Tax Compliance As A System

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 12

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/287109599

Tax Compliance as a System: Mapping the Field

Article in International Journal of Public Administration · December 2015


DOI: 10.1080/01900692.2015.1028636

CITATIONS READS
51 3,570

1 author:

Kerly Randlane
Estonian Academy Of Security Sciences
6 PUBLICATIONS 87 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Kerly Randlane on 27 January 2016.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01900692.2015.1028636

Tax Compliance as a System: Mapping the Field


Kerly Randlanea,b
a
Faculty of Social Sciences, Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn, Estonia; bThe Financial College, Department of Taxation and Customs,
Estonian Academy of Security Sciences

ABSTRACT KEYWORDS
Tax evasion is a serious and growing problem all over the world. In most cases, non-compliant tax Non-compliance; system; tax
behavior is associated with tax evasion. Such approach, however, is incomplete. There is a lack of behavior; tax compliance;
tax morale
clear definitions of compliance and non-compliance. This article focuses on defining the key terms
related to tax compliance and on mapping and systematizing the determinants of tax compliance
and proposes a way to develop an administrative strategy for tax compliance. The novelty of the
study lies in approaching tax compliance as a systemic whole. A systemic approach to tax
compliance as a comprehensive whole could serve as the basis for the tax authority in developing
administrative strategies.
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

Introduction approach. Thus, while initially tax compliance was stu-


died from the viewpoint of economic theory, followed
Tax evasion is a serious and growing problem all over the
by the integration of economics and social psychology,
world. Every year, millions of tax revenues remain uncol-
currently the tax behavior of individuals is additionally
lected due to tax fraud regarding value-added tax or
explained with the help of the neuroeconomic
envelope wages, reductions in the tax burden, etc.
approach.2 Studies in neuroeconomics report that in
Uncollected tax revenue primarily affects the amount
situations where taxpayers feel uncertain about rewards
and quality of public goods and services provided by the
and losses, the decision-making process is guided by
state. In 2011, the total tax gap in the EU-26 countries was
emotions (Bătrâncea & Nichita, 2012).
estimated at 193 million euros or 1.5% of GDP (European
It is because of the interdisciplinary nature of tax
Commission, 2013). The tax gap is more than a problem
compliance that various problems appear, starting with
of lost revenue. It is a visible sign of non-compliance.
the vagueness of concepts, the reliability of informa-
For some time already, the research in the field of
tion, and the variety of measurement tools. Several
tax behavior has not focused on tax evasion but on
studies present controversial and unconvincing evi-
voluntary tax compliance, i.e., the question is not
dence due to the terminological confusion, the large
about why taxes are evaded but rather why taxes are
number of determinants and measurement tools, and
paid. The key question is that of increasing voluntary
the lack of reliable information, the complexity, and the
tax compliance1 and thereby decreasing the state’s
relatively early development stage of the research field.
administrative costs. Additionally, the approach to the
The problems of researching tax compliance can be
research object has changed in recent years. The tax-
divided into two groups: the vagueness of terms and the
payer is no longer viewed as an individualistic and
problems related to the concept itself. There is a lack of a
rational being, i.e., behaving like homo economicus.
clear definition of compliance and non-compliance
The tax behavior of individuals and their readiness to
(Kirchler & Wahl, 2010). The existing definitions of tax
pay taxes can be addressed as a universal phenomenon
compliance are incomplete. The vagueness of terms and
which is influenced by a variety of factors.
problems related to the discipline itself have contributed
Since tax compliance as a phenomenon involves
to the lack of a comprehensive picture of compliant and
diverse scientific disciplines, it is hard to define. As a
non-compliant behavior. Usually, only one or two ele-
research field, tax behavior is mainly related to eco-
ments are studied, but not tax compliance as a whole.
nomics, psychology, sociology, politics and law.
In order to address these problems, the article
Recently, studies of tax behavior have even included
attempts to define the key concepts related to tax
knowledge from the medical field, i.e., the neurological

CONTACT Kerly Randlane kerly.randlane@gmail.com Udeselja street 2-8, 11913 Tallinn, Estonia.
© 2015 Taylor & Francis
2 K. RANDLANE

compliance, to map and systematize the factors deter- economic benefits, but also on the personal and social
mining tax compliance, and to provide a basis for norms of the individual (OECD, 2010).
developing an administrative strategy for tax It is noteworthy that the influence of social norms
compliance. on tax behavior was highlighted already in the 1960s.
The concept of tax compliance as a complex phe- German economist Günter Schmölders noted that the
nomenon is approached by applying the principles of economy and economic behavior should not be ana-
system theory. According to the system theory, key lyzed only from the classical theoretical perspectives
concepts are determined and defined, and their rela- (Schmölders, 2006). Schmölders emphasized that indi-
tionships are described. In addition to the system the- viduals’ tax behavior does not depend only on rational
ory, concept mapping approach is applied in decisions; tax compliance is a behavioral issue
determining the elements to be considered in compil- (Schmölders, 1970).
ing the theoretical model of tax compliance. In map- Given the above, the studies of tax compliance can,
ping and systematizing the determinants, emphasis is in general terms, be divided into two groups: those
laid on individuals and their decision to be or not to be based on the economic approach and those based on
tax compliant. The novelty of the study lies in the behavioral approach. The economic approach pre-
approaching tax compliance as a systemic whole. sumes that people act rationally, and the key measure
The article is structured as follows. The first part for avoiding tax fraud is high penalty rates and a high
explains the concepts of tax compliance and tax morale. probability to get punished. The behavioral approach
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

In addition, the arguments are given for why it is impor- states that people do not usually act rationally but
tant today to pay attention to tax morale. In the second irrationally, and this is largely due to social determi-
part, the focus is on identifying the main determinants nants. In other words, tax evasion is a technical pro-
of tax compliance. In the third part, the theoretical blem in the opinion of economists and a social problem
model of the systemic approach to tax compliance is in the opinion of social scientists (Schmölders, 2006).
presented. The article concludes in the fourth part. Tax compliance has also been defined as the indivi-
dual resourcefulness of the taxpayer in paying mini-
mum taxes (Kirchler & Maciejovsky, 2001). In most
The concept of tax compliance cases, non-compliant tax behavior is associated with
tax evasion. Such approach, however, is incomplete.
Explaining tax compliance
There is a lack of clear definitions of compliance and
Tax compliance is considered to be a relatively new non-compliance. Non-compliance is a broader concept
research field. According to various recent publications than just reducing one’s tax liability by illegal means.
(e.g., Alm & Torgler, 2011; Alm et al., 2012b; Kirchler Evading taxes, decreasing taxes, or avoiding taxes are
& Wahl, 2010), studies on tax compliance began in the achievable by both legal and illegal means. According
early 1970s, when the decision to comply was framed as to the economic interpretation in tax law, it is not the
a purely economic decision under risk (Alm et al., legal form of a transaction that is relevant but its
2012b). Allingham and Sandmo (1972) and Srinivasan economic content and objective. In other words,
(1973) found that taxpayers have only two options: decreasing tax liabilities either by illegal or by legal
either to declare their income or to declare less than means are both examples of non-compliance. In this
their actual income. The decision whether to be or not approach, non-compliant people include also these
to be compliant is based on the cost–benefit calculation. people who reduce their tax liabilities by legal means
Unpaid taxes were considered as the typical income or avoid taxes (Figure 1). In addition to tax avoidance
and the risk to get caught and the size of the potential and tax evasion, a person who fails to fulfill at least one
punishment were viewed as the typical cost (OECD, of the main obligations of the taxpayer is theoretically
2010). According to this approach, tax compliant or also non-compliant.
tax non-compliant behavior is the outcome of cost– The principal obligations of the taxpayer are univer-
benefit calculation and depends primarily on the active- sal and do not depend on the profile or the field of
ness in applying coercive measures. activity of the taxpayer. In general, such obligations
However, by now, there is increasing evidence that a include the registration in the system, timely filing of
simple cost–benefit approach cannot be used to predict the declaration, reporting of complete and accurate
everyday choices of people (Frank, 1991), including tax information, and timely payment of tax obligations
compliance (e.g., Alm, McClelland, & Schulze, 1992; (OECD, 2009). According to this approach, individuals
Alm, Sanchez, & Juan, 1995). In other words, indivi- can be considered non-compliant when they do not
duals’ tax behavior does not depend entirely on intentionally avoid paying taxes but have problems
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION 3

Figure 1. Actual tax behavior (compiled by the author).

with paying taxes on time due to various reasons. Thus, whole, the factors that influence the decision of the
the term “non-compliant” characterizes not only tax taxpayer to be or not to be compliant need to be
evasion, but also the cases when tax is not paid in due understood. This means taking a step back and explain-
time, either intentionally or unintentionally (Webley ing the willingness to pay taxes and the factors that
et al., 2010). In general, tax compliance is the degree influence it.
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

to which taxpayers comply with the tax rules.


Tax compliance can also be defined by the way of
achieving it. By defining it in this way, tax compli-
Tax morale as the taxpayers’ willingness to pay
ance is either voluntary or enforced (Kirchler, Hoelzl,
taxes
& Wahl, 2008; OECD, 2008). Voluntary compliance
means the taxpayers’ voluntary fulfillment of their Tax compliance is the outcome of the taxpayers’ tax
main obligations without the involvement of the tax behavior which depends on the taxpayers’ willingness
authority: people voluntarily declare and timely pay to pay taxes. The willingness to pay taxes is defined in
their tax obligations, and their tax accounting is in professional literature as tax morale. Tax morale is, in
accordance with the norms in tax law (OECD, 2004). general terms, the attitude of the individuals toward
Enforced compliance means that tax compliance is paying taxes, their individual conceptions and norms,
achieved with the intervention by the tax authority, and their intrinsic motivation (Randlane, 2013).
which may involve correcting data during control or Tax morale as the willingness to pay taxes was dis-
implementing coercion in collecting tax arrears. In cussed already in the 1930s (Schmölders, 1932), when
other words, the administrative burden of the tax attention started to be paid on the relationship between
authority is minimal in voluntary compliance and the taxpayer and the state. This time is also considered
heavy in enforced compliance. to be the beginning of researching tax behavior. The
The vagueness of the terms is illustrated by the more concept of tax morale was defined first in the 1960s as
widespread approach, according to which tax compli-
the attitude of a group or the whole population of
ance is probably the most neutral term to describe the taxpayers regarding the question of accomplishment
taxpayers’ willingness to pay their taxes3 (Kirchler, or neglect of their tax duties; it is anchored in citi-
2007). This, however, is not supported by the approach zens´ tax mentality and in their consciousness to be
described above. Therefore, I argue that tax compliance citizens, which is the base of their inner acceptance of
is not the willingness of the taxpayer to pay taxes but an tax duties and acknowledgment of the sovereignty of
the state (Schmölders, 1960, pp. 97–98).
outcome already achieved. In other words, tax compli-
ance has been achieved either voluntarily or through Despite the solid historical background of the term
the intervention of the tax authority (see Figure 1). “tax morale,” quite recently it was still considered an
The OECD (2014) defines tax compliance as a underdeveloped research field (Andreoni, Erard, &
degree to which the tax behavior of taxpayers complies Feinstein, 1998, p. 852). Contemporary professional
(or fails to comply) with the tax rules of their country. literature has emphasized the lack of a broad approach
In short, it cannot be said that tax compliance is the to tax morale as well as its treatment as a black box or
taxpayer’s ambition, will, or readiness to pay taxes in residuum (e.g., Feld & Frey, 2002; Frey & Torgler,
the required amount. Rather, tax compliance is the 2007). Tax morale is primarily viewed as a problem in
outcome of the tax behavior of the taxpayer. In order rational decision-making, and its connectedness with
to understand tax compliance as a comprehensive socio-psychological indicators is ignored. Research has
4 K. RANDLANE

demonstrated, however, that the tax behavior of an Why is tax morale important right now?
individual is a complex phenomenon that is not based
Why do people pay taxes? In most OECD countries,
only on the individual’s economic behavior (Frey &
the simple answer would be that they are forced to
Torgler, 2007). Thus, the question of tax morale is
comply with regulations (Daude, Gutiérrez, &
broader than the question of why people do not
Melguizo, 2012). The taxpayer used to be viewed as
cheat, even if they could do so (Torgler, 2007).
a rational and egotistic person whose aim was to
It has been stated repeatedly that tax morale is a
maximize personal benefits. In the 1970s, most
social phenomenon which is hard to define unambigu-
researchers agreed with this administrative approach,
ously. According to the general definition, tax morale is
arguing that tax compliance depended only on the
understood as the taxpayer’s internalized willingness or
effectiveness of implementing coercive measures (e.g.,
intrinsic motivation to pay taxes (e.g., Alm & Torgler,
Allingham & Sandmo, 1972; Srinivasan, 1973). The
2006; Braithwaite & Ahmed, 2005; Feld & Frey, 2002)
studies of tax evasion were based on the economics-
but also as a moral duty and belief in the social con-
of-crime approach by Becker (1968), which presumes
tribution as the outcome of paying taxes (Torgler &
that people seek to increase benefits through criminal
Schneider, 2006).
activities while simultaneously minimizing costs and
It is important to stress that tax morale and tax
risks. Thus, the taxpayer was seen as a rational and
compliance are not synonyms. Tax morale is the will-
egotistic person whose aim was to maximize personal
ingness to pay taxes, while tax compliance is the con-
gain (Kirchler, 2007). Such an administrative
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

dition already achieved. Tax morale is considered an


approach where the taxpayer is treated as a potential
important determinant of tax compliance. Thus, when
criminal, and better enforcement of coercive measures
tax morale is high, tax compliance is probably also
is assumed to lead to honest payment of taxes, is
relatively high and vice versa (Torgler, 2007).
called the traditional “enforcement” paradigm (Alm
Research findings indicate that tax morale helps to
& Torgler, 2011, p. 646). Increasing the probability
explain why people pay taxes. However, a causal
of control and making the sanctions more effective
relationship between actual tax compliance and tax
were seen as the only measure of ensuring tax com-
morale has not been proved (Halla, 2012). The ques-
pliance. The administrative approach based on coer-
tion is not about whether there is any relationship
cion is characterized primarily by the confrontation
between the two, but rather how to measure it. Since
between the tax authority and the taxpayer, a large
it is hard to collect information about tax compli-
social distance, punishments, a pure rational cost–
ance, people’s attitudes and beliefs are usually mea-
benefit model, intensive intervention by the tax
sured and not their actual tax behavior. Research
authority, and therefore forced tax compliance
results show that both economic factors and social
(Figure 2).
norms (including moral judgments) affect people’s
The implementation of coercive measures is presum-
tax behavior (Halla, 2012). The moral sentiments
ably the easiest way to force taxpayers to pay taxes. The
are considered more dominant than other factors
question is, however, whether addressing all taxpayers
(Alm & Torgler, 2011).
as rational and egotistic individuals can explain their
Thus, individuals’ attitude toward paying taxes, their
tax behavior. Research demonstrates that tax evasion
personal conceptions, norms, and motivation can be
cannot be explained convincingly only by the greed of
expressed by the term “tax morale.” In other words,
people (e.g., Alm & Torgler, 2011; Alm, Kirchler, &
by taking the core meaning of the term “morale,” tax
Muehlbacher, 2012a; Frey, 2003; Webley et al., 2010).
morale can be viewed as the tradition to pay taxes,
The traditional “enforcement” paradigm, which histori-
which has developed historically and has become
cally has been used as a way to analyze tax compliance
rooted in the deep consciousness of people (Randlane,
and as a measure to influence tax compliance, and in
2013, p. 76).
which the taxpayer is treated as a potential criminal, is
Tax morale is a multidimensional concept which is
by now ideologically outdated. Studies have provided
affected by various factors. Tax morale serves as the
clear evidence that the strategy for influencing tax
common denominator for non-rational determinants
compliance requires something more than better enfor-
and motivation, such as social norms, personal
cement of coercive measures (Alm et al., 2010).
values, and various cognitive processes (Kornhauser,
The breakthrough in the relationship between the
2007). Tax morale is complex, and its elements are
tax authority and the taxpayer took place in the early
not static (Kornhauser, 2007), i.e., tax morale is not a
1990s together with the spreading of the principles of
thing in itself, but needs to be addressed and
New Public Management (NPM).4 The tax authority
developed.
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION 5

Figure 2. Compliance strategies and tax climate (compiled by the author).

was identified as a service provider and the taxpayer compliance is a complex system which is primarily the
began to be called the “customer.” The “service” para- outcome of the interaction between the tax authority
digm acknowledges the importance of coercive mea- and the taxpayer.
sures in tax administration, but emphasizes the role of Research on tax behavior indicates that in develop-
the tax authority as a service provider (e.g., Alm & ing and shaping tax compliance, there is a clear move-
Torgler, 2011; Alm, Cherry, Jones, & McKee, 2010; ment from the coercive approach where the taxpayer is
Alm et al., 2012a; Kirchler et al., 2008). Taxpayers treated as a rational, profit-oriented person toward an
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

were no longer seen as a single anonymous group individual approach (Alm et al., 2012). Traditional
with a dominant motivation (Alm et al., 2012a), i.e., coercive measures (e.g., audit, penalties) can only
the taxpayer as a customer was treated as a unique explain a small part of tax compliance. The question
individual. The increase in tax compliance was consid- is no longer about why people cheat but rather why
ered to be achieved through an increase in the quality people pay taxes.
of services and customer-friendly treatment of the Tax compliance is not simply the outcome of
taxpayer. opportunities to evade tax and the deterrence and
Still, even the above-mentioned administrative stra- prevention strategies of tax authorities. To a consider-
tegies (enforcement and service) are not sufficient to able extent, tax compliance has to be attributed to the
ensure voluntary tax compliance. Tax compliance is not tax morale of taxpayers. (Feld & Frey, 2002) The will-
merely the outcome of evading taxes, implementing ingness of the taxpayers to pay taxes and their internal
coercive measures, or service activities. To increase motivation, or the “tax morale,” is considered the key
voluntary tax compliance, it is important to have a in studying tax compliance (e.g., Kirchler, 2007;
mutually trustful relationship between the tax authority Kornhauser, 2007; Torgler, 2007). Tax morale is not
and the taxpayer. This relationship is also called the a thing in itself, but it depends, among other factors,
“psychological contract” (Feld & Frey, 2002, p. 89). It on the relationship between the taxpayer and the tax
means that the tax authority treats the taxpayer in a authority. Research has demonstrated that treating
respectful manner, and in return the taxpayer honestly taxpayers in a respectful manner supports and even
declares and pays tax liabilities. Thus, establishing and increases their willingness to pay taxes while disre-
maintaining a trustful relationship plays an important spect increases the taxpayers’ motivation to avoid
role in the strategy of ensuring tax compliance. The taxes (Feld & Frey, 2002).
“trust” paradigm includes morale, ethics, elements of Why then is tax morale so relevant today? It is
social norms, and other behavioral factors (Alm & primarily because the classical economic theory fails
Torgler, 2011, p. 646). A trustful administrative to fully explain tax compliance. It is clear by now that
approach is characterized by the willingness to coop- there does not exist rational behavior totally isolated
erate, synergetic climate and minimal intervention by from the environment. An individual’s tax behavior
the tax authority (voluntary compliance), a personal does not depend entirely on economic gains and the
approach, and the implementation of coercive mea- economic-of-crime-approach is not able to explain
sures only in case of need (Figure 2). everyday choices of the individual. Although the imple-
The administrative strategy for ensuring tax compli- mentation of coercive measures is the easiest way to
ance requires, given the above, a multidimensional increase tax compliance, it is also the most expensive
approach—a combination of enforcement, service, and one. Since resources are limited, the challenge lies in
trust. Thus, if coercion is increased, the levels of service maximizing the share of taxes paid voluntarily. To
and trust have to be increased at the same time. Tax increase voluntary tax compliance, attention needs to
6 K. RANDLANE

Figure 3. Main determinants of compliance behavior (compiled by the author).

be paid to the relationship between the taxpayer and wholeness. The observable elements (potential impact
the tax authority. This relationship has a direct impact factors) and their mutual relationships are determined
on the willingness of people to pay taxes, i.e., their tax in order to achieve the optimal functioning of the
morale and in this way also on tax compliance as a system as a whole.
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

whole. In sum, an individual approach has replaced the Based on the research findings, the determinants of
impersonal coercive approach, and attention is being tax compliance can be divided into two major groups:
focused on the relationship between the taxpayer and economic or rational factors and non-economic or
the tax authority and via this relationship on the will- non-rational factors (Figure 3).
ingness of people to pay taxes, their tax morale. Thus, Economic or rational factors are mainly associated
in researching tax compliance the factors that affect the with rational choice (e.g., Allingham & Sandmo, 1972;
willingness to pay taxes are of major importance. Srinivasan, 1973). Economic or rational factors usually
include the probability of audit and of implementing
sanctions, the tax rate, the economic benefit, the
Determinants of compliance behavior amount of income, and the tax burden. A taxpayer
evaluates the expected outcomes of the choice to
While most researchers have reached a common under- evade and the choice not to evade taxes, the probability
standing that tax compliance cannot be explained only of evasion detection, punishment of evasion, and the
by economic factors, there is still no agreement on what probability of audits (e.g., Kirchler, 2007; Torgler, 2007;
exactly affects the willingness to pay taxes. Wenzel, 2005). The rational choices of individuals are
The studies on tax compliance can, in broad terms, mainly guided by economic benefits, the implementa-
be divided into behavioral psychology analyses and cri- tion of sanctions, and their potential size.
tical tax studies. Behavioral psychology focuses on the Non-economic or non-rational factors include pri-
relationship between tax compliance and various beha- marily social norms (Alm et al., 1995), but also personal
vioral factors. The critical tax studies analyze the var- norms, demographic indicators (e.g., age, gender, and
ious practices, techniques, and discourses used by states education), etc. Alm, Schmölders, and others under-
to create taxpaying citizens (Boll, 2014). In most cases, stand social norms as tax morale or internal motiva-
only a limited amount of determinants are analyzed, tion. Kornhauser (2007) addresses tax morale in even
and tax compliance as a whole is not addressed. The broader terms and claims that tax morale is the com-
decision of the taxpayer to be or not to be compliant is, mon denominator for all non-rational factors and
however, complex and affected by numerous factors. motivation.
Alm and Torgler (2011) emphasize the following: Non-economic factors can be divided into two
Tax compliance sets limits to the theoretical as well as groups: external and internal norms. Different authors
the empirical approach. The theoretical models do not often use different terms in describing similar factors
reflect the complexity of issues and the research results and assessing their influence. Thus, for example, the
are often ambiguous. The empirical work is plagued by external norms have been called societal norms or
the absence of reliable information about the decisions community standards or national norms or political-
of an individual regarding tax behaviour (pp. 640–642).
legislative or institutional factors, etc. In broad terms,
Given the above-described problems, my approach to external factors include the functioning of the legal
researching tax compliance relies on its systemic system, democracy, trust in government, the
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION 7

complexity and fairness of the tax system, the efficiency words, tax compliance depends primarily on the parti-
of the public sector, social cohesion, and the relation- cipant and the environment. It is important to note
ship between the tax authority and the taxpayer (e.g., here that norms are not static. External and internal
Alm & Torgler, 2006; Frey 2003; Kirchler, 2007; norms interact with each other and with the environ-
Kornhauser, 2007; Lago-Peñas & Lago-Peñas, 2010; ment. Thus, the tax authority as an external influencer
Taylor, 2003; Torgler 2003, 2005, etc.). has a direct impact on the taxpayers’ willingness to pay
Besides economic and external factors, an indivi- taxes or the taxpayers’ tax morale, and thereby also on
dual’s willingness to pay taxes is affected by the indivi- their tax compliance (see Figure 4).
dual’s internal norms and individual characteristics or The above-described determinants of tax compli-
socio-psychological factors (Kirchler, 2007). Research ance, even though approached somewhat differently
has demonstrated that the decision of taxpayers to be by various authors, have been the main determinants
or not to be compliant depends on their knowledge and investigated in tax compliance research. The author’s
understanding of taxation, their individual attitudes aim is to systematize the determinants (Figure 3) and to
and beliefs, the social norms and attitudes of the develop, based on these determinants, a systemic
society, as well as demographic characteristics such as approach to tax compliance, i.e., a comprehensive
age, gender, education, marital status, etc. (e.g., Alm & model (Figure 4).
Torgler, 2006; Frey & Torgler, 2007; Kirchler, 2007;
Torger, 2005; Torgler, 2007). Internal norms are pri-
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

marily an individual’s intrinsic factors or social and


The conceptual model of tax compliance
personal norms (Kornhauser, 2007). Personal norms
are understood as the individual behavioral norms of Professionals writing about tax compliance emphasize,
a person. Social norms are related to the behavior of the on the one hand, psychological determinants as the key
reference group (e.g., family, friends, etc.). Research behavioral factors in understanding tax compliance,
findings have shown that social norms are relevant and on the other hand, tax compliance as a social and
only for those people who identify strongly with a institutional practice (Boll, 2014). Tax compliance is a
group of people (Wenzel, 2004). Both social and perso- social phenomenon which is affected both by economic
nal norms affect tax morale. and by non-economic factors, as well as their interplay.
As a new, alternative approach, it has been proposed Thus, in order to increase tax compliance, something
that tax compliance is a socio-material assemblage and more than better coercive measures is needed (Alm
compliance is a distributed action (Boll, 2014). In other et al., 2010).

Figure 4. A simplified model of tax compliance as a system (compiled by the author).


8 K. RANDLANE

It is increasingly being emphasized that tax compli- 1975). It is important to stress that system analysis is
ance is the outcome of the taxpayer’s personal norms not about applying mathematical methods or proce-
and individual experience (e.g., Kornhauser, 2007; dures, but about logical elaboration of alternative
OECD, 2010; Wenzel, 2004). In getting certain experi- possibilities. The final results of the analyses are not
ences, the activities of the tax authority and the choice found by calculations and they are not expressed
of measures play a major role in addition to the social numerically (Mereste, 1987).
and economic environment (see Figure 2). High tax The theoretical model of tax compliance has been
compliance is not achieved by the domination of one built on the feedback system by Norbert Wiener (1961)
dimension, but it is the outcome of combining several in which the system consists of elements which are
measures. That means that in choosing the measures, connected and intertwined and of the environment in
the tax authority has to consider the profile of the which activities take place.
taxpayers and various factors that can influence tax According to the model in Figure 4, tax compliance
compliance. Taxpayers have to be treated according to is a complex phenomenon and affected by both eco-
their tax behavior: non-compliant payers by applying nomic and non-economic factors, including both poli-
coercion and fear and compliant payers by applying tical and socio-psychological factors. The factors have
trust and persuasion (Kirchler, 2007). Policies based been placed in the figure from inside out as assessed by
on fear should not be used with honest taxpayers. the author according to their order of importance and
Voluntary tax compliance presumes a partnership based on the author’s analysis and the findings of ear-
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

between the taxpayer and the tax authority, not their lier studies. The economic factors in the centre of the
confrontation. model show that an individual does not act in isolation,
The OECD (2010) admits that tax compliance is and in addition to the opportunity to maximize bene-
an outcome of the complex behavior of an individual, fits, the taxpayer is also affected by non-economic fac-
which requires a complex approach from the tax tors and the environment. The socio-psychological
authority. Thus, the choice of measures should result factors in the outer circle of the model indicate their
from meaningful activities of the tax authority. It is relevance in shaping tax compliance, continuous
also emphasized that becoming knowledgeable about research opportunities as well as the opportunities for
the essence of the factors is more relevant than mea- profiling people when choosing measures. The environ-
surement results. The amount of academic research ment as the most outward, not clearly defined factor, is
in the field does not change the situation unless the characterized by uncertainty. The elements of the sys-
revenue body develops strategies to improve tax tem or the determinants of tax compliance interact with
compliance. one another and are affected by the external
Based on the research which was conducted to study environment.
these problems, I argue that a systemic approach in The model is an abstraction, the aim of which is to
which tax compliance is addressed as a comprehensive simplify the understanding of real-life situations. The
whole helps to understand tax compliance and make model is a system illustrating defined objects and their
strategic choices in the implementation of measures. interactions. In order to know the system better, it
According to the principles of the systemic approach, needs to be developed and managed. The theoretical
everything that can be treated, and is reasonable to treat model idealizes tax compliance as a phenomenon, with-
systemically, should be treated so, including the deter- out making its empirical content explicit. At the same
mination of the elements to be studied, their character- time, the conclusions made on the basis of the theore-
istics, and interactions (Lorents, 2006). tical model depend on the general knowledge about the
The systemic approach in solving complex pro- phenomenon and are not logical constructions totally
blems presumes the creation of a model that imitates separated from the phenomenon.
the research object. The model depends primarily on Tax compliance as a system depends on the inter-
how the problem is structured. Tax compliance is a play of determinants as well as these components of
weakly structured system which can only be partly the system that derive from the uncertainty of the
described mathematically, because it is dominated by external environment. What is usually known about
undefined internal relationships and the impact of tax compliance as a system is its inputs (or taxpayers)
the external environment (Rozenfeld, 1975). While and the output (the collected tax revenue). Although
the functioning of a well-structured system can be the tax authority usually lacks knowledge about tax
studied with quantitative measures of operational compliance as a structured system and about the
analysis, in the study of weakly structured systems, regularities in the system, it is also possible to oper-
systems analysis is applied (Mereste, 1987; Rozenfeld, ate only with inputs and outputs, i.e., to use the
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION 9

principle of “black box” by Ashby (1958). By gradu- outcome of an individual’s tax behavior. The willing-
ally changing the inputs, or the profiles of taxpayers, ness to pay taxes is called tax morale. Tax morale
and recording the changes in outputs, the reactions describes the attitude of individuals toward paying
of the black box can be studied. The systemic taxes, their personal beliefs, and norms and intrinsic
approach is about creating feedback systems which motivation. Tax morale is considered the key in
provide regular information and which enable to researching and influencing tax compliance. The cur-
change activities. The factors deriving from the exter- rent importance of tax morale can be explained by the
nal environment, i.e., the strategic actions of the tax development of the area. Some time ago, the taxpayer
authority directly influence the output of the system was viewed as a rational being oriented toward max-
or the achieved tax compliance. imizing benefits, whose behavior could only be
In sum, tax compliance is not a thing in itself, but a improved by making coercive measures more effective.
process managed to a large extent by the tax authority It is clear now that there does not exist rational beha-
(the state). “A one-size-fits-all-enforcement model” as vior entirely isolated from the environment and that in
an administrative approach has not provided any order to improve tax behavior something more than
expected results for quite some time (Kornhauser, the improvement of coercive measures is needed. In
2007, p. 157), and traditional coercive measures short, the impersonal approach based on coercion has
explain only a part of tax compliance (enforced com- been replaced by an individual approach where empha-
pliance). Until there is no single clear and simple sis is laid on the relationship between the taxpayer and
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

answer as to how to affect individuals’ tax behavior the tax authority and thereby on the willingness to pay
in the best possible manner, the choice of measures by taxes, or tax morale.
the tax authority and the development of these mea- Second, I highlighted the fact that due to the
sures to improve tax compliance are of key heterogeneous nature of research done in the field,
importance. the large number of factors, and the numerous ways
to interpret these factors, there is no clear answer to
the question of what influences the willingness to pay
Concluding remarks
taxes. The decision to be or not to be compliant is a
This article has clarified the concept of tax compliance complex one, depending on various factors and the
and its influencing factors to theories and different interplay of these factors. Despite some differences,
studies. The article focused on defining the key terms the range of factors influencing tax compliance has
related to tax compliance, on mapping and systematiz- remained unchanged for a long time, which has pro-
ing the determinants of tax compliance, and on propos- vided the opportunity to systematize them and to use
ing a way to develop the administrative strategy for tax them as inputs in creating a comprehensive model of
compliance. tax compliance.
First, I argued that there is a lack of a clear definition Third, due to the complexity of the determinants of
of compliance and non-compliance. Non-compliance is tax compliance, I argue that a systemic approach where
usually associated with tax evasion. This, however, is tax compliance is treated as a comprehensive whole
only a partial view. The concept of non-compliance is helps to understand tax compliance and make strategic
broader and includes both tax evasion and tax avoid- choices in the implementation of measures. It is not the
ance. In addition, individuals are non-compliant when measurement results which are that important, but the
they do not fulfill at least one of the main obligations of substance of the factors and their impact on tax com-
the taxpayer (e.g., not submitting the declaration on pliance. Tax compliance is a comprehensive system
time, not paying a tax liability, etc.). Individuals are which depends on the interplay of the factors, the
also non-compliant when their tax compliance has been uncertainty of the external environment, as well as the
achieved through coercion. Compliance behavior or strategic actions of the tax authority. Even if the inter-
voluntary compliance means that individuals volunta- nal structure of tax compliance as a system and its
rily declare and pay their tax liabilities, and that their regularities are not known, it is possible to develop a
tax accounting is in accordance with the existing feedback system by operating with inputs and outputs,
norms. and thereby to affect tax compliance. In conclusion, tax
Additionally, I argued that tax compliance is not the compliance is not a thing in itself but a process man-
willingness of the taxpayer to pay taxes but a condition aged by the tax authority. A systemic approach to tax
already achieved—an outcome or some level which has compliance as a comprehensive whole could serve as
been reached either voluntarily or with an intervention the basis for the tax authority in developing adminis-
by the tax authority. Thus, tax compliance is the trative strategies.
10 K. RANDLANE

Notes Economic Psychology, 26, 523–540. doi:10.1016/j.


joep.2004.08.003
1. Voluntary means compliance without any actions taken Daude, C., Gutiérrez, H., & Melguizo, Á. (2012). What drives
by the tax authority. tax morale? (Working Paper 315). Paris, France: OECD
2. Neuroeconomics is one of the newest fields among Development Centre.
social sciences, a hybrid between neuroscience, experi- European Commission. (2013). Study to quantify and analyse
mental economics, and psychology which studies the the VAT Gap in the EU-27 Member States. The Hague, The
neural basis of economic decisions (Bătrâncea & Netherlands: DG TAXUD, European Commission.
Nichita, 2012). Feld, L. P., & Frey, B. S. (2002). Trust breeds trust: How
3. The author has applied the same approach in her ear- taxpayers are treated. Economics of Governance, 3, 87–99.
lier studies. doi:10.1007/s101010100032
4. NPM is the transfer of business principles and manage- Frank, R. H. (1991). Microeconomics and behavior. New
ment techniques from the private into the public sector York: McGraw-Hill Education.
(Pollitt & Bouckaert, 2011). Frey, B. S. (2003). Deterrence and tax morale in the European
Union. European Review, 11(3), 385–406.
Frey, B. S., & Torgler, B. (2007). Tax morale and conditional
cooperation. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35, 136–
References 159. doi:10.1016/j.jce.2006.10.006
Halla, M. (2012). Tax morale and compliance behavior: First
Allingham, M. G., & Sandmo, A. (1972). Income tax evasion:
evidence on a causal link. The B.E. Journals of Economic
A theoretical analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 1,
Analysis & Policy: Advances, 12(1), 1–25.
323–338. doi:10.1016/0047-2727(72)90010-2
Kirchler, E. (2007). The economic psychology of tax behavior.
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

Alm, J., Cherry, T., Jones, M., & McKee, M. (2010). Taxpayer
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
information assistance services and tax compliance beha-
Kirchler, E., Hoelzl, E., & Wahl, I. (2008). Enforced versus
vior. Journal of Economic Psychology, 31(4), 577–586.
voluntary tax compliance: The ‘slippery slope’ framework.
doi:10.1016/j.joep.2010.03.018
Journal of Economic Psychology, 29, 210–225. doi:10.1016/j.
Alm, J., Kirchler, E., & Muehlbacher, S. (2012a). Combining
joep.2007.05.004
psychology and economics in the analysis of compliance:
Kirchler, E., & Maciejovsky, B. (2001). Tax compliance within
From enforcement to cooperation. Economic Analysis &
the context of gain and loss situations, expected and current
Policy, 42(2), 133–151. doi:10.1016/S0313-5926(12)50016-0
asset position and profession. Journal of Economic
Alm, J., Kirchler, E., Muehlbacher, S., Gangl, K., Hofmann,
Psychology, 22, 173–194. doi:10.1016/S0167-4870(01)00028-9
E., Kogler, C., & Pollai, M. (2012b). Rethinking the
Kirchler, E., & Wahl, I. (2010). Tax compliance inventory
research paradigm for analysing tax compliance behaviour.
TAX-I: Designing an inventory for surveys of tax compli-
CESifo Forum, 13(2), 33–40.
ance. Journal of Economic Psychology, 31, 331–346.
Alm, J., McClelland, G. H., & Schulze, W. D. (1992). Why do
doi:10.1016/j.joep.2010.01.002
people pay taxes? Journal of Public Economics, 48(1), 21–
Kornhauser, M. E. (2007). Normative and cognitive aspects of
38. doi:10.1016/0047-2727(92)90040-M
tax compliance: literature review and recommendations for
Alm, J., Sanchez, I., & Juan, A. (1995). Economic and none-
the IRS regarding individual taxpayers. II National
conomic factors in tax compliance. Kyklos, 48(1), 1–18.
Taxpayer Advocate, Annual Report to Congress, 138–180.
doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.1995.tb02312.x
Retrieved from https://www.irs.gov/pub/tas/arc_2007_vol_
Alm, J., & Torgler, B. (2006). Culture differences and tax
2.pdf.
morale in the United States and in Europe. Journal of
Lago-Peñas, I., & Lago-Peñas, S. (2010). The determinants of
Economic Psychology, 27, 224–246. doi:10.1016/j.
tax morale in comparative perspective: Evidence from
joep.2005.09.002
European countries. European Journal of Political
Alm, J., & Torgler, B. (2011). Do ethics matter? Tax compli-
Economy, 26(4), 441–453. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2010.06.003
ance and morality. Journal of Business Ethics, 101, 635–
Lorents, P. (2006). Süsteemide maailm [The world of sys-
651. doi:10.1007/s10551-011-0761-9
tems]. (2nd ed.). Tartu, Estonia: Tartu Ülikooli Kirjastus.
Andreoni, J., Erard, B., & Feinstein, J. (1998). Tax compli-
Mereste, U. (1987). Süsteemkäsitlus: Süsteemsest
ance. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 818–860.
mõtlemisviisist majandusnähtuste käsitlemisel [A systema-
Ashby, W. R. (1958). General system theory as a new disci-
tic approach: A systematic way of thinking in the treat-
pline General Systems, 3, 1–6. Cited in Mereste (1987).
ment of economic phenomena]. Tallinn, Estonia: Valgus.
Bătrâncea, L. M., & Nichita, R. A. (2012). A neuroeconomic
OECD. (2004). Compliance risk management: Managing and
approach of tax behavior. Annals of the University of
improving tax compliance. Paris, France: Organisation for
Oradea. Economic Series, 1, 649–654. TOM XXI.
Economic Co-operation and Development.
Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic
OECD. (2008). Monitoring taxpayers’ compliance: A practical
approach. The Journal of Political Economy, P76(2), 169–
guide based on revenue body experience. Paris, France:
217. doi:10.1086/jpe.1968.76.issue-2
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Boll, K. (2014). Mapping tax compliance: Assemblages, dis-
Development.
tributed action and practices: A new way of doing tax
OECD. (2009). Managing and improving compliance: Recent
research. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 25(4–5),
developments in compliance risk treatments. Paris, France:
293–303. doi:10.1016/j.cpa.2013.03.002
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Braithwaite, V., & Ahmed, E. (2005). A threat to tax morale:
Development.
The case of Australian higher education policy. Journal of
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION 11

OECD. (2010). Understanding and influencing taxpayers´ Taylor, N. (2003). Understanding taxpayers attitudes through
compliance behaviour. Paris, France: Organisation for understanding taxpayers identities. In V. Braithwaite (Ed.),
Economic Co-operation and Development. Taxing democracy: Understanding tax avoidance and eva-
OECD. (2014). International tax terms. Retrieved June 16, sion (pp. 71–92). Aldershot, UK: Ashgate.
2014, from http://www.oecd.org/ctp/33967016.pdf Torgler, B. (2003). Tax morale, rule-governed behavior and
Pollitt, C., & Bouckaert, G. (2011). Public management trust. Constitutional Political Economy, 14(2), 119–140.
reform: A comparative analysis–new public management, doi:10.1023/A:1023643622283
governance, and the Neo-Weberian state (3rd ed.). New Torger, B. (2005). Tax morale and direct democracy.
York, NY: Oxford University Press. European Journal of Political Economy, 21(2), 525–531.
Randlane, K. (2013). A systematic approach to tax compli- doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2004.08.002
ance: The case of Estonia. Sovremennaâ Èkonomika: Torgler, B. (2007). Tax compliance and tax morale: A theoretical
Problemy, Tendencii, Perspektivy, 9, 73–93. and empirical analysis. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Rozenfeld, I. (1975). Süsteemanalüüs [Systems analysis]. Torgler, B., & Schneider, F. (2006). What shapes attitudes
Tallinn, Estonia: Valgus. toward paying taxes? Evidence from multicultural
Schmölders, G. (1932). Steuermoral und Steuerbelastung. European Countries (Discussion Paper 2117). Bonn,
Vierteljahresschrift Für Steuer- Und Finanzrecht, 6, 151–161. Germany: The Institute for the Study of Labor.
(reference is to the 2006 edition The Psychology of Money and Webley, P., Robber, H., Elffers, H., & Hessing, D. (2010). Tax
public finance, Great Britain, Palgrave Macmillan). evasion: An experimental approach. Cambridge, UK:
Schmölders, G. (1960). Das Irrationale in der öffentlichen Cambridge University Press.
Finanzwirtschaft. Probleme der Finanzpsychologie. Wenzel, M. (2004). An analysis of norm processes in tax
Hamburg, Germany: Rowohlt. compliance. Journal of Economic Psychology, 25, 213–228.
Schmölders, G. (1970). Survey research in public finance–a doi:10.1016/S0167-4870(02)00168-X
Downloaded by [62.65.59.21] at 01:00 27 January 2016

behavioural approach to fiscal theory. Public Finance, 25, Wenzel, M. (2005). Motivation or rationalization? Casual
300–306. relations between ethics, norms and tax compliance.
Schmölders, G. (2006). The psychology of money and public Journal of Economic Psychology, 26, 491–508. doi:10.1016/
finance. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. j.joep.2004.03.003
Srinivasan, T. N. (1973). Tax evasion: A model. Journal of Wiener, N. (1961). Cybernetics or control and communication
Public Economics, 2(4), 339–346. doi:10.1016/0047-2727 in the animal and the machine (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA:
(73)90024-8 MIT Press.

View publication stats

You might also like