as pricing. For those projects, limiting returns on equity or providing for
this does not differ greatly from country to country, and therefore can revenue sharing can be used in lieu of rate caps to protect against
provide grounds for safer and more comparable calculations. monopoly profits.
Summing the operating and maintenance costs of each considered While private operators are usually allowed to increase toll rates in
road segment, and dividing the resulting costs with the corresponding accordance with major economic indices, they are not required to do so,
number of veh-km, the total maintenance and operating costs per veh- and have strong incentives not to increase the toll rates if it would
km is obtained. This value corresponds to a minimum rate that could be decrease use of the facility and reduce revenues.
charged per veh-km, without causing losses to the toll operator, but also Our approach uses experience from recent agreements for operation
without contributing to the amortization of fixed costs—contribution of existing or newly constructed toll roads to develop guidelines on how
margin is zero. often and how much toll rates could be increased. The process used to
At this point the mathematical problem which arises, regarding the adjust toll r involves setting the principles that mandate toll duration &
calculation of the minimum toll rate that could be charged per veh-km, tariff escalation, and developing the toll commercial policy. This pro-
is the following: cess is described in the application example in Section 4.3 below.

1262
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

4. Application of the model in the CS kilometer (pax-km) is calculated at about 0.50 min;
• The passenger time savings are converted into EUR saved per pax-
4.1. Definition of policy-focused scenarios km using a VoT of 2.6 EUR/h; the result is 0.021 EUR;
• Multiplying the 0.021 EUR saved per pax-km with the average
To identify equitable and affordable toll rates in the CS, two explicit occupancy rate of 1.63, a 0.035 EUR saved per veh-km is ob-
policy scenarios have been specified: tained.
• Total maintenance costs—Routine maintenance (vegetation cutting,
• a diffusion scenario, and drainage cleaning, basic maintenance of traffic devices, etc.) and
• a retrenchment scenario. periodic maintenance (resealing and overlay pavement works) are
considered, as mentioned, in the cost estimation. Costs take account
The diffusion scenario assumes welfare maximization by applying the of road geometry, type of terrain, weather conditions and geo-
smallest possible toll rate to a bulk of demand needed to generate technical/hydraulic risks.
sufficient revenue for the operation and maintenance needs of the en- • Cost of tolling plaza operation including revenue collection—In the ab-
tire network (breakeven condition). sence of previous experience from tolls in the CS, average EU and US
The retrenchment scenario assumes revenue maximization by ap- values were used as a proxy for assessing transaction costs of the
plying the maximum rate users can bear (also called the “‘affordability ETC (found between 0.04 and 0.10 EUR) and manual collection (in
threshold”) to a bulk of demand needed to generate sufficient revenue the range of 0.33–0.43 EUR). Construction costs of a toll plaza were
for the operation and maintenance of a selected network of primary (P) provided by the TA; it is about 150.000 EUR per lane. Whilst con-
and main secondary (SP) roads. structing and operating more than one tolling plazas will generate
To operationalize the specified scenarios the following factors have more revenue, there would be significant extra costs.
been considered: • Wider effects—Suppressed demand from applying tolls has been
determined assuming (in the interest of prudence) elasticity be-
• Network coverage—From the road inventory data provided by the tween cost and demand changes of −1. This value is representative
TA, the total length of the considered road network under the dif- of a 10% decrease in demand following a 10% increase of the
fusion scenario was set at 4250 km, while for the retrenchment generalized costs (including the toll) currently incurred by passen-
scenario the total length was set at 1380 km. gers. The issue of suppressed demand is more thoroughly discussed
• Results of WTP surveys—The results of the available CS’ surveys in Section 4.2.4.
showed value of time for car users of 2.6 EUR and for trucks of
13.4 EUR. Car occupancy rate has been found at 3.27. The figure With the preceding points in mind, Figs. 1 and 2 illustrate the dif-
was deemed too high (the corridor is serving long distance tourist fusion and retrenchment scenario used in the CS case, with their dif-
traffic which usually means entire families traveling together) for ferent variants defined along the axes of equity and affordability.
national average and has been reduced to 1.63 based on data pub- It can be noted in the two scenarios that the tolling scope (network
lished by Schiffer (2012). That value is in the range of the European coverage) changes with the equity perspective (100 km for vertical
(1.6) and US (1.5) averages, reflecting also trends (higher con- equity, 300 km for horizontal equity, 200 km for in between),3 whereas
solidation) due to the recent economic crisis (International the Basic toll Rates (BR) change with affordability level from
Transport Forum, 2012). 0.005 EUR/veh-km to 0.035 EUR/veh-km4 (low affordability stipulates
• Tolling levels in neighbouring countries—Average toll rates in neigh- low toll rates and vice-versa). Moreover, the contribution margin5 (up
bouring country A range between 0.02 and 0.03 EUR per km for cars over 100% in maintenance cost covered) appears positive throughout
and pickups. Medium trucks are charged 2–3 times more. The toll variants r1 to r5 of the retrenchment scenario, namely 197%, 138%,
level is lower for neighbouring country B and C, ranging for do- 35%, 81% and 46%; and in variant d7 of the diffusion scenario (16%).
mestic vehicles between 0.01 and 0.04 EUR per km and up to 20 Another interesting observation in the above illustrations is that the
cents per km for large trucks. Foreign car owners in country B are closer one gets to the lower left corner of Fig. 1, the closer is to the
paying between 0.07 and 0.075 EUR per km depending on the “social” end of the tolling policy spectrum. The more one approaches
specific toll road. In country C a car is charged 2.5 EUR for a 40 km the top right corner of Fig. 2, the closer gets to more “liberal” tolling
trip (rate of 6 cents per km) offering a saving of 45 km or over 1 h of policies where the philosophy is “pay what you get and get what you
travel time over the alternative route. Likewise, the toll level in pay”. Variant d1 (of the diffusion scenario) represents the most “social”
neighbouring country D ranges from 0.03 to 0.05 EUR per vehicle policy of all, whereas variant r3 (of the retrenchment scenario) the most
kilometer. “liberal” one.
• Level of toll in comparison to fuel costs and driver incomes—Fuel costs
in the CS are typically 1.1 EUR per liter, and this equates to between
8 and 10 cents per km travelled for a car. Fuel rates for buses and 4.2. Tariff setting
trucks are higher. Total vehicle costs can rise up to 40 cents per km
considering fuel and non-fuel costs. 4.2.1. Base rate
• Time savings per veh-km—Using the average speed on the primary By applying the model outlined in Section 3.2, the minimum toll
rate that could be charged per veh-km to cover all costs is calculated.
and secondary CS network, time saving benefits were estimated in
the region of 0.035 EUR/veh-km (Basic Rate—BR for the diffusion This is a 0.005 EUR/veh-km rate that could be imposed in a typical low
scenario). This value roughly represents the maximum toll rate that 2-axle vehicle class category per kilometer (Basic Rate—BR for the re-
could be imposed in a typical low 2-axle vehicle class category per trenchment scenario) without causing losses to the toll operator, but
kilometer. It corresponds to about 20–40% of total user cost savings
as it does not account for fuel and non-fuel vehicle- or safety-related 3
The 100, 200 and 300km toll coverage was the result of an open con-
cost savings. This maximum toll rate is also called the affordability
sultation process between the TA and other political, financial and social sta-
threshold and it is calculated as follows: keholders.
• From the road inventory data (provided by the TA), an average 4
For details on the calculation of those values see Section 4.2.1.
speed of 78 km/h is calculated for highways and 45 km/h for the 5
Definition: the portion of toll revenue that is not consumed by maintenance
alternative network; and operating costs and so contributes to the amortization of the im-
• Based on the speed difference, average time saved per passenger- plementation cost.

1263
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

Fig. 1. . The diffusion scenario.

also without contributing to the amortization of fixed costs—recall that in time.


the 0.035 EUR/veh-km (Basic Rate—BR for the diffusion scenario) re-
presents the maximum toll rate that could be imposed in the same
vehicle class category per kilometer. Both the 0.005 EUR/veh-km and 4.2.2. Tariff structure by vehicle categories
0.035 EUR/veh-km rate set the envelope of tariff variation in the CS Tariff setting involves also an issue of specifying the number of
case. vehicle categories to be charged different toll rates and the rate dif-
With the preceding points in mind, Table 1 calculates the total ferences across categories. Current practice for inter-city highways
revenue generated from applying the base rates for the different sce- (France, Italy, Japan, and Spain) suggests five vehicle categories most
narios, as well as the annual average daily traffic, the total operation commonly used; although ways of classifying them vary somewhat
and maintenance costs, and the number of veh-km of roads with the across countries. A larger number of categories tends to enhance the
highest levels of traffic. Note that these roads are organized in pools of sense of fairness and thus is more politically acceptable. For that reason,
100 km, 200 km and 300 km, which reflect our recommendation to the the number of vehicle categories to be charged different toll rates was
CS Government of different waves of investment at different moments raised in the CS from five to nine. With this change, complaints by users
about vehicle categorization are expected to decrease. But there might

Fig. 2. . The retrenchment scenario.

1264
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

Table 1
. Toll revenues, traffic, veh-km and total costs of roads with the highest levels of traffic.
Road name Road segment AADT Length (km) Veh-km travelled Total cost Toll revenue Toll revenue
(EUR/km) (BR—retrenchment) (BR diffusion)

100 km—First wave of investment


Road 1 (autostrada) Segment 1-i 31.268 11,50 359.582 17,84 1.798 3.596
Road 1 (autostrada) Segment 1-ii 29.631 7,30 216.306 18,61 1.082 2.163
Road 1 (autostrada) Segment 1-iii 29.631 4,90 145.192 19,63 726 1.452
Road 1 (autostrada) Segment 1-iv 29.631 4,50 133.340 19,90 667 1.333
Road 2 (B) Segment 2-i 24.157 10,50 253.649 16,52 1.268 2.536
Road 2 (B) Segment 2-ii 24.157 7,30 176.346 8,91 882 1.763
Road 2 (B) Segment 2-iii 24.157 7,00 169.099 16,52 845 1.691
Road 2 (B) Segment 2-iv 19.069 9,70 184.969 19,42 925 1.850
Road 2 (B) Segment 2-v 19.547 7,85 153.444 17,20 767 1.534
Road 2 (B) Segment 2-vi 19.547 4,60 89.916 11,15 450 899
Road 2 (B) Segment 2-vii 10.588 12,10 128.115 17,20 641 1.281
Road 2 (B) Segment 2-viii 10.588 9,20 97.410 10,52 487 974
Road 3 (B) Segment 3-i 19.547 8,10 158.331 6,31 792 1.583

200 km—Second wave of investment


Road 3 (B) Segment 3-ii 10.588 39,00 412.932 10,52 2.065 4.129
Road 4 (A1) Segment 4-i 10.423 11,60 120.907 10,63 605 1.209
Road 4 (A1) Segment 4-ii 14.604 8,20 119.753 18,35 599 1.198
Road 4 (A1) Segment 4-iii 9.685 9,70 93.945 13,54 470 939
Road 4 (A1) Segment 4-iv 8.335 16,40 136.694 11,68 683 1.367

300 km—Third wave of investment


Road 4 (A1) Segment 4-v 4.044 35,60 143.966 11,66 720 1.440
Road 5 (A2) Segment 5-i 1.200 24,20 290.400 17,56 1.452 2.904
Road 6 (A3) Segment 6-i 6.500 12,90 83.850 6,30 419 839
Road 7 (C) Segment 7-i 4.507 20,50 92.394 12,60 462 924
Road 7 (C) Segment 7-ii 4.107 21,10 86.658 15,17 433 867
Totals 303,75 3.847.198 327,74 19.238 38.470

A: Highway, B: Main Interurban, C: Interurban Secondary.

be cases during the application of the tariffs where a smaller number of small portion for household savings at the rate of 3% (estimate).
vehicle categories would be desirable, primarily for technical reasons. It can be seen in Table 4 that about 94 EUR is spent monthly on
For example, toll plazas with long queues in order to minimize time and luxuries covering restaurants, hotels, recreation, culture, tobacco and
queue length for toll collection might consider using less vehicle cate- alcohol, which can be considered “elastic” expenditures that could be
gories. avoided. That amount can be thought of, roughly, as the maximum
There is no simple equation or a universal theory to determine rate amount of extra toll charges that could be afforded by households in the
differences across vehicle types. For inter-city highways for example, a CS per month (in 2014 prices).
fairly substantial variation is observed in the extent of rate differences. With the preceding points regarding luxury spending in mind, the
It is also often argued that commercial vehicles including trucks and possible impact of tolls on the household budget is illustrated in the
buses are favored in terms of the toll levels; as compared to the capital following representative example. Assume that a household6 car spends
and maintenance costs incurred by those vehicles. For a country like the on average 10 days per month on toll roads and travels 30 km per day.
CS it is strongly recommended that a lower rate for buses should be If the toll rate is 0.01 EUR per km (basic rate for some variants of the
applied as part of the welfare maximization (diffusion) scenario to diffusion scenario—see Section 4.1 above), the monthly toll budget
support public transport operators and to encourage bus use. would correspond to an additional 3.0 EUR per month, i.e. an 11%
To facilitate the allocation of infrastructure costs into the considered increase in the household transport budget, or a 3% shift from luxury
vehicle classes, class coefficients have been used to obtain the dis- spending to offset the increased transport costs. Likewise, if the toll rate
tribution of toll rates shown in Table 2. It can be seen that motorcycles/ is 0.02 EUR per km (intermediate rate—see Section 4.1), the monthly
tricycles pay 0.5 times (50%) the basic rate, vehicles with 4 axles pay toll budget would correspond to an additional 6.0 EUR per month,
1.5 times (150%), vehicles with 4 axles (including buses) pay 2–3 times leading to a 22% increase in the household transport budget and a 6%
(200–300%), vehicles with 5–6 axles pay 3 times (300%) the basic rate, shift between luxury and transport spending. Finally, if the toll rate is
and so on. 0.035 EUR per km (affordability threshold—also in Section 4.1), the
It is important to note that the suggested tariff structure constitutes monthly toll budget would correspond to an additional 10.5 EUR per
preliminary recommendation on how the CS should accomplish a fair month or a 39% increase in the household transport budget, requiring
and reciprocating road pricing scheme. That structure can change in the an 11% reallocation of luxury budget.
duration of the application of tolls within the lines of any potential Those values advocate that the additional burden created on
private sector contract or under a certain threshold. Of course, toll rates household budget by toll rates less than 0.035 EUR per km is quite
can also be adapted yearly according to the consumer price index. affordable. Rates of 0.01–0.025 EUR per km can be considered accep-
table by the average CS’s household. Of course, special (higher) rates of
0.05, 0.06 EUR per km or more might be applied in cases of selective
4.2.3. Assessment of toll affordability
tolling or where a free alternative route does not exist, but suppressed
Table 3 shows per capita GDP and average household income for
demand from applying these rates should be thoroughly investigated.
countries in the CS region with indication that Country F has by far the
highest figures.
Table 4 demonstrates the proportion of income spent on essentials
and luxuries, and the likely impact of increased transport costs on the
CS’s household expenditures. Note that the expenditure level indicates a 6
Average household size in the CS was 3.9 in 2011.

1265
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

Table 2
. Tariff structure and vehicle classes likely to be tolled.

Table 3 sensitivity to changes in toll rates is indicated by the changes in the


. Per capita GDP and average net (after taxes) wage. traffic levels on the new highway.
Country Per capita Monthly average income Average monthly net Following the mandate of current best-practices to account for toll
GDP (PPP)a per household in EUR wage EUR (2014)** elasticity, suppressed demand has been determined in the CS assuming
EUR (2014 (2014)** elasticity between cost and demand changes of −1 (see Section 4.1).
est.)* This value implies that a 10% increase of the generalized costs currently
CS 10,248 515 420
incurred by users will cause a 10% decrease in demand.
Country A 14,033 660 478 For the calculation of the generalized cost the following equation is
Country B 7386 450 360 used:
Country C 9048 680 415
Country D 12,187 590 353 Section length Segment length · Vehicle Costs
Country E 11,540 554 363 Generalized cos t = ·VoT +
Country F 23,819 1200 1004
Average speed Average occupancy rate

* Source: The World Fact Book, CIA, 2015. where “Segment length” is given in km, “Average speed” in km/h, the
** Source: National sources. “Value of Time (VoT)” is in hours and the “Vehicle costs” are in EUR/km.
a
Purchasing Power Parity. Following the calculations of the generalized costs, three alternative
rates have been tested for possible suppression effects on demand:
Table 4
. Average monthly household expenditure in the CS.
• A base rate, i.e. 0.01 and 0.005 EUR per km for the diffusion and
7

Main household expenditure categories by Total monthly household the retrenchment scenario respectively;
COICOP* expenditure** • intermediate rate of 0.02 EUR per km, and
An

EUR %
• A maximum rate of 0.035 EUR per km.
Food and non-alcoholic beverages 195 39% The maximum toll rate (affordability threshold) is calculated as
Alcoholic beverages, tobacco and narcotics 16 3% shown in Section 4.1.
Clothing and footwear 20 4% When imposing a base rate of 0.01 EUR per km traffic, under the
Housing, water, electricity, gas and other fuels 65 13% diffusion scenario, responds with an average decrease of 3.16%. The
Furnishing, households equipment and routine 30 6%
maintenance of the house
traffic declines by between 2.98% and 3.44% depending on the seg-
Health 24 5% ments. When testing the traffic for the retrenchment scenario (base rate
Transport 27 5% at 0.005 EUR per km), the average decrease in traffic is 1.39% corre-
Communications 9 2% sponding to a decline of 1.31% to 1.51%, also depending on the seg-
Recreation and culture 64 13%
ments.
Education 15 3%
Restaurants and hotels 14 3% When imposing an intermediate toll rate of 0.02 EUR per km, the
Miscellaneous goods and services 20 4% model yields an average decrease of 6.85% in traffic, which varies
Total monthly household expenditure 500 between 6.47% and 7.46% depending on the segments.
Finally, when testing the traffic for the maximum toll rate
* Classification of Individual Consumption According to Purpose.
(0.035 EUR per km) the average decrease in traffic is 11.9%, corre-
** Projected data based on the 2007 CS’s National Census.
sponding to a decline of between 11.25% and 12.97% depending on the
segments.
4.2.4. Traffic sensitivity to tariffs and impact on total toll revenue
Applying tolling will reduce the traffic on a highway, as some users
will prefer the existing road rather than paying for using the new
highway. Those users will only obtain limited time savings and safety
savings, as they will stay on the existing road, imposing an economic 7
These values are calculated by applying the break-even model of Section
loss and, hence, reducing potential benefits for the new highway. The
4.2.1.

1266
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

4.3. Tariff adjustment not—may be set by the Government in advance of the actual tender or
be part of the decision criteria for selecting the preferred bidder.
4.3.1. Duration of tolls Caution, however, should be exercised on the importance assigned to
It is known that the objectives of applying tolls include among toll duration as a selection criterion; if it is the only one, it may have
others: unexpected effects, like in Mexico, where toll rates soared causing many
toll road operators to fail and appeal for Government bailout (Gómez-
• Covering construction costs for new roads; Ibáñez, 2007).
• Covering improvement/rehabilitation/capacity expansion cost for
existing road network;
• Covering maintenance and operation of existing road network. 4.3.2. Tariff escalation policy
Tariff escalation is generally defined as the policy or rules by which
Deciding the time frame for tolls is a complex issue that depends toll fees change in the long run. Depending on whether or not there is
primarily on the following parameters: private participation, price escalation may be provided:

• Tolling objective; • As a rule in the feasibility study when tolls are intended to cover
• Expected revenue; construction costs, or when the private sector is involved;
• Private sector involvement. • As a budgetary need of the Governmental authority in charge of
tolls, when there is no private sector involvement.
Should tolls are aimed at covering construction costs, the tolling
period can be long depending on the project’s financial structure, the When a Governmental authority is the sole body responsible for
anticipated traffic and the implementation cost. Should traffic levels are setting the toll tariffs, escalation is in line with the forecasted annual
high, toll duration may be shorter. But when the public sector bears the budgetary needs. It is usually based on Consumer Price Index (CPI) or
cost, it is very common that the tolling period expends indefinitely; inflation, either as a whole or as a percentage e.g. 95% of CPI. Tariff
with the notable exception of Japan which has made 61 roads toll free escalation may also be based on the GDP annual change ratio, though
after recovering construction costs. this is not usual. Tariff escalation time may be set annually or more
When the primary toll objective is to cover improvement/re- infrequently.
habilitation/capacity expansion costs then the tolling period depends As tariff escalation is primarily a Governmental decision, it is likely
on the length of network, expected revenue and is usually long. In the to be affected by other non-financial factors, political or social, such as
case of public tolls, this period is usually extended after the cost has public opposition and local contingencies. For example in Texas, the
been recovered because Governments would rarely admit their goals toll rates on the Dallas North Tollway have not been increased since
have been achieved. 1982 (STF, 2018). This is not an unusual situation where toll roads are
When the private sector is involved, project economics change as managed by the public sector.
new costs and benefits arise with a private sector contract. A typical In cases, however, where the private sector is involved in the op-
format of private sector involvement is a Build-Operate-Transfer (BOT) eration of tolls, the tariff escalation formula is normally negotiated and
concession which grant the concessionaire the right to construct agreed prior to contract signing. Of course, over the contract period
maintain and toll a road over a certain period of time after which the much is likely to change, including the costs of major inputs, specific
road is transferred to Government. service requirements as well as the wider legal, social and economic
Factors to be taken into account for the duration of a BOT project environment in which the contractor operates. Thus, toll contracts
include: should be flexible as to allow prices to be adjusted over time, without
prior knowledge of what these adjustments should be or what will
• Pre-construction issues (e.g., environmental issues, possible oppo- trigger them.
sition from special interest groups, legal issues and problems in se- Regarding concession agreements, the majority includes a toll es-
curing project financing); calation formula that is related to the consumer price in-
• Uncertainty in traffic and demand issues; dex—sometimes also to foreign exchange devaluation—allowing for
• Investment/business risks (revenues, costs, interest rate, inflation); toll increases every year or every once in a few years. In Spain, for
• Taxation and regulatory risks; example, the toll rate review system for the highways granted by the
• Construction risks such as cost over runs, delays and specifications Government takes into consideration the Consumer Price Index cor-
not met, etc. rected by a coefficient that shows the difference between the estimated
• Risks in operations; AADT (Average Annual Daily Traffic) and the real ADT, while in
• Competition from existing high quality toll-free routes; Portugal tariffs are adjusted up to 90% of the annual CPI. It should be
• Risk in maintenance and rehabilitation cycles. mentioned that small annual increases can be easier for users to in-
corporate in their spending patterns than larger, but less frequent rises.
The determination of the duration of a toll contract is based inter Economic forecasts and financial analysis should however consider, as a
alia on: sensitivity test, the failure to increase tolls for several years and a
failure to agree/pay specified compensation.
• Toll objective, i.e. covering construction or maintenance costs or It is also noteworthy that in toll operation agreements there is often
both; a clause providing for Governmental approval of any increases and
• Financial instruments available—in some markets there is no pos- compensation arrangements, should that approval is withheld.
sibility of long term financing from the private sector; Government approval, however, is not always given and operators do
• Political imperatives/security concerns. not always receive the specified compensation immediately. This is an
area of considerable political interest, and increases might meet violent
Typical BOT concessions last from 20 to 30 years, whereas main- opposition from the public, particularly if the economy is weak. To use
tenance contracts or concessions are usually shorter, ranging from again the example of Spain, the central Government and some regional
-5 years. The reason for this spread in duration is the difference in fi- Governments have reduced the toll rates or have frozen the annual
nancial requirements. review of the rates. In all cases, they were obliged to compensate the
The duration of a toll contract—be it a concession agreement or concession holding company (Gómez-Ibáñez and Meyer, 2013).

1267
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

4.3.3. Commercial policy business targets;


4.3.3.1. Basic actions. For CS tolls to succeed in their goals the • The toll services have to achieve a certain degree of market pene-
forecasted revenue should be achieved. This in turn means that users tration;
must use the infrastructure despite any possible suppression effects • User base must be continuously growing in order to generate in-
from the application of tolls. To “sell” tolls to the road users a creased revenue over time in order to cover operating and devel-
commercial policy has to be planned and implemented from the toll opment costs.
operator with a twofold aim:
Assuming that the pricing and market size issues are thoroughly
• Offer the right product in the right price; investigated before a toll project is launched, and that the majority of
• Increase the number of users, thus generating more income. revenue risks are hedged contractually, it remains for the toll operator
to develop a sufficient user base which should be able to expand over
This paper has recognized the basic elements of a CS’s toll com- time.
mercial policy, which include: Accumulated experience shows that conditions in road tolling may
change over time and competition (in the form of alternative routes or
1. User segmentation: User segmentation is necessary to establish a modes of transport) may come even from the State itself for various
differential pricing scheme based on user characteristics. Basic user reasons. What is important to maintain is the user base which should
segmentation classifies users by: remain stable or potentially expanding as a guarantee of a constant

Vehicle type (category) based on the number of axles which re- revenue stream. It is important for users to feel that they are charged for
presents the road space used by the vehicle and the damage that something that is of value to them rather than to feel that they are
the vehicle causes on the road pavement; paying another tax in the most inconvenient way (having to stop to do

Frequency of use, where users are classified as frequent/regular or so).
occasional users depending on the number of trips in a certain To establish this sense of worthwhileness, a campaign should be run
time period (usually monthly). in the CS before introducing the tolls. That campaign should stress the
2. Basic products definition/pricing: Basic products should cover the advantages of using the tolled roads (safety, traveling speed, quality,
needs for both the frequent and the occasional user and should be etc.) from many different perspectives. For example, the use of ETC is a
applied to both manual and electronic methods of payment. For feature central to that campaign. Advantages of ETC that could be ad-
example, a special prepaid smart card issued by the toll operator is vertised include ease of use, no need for cash, less time spent in toll
an option that could be used to pay tolls manually. It is important plazas, dedicated lanes and possible reductions for the subscription
that all products offered do not make subscription obligatory; there program offered. The ETC has significant advantages for the operator
should be at least one product per vehicle category for occasional (lower operating cost, less cash handling, higher throughput in toll
users and at least one per vehicle category of frequent users. plazas, advance payment capability for pre-paid subscription), so every
Additional products (subscription products/packages) may also be effort to establish a considerable base of ETC users would generate
defined targeted to different classes of frequent users as the system is significant economic benefits for the toll project. ETC campaigns should
established and the number of users increases or the user segmen- be run regularly especially when a new subscription program is about
tation becomes more detailed. Pricing of these products usually to be introduced. Local campaigns may also be run to attract local
depends on the number of trips per month and/or time of day. commuters and leaflets about ETC use should be given to every user
3. Advertising/product introduction actions: An integrated marketing that pays cash in the toll plazas for a long period. While ETC to occa-
program should be in place before the launching of any new product sional users is an option, the main effort remains to frequent users who
or to increase the penetration of an existing one. Newspaper ads, should be encouraged to enter a subscription program or package.
leaflets in toll stations, radio spots, banners in popular internet sites Similarly, subscription programs/packages need to be established
are some indicative actions of a marketing campaign. for every vehicle class. The author recommends that these packages are
tied with a loyalty scheme offering reductions. The amount of reduction
Should ETC is implemented in the CS, a commercial policy might will be based on the number of trips or other appropriate criteria (e.g.
also be targeted to ETC-generated opportunities such as: fleet owners, local residents). Reduction rates may be fixed or vary
depending on the number of trips. The offered subscription programs
• On-Board Unit (OBU) cost charging, replacement. OBU should be should be heavily advertised stressing on advantages over manual or
given free of charge for subscribers, while for non-subscribers a simple ETC use (smaller fee per trip, dedicated lanes, invoicing for
refundable deposit may be asked. Replacement of faulty OBUs professional/tax reasons, account statement etc.) and making clear
should be free of charge; distinctions between offered subscription programs in order to help the
• OBU distribution channels organization/monitoring; user choose the appropriate one.
• User credit policy. Depending on the payment method (prepaid, user At a subsequent stage, marketing actions should be taken with a
account tied to a standing bank order or user account charged by twofold aim:
credit card) users may or may not be granted a credit period;
• User access to personal account information. Users should be offered • Attraction of new users;
different ways to access details of their account (balance, charges) • Increasing the frequency of use of the existing ones.
and other information related to their use of the road. Account
statements may be sent by post on a nominal fee or free, depending These actions should include (not an exhaustive list):
on the account; or user may have access to his account via internet
secure connections. • Additional reductions for regular/frequent users based on number of
trips;
4.3.3.2. User acquisition and retention policy. For the CS’s tolling • Introduction of a monthly or daily “unlimited” subscription package
programme to succeed, some basic conditions should be met: (as in mobile telephony with a maximum limit of trips);
• Introduction of “return” ticket;
• The services offered must be competitive in terms of the quality- • Different pricing for week-ends and/or time of day;
price ratio; • Lotteries for subscribers.
• The demand must be sufficiently high to support the specific
1268
K. Panou Case Studies on Transport Policy 8 (2020) 1256–1269

All the above actions should be carefully evaluated for their per- 795–812.
formance against the targets set above to decide the most effective ones. Brazilian Toll Road Programme—BTRP, 2015. Proceedings of the Annual Meeting &
Exhibition–IBBTA, International Bridge, Tunnel, and Turnpike Association, Oct 10-
14, 2015, New York, pp. 55–68.
5. Conclusions Carruthers R., 2014. Privatization of transport infrastructure and operations in
Mexico–has it been worthwhile? In: Financing Transport Infrastructure–A
Compilation of Major Papers Selected from PTRC’s Summer Annual Meeting and
An empirical model has been developed in this paper based on Conferences, pp. 143–152.
break-even analysis to compute the minimum toll rate that could be Draeger, K.J., 2010. Scenario visioning and participatory system dynamics modeling to
charged per vehicle-kilometer (veh-km) on a given volume of traffic to investigate the future: lessons from Minnesota 2050. Sustainability 2, 2686–2706.
Gómez-Ibáñez, J.A., Meyer, J.R., 2013. Chapter 8 In: The Modern pioneers: France and
cover all costs. Spain, Going Private: The International Experience with Transport Privatization. The
The contextualization of the model calls for particular attention to Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., pp. 107–145.
the definition of the costs to be covered, and the users’ VoT which Gómez-Ibáñez J.A., 2007. Mexico’s Private Toll Road Program, C15-97-1402.0, 2007.
International Transport Forum, 2012. Trends in the Transport Sector. OECD/ITF, Paris.
combines the ideas of affordability and willingness-to-pay. Significant
Litman, T., 2009. Transportation Affordability—Evaluation and Improvement Strategies.
determinants are the objectives and expectations from tolls, which are Victoria Transport Policy Institute.
summarized in a number of equity and affordability scenarios. Manville M., 2017. Is congestion pricing fair to the poor? 100 Hours (https://100 hoursla.
The main advantage of the suggested model is that it points out the com); at https://medium.com/100-hours/is-congestion-pricing-fair-to-the-poor-
62e281924ca3.
relationship between operation and maintenance cost, traffic volumes, Nishida, T., 2015. Toll rate revision and project planning of national expressways.
tariffs and toll revenues. It can be extended to show how changes in Expressway Automobiles 38 (2).
maintenance-operation cost relationships, tariffs and total revenues will Ortega, A.M., 2003. Chilean Infrastructure Concessions. International Supplement to
RCC’s Public Works Financing.
affect profit levels and break-even points. Panou, K., 2019. A scenario-based approach for the development of toll pricing strategies
The model has been applied in the CS case using two policy sce- contemplating transportation equity and affordability. Transp. Res. Part A: Policy
narios; (a) diffusion—aimed at welfare maximization in wider areas Pract Under Publication.
Planta, R.M., 1998. Toll Adjustment Formula: Issues. National Economic and
(horizontal equity); fair to people with medium–low to low afford- Development Authority.
ability and, (b) retrenchment—aimed at revenue maximization from Ringland, G., 1998. Scenario Planning: Managing for the Future. John Wiley & Sons, New
selective tolling (vertical equity); fair to people with high affordability, York, USA.
Schiffer, R.G., 2012. Long-Distance and Rural Travel Transferable Parameters for
who because they pay more are entitled to get more. Statewide Travel Forecasting Models, NCHRP REPORT 735. Transportation Research
The application of the model has shown that it can systematically Board, Washington, D.C, pp. 75–80.
combine policy- and project-specific information to indicate tariff Schweitzer, L., Taylor, B., 2008. Just pricing: the distributional effects of congestion
pricing and sales taxes. Transportation 35 (6), 797–812.
structures that, during the application of the toll, are likely to face low
Schweitzer L., 2009. Empirical Research on the Social Equity of Gas Taxes, Emissions
or of no significance public opposition. Fees, and Congestion Charges, Special Report 303: Equity of Evolving Transportation
Finance Mechanisms, Transportation Research Board; at http://onlinepubs.trb.org/
CRediT authorship contribution statement onlinepubs/sr/sr303Schweitzer.pdf.
Shaheen, S., Stocker, A., Meza, R., 2019. Social Equity Impacts of Congestion
Management Strategies. Transportation Sustainability Research Center, University of
Konstantinos Panou: Conceptualization, Data curation, Formal California.
analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Validation, Writing - original Statistical Traffic Figures—STF, 2018. Dulles Toll Road, Dulles Greenway, Coleman
Bridge, tables, Virginia DOT, Sep 2018.
draft, Writing - review & editing. Takeda, F., 2016. New policies for motorway and toll systems in France/Italy. Expressway
and Automobiles, Japan 38 (6).
References Tam A., 2009. Hong Kong Tunnel Concession Rebidding Hitch, Public Works Financing,
February 2009.
Wiek, A., Binder, C.R., Scholz, R.W., 2006. Functions of scenarios in transition processes.
ASECAP, 2018, Greek toll road network: the revolution of Greek road infrastructure. In: Futures 38, 740–766.
5th Marketing Workshop, Athens, 3rd of May 2018. World Bank, 1999. Asian Toll Road Development Program. The World Bank and Ministry
Bradfield, R., Wright, G., Burt, G., Cairns, G., van der Heijden, K., 2005. The Origins and of Construction, Japan.
evolution of scenario techniques in long range business planning. Futures 37 (8),

1269

You might also like