Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681

www.elsevier.com/locate/technovation

Innovation risks of strategic outsourcing


A. Hoecht*, P. Trott
University of Portsmouth, Business School, Portland Street, Portsmouth, Hampshire PO1 3DE, UK

Abstract

Outsourcing was originally confined to peripheral business functions and mainly motivated by a cost saving logic, but has now developed
into a routine strategic management move that affects not only peripheral functions but the heart of the competitive core of organisations. At
the same time there is a move from traditional outsourcing with one or a small number of key partners and long-term contracts to strategic
outsourcing with multiple partners and short-term contracts. This paper investigates the innovation-related risks that can arise from strategic
outsourcing and adopts a trust, collaboration and network perspective for this analysis. It uses the example of Information
technology/Information Systems (IT/IS) outsourcing to highlight the increased risks that arise from a move from traditional to strategic
outsourcing and discusses some measures that managers can take to attempt to control these risks. The nature of the risk is closely related to
the risk of information leakage that arises from collaborative research and technology development between organisations in technology-
intensive sectors that has been analysed by Hoecht and Trott [Hoecht, A., Trott, P., 1999. Trust, risk and control in the management of
collaborative technology development. International Journal of Innovation Management 3(1), 257–270].
q 2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Strategic outsourcing; Information leakage; Trust; Control; Innovation

1. Introduction when business organisations collaborate in order to gain


access to knowledge and expertise that they cannot develop
Just like ‘downsizing’ and ‘delayering’, outsourcing has on their own. Hoecht and Trott (1999) have demonstrated
become one of the staple diets in the strategic management that there is trade-off between access to cutting-edge
field in the last decade and it has recently received much public knowledge via collaborative research and technology
attention for its impact on national employment in the media as development in knowledge-intensive industries and the
outsourcing does not longer stop at national borders (Financial risk of losing commercially sensitive knowledge to
Times, 2004). The academic and professional literature on competitors. This risk, they argue, cannot be controlled by
outsourcing has matured and overcome its original euphoria traditional management approaches and legal contracting
stage. Some of the risks associated with large-scale out- alone, but requires the operation of social control and in
sourcing, in particular where non-peripheral business pro- particular the development of high levels of mutual trust.
cesses are concerned, are now increasingly discussed in the We will discuss outsourcing-related risks in Section 2
literature. These risks include the choice of the right supplier or and we will explain how outsourcing can create an
service provider, their ability to deliver the desired ‘best in innovation dilemma that very much resembles the risk of
world’ expertise or service in the long run and the risk of losing information leakage in collaborative research and technol-
one’s core competencies to the service provider. ogy development. We will then discuss the importance of
In this article, we wish to draw attention to another trust for relationship management in outsourcing relation-
strategic risk of outsourcing that so far has not been ships in general before we move on to explain the
innovation dilemma and how its relates to trust and ‘social
discussed in the literature. This risk is closely related to
control’ in more detail. The next section will explain why
the more general issue of information leakage that arises
this innovation dilemma is much more prominent in the new
world of strategic outsourcing where companies have short-
* Corresponding author. Tel.: C44 2392 844052; fax: C44 2392 844319. term relationships with multiple partners than in traditional
E-mail address: andr.hoecht@port.ac.uk (A. Hoecht). large-scale long-term single provider relationships.
0166-4972/$ - see front matter q 2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. A number of potential management solutions for tackling
doi:10.1016/j.technovation.2005.02.004 this problem are discussed at the end of this paper.
A. Hoecht, P. Trott / Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681 673

2. Innovation-related risks of outsourcing core competencies and specialised skills can be reliable
identified. McIvor (2000: 48), for example, is much less
Outsourcing has become very widespread in the last confident than other writers that these competencies can be
decade and has moved on from limited applications where accurately predicted:
peripheral business functions are ‘outsourced’ to much more
vital business functions being outsourced today (Jennings, A current competency may cease to be a source of competitive
1997; Quelin and Duhamel, 2003). Despite the rather mixed advantage if there is a change in customer requirements or
record of large-scale long-term total outsourcing deals with competitors develop innovative technologies.
single suppliers in particular in the IT/IS industry (Lacity
and Willcocks, 1998), such contracts are still entered into There is also the important question of the potential for
insignificant numbers. The academic literature has ident- losing one’s core skills and competitive advantage to
ified a number of expected gains that companies can derive competitors in the process of collaboration. Hamel (1991)
from outsourcing. They range from the reduction of maintains that core skills can be learnt from the other party
operational costs (Lacity and Hirschheim, 1993) and the and absorbed into one’s own company just as much as one’s
ability to transform fixed costs into variable costs (Alex- own skills can be absorbed by a partner and one’s unique
ander and Young, 1996), to the ability to focus on core competitive advantage lost in the process. Bower and Keogh
competencies (Quinn and Hilmer, 1994) while having (1997) observed the behaviour of technology leaders in the
access to the industry-leading external competencies and close-knit North Sea upstream offshore oil and gas industry
expertise (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2002). There is, and found that participating in networks sharing leading edge
however, also an emerging literature that highlights the technology was exposing firms to the risk of their
weaknesses and risks associated with large-scale outsour- competitive edge being lost to competitors. Interestingly,
cing arrangements, in particular where non-peripheral this risk was found to be much smaller for resourceful and
business functions are concerned. Alexander and Young influential companies benefiting from a network centrality
(1996) highlight the risk of becoming dependent on a position than for smaller and less well positioned companies.
supplier, Barthelemy (2001) draws our attention to the
hidden costs of outsourcing and authors such as Doig et al.
(2001) and Quinn and Hilmer (1994) identify the possibility 3. The management of innovation within firms: why
of a loss of vital know-how in particular with respect to core outsourcing may hinder innovation
competencies as a major risk factor in outsourcing. There is
also the problem of selecting the most suited supplier/ The management of innovation is a large and diverse
service provider and their longer-term ability to offer the body of literature. It recognises that while there is much
capabilities that are needed in particular in business complexity and uncertainty in managing innovation and
environments with rapid technology change (Earl, 1996). new product development much is known. There is already
From an innovation and long-term competitiveness considerable agreement on many of the factors that
perspective, the traditional cost concerns are far less important contribute to success and the activities and processes that
than the question of how to identify and to retain a company’s need to be undertaken if innovation is to occur. Over the
competitive core and not to lose its future ability to compete in past 50 years there have been numerous studies of
fast-moving and unpredictable markets. The strategic man- innovation attempting to understand not only the factors
agement literature is divided on this issue. There are tools like necessary for it to occur, but how they influence the process
Hamel and Prahalad’s (1994) three tests for critical business and when and where they are required and in what order.
processes, namely ‘customer value’, ‘competitor differen- Table 1 captures some of the key studies that have
tiation’ and ‘extendibility’ that are claimed to be useful and influenced our understanding.
reliable for identifying core competencies and authors like At the corporate level, a number of research paradigms
Quinn (1999) are optimistic that these competencies can be have attempted to explain the international difference in
identified but warn companies never to outsource their core technological development and innovation. Neo-classical
(defined as ‘best in world’) competencies. A number of economic theorists believe market structure, competition
researchers also believe that not only the core competences but pressure, local supply of skills together with openness of
also most special skills related to competitive advantage need communication are the most important factors (Stoneman,
to be kept in-house (Reve, 1990; Quinn, 1999). Nevertheless, 1983; Geroski, 1993; Ansoff, 1965; Porter, 1980, 1985,
there appears to be a general consensus in the strategic 1990). However, this approach has not been able to fully
management literature that at least the complementary skills or explain the dynamics of innovation processes and the role
organisational competences can be handled and developed played by firms and other institutions (Patel and Pavitt,
by alliances and opened up to collaboration and that goods and 1984; Lundvall, 1988). In terms of firm specific character-
services of little strategic value can be purchased on the open istics that are required for firms to become more innovative
market (Brandes et al., 1997). The key strategic management much has been written about this (Quinn, 1991; Kanter,
controversy however, remains about the issue whether these 1998; Wolfe, 1994). There is also significant amount of
674 A. Hoecht, P. Trott / Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681

Table 1
Key studies of innovation management

Study Date Focus


1 Carter and Williams 1959 Industry & technical progress
2 Project Hindsight-TRACES, (Isensen) 1968 Historical reviews of US government funded defence
industry
3 Wealth from knowledge (Langrish et al.) 1972 Queens Awards for technical innovation
4 Project Sappho (Rothwell et al., 1974) 1974 Success & failure factors in chemical industry
5 Minnesota Studies (Van de Ven) 1989 14 case studies of innovations
6 Rothwell 1992 25 yr review of studies
7 Sources of innovation (Wheelwright and Clark) 1992 Different levels of user involvement
8 MIT studies (Utterback) 1994 5 major industry-level cases
9 Project NEWPROD (Cooper) 1999 Longitudinal survey of success & failure in new
products
10 Radical innovation (Leifer) 2000 Review of mature businesses

Source: Trott (2005).

literature on the strategic dimension of competition (Porter, Indeed, Rothwell (1992) put forward the idea of a fifth-
1980; Pavitt, 1984; de Woot, 1990). Many writers on generation model of innovation management, based on
innovation consider it mainly as a process that needs careful inter-company networking facilitated by IT systems. More
management (Souder, 1987; Trott, 2005; Twiss, 1992), recently, the term network has become widely used.
while others view innovation more as a cognitive and The need for connectivity and the complexity of the
behavioural phenomenon (Van de Ven, 1989; Madique, interactions it entails therefore emerges as a major factor
1988). Despite their differences, most of these writers seem influencing the management of innovation.
to accept that innovation is a phenomenon that can be Given the significance of the beneficial effect of inter-firm
subjected to human control and is considerably affected by collaboration and the role of networks for innovation and
human interaction. We also know that individuals create organisational learning (Hamel, 1991), it is necessary to
knowledge through collaborating with others in groups/ explore this concept in more detail. March (1991) dis-
teams in an organisational context; helping individuals to tinguishes between exploration and exploitation in organis-
achieve their full potential and contribute new knowledge is ational learning. He argues that there are major differences
a critical management issue which has also received between experimentation with new alternatives (exploration)
considerable attention in the literature (Tidd, 2000; Nonaka, and the refinement of existing technologies and organis-
1991; Nonaka and Takeuchi, 1995; Polyani, 1966). ational competencies (exploitation). The latter can be
The studies in Table 1 have widely contributed to the conceived as a close relative of the keep in house-or
accepted view that a firm’s ability to successfully develop outsource decision, where collaboration arises from an
innovative new products is not only the result of public and unwillingness to go-alone and a strong preference for risk-
private investments in tangibles and intangibles by individ- limitation will always be prevalent. On the other hand,
ual elements in the economy, but that it is also strongly explorative knowledge creation relies on much more ‘open-
influenced by the character and intensity of the interactions ness’ and a dedicated participation in research communities,
between the elements of the system. This position is firms, universities, research laboratories, suppliers and
strongly advocated in the literature on ‘National Innovation customers (Powell, 1990). What is required here is a much
Systems’ (Freeman, 1982; Lundvall, 1992; Nelson, 1993). more intimate form of collaboration where both parties are
In this view, innovation and technological development in contributing, rather than the handing over of responsibility of
particular depend increasingly on the ability to utilise new an activity, which is often associated with the outsourcing
knowledge produced elsewhere and to combine this with decision. Furthermore, Powell et al. (1996) argue that the
knowledge already available in the economy and its actors. locus of explorative innovations is to be found in networks of
The capacity to absorb new knowledge, to transfer and inter-organisational relationships and that a firm’s success
diffuse knowledge and the ability to learn through crucially depends on its ‘centrality-position’ in such net-
interaction are crucial success factors in innovation works and the experience gained in managing its networks.
(e.g. Cohen and Levinthal, 1989; Chesborough, 2003). Powell et al. (1996:119) argue that internal capability and
New and commercially useful knowledge is not only the external collaboration rather than being substitutes are
result of the conscious action of creative individuals. complementary:
It is also the outcome of the interaction and learning
processes among various actors in innovation systems, i.e. “Internal capability is indispensable in evaluating research
producers, users, suppliers, public authorities, and scientific done outside, while external collaboration provides access
institutions, which David and Foray (1995) have coined the to news and resources that cannot be generated internally.
‘knowledge distribution power’ of the innovation system. A network serves as a locus of innovation because it
A. Hoecht, P. Trott / Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681 675

provides timely access to knowledge and resources that are the company. In a traditional outsourcing relationship, a long-
otherwise unavailable, while also testing internal expertise term commitment is entered into that ‘locks’ a company to a
and learning capabilities.” service provider for the length of the service contract. The
ability to infuse best industry practice may not only depend on
In their empirical study of the network behaviour of the relative competence of the provider, but the service
biotechnology firms operating in the human therapeutics providers may also be restricted in their ability to pass on best
and diagnostics field (1960–94) they found strong support practices by confidentiality agreement with previous and other
for their hypothesis that a firm’s centrality in network current clients. A significant dilemma emerges: Individual
relationships and its incrementally acquired experience in firms have a reasoned case against competitors gaining the
managing network ties is a strong predictor for its growth fruits of their investment and innovation efforts, while at the
and economic success. Network experience, it appears, same time the majority of companies choose outsourcing not
should be considered as an incremental learning process least in the hope of gaining such advantages from other firms.
both in terms of the management of collaborative ties and in This dilemma is mainly left to the service providers and the
terms of the actual technical learning of biotechnology individual consultants they employ to resolve. It is, however, a
innovations (Powell et al., 1996). The decision to outsource very important issue from an organisational innovation
an activity includes the inherent risk of forgoing a firm’s perspective. We will see below that this issue becomes even
centrality of participation in valuable networks. more pressing when companies and industries move away
The development of network models of innovation have from traditional long-term outsourcing relationships with
helped to illustrate further the prominence now given to single service providers to strategic outsourcing, i.e. to much
internal and external interactions (networks) within the more open, short-term relationships with multiple suppliers
innovation process. All these knowledge flows contribute to involving all business processes.
the wealth of knowledge held by the organisation (Woolgar
et al., 1998; Rothwell, 1992; Major and Cordey-Hayes,
2003). Recognising this, capturing and utilising it to develop 4. The important role of trust in the management
successful new products are the difficult management of outsourcing relationships: the example of Information
process of innovation. Here then lies the potential problem Systems outsourcing
for firms if key activities are outsourced: whether at the very
least the firm risks disrupting the knowledge flows to the Outsourcing has a long tradition in relation to the IT
organisation and more worryingly for senior managers is industry. Because of the high costs of IT infrastructure and
whether it will isolate a firm from valuable networks. the rapid change in technology, many organisations have
Furthermore, the inability to retain a company’s been looking at external providers for the IT function since
competitive core will not only endanger its future competi- the early 1980s.
tiveness, but can also create a serious risk of dependency on The reasons for this move are rational. If information
outside providers. A crucial question is whether the desired services play a supporting role for the key business
access to ‘best in industry’ capabilities are sufficient to functions and this service can be bought in at higher quality
sustain its competitive advantage in particular where the of service delivery without having to commit substantial
provider serves ‘many masters’ and the particular expertise assets and resources, it makes good sense to look at the
ceases to be unique and becomes best-practice industry external market for providers.
standard. While there is no shortage of advice in the In most cases, the outsourcing relationship goes further
literature on how to manage the risk of dependency from than just substituting for an internal IT service and a
outside providers and suppliers in general (see for instance contractual relationship is sought where the service provider
Currie and Willcocks, 1998 who suggest multi vendor assumes responsibility for one or more of the organisation’s IT
approaches and shorter term contracts for handling large- or even business functions (Willcocks and Lacity, 1999).
scale long-term total outsourcing contracts with IT/IS In this case, the relationship includes the transfer of resources
providers), the specific problem that access to world-leading of the outsourcing organisation to the external service provider
expertise via outsourcing may well be compromised by the and involves a long-term commitment with a detailed legally
‘levelling-out’ of unique advantages when leading service binding contract. Significant organisational changes are
providers spread their world-leading expertise to several needed as the role of the internal IT department changes
clients has not received much attention. from being a supplier of its own services to assuming
As a consequence of the problem of ‘levelling out’ of the function of a controller and broker of IT and/or business
leading edge expertise, the innovation impact of outsourcing is services. Because of the level of mutual commitment, lengthy
not limited to the issue of core competencies and the need of contract negotiations (9–12 months) and detailed rules are
companies to retain at least the absorptive capacity to exploit the norm which later can become problematic as technology
innovations that have been developed by outside service base and business requirement tend to change, at times even
providers. There is also the problematic assumption that before the contract is finally signed (Woolfe, et al., 2001).
service providers are always able to infuse best practice into As the original focus is traditionally on cost saving on the basis
676 A. Hoecht, P. Trott / Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681

of existing solutions, both parties can be locked in inflexible the industry who can point towards a record of previous
arrangements that lead to a lack of satisfaction with the achievements or who have been directly recommended
services received by the outsourcer and frustration with the although the contract tendering process will be principally
constraints imposed by the service provider (Da Rold, 2001). open to all contender who can meet the project
Due to the long-term timeframe, the level of resources requirements. As outsourcing involves close cooperation
committed and the emphasis on cost efficiency, a bureaucracy- between internal and external staff, interpersonal trust
based approach to relationship management and management relationships become very important for the success of the
control is often pursued which as it is not well suited for coping project. The long-term time frame of the contracts allow
with changing requirements and therefore leads to disappoint- for interpersonal trust relationships to be built, but this
ment on both sides and further enforces the desire to impose a trust-building can be undermined if the contractual terms
high level of management control. Ironically, despite a high do not sufficiently allow for a dynamic adjustment of the
level of dissatisfaction with current service providers, a high services to be delivered to changing circumstances of the
number of organisations stick with their existing provider outsourcing organisations (such as growth through acqui-
when it comes to contract renewal because of the high level of sitions or moving into new markets) or to changes to the
sunk costs (Barthelemy and Geyer, 2000). technology and products/services available at the cutting
Outsourcing relationships need to be managed during the edge of the market. In such cases, rather than having
lifespan of the projects concerned. The costs involved and the governance procedures in place that allow for quick
complex nature of the projects that frequently involve the response and dynamic adjustment of terms, outsourcing
transfer of assets from the outsourcer to the provider call for contracts often are inflexible, require substantial renegotia-
detailed contractual arrangements. Theses are also in the tion and lead to dissatisfaction on both sides. Once
interest of the service provider who does not wish to face however, disagreements and tensions have set in, it
spiralling costs due to ambiguities. In principle, detailed becomes more difficult to renegotiate and find mutually
contractual arrangements are often considered good pro- beneficial solutions on the basis of trust (Sitkin and
fessional practice—the one who has good intentions can sign a Stickel, 1996). Even worse, signals that relationships with
detailed contract—and need not be considered as a substitute service providers have become difficult seem to reinforce
for or undermining trust in relationships. Detailed contracts preferences for a bureaucracy-based approach
and legal means are of course more of a background safeguard, to management control (van der Meer Kooistra and
providing contract parties with the confidence that although Vosselman, 2000) with closer supervision and monitoring
the law is slow and costly and seeking legal redress is not the and more direct intervention of the outsourcing company.
best avenue to solve conflicts, they do have a safeguard against Given that at least one of the causes of this adverse
gross malfeasance (Sitkin and Roth, 1993; Deakin et al., dynamic, the rate of technology change is bound to
1994). Beyond contract, however, a fair amount of trust1 is increase, the nature of IT outsourcing contracts is in need
required to make outsourcing relationships work. The out- of flexibilisation. Rather than chasing ‘moving targets’
sourcing organisation must at least have trust in the service with closer nets, a more developmental, trust-enabling
provider’s competence and willingness to keep to approach to contact and relationship management is
contractual obligations. This will normally be based on needed. A move towards a trust-enabling governance
the service provider’s record of achievement and repu- structure and management control approach would need to
tation. Most of the larger outsourcing contracts are incorporate changes such as shared flexible decision-
making and goal setting by a joint alliance board with
awarded to the reputed and established players in
backing from senior management level, open book
accounting, outcome-based rewards with a clear recog-
1
There are literally hundreds of definitions of trust. A useful pragmatic nition of a priority to meet dynamic goals rather than
definition of trust is that ‘an agent exhibits trust when he/she exposes static contractual obligations (Dekker, 2001). Such an
herself/himself to the risk of opportunistic behaviour by others and when
he/she has no reason to believe that the trusted other will exploit this
approach to management control, however, must be
opportunity’ (Humphrey and Schmitz, 1996:4). A key point is that trust implemented before trust has been lost. It also requires
makes the trustor vulnerable to the behaviour of the trustee, but the trustor a move away from a mainly tactical orientation towards
ignores this possibility. This chosen ignorance makes social interaction cost efficiency to a more strategic consideration of overall
possible. According to Zucker (1986), trust can be based on ascription (such business objectives and the role IT and IS can play to that
as membership of same group), can be process-based (tied to past or
expected exchange such as previous interaction experience and reputation)
end.
and can be institutional-based (where trust is tied to formal structures,
depending on individual or organisation-specific attributes, for example
membership in professional associations). Trust is more difficult to produce 5. Information leakage, trust, reputation
in modern complex societies as there is normally no direct personal and the innovation dilemma
knowledge or interaction experience as a basis for developing trust and
institutional trust becomes paramount. Lane and Bachmann (1998)
provides a very useful concise introduction into theories and issues related We have argued above that from an innovation
to trust within and between organisations. perspective, the reliance on outside providers can be
A. Hoecht, P. Trott / Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681 677

problematic, not only because key areas of expertise may cases when legal instruments and direct, bureaucratic
be gradually lost to the outsourcing organisation but also control are of limited effectiveness, companies need to
because outside providers may not have the desired rely on trust and social control in order to be able to work
leading edge expertise over the long-term (Earl, 1996) or with the individuals in question. And although trust is
may spread their expertise among many clients so that it always ‘ultimately a leap into the dark’ (Luhmann, 1979),
degrades from ‘best in world’ to mere industry standard. research organisations have good reasons to trust these
The problem of information leakage lies at the heart of individuals as their personal and professional integrity is
this dilemma. Companies want exclusivity in their based on their need to protect their professional reputation
relationship with their service providers, but consultants as the ‘social capital’ (Coleman, 1990) which makes them
who work with many clients are unlikely to be able not so desirable to their employers. As a consequence of their
be influenced and not to spread the best practice that self-awareness of the need to protect their reputation as
they acquire when working with many client firms. their social capital, external hired experts and organis-
Detailed legal contracts may offer short-term solutions as ational boundary spanners more than any other group of
they can protect tangible outcomes from specific projects scientists ‘internalise’ proper professional conduct in
undertaken, but not every innovation related project themselves.
outcome is tangible and can be clearly defined in legal The problem of information leakage and how to control it
contracts. And consultants are clearly expected to work also applies in the case of outsourcing of knowledge-
at the cutting edge of their professional expertise for all sensitive business processes with high innovation potential.
of their clients. We have encountered this issue as a pressing ethical and
The problem of information leakage in collaborative professional problem for a number of IS consultants that we
research and technology development has been investi- interviewed for another innovation-related research project
gated by Hoecht and Trott (1999). They contend that (Trott and Hoecht, 2004). With the move from traditional
companies need to be outward-looking to gain access to long-term single provider to strategic outsourcing, it will
new knowledge and that this openness comes at the risk become much more of an issue as will be discussed in the
of commercially sensitive information being leaked to next section.
competitors. The more outward-looking the R&D strategy
of these companies, the less suitable are traditional
approaches such as legal instruments for controlling this 6. Strategic outsourcing and the innovation dilemma
risk and the more these companies have to rely on
mechanisms of social control, in particular trust and Strategic outsourcing goes beyond traditional outsour-
reputation concerns. When companies pursue an extrovert, cing in the sense that competitive advantages are being
sought through opening up all business functions, including
the most outward-looking technology development strat-
the core competencies which should provide competitive
egy, they rely on the expertise of distinguished individual
advantage to whoever can provide the perceived best
researchers, either as temporarily hired subject field
solution, internal or external (Quelin and Duhamel, 2003).
experts or as prominent members of research community
In contrast to traditional outsourcing, there are no protective
networks working within an organisation and acting as
boundaries around core activities in the hope that the
boundary spanners between the organisation and the
organisations can maximise their innovative capacity by
scientific community. Because of their superior subject
being an active part of a networked economy. This means
knowledge and their privileged position in the research
that rather than having exclusive arrangements with one or
community, which is after all the prime reasons for
very few service providers of long periods of time which
employing them, they have, at least in theory, ample
will be expected to offer tailor-made solutions, strategic
opportunities to leak information to competitors and to
sourcing arrangements will be with multiple partners over
betray the organisations hiring their services if they wish short periods of time and with very little protection of
to do so. Direct, bureaucratic control is largely ineffective internal core competency functions against outsiders (Berg
and non-implementable in situations where the controllers and Young, 2001).
lack detailed understanding of the nature of the controlled There is a certain paradox inherent in this approach: a
person’s work,2 legal contracts such as detailed secrecy very high level of trust is required for such relationships as
clauses and intellectual property agreements are accepted the risks involved are substantial while at the same time the
as a matter of professional good practice, but detection of conditions for building trust are undermined by a shorter-
contravention would be very difficult and the contra- term orientation with less commitment compared to
vention difficult to prove and any legal redress would not traditional outsourcing relationships. The risks are signifi-
compensate for the commercial damage incurred. In such cantly higher than with traditional outsourcing: Not only is
the risk of leakage of commercially sensitive information
2
Quinn (1999) acknowledges this as a major problem in controlling the significantly increased when firm cooperate with multiple
risks involved in ‘intellectual outsourcing’. partners (Hoecht and Trott, 1999), but also the very core of
678 A. Hoecht, P. Trott / Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681

the competitive advantage in terms of knowledge, expertise entertaining more than one relationship with external
and capabilities will be made dependant on outsiders. There service providers itself, the individual buyer firm would
is a danger that the organisations pursuing strategic sourcing still have less certainty than before in its exclusive
may even loose the absorptive capacity required to relationships, but at least it would also have the chance
recognise and exploit new opportunities by themselves. to benefit from the more widely shared industry best
There appears to be a general consensus that complementary practice, spread among its competitors by the service
skills or organisational competences can be handled and providers. The effect might be a levelling out of core skill
developed by alliances and opened up to collaboration and advantages within the industry, benefiting the industry
that goods and services of little strategic value can be overall, but eroding the competitive advantage of some of
purchased on the open market (Brandes et al., 1997). its members. From the point of view of the individual firm,
A number of researchers, however, believe that the core the question is how it can maintain a commitment to
competences and most special skills related to competitive secrecy and confidentiality from multiple service provider
advantage need to be kept in-house (Reve, 1990). Hamel firms while sharing in the benefits of best practice in the
(1991) maintains that core skills can be learnt form the other industry. As the example of inter-firm collaboration in the
party and absorbed into one’s own company just as much as North sea oil and gas industry suggests, this may well be a
one’s own skills can be absorbed by a partner and one’s question of the relative bargaining power of client firms as
unique competitive advantage lost in the process. Bower well as the service provider firms’ interest in repeat
and Keogh (1997) observed the behaviour of technology transaction with their key clients.
leaders in the close-knit North Sea upstream offshore oil and The problem of information leakage is inherent in all
gas industry and found that participating in networks outsourcing relationships, but the magnitude of this problem
sharing leading edge technology was exposing firms to the is greatly increased when dyadic relationships are replaced
risk of their competitive edge being lost to competitors. by multiple partner and network arrangements. There is
While large players could afford to stay more aloof and to some tentative evidence that ‘powerful’ firms may be more
withhold their most novel technology solutions, small firms able to protect their sensitive information than weaker ones,
found that their technology solutions were prone to being but this is far from certain and may well be influenced by
appropriated by network rivals. managerial competence of the participating firms. It is also
If we are experiencing a move towards a global not always easy to determine the exact boundaries between
networked economy (Castells, 1996) with rapid technology the required up-to-date professional knowledge of individ-
change and an increasing need for sharing information and ual consultants derived from current industry experience
cooperative R&D, then long-term exclusive relationships and cutting edge innovative practices exclusively developed
between buyers and service providers may have too for a particular client that have to be kept confidential. This
unsustainably high opportunity costs because of the boundary will become even more blurred the faster
inherent lock-in that can seriously hinder innovation. technology development progresses.
From a risk-control perspective exclusive relationships
with clearly defined organisational boundaries may be
preferable, but the cost of restricting information exchange 7. Discussion and managerial implications: innovation,
among service providers in networks and limiting oneself networks and trust
to the expertise of just one firm can be significant.
Furthermore, as discussed above, such exclusive relation- Innovative capability of the firm is largely dependent
ships, when managed with a bureaucracy rather than trust- on cumulative knowledge built up over many years of
based approach to management control can be unproduc- experience. Contrary to the model used by economists,
tive. The challenge then is to find ways in which more core innovative ability cannot be simply bought and sold.
business functions (but not all!) can be opened to the Hence, the need to remind senior managers of the
shared knowledge of the external service providers as a unwitting harm that may be inflicted on the ability of
networked industry without losing core competitive the organisation to survive in the long term if its core
capabilities, be it as a consequence of extensive reliance competencies are slowly eroded through outsourcing. This
on outsiders, or through imitation by competitors as a paper has put forward a different conceptual approach for
consequence of information leakage. how companies can view the role of outsourcing and its
In a networked economy, there is hardly any choice for impact on innovative capability. We need to look again at
a firm but to have close relationships with more than one what delivers long-term success as opposed to short-term
service provider. If an industry develops closer networked gains. A different conceptual approach is required.
links among constituent firms and if every single service Managers should not be obsessed with cutting costs in a
provider firm entertains more and shorter-term relation- vain effort to compete with developing countries. They
ships with competing buyer firms, then ‘information should be concentrating on utilising their organisational
boundaries’ (Zucker et al., 1996) are opened up and knowledge bases to develop new products for the future
long-term relationship commitments are reduced. By (sometimes referred to as ‘high added-value products’).
A. Hoecht, P. Trott / Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681 679

Senior managers need to reconsider their strategies to normally not affect their core skills and competitive edge,
ensure they have activities in place that will facilitate the risks will be acceptable.
creativity and ultimately realise new products in the If networking and shared technology development is the
future. This of course has to be achieved against a future for the IT industry, another option would be for large
backcloth of fierce pressures to reduce costs and ensure buyers to retain the capacity to participate themselves
the business remains competitive in the immediate term. directly in these networks. This could be achieved by either
This paper has highlighted two particular strategic risks retaining or recruiting individuals into the buyer firms who
associated with outsourcing. Firstly, that not only does have the ability to judge industry developments and to
outsourcing involve the inherent risk of forgoing the actively participate in industry networks. The task of these
development of the knowledge base of the firm but also individuals, who have to be highly regarded experts in their
that the firm’s existing skills and core competencies may be field, would be to act as boundary spanners between
unwittingly being leaked via the third party provider. The scientific research, the service providing consultancy firms
concept of trust is introduced as a possible mechanism for and their respective buyer firm. Their job would entail the
managers not only to understand the dynamics of knowl- definition and demarcation of high-risk areas within their
edge leakage, but also as a means of managing the dilemma. home organisations and the selection and supervision of
From the point of view of the individual firm, the question is those ‘externals’ who would be granted access to the
how it can maintain a commitment to secrecy and business functions and processes identified as high risk. As
confidentiality from multiple partners. One solution would external service providers can easily be made to specify the
be their interest in repeat dealings. If the buyer firm is a individuals assigned to specific tasks as part of the tendering
significant player in its industry, the service providers may process specification and as part of the final contract, the
fear to loose it as a future customer and may therefore boundary spanner’s judgement on the competence as well as
control their own behaviour. This would require a certain trustworthiness of the specified individuals could be used as
likelihood that potential betrayals would be noticed, which a device to control the risk of secrecy betrayal. As a
consequence, it would be very much in the career interest of
in terms depends on the nature of the relations between
the staff of external service providers to keep and earn the
service providers. If there is sufficient competitive rivalry
trust of the boundary spanners of their main client firms as
(despite the network cooperation) between service provi-
this would become a key selection criterion for the award of
ders, some of their members may be prepared to ‘shop’ the
future contracts to their firms. As a consequence, the
betraying service provider to the buyer in the hope of
problem of trust would be transferred onto a higher level,
securing a future contract.
from trust in service providers to trust in the controllers/
Another way of securing commitment would be for the
boundary spanners. Although this resounds of Shapiro’s
buyer to acquire a stake in one or more of the service
(1987) observation that ‘ one of the ironies of trust is that we
providers. Partial ownership may make the service provider
frequently protect it and respond to its failure by bestowing
as a consultant/provider less attractive to other buyers, but it even more trust’—onto regulators and guardians in this
would offer a degree of control in the sense that the buyer case, the experience of other industries such as biotechnol-
firm could exercise direct influence in managerial decisions ogy with boundary spanners as guardians of company
and the employees of the service provider would be less secrets is positive (Liebeskind and Oliver, 1998; Hoecht and
likely to harm ‘part of their own’ organisation. This is, Trott, 1999). Boundary spanners have an overwhelming
however, a very costly way to buy loyalty and the associated interest in guarding their reputation as being both trust-
costs could well be far higher than the benefits derived from worthy and competent as this reputation amounts to their
strategic sourcing itself. ‘social capital’ (Coleman, 1990). Naturally, the monitoring
Tightening legal contracts would also be an option, at and supervision which can be exercised by boundary
least in theory. In practice, the knowledge base of core spanners themselves is limited to ‘working hours’ and the
competencies is often of a tacit nature and difficult to codify, ‘trusted externals’ could still pass on information after hours
and it is next to impossible to prove that betrayal has and during future assignments with competing firms, in
occurred. Furthermore, the essence of strategic sourcing is particular as there are no sufficiently effective legal
to move to shorter relationships including more flexible, less sanctions to prevent this from happening. Therefore, in
closely defined contracts. order to control this risk, some minimum level of exchange
To some extent, developments in IT may provide a of information among boundary spanners of large buyers
solution. Those services which are mainly focused on IT would be required. It is, after all, in the collective interest of
(cost) efficiency (such as product support, network main- buyers to limit the risk of betrayal and therefore to expel
tenance and help desk services) may well cease to require unreliable individuals from the circle of consultants with
buyer-owned assets and to be firm specific altogether. access to high risk areas in their clients’ organisations.
Instead of longer-term service contracts, buyers may opt for Whether this collective interest would prevail or the short-
a just in time/pay as you go ‘access’ model where they tap term benefits derivable from acts of betrayal would prove to
into standardised solutions (Da Rold, 2001). As this will be too tempting is very much a question of the character of
680 A. Hoecht, P. Trott / Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681

the network of boundary spanners in question. Given that Earl, M., 1996. The risks of outsourcing IT. Sloan Management Review
the collective sanctioning interest of networks cannot Spring, 26–32.
Financial Times (2004) Lex Column: Equity Research, Nov 29.
necessarily be relied upon particularly if detection is Freeman, C., 1982. The Economics of Industrial Innovation, Second ed.
unlikely, other safeguards would be needed. Such as Frances Pinter, London.
safeguard could be the external consultants own interest in Geroski, P., 1993. Technology and markets, in: Stoneman, P. (Ed.),
protecting their reputation as their social capital. It may not Handbook of the Economics of Innovation and Technical Change. Basil
be likely that a boundary spanner can be proven to have Blackwell, London.
Hamel, G., 1991. Competition for competence and interpartner learning
failed to inform his network colleagues of a betrayal, but the within international strategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal
self-interest of the external consultants themselves is likely 12.
to stop them from committing acts of betrayal in the first Hoecht, A., Trott, P., 1999. Trust, risk and control in the management of
place. collaborative technology development. International Journal of Inno-
vation Management 3 (1), 257–270.
Humphrey, J., Schmitz, H., 1996. Trust in Economic Development.
University of Sussex, Brighton (IDS paper 355).
Isenson, R., 1968. Technology in retrospect and critical events in science
References (Project Traces). Illinois Institute of Technology/National Science
Foundation, Chicago.
Alexander, M., Young, D., 1996. Outsourcing: where’s the value?. Long Jennings, D., 1997. Strategic guidelines for outsourcing decisions. Journal
Range Planning 29 (5), 728–730. of Strategic Change 6, 85–96.
Ansoff, H.I., 1965. The firm of the future. Harvard Business Review 43 (5), Kakabadse, A., Kakabadse, N., 2002. Trends in outsourcing. European
162–178 (Sept–Oct). Management Journal 20 (2), 189–198.
Barthelemy, J., 2001. The hidden costs of IT outsourcing. Sloan Manage- Kanter, R.M., 1998. When a thousand flowers bloom: structural, collective,
ment Review 42 (3), 60–69. and social conditions for innovation in organisation. Research in
Barthelemy, J., Geyer, D., 2000. It outsourcing: findings from an empirical Organisational Behaviour 10, 169–211.
survey in France and Germany. European Management Journal 19 (2), Lacity, M., Hirschheim, R., 1993. Information Systems Outsourcing:
195–202. Myths, Metaphors and Realities. Wiley, Chichester.
Berg, T., Young, A., 2001. The future of outsourcing. Gartner Group, Lacity, M., Willcocks, L., 1998. An empirical investigation of information
Strategic Analysis Report, May 2001. technology sourcing practices: lessons from experience. MIS Quarterly
Bower, D.J., Keogh, W., 1997. Conflict and cooperation in technology- 22 (3), 363–408.
based alliances. International Journal of Innovation Management 1 (4), Lane, C., Bachmann, R. (Eds.), 1998. Trust within and between
387–409. Organizations Conceptual Issues and Empirical Applications. Oxford
Brandes, H., Lilliecreutz, J., Brege, S., 1997. Outsourcing-success or University Press, Oxford.
failure? Findings from five case studies. European Journal of Langrish, J., Gibbons, M., Evans, W.G., Jevons, F.R., 1972. Wealth from
Purchasing and Supply Management 3 (2), 63–75. Knowledge. Macmillan, London.
Carter, C.F., Williams, B.R., 1959. The characteristics of technically Leifer, R., Colarelli O’Connor, G., Peters, L.S., Rice, M., Veryzer, R.W.,
progressive firms. Journal of Industrial Economics March, 87–104. McDermott, C.M., 2000. Radical Innovation. Harvard Business School
Castells, M, 1996. The Information Age. Economy, Society and Culture. Press, Boston, MA.
Volume 1: The rise of the network society. Blackwell Publishers, Liebeskind, J., Oliver, A., 1998. From handshake to contract: intellectual
Oxford. property, trust and the social structure of academic research, in:
Chesborough, H., 2003. Open Innovation: The New Imperative for Creating Lane, C., Bachman, R. (Eds.), Trust within and between Organizations.
and Profiting from Technology. Harvard Business School Press, Conceptual Issues and Empirical Applications. Oxford University
Boston, MA. Press, Oxford, pp. 118–145.
Cohen, W., Levinthal, D., 1989. Innovation and learning: the two faces of Luhmann, N., 1979. Trust and Power. Wiley, Chichester.
R&D. The Economic Journal 99, 569–596. Lundvall, B.A., 1988. Innovation as an interactive process: from user
Coleman, J., 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Harvard University producer interaction to the national system of innovation, in: Dosi et al.
Press, Cambridge: MA. (Ed.), Technical Change and Economic Theory. Pinter Publishers,
Cooper, R., 1999. The invisible success factors in product innovation. London and New York.
Journal of Product Innovation Management 16 (2). Lundvall, B.A., 1992. Introduction to national systems of innovation, in:
Currie, W.L., Willcocks, L.P., 1998. Analysing four types of IT sourcing Lundvall, B.A. (Ed.), National Systems of Innovation. Pinter, London,
decisions in the context of scale, client/supplier interdependency and pp. 1–22.
risk mitigation. Information Systems Journal 8 (2), 119–1434. Madique, M.A., 1988. Entrepreneurs, champions and technological
Da Rold, 2001. Buying commodity/access services instead of outsourcing. development, in: Tushman, M.L., Moore, W.L. (Eds.), Readings in
Gartner Group, Research Note, June 2001. the Management of Innovation, Second ed. Harper Business, New
David, P.A., Foray, D., 1995. Accessing and expanding the science and York, pp. 565–584.
technology knowledge base. STI-Review 16, 13–68. Major, E., Cordey-Hayes, M., 2003. Encouraging innovation in small firms
Deakin, S., Lane, C., Wilkinson, F., 1994. ‘Trust’ or Law? Towards an through externally generated knowledge, in: Shavinina, L. (Ed.),
integrated theory of contractual relations between firms. Journal of Law International Handbook on Innovation. Elsevier, Oxford.
and Society 21 (1), 329–349. March, J.G., 1991. Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning.
Dekker, H.C., 2001. Control of inter-organizational relationships, Theor- Organization Science 2, 71–87.
etical frameworks and an empirical investigation, ARCA Research McIvor, R., 2000. Strategic outsourcing: lessons from a systems integrator.
Memoranda. Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam (ARCA-RM 01–12). Business Strategy Review 11 (3), 41–50.
de Woot, P., 1990. High Technology Europe: Strategic issues for global Nelson, R.R. (Ed.), 1993. National Systems of Innovation: A Comparative
competition. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Study. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Doig, S.J., Ritter, R.C., Speckhals, K., Woolson, D., 2001. Has outsourcing Nonaka, I., 1991. The Knowledge Creating Company. Harvard Business
gone to far?. McKinsey Quarterly 4, 24–37. Review 69 (Nov–Dec), 96–104.
A. Hoecht, P. Trott / Technovation 26 (2006) 672–681 681

Nonaka, I., Takeuchi, H., 1995. The Knowledge-Creating Company. Trott, P., Hoecht, A., 2004. A preliminary study of Enterprise Resource
Oxford University Press, Oxford. Planning (ERP) and its impact on the innovative capability of firms.
Patel, P., Pavitt, K., 1994. The continuing widespread (and neglected) Paper presented at Irish Academy of Management Conference, Trinity
importance of improvements in mechanical technologies. Research College, Dublin, Sept 2–4.
Policy 23, 533–545. Twiss, B., 1992. Managing Technological Innovation, Fourth ed. Pitman,
Pavitt, K., 1984. Patterns of technological change: towards a taxonomy and London.
a theory. Research Policy 13 (6), 343–373. Utterback, J., 1994. Mastering the dynamics of innovation. Harvard
Polyani, M., 1966. The Tacit Dimension. Routledge & Kegan, London. Business School Press, Boston, MA.
Porter, M., 1980. Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analysing Van de Ven, A.H., 1989. Central problems in the management of
Industries and Competitors. The Free Press, New York. innovation, in: Tushman, M.L., Moore, W.L. (Eds.), Readings in the
Porter, M., 1985. Competitive Advantage. The Free Press, New York. Management of Innovation, Second ed. Harper Business, New York,
Porter, M., 1990. Competitive Advantage of Nations. Macmillan, New pp. 103–122.
York. van der Meer-Kooistra, J., Vosselman, E.G., 2000. Management control of
Powell, W.W., 1990. Neither market nor hierarchy: network forms of interfirm transactional relationships: the case of industrial renovation
organisations. Research in Organisational Behaviour, 12, 295–336. and maintenance. Accounting, Organizations and Society 25, 51–77.
Powell, W., Koput, K., Smith-Doerr, L., 1996. Interorganizational Wheelwright, S., Clark, K., 1992. Revolutionising Product Development.
collaboration and the locus of innovation: networks of learning in Free Press, New York.
biotechnology. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41(1), 116–146. Willcocks, L., Lacity, M., 1999. IT outsourcing in insurance services: risk,
Quelin, B., Duhamel, F., 2003. Bringing together strategic outsourcing and creative contracting and business advantage. Information Systems
corporate strategy: outsourcing motives and risks. European Manage- Journal 9, 163–180.
ment Journal 21 (5), 647–661. Wolfe, R.A., 1994. Organisational innovation: review and critique and
Quinn, J.B., 1991. Managing innovation: controlled chaos, in: suggested research directions. Journal of Management Studies 31 (3),
Mintzberg, H., Quinn, J.B. (Eds.), The Strategy Process: Concepts, 405–431.
Contexts and Cases, Second ed. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Woolfe, R., Mc Nurlin, Tucker, C., 2001. Sourcing—from remedy to
pp. 746–758. strategy. Gartner Group, December 2001.
Quinn, J.B., 1999. Strategic outsourcing: leveraging knowledge capabili- Woolgar, S., Vaux, J., Gomes, P., Ezingeard, J.-N., Grieve, R., 1998.
ties. Sloan Management Review Summer, 9–21. Knowledge and the speed of transfer and imitation of organisational
Quinn, J., Hilmer, F., 1994. Strategic outsourcing. Sloan Management capabilities: an empirical test. Organisation Science 6 (1), 76–92.
Review Summer, 43–55. Zucker, L., 1986. Production of trust; institutional sources of economic
Reve, T., 1990. The firm as a nexus of internal and external contracts, in: structure, 1840—1920. Research in Organizational Behaviour 8,
Aoki, M. (Ed.), The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties. Sage, London. 53–111.
Rothwell, R., 1992. Successful industrial innovation: critical success Zucker, L., Darby, M., Yusheng, P., 1996. Collaboration structures and
factors for the 1990s. R&D Management 22 (2), 221–239. information dilemmas in biotechnology: organizational boundaries of
Rothwell, R., Freeman, C., Horlsey, A., Jervis, V.T.P., Robertson, A.B., trust production, in: Kramer, R., Tyler, T. (Eds.), Trust in Organiz-
Townsend, J., 1974. SAPPHO updated: project SAPPHO phase II. ations: Frontiers of theory and Research. Sage, London, pp. 90–113.
Research Policy 3, 258–291.
Shapiro, S., 1987. The social control of impersonal trust. American Journal
of Sociology 93 (3), 623–658.
Sitkin, S., Roth, N., 1993. Explaining the limited effectiveness of legalistic
remedies for trust/distrust. Organization Science 4, 367–392. Dr. Andreas Hoecht is a Senior Lecturer at the Business School,
Sitkin, S., Stickel, D., 1996. The road to hell: the dynamics of distrust in an University of Portsmouth. He is an economist and political scientist
era of quality, in: Kramer, R., Tyler, T. (Eds.), Trust in Organizations. with a particular research interest in the role of trust in business
Frontiers of theory and Research. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA. relations. He holds a doctorate in Economics (Budapest) and an MA in
Souder, W.E., 1987. Managing New Product Innovations. Lexington Political Science (Hamburg).
Books, Lexington, MA.
Stoneman, P., 1983. The Economic Analysis of Technological Change.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Tidd, J., 2000. From knowledge management to strategic competence:
Measuring technological, market and organisational innovation.
Dr Paul Trott is a Principal Lecturer at the Business School,
Imperial College Press, London.
University of Portsmouth. He holds a PhD from Cranfield University.
Trott, P., 2005. Managing Innovation and New Product Development,
His research focuses on aspects of innovation management.
Third ed. Prentice Hall, London.

You might also like