Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 5

Ricardo, David (1772–1823)

Paul A Samuelson, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA, USA


Bryan S Turner, The Graduate Center, The City University of New York, New York, NY, USA
Ó 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
This article is a revision of the previous edition article by P.A. Samuelson, volume 20, pp. 13330–13334, Ó 2001, Elsevier Ltd.

Abstract

David Ricardo is widely regarded as a founding figure in both classical economics and political economy alongside such
figures as Adam Smith and Thomas Malthus. As a practicing financier on the London stock market, he brought his practical
understanding of economics to basic problems in economic theory. Although his contributions to economics have often
been criticized, his position as a founding father of the discipline is secure. A full-scale biography was published in 2013 and
his collected works were edited by Piero Sraffa in 11 volumes (1951–73). Ricardo made important contributions to political
debates in his time such as the corn trade. He made lasting contributions to both microeconomics and macroeconomics in
the law of diminishing returns and to the labor theory of value; consequently, his work was much admired by Karl Marx. By
recognizing that technological improvements could reduce the need for labor if not displace it, he anticipated what is now
referred to as the de-skilling of labor. However, according to Paul Samuelson, Ricardo’s major contribution was to the theory
of comparative advantage, which says that, given international competition, an economy should specialize. Finally, Ricardo
was a champion of free trade and the so-called laissez-faire economics. While Ricardo is highly regarded in economics, his
contribution to the theory of social classes in his analysis of rent, profit, and wages has been neglected in sociology.

One of the most influential of the classical economists, David the Political Economy Club, the King’s Club, and the Geolog-
Ricardo was born in London in 1772 to a Sephardic Jewish ical Society. These social connections were important in his
family of Portuguese origin, who had emigrated from the entry into Parliament in 1818 through purchasing the borough
Netherlands. At 14 years of age Ricardo joined his father at the of Lord Portarlington for 4000 sterling. Ricardo died at Gat-
London Stock Exchange, where he acquired a practical combe Park, Gloucestershire, at 51 years of age from an ear
understanding of the actual mechanics of both domestic and infection that resulted in septicemia. Buried at St Nicholas
international finance. These early experiences laid the foun- Churchyard Chippenham, Wiltshire, he never lived to see the
dation for his subsequent success in amassing a personal 1836 Repeal of the Corn Laws, which was a vindication of his
fortune. Rejecting the orthodox beliefs of his Jewish family, he pamphleteering for free trade, and he did not live to witness
eloped at 21 years of age with Priscilla Anne Wilkinson in Ireland’s great famine of the 1840s with its brutal confirmation
1793, a Quaker by whom he had eight children. On subse- of the laws of the free market.
quently becoming a Unitarian, he was rejected by his family. Among the educated public only a few names stand out in
The elopement and separation from his parents resulted in the history of economic thought. These are Adam Smith, the
a period of personal hardship, forcing him to seek new means spokesman for individualism and competitive capitalism;
to support himself. Robert Malthus, who earned for economics the title of ‘the
With his practical experience of finance, he became a highly dismal science’ from Thomas Carlyle in 1849, by virtue of his
successful stockbroker by unscrupulously trading on the bond belief that any temporary gain in well-being would be under-
market during the Battle of Waterloo in 1815. He was able to mined as a consequence of inducing a population explosion
post an observer at the famous battle conducted by the Duke of that would entail diminishing returns and a retreat back to
Wellington to convey the results of the military engagement. By a subsistence ration of real wages; Karl Marx, the prophet of
creating the impression that the battle had been won by the capitalist crises and the exponent of allegedly scientific
French, he bought government bonds at a sharp discount in the socialism; John Maynard Keynes, proponent of the mixed
ensuing market panic to which he had contributed. This early economy, who rescued capitalism from the post-1929 Great
success formed the basis of his personal fortune, which was Depression and designed Britain’s postwar recovery by inter-
estimated on his death to be worth $100 million in present day ventionist governmental macroeconomic policies and public
dollar values. His private wealth allowed Ricardo to retire early regulation. The classical political economy of Malthus and
and to engage in his scientific interests. He became attracted to Ricardo is often associated with the idea of negative unin-
the study of economics as a result of reading Adam Smith’s The tended consequences of action. Both men were criticized by
Wealth of Nations (1776) while on vacation in the English resort Albert O. Hirschman for their ‘rhetoric of reaction’ or the
of Bath in 1799. Ricardo began to write influential articles ‘perversity thesis,’ namely “any purposive action to improve
about the pressing economic matters of the day such as the corn some feature of the political, social, or economic order only
trade and became acquainted in 1811, with such influential serves to exacerbate the condition one wishes to remedy”
figures as Jeremy Bentham and James Mill. He engaged (Hirschman, 1991: 7). For example, raising the wages of the
a lengthy correspondence with Thomas Malthus over the role working class would be self-defeating, because it would
of the landowning class in British society. He achieved prom- increase the fertility rate of the poor resulting eventually in
inence as a member of several influential London clubs such as more poverty.

660 International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2nd edition, Volume 20 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.61111-X
Ricardo, David (1772–1823) 661

Within the economics profession, Ricardo has now ach- However, even in those distant times much of the money
ieved a prominent status, but in the past he was not always employed for purchase and sale transactions involved the use
respected and recognized. In his History of Economic Analysis, of paper money currency. As is customary in times of war,
Joseph A. Schumpeter (1954) coined the phrase ‘the Ricardian whatever the supply of domestic gold or silver, there ensued
vice’ to describe how Ricardo piled up arguments to hide his a considerable rotation of the printing press to finance
confusion of facts and values. He also complained that Ricardo government needs and accommodate the desire for the
had failed to make any real progress in the development of enhanced cash necessary to conduct the enlarged volume of
a general equilibrium model. Among twentieth-century econ- goods transactions and their higher average prices. Under these
omists perhaps the most important tribute to Ricardo came circumstances, whenever a government chooses not to redeem
from Paul A. Samuelson (1969), who was once challenged by paper currency notes into specie at their previous face value,
Stanislaw Ulam the Polish mathematician, to name any those notes will depreciate in price relative to ounces of specie.
nontrivial universal law in the social sciences. After some The high price of gold is what the person in the street calls this
reflection, Samuelson claimed that it was Ricardo’s analysis of phenomenon and there was considerable controversy as to its
‘comparative advantage,’ which stated that to achieve successful causes. Ricardo attributed all of the rise in gold prices to over-
development a society should not attempt to focus on a range issue of paper notes.
of diverse productive activities, but only on those economic Today one can entertain counterfactual history. Somehow
activities that gave them a comparative advantage in interna- the British government might have taxed the populace more
tional trade. heavily to finance the enhanced war effort and maintain
In retrospect we can now see him as the archetypical clas- a balanced budget and the inescapable rise in relative import
sical economist, the economist’s economist who supposedly prices. As a general strategy the government could have
improved upon Smith and spelled out with Euclidean logic the imposed tightness in bank lending, enforceable only at higher
eternal behavior of the market system. In an amiable exchange interest rates, and conceivably could have kept the stock of
of letters with Malthus, Ricardo was undoubtedly the outright paper currency unchanged. The outcomes would almost
winner, because Malthusian fears of recurrent depression certainly have included higher unemployment and extra loss of
stemming from underconsumption spending were argued to consumption on the civilian populace. With heroic tightness,
be fallacies. The self-made millionaire David Ricardo captured trade balances might even have been forced to cancel out to
the respect of the Victorian devotees to laissez-faire as well as zero. It is hard to envisage how normal peacetime unemploy-
socialistic critics of Marxian or romantic stripe. He has recently ment levels could have somehow been made to prevail from
received an excellent if somewhat overdue full-scale biography say 1795 to 1810 in this counterfactual scenario. An inflation-
(King, 2013). free war can thus be painfully conjured up in counterfactual
Ricardo was also fortunate in having Piero Sraffa edit for the history and with no wartime increment of paper currency issue.
Royal Economic Society, over a period of 25 years, a magnifi- In actual history, paper notes depreciated and price levels
cent and complete edition in 11 volumes of The Works and soared. As happened a century later, during the 1920–23,
Correspondence of David Ricardo (1951–73). Although this German hyperinflation, economists held opposing views of
collection revived interest in Ricardo’s economic thought, appropriate economic policies. Ricardo argued that overissue
oddly it seems to have contributed to a revisionist erosion of in currency M explained virtually all of the rise in the price of
his analytic reputation. Whereas the late-Victorian Alfred bullion. Henry Thornton, practical banker and Bank of England
Marshall, pillar of post-1870 neoclassicism, had idiosyncrati- authority (at first), argued that the microeconomic phenomena
cally argued that the good modern stuff was already in Ricardo, of adverse trade balances and war-induced buoyant business
and whereas Keynes had written in the 1920s that Ricardo had activity explained a significant fraction of the observed appre-
‘the finest mind that had come to economics’ – neither ciation of bullion. Ricardo’s 1809–10 strong assertion of what
Ricardo’s late twentieth-century admirers nor detractors could was called the ‘bullionist view’ won him instant celebrity,
agree among themselves as to what his different virtues and particularly with the dogmatic James Mill. But this economic
vices actually were. A scholar who is much misunderstood debate was not really a zero-sum game in which Ricardo’s gain
cannot be acquitted of all responsibility for ambiguity. had to equal Thornton’s loss. Both men agreed on the likely
Reversing the usual order of intellectual progress, Ricardo longest-run outlook. The price of gold in terms of paper would
first made his mark in what has come to be called macroeco- be the same in 1850 if, in the many preceding decades, the
nomics. His unqualified verdict typifies his noneclectic style. supply of paper currency was limited enough to permit free
To finance a very long war against Napoleon, Britain specie–currency convertibility at the old 1790 ratio. In this
expanded its money supply of paper currency in order to instance, the so-called ‘Ricardian vice’ was his use of long-run
procure goods at home and abroad for its armies. Price-level true relations to characterize actual short-run patterns in
inflation was unsurprisingly part of the economic history in economic history.
that period. The eclectic theory of Adam Smith would no After the first decade of the nineteenth century, Ricardo
doubt have predicted as well a worsening of terms of trade as concentrated mostly on microeconomics. In 1815 (and not prior
Britain and other belligerents bid up the relative prices of to then), along with Malthus and Edward West he helped to
needed imports. Had gold and silver been the sole money articulate the ‘law of diminishing returns’ and its consequences
used then in Britain and elsewhere, the 1750 theories of David for land rent determination. Society’s product, for example,
Hume would have predicted a drain of specie from London to corn, is produced by labor and by land, both working together.
pay for the war-induced trade deficit of exports compared When you increase labor in two equal increments, working on
to imports. fixed land, you acquire two successive increments of corn. But
662 Ricardo, David (1772–1823)

the second gain is presumptively less than the first – a techno- durable tools). He may even have worked out, in an unpub-
logical law of nature. Thus the wage that the competitive lished manuscript that has not survived, a one-sector farm-only
market can pay to labor goes down when labor/land density model. A determinate model of distribution could have
increases, and the rent that the market will pay for land will go cogently defined a long-run stationary-state equilibrium for
up. This is not a new idea – it is in Benjamin Franklin (1755) (real corn wage rate, interest rate, real corn rent rate) ¼ (W/
early in the eighteenth century and already in Smith (1776) – Pcorn ¼ w ,r , Rent/Pcorn ¼ R*). How would it have gone?
but it is an important insight that needed to be made explicit. Like Malthus and other predecessors, Ricardo would have
Already Ricardo had perceived what he considered faults in specified exogenously a classical ‘subsistence wage’ rate, w ,
Adam Smith. Posterity can be grateful that this perception needed to keep population just reproducing itself. Like his
tempted Ricardo into economics, even though it can be argued classical successors Ricardo would have specified exogenously
convincingly that Smith was mostly correct in the cases where a minimal interest rate, r , needed to keep capital(s) just
Ricardo criticized him. For example, in the capital-and-land- reproducing themselves. Land being a classical constant, A,  its
and-produced-capital models that both writers worked with, stationary equilibrium rent rate he would residually determine
Smith was right to jettison the ‘labor theory of value’ as soon as once variable labor-and-capital stocks, Lt and Kt, dynamically
either the interest rate and/or the land rent rate becomes converged to their long-run, asymptotic stationary equilibrium
significantly positive. levels: Lt / L*; Kt / K*, when K is a single scalar. Finally,
As between the two tasks of political economy – short-run determination of wt and rt would be market-clearing
(1) understanding how relative scarcities of factors of produc- rates dependent on the relative transitional abundances
tion constrain the alternative availabilities of different goods of Lt and Kt.
and their valuation relations; and (2) how society’s harvest gets Here is how in the spirit of Prokofiev’s ‘Classical’
distributed among and between the different social classes of Symphony, an ambitious neophyte in a 1932 Hicks–Wicksell
workers and owners of property – Ricardo arbitrarily declared it neoclassical workshop might synthesize these classical insights
was distribution that was all important. Yet nowhere in the into a coherent simplistic dynamic :
equation system, using the
11 volumes of his Works and Correspondence (1951–73) will the notational convention dYt/dt ¼ Y t :
reader find a complete and satisfactory theory of distribution
:
that went beyond what was already in Smith, Malthus, Mill, or Factor supplies : Lt =Lt ¼ j Þ
ajεðwt  w
: [1]
modern mainstream writers.  ðrt  r Þ; At hA
K t =Kt ¼ b  ¼ 1
Perhaps the lack of a university education contributed to
Ricardo’s methodological style. Frequently, he asserted general 1=3
 Kt
Factor demands : wt ¼ s =L2=3
‘truths’ that admit of important exceptions; repeatedly he failed 1=3 2=3 [2]
Lt =Kt
rt ¼ s
to distinguish between necessary and sufficient conditions for an
argument. He was a superb miniaturist but with an absence of where s is an exogenous parameter denoting level of technical
coherence, particularly in his post-1815 textbook phase. productivity.
Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage in international When the modern crank of deduction gets turned, Ricardo’s
trade, similar to that of the contemporary Colonel [1] and [2] do lead convergently to a determinate classical
Robert Torrens, is a brilliant example of his miniaturist  0, as t / N,
stationary state. From any initial (L0 K0 A)
virtuosity.
  
Perhaps with hindsight, this is a somewhat harsh judg-  Kt A;
wt ; rt ; Lt A;  Rt
ment on 1810–23 David Ricardo, but one can be even    
1  2  1   1 [3]
harsher on Ricardo’s twentieth-century commentators. The / w ; r ; s w  r ; s  ; s
 r 2 w ½rw :
3 3 3
brightest and the best of them – Piero Sraffa, George Stigler,
Samuel Hollander, Mark Blaug, and scores of others – while One must commend the classical tradition for so subtle an
understanding that the positive interest and time-phasing accomplishment. The version worked out here differs from
of production generically invalidate Ricardo’s champion- Paul Samuelson’s ‘canonical’ model, which had more faithfully
ing of the labor theory of value (as, indeed, Ricardo himself adhered to the conventional labor-capital ‘dose’ version
intermittently admitted), at the same time they appear (Samuelson, 1978).
blind to the parallel fact that positive rent(s) on scarce This above supply–demand equilibrium is definitely not
land(s) must similarly invalidate the labor theory of value. independent of the problem of how consumers wish to allocate
Edwin Cannan, Knut Wicksell, Jacob Viner, and Lionel their earned incomes among the many goods, when there are
Robbins are exceptions to this general criticism about how many noncorn goods in the market. Then there are no ‘natural
labor/land intensities generically invalidate any labor prices’ definable independently of how consumers choose to
theory of value in the same logical way that time intensities spend their incomes.
are known to do so. Definitely goods’ relative price ratios do not remain
Around 1815, between his macroeconomic works on gold close to proportionality with their respective embodied
and his Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817, 1819, labor contents, P it /P jt s (Lit /qit)/(Lj/q jt). Likewise embodied
1821), Ricardo puzzled over a simple scenario involving a farm land contents (Ait /qit)/(Ajt/q jt) and embodied capital contents
good (corn) and one or more manufactured goods (cloth and (K it /qit)/(K jt /q jt) similarly fail as approximations to empirical
other products), all produced by, say, homogeneous labor, actual P i/P j ratios.
homogeneous land, and by one or more produced inputs (corn Since Ricardo did not coherently understand the intricacies
seed, raw materials from farming used for manufactures, and of his own classical scenario, he never realized how
Ricardo, David (1772–1823) 663

unattainable was his hankering to have all relative prices filter-down process, the armchair philosophers were getting their
determinable purely by objective technology and cost data. first intimations of the complexity of how a market system hands
Subjective variabilities (1) of consumers’ utilities and demand out its distributive awards.
choices, and (2) of intertemporal saving-and-consuming In summary, David Ricardo, like the twentieth-century
choices – which became central preoccupations of post-1870 economists Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman, impor-
neoclassical thinkers to the classical school – were thus tantly pushed voters and public opinion toward libertarian
already unavoidable in the capital, land, and labor models of laissez-faire. Victorian England’s Whig society and Manchester
classical theory and in the competitive scenarios that Marx School owed much to him. In the modern debate about how
grappled with all his working life. This inevitability will come a modern mixed economy can optimally compromise between
with pain for the small sect of Sraffian neo-Ricardians who market mechanisms and democratic rules of conduct, Adam
proliferated after 1925 and especially 1960. Smith and John Stuart Mill appear to be more subtle classical
Ricardo was low keyed and civil in argumentation, albeit thinkers. From these two, autocratic rulers like Lenin, Stalin,
firm in holding to his strong positions. The letters between and Mao could have had much to learn. But among the
Ricardo and Malthus, notwithstanding their obvious differ- worldly philosophers, David Ricardo must be counted as an
ences, were a model of courtesy and affection. Despite Ricardo’s important influence on the formation of the twenty-first-
typical unqualified dicta, he did not hesitate to change his century mind.
mind and admit to previous mistakes. Marx, who abhorred While Ricardo’s status among classical economists is secure,
classical authorities and for whom ‘Parson’ Malthus was he has not received sufficient attention from sociologists.
a particular bête noir, was uncharacteristically soft toward Ricardo developed the basis of a theory of social classes before
Ricardo. Here is an illustrative incident. After the first edition of Karl Marx’s class conflict theory and before Max Weber (1978)
Principles, but prior to its third edition, Ricardo had declared had developed his famous model of ‘class, status, and power.’
that technical invention must always help all factors of There were important social classes in Ricardo’s work – the
production, including the working man. He encouraged disci- working class who depend on wages, the landowning class who
ples, like J.R. McCulloch, to affirm this strong view. However, extract rent, and the bourgeoisie who exploit the labor of the
on reconsideration, Ricardo came to realize that some inven- workers to create profit. Ricardo had been especially critical of
tions can assuredly replace labor and reduce the demand for labor in ‘Old Corruption,’ namely the ability of the rent-seeking aris-
the short and the long run. Therefore, despite warnings from his tocracy to dominate Parliament in their own narrow interests.
friends that this position would weaken the case for laissez-faire, In classical sociology, Marx argued that with the maturation
Ricardo added a new chapter on Machinery to the third (1820) of capitalist society there would be a class polarization and two
edition of the Principles, presenting exposition and numerical dominant classes would appear – the proletariat and the
examples designed to show how labor’s share of national bourgeoisie – as the driving force of history. Barrington Moore
income could suffer from certain possible inventions and how (1966) in The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy
long-run equilibrium populations and gross income levels provided a more complex comparative analysis more consist
could be permanently lowered. With virtually no exceptions, with Ricardo in which democracy required a thriving bourgeois
ancient- and twentieth-century authorities agreed that for once class, while authoritarian regimes are the product of a weak
Homer had nodded. For once Ricardo must have invoked bourgeoisie and an alliance between the peasantry and aristo-
rigidity of wage rates with its resulting unemployment, thus for cratic landowning class such as the Junkers in Germany. He
once denying J.-B. Say’s sacred dogma that overproduction is advanced the slogan – ‘No bourgeoisie, no democracy.’
impossible in a capitalist system. Karl Marx praised the scholar Advanced capitalist societies are no longer so obviously strati-
for his honesty. fied into social classes that exert collective political influence,
It is a story that casts discredit on virtually all. The Ricardo– and some sociologists argue that, following Ricardo, the tech-
McCulloch original sweeping position was gratuitously wrong. nological revolutions of the twentieth century have brought
A new wind that raises an economy’s potential for production about some de-skilling of the workforce leading to an erosion
and consumption most certainly can do harm to some compet- of the political clout of the working class (Braverman, 1974).
itors while helping others. Ricardo did not claim, as J.S. Mill and Modern societies are instead characterized less by class conflict
Vilfredo Pareto were to argue subsequently, that gainers could and more by growing income inequality and the hollowing out
always bribe losers so that with intervention all could gain. Nor did of the middle class (Krugman, 2003). These sociological
Ricardo’s new understanding motivate him to abandon debates indicate that Ricardo should be regarded as a founder
a dogmatic defense of laissez-faire. His critics on Machinery, both of modern sociology as well as of classical political economy.
then and in our time – including Knut Wicksell, Nicholas Kaldor,
Joseph Schumpeter, and George Stigler – failed to see the
See also: Economic Growth: Measurement; Economics, History
absence in Ricardo’s exposition of any denial of dogmatic Say’s
of; Innovation and Technological Change, Economics of;
Law and its ruling out theoretical harm from under-
Libertarianism; Malthus, Thomas Robert (1766–1834); Market
consumption. Instead his usual classical scenario of population
Structure and Performance; Marx, Karl (1818–83); Monetary
decline dictated by the induced drop in the wage below an
Policy Since the 2007–2009 Financial Crisis; Political Economy,
alleged equilibrium subsistence rate would, as the Machinery
History of; Regulation, Economic Theory of; Smith, Adam
chapter alleged, call for an ultimate drop in population and gross
(1723–90); Social Stratification; Sociological Theory; Stock
product as a result of labor-saving invention(s). Just as the
Market Predictability.
Industrial Revolution was beginning to raise wages by a genuine
664 Ricardo, David (1772–1823)

Bibliography Niehans, J., 1990. A History of Economic Theory. Classic Contributions, 1720–1980.
The Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.
Ricardo, D., 1817. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. John Murray, London.
Braverman, H., 1974. Labor and Monopoly Capitalism. The Degradation of Work in the
Ricardo, D., 1951–73. In: Sraffa, P., Dobb, M.H. (Eds.), The Works and Correspon-
Twentieth Century. Monthly Review Press, New York.
dence of David Ricardo, 9 vols. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Franklin, B., 1755. Observations Concerning the Increase of Mankind and the Peopling
Samuelson, P.A., 1969. The way of an economist. In: Samuelson, P.A. (Ed.), Inter-
of Countries.
national Economic Relations: Proceedings of the International Economic Associa-
Hirschman, A.O., 1991. The Rhetoric of Reaction. Perversity, Futility, Jeopardy. The
tion. Macmillan, London, pp. 1–11.
Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Samuelson, P.A., 1978. The canonical classical model of political economy. Journal of
Keynes, J.M., 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money.
Economic Literature 16, 1415–1434.
Reprinted in: 1977–81 the Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Macmillan,
Samuelson, P.A., 1989. Ricardo was right! Scandinavian Journal of Economics 91,
London.
47–62.
King, J.E., 2013. David Ricardo. PalgraveMacmillan, London.
Schumpeter, J., 1954. History of Economic Analysis. Oxford University Press,
Krugman, P., 2003. The Great Unravelling. Losing Our Way in the New Century. W.W.
New York.
Norton, New York.
Smith, A., 1776/1937. In: Cannan, E. (Ed.), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of
Malthus, T.R., 1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population as It Affects the Future
the Wealth of Nations. The Modern Library, New York.
Improvement of Society, with Remarks on the Speculations of Mr. Godwin, M.
Sraffa, P., 1926. The laws of returns under competitive conditions. The Economic
Condorcet and Other Writers. J. Johnson, London [Reprinted by Macmillan,
Journal 36, 535–550.
London, 1926].
Sraffa, P., 1960. Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. Cambridge
Marshall, A., 1890–1920. Principles of Economics. Macmillan, London.
University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Marx, K., 1867, 1885, 1894. In: Capital Volumes I, II, and III. Verlag von Otto
Thornton, H., 1802/1962. An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of
Meissner, Hamburg [Penguin Books, Harmondsworth, 1976, 1978, 1981].
Great Britain. Augustus Kelley, New York. Reprinted, Frank Cass, London.
Moore, B., 1966. The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Lord and Peasant
Weber, M., 1928/1978. Economy and Society. University of California Press, Berkeley.
in the Making of the Modern World. Beacon Press, Boston.

You might also like