Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 7

American Economic Association

Experimental Economics: Induced Value Theory


Author(s): Vernon L. Smith
Reviewed work(s):
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 66, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Eighty-
eighth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1976), pp. 274-279
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1817233 .
Accessed: 03/08/2012 10:55

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org
ExperimentalEconomics:Induced
Value Theory
By VERNON L. SMITH '

It is the premise of this paper that the logical to modify the model in ways sug-
study of the decision behavior of suitably gested by the results of the last experiment.
motivated individuals and groups in lab- Since economic theories always deal with
oratory or other socially isolated settings certain alleged behavioral tendencies in
such as hospitals (R. Battalio, J. Kagel, isolation, the experimental laboratory is
et al., 1973) has important and significant uniquely well suited for testing the validity
application to the development and veri- of such theories. It provides an excep-
fication of theories of the economic system tionally rigorous discipline of our ability to
at large. There are two reasons for this. model elementary situations whether or
1. The results of laboratory studies can not field data can be regarded ultimately
serve as a rigorous empirical pretest of as having been generated by such elemen-
economic theory prior to the use of field tary models.
data tests. The state of economic hypothe- 2. The results of experiments can be di-
sis testing, as it is sometimes done, can be rectly relevant to the study and interpre-
described roughly as follows: based on tation of field data. Other so-called nonex-
casual observation of an economic process perimental sciences such as meteorology
and the self-interest postulate, one de- and astronomy have depended crucially
velops a model, which is then tested with for their development on (a) small-scale
the only body of field data that exists. The laboratory experiments in the physics of
results of the test turn out to be ambiguous mass motion, thermodynamics, and nu-
or call for improvements, and one is clear reactions; and (b) the postulate that
tempted to now modify the model in ways such microphysical experimental results
suggested by the data "to improve the apply, with suitable modifications, to the
fit." Any test of significance now becomes study of the weather, the planets and the
hopelessly confused if one attempts to stars. This parallelism, "As far as we can
apply it to the same data. Where it is pos- tell, the same physical laws prevail every-
sible and feasible, as in the study of price where" (Harlow Shapley 1964, p. 43), also
formation, the data from controlled experi- has application to the study of social
ments can be used to test hypotheses economy. Laboratory experience suggests
stemming from prescientific casual ob- that all of the characteristics of "real
servations of a particular phenomenon. world" behavior that we consider to be of
The fact that one can always run a new primitive importance-such as self-interest
experiment means that it is never tauto- motivation, interdependent tastes, risk
aversion, subjective transactions cost (time
* Department of Economics, University of Arizona. is consumed), costly information (it takes
Support from NSF grants is gratefully acknowledged. time to acquire and process information),
This paper is an articulation of concepts originally and so on-arise naturally, indeed inevit-
developed in the course of several seminars in experi-
mental economics taught at Purdue University, ably, in experimental settings. Anyone
1964-67. who had begun the study of economics in
274
VOL. 66 NO. 2 EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS 275

the laboratory without these concepts qi units acquired by subject i in an experi-


would soon find himself inventing them. mental market. The instructions state that
Furthermore, the process of experimental if subject i acquires qi units at prices p;,
design forces one to articulate rules and p . . . pi, he will receive cash earnings
procedures, the collection of which forms of Ri(qi) -Ekqi1 pk. Neoclassical demand
an institution, organization, or "body of is defined as the quantity that would be
law" with striking "real world" parallels purchased as a function of a given hypo-
(cf. Martin Shubik 1974). The laboratory thetical price p. By this definition, if for a
becomes a place where real people earn fixed p a subject purchases qi units, he
real money for making real decisions about earns Ri(qi)-pqi. If his utility for money
abstract claims that are just as "real" as a is Ui(Mi) he will wish to max,i U [Ri(qi)
share of General Motors. -pqi]. We have an interior maximum if
and only if
I. The Theory of Induced Valuation
(R! -p)U! =0, U' >0, or qi=Ri'(- )(p),
Control is the essence of experimental
methodology, and in experimental ex- for the class of functions Ui, Ri such that
change studies it is important that one be (RI -p)2U'+ U/Ri" <O. This reward
able to state that, as between two experi- scheme induces arbitrary demand R! (-1)(p)
ments, individual values (e.g., demand or on subject i, and the experimentally con-
supply) either do or do not differ in a spe- trolled market demand becomes Q=
cified way. Such control can be achieved Z-1 R' (-l)(p) independent of the U,.
by using a reward structure to induce pre- Similarly, let j-1, 2, . . ., m subject sel-
scribed monetary value on actions. The lers be given cost functions Cj(qj), and re-
concept of induced valuation (Smith 1973) ceive cash earnings pk= kCjq) - from
depends upon the postulate of non- selling qj units at prices pi, pi, . . ., pg . If
satiation: utility is Vj(Mj), Vf >0, then max<. V}[pqj
Given a costless choice between two -Cj(qj)] implies a supply function qj=
alternatives,identical except that the first Cf (-1)(p). The experimentally controlled
yields more of the reward medium (usu-
allv currency) than the second, the first market supply is Q= Ejml Cf (-1)(p) in-
will always be chosen (preferred) over dependentof the Vj. Suchinducedsupply
the second, by an autonomousindividual, and demandbecome flows per period in
i.e., utility is a monotone increasingfunc- experimentsin whichtradingis conducted
tion of the monetary reward, U(M), U' in a sequenceof periods.
> 0. [pp. 22-231
Example2: Let subjecttradersbe given
This postulate applies to experiments de- a tablelistingincreasingconcavecurrency
signed to test price theory propositions receipts M(x,, x2) to be paid by the experi-
conditional upon known valuations. Sepa- menter for terminal stocks (xl, x2) of each
rate experiments can be designed to test of two abstractexperimentalcommodities
propositions in preference theory. exchanged in an experimental general
Example 1. In the experimental study of equilibriummarket.Then subject i's un-
competitive equilibria in isolated markets knownutility for currencyUi(M) induces
it is necessary to induce known (to the ex- the value Ui[M(xl, X2)] on terminalstocks
perimenter) supply or demand on individual (xl, x2). Consequently, the experimentally
subjects. Let subject buyers i= 1, 2, . .. , n controlledindifferencemap given by the
each be given a table listing increasing con- level contours of M(xl, X2) are induced up-
cave total receipts Ri(qj) representing the on subjecti independentof his particular
currency redemption or "resale" value of Ui. That is, each subject'smarginalrate
276 AMERICAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION MAY 1976

of substitution of x2 for xi is given by there is a cost (value) to transacting in the


Ui'Mll U' M2= MlIM2, Uft>0. This al- experimental task, the induced demand
lows the "Edgeworth Box" representation will be smaller (larger).
of general exchange equilibrium to be re- There are several ways of dealing with
produced experimentally by inducing a this problem:
given indifference map on each member of (a) One is to examine the experimental
one group of subjects, and another indiffer- results to see if the quantity exchanged is
ence map on each of a second group of less than predicted. If it is, this is con-
subjects. With given endowments of the sistent with a significant transactions cost.
abstract commodities for members of each Awareness of such transactions cost may
of the two trading groups, the experi- provide valuable clues to understanding
mental stage is set for exchange. why certain experiments may fail to pro-
duce predicted results. The process is not
II. Some Qualifications tautological as long as one can redesign the
There are three important qualifications experiment and show that such conjectured
to the nonsatiation postulate: transactional effects can be reduced.
1. There may be subjective costs (or (b) Another approach is to use a reward
values) associated with market decisions. structure to compensate for, or offset, the
In a competitive market experiment a sub- subjective costs of transacting. There are
ject may find it arduous to monitor and two ways of doing this. (i) One way (Siegel
make quotations, and to execute transac- 1961) is to simply raise the reward level.
tions. If such considerations are not neg- This increases the subjective value relative
ligible, then we lose some control over the to the subjective cost of acquiring units
process of induced valuation. The effect of qi. Let a be a scale parameter determin-
boredom and the subjective costs of deci- ing reward level. Then utility becomes
sion making have been emphasized in the Ui a(Ri [q(Ei) ]-pqi(Ei)), Ei }. Induced
important study by Sidney Siegel (1961). demand is now qi= RI' (-1)(p_ p-U2/Uqia)
Roger Sherman (1974) has interpreted al- ->R (-l)(p) in the limit as a increases pro-
leged violations of the Savage axioms in vided that the marginal rate of substitu-
terms of the subjective cost of making the tion - UI/Ulqi'a decreases with the re-
appropriate computations. In terms of the ward level. (ii) Alternatively, and this is
utility interpretation of the previous sec- the device used most extensively, subjects
tion, the utility function can now be writ- are promised a "commission," i, for each
ten UP(Mi, Ei) where Ei is the "transac- transaction in addition to their cash trad-
tional effort" required to obtain reward Mi ing profits. Now utility is Ui { Ri [qi(Ei) ]
- (p-d3)qi(Ei), Ei }, and induced demand
(cf. Harvey Leibenstein 1969; and im-
plicitly, Ronald Coase 1960). To see the is
potential implications of costly choice,
consider example 1 of the previous section qi = (-U2/ )
Ri 1
in which demand Ri' (-1) (p) is induced upon (-1)p) if :3? - Ul/U,q, > 0.
i. Utility is now U{Ri[qi(Ei)J-pqi(Ei),
Ei } where it is assumed crudely that "bar- Compare two experiments (Charles Plott
gaining effort," Ei, results in the purchase and Smith 1975, pp. 20-21) in which the
quantity qi(Ei). Then maxE, Ui implies induced supply and demand conditions
(Ri'-p) q/ U'+U2=0, and now the in- were identical but one paid no cash trading
duced demand is qi-=R! (-')(p-UUl2Uq) commission, only trading profit, while the
<R (-l)(p), if U <0, q!' >0. Hence, if other paid both: In the one experiment,
VOL. 66 NO. 2 EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS 277

volume was below (17-18 units) the "theo- ditions.) (See Smith 1964, pp. 199-201 for
retical" equilibrium quantity (20 units) in the instructions.) In the first case (Smith
all seven trading periods; in the second ex- 1962, p. 118, Chart 3) subjects trade only
periment, volume was below (19 units) one unit per trading period. The absence
equilibrium in only two of eight trading of cash rewards does not hinder conver-
periods. gence to prices near equilibrium by the
2. Individuals may attach game value third trading period. However, deviations
to experimental outcomes. A profit in increase in period 4. In the absence of cash
"points," Ri(qi) - pqi, may have subjective rewards this is more likely to occur as
value Si [Ri(q) - pqi ]. If Si is monotone in- gaming boredom follows an initial (pleas-
creasing then such game utilities create no ant) experience of learning.
methodological problems since they rein- In a second experiment (previously un-
force rather than distort the effect of an published) buyers received multiunit reve-
explicit monetary reward structure. Be- nue (or resale value) schedules, and sellers
cause of such game utilities it is often pos- multiunit total cost schedules. There were
sible in simple-task experiments to get three buyers with one schedule, eight with
satisfactory results without monetary re- another; four sellers with one cost schedule,
wards by using instructions to induce value eight with another. Now the task is more
by role-playing behavior (i.e., "think of difficult and incentives are weak. Price
yourself as making a profit of such and convergence is strong, especially in the
such when . . . "). But such game values second period, since the greater volume
are likely to be weak, erratic, and easily when traders are given multiple-unit ca-
dominated by transactions costs, and sub- pacities increases the learning experience
jects may be readily satiated with "point" within a trading period. But volume is
profits. considerably below (24 and 26 units in the
Qualifications 1 and 2 are illustrated in first and second periods) the competitive
the convergence behavior of three experi- prediction (30 units). This is consistent
mental markets with no cash rewards and with the above theory where the task is
seven markets with complete and with more difficult (higher transactions cost)
random cash rewards. In the first three and monetary rewards are absent.
cases subjects were asked to imagine that Case 3 (Smith 1962, p. 119, Chart 4)
trading profits and commissions were real. illustrates an experiment which fails to
In each case the market was organized as a reach either the competitive price or quan-
continuous double auction. (Buyers could tity although the market stabilizes nicely.
make oral bids and sellers oral offers for a In this case equilibrium requires contract
single unit, and any seller could accept a prices to fall to the common limit price of
bid, any buyer an offer. Each subject all sellers. They are to "imagine" them-
knew only his own demand or supply con- selves as making a 5-cent commission on

TABLE 1-MEAN CONTRACT PRICE BY TRADING PERIOD

Experiment 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Excess Supply 5 5 5 5 8 8 8
Reward Condition Complete Complete Random Complete Complete Complete Complete
Information Condition Incomplete Incomplete Incomplete Complete Incomplete Incomplete Complete
Trading Period 1 3.48 3.67 3.60 3.51 3.26 3.49 3.56
Trading Period 2 3.29 3.26 3.44 3.40 3.15 3.28 3.25
Trading Period 3 3.19 3.12 3.31 3.34 3.11 3.13 3.20
Trading Period 4 3.14 3.10 3.24 3.37 3.10 3.12 3.17
278 AMERICAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION MAY 1976

trades at these limit prices, but clearly this erable not to embellish the instructions
is not real enough to induce many con- with well-intentioned attempts at "realism."
tracts at $3.10 (the theoretical equilib- Let the explicit reward structure be the
rium). Not even a decrease in demand suc- singular source of valuation, insofar as this
ceeded in lowering contracts to $3.10 is possible.
(Table 1). This contrasts with several ex- 3. Individuals may not be autonomous
periments (1, 2, 5, 6 in Table 1) using com- own-reward maximizers. Interpersonal util-
plete cash rewards in which the supply and ity criteria may qualify the theory of in-
demand are even more asymmetric than in duced valuation. Thus subject i's utility
case 3. In Table 1, markets with an excess may depend upon both i's and k's reward,
supply of five (eight) consisted of eleven Ui [Ri(qi)-pqi, Rk(qk)-pqk ] . If this condi-
buyers with limit prices $4.20 and sixteen tion prevails, then the demand of i may
(nineteen) sellers with limit prices $3.10. A depend upon that of k. However, this kind
different subject group participated in each of interdependence is effectively controlled
double auction experiment. Convergence by the experimental condition of "incom-
to the competitive price and quantity by plete" informatioln, first defined and
trading period 4 was strong, although at studied by Lawrence Fouraker and Siegel
the equilibrium price each buyer receives (1960, 1963) in experimental studies of bi-
$1.15 profit with commission per trade lateral bargaining and oligopoly. Under in-
while each seller receives only the 5-cent complete information subjects only know
commission. their own payoff contingencies. With Rk(qk)
A controlled measurement of the effect unknown to i, it cannot appear as a subjec-
of complete versus random monetary re- tive argument of Ui.
wards is shown in Table 1, experiments The effect when subjects have complete
1--3. In 1 and 2 all subjects were paid their information on each other's payoff con-
trading profit plus commission in cash, tingencies is seen (Table 1) by comparing
while in 3 four of the 27 subjects were 1 (5) and 2 (6) with 4 (7). In 1 (5) and 2 (6)
chosen at random to receive cash profits at each subject knew only his own limit price.
the end of each trading period. The weaker In 4 (7) the only change in the instructions
random reward structure significantly re- was to add the information that there were
tards the market's convergence. eleven buyers, each with a $4.20 resale
Qualifications 1 and 2 lead to a precau- value, and sixteen (nineteen in 7) sellers,
tionary corollary: with or without mone- each with unit cost $3.10. From the mean
tary rewards, the experimenter may be price series it is seen that "complete" in-
tempted to add "realism" by giving the formation of this kind retards the equilib-
abstract experimental commodity a name rium tendencies of the double auction.
such as "wheat," or otherwise attempt to Mean prices, especially in periods 3 and 4,
use instructions to simulate the alleged tended to be higher under complete in-
circumstances of a particular market. This formation than under incomplete informa-
runs the danger of so enriching induced tion. The explanation is that with in-
values that control over valuation is lost. formation on each other's payoffs, the way
Suppose, as above, that a subject is paid is open for "equity" considerations to
Ri(qi)-pqi, but also perceives that he modify self-interest choices. Sellers, believ-
must attach instruction-induced value to ing that it is "fair" for trading profits to be
qi. Utility may now be Ui[Ri(qi)-pqi, qi], shared between buyers and sellers, try to
and demand becomes qi= R- (-1)(p-U UlU,) resist price decreases more vigorously than
> R '(1) (p). Consequently, it may be pref- when they do not know what constitutes
VOL. 66 NO. 2 TOPOLOGY AND GLOBAL ANALYSIS 279

such a fair price. Buyers acquiesce in this H. Leibenstein, "Organizationalor Frictional


sharing by accepting many contracts well Equilibria, X-Efficiency, and the Rate of
above $3.10, but since there is an excess of Innovation," Quart. J. Econ., Nov. 1969,
sellers, those holding out for the higher 83, 600-23.
prices are the sellers most likely to fail to C. Plott and V. Smith, "An Experimental
Examinationof Two ExchangeInstitutions,"
make contracts. Consequently, contract
California Inst. of Tech. 1975.
prices tend to decline, if slowly, when ex- H. Shapley, Of Stars and Men, Boston 1964.
cess supply is 5, but more rapidly when ex- R. Sherman, "The Psychological Difference
cess supply is 8. The tendency of prices to Between Ambiguity and Risk," Quart. J.
be higher under complete information is Econ., Feb. 1974, 88, 166-69.
contrary to the view of those who have M. Shubik, Strategy and Market Structure,
argued that "perfect" information is es- New York 1959.
sential for establishing competitive prices. - "A Trading Model to Avoid Taton-
The results are consistent with the game- nement Metaphysics," Cowles Foundation
theoretic proposition that more informa- disc. pap. no. 368, Feb. 13, 1974.
tion increases the prospect of collusion S. Siegel, "Decision Making and Learning
(Shubik 1959, p. 171), and with the results under Varying Conditions of Reinforce-
of Fouraker and Siegel (1963, p. 187) in ment," Ann. N. Y. Acad. Sci., 1961, 89,
766-83.
which the tendency of the competitive
and L. Fouraker, Bargaining and
equilibrium to prevail under duopoly bar- Group Decision Making, New York 1960.
gaining is reduced under complete infor- V. L. Smith, "An Experimental Study of
mation. Competitive Market Behavior," J. Polit.
Econ., Apr. 1962, 70, 111-37.
REFERENCES "Effect of Market Organization on
R. Battalio, J. Kagel, J. Winkler, R. Fisher, Competitive Equilibrium,"Quart. J. Econ.,
R. Basmann and L. Krasner, "A Test of May 1964, 78, 181-201.
ConsumerDemand Theory Using Observa- "Experimental Auction Markets and
tions of Individual Consumer Purchases," the XValrasianHypothesis," J. Polit. Econ.,
West. Econ. J., Dec. 1973, 411-28. Aug. 1965, 73, 387-93.
R. Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," --, "Notes on Some Literaturein Experi-
J. Law. Econ., 1960, 3, 1-44. mental Economics," Social Science working
L. Fouraker and S. Siegel, Bargaining Be- pap. no. 21, California Inst. of Tech., Feb.
havior, New York 1963. 1973, 1-27.

You might also like