Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Global Finance Journal


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/gfj

Sustainable finance: A new paradigm☆


Ali M. Fatemi a,⁎, Iraj J. Fooladi b
a
Department of Finance, Driehaus College of Business, DePaul University, 1 East Jackson Blvd., Chicago, IL 60604, United States
b
Douglas C. Mackay Chair in Finance, School of Business Administration, Dalhousie University, Halifax, NS, B3H 3J5, Canada

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Available online 16 July 2013 We argue that our current approach to shareholder wealth maximization
is no longer a valid guide to creation of sustainable wealth: An emphasis
JEL Classification: on short-term results has had the unintended consequence of forcing
G32 many firms to externalize their social and environmental costs. An
G39 unwavering faith in markets' ability to efficiently uncover long-term
value implications of short-term results has created many unacceptable
Keywords: outcomes. Given the social and environmental challenges ahead, such
Sustainable finance practices and their unacceptable outcomes cannot be sustained.
Value creation Therefore, a shift in paradigm is called for. We propose a sustainable
Corporate social responsibility
value creation framework, within which all social and environmental
costs and benefits are to be explicitly accounted for.
© 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction

This paper was first delivered at the 2011 meetings of Global Finance Conference, April 5–7 in Bangkok,
Thailand. The April 2, 2011 edition of Bangkok Post, like other local papers, was filled with reports of the
flooding that had brought death and devastation to many areas of Thailand, and the Krabi area in particular.
Its front page prominently displayed a quote from Samran Thetkit, a Krabi resident: “we have harmed nature,
so nature has taken revenge.” The emphatic tone of this Krabi resident was, perhaps, one of the most
remarkable features of the article reporting on the devastating floods hitting the region. Two days later, the
same paper laid out the cause and effect relationship that Mr. Thetkit had in mind. In that issue, Thawil
Suwanwong, a former Thai agricultural official, blamed illegal logging for Thailand's 2011 flooding.
Mr. Suwanwong was further quoted as laying the blame squarely at the doors of the Thai government,
criticizing its policies in “promoting the planting of rubber and palm trees by boosting their prices”. In
essence, government's actions were held responsible for the deforestation that ultimately led to the flooding
disasters of Thailand in 2011.
Half a dozen years earlier, on a different continent and in the aftermath of Hurricane Katrina, government
inaction was blamed for the extent of damage caused by that storm. Long before Katrina hit the Gulf Coast of

☆ The helpful comments of participants at the 2011 meetings of Global Finance Conference are acknowledged and appreciated.
⁎ Tel.: +1 312 362 8826; fax: +1 312 362 6566.

1044-0283/$ – see front matter © 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gfj.2013.07.006
102 A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113

the United States, the American Society of Engineers had warned of the inadequacies of the Gulf Coast's
defenses against a major storm. The warnings were not heeded, and the country ended up picking the storm's
tab estimated at more than $110 billion. Moving forward in time, the same society's warnings, issued in 2009,
regarding the precarious situation of New York were also treated with indifference.1 Summarizing the results
of simulations of storm surge threats, the group had recommended the installation of surge barriers in New
York harbor to protect New York City. The report was shelved and two years later hurricane Sandy hit the
Northeastern seaboard and the initial estimates of damage ran well in excess of $100 billion. The common
characteristic of these types of governmental actions (or inaction, as the case may be) is an apparent failure to
consider the issue of sustainability in the decision making process. In our first example, to mollify the income
aspirations of an electorate, a government chooses to adopt policies that have short-term payoffs but are
detrimental to the long-term interest of the population and are, therefore, not sustainable. In the second case,
in an effort to minimize the immediate pain of imposing taxes (or otherwise finding a source of financing), a
government ignores the longer-term needs of the society, thus exposing it to much greater risks and to much
higher costs over the long run.2
Similar examples of sacrificing the long-term viability of the firm in exchange for the shorter-term payoffs
are plentiful and can be easily documented across the world. One of the issues that the field of financial
economic needs to address is the question of how to minimize the occurrence of such clearly inferior
outcomes. In this paper, we argue that the solution, or at least part thereof, can be found in academia. Indeed,
it can be argued that some of the blame for the occurrence of these inferior outcomes lay squarely at the doors
of academia. Given our unquestioned faith in the efficiency of the markets, we have turned managers, and
other decision makers, one generation after another into believers of the gospel that today's share price is the
best indicator of long-term true value and that end-of the-quarter earnings numbers are the best indicators of
a firm's true economic performance. Emulating the corporate world, other sectors have followed suit by
putting undue emphasis on the “immediate” and the “short-term” at the expense of longer-term benefits,
thus creating inferior outcomes. However, given the current paper's focus, and without loss of generality, our
analysis will deal with the corporate decision making process.

1.1. Inferior decision outcomes

Perhaps, one of the best ways of demonstrating the detrimental effect of putting too much faith in
short-term earnings numbers and on the share price would be to examine (albeit selectively) the careers of
some who came to be known as the masters of such craft in producing explosive earnings numbers and
skyrocketing share prices. The CFO Magazine annually recognizes such people as having reached the pinnacle
of their careers and bestows upon them the CFO Excellence Award. Let us review the longer-term
accomplishments of the three of their honorees beginning with the winner of the 1998 award, Scott Sullivan
of Worldcom. Less than four years after having received this award, Worldcom filed for Chapter 11
bankruptcy on July 21, 2002, the largest such filing up to that point. In between the recognition and the
bankruptcy, auditors unearthed a $3.8 billion fraud and an avalanche of bogus accounting entries
orchestrated by Mr. Sullivan and his colleagues in Worldcom's executive suite.
The recipient of the 1999 CFO Excellence Award was Andrew Fastow, Enron's CFO. An award that
recognized the spectacular growth of Enron's EPS and its share price which reached a record high of $90 per
share by mid-2000. Not more than a year later a huge scandal unfolded and Enron's shareholders lost nearly
$11 billion when the stock price plummeted to less than $1 per share by the end of November 2001. When

1
See New York Times, “Engineers' Warnings in 2009 Detailed Storm Surge Threat to the Region,” November 4, 2012.
2
Shortsightedness of this type is not limited to national governments or large cities. Examples can be found in many smaller-sized
communities, where decision makers are much more likely to be affected by the consequences of their actions; either directly at a
personal level or indirectly through their effects on their relatives and friends. One such example, reported in the August 30, 2009
edition of the New York Times, from Uniontown, Alabama is worth considering. In exchange for $30 million and the prospect of 30
new jobs, county officials there decided to bury three million cubic yards of coal ash into a landfill. One can easily rule out the
possibility that such a deal could be in the long-term interest of the community, if one considers (1) that coal ash, because of its high
concentrations of toxins (such as mercury, arsenic and other substances), is considered a hazardous waste by the EPA, (2) that the
main source of livelihood for the area residents is catfish farming which will be confronted by a significant risk of contamination
once the coal ash is buried in the landfill, and (3) that the area is susceptible to flooding and tornadoes, exposing the buried material
to a high risk of uncontrolled dispersal. Indeed, the negative elements of the deal appear to overwhelm the short-term benefits.
A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113 103

the dust settled, Enron was forced into bankruptcy as was its auditor Arthur Andersen (the world's largest
accounting firm at the time). The man recognized by the CFO Excellence Award, was found to be the principal
character behind Enron's use of accounting loopholes, special purpose entities, poor financial reporting, and
the concealment of billions of dollars in debt from failed deals and projects.
The winner of the 2000 CFO Excellence Award was Mark Swartz of Tyco International, the man who was
convicted in 2005 of crimes related to his receipt of $81 million in unauthorized bonuses, the use of corporate
funds to purchase art (worth $14.725 million) and a $20 million payment (disguised as investment banking
fees) to a former Tyco director (named Frank Walsh). He was convicted and imprisoned to serve a term of up
to 25 years.
Clearly, these executives, and others like them, were recognized for their short-term performance as
judged by measures rooted in a narrow definition of shareholder value. Had the award criteria been set in a
manner that would have accounted for sustainable performance, these men would obviously not have made
the cut. Indeed, it can be argued that, had the criteria for measuring financial executives' success been defined
with sustainability in mind, the global financial system would have been less fragile, more secure and more
prosperous. To develop a better insight into the degree of fragility of this system and its non-sustainability, let
us now turn attention to four high-profile executives starting with Richard S. Fuld, the former CEO of Lehman
Brothers.
In 2006, the Institutional Investor Magazine named Mr. Fuld America's top CEO in the private sector. In 2007
he had reached the pinnacle of success by having Lehman produce a profit of $4.2 billion (compared to a 1993
loss of $102 million). In March of 2008, he appeared on Barron's list of the 30 best CEOs and was dubbed
“Mr. Wall Street.” He received nearly half a billion dollars in total compensation from 1993 to 2007. In
June of 2008, when Lehman's conditions were rapidly deteriorating, Mr. Fuld expressed confidence about the
firm, declaring it sound. Yet, the bank posted a second-quarter loss of $2.8 billion caused by bad mortgage
investments. A truer picture emerged by March of 2010 when Anton R. Valukas, the bank's court-appointed
examiner, declared that Lehman had used what amounted to financial engineering to shuffle $50 billion of
troubled assets off its books in the months before its collapse in order to conceal its dependence on leverage.
In 2009, the world of investments was shocked by the magnitude of fraud committed by Bernard Madoff, a
former Chairman of the NASDAQ, after he admitted to having operated what has since been described as the
largest Ponzi scheme in history. The amount missing from client accounts, including fabricated gains,
was almost $65 billion and the court-appointed trustee estimated actual losses to investors of $18 billion.
Mr. Madoff admitted that he began the Ponzi scheme in the early 1990s. However, federal investigators
believe that the fraud began as early as the 1970s, and those charged with recovering the missing money
believe the investment operation may never have been legitimate.
A year later, the world witnessed one of the worst industrial accidents in the Gulf of Mexico involving BP.
On April 20, 2010, following an explosion in one of its rigs that killed 11 people, oil started flowing into the
Gulf of Mexico at a rate of 60,000 barrels per day. Eventually more than 4.9 million barrels of oil flowed into
the Gulf. Annoyed by the many questions raised in its aftermath, Tony Hayward, BP's CEO declared on May 30,
2011 “I'd like my life back.”3 Ironically, a year earlier (in May 2009) he had declared that “…our primary
purpose in life is to create value for our shareholders. In order to do that, you have to take care of the world.”4
Fast forward to November 15, 2012, when BP pleaded guilty to 14 criminal charges related to the spill and
agreed to pay a $4.5 billion fine and the total direct bill for the spill may exceed $36.5 billion.5
As a last example in this category, consider the case of MF Global, headed by Mr. John Corzine, that was
forced into bankruptcy on October 31, 2011. The firm's downfall was attributed to its heavily leveraged
purchases of debt from Spain, Italy, Portugal, Belgium & Ireland (by June 2011, it had total debt of $44.4 billion

3
See New York Times, June 3, 2010.
4
Before the Nov 15, 2012 announced payments, BP was forced to spend more than $14 billion on operational response and
cleanup costs and $1 billion on early restoration projects, and paid out more than $9 billion to individuals, businesses and
government entities. In March 2012, BP agreed with the lawyers for plaintiffs to settle claims of economic loss, including from the
local seafood industry, and medical claims stemming from the oil spill. The company said it expected that settlement to be an
additional $7.8 billion, which it will pay from a trust it set aside to cover such costs. Additionally, under the Clean Water Act, BP's
fines could range from $1100 for every barrel spilled through simple negligence to as much as $4300 a barrel if the company were
found to have been grossly negligent. With an estimated 4.9 million barrels of oil spilled in the accident, the company faces liabilities
of as much as $5.4 billion to $21 billion.
5
See “For BP, The Cleanup Isn't Entirely Over,” Wall Street Journal, February 4, 2013, P. B2.
104 A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113

and an equity of only $1.4 billion). In the aftermath of its bankruptcy, it was discovered that hundreds of
million dollars of customer monies were missing.6 One of the many interesting and puzzling aspects of MF
Global story was its compensation policy. In a 2010 speech at Princeton Mr. Corzine slammed excessive
compensation on Wall Street. Yet, the firm's 2011 second quarter results showed that no less than 64% of its
revenue went to compensation. Additionally, Mr. Corzine, in a last-ditch effort, made an attempt to sell MF
Global as late as one day before its bankruptcy. However, had that deal gone through, Mr. Corzine would have
pocketed $12 million in severance pay.7 It is almost impossible to determine if the efforts to sell the firm were
aimed at saving the operations or just a self-serving ploy. Given that it subsequently became clear that
hundreds of millions of dollars of customer monies were missing, it is hard to make a convincing argument in
favor of the first motive.
The common trait among these four individuals and their behavior is an emphasis on immediate results
and a lack of appreciation for the longer-term effects of their decisions. While Tony Hayward may have meant
what he said (i.e., that his objective was to create value for shareholders of BP), his behavior was indicative of
his not having a clue about how to create sustainable value. However, it should be added that the conduct of
Mr. Hayward (and his peers) is, in many ways, the artifact of the system in which they operate. Specifically, if
our decision maker is compensated on the basis of end of quarter results or the corresponding observed share
price, we cannot expect much different behavior. Nor should we have expected anything different from
Richard Fuld and John Corzine.8 In this regard, it appears that all our examples point to a common theme:
doing business like there is no tomorrow. Paraphrasing Richard Branson, sustainability considerations would
call for conducting business as if there is a tomorrow.
It should be noted that this is not a problem confined to corporate executive suites. Too often, it
manifests itself in many personal decisions as well as those made by governmental agencies. On the
former, let us suffice with the example of a dentist by the name of Thomas McFarland who, on August 22,
2008, took his boat to Townsend Inlet near Avalon on the Jersey Shore and dumped a bagful of some 300
dental-type needles and other medical waste from his medical office. The dumping sullied the coast in a
popular area and forced beach closings at the height of vacation time. Dr. McFarland was obviously trying
to maximize his own profits in having chosen to avoid the costs of proper disposal of medical waste by
externalizing his costs to the society at large.9
As an example of the latter, consider the story of what took place in Treece, Kansas. A thriving boom town
of the early 20th century, the unofficial capital of the ore-producing zone in the US. Rich in zinc, lead and iron
ore, it was home to 20,000 people and thriving. The mines closed in the early 1970s and the mining
companies left town. By 2009, the city's population had dwindled to 140 persons living in “a toxic waste
dump of lead-tinged dust, contaminated soil and sinkholes; children riding their bikes around enormous
mounds of pulverized rock laced with lead and iron.”10
The companies that mined Treece, Kansas and left it in such condition did so, most likely, with a single
objective in mind; maximizing shareholder wealth. There is a possibility that they did so while those charged
with the responsibility of looking after the interests of Treece and its residents were looking the other way.
More likely, they did so with the full consent of these “trustees” and “responsible” officials. However, such
consent and approval was not granted with any intended malice. To the contrary, it can be argued that it was
granted out of a desire to maximize the immediate benefits accrued to the community, albeit without any
consideration given to the sustainability of such benefits and the costs attached thereto. It can also be argued
that these officials did so motivated by the political expediency of incentives that drive popular local elections,
namely the creation of jobs and other visible/measureable benefits to the electoral base. Uniontown, Alabama
is a contemporary example, on a smaller scale, of what may have happened in Treece, Kansas a century earlier.
In return for a $30 million infusion of cash into the county's budget and a promise of 30 new jobs, officials
there agreed to bury three million cubic yards of coal ash in Uniontown's landfill.11 The coal ash, from a

6
A US House of Representative report issued on November 15, 2012 concluded that John Corzine's risky bets aided the downfall of
MF Global.
7
See New York Times, “Corzine Crashes Like its 2008,” October 31, 2011.
8
The only exception would have been in the case of Bernard Madoff, where he knowingly committed fraud. But, even in his case
we have a glaring disregard for the question of sustainability.
9
See the Chicago Tribune, September 5, 2008.
10
See “Welcome to Our Town: Wish We Weren't Here,” New York Time, September 14, 2009.
11
See “Clash in Alabama Over Landfill's Plan to Take Tennessee Coal Ash” New York Times, September 30, 2009.
A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113 105

massive spill in an East Tennessee power plant, had a high enough concentration of toxins to be classified as a
“hazardous waste” by the Environmental Protection Agency.12 Given that the main source of livelihood for the
residents of Uniontown is catfish farming, and that the area is subject to frequent floods and tornadoes, it is
not clear that the officials making the decision on behalf of its residents had evaluated the (admittedly harder
to measure) long term costs of their decision before proceeding.13

2. The academic problem

Of course, one may blame mankind's impatience and the relative ease of identifying and measuring
shorter-term costs and benefits as reasons for these kinds of failures. However, a more compelling argument
can be forwarded that, although as advanced societies we have made significant progress on many
longer-term projects (space exploration is one example); we have not made adequate progress on issues
dealing with sustainability. Indeed, one can easily trace back the reason for this failure all the way to the field
of education. Evaluating our students on the basis of outcomes that are dependent on their ability to perform
on standardized tests, and their mastery of test-taking techniques, as opposed to deep learning and dealing
with unstructured problems, we condition them to focus on the short-term. In the field of finance, we go even
further along this path and drill down the notion that the only thing that matters is the maximization of
shareholder's wealth. Further, invoking the efficient markets hypothesis, we turn them into true believers of
the gospel that today's share price is the only barometer that they ever need to watch for. By implication,
therefore, all other issues can be safely ignored.14
Having been so indoctrinated, it should not come as a surprise that the occupants of corporate executive
suites (or those of the boardrooms intended to provide for systems of checks and balances) have their eyes
and minds trained exclusively on the short term payoffs within a me-first framework. Neither should we be
surprised when officials who called the shots in Treece, Kansas, or a century later in Uniontown, Alabama did
so with an apparent total disregard for the long-term consequences of their decisions. Of course, these are
anecdotal examples. But, by no means are they isolated observations. A critical examination would reveal
many other examples. However, whereas up to this point the offenders were able to get away with such
conduct, a different future lies ahead. Driven by dramatic changes in the dynamics of the marketplace, and
innovations in mechanisms for settling up (both ex-ante and ex-post), a radically different decision making
framework is called for. As a result, there is an acute need for a change in our paradigm. The existing models,
that give rise to the kinds of unacceptable outcomes we have reviewed, are no longer tenable and a new
framework will need to replace the current. Otherwise, it will be just a matter of exact time as to when we will
join the ranks of dinosaurs.

2.1. Sustainable value creation

The examples outlined in Section 1.1 share another common characteristic: adoption of a narrow
definition of value; one that ignores and otherwise externalizes some of the costs of a project. These examples
share another common feature as well: unacceptable outcomes. A failure to take into consideration the social
and the environmental costs of a project along with its economic benefits has the potential to create these
unacceptable, and sometimes disastrous, outcomes. Alternatively stated, in order to avoid unacceptable
outcomes the decision maker needs to recognize, and account for, all costs and benefits (economic, social and
environmental) before adopting (or rejecting) a project. In the words of Michael Treschow, Chairman of

12
Mercury, arsenic and other substances that are filtered out, by devices designed to control air pollution, end up in the ash and
make it highly toxic.
13
For a critical review of the questionable outcomes of governmental subsidies aimed at creation of jobs see the New York Times
series on United States of Subsidies, starting with “As Companies Seek Tax Deals, Governments Pay High Price” on December 1, 2012
and concluding with “Lines Blur as Texas Gives Industries a Bonanza” and “Michigan Town Woos Hollywood, but Ends Up With a Bit
Part” on December 2 and 3, 2012.
14
Interestingly, the arguments in favor of this emphasis on the easily identifiable and the shorter-term results and against more
inclusive and robust models have recently become intense. In contrast, elsewhere, we have made significant strides in becoming less
self-centered and more mindful, including the adoption of rules and laws aimed at protecting the rights of vulnerable groups
(children, animals, etc.), and the sanctity of life (consider the extreme expenses we incur by dispatching ambulances, fire trucks and
police to sites of minor traffic accidents).
106 A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113

Fig. 1. The traditional profit maximization model.

Unilever, “[a]t a time when companies are looking to secure long-term growth strategies, we have to develop
approaches that are sustainable in both business and societal terms.” Therefore, we need to shift focus away
from the traditional shareholder wealth maximization and onto sustainable value creation; a model in which
all relevant costs and benefits are appropriately accounted for, rather than simply externalized.
The skeptics would, of course, raise an objection that a firm's only responsibility is to its shareholders and
that its responsibility does not call for dealing with social and environmental issues. However, this argument,
as elegant as it appears at the theoretical level, breaks down at the practical level. The many examples of
product boycotts, legal suits, and activists' actions targeting firms around the globe may be all that is needed
to provide as evidence to the contrary. Nonetheless, we will proceed to provide a more robust reasoning.
Within this context, consider a simple non-constrained profit maximization model portrayed in Fig. 1. A
rational economic agent would produce enough goods or services to achieve maximum profits. If we now
impose a constraint requiring the agent to take remedial action that would compensate for its environmental
impact (associated with its production of goods and services), our simple profit maximization model will turn
into a constrained maximization problem. Absent a shift in the demand curve, the new maximum will be
inferior to the old, as portrayed in Fig. 2. However, the rest of this paper makes an argument that, because of
the world's many challenges ahead, our old models and their accompanying assumptions will no longer
represent reliable guides to the value creation process. Specifically, we argue that, as portrayed in Fig. 3, a
decision to introduce social and environmental constraints has the potential to shift the demand curve such
that the new achievable maximum would dominate the old.
Invoking examples of firms such as Patagonia, Revolution Foods and Waste Concern (among others), it is
easy to see that an enhanced global awareness regarding the full impact of a firm's decisions, coupled with an
ever-increasing availability of information across the globe, will guarantee that the early adopters of social and
environmental responsibility will experience a favorable demand shift for their products and services. More
importantly, it can be argued that non-adopting firms (i.e., those following the traditional profit maximization
model) will experience a negative demand shift as the detrimental effects of inattention to social and
environmental issues become more broadly recognized.15 A failure to duly and fully recognize all costs of doing
business will lead to value destruction rather than value creation. Indeed estimates published by UNEP-FI
(United Nations Environment Program Finance Initiative) indicate that more than 50% of company earnings in

15
Consider the following example: on November 24, 2012 a fire at a garment factory in Bangladesh killed 112 workers. According
to a New York Times article published on December 6, 2012, documents released on December 5, 2012 revealed that five of the 14
production lines in the factory were devoted to the production of garments for Walmart, including its Faded Glory line. These
documents also revealed that Walmart officials played the lead role in blocking efforts to have the firm pay more for apparel to help
the factories improve their electrical and fire safety. Similar articles, containing pictures of the Faded Glory garments sold by
Walmart, appeared in many other news media outlets in the US and the rest of the world. One can then only imagine the reaction of
consumers the next time they come across this brand and associate it with the horrific fire that killed 112 workers.
A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113 107

Fig. 2. The traditional profit maximization in the presence of a constraint.

an equity portfolio, weighted according to MSCI's All-Country World Index, are at risk from environmental
costs alone.16 As an example, consider that following BP's 2010 spill the Norwegian Government Pension Fund
Global, with a 1.75% stake in BP shares, lost more than $1.4 billion.17 Therefore, only an explicit recognition of
social and environmental impacts of the firm's decisions will ensure the sustainability of the value created in
this process.

3. Challenges ahead

3.1. Population growth

According to the statistics published by the United Nations, the current population of the world is seven
billion people.18 Changing characteristics, from high mortality and high fertility to low mortality and low
fertility, this population is expected to grow to 9.2 billion by 2050.19 In order to keep up with this population
growth, and its accompanying economic growth, global food production has to double within the next
30 years.20 Consequently, demand for water and for the croplands needed to feed the world is bound to
outstrip the availability of such resources. Indeed, at the current rate of consumption, many parts of the world
are simply running out of water as aquifers and rivers are sucked dry for irrigation purposes. Rainforests are
also threatened with extinction as demand for new croplands far exceed the supply.
It should be noted, however, that the emergence of new technologies may help reduce the acuteness of this
problem. Nonetheless, while the problem is certain to occur the emergence of such technologies is uncertain.
Furthermore, while such new technologies may provide a temporary respite, they are also capable of
aggravating the problem. In support of this argument consider the fact that during the period between 1700
and 1961 world population grew fivefold as did the global croplands to feed it. That ratio changed dramatically
for the 1960–1990 period as availability of nitrogen fertilizers led to a growth rate of only 8% to meet the needs
of a world population that grew by 80% during this period. However, the magic of nitrogen fertilizers has come

16
See Why Environmental Externalities Matter to Institutional Investors, 2011, UNEP Finance Initiative.
17
See Why Environmental Externalities Matter to Institutional Investors, 2011, UNEP Finance Initiative. The BP oil spill also created a
2.5% loss for a typical UK pension account.
18
See www.unpopulation.org.
19
Life expectancy is expected to increase by one year each year through 2030.
20
Forecasting into 2030, the US National Intelligence Council in 2012 concludes that at the global level, “growth of the middle class
constitutes a tectonic shift.” It also warns that more than half of the world's population will be living in areas that suffer from server
shortages of fresh water.
108 A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113

Fig. 3. Constrained profit maximization with a rightward shift in the demand curve.

to an end as yield increases have leveled off. The world is once again back to clear cutting, this time into the
rainforests and some of the most bio-diversity sensitive areas of the earth (like the Krabi area of Thailand).
Note, however, that once we consider the negative side effects of nitrogen fertilizers on drinking water
supplies, freshwater species, wildlife, and the health problems that it has engendered, it remains far from clear
whether this technology was a desirable solution. Indeed, scientists have blamed farmland runoffs, laden with
the nitrogen fertilizers, as the culprit in creating the dead zone in the Gulf of Mexico that made hurricane
Katrina such a devastating force to New Orleans.21 Therefore, as promising of a solution as they can be,
emerging technologies pose their own set of threats, which could further exacerbate the problem.
Further, note that as producers aim to respond to increased demand for food, negative side effects
may abound. For example, a drive to increase meat and dairy products has had the effect of a diversion of
cereals to animal feedlots. To make matters more unpredictable, government subsidies, aimed at
production of bio-fuels, have encouraged a diversion of additional food sources to the production of fuel.
The result has been acute food shortages and inflation in some areas of the world already suffering from
such problems.22

3.2. Environmental problems

Even if for some unpredictable reason the world population does not increase as predicted, climate change
will make the challenge of feeding the world more of a daunting one. Current estimates indicate that climate
change can curtail world's agricultural production by 17% by the year 2020.23 Further, as the World Wildlife
Foundation and other environmental watch groups have reported, currently 40% of the population of the
world is living in water stress areas. Additionally, one out of ten of the world's major rivers fails to reach the
seas they once did; some do not reach their destined seas at all, others do not reach them part of the year.
(Consider, for example, Rio Grande, Colorado, Indus, Murray-Darling and Yellow Rivers.) As quoted in
BusinessWeek, Ma Jun of China's Institute of Public and Environmental Affairs believes that “China is facing a
dire situation in its water supply.” However, China and its emerging economy is not the only area of concern.
Indeed, the rate of growth in consumption of natural resources (water included) in all emerging markets
exceeds their population growth. To put it mildly, this indicates a less-than sustainable approach to
consumption of natural resources.24 A quantifiable assessment of the environmental damage is provided by
the Finance Initiative of UN Environment Program (UNEP-FI). According to a 2011 study by this agency, the

21
Size of the dead zone in the Gulf of Mexico is estimated to be equal to that of the state of New Jersey.
22
See, for example, “As Biofuel Demand Grains, So Do Guatemala's Hunger Pangs,” New York Times, January 9, 2013.
23
See The Economist, 2009.
24
See Thomas Friedman, Hot, Flat and Crowded, Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2008.
A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113 109

annual environmental costs attributable to global human activity are estimated at $6.6 trillion, equating to
11% of 2008 global GDP.25 The same report puts a price tag of $2.14 trillion on the costs of environmental
damage caused by the world's largest 3000 publicly traded firms in 2008.

3.3. Consumption problem

Let us define sustainable consumption as one that enables the population to enjoy the available goods and
services at a level that would preserve the next generation's ability to do the same. Given this definition,
current global consumption is 1.5 times its sustainable level.26 Needless to say, this ratio is a positive function
of the degree of economic development; much higher in the developed world and highest is the US. World
Wildlife Fund has estimated that if the rest of the world is granted their wish to consume at the same rate as
the average American household (while holding the US rate constant), an equivalent of 11 planet earths will
be needed to support global consumption.27 This is obviously not feasible and, therefore, the world has to find
a way of living within its means.28 Arguably, one of the easiest methods of dealing with this problem may be
to devise new methods to combat food waste. A recent report by UK's Institution of Mechanical Engineers
indicates that almost as much as half of the food produced in the world currently ends up in waste each year.29
The report lists many factors as contributors to this problem: strict sell-by dates, poor infrastructure, and buy
one-get-one free promotions among them. Included in this waste are vegetables as well as meats. However,
transitioning into our next topic, it takes 20–50 times the amount of water to produce a given quantity of meat
than it does to produce the same amount of vegetables.

3.4. Water issues

Estimates compiled by the UN indicate that currently about 700 million people face water scarcity. More
worrisome are the estimates that the combined effects of climate change, population growth and the
increasing per capita demand for water would force this number up to three billion by the year 2025. Further,
it is estimated that over a billion people currently lack access to clean water, and that about 2.6 billion people
lack adequate sanitation. Indeed, about 80% of diseases in the developing world are water related, resulting in
1.8 million deaths each year due to diarrhea. Alarmingly, 90% of such deaths are children under the age of five.
Finally, considering the fact that agriculture already accounts for 70% of human usage of fresh water and that
water scarcity is only likely to worsen, many analysts have become increasingly convinced that the wars of
future are likely to have water at their root.

3.5. Climate change

Alarmed by the preponderance of scientific evidence on human-activity related warming of the planet the
decade of seventies saw the birth of a vigorous debate among policy makers across the globe for possible
solutions to the problem of climate change. However, the 1990s witnessed the emergence of a powerful lobby
that began to question these findings. Financed generously by those with a vested interest in status quo, this
lobby began challenging the veracity of the climate change evidence. Taking a page from the book of tactics
utilized by the tobacco industry to question the reliability of evidence, this lobby has been successful in
forestalling action to combat global warming. Meanwhile, aided simply by anecdotal observations, public
opinion has been shifting in favor of some form action to combat global warming.30 The annual price tag

25
See Why Environmental Externalities Matter to Institutional Investors, 2011, UNEP Finance Initiative.
26
WWF, Living Planet Report, wwf.org.
27
See www.wwf.org.
28
Consider, for example, fish as one component of global food chain. WWF statistics indicate that the global supply of freshwater
species is being depleted at an alarmingly high rate. Holding 1970 as the reference point, global freshwater species population index
stand at less than 50%.
29
Global Food Waste Not, Want Not, Institution of Mechanical Engineers, January 2013.
30
Extreme weather patterns, including unusually strong hurricanes and blizzards, as well as alarming patterns of air pollution have
been contributing factors in this evolutionary process. For example, a January 14, 2013 Financial Times article reporting on the quality
of air in Beijing, indicated that the Chinese government had recorded 900 mg of particulates per square meter, compared with the
usual scale of 50 (healthy) to 500 (dangerous).
110 A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113

associated with climate change is now running at $1.2 trillion, its annual human death toll is estimated at a
staggering 400,000 persons, and is wiping 1.6% annually from global GDP.31 To most decision makers, and to
most electorates, this is not an acceptable outcomes and a change of course is called for.

3.6. Energy

Economic growth, particularly in China, India and the rest of the emerging markets, will give rise to an
explosive increase in demand for energy. Indeed, estimates indicate that world energy demand could nearly
double by 2030, with India and China accounting for more than half of the increase. By that time, fossil fuels
will be meeting 80% of the world's energy demand. The heavy reliance on fossil fuels will take place in spite of
a projected rate of growth of 7.2% per year in renewable sources, principally wind and solar. However, as if
climate change is not a source of immediate risk, approximately 1000 coal-fired plants without CO2 capture
are in various stages of planning and construction across the globe. Ironically, driven by a desire to become
“energy self-sufficient” many countries, including the US, have started diverting agricultural products
(sources of foods to many) into the production of fuel. The shortsightedness of these policies is fairly obvious,
given that in most cases production of biofuels results in a net loss of energy. Additionally, when evaluated in
the context of population growth, these kinds of policies are bound to further exacerbate the challenge of
feeding the world. For example, considering that the United States is currently using 40% of its crop to produce
biofuel, it is not surprising that tortilla prices have doubled in Guatemala, a country that imports nearly half of
its corn. At the same time, Guatemala's lush land has proved ideal for producing raw materials for biofuels.
Suchitepéquez Province, a major corn-producing region five years ago, is now carpeted with sugar cane and
African palm.32

4. Sustainable finance

Although not exhaustive in its presentation of the challenges ahead, the preceding list should be
sufficient in convincing even the most skeptical among us that business as usual is no longer a viable
option. Our current model of shareholder wealth maximization has given rise to practices that either
explicitly or implicitly favor the externalization of many costs of a project, thus creating unacceptable
outcomes. To return to a sustainable path, the current model needs to be discarded in favor of one that
appropriately accounts for the social and environmental costs of a project. Given the scope and the
magnitude of the challenges ahead; (1) the early adopters of models that incorporate the social and
environmental costs of doing business into their decision making framework will experience a favorable
demand shift for their products and services, and (2) the non-adopters will experience a negative demand
shift as the detrimental effects of inattention to social and environmental issues become more broadly
recognized.33 Therefore, failure to account for all costs of doing business will indeed lead to value
destruction rather than value creation. Only an explicit recognition of social and the environmental
impacts of the firm's decisions will ensure sustainability of the value created in this process. It should,
however, be noted that doing so does not call for the NPV approach to be discarded. Rather, it calls for the
full consideration of all incremental, incidental, and opportunity costs as well as such benefits.
X t
Value0 ¼ Cash Flowst =ð1 þ Cost of CapitalÞ
t

Therefore, in addition to the inclusion of usual set of cash flows, the sustainable value creation
approach calls for the explicit recognition of incremental cash flows attributable to the firm's sustainability
efforts. Examples include enhanced brand value, increased customer loyalty, improved ability to recruit
and retain talent, ability to attract new customers (including those demanding social and environmental

31
See Climate Vulnerability Monitor: A Guide to the Cold Calculus of A Hot Planet, Fundación DARA Internacional 2012.
32
The American renewable fuel standard mandates that an increasing volume of biofuel be blended into the nation's vehicle fuel supply
each year to reduce carbon dioxide emissions from fossil fuels and to bolster the nation's energy security. New York Times, Jan 6, 2013.
33
A recent decision by one of US pension funds to divest itself off of the shares of oil companies, because of their contribution to
climate change, is one example of the likely trend ahead. See Financial Times, January 30, 2013, “US pension fund eyes selling oil
holdings.”
A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113 111

results) and the option value of entering markets restricted to firms enjoying a reputation for their
sustainability efforts. It also calls for the explicit recognition of reduced costs due to lower water and
energy usage and the lower costs of: waste, employee healthcare, agency compliance, labor action, liability
and litigation. Further, given that socially responsible firms do a better job of managing their risks (both as
a matter of definition and as supported by empirical evidence), their lower cost of capital should also be
accounted for.34
Does such an approach actually pay off, or does all of this just add up to simple academic musings?
Evidence is accumulating, at a fairly rapid rate, in support of the argument that firms can “do well by doing
good.” For example, evidence compiled by SAM, and reported in its annual reports provides strong support in
favor of the argument that sustainability does pay off.35 Further, indirect support can be inferred through an
examination of the rate of growth in assets under management classified as socially responsible investments.
As reported by Social Investment Forum Foundation, SRI assets under management in the US grew from
$639 billion in 1995 to more than $3 trillion or one out of every eight dollars invested, in 2009. In comparison,
European SRI under management was more than $7 trillion and nearly half of each dollar invested in 2009.
Meanwhile, empirical studies dealing with this question have also been accumulating at a rapid rate with
the majority of evidence in support of the notion that corporate social responsibility does create shareholder
value. Utilizing a database provided by a large financial institution, Dimson, Karakas, and Li (2011) document
an average 4% abnormal return for firms that successfully initiate corporate social responsibility (CSR)
engagement.36 They also document that when the firm's engagement is in the area of climate change or
corporate governance, the market reaction is stronger. This is consistent with the findings of El Ghoul,
Guedhami, Kwok, and Mishra (2011), and Plumlee, Brown, Hayes, and Marshall (2010), who show that US
firms with superior CSR performance enjoy cheaper equity financing.
Barnea and Rubin (2005) find that at low levels of CSR expenditure, the link between these
expenditures and a firm's value is positive, but that the relationship becomes negative when these
expenditures go beyond a certain level. This kind of non-monotonic relationship is also reported by Goss
and Roberts (2011) who study the cost of borrowing and find that firms at the lower end of the CSR
spectrum bear a higher cost of borrowing. Utilizing data for 2261 firms in 43 countries over the 2002–2008
period, Hawn and Ioannou (2012) examine the differential impacts of symbolic and substantive corporate
ESG actions on firm performance. Their results suggest that symbolic ESG actions in the presence of higher
intangibles have a higher positive impact on the firm's market value. Also utilizing data from a large
sample, Servaes and Tamayo (forthcoming) find that CSR activities enhance the value of the firm when
they are accompanied by high public awareness (as proxied proxy by advertising intensity).
Evaluating the question from an investments perspective, and comparing returns of four indexes of
socially responsible companies with that of the S&P 500 index, Statman (2005) finds that Socially Responsible
Investment (SRI) indexes performed better than the S&P 500 during the 1990s and worse during the early
2000s. On the other hand, comparing the characteristics of mutual funds investing in responsible firms with a
group of randomly selected conventional funds, Bello (2005) reports that socially responsible funds do not
differ significantly from conventional funds in characteristics such as diversification and returns. Statman and
Glushkov (2009) report that an investment strategy that is long with CSR leaders and short with laggards
would have produced an annual excess risk-adjusted return of 6.12% for the period 1992–2007.
Using different CSR rankings and similar trading strategies, Derwall, Guenster, Bauer, and Koedijk (2005),
Edmans (2010), and Kempf and Osthoff (2007) report similar findings on the presence of a significant
risk-adjusted outperformance. Fatemi, Fooladi, and Wheeler (2009) compare the characteristics of firms in
the DS 400 index with those of similar firms not included in the index. They report that when compared to
their control group over the period 1990–2005, firms in the DS 400 index produce statistically identical
returns and exhibit similar market risk characteristics. However, they find that their idiosyncratic risk is
significantly lower in every year at the 1% level. They also report that firms that are added to the DS 400 index
experience a positive abnormal return upon the announcements of such occasions. The reverse holds for firms

34
See Fatemi, Fooladi and Wheeler (2009) for evidence on socially responsible firms enjoying a lower risk profile.
35
For example, in a comparison of the performance of sustainability leaders (top 20%) with laggards (bottom 20%) they report an
outperformance of 1.48 for the former and −1.46% for the latter, with corresponding tracking errors of 3.17 and 3.22. See “The
Sustainability Yearbook 2010” SAM-Group.com.
36
However, they find no market reaction where the engagement is not successful.
112 A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113

that are deleted from the index. Nofsinger and Varma (2012) study the performance of a sample of SRI mutual
funds and their matching control groups over the 2000–2011 periods, and report finding that SRI funds
outperform their peers during periods of financial crisis and underperform them during non-crisis periods.
Addressing the question from the broader sustainability perspective, Eccles, Ioannou, and Serafeim (2012)
compare a group of 180 high sustainability corporations (those that voluntarily adopted environmental and
social policies by 1993) to a matched sample of low sustainability firms. They find that high sustainability firms
exhibit fundamentally different characteristics in terms of the roles played by the boards of directors, the
incentive structure of their executive, procedures for stakeholder engagement, and their tendency to be more
long-term oriented. They also report findings indicating that high sustainability firms significantly outperform
their counterparts over the long term. Finally, in a comprehensive study of the effect of CSR on investment
performance, Huppé (2011) reports finding a significant positive relationship between CSR and investment
performance. However, comparing the pre- and post-2005 results, he finds that a trading strategy based on an
equally-weighted, long-only portfolio of good CSR companies produced significantly lower abnormal returns in
the post-2005 period than it did in the 1992–2005 periods. He, therefore, concludes that it may have become
more difficult to achieve superior investment results via a security selection process that is based on the CSR
criteria. As such, CSR characteristics may now be fully priced in the market value of these companies.
In summary, the majority of extant empirical evidence provides robust support for the proposition that
firms are rewarded for their sustainability focus. Further, a growing body of evidence indicates that
expectations of progressively better societal and environmental performance are being built into the markets'
valuation of the firm over time. This evidence combined with exponential increases in settling up costs of
social and environmental damage (both the ex-post and ex-ante) suggests that sustainable value creation is
the only viable way forward. Early adopter of such a framework (those that discard the traditional model that
emphasizes the short term and embrace the sustainable value creation model in its place) will be rewarded in
terms of a market value premium. Firms that choose not to adopt the model will become laggards in the
process of creating value for shareholders.

5. Conclusions

In this paper we argue that the old approach to shareholder wealth maximization is no longer a valid guide
to the creation of sustainable wealth. We propose the adoption of a framework that explicitly recognizes all
incidental and incremental costs and benefits of a project, including all hereto externalized. We argue that (a)
changes in the dynamics of the marketplace has necessitated such a shift in paradigm and that (b) firms that
fail to adopt the sustainable value creation model will become the laggards of their sector, witnessing a
gradual erosion in their market values. As Roberts (2004) posits “[f]irms are institutions created to serve
human needs” (p. 20) and, therefore, “[i]t is also necessary that all the relevant interests [not just those of
shareholders] are recognized and taken into account” (p. 21). As Porter and Kramer (2011) argue, the existing
paradigm of value creation is outdated. In their terminology, “shared value” is the right way of thinking about
value creation so that both the firm and the community benefit from the firm's activities. Alternatively, as
Janicke and Jaco (2012) hypothesize, focus on sustainability will amount to the Third Industrial Revolution.
These new realities call for modifications to the traditional valuation framework in a manner that takes into
account all social and environmental impacts of a firm's activities. If the firm chooses either to ignore such
impacts, or to externalize them, it may be able to buy itself some time. However, the costs of ex-post settling
up will exceed their ex-ante levels by a significant margin. Indeed, emerging evidence suggests that the
probability of ruin may be much higher for such firms.37

37
This is supported by considering the fate of firms that pursue the narrow definition of shareholder wealth maximization only to
find themselves forced into bankruptcy (e.g., see the examples in the first section of this paper) as well as those that come
dangerously close to ruin (e.g., BP). Further support is provided by empirical results such as those of Flammer (2011) who reports
that during the three decades since 1980, negative environmental news has affected firm values at an increasingly negative rate (an
average of .42% drop in the stock price during the 1980–1989 period, 0.66% drop in the 1990–1999 period, and 1.12% drop during the
2000–2009 period). She also reports finding that positive news on a company's environmental behavior is rewarded by an average
increase in stock returns of 0.84%, although the positive investor response to good environmental news has been tapering off in more
recent years. This latter finding is consistent with our proposition that good environmental, social and governance performance will
become the new norm.
A.M. Fatemi, I.J. Fooladi / Global Finance Journal 24 (2013) 101–113 113

We have labeled this the sustainable value creation model. Within this model, valuation of a firm that
ignores its social and environmental responsibilities would require the analyst to fully account for all inherent
costs of environmental and social degradation, including those associated with cleanup, replenishment,
workforce retraining, and community rebuilding, among others. Valuation of firms that have adopted the
sustainable value creation framework, on the other hand, calls for a full accounting of the benefits due to such
entities. Examples include enhanced brand value, increased customer loyalty, improved talent recruitment
and retention, the option value of entering markets restricted to firms enjoying a reputation for their
sustainability efforts, and the ability to attract new customers (including those demanding social and
environmental results). For these firms, there also needs to be an explicit recognition of the incremental
reduction of costs due to sustainability efforts; e.g., savings on water and energy usage, lower costs of waste,
reduction of employee healthcare costs, lower agency compliance costs, and lower expected costs associated
with labor action, liability and litigation. Further, given that firms operating within a sustainable framework
are less risky, their lower cost of capital also needs to be accounted for. This paper further argues that it is only
a matter of time before good environmental, social and governance performance will become the new norm.
Therefore, and as confirmed by empirical evidence, firms that fail to recognize their environmental and social
responsibilities will find themselves valued at a discount relative to their peers.

References

Barnea, A., & Rubin, A. (2005). Corporate social responsibility as a conflict between owners. Working paper. : Simon Fraser University.
Bello, Z. (2005). Socially responsible investing and portfolio diversification. Journal of Financial Research, 28(41), 57.
Derwall, J., Guenster, N., Bauer, R., & Koedijk, K. (2005). The eco-efficiency premium puzzle. Financial Analysts Journal, 61(51), 63.
Dimson, E., Karakas, O., & Li, X. (2011). Activism in corporate social responsibility. Paper presented at the annual meetings of the
financial management, Europe, Istanbul, Turkey.
Eccles, R. G., Ioannou, I., & Serafeim, G. (2012). The impact of a corporate culture of sustainability on corporate behavior and
performance. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 17950.
Edmans, A. (2010). Does the stock market fully value intangibles? Employee satisfaction and equity prices. Working paper. University
of Pennsylvania.
El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O., Kwok, C. C. Y., & Mishra, D. R. (2011). Does corporate social responsibility affect the cost of capital? Journal
of Banking and Finance, 35, 2388–2406.
Fatemi, A., Fooladi, I., & Wheeler, D. (2009). The Relative valuation of socially responsible firms: An exploratory study. In H. -C. de
Bettignies, & F. Lépineux (Eds.), Finance for a better world: The shift toward sustainability. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.
Flammer, C. (2011). Corporate social responsibility and shareholder value: The environmental consciousness of investors. MIT Sloan
School of Management.
Goss, A., & Roberts, G. (2011). The impact of corporate social responsibility on the cost of bank loans. Journal of Banking and Finance,
35, 1794–1810.
Hawn, O., & Ioannou, I. (2012). Do actions speak louder than words? The case of corporate social responsibility (CSR). SSRN working
paper series.
Huppé, G. A. (2011). Alpha's tale: The economic value of CSR. PRI academic network conference, Sigtuna, Sweden.
Janicke, M., & Jaco, Klaus (2012). A third industrial revolution? Solutions to the crisis of resource-intensive growth. SSRN working
paper series.
Kempf, A., & Osthoff, P. (2007). The effect of socially responsible investing on financial performance. European Financial Management,
13, 908–922.
Nofsinger, J., & Varma, A. (2012). Socially responsible funds and market crises. SSRN working paper series.
Plumlee, M., Brown, D., Hayes, R. M., & Marshall, S. (2010). Voluntary environmental disclosure quality and firm value: Further
evidence. Working paper. University of Utah and Portland State University.
Porter, M. E., & Kramer, M. R. (2011). Creating shared value. Harvard Business Review, 89(62), 77.
Roberts, J. (2004). The modern firm. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Servaes, H., & Tamayo, A. (2013). The impact of corporate social responsibility on firm value, the role of customer awareness.
Management Science (Forthcoming).
Statman, M. (2005). Socially responsible indexes: Composition and performance. SSRN working paper series.
Statman, M., & Glushkov, D. (2009). The wages of social responsibility. Financial Analysts Journal, 65(33), 46.

You might also like