The Journal of Finance - 2023 - KEPLER - Stealth Acquisitions and Product Market Competition

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 101

Stealth Acquisitions and Product Market Competition

JOHN D. KEPLER, VIC NAIKER, and CHRISTOPHER R. STEWART1

1
John D. Kepler is at the Stanford Graduate School of Business. Vic Naiker is at the University of Melbourne.
Christopher R. Stewart is at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business. We thank Chris Armstrong,
Phil Berger, Henk Berkman, Philip Bond (Editor), Judy Chevalier, Merle Erickson, Ian Gow, João Granja, Joe
Harrington, Jerry Hoberg, Bob Holthausen, Amy Hutton (discussant), Steve Kaplan, Zach Kaplan, Dave
Larcker, Christian Leuz, Neale Mahoney, Mihir Mehta (discussant), Mike Minnis, Valeri Nikolaev, Micah
Officer, Eric Posner, Claudia Robles-Garcia, Joe Schroeder, Amit Seru, Shawn Shi, Douglas Skinner, Chad
Syverson, Dave Tsui, Rodrigo Verdi (discussant), Lulu Wang, Thomas Wollmann, Alminas Žaldokas
(discussant), several current Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission staff members, and two
anonymous reviewers, as well as workshop participants at Boston College, Deakin University, Singapore
Management University, University of Amsterdam, University of Chicago, University of Notre Dame, Stanford
GSB, Stanford Summer Camp, the UTS Summer Accounting Conference, the University of Illinois Young
Scholars Research Symposium, and the Western Finance Association Conference for helpful comments and
suggestions. We thank Janelle Nelson, Nicolas Min, Nicholas Scott-Hearn, and the Stanford GSB Data,
Analytics, and Research Computing team for outstanding research assistance. We gratefully acknowledge
financial support from the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, the University of Melbourne, and
the Stanford GSB. Researcher(s) own analyses calculated (or derived) based in part on data from Nielsen
Consumer LLC and marketing databases provided through the NielsenIQ Datasets at the Kilts Center for
Marketing Data Center at The University of Chicago Booth School of Business. The conclusions drawn from
the NielsenIQ data are those of the researchers and do not reflect the views of NielsenIQ. NielsenIQ is not
responsible for, had no role in, and was not involved in analyzing and preparing the results reported herein. We
have read The Journal of Finance’s disclosure policy and have no conflicts of interest to disclose.

Correspondence: John D. Kepler, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, 655 Knight Way,
Stanford, CA 94305; e-mail: jdkepler@stanford.edu.

This article has been accepted for publication and undergone full peer review but has not been
through the copyediting, typesetting, pagination and proofreading process, which may lead to
differences between this version and the Version of Record. Please cite this article as doi:
10.1111/jofi.13256.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
ABSTRACT

We examine whether and how firms structure their merger and acquisition deals (M&As) to avoid

antitrust scrutiny. There are approximately 40% more M&As than expected just below deal value

thresholds that trigger antitrust review. These “stealth acquisitions” tend to involve financial and

governance contract terms that afford greater scope for negotiating and assigning lower deal values.

We also show that the equity values, gross margins, and product prices of acquiring firms and their

competitors increase following such acquisitions. Our results suggest that acquirers manipulate

M&As to avoid antitrust scrutiny, thereby benefiting their own shareholders but potentially harming

other corporate stakeholders.

A core mission of regulators in most countries is to prevent anticompetitive practices that harm

consumers. To carry out this mandate in the United States, the Department of Justice (DOJ) and

Federal Trade Commission (FTC) conduct extensive reviews to evaluate the potential impact of

corporate mergers and acquisitions (M&As) on competition. Concerns about the increasing

incidence of anticompetitive M&As motivated the adoption of the Hart-Scott-Rodino (HSR) Antitrust

Improvements Act of 1976, which established a premerger notification threshold that requires

parties to notify the DOJ and FTC of their intent to merge if their deal is above a specified value.2

2
As of 2020, at least 41 countries, including all 10 of the world’s largest economies, have some threshold in

place for the purpose of premerger notification (Thomson Reuters Practical Law (2020)).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

2
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Recent adjustments to the threshold rule mean that the vast majority of M&As now go without

antitrust review (e.g., Wollmann (2019)).3 Thus, although a key purpose of M&As is to achieve

productivity improvements for acquirers or synergies between acquirers and targets (e.g., David

(2021)), many questions remain about the potential anticompetitive effects of M&As that are not

subject to regulatory scrutiny.

A long line of corporate finance research examines the role of M&As in creating or

destroying shareholder value (see, for example, Eckbo (1983), Schipper and Thompson (1983), and

Asquith (1983), Agrawal, Jaffe, and Mandelker (1992)), and suggests that one important way M&As

create value for shareholders is by consolidating the acquirer’s industry to increase the firm’s own

market power (e.g., Hoberg and Phillips (2010a), Fathollahi, Harford, and Klasa (2021)). Such

increases in market power can be substantial and potentially harmful to other corporate

stakeholders—especially consumers—and thus are precisely the reason that antitrust regulators pay

close attention to the competitive effects of M&As. Accordingly, prior literature typically assumes

that firms conduct their M&As seeking regulatory approval for a given deal under the confines of the

current antitrust regime. However, this literature assumes away the possibility that firms can

actively circumvent the regulatory rules for screening of anticompetitive deals.

In this paper, we study whether firms engage in “stealth acquisitions,” that is those

deliberately negotiated and structured to assign deal values that fall “just below” the regulatory

notification threshold. We find a substantial number of stealth acquisitions where by firms

3
In our full sample from 2001 through 2019, we find that almost two-thirds of M&A deals, which collectively

represent $240 billion in aggregate deal value, fall below the applicable filing threshold.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

3
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
manipulate the terms of their M&A financial and governance contracts to avoid oversight and review

by antitrust regulators. These acquisitions, while beneficial to shareholders of the acquiring firm,

have broader stakeholder implications by inducing anticompetitive effects that can harm other

corporate stakeholders (e.g., target shareholders and consumers).

The question of acquirers systematically circumventing antitrust rules is not only of

academic interest to financial economists. Reflecting concerns about stealth acquisitions, the FTC

recently launched initiatives aimed at understanding the anticompetitive effects of nonreportable

deals (FTC (2020)).4 For example, in 2020 the FTC launched antitrust investigations into all

nonreportable acquisitions since 2010 by five of the leading U.S. technology firms—Amazon, Apple,

Facebook, Google, and Microsoft—due to concerns that many of these deals had anticompetitive

consequences (e.g., Kamepalli, Rajan, and Zingales (2021)). These regulatory concerns extend

beyond the technology sector, as stealth acquisitions in nontechnology industries could have more

direct consequences for other stakeholders in terms of increased product prices for consumers. Yet

little is known about whether acquirers across industries systematically structure deals to evade the

notice of resource-constrained antitrust regulators and, if so, how these stealth acquisitions are

structured and the extent to which these deals impact product market competition. This paper

attempts to fill this gap.

4
In 2014, DOJ Deputy Attorney General Overton noted that potential harm to consumers cannot be measured

by the size of the transaction or merging parties (DOJ (2014)). She elaborated on how nonreportable

transactions could give rise to antitrust concerns, including harm to consumers in regional markets, adversely

affecting the market for a key input to a downstream product, and reducing competition in a narrow product

market that still creates issues.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

4
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Using data on all M&A transactions for U.S. firms between 2001 and 2019, we first

document evidence of a discontinuity around the premerger notification threshold. Specifically, we

find a 28% to 45% higher-than-expected number of deals “bunching” immediately below the

threshold that would trigger antitrust review.5 We refer to these potentially manipulated deals as

“stealth acquisitions.” If scrutinized by antitrust regulators, these stealth acquisitions would increase

the number of Second Requests by 4% to 6%.6 We further find that bunching of M&As just below the

threshold does not occur when we examine other M&A deals whose values are further away from

the threshold that would trigger antitrust review, when we focus exclusively on acquisitions in

industries that are always exempt from the premerger notification program (i.e., hotels and real

estate; FTC (2008)), and when we assess deal discontinuity based on the next year’s notification

threshold. Evidence of significant M&A activity just below the threshold, together with the absence

of such a discontinuity in the “falsification tests” suggests that some acquirers deliberately manage

the size of their deals to avoid antitrust review.

We next conduct several tests to better understand the characteristics of the targets and

acquirers engaging in these stealth acquisitions. First, consistent with concerns that large public

5
Our lower-bound estimate of 28% deals more than expected just below the threshold assumes an ―intended

effect‖ of the regulation, that is, the increase in deal activity just below the threshold regulators would expect to

see. Our upper-bound estimate of 45% assumes no expected discontinuity around the threshold and compares

actual mergers to expected.

6
A Second Request allows the FTC or DOJ to extend its merger review and ask the parties to submit additional

information to accommodate a closer look at how the merger will impact competition. We discuss our procedure

for collecting Second Request data in Section III.F.3.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

5
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
companies find ways to make reportable transactions nonreportable, we find that acquisitions

involving public firms acquiring smaller private targets are 31.3% more likely to occur just below the

threshold. We also find that financial contracts incorporating earnouts, which allow managers of

acquiring firms to exercise discretion in the methods used to assign deal values so that they fall just

below the deal-size threshold, are more likely in these just-below acquisitions. In addition, we find

that deals involving acquirers that extend the directors and officers (D&O) insurance coverage of

private target firms or that agree to higher post-acquisition breach-of-terms deductible thresholds,

both of which can allow acquirers to negotiate lower deal values, are more likely to be just below

the threshold. Consistent with these lower deal values being actively managed to avoid antitrust

review, we find that public acquirers pay lower deal premiums for private targets in acquisitions that

fall just below the threshold.

One might wonder why, in equilibrium, managers of target firms are willing to accept values

that are manipulated to fall below the threshold. We conduct several tests that provide insights into

why target firm managers would be willing to make such decisions. First, we find that deals involving

cash payments, which reduces the exposure of targets to risk associated with the post-acquisition

stock holding requirements of U.S. securities laws, are 28% more likely to be just-below deals.

Second, consistent with concerns that acquirers can take advantage of target shareholders by

providing private benefits to target CEOs in exchange for lower deal values (e.g., Morck, Shleifer, and

Vishny (1988), Fich, Cai, and Tran (2011)), we find that deals with governance contracts that employ

target CEOs post-acquisition are more likely to be stealth acquisitions, and in such cases earnout

provisions are 6% more likely to pay off. These findings suggest that acquirers compensate target

firms and their managers for lower deal values with implicit and explicit benefits in financial and

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

6
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
governance contracts to facilitate deal values that fall below the threshold that otherwise would

have triggered antitrust review.

Next, we study the economic incentives of acquirers to negotiate and assign lower deal

values to avoid antitrust scrutiny. We expect deals involving acquirers with incentives to coordinate

with their targets—e.g., acquisitions in concentrated industries, which are typically of greater

concern to antitrust regulators due to their potential to harm consumers (Gowrisankaran, Nevo, and

Town (2015), Wollmann (2019), Eliason et al. (2020))—are more likely to fall just below the

premerger review threshold. Consistent with this expectation, we find that the discontinuity is

largely due to acquirers with the strongest incentives to coordinate with their targets, that is, rivals

from the same industry. We also find that this relation is more pronounced for deals that involve

acquirers and targets in the same geographic area and deals in more concentrated industries.

Together, these findings suggest that deals likely to have anticompetitive effects that are harmful to

consumers tend to be structured as stealth acquisitions that narrowly avoid antitrust review.

We conduct several tests to examine whether stealth acquisitions benefit acquiring firms’

shareholders at the cost of other stakeholders such as consumers through reduced product market

competition. Prior studies argue that certain patterns in the returns of industry rivals around a

merger are indicative of reduced product market competition. In particular, benefits of mergers that

only provide synergies to the acquirer should not propagate to rival firms, while benefits from

mergers that result in increases in product market prices should (e.g., Eckbo (1983), Stillman (1983),

Chevalier (1995a), Fathollahi, Harford, and Klasa (2021)). Consistent with the anticompetitive nature

of stealth acquisitions, we find that public announcements of just-below mergers are associated with

12.5% higher abnormal returns for rival firms when such acquisitions are horizontal in nature, that is

between direct competitors operating in the same industry, relative to announcements of horizontal

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

7
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
mergers that are just above the threshold. We also examine changes in the gross margins of

acquirers and their industry rivals and find a 1.1 percentage point increase in industry-average gross

margins in the year after horizontal acquisitions falling just below the threshold compared to

horizontal acquisitions just above the threshold.

As a direct test of the impact of stealth acquisitions on consumers, we narrow our focus to

three acquisitions during our sample period—one just below, one just above, and one well below

the premerger deal value threshold—by horizontal rivals in the consumer products industry. This

analysis, which employs product-level prices for the acquirer and rivals that share common products

with the targets, is based on the idea that product pricing patterns of industry rivals following events

that reduce product market competition can help identify anticompetitive behavior (e.g., Chevalier

(1995b), Azar, Schmalz, and Tecu (2018)). Consistent with reduced product market competition, we

find an increase in average monthly product prices for product market rivals’ common products

following our stealth acquisition of interest, while we find no change in prices for the just-above or

well-below deals.

We conduct several additional tests to assess the robustness of our results and consider

potential alternative explanations. Our results are robust to alternative bin sizes, do not hold for

several definitions of already-exempt mergers, are robust to alternative fixed effect structures (e.g.,

industry-year), and are robust to alternative definitions of “horizontal” mergers (e.g., Hoberg and

Phillips (2016)). When we consider several nonmutually exclusive alternative explanations for our

inferences, we do not find evidence that the bunching we find below the threshold is driven by (i)

acquirers’ incentives to delay merger announcements until the subsequent year, (ii) mergers that

are already exempt under alternative thresholds (i.e., the “size-of-person” test), or (iii) firms

avoiding Second Requests from antitrust authorities for innocuous reasons.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

8
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Our study makes three contributions to the broad literature on the role of M&As in product

market competition. First, we contribute to the emerging literature on the relation between

antitrust enforcement screening and M&A activity. While newly exempt horizontal deals increased

following a change to the notification screening thresholds (Wollmann (2019, 2020)), our study

highlights differences in and potential manipulation of the contracts of deals that fall just below the

threshold. In particular, we show that firms can structure M&As to avoid antitrust scrutiny and

reduce competition by exploiting regulators’ monitoring resource constraints at the expense of

target shareholders and consumers. While prior literature typically assumes that managers extract

private benefits from shareholders alone, our study adopts a broader stakeholder governance

perspective to shed light on the possibility of managers extracting private benefits from other,

nonshareholder stakeholders such as consumers.

Our study also contributes to the literature on the interaction between corporate finance

and product market competition—e.g., Eckbo (1983, 1992), Chevalier (1995a, b), Sheen (2014),

Wollmann (2020), Eliason et al. (2020), Fathollahi, Harford, and Klasa (2021)—by providing initial

evidence on whether and how acquirers intentionally structure deals to avoid antitrust enforcement

and reduce product market competition. A concurrent study by Wollmann (2020) on mergers in the

U.S. kidney dialysis sector does not find bunching of M&A deal values around the notification

thresholds, and attributes this result to the legal risk associated with intentional avoidance of

notifications. In related work, Cunningham, Ederer, and Ma (2021) show that incumbent

pharmaceutical firms acquire innovative targets solely to “kill” their projects, and that some of these

deals fall just below the threshold for premerger review, but they do not examine how these deals

are structured to avoid antitrust scrutiny. Our study contributes to this recent literature by

documenting the explicit financial and governance contracting mechanisms that are used to

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

9
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
manipulate deal values. Given the effects of these deals on nonshareholder stakeholders such as

consumers, future research at the intersection of corporate finance and antitrust regulation can play

a particularly important role in informing academic and policy debates about shareholder- versus

broader stakeholder-based corporate governance (e.g., Bebchuk (2004, 2005), Edmans (2021)).

Finally, our study contributes to the industrial organization literature on the evolution and

regulation of competition (e.g., Shahrur (2005), Azar, Schmalz, and Tecu (2018), Wollmann (2019),

De Loecker, Eeckhout, and Unger (2020)). Our evidence suggests that concerns about the limited

efficacy of sharp premerger review guidelines are warranted (e.g., Rose and Sallet (2020)), as a

conspicuous number of firms appear to manipulate their deal size to circumvent regulatory review,

potentially harming consumers. Moreover, while our focus on M&As around this threshold is well

suited to identify bunching as evidence of deal manipulation, our findings likely extend to M&As

around other filing thresholds and regulations. Therefore, if anything, our estimates likely

underestimate the frequency and impact of M&A antitrust regulation avoidance.

The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. Section I discusses institutional features of

antitrust regulation for M&A deals and related academic literature. Section II describes our sample

and key variables. Section III presents results on the existence of and contracting for stealth

acquisitions. Section IV presents results on the effects of stealth acquisition on product market

competition. Section V provides concluding remarks.

I. Institutional Background and Related Literature

A. Antitrust Regulation and M&As

Competition law in the United States places strict limits on the ability of M&A deals to

impact industry competition. For instance, Section 7 of the Clayton Act prohibits M&As “in any line

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

10
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
of commerce or in any activity affecting commerce in any section of the country, [where] the effect

of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly.”

Moreover, Section 5 of the FTC Act prohibits “unfair” methods of competition. To enforce these

regulatory objectives, the antitrust division of the DOJ and the FTC rely on the HSR Antitrust

Improvements Act of 1976 to review potential anticompetitive effects of M&A deals before they

take place. The filing of the premerger notification report allows regulators up to 30 days to perform

a review of whether the proposed transaction will adversely affect U.S. commerce under antitrust

laws.7 Figure 1 illustrates the FTC’s typical premerger review notification process and potential

outcomes of this process on an M&A deal’s ability to proceed.

[INSERT FIGURE 1 ABOUT HERE]

While the HSR Act initially required notification filings on all transactions that exceeded a

threshold of $15 million, in 2000 Congress significantly amended this size-of-transaction threshold to

apply only to transactions with a deal value above $50 million.8 The rationale for exempting deals

7
The 30-day period is expected to allow regulatory agencies to request additional information, extend the

waiting period by another 30 days, and determine whether it will file a challenge based on antitrust regulations

to block a deal. Notwithstanding a request for additional information by the regulators, the parties must wait 30

days after filing (15 days in the case of a cash tender offer) or until the agencies grant early termination of the

waiting period before they can close the transaction.


8
Size-of-transaction refers to the value of the assets, voting securities, and noncorporate interests that are being

acquired. Since September 30, 2004, the size-of-transaction filing threshold has been adjusted each year based

on the change in gross national product and applies to deals valued at $94 million or more effective as of

January 21, 2020. For transactions above the size threshold and below a higher threshold (e.g., $200 million in

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

11
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
with a value below $50 million was that such transactions were unlikely to raise substantive antitrust

concerns. In which case requiring notifications for smaller deals may impose an unnecessary burden

on firms and/or weaken regulators’ monitoring capacity, costs that can exceed the social welfare or

efficiency benefits from identifying competitive issues from small deals.9

The adjustment to the size of the transaction threshold had a dramatic effect on premerger

notifications. Notably, while the number of annual notifications increased by around 33% in the

three-year period leading up to the 2000 size-of-transaction threshold amendment, notifications fell

by 79% in the three years immediately following the amendment (DOJ (2004), FTC (2004)). Recent

evidence suggests that the increase in the size-of-transaction threshold increased the prevalence of

horizontal mergers between firms in the same industry. For instance, Wollmann (2019) estimates

that the decade following the threshold increase witnessed up to 324 additional horizontal mergers

per year that collectively involved the acquisition of targets worth a total of $53 billion in annual

revenue. Further, while the general authority granted to FTC and DOJ under Sections 6 (b), 9, and 20

of the FTC Act and Section 1312 of the United States Code on Commerce and Trade permits them to

retrospectively investigate nonreportable transactions, Wollmann (2019) shows that mergers that

are newly exempted from the premerger notification requirement are less likely to be subject to

regulatory investigation after the M&A deal is executed. These observations give rise to concerns

2001), premerger antitrust review might be avoided if the sales or assets of the target or acquirer are less than a

specified amount (e.g., $10 million for the target and $100 million for the acquirer in 2001), which is referred to

as the size-of-person test. We examine the impact of the size-of-person test on our results in Section III.F.5.
9
Fines for failing to file a transaction that meets the requirements for premerger notification are $41,484 per day

as of January 23, 2018, which is typically enforced.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

12
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
that smaller nonreportable M&A deals can also raise competitive issues that violate antitrust

statutes.

Concerns over antitrust risk from small deals are further supported by anecdotal evidence of

higher financial gains that acquirers realize from such deals. For example, a study conducted by

McKinsey & Company indicates that firms that adopt a systematic approach to M&As through the

use of an increased number of small deals are able to accrue more market capitalization relative to

peers that focus on larger deals and selective acquisitions (Rudnicki, Siegel, and West (2019)). These

concerns have led antitrust regulators to question the potential anticompetitive effects arising from

nonreportable M&A transactions. For instance, in a 2014 speech, DOJ Deputy Assistant Attorney

General Overton noted that potential harm to consumers is unlikely to be captured by the size of the

transaction or by merging party market values (DOJ (2014)), and he elaborated on how

nonreportable transactions could give rise to antitrust concerns, including harm to consumers in

regional markets, adverse effects on the market for a key input to a downstream product, and

reduced competition in a narrow product market that still creates broader or national issues (e.g.,

impair the quality of voting equipment systems).

Consistent with these regulatory concerns, antitrust challenges against nonreportable

transactions have increased significantly in recent years (e.g., Mason and Johnson (2016)).

Moreover, in February 2020, the FTC issued an order under Section 6(b) of the FTC Act to formally

launch its own antitrust investigations into every nonreportable acquisition made by five of the

leading U.S. technology firms—Google, Amazon, Apple, Microsoft, and Facebook—dating as far back

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

13
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
as 2010. 10 The FTC stated that its probe would help it understand “whether large tech companies are

making potentially anticompetitive acquisitions of nascent or potential competitors that fall below

HSR filing thresholds” and reform its policies to promote competition and protect consumers.

Subsequent statements released by FTC commissioners Rohit Chopra and Christine Wilson

questioned the sufficiency of the HSR notification process in other industries and called for studies

across a broader range of industries to gain a better understanding of the competitive effects of

nonreportable mergers (Wilson and Chopra (2020)).

B. Related Literature

Although it is illegal for firms to engage in business practices that harm competition under

Section 7 of the Clayton Act, a large body of industrial organization research studies firms’ incentives

to engage in anticompetitive behavior (e.g., Stigler (1964), Harrington and Skrzypacz (2011)). Within

this literature, several studies examine how lax M&A antitrust enforcement in the pharmaceutical

industry leads to an increase in anticompetitive mergers and worse product market outcomes for

consumers in terms of higher product prices (e.g., Eliason et al. (2020)).11 Furthermore, Cunningham,

10
For example, Facebook made more than 80 acquisitions during this time, of which dozens involved small

deals that were not reportable under the HSR Act (Cox (2020)). See www.arstechnica.com/tech-

policy/2020/02/feds-launch-a-probe-into-big-techs-smallest-acquisitions.

11
Related work by Eliason et al. (2018) and Einav, Finkelstein, and Mahoney (2018) exploit variation in

thresholds that determine hospital reimbursements in the setting of long-term care hospitals to identify strategic

behavior on the part of hospitals as to when they discharge patients.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

14
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Ederer, and Ma (2021) provide evidence that this result is due in part to large acquirers amassing

firms with similar research projects and terminating overlapping innovation—i.e., risky

pharmaceutical drug projects—of targets. These studies examine whether certain M&A deals have

anticompetitive effects, but do not examine how firms achieve such anticompetitive M&A deals in

the first place.

Building on this literature, a burgeoning corporate finance literature explores the broader

relation between anticompetitive behavior and corporate finance practices. For example, Eckbo

(1992) and Shahrur (2005) find that horizontal mergers tend to be bad for consumers and that rents

accrue to all firms in an industry following horizontal M&A deals, consistent with recent evidence on

firms’ efforts to more easily navigate the FTC’s antitrust review process (e.g., Mehta, Srinivasan, and

Zhao (2020)). More recently, Dasgupta and Žaldokas (2019) find that increases in the cost of explicit

collusion lead to more M&A activity and equity issuances, and Azar, Schmalz, and Tecu (2018)

provide evidence from the U.S. airline industry that a common ownership structure can lead to

anticompetitive pricing strategies.

Our study contributes to these growing corporate finance and economics literatures by

identifying (i) evidence of firms manipulating the size of their M&A deals to avoid antitrust scrutiny

as a novel channel through which firms avoid regulatory scrutiny, (ii) the financial contracting

characteristics of these stealth acquisition deals that facilitate regulatory avoidance, (iii)

heterogeneous industry and market conditions that incentivize firms to participate in stealth

acquisitions, and (iv) the impact of these stealth acquisitions on competition among firms’ product

market rivals. In these regards, our study is the first to examine firms’ avoidance of antitrust

regulation by manipulating the size of their deals, and offers novel evidence that such avoidance is

detrimental to consumers.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

15
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
II. Data and Descriptive Statistics

A. Data Sources and Key Variables

Our initial sample comes from all completed and terminated U.S. M&As involving public and

private targets and acquirers announced from January 2001 through February 2020 on the Thomson

Securities Data Company (SDC) Mergers and Acquisitions database. Following Moeller,

Schlingemann, and Stulz (2005), we exclude deals below $1 million. We also discard all deals

involving targets that are financial firms (SICs 6000 to 6999) or regulated utilities (SICs 4900 to 4999),

as M&As of these types are subject to industry-specific merger regulation that is unrelated to our

analysis. Finally, we exclude deals involving the acquisition of hotels and motels (SIC 7011), as these

acquisitions are always exempt from premerger review (FTC (2008)). This selection process,

presented in Panel A of Table I, yields a final sample of 19,886 deals with non-missing acquirer and

target firm data for the key variables in our analyses. We use this sample of deals to test for a

discontinuity in M&As around the premerger review threshold and assess the types of firm and deal

characteristics involved in stealth acquisitions.

[INSERT TABLE I ABOUT HERE]

We also examine the financial contracting terms, incentives, and product-level prices for

stealth acquisitions. While we rely on the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) and SDC for

data to construct many of our key variables, data to capture other deal provisions important to our

study (e.g., earnouts, deal premiums for private targets, provisions for extended D&O coverage, and

post-closing deductible thresholds) are collected by reading through merger-related financial

contract disclosures found in EDGAR 8-K, 10-Q, and 10-K public filings. For tests that require

extensive hand collection, we restrict our test sample to 640 deals that fall just below and above the

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

16
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
premerger notification thresholds, presented in Panel B of Table I. Our data collection process is

detailed in the Internet Appendix.12

B. Descriptive Statistics

Panel C of Table I shows that the top 10 industries represented in our full sample account for

almost 70% of M&A deals, with the largest number of deals (around 30% of all deals) completed by

acquirers in the business services industry. Panel D of Table I presents the comparable distributions

for the top 10 industries in two subsamples representing deals with transaction values that are

within 10% of the annual FTC notification threshold—i.e., deal values that are either ≥ 0% but ≤ 10%

below the threshold, or ˃ 0% but ≤ 10% above the threshold (just-below-threshold deals and just-

above-threshold deals, respectively). We find that the top 10 industries in these two subsamples

consist of the same industries in Panel C, with the exception of the personal services industry and

the construction industry, indicating that the mix of deals that occur near the premerger notification

threshold is similar to the mix across all M&A deals. Further, the two subsamples are similar to each

other and the full sample on the distribution of observations across industries (e.g., business services

accounts for 33% to 34% of observations). The absence of any industry being overrepresented in the

subsample of deals that are within 10% below the threshold suggests that the scrutiny of deals by

DOJ/FTC does not appear to vary significantly across industries in a manner that produces a greater

concentration of below-threshold deals in certain industries.

[INSERT TABLE II ABOUT HERE]

12
The Internet Appendix is available in the online version of this article on the Journal of Finance website.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

17
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Panel A of Table II presents descriptive statistics on the variables used in our main empirical

analyses. We find that the average deal value of acquisitions in our full sample is approximately $400

million (DealValue) and that roughly 77% of deals involve a private target (PrivateTarget).

Panel B of Table II illustrates how the acquirer, target, and deal attributes vary across the

two restricted subsamples of just-above- and just-below-threshold deals. While the statistical

difference between the values of deals (DealValue) involving just-above- and just-below-threshold

targets is expected, the mean difference amounts to only $7.31 million, which is small relative to the

general variance of deal values in our full sample (standard deviation = $2.6 billion). This implies that

deals just above and just below the threshold are in essence fundamentally similar, as suggested by

the insignificant differences in the values of nearly all of the other variables across the two

subsamples of firms. We find some evidence of greater use of earnouts (Earnouts) and cash and

other nonstock payments (AllCashandOther), as well as lower use of all-stock financing (AllStock), in

just-below-threshold deals. Moreover, acquirers in deals that are just below the threshold are more

likely to have a future economic tie with a target CEO (EconomicTie).

III. Characteristics of Stealth Acquisitions

This section examines three features of stealth acquisitions. First, we examine the existence

and prominence of stealth acquisitions by assessing the frequency of deals occurring just below

relative to just above the premerger review notification threshold. The advantage of this approach is

that it focuses on a narrow subset of deals in close proximity to the threshold, deals for which

merger activity and attributes of the acquirers and targets involved should be similar. Second, we

examine differences in deal and financial contract characteristics for M&A deals occurring just below

relative to just above the premerger review notification threshold. These tests allow us to identify

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

18
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
the types of deals that most often bunch just below as well as the financial and implicit contracting

mechanisms that facilitate acquirers’ ability to manipulate deal values to below-notification levels.

Finally, we investigate whether stealth acquisitions are more likely to consist of deals that can lead

to anticompetitive outcomes. Together, these analyses allow us to understand the incentives that

drive firms to intentionally structure deals to avoid antitrust scrutiny.

A. Existence of Stealth Acquisitions

We first examine whether firms seeking to avoid antitrust review structure financial

contracts such that deal sizes bunch just below the premerger review dollar-based threshold, leading

to a discontinuity in the number of M&As occurring in close proximity to the threshold. While

circumventing the review process significantly reduces potential regulatory costs, such as forced

asset divestitures or even blocking of the merger, to the benefit of shareholders, anticompetitive

behavior following the acquisitions of existing or nascent competitors can attract complaints from

customers and competitors in the aftermath of acquisitions. This in turn can prompt regulators to

conduct post-acquisition reviews and issue enforcement actions aimed at deals that were not

subject to premerger notification—even years after deals have been completed, which can be costly

to shareholders. The significance of this threat is underscored by the fact that remedies sought by

antitrust regulators in such cases can be harsher than in deals with premerger notification (Heltzer

and Peterson (2018)). This is because the unwinding of transactions to restore competition to

premerger levels can require the closure of business units, divesture of acquired assets at fire-sale

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

19
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
prices, and other costly interventions.13 Such potential costs can disincentivize acquirers and targets

from manipulating transaction sizes to avoid notification. Consistent with this view, Wollmann

(2020) does not observe bunching of deal values just below the threshold in the dialysis industry. As

such, the extent to which a discontinuity exists in the number of M&As surrounding the notification

thresholds across sectors in the broader economy is an open question.

A.1. Research Design

To first document evidence on the existence of stealth acquisitions, that is, on a

discontinuity in the number of M&A deals around the premerger notification threshold, we take

advantage of two notable features of the HSR Act: (i) annual adjustments to the dollar-based

threshold for requiring premerger notifications (shown in Figure 1), and (ii) the tracking of these

adjustments to the U.S. gross national income growth rate. Together, these features result in a time-

varying threshold that grows (or shrinks) by unequal dollar amounts annually, which we exploit to

examine near-threshold deal size activity.

We begin by calculating the signed distance, in dollars, between each deal’s value and the

threshold in a given year (see Appendix B for a discussion of the data we use to measure deal

values). We define this measure as

Distance-from-Thresholdi,t = DealValuei,t – Thresholdt, (1)

13
For example, in 2017 the FTC challenged the acquisition of Synacthen Depot by Mallinckrodt subsidiary

Questcor Pharmaceuticals, Inc., which was not subject to the premerger notification requirement. The

allegations were settled by Mallinckrodt agreeing to disgorge $100 million in obtained profits as well as

divesting part of the acquired assets.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

20
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
where i represents a unique deal and t represents time.14 Our Distance-from-Thresholdi,t measure

standardizes the time-varying threshold, allowing us to plot our data around a single threshold

centered on zero.

In our first set of tests, we use these signed distances and employ McCrary’s (2008) test for a

discontinuity at the threshold (e.g., Jäger, Schoefer, and Heining (2021)). The null hypothesis of the

McCrary test in our setting is that the discontinuity around the premerger notification threshold is

zero, that is, absent manipulation of deal sizes, a significant difference in the number of deals

occurring just below relative to just above the threshold should be unobservable. In a first stage,

McCrary’s test obtains a finely graded histogram and smooths the histogram on either side of the

threshold using local linear regression techniques. In a second stage, the McCrary test evaluates the

difference in the density heights just below and just above the threshold. A finding of a significant

difference in these heights would be indicative of a discontinuity.

A.2. Main Results

[INSERT FIGURE 2 ABOUT HERE]

Figure 2 presents a graph of the McCrary (2008) test of continuity in the density function

around the premerger review threshold. The solid lines, which depict the density function around

the review threshold along with the 95% confidence intervals (i.e., dotted lines), provide visual

14
For example, a deal of size $85 million ($95 million) in 2018 (2019) when the premerger notification

threshold was $84.4 million ($90 million) would be assigned a Distance-from-Thresholdi,t value of $85 – $84.4

= $0.6 million ($95 – $90 = $5 million).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

21
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
evidence of a discontinuity. A Wald test, reported in Panel A of Table III, confirms this by rejecting

the null of continuity of the density function at the threshold (p-value < 0.01).

[INSERT TABLE III ABOUT HERE]

The results above provide evidence that is consistent with the manipulation of deals by

acquirers and targets to avoid premerger antitrust reviews. Nonetheless, we conduct several

additional tests to further support this inference.15

[INSERT FIGURE 3 ABOUT HERE]

In our initial additional test, given that the McCrary (2008) method automatically selects

optimal bin widths, we construct a histogram on bin widths of $2.5 million around the premerger

review threshold and compare the frequency of deals above versus below the threshold. The

histogram, presented in Figure 3, shows that deal frequencies generally increase as deal values

decrease. However, we find a sharp increase in the number of deals occurring in the bin to the

immediate left of the threshold as compared to the bin to the immediate right.16 To test whether

there is a significant difference in these bin heights relative to what we would expect, we employ a

commonly used statistical approach for testing for discontinuities. This approach entails comparing

15
We find similar results, which we present in Figure IA.1 in the Internet Appendix, when we conduct a

McCrary test using percent from threshold distance as our measure.

16
In Figure IA.2 of the Internet Appendix, we construct four additional histograms with alternative bin widths,

namely 2 million, $1.5 million, $1 million, and $0.5 million (the last of which approximates the optimal bin

width set by the McCrary test of $0.55 million), and continue to find a sharp increase in the number of deals in

the bin to the immediate left of the threshold.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

22
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
the actual frequency of deals in each bin with the expected deal frequency, computed as the mean

of deal frequencies in the two adjacent bins. The results, reported in Panel B of Table III, show that

the actual number of deals in the left (right) bin is around 45% (30%) higher (lower) than the

expected number (p-value < 0.01).17 Given that over our sample period the FTC and DOJ made 928

Second Requests, of which 10% involved mergers occurring above and within $50 million of the

threshold, our results suggest an economically meaningful number of deals (i.e., 55) that represent a

nearly 6% increase in Second Requests potentially manipulated to avoid premerger review.18,19

A.3. Falsification Tests

We conduct a set of falsification tests to help alleviate the concern that other prominent

deal features explain the phenomenon we observe around the threshold. We first test for

discontinuities at other points in the distribution of deals by constructing a set of “placebo”

17
Our inferences from this method are unaffected when we draw our comparisons based on bin widths of $5

million around the premerger review threshold.

18
We also construct a histogram using the percent distance from the threshold as our measure and set bin widths

to 2%. The results presented in Figure IA.3 of the Internet Appendix document a similar discontinuity around

the threshold, confirming our main analysis.

19
We also consider the possibility that regulators expected an increase in below-threshold deals, that is an

―intended effect‖ of the regulation. To estimate this value, we use the average growth rate in bin heights for the

six bins immediately to the left of our focal bin and then use this rate to estimate the height for the just-below-

threshold bin. Our calculation indicates an expected bin height of 138 deals, which is still roughly 40 deals less

than what we find occurring in practice.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

23
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
thresholds (e.g., Goncharov, Ioannidou, and Schmalz (2021)). To construct placebo thresholds, we

adjust the actual threshold in a given year by +/– 1% to +/– 25% relative to the actual threshold

value, and standardize the threshold each year around zero.20 Under the assumption that these

other thresholds are as-if random, the rank of the McCrary t-statistic at the actual threshold when

compared to the ranks of the McCrary t-statistics for these placebo thresholds indicates the

probability of observing a similar t-statistic as we find in our main results by chance. We limit this

analysis to 50 placebo thresholds—25 above the actual threshold and 25 below—since deals occur

increasingly less (more) frequently above (below) the actual threshold, which could result in spurious

discontinuities as there are significantly fewer deals (zero in many cases) in deal value bins far above

the actual threshold.21 Using these 51 t-statistics, we estimate a p-value for the percentile rank,

which is calculated by taking the rank of a t-statistic relative to the other t-statistics (rank) and

dividing by the number of permutations (n) plus one (i.e., rank / n+1). The resulting p-value

represents the probability of observing a discontinuity by random chance.

[INSERT FIGURE 4 ABOUT HERE]

Figure 4 plots t-statistics over all 50 placebo thresholds and the actual threshold.22 The t-

statistic for the discontinuity at the actual threshold—see Table III, Panel A—has the second- highest

20
Our placebo thresholds begin at +/- 1% and end at +/- 25% to ensure that these tests are conducted on

thresholds that are sufficiently far away from the actual threshold each year.

21
We limit our analysis to 50 placebo thresholds following prior literature conducting similar analysis of

placebo thresholds (e.g., Goncharov, Ioannidou, and Schmalz (2021)).

22
For ease of interpretation and comparison, Figure 4 displays the absolute value of the t-statistic.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

24
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
rank (i.e., rank = 2), with a p-value of 0.039 (2 / 51).23 To increase the precision of this test, we

increase the number of permutations within +/– 1% to +/– 25% of the threshold to 100—50 above

and 50 below the actual threshold—we randomly draw one threshold, and we repeat our analysis

for all 100 permutations, resulting in 100 t-statistics. We find that the t-statistic for the actual

threshold has the highest rank (rank=1) and a p-value of 0.009 (i.e., 1 / 101).

[INSERT FIGURE 5 ABOUT HERE]

We conduct two additional falsification tests. First, we repeat our main McCrary test using a

sample of real estate and hotel M&A deals that occur around the threshold and, by law, are always

exempt from premerger review (FTC (2008)), and repeat the analysis in from our main McCrary test.

The McCrary graph presented in Figure 5 reveals no detectable discontinuity around the threshold

(t-statistic of 0.445; see also Table III, Panel A).24 Second, in Figure 6, we assign the following year’s

threshold to each year. We find no discontinuity under this alternative threshold. Collectively, the

23
The highest-ranking t-statistic is the placebo threshold at 1% above the actual threshold; it has a t-statistic of

5.11 compared to 5.02 for the actual threshold, suggesting that the closer we get to the actual threshold, the more

likely the discontinuities we find represent the actual threshold rather than a placebo threshold.

24
The number of hotel and real estate deals immediately around the threshold (e.g., within +/-10%) is relatively

small—we have eight such deals within that bin width (and 41 within +/- $25 million of the threshold), and thus

we urge caution in drawing inferences from this analysis alone. However, in additional analysis presented in

Section IV.F.2., we collect data on 68 deals within +/-10% of the thresholds that are already exempt from

premerger review based on an alternative threshold rule and find similar evidence of no discontinuity around the

threshold.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

25
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
results from these falsification tests support our inference that the discontinuity of deals

documented in our earlier analyses is driven by the manipulation of deals to avoid premerger

reviews. In the following analysis, we examine the techniques and incentives that drive the

avoidance of premerger antitrust review, and we explore the implications of these stealth

acquisitions for acquirer and target shareholders, rivals, and consumers.

[INSERT FIGURE 6 ABOUT HERE]

B. Financial Contracting for Stealth Acquisitions

We next examine whether deals bunching just below the threshold involve financial contract

characteristics that differ systematically from (1) all other deals, and from (ii) deals just above the

threshold in subsequent near-threshold tests.

We first focus on examining the types of acquirers and targets participating in just-below-

threshold deals. We then examine a set of deal terms that legal practitioners suggest could

incentivize or induce target managers to structure deals that avoid premerger reviews. Specifically,

we look at (i) the form of payment (cash versus stock), (ii) the deal premium level, (iii) the use of

contingency payments such as earnouts, (iv) the extension of D&O insurance for target managers

and directors, and (v) the deductible acquirers are willing to pay before demanding breach-of-terms

damages from the target.

B.1. Research Design

To investigate how thes aforementioned deal characteristics relate to just-below-threshold

M&As, we estimate the OLS model

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

26
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
JustBelowThresholdi,t = α + β Xi,t + θ Controlsi,t + j + δt + εi,t,

(2)

where i represents a unique deal announced in year t. Our dependent variable,

JustBelowThresholdi,t, which is designed to capture deals just below the premerger threshold, is

measured as an indicator term that assumes the value of one if the deal size is ≥ 0% but ≤ 10% below

the threshold, and zero otherwise.25 The variable Xi,t represents one of several test variables (e.g.,

firm type, form of payment, deal premium, use of earnout provisions), and Controlsi,t is a vector of

firm- and deal-level variables whose inclusion we describe in the table notes. We also include

industry and year fixed effects—j and δt, respectively—to account for common factors within an

industry and over time in M&A financial contracting. In all specifications of this model, we double-

cluster standard errors at the industry and year of deal announcement levels. Note that, despite

JustBelowThreshold being binary in nature, our choice to estimate an OLS model in (2) follows a

similar empirical approach as Garmaise (2015) and Card, Dobkin, and Maestas (2008) and addresses

the incidental parameters problem in nonlinear maximum likelihood estimation introduced by our

inclusion of multiple fixed effects (Abrevaya (1997)).

In our first set of tests, to provide evidence that JustBelowThresholdi,t deals differ in

systematic ways from other deals occurring below but not proximate to the threshold, we estimate

(2) using both our full sample of M&As and our sample of near-threshold deals.

B.2. Results

25
We estimate equation (2) using linear probability models.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

27
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
[INSERT TABLE IV ABOUT HERE]

To determine the types of firms that are likely to be involved in stealth acquisitions, we

estimate equation (2) using indicator variables that capture the ownership status of targets and

acquirers (i.e., public versus private). Our results, reported in the first four columns of Table IV,

indicate that deals that involve public acquirers buying public targets (column (1)) are less likely to

fall just below the threshold. Notably, in column (2), we find that takeovers of privately held firms by

publicly listed ones are 31.3% (0.005 / 0.016) more likely to be just-below-threshold deals, aligning

with recent concerns of regulators on nonreportable deals undertaken by large public acquirers.26,27

Next, we evaluate the prevalence of cash-financed deals, which, by providing lower-risk

payoffs, might lead targets to accept a lower offer price that helps acquirers avoid premerger

reviews. The results from this analysis, presented in columns (5) through (8) of Table IV, indicate that

deals that include all-cash payments (column (4)) or a combination of cash and other nonstock

26
This finding is unlikely to be explained by below-threshold deals naturally involving smaller targets that are

likely to be private firms. This is because the majority of acquisitions coded zero for our dependent variable are

deals that are smaller than the just-below-threshold deals. Hence, the completion of deals involving public

acquirers and private targets is systematically higher in just-below-threshold acquisitions compared to the entire

population of deals, including many smaller deals. In Table IA.I of the Internet Appendix, we confirm this using

a sample of deals that fall further below the threshold (i.e., further-below) and compare this group of deals to all

other deals to show no systematic difference across types of firms involved. We also repeat this analysis using

only the further-below and just-above deals and again find no systematic differences.

27
In Table IA.II the Internet Appendix, we show that our main results in Table IV hold when we use a smaller

bin width (i.e., within 5% of the threshold).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

28
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
consideration (column (7)) are indeed 28% (0.005 / 0.018) and 62% (0.008 / 0.013) more likely to be

just-below-threshold deals. Conversely, we find that all-stock-financed acquisitions (column (6)) and

deals employing a combination of stock and other noncash consideration (column (8)) are much less

prevalent in just-below-threshold acquisitions.28 The greater use of cash versus stock payments in

just-below-threshold deals is consistent with targets accepting the most liquid and least risky form of

payments in exchange for a lower deal price, given post-acquisition holding requirements in stock

transactions prescribed by U.S. securities laws (“Rule 144”; Latham & Watkins (2008)).29

In addition to, or as an alternative to, offering lower-risk payoffs to targets, legal

practitioners highlight other options available to acquirers that may facilitate the manipulation of

deal values to avoid premerger notifications. First, we consider the use of earnouts, that is deferred

payments that are contingent on a target's ability to meet or exceed certain milestones, in just-

below-threshold deals. An important nuance of the premerger regulations is that the inclusion of

28
The t-statistic (–12.16) in column (6) of Table IV is noticeably larger than the other t-statistics in this table

due to our choice of industry classification (Fama-French 48) for clustering standard errors. We find that the t-

statistic in column (6) is weakly sensitive to alternative industry classifications: using two-digit SIC, four-digit

SIC, and Fama-French 12 classifications yields t-statistics that range from –6.56 to –10.97. Results from all of

our tests are qualitatively similar in analyses using these alternative industry classifications, with the Fama-

French 48 classification consistently providing the most conservative t-statistics.

29
In the United States, when a target shareholder receives registered securities as payment for the sale of the

company, Rule 144 requires the shareholder to hold the stock for a minimum of six months (if the buyer is a

Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) reporting company) or a minimum of one year (if the buyer is not a

SEC reporting company), and may be required to comply with ―volume limitations‖ when selling.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

29
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
contingency payments such as earnouts necessitates the assessment of the fair value of the

acquisition rather than using the face value of the deal to determine whether the deal meets the

size-of-transaction test for filing premerger notifications. The FTC expects that the fair value

determinations will be performed in good faith and on a commercially reasonable basis by the

acquirer’s board of directors. However, use of an earnout could be an accounting and valuation

method to generate a fair valuation that falls below the premerger notification thresholds.30 We

investigate this possibility for a restricted sample of deals with values falling within a +/– 10%

window centered around the FTC threshold after hand-collecting the relevant granular data on

acquisitions—e.g., use of extended D&O insurance—which would increase the power of these tests

if collected for the full sample.31

[INSERT TABLE V ABOUT HERE]

Table V presents the results. Consistent with the view that earnouts allow greater discretion

in assigning deal values, the results reported in column (1) indicate that the use of earnouts is

30
Correspondence between legal representatives of acquirers and antitrust regulators, which are publicly

disclosed on the FTC website, reveals that acquirers actively consider the impact of contingency payments on

deal price. Such correspondence frequently requests confirmation from the FTC on acquirers’ ability to

unilaterally choose discount rates and probabilities of payoff, for example, when estimating the fair market

value of earnouts, and on whether acquirers’ valuation methods would exempt a deal from premerger review.

31
In subsequent tests we focus on this subsample of 640 near-threshold mergers. Variation in sample sizes is

attributed to tests that (i) use only private targets; or (ii) use only public acquirers; or (iii) data limitations due to

a lack of disclosure.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

30
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
associated with a 6.2 percentage point increase (or 39% increase compared to the sample mean) in

the probability of a deal being just below relative to just above the threshold (p-value < 0.05). When

we examine whether earnouts account for a larger fraction of transaction value in the just-below-

threshold deals, conditional on deals using earnouts, we do not find significant results (column 2 of

Table V), likely due to the fact that the use of valuation methods to generate deal values below

notification thresholds is triggered by the existence rather than the size of earnouts.

[INSERT TABLE VI ABOUT HERE]

Next, we examine the inclusion of financial contracting provisions by acquirers to lower deal

prices below the premerger notification thresholds. In the context of our setting, for instance, the

agreement to extend, and pay for, D&O coverage for private target firms can serve as another

mechanism for acquirers to manipulate deal values to just below the threshold. Note that the cost to

the acquirer of extending D&O coverage is not trivial, with combined premiums often exceeding $1

million, and is likely to be weighed against the total deal price (Goodwin Procter (2020)).32 To assess

this possibility, we focus on private targets (which comprise the vast majority of firms involved in

just-below-threshold deals), and hand collect data on insurance payment terms for the deals in our

sample.33 Table VI presents the results. In column (1), we find that extending D&O coverage for the

32
In Section III.D.1, we provide estimates of the value to the target of D&O insurance.

33
We provide details on our data collection procedure in Section I of the Internet Appendix. Although targets

provide D&O coverage during the course of the acquisition, such coverage ceases after the transaction closes.

However, because target-firm executives and directors can still be held liable for their firm’s pre-acquisition

activities after the deal closes, targets and acquirers typically negotiate run-off policies that extend this insurance

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

31
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
former directors and officers of the target increases the likelihood of a deal being a stealth

acquisition by 13.1 percentage points or 25% relative to the mean (p-value < 0.05).

In column (2), we conduct another test that examines the level of the deductible that an

acquirer is willing to accept before demanding post-acquisition breach-of-terms damages from the

target. Deductible levels in a merger financial contract are analogous to deductibles in other settings

(i.e., car or health insurance), in that a higher deductible should be associated with a lower deal

premium. Thus, the existence of higher deductibles in just-below-threshold deals would be

consistent with acquirers willing to accept higher post-closing risk in exchange for a lower deal price.

Consistent with this view, we find that higher deductible thresholds are more likely for stealth

acquisitions (p-value < 0.05). Taken together, the results from Table VI indicate that stealth

acquisitions are more likely to feature financial contracting terms that implicitly compensate targets

with greater legal protections that are typically associated with lower deal prices.

[INSERT TABLE VII ABOUT HERE]

To the extent that firms employ financial contracting provisions to manipulate deal values to

avoid antitrust review, we expect to find lower average deal premiums for targets just below versus

coverage well beyond the effective date of the deal. Private discussions with M&A lawyers indicate that

extended D&O premiums are economically meaningful to the acquirer and can be used as leverage to negotiate

a lower upfront deal price. Similarly, escrow arrangements that facilitate post-closing clawbacks of the deal

price should the target be sued for events that occurred prior to the merger are subject to a deductible threshold.

Higher thresholds are more desirable to targets but allocate higher risk to acquirers (i.e., inability to recover

losses below the deductible threshold). In exchange for accepting a high deductible threshold, M&A lawyers

suggest that acquirers can negotiate a lower upfront deal price.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

32
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
just above threshold. However, an empirical challenge in assessing the deal values of private targets

is that private firms do not have observable market values with which to calculate the premium paid

by the acquirer firm. To overcome this limitation, we take advantage of SEC reporting rules that

require publicly traded firms to report in their filings the amount paid for the target that is above the

fair value of net assets (i.e., the goodwill portion of the deal). Because goodwill reflects the premium

paid above the fair value of the target’s net assets, it is analogous to the market premiums paid for

public targets. We hand collect from public SEC filings the reported goodwill amounts for all deals

involving public acquirers and private targets around the threshold over our entire sample period

and calculate the proportion of the deal value that is recognized as goodwill. Table VII presents the

results. Column (1) indicates a negative relation between premiums paid for private targets and just-

below-threshold deals (p-value < 0.10). This result suggests that an interquartile downward shift in

deal premium increases the likelihood of a deal being below the threshold by 135%. In column (2),

we find no difference between the deal premium paid for public targets in deals falling just above or

just below the threshold.34 Taken together, this evidence is consistent with deal values, particularly

for private targets, being manipulated to fall below the notification threshold.35

34
Our findings also help rule out the possibility that the unusually high level of merger activity just below the

threshold is being driven by acquisitions involving better targets that are already below the threshold. Such

targets would likely command higher deal premiums. We find the opposite for deals just below the threshold,

which is further consistent with a detectable mass of stealth acquisitions involving manipulated deal values.

35
We also examine, in a smaller sample of deals, market reactions to the acquirer’s stock price in deals

involving private targets. We find that horizontal deals with positive cumulative abnormal returns (using the

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

33
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
[INSERT TABLE VIII ABOUT HERE]

Finally, we consider corporate governance concerns such as the use of continued economic

ties with target managers (e.g., Morck, Shelifer, and Vishny (1988), Fich, Cai, and Tran (2011)) and

more attainable earnout targets as implicit compensation for lower deal values. We manually collect

data on post-merger employment between target CEOs and the acquiring firms in near-threshold

deals (e.g., from executives’ LinkedIn pages, Bloomberg, and public proxy statement profiles). To the

extent that acquirers exploit such economic incentives to reduce the purchase price to below the

premerger notification threshold, we expect a greater representation of deals with target CEOs

retained by or offered an economic interest in an acquiring firm for deals that are just-below the

threshold. Such private benefits can also persuade target CEOs to accept deal terms that contain

contingency payments, since earnout negotiations are typically shaped by target executives who

know how to maximize the probability of meeting the earnout targets. Accordingly, we examine

whether economically connected executives are more likely to achieve post-acquisition earnout

payoffs. Table VIII presents the results. In Panel A, we find a positive relation between target CEOs

that have post-merger economic ties with acquirers and just-below-threshold deals (p-value < 0.05).

Panel B documents a positive and significant (p-value < 0.01) interaction effect between CEOs with

post-merger economic ties in acquirers and earnout payoffs in just-below-threshold deals. Together,

these results are consistent with the use of discretion to employ target executives and with greater

earnout payoffs as a means to implicitly compensate such executives for lower deal premiums.

three-day cumulative abnormal return centered on the announcement date) are more likely to be just below the

threshold (although the result is marginally insignificant).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

34
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
C. Heterogeneity in Stealth Acquisitions: Incentives to Coordinate

We next examine whether horizontal M&As (i.e., targets and acquirers operating in the

same industry), deals between geographically proximate targets and acquirers, and deals in

concentrated industries—all of which represent M&As that are theoretically more likely to lead to

anticompetitive outcomes—have a higher likelihood of falling just below the threshold.

C.1. Research Design

To explore the prevalence and nature of horizontal mergers in just-below-threshold deals,

we employ equation (2) and estimate the OLS model

JustBelowThresholdi,t = α + β Zi,t × Wi,t + Zi,t + Wi,t + θ Controlsi,t + j + δt + εi,t,

(3)

where i represents a unique deal announced in year t. Our dependent variable,

JustBelowThresholdi,t, is as defined in equation (2). The binary interaction term Zi,t × Wi,t assumes the

value of one if (i) the deal is horizontal and involves firms that share the same state of operations

(column (3) of Table IX, Panel A), (ii) the deal is horizontal and the industry is highly concentrated

(columns (2) and (5) of Table IX, Panel B), or (iii) the deals involve firms that share the same state of

operations and the industry is highly concentrated (columns (3) and (6) of Table IX, Panel B), and

zero otherwise. Finally, Controlsi,t is a vector of firm- and deal-level variables described in the table

notes. In all specifications of this model, we double-cluster standard errors at the industry and year-

of-deal-announcement levels.

C.2. Results

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

35
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Prior to estimating equation (3), we again employ McCrary’s (2008) test to examine the

discontinuity around the threshold after restricting attention to horizontal mergers. Figure IA.4

shows this result. We find a noticeable jump in the number of horizontal deals just to the left of the

threshold, which we verify with a Wald test (p-value < 0.01). It is important to note that while prior

research suggests that changing the notification threshold level is associated with more horizontal

mergers at all deal-size levels below the threshold (Wollmann, (2019)), our findings in this section

reveal a higher-than-expected number of such mergers in deals that are just below the threshold.

[INSERT TABLE IX ABOUT HERE]

Next, we estimate equation (3) for the sample of deals that fall immediately below and

above the premerger notification threshold. The results, reported in column (1) of Table IX, Panel A,

confirm a greater likelihood horizontal mergers occurring just below the threshold (p-value < 0.05).

Notably, we do not find that deals in which targets and acquirers share the same state of operations,

which can allow acquirers to realize significant gains than from geographic proximity are more likely

to fall just below threshold (column (2) of Panel A). However, when we expand the analysis to

include interaction effects of these intrastate deals and horizontal mergers in column (3) of Panel A,

we find a significant result for the interaction effect, indicating that our findings for horizontal

mergers in column (1) are driven by intrastate horizontal mergers (p-value < 0.01).

To further explore factors that motivate the implementation of horizontal acquisitions in

just-below-threshold deals, we also consider the role of industry concentration, given evidence on

increased market power in concentrated industries (e.g., hospitals and dialysis centers) adversely

affecting not only prices but also quality of services (Gowrisankaran, Nevo, and Town (2015),

Wollmann (2019), Eliason et al. (2020)). We do so by considering the interaction between horizontal

mergers and two measures of concentrated industries, namely, the Hoberg and Phillips (2010b)

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

36
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
measure and a concentration measure estimated using net sales by four-digit SIC code (Hou and

Robinson (2006)).36 The results are reported in Panel B of Table IX. While we do not find that deals

involving concentrated industries are more likely to be just-below-threshold acquisitions (columns

(1) and (4)), we do find evidence (p-value < 0.05) of horizontal mergers in concentrated industries

having a higher likelihood of falling just below the threshold (columns (2) and (5)).37 Together, our

findings in Table IX are consistent with more pervasive manipulation of deals to avoid premerger

reviews in horizontal mergers, especially those that occur between firms in the same state and firms

in concentrated industries.38

36
The Hoberg and Phillips (2010b) measure aims to capture industry concentration for both public and private

firms, and thus is a suitable measure for our setting, given we focus on both public and private firms. To

construct their measure, the authors use publicly available Department of Commerce Herfindahl–Hirschman

Index (HHI) calculated for a smaller group of industries to estimate coefficients for a set of predictors of HHI.

The authors then use the regression coefficients to compute fitted HHIs for all industries. We obtain these fitted

values from the authors’ data library located on their website.

37
Our use of the Hoberg and Phillips (2010b) measure of industry concentration likely does not perfectly

capture concentrations for the specific products markets that are impacted by the merger. As highlighted in

Shapiro (2018), it is difficult to measure market concentration across many industries, and thus the

concentration measures we employ may not accurately reflect the actual concentrations computed by regulators.

38
We also examine the level of HHI for horizontal mergers in near-threshold deals. Antitrust regulators consider

an HHI of 1,800 or more to be indicative of a highly concentrated industry. We find that horizontal deals just

below the threshold have a mean (median) industry HHI of 2,111.5 (1,624.6), whereas deals just above the

threshold have a mean (median) industry HHI of 1,673.5 (1,317.4). Due to data limitations (e.g., we do not have

sales data for private firms), we cannot calculate the change in HHI due to mergers. For example, antitrust

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

37
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
D. Quantifying the Value of Avoidance Techniques to the Target

Our results thus far suggest that acquirers and targets employ techniques to reduce deal

values and thereby avoid premerger antitrust review. In this section, we quantify the value of such

deal enhancement techniques from the perspective of target shareholders who must accept lower

listed deal prices. Figure IA.3 shows a large spike of deals occurring just below but within 2% of the

threshold—indicating that the typical “stealth” acquisition is structured such that the deal value is

approximately $1 million to $1.8 million below the threshold depending on the year of the deal.39

Figure IA.3 also shows that the heights of the first two bins located just above the threshold (i.e., 2%

to 4% above) are shorter than what would be expected under no manipulation, indicating that deals

occurring just below plausibly originate from the two bins just above the threshold. In the analysis

that follows, we examine whether our estimated values of these enhancement techniques are large

enough—either on their own or jointly with each other—shift a deal from one of the two bins

located just above to the bin located just below the threshold, that is whether use of one or more of

these techniques can facilitate a reduction of $1.5 million to $2.7 million from the headline deal

regulators state that an increase in HHI of 50 or more (in a highly concentrated market) potentially raises

significant competitive concerns.

39
This $1 million to $1.8 million range comes from taking the threshold in 2001 (i.e., $50 million) to the

threshold in 2019 (e.g., $90 million) and multiplying each by 2%.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

38
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
price.40 In this analysis, we focus on D&O insurance, deductible thresholds, and private benefits to

target CEOs, since these deal enhancement techniques can impact the negotiated deal price in

quantifiable ways.41 However, we acknowledge that other techniques, such as the use of earnouts or

the inclusion of cash as a less risky form of payment, may improve the probability of deal completion

and thus be of value to the target. Our estimated values of these enhancement techniques are

therefore likely to represent lower bounds on the actual extent to which deal values can be

manipulated to fall below the threshold.

D.1. D&O Insurance

We collect information on the typical coverage for small firms, in addition to other standard

features of D&O insurance policies, to estimate the value to the target of extending the D&O

insurance, since coverage amounts are not publicly disclosed in our sample. For example, for the

typical modest-size company, the annual D&O premium ranges from $50,000 to $60,000 per million

in coverage, where post-merger premiums for target firms are generally two to four times that of

regular D&O insurance premiums (Goodwin Procter (2020)). In terms of coverage, the typical small

firm carries a policy with $5 million to $10 million in post-merger coverage (Goodwin Procter

40
We estimate this range by assuming that, in any given year, the average stealth acquisition shifts from the

midpoint between 0% and 4% above threshold to the midpoint between 0% and 2% below the threshold. In

2001 (2019), this would be equivalent to reducing deal value by $1.5 million ($2.7 million).

41
Our focus on these deal enhancement techniques in particular is further supported by our finding in Section

III.F.4 that use of these techniques persists across different bin width assumptions (e.g., 10% through 5%).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

39
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
(2005)). Accordingly, the average policy can have an out-of-pocket cost of $1.24 million for the

acquirer (with a range of $0.5 million to $2.4 million).42 Thus, in isolation, the average post-merger

D&O policy likely has enough value to the target that it is more than the $1 million we estimate

needed to shift a deal from just above to just below the premerger review threshold. Even at the low

end of our estimate ($0.5 million), post-merger D&O insurance together with the other deal

enhancement techniques could be sufficiently valuable to the target to warrant a deal price that

shifts below the threshold.

D.2. Deductible Thresholds

Deductible thresholds in our sample of deals range from $0 to $2.5 million, with an average

of $0.35 million or approximately 0.6% of total deal value. Thus, at the high end of this range, all else

equal, an acquirer is willing to accept $2.5 million in post-acquisition legal costs for claims directed at

the target before drawing from the portion of the deal payment held in escrow to defend against or

settle lawsuits. From the perspective of the target, higher post-acquisition legal risk for the acquirer

typically results in a reduction in the deal premium it receives.43 Such a trade-off can be valuable

overall to the target if, for instance, the reduced deal premium it receives is less than the increase in

42
We calculate this amount by multiplying the midpoint values of the D&O premium ($55,000), the ratio of the

post-merger premium to regular D&O insurance premium (3), and the post-merger coverage value in millions

(7.5), that is $55,000 × 3 × 7.5 = $1,237,500.

43
Consistent with this intuition, in Table IA.III in the Internet Appendix, we find a negative correlation between

deductible thresholds and deal premiums in our sample of near-threshold deals.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

40
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
the deductible threshold. To quantify this value, we calculate the elasticity of the deal premium with

respect to the deductible threshold (i.e., the coefficient from an OLS regression of the natural log of

the deal premium regressed on the natural log of the deductible threshold), which, in our sample of

deals, is −0.6%. Using this elasticity, along with the 25th and 75th percentiles of the deductible

threshold in our sample (i.e., $0.15 million and $0.5 million, respectively), we calculate the net value

to the target from an interquartile shift upward in the deductible threshold. For instance, $0.35

million in additional deductible reduces the deal premium by an estimated $0.21 million, which

amounts to a net increase in value to the target of approximately $0.14 million. In this case, the

decrease in the deal premium of $0.21 million will be economically important to many acquirers as it

represents between 14% to 8% of the $1.5 million to $2.7 million reduction in deal value required to

facilitate avoidance of antitrust review.

D.3. CEO Private Benefits

We document that target CEOs receive post-acquisition employment contracts more often

in deals just below the threshold. While we cannot directly observe the economic value of the

benefits conveyed to target CEOs from these employment contracts (since the monetary terms of

employment contracts for private targets are not publicly disclosed), we use publicly available

compensation data for CEOs of similar public firms to estimate what these post-acquisition contracts

are potentially worth. For instance, in a sample of the largest public U.S. firms from 2006 through

2014, Guay, Kepler, and Tsui (2019) provide descriptive statistics for CEO compensation during our

sample period. The smallest firm in their sample has market value of equity of $17 million and

annual total CEO compensation of $0.2 million. The average acquisition price for a deal in our just-

below-threshold sample is $61 million—about 3.5 times the size of the smallest firm in their study.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

41
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Thus, we conservatively estimate that the value of continued employment with an acquirer is likely

to be at least $0.3 million per year. Consistent with this finding, the CEO of one of our public targets

acquired below the threshold in 2011 for $59 million received an average total compensation during

the two years prior to acquisition of $0.338 million.44 Assuming continued employment of the target

CEO for two to three years post-acquisition, this lower-bound estimate of a target CEO’s annual

employment contract provides between $0.6 million and $0.9 million in value to a target CEO.

E. Magnitude of Results

In this section we conduct several additional robustness tests to assess the sensitivity of our

results to alternative research design choices, and we discuss the reliability of our findings thus far.

While the relatively small-sample tests that we examine yield statistically significant results, the

economic significance of the findings may be subject to alternative explanations. For example, while

we find a statistically significant difference in the use of earnouts in deals just below the threshold

relative to just above, the importance of this finding is arguably more reliable after considering that

earnouts appear in 58 of the 366 deals (or 16%) below the threshold as compared to (i) 31 of the 274

deals (or 11%) above the threshold and (ii) 32 of the 299 deals (or 11%) further below the

44
See www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/742550/000110465910010132/a09-36350_1def14a.htm.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

42
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
threshold.45 Using these just-above and further-below bins as a proxy for our expectation under no

manipulation of the proportion of earnouts in deals at this point in the distribution of deals, we

expect 40 of the 366 just-below deals (or 11%) to include an earnout provision, rather than the 58

that we find. This 45% difference (i.e., 18 / 40=0.45) suggests that our finding is reliable and

economically meaningful.

Our tests examining D&O insurance and deductible thresholds also result in statistically

significant differences between firms just above and just below the threshold. For instance, focusing

on the private targets for which we could obtain data, we find that 30 of the 78 targets (or 38.5%)

just below the threshold have extended D&O insurance as compared to 17 of the 64 targets (or 27%)

just above the threshold. Under the assumption of no manipulation, we expect to observe

approximately nine fewer deals with extended D&O insurance just below the threshold (i.e., 78 ×

0.27 = 21 instead of 30). Thus, under these assumptions, D&O insurance alone has avalue to the

target that could potentially shift a deal from above to below the threshold (see Section III.D.1).

However, given that 142 of the deals for which we obtain data account for about 28% (i.e., 142 of

508) of all deals involving private targets around the threshold, if our data collection methods are

not systematically biased then our finding likely underestimates the prevalence of this behavior in

the just-below-threshold deals in practice.

45
The Thomson Securities Data Company (SDC) Mergers and Acquisitions database includes data, i.e., binary

indicator variable, on whether the deal includes an earnout provision, allowing us to conduct the just-above and

further-below comparison. For our manually-collected data (e.g., the inclusion of extended D&O insurance), we

limit our analysis to only near-threshold deals (i.e., those within +/- 10% of the deal-size threshold).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

43
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
F. Alternative Explanations and Robustness Tests

In this section, we discuss several potential alternative explanations for and robustness tests

of our findings and inferences regarding strategic manipulation to avoid antitrust enforcement.

F.1. Delaying the Merger Announcement

Given that the premerger threshold is adjusted annually, and the effective date of the

threshold occurs on approximately the same date every year, one possible explanation for the

bunching we find is that acquirers and targets agree to delay announcement of the deal such that

deals just above the threshold become just-below deals when announced in the following year if the

premerger review threshold increases by enough. For instance, using the $50 million threshold in

2004 as an example, a deal that is $51 million in value, if announced at the end of 2004, would be

above the threshold and therefore subject to the premerger review requirement, while the same

merger announced after the threshold was adjusted to $53.1 million on March 2, 2005 would be

exempt from premerger review.

We test whether merger announcement delays commonly occur in practice by identifying 55

deals in our near-threshold sample that (i) are announced within three months before or after the

date that the new threshold becomes effective and (ii) have a deal value below the new threshold

but above the immediately preceding threshold. We then measure the number of calendar days

between the date the threshold was adjusted and the date the merger was announced to assess

whether announcements of these deals are delayed to occur after the threshold adjustment. In

Figure IA.5, we do not find evidence of systematic delay, as 29 of the 55 deals are announced within

three months after the threshold-change date as compared to 26 announced within three months

before the threshold-change date.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

44
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
F.2. Already Exempt Mergers: Size of Person Test

We examine how other, nondeal size thresholds that trigger antitrust review may explain

our bunching results. While deals below the deal-size threshold are always exempt from premerger

review, it is not always the case that deals above the deal-size threshold are subject to review.

Specifically, for deals above the deal-size threshold but below a much higher “size-of-person-test”

threshold (e.g., $200 million in 2001 and up to $359.9 million in 2019), the merger is subject to

antitrust review only if both the acquirer and target have assets and sales above a specified level—

e.g., $100 million for the acquirer and $10 million for the target in 2001 (FTC (2008)). Although it is

arguably difficult to manipulate sales or assets downwards, as this would need to occur in the year

prior to the merger announcement, such manipulation could also lead to lower deal values, and

therefore contribute to the bunching we find below the deal-size threshold. To explore this

possibility, we manually collect all annual reports, media articles, press releases, and industry

publications to obtain the sales and or assets of firms involved in as many of our 640 near-threshold

deals as possible; see Section II of the Internet Appendix for additional details on our collection

procedure. This search results in data for 545 of the 640 deals (i.e., 85% of our near-threshold

sample).46

46
Overall, our search yielded data for 545 of the 640 deals in our sample (or 313 / 366 = 85.5% of our below-

threshold sample and 232 / 274 = 84.7% of our above-threshold sample) for which that we could identify

whether a deal would be exempt from premerger review on the basis of the size-of-person test.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

45
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Of the 545 deals, 68 would be considered exempt from premerger review based on the size-

of-person test. We find that deals just below the threshold, compared to those just above in a simple

difference-in-means test, are more likely to not be exempt from premerger review based on the

size-of-person test (i.e., 92% versus 81.5%; p-value = 0.002). In regression analysis, we do not find a

statistically significant difference in the propensity for already-exempt deals (based on the size-of-

person test) to occur just below relative to just above the threshold (t-statistic = 1.29; p-value =

0.212). These results suggest that the bunching we find does not appear to be driven by firms

manipulating their sales or assets downward to avoid the size-of-person threshold. Given that there

are more deals above the threshold that would meet premerger review exemption based on the

size-of-person test, if we were to remove these 68 already-exempt deals from our near-threshold

sample, we would see a net increase of 18 in the difference between the number of deals occurring

just below relative to just above the threshold, suggesting that our main results underestimate the

prevalence of deal-size avoidance that occurs in practice.

F.3. Avoiding Second Requests

Although our analyses thus far are consistent with acquirers structuring their deals to avoid

antitrust scrutiny, particularly when these deals are anticompetitive, the incentives to avoid a costly

(and lengthy) premerger Second Request may also explain our results. To explore this possibility, we

conduct interviews with legal practitioners and collect additional data on the estimated costs

involved in a lengthy premerger review. We learn from the interviews that the probability of a

Second Request—a request by the FTC or DOJ to provide additional documentation beyond that

required for the initial premerger notification filing—is relatively low but highly predictive of the

merger being blocked. We confirm this by analyzing all HSR Annual Reports created by the regulators

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

46
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
during our 19-year sample period.47 We find that over this period, a total of 31,056 filings were

submitted to regulators, of which 928 were subject to Second Requests (or approximately 3% of all

filings). Of these Second Requests, 77% led to a challenge by either the FTC or DOJ. We further find

that 10% of the Second Requests were for mergers with values between $50 and $100 million, that

is mergers that are relatively close to the premerger notification threshold. Thus, even relatively

small deals can be a concern to regulators, which suggests that deals involving smaller targets may

also have incentives to avoid a Second Request review. Private correspondence with legal

practitioners also indicates that the costs associated with a Second Request are estimated to be

between $5 million to $10 million per request (regardless of deal size), and that Second Requests

last six months on average.

In sum, acquirers seeking to avoid Second Requests plausibly do so because such

investigations are both costly and likely to lead to a blocked merger. Thus, deals that are more likely

to be scrutinized by the regulator, such as those involving horizontal rivals in highly concentrated

industries and/or sharing the same geographic markets (i.e., mergers with deal values shifted below

47
We collect all ―Annual Reports to Congress Pursuant to the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of

1976‖ from the FTC Annual Competition Reports page located here: https://www.ftc.gov/policy/reports/policy-

reports/annual-competition-reports. Annual Reports include data on the total number of premerger filings during

the year, number of Second Requests (including the number of Second Requests within a range of deal values,

e.g., in 2001 there were 70 Second Requests, 8 of which were for deals with a value in the range of $50 to $100

million), and the number of challenges from the FTC and DOJ. We use this data to calculate, e.g., the

probability of a Second Request for deals within $50 million of the deal-size threshold; and to calculate the

probability of a FTC or DOJ challenge, conditional on a Second Request.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

47
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
the threshold), have powerful incentives to avoid a premerger review. The fact that we find 55 more

deals than expected just below the threshold and, during the same period, regulators issued Second

Requests for 90 mergers in close proximity to the threshold suggests that the economic magnitude

of our findings is realistic, with these deals likely representing deals that would have faced

heightened scrutiny if they had not avoided review.48 Nonetheless, firms may also have incentives to

avoid the costs of Second Requests to the extent that they believe that antitrust regulators

imperfectly identify anticompetitive mergers and hence sometimes issue Second Requests for

mergers that are not anticompetitive. In Section IV.C, we address this alternative explanation by

analyzing post-merger product pricing for horizontal mergers above and below the premerger

notification threshold to assess the effectiveness of regulatory review for deals around the

threshold.

48
We also examine the use of acquirer (or ―reverse‖) termination fees in deals around the threshold. Such fees

are paid by acquirers to targets in the event that a deal is terminated, including if a deal fails to receive

regulatory approval, and are intended to compensate the target for business disruption during the premerger

review process. However, if targets are able to transfer regulatory risk to acquirers in the form of higher

termination fees, then targets are less likely to have incentives to avoid compliance costs. Consistent with targets

transferring risk in deals that are just above the threshold, we find that acquirer termination fees are roughly $0.7

million higher ($3.1 million versus $2.4 million) in deals just above relative to just below the threshold,

suggesting that acquirers are willing to compensate targets for regulatory risk. In addition, in Table IA.IV of the

Internet Appendix, we find that deals with higher acquirer termination fees are less likely to be just below the

threshold.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

48
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
F.4. Robustness to Alternative Bin Sizes

Most of our analyses above use deals that fall within + / – 10% of the deal-size threshold

each year. In robustness tests we use decreasing bin widths—e.g., 9%, 8%, 7%, 6%, and 5%. Table

IA.V shows that our results remain stable across different bin widths. Coefficients are of the same

sign and have similar magnitudes, although the results generally decrease in statistical significance

as the sample size shrinks. For many of the deal enhancement-techniques we examine—including

extended D&O insurance, deductible thresholds, and the retention of the target CEO—our main

results persist regardless of bin width choices, consistent with our earlier analysis and inferences

indicating which deal enhancement techniques provide sufficient economic value to the target to

warrant accepting lower headline deal values.

F.5. Robustness to Already Exempt Mergers

Given our sample of always-exempt hotel and real estate deals is relatively small, and these

deals lack the contractual features needed to conduct further analysis, In Section III.F.2 we employ a

sample of 68 already-exempt deals based on the size-of-person test. In addition to having similar

deal size and having contractual features similar to other deals around the threshold, these deals

cover many different industries and thus we use this large sample of already-exempt deals to

conduct additional placebo tests. Unlike deals whose values would trigger premerger review if they

were above the threshold, these already-exempt deals are not expected to have incentives to

manipulate deal value and thus, all else equal, we do not expect to find differences in the structure

of these deals. Consistent with this prediction, in Figure IA.6 we find no evidence of bunching below

the threshold for already-exempt mergers. Furthermore, results from falsification tests in Table IA.VI

indicate that nearly all of our tests (i.e., 21 of 23) yield no statistically significant differences between

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

49
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
just-above and just-below deals when they are already exempt from premerger review based on the

size-of-person test.

F.6. Robustness to Alternative Fixed Effects

Our main research design controls for unobservable industry and time heterogeneity by

including separate industry and year fixed effects. In this section, we take an alternative approach

and use the interaction of industry and year fixed effects, that is, industry × year fixed effects, which

control for unobservable factors within an industry in a given year that could be associated with our

outcome variables.49 Table IA.VII presents the results. We find that the coefficient estimates based

on industry × year fixed effects are similar to those in the main specifications that include separate

industry and year effects. In general, for tests employing our larger samples (e.g., Table IV), our main

results hold. In tests employing our relatively smaller samples (i.e., Tables V through X), we typically

find similar estimates, albeit with weaker statistical significance or marginal insignificance.50

49
These tests rely on the presence of within-industry-year variation, which we sometimes lack, particularly in

tests using small samples. Moreover, it could be the case that, even if two mergers (in the same industry-year)

are manipulating the deal price—for example, by extending D&O insurance—if both mergers are below the

threshold and no other mergers in that industry-year are announced, the effect would be subsumed by the

industry × year fixed effects that we include in the model.

50
More specifically, of the 19 results that are statistically significant in our main tests, nine remain significant

after the inclusion of industry × year fixed effects, of which eight are significant at the 5% level or better. In one

test, we do not have enough observations to estimate a model; in three other tests the results are marginally

insignificant (e.g., p-value = 0.14).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

50
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
IV. Product Market Competition following Stealth Acquisitions

In this section, we examine whether stealth acquisitions are associated with patterns

consistent with reduced product market competition. In particular, we first examine whether

successful antitrust avoidance provides economic benefits for acquirers and their horizontal rivals.

We then examine multiple falsification tests based on acquisitions just above the premerger

notification threshold and further below the premerger notification threshold.

A. Effects on Product Market Competition: Industry Rival Returns

We next examine whether successful premerger notification avoidance has product market

consequences in horizontal mergers. It is well known that mergers of industry competitors can

reduce competition among industry rivals and facilitate monopolistic prices at the expense of

consumers (e.g., Stigler (1964)). Following Eckbo (1983), Stillman (1983), Chevalier (1995a), and

Fathollahi, Harford, and Klasa (2021), we formally test for this is by examining the abnormal returns

of industry rivals around the announcement date of horizontal mergers. The intuition is that if these

mergers are more anticompetitive in nature, monopoly rents should accrue to merging firms. Rents

should also accrue to industry rivals, since these firms can free ride on higher product prices.

Assuming markets are efficient, stock prices—including those of horizontal rivals—should reflect

these rents soon after the merger is announced, because the combined effect of expected future

cash flows should be impounded into prices relatively quickly.

A.1. Research Design

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

51
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
We test for a discontinuity in announcement-date abnormal returns of horizontal rivals

around the threshold by estimating the OLS model

yi,[-1,1] = α + β1JustBelowThresholdi,t × Horizontali,t + β2 Horizontali,t

+ β3JustBelowThresholdi,t + θ Controlsi,t + j + δt + εi,t,

(4)

Where, for deal i, yi,[-1,1] is the 3-day market-adjusted portfolio return (centered around the

announcement date) of all horizontal rivals of the acquiring firm. Following Eckbo (1983), Stillman

(1983) and Fathollahi, Harford, and Klasa (2021), we construct equal-weighted portfolios. The

variable JustBelowThresholdi,t is an indicator for whether the deal falls just below and within 10% of

the threshold, while Horizontali,t is an indicator for horizontal mergers (acquirers and targets that

share the same four-digit SIC code). The vector Controlsi,t contains firm- and deal-level

characteristics. We double-cluster standard errors at the industry and year levels.

While our estimate of equation (4) resembles that of a standard regression discontinuity

design (RDD), the empirical approach in our study differs in notable ways and is more akin to a

“bunching” design (see Kleven (2016) for a review). Unlike the standard RDD approach, which, for

the researcher to draw causal inferences about a treatment or policy, relies on the strong

assumption that firms cannot endogenously determine whether they are above or below a specified

threshold, we examine whether firms manipulate deal values to avoid antitrust scrutiny in mergers

and then look at product market effects. In our setting, if firms can manipulate deal values, then it

could be the case that those firms that choose to be just below the threshold are somewhat

different from those that choose to be just above, which would invalidate the standard RDD

approach (Lee and Lemieux (2010)). Thus, evidence of discontinuous product market effects around

the threshold can shed new light on the impact of systematic regulatory avoidance in the M&A

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

52
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
market, which is what the RDD techniques are designed to describe (Garmaise (2015)) but

interpretation of our results differs from that of a standard RDD.

A.2. Results

[INSERT TABLE X ABOUT HERE]

Prior to estimating equation (4), we consider the relation between just-below-threshold

deals and the abnormal returns of industry rivals across all deals. While this analysis does not yield

significant results (column (1) of Table X), our findings from the estimation of equation (4) in column

(2) of Table X indicate that just-below-threshold deals generate 12.5% higher abnormal returns for

rivals in horizontal mergers falling just below the threshold relative to horizontal mergers just above

(p-value < 0.05). These results suggest that investors recognize that industry rivals benefit more from

below-threshold horizontal mergers.

One alternative explanation for our results on rival returns is that “winners” of acquisition

auctions overbid for targets, leading to increases in the stock prices of “losers”—some of which may

be rivals—who avoid overpaying. If so, we would expect our return results to be driven by those

deals with the highest deal premiums (i.e., for which acquirers overpaid by the greatest amount).

We formally test this conjecture by including the additional interaction term, HighDealPremi,t, which

equals one if the deal premium is in the highest quartile and zero otherwise.51 Table IA.VIII in the

Internet Appendix shows that high deal premiums are not associated with higher rival

announcement returns in deals just below the threshold. Moreover, the coefficient on Horizontali,t ×

51
Data limitations on deal premiums reduce our return sample by nearly 50%, similar to deal premium tests in

Table VII.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

53
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
JustBelowThresholdi,t × HighDealPremi,t is negative and statistically significant, which is inconsistent

with the aforementioned alternative explanation of our results. The coefficient on Horizontali,t ×

JustBelowThresholdi,t, however, remains positive and of similar magnitude as in column (2) of Table

X. Overall, the results in Table X and Table IA.VIII are consistent with equity market investors

recognizing that horizontal mergers that avoid antitrust scrutiny also benefit industry rivals.

A.3. Robustness to Alternative Measure of “Horizontal” Mergers

Our main measure of a horizontal merger uses four-digit SIC codes, as this classification

mirrors what antitrust regulators have historically used to define “horizontal.” A more conceptually

advanced method of defining horizontal competitors, such as the text-based approach developed by

Hoberg and Phillips (2016), requires firms to be public in order to develop measures of horizontal

competitors from public filings. Given that much of our sample comprises private acquirers and

targets, we develop a new approach to measuring horizontal mergers that captures similar degree of

granularity as the Hoberg and Phillips approach.52 Specifically, we measure the proportion of

acquirer-target product-market overlap using all four-digit SIC codes that the target and acquirer

operate in and, using the overlap of these codes (i.e., the number of shared four-digit SIC codes), we

measure the proportion of product-market overlap between the two firms scaled by the total

number of industries the target operates in (i.e., the number of four-digit SIC code matches divided

52
We cannot apply the Hoberg and Phillips (2016) text-based methodology in our setting, since it uses the 10-K

disclosures of public firms, which we do not have for private firms.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

54
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
by the total number of SIC codes for the target).53 To validate this measure, for the 36 deals in our

sample that involve both public acquirers and public targets, we find a positive and statistically

significant correlation (coefficient of 0.18) between our new measure of product-market overlap and

the Hoberg and Phillips measure. Our novel measure therefore captures a significant amount of the

variation that the Hoberg and Phillips measure is designed to capture.54

Next, we use our measure to reestimate the results from column (1) of Table IX, Panel A. We

find that the estimates increase in economic magnitude and statistical significance relative to our

results using only the primary SIC code. We also reestimate our tests of rival-returns results from

Table IX. Column (1) of Table IA.IX in the Internet Appendix shows that our magnitudes increase

when using our novel measure of horizontal competitors. Taken together, these results indicate that

our results in Tables IX and X are not driven by how we define horizontal mergers.

B. Effects on Product Market Competition: Gross Margins

We also reestimate equation (4) to test for a discontinuity in the change in industry-level

gross margins around the threshold (e.g., Fathollahi, Harford, and Klasa (2021)), which can be further

53
To verify that that this new measure is not perfectly capturing the current binary measure, we find that the

correlation between the two measures is approximately 0.64. We also find that, in the deals that were previously

classified as horizontal based on our binary measure, the average product market overlap is roughly 0.83.

Interestingly, for deals that were previously categorized as 0 (i.e., not horizontal), we find an average product

overlap of about 0.24.

54
By comparison, our original four-digit SIC measure and the Hoberg and Phillips (2016) measure have a

positive correlation of 0.09.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

55
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
indicative of economic benefits to acquirers and their industry rivals resulting from reduced product

market competition following stealth acquisitions, and can also help validate the economic

mechanism of our return results in Section IV.A.2. In column (4) of Table X, the evidence is consistent

with firms and their industry rivals benefitting from stealth acquisitions: industry-average gross

margins increase by 1.1 percentage points in the year after as compared to the year before just-

below-threshold (relative to just-above-threshold) horizontal deals. In column (2) of Table IA.VII in

the Internet Appendix, we check robustness to our alternative measure of horizontal mergers and

find a similar result, albeit slightly smaller in magnitude.

C. Effects on Product Market Competition: Product Prices

In our final set of tests we provide direct evidence on how horizontal stealth acquisitions can

impact product market competition by considering how such acquisitions impact product prices of

industry rivals that share common products. Product price increases by rivals following events that

reduce product market competition can be indicative of such effects (e.g., Chevalier (1995b), Azar,

Schmalz, and Tecu (2018)). Evaluate changes in product prices after deal completion requires data

on detailed micro-level product pricing data for shared common products of industry rivals over

time. Although such data are scarce, we are able to study three horizontal mergers in the consumer

products industry—one in the beauty products sector located just below the premerger notification

threshold, one in the infant products sector located just above the threshold, and one in the food

products sector located further below the threshold—for which we can (i) identify common products

of the acquirer’s rivals via exhaustive analysis of product groupings in online advertising and in retail

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

56
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
stores, and (ii) obtain retail scanner pricing data for the rivals’ products using Universal Product

Codes (UPCs) provided by Nielsen Consumer.55 These criteria yield a sample that consists of

approximately 1.9 million observations of rival retail scanner observations related to common

products that were sold during a two-year period around the closing of the three mergers. To the

extent that stealth acquisitions reduce product market competition, we expect an increase in the

prices of the rivals’ common products following the merger located just below the threshold (i.e.,

the “stealth acquisition”), relative to the prices of the rivals’ common products following the two

other mergers.56 This prediction of price changes in the immediate 12 months following the

completion of deals is in line with prior studies documenting consumer price effects shortly after

acquisitions that reduce competition in the consumer products industry (e.g., Chevalier (1995b)).57

C.1. Research Design

To assess changes in the pricing of rivals’ common products, we estimate the difference-in-

differences specification

yi,t = α + β1 JustBelowThresholdi,t×Postt + β2 JustBelowThresholdi,t + β3Postt

55
Agreements with Nielsen Consumer LLC preclude us from disclosing the names of the firms or the specific

products.

56
In the just-below-threshold merger, we are not able to investigate changes in the pricing of the acquirer’s focal

products because of a lack of product pricing data for the private target’s products during the premerger period.

57
For example, Chevalier (1995b) shows that supermarket prices begin increasing in the first quarter following

a leveraged buyout.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

57
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
+ θ Controlsi,t + εi,t,

(5)

where yi,t is the normalized average weekly prices for the common products of acquirers and rivals,

JustBelowThresholdi,t is an indicator for whether the deal falls just below and within 10% of the

threshold, Postt is an indicator for after completion of the acquisition, and Controlsi,t includes a

measure of time trends and various fixed effects depending on the specification.58 We double-

cluster standard errors at the product and week levels.

C.2. Results

[INSERT FIGURE 7 ABOUT HERE]

Figure 7 illustrates that, for each of the three mergers, the normalized monthly average

prices for acquirers’ and rivals’ common products are stable during the months leading up to the

acquisition date, indicating no evidence of pre-trends. However, in contrast to the pre-acquisition

period, the same figure shows that normalized prices increase sharply following the completion of

the “stealth” acquisition only.59 While prices in the pre-acquisition period vary across all three

mergers before the announcement date, such prices tend to stay within a band ranging from zero to

58
We follow Sheen (2014) and define a product as ―common‖ based on interviews with marketing experts and

discussions in firms’ public SEC filings, which we discuss further in Section II of the Internet Appendix.

59
This documented increase in product prices helps mitigate the concern that our earlier finding of a positive

stock price reaction for rivals following such deals is due to a general improvement in product quality, since it is

unlikely that all rivals would improve their product quality within a few months of the stealth acquisition being

completed.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

58
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
0.5 standard deviations away from a mean of zero. In contrast, product prices for the stealth

acquisition just below the threshold during the post-acquisition period are higher by one to two

standard deviations relative to product prices in the two other mergers.

[INSERT TABLE XI ABOUT HERE]

We test for the statistical significance of these differences by estimating equation (5) using

five specifications with various fixed effect structures to control for time trends in product prices and

local economic shocks (i.e., using week and geographic region fixed effects).60 Table XI presents the

results. Across all specifications, we find evidence of a positive and statistically significant coefficient

on the interaction between JustBelowThresholdi,t and Postt, indicating a roughly 1.2 standard

deviations increase in the prices of rivals’ common products in the first year following the

completion of the stealth acquisition, relative to price changes for common products of acquirers

and rivals in the two other mergers. Overall, while these findings are based on only three mergers,

the evidence suggests that (i) unlike stealth acquisitions occurring just below the threshold, mergers

occurring just above and further below the threshold have no detectable pricing consequences for

consumers, and (ii) the regulatory review process in this case appears to be effective in that it allows

mergers above the threshold that do not harm competition to go forward. This latter finding also

60
We define geographic fixed effects using Nielsen’s Designated Market Area (DMA) codes, which represent

standardized regions for local television marketing. In addition, because our mergers occur in different years,

our week fixed effects are standardized, that is, the week is given relative to the effective date of the merger, to

control for seasonality.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

59
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
supports our argument that firms seek to avoid regulatory scrutiny because it is likely that their

proposed mergers would be blocked by an effective regulator.

C.3. Robustness to Different Product Markets

We also obtain retail scanner data for product markets that are not directly affected by

these three acquisitions, that is, for product markets that are not common to the target and the

acquirer, to draw comparisons with relative price changes in these products. For each of the three

mergers, we separately estimate changes in common product prices relative to uncommon product

prices in a difference-in-differences design. Specifically, we estimate the specification

yi,t = α + β1 CommonProducti,t×Postt + β2 CommonProducti,t + β3Postt

+ θ Controlsi,t + εi,t,

(6)

where yi,t is the average weekly price for the products of acquirers and rivals, CommonProducti,t is an

indicator for whether the products sold by the target of the stealth acquisition are also sold by the

rival firm(s), Postt is an indicator for after completion of the stealth acquisition, and Controlsi,t

includes a measure of time trends and various fixed effects depending on the specification. We

double-cluster standard errors at the product and week levels.

Panels A to C of Table IA.X in the Internet Appendix present results from estimating equation

(6) using five specifications with various fixed effects to control for time trends in product prices and

local economic shocks (i.e., using week and geographic region fixed effects). In Panel A, for the

stealth acquisition, we find evidence across all specifications of a positive and statistically significant

coefficient (p-value < 0.01 in all columns) on the interaction between CommonProducti,t and Postt,

indicating a 5.5% increase in the prices of the rivals’ common products in the first year following the

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

60
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
completion of the stealth acquisition, relative to changes in the prices of their uncommon products.

If similar price increases occur—for a similar number of annual units sold—across the 55 more-than-

expected mergers occurring just below the threshold in our sample period, and assuming that this

increase benefits an acquirer (i) in a duopoly (i.e., with one additional competitor in the product

market) or (ii) with four additional competitors (i.e., in a product market of five rivals, which

antitrust regulators tend to consider a threshold for “highly concentrated”), then our calculation

conservatively estimates that such stealth acquisitions cost consumers between $182 million and

$454 million in terms of increased prices for consumers during the first 10 years following these

deals.61 By contrast, for the competitive acquisitions (in Panels B and C), we do not find an increase

61
We first assume that our below-threshold merger analyzed in this section is representative of the typical

anticompetitive merger in our just-below-threshold sample of 366 deals. We next calculate the cost to

consumers, in dollars, of the post-merger price increase for this single merger by multiplying the 205,000 units

sold in the first year after the merger by the 5.5% price increase, resulting in a $128,330 increased cost to

consumers in the first year. Since rivals also tend to benefit from the price increase, we next extrapolate this

effect across the industry. To do so, we use the FTC and DOJ’s benchmark for highly concentrated industries,

namely an HHI of 1,800 or above. Specifically, if we assume that five firms have equal market share in an

industry, then the implied HHI would be 2,000, which is just above the regulators’ threshold level of concern. In

our sample of just-below-threshold deals, we find that approximately one-quarter of the deals have five industry

rivals or less. We therefore use as a lower bound a two-firm industry (i.e., a duopoly) and as an upper-bound a

five-firm industry for our estimates of affected rivals. In other words, if the price increase we observe in our

single merger was extrapolated across two to five rivals, then the cost to consumers in that industry would be

estimated to be between $256,000 and $641,000 in the first year. If we further interpolate these amounts across

the 55 more-than-expected deals bunching just below the threshold, this yields an increased cost to consumers

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

61
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
in prices in the months after the merger: the coefficient on the interaction term, CommonProducti,t

and Postt, is insignificant in all columns of Panel B and insignificant in column (5) (our main

specification) of Panel C. Together, these results provide further evidence of the potentially

economically meaningful pricing consequences for consumers in markets impacted by stealth

acquisitions.62

V. Conclusion

We show that a greater-than-expected number of M&A deals are structured to narrowly

avoid antitrust scrutiny (i.e., filing of premerger notifications with the DOJ and FTC), and that these

“stealth acquisitions” are driven by acquisitions of private targets that entail financial contracting

terms with lower deal premiums and payoff functions that allow for more discretion in assigning

deal values. We explore the economic mechanisms driving this bunching of acquisitions below the

premerger notification threshold and find that the discontinuity in stealth acquisitions around the

premerger notification threshold is driven by firms with the greatest incentives to coordinate, which

is indicative of stealth acquisitions occurring in settings more likely to have anticompetitive effects.

for the first year following the merger of $14.1 million to $35.3 million. If we assume that prices grow at a

similar rate (i.e., 5.5% annually), this results in turn in an increase in total cost to consumers of $182 million to

$454 million over the first 10 years after these 55 mergers.

62
In Table IA.X in the Internet Appendix we repeat the tests for column (5) in Panels A, B, and C using

normalized prices. Our results remain statistically significant.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

62
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
We further find that both acquiring firms and their industry rivals benefit from stealth acquisitions,

consistent with reduced product market competition that limits output and raises prices.

Our findings have important policy implications. Current antitrust review guidelines include

bright-line thresholds that trigger premerger review. Firms can manage financial contracting

features of their M&A deals, however, to avoid antitrust scrutiny from regulators. Such regulatory

avoidance can have deleterious effects on consumers. Our results suggest a more nuanced view of

government resource allocation in monitoring the antitrust implications of corporate M&A deals:

setting arbitrary thresholds can have real effects on industrial organization behavior to the extent

that firms have discretion to manipulate the criteria used to identify corporate transactions that

warrant regulatory scrutiny. In particular, our study provides evidence supporting regulatory concern

about the limitations set by premerger review thresholds, as firms appear to systemically manipulate

the size of their deals to circumvent regulatory review. Moreover, our results suggest that firm

discretion in the antitrust review process facilitates avoidance of regulatory scrutiny of the effects of

corporate deals on product market competition. We view these and related topics as promising

avenues for future research into the role of corporate financing strategies in anticompetitive

behavior.

Initial submission: August 27, 2021; Accepted: June 2, 2022

Editors: Stefan Nagel, Philip Bond, Amit Seru, and Wei Xiong

Appendix A. Variable Definitions

This appendix provides definitions for the key variables used in our tests.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

63
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Variable Description Source

Dependent variables

JustBelowThreshold Indicator variable equal to one if a merger's deal value is within ≥ -10% SDC
and ≤ 0% of the threshold, calculated as [(deal value − threshold)/deal
value], and zero otherwise.
RivalRet Equal-weighted portfolio return of horizontal rivals (at the four-digit SIC CRSP
level), measured over the three-day window [-1, 1] centered on the
announcement date.
∆ GrossMargin Continuous variable equal to the change in the industry-average gross Compustat
margin, measured as the difference between the industry-average gross
margin one year after the merger and the industry-average gross margin
one year before the merger, where gross margin is calculated as (sales −
cost of goods sold)/sales. Industry is determined at the four-digit SIC
code level.
NormalizedPrice Average weekly normalized product price, by UPC code. NielsenIQ

Price Average weekly product price, by UPC code. NielsenIQ

Explanatory variables

PublicAcquirer Indicator variable equal to one if the acquirer is a publicly traded SDC
company, and zero otherwise.
PrivateAcquirer Indicator variable equal to one if the acquirer is a private company, and SDC
zero otherwise.
PublicTarget Indicator variable equal to one if the target firm is a publicly traded SDC
company, and zero otherwise.
PrivateTarget Indicator variable equal to one if the target firm is a private company, SDC
and zero otherwise.
Public-Public Indicator variable equal to one if both the acquirer and the target firm SDC
are publicly traded companies, and zero otherwise.
Public-Private Indicator variable equal to one if the acquirer is a publicly traded SDC
company and the target firm is a private company, and zero otherwise.
Private-Public Indicator variable t equal to one if the acquirer is a private company and SDC
the target firm is a publicly traded company, and zero otherwise.
Private-Private Indicator variable t equal to one if both the acquirer and the target firm SDC
are private companies, and zero otherwise.
AllCash Indicator variable th equal to one if the payment terms include 100% SDC
cash, and zero otherwise.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

64
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
AllStock Indicator variable equal to one if the payment terms include 100% SDC
stock, and zero otherwise.
AllCashandOther Indicator variable t equal to one if the payment terms include 100% SDC
cash and other nonstock and noncash consideration (e.g., debt,
earnouts, etc.), and zero otherwise.

Appendix A. Variable Definitions (cont’d)

Explanatory variables (continued)

AllStockandOther Indicator variable equal to one if the payment terms include 100% stock SDC
and other noncash and nonstock consideration (e.g., debt, earnouts,
etc.), and zero otherwise.
Horizontal Indicator variable equal to one if the acquirer and target share the same SDC
four-digit SIC code, and zero otherwise.
Horizontal(continuous) Continuous variable equal to the proportion of overlap (i.e., from zero SDC
to one) of the target’s and acquirer’s four-digit SIC codes for the product
markets they operate in. Overlap is calculated as the number of
overlapping SIC codes divided by the total number of target SIC codes.
Intrastate Indicator variable equal to one if the headquarters of the acquirer and SDC
target are in the same state, and zero otherwise.
HighConc Indicator variable equal to one if the industry is above the median Hoberg
concentration, and zero otherwise. We calculate industry concentration and
using (i) Hoberg and Phillips (2010b) and (ii) net sales (by four-digit SIC Phillips
code) to compute Conc_HP and Conc_Sales, respectively. website.

Earnouts Indicator variable equal to one if earnouts are included in the payment SDC
terms, and zero otherwise.
EarnoutPerc % of deal value that consists of earnouts. SDC

AcqTermFeePercent Continuous variable that measures the acquirer’s termination fee as a SDC
proportion of the total deal value.
PrivateTargetDealPrem Premium paid for a private target. Measured as the proportion of SEC
goodwill relative to total deal value. Calculated using the amount of
goodwill recognized in the first available 10-K SEC filing for publicly EDGAR
traded acquirers.
EconomicTie Indicator variable equal to one if the target CEO is retained by and/or Various
holds equity in the acquiring firm, and zero otherwise. online
sources

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

65
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
PublicTargetDealPremium Premium paid for a publicly traded target firm. Measured as the deal SDC
price divided by the target firm's stock price (four weeks prior to the
announcement date) minus one multiplied by 100.
EarnoutPayoff Indicator variable equal to one if an earnout is achieved (and paid out), SEC
and zero otherwise. EDGAR

ExtendedLiabilityCoverage Indicator variable equal to one if the acquiring firm agrees to extend SEC
and pay for D&O liability insurance for directors and officers of the EDGAR
target firm, and zero otherwise.
DeductibleThreshold Continuous variable that measures the dollar-based threshold above SEC
which the acquirer can claw back a portion of the purchase price to EDGAR
defend and pay damages associated with post-closing breaches of
representations and warranties made by the target.
CommonProduct × Post Indicator variable equal to one if an acquirer’s rival’s product overlaps NielsenIQ
with a product of the target and retail purchase occurs after the
effective date of the merger, and zero otherwise.
Appendix A. Variable definitions (cont’d)

Control variables

DealValue Value of the merger in US$ millions. SDC

TargetTermFee Indicator variable equal to one if the deal includes a termination fee SDC
payable by the target firm, and zero otherwise.
TenderOffer Indicator variable equal to one if the deal is structured as a tender offer, SDC
and zero otherwise.
NumRivals Number of horizontal rivals of the acquirer. Calculated using the CRSP
number of publicly traded companies that share the same four-digit SIC
code as the acquirer.
LowNumRivals Indicator variable equal to one if the number of public rivals is below CRSP
the median for all industries, and zero otherwise. We use the number of
publicly traded companies that share the same four-digit SIC code as the
acquirer to calculate the number of rivals.
TargetTermFeePercent Continuous variable that measures the target termination fee as a SDC
proportion of the total deal value.
RepsSurvive Indicator variable equal to one if the representations and warranties SEC
made by the target and contained in the merger agreement survive EDGAR
beyond the effective date of the deal, and zero otherwise. Data are
hand collected from merger agreements located on EDGAR.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

66
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
SurvivalPeriod Continuous variable that measures the amount of time the SEC
representations and warranties made by the target in the merger EDGAR
agreement have been extended. Data are hand collected from merger
agreements located on EDGAR.
Escrow Indicator variable equal to one if the purchase price holdback is kept in SEC
third-party escrow, and zero otherwise. EDGAR

TimeTrend Continuous variable that measures, for each observation, the number of NielsenIQ
days after the effective date of the deal. Observations prior to the
effective date assume a negative value.

Appendix B. Measuring Deal Values

We obtain data on deal values from the SDC Mergers and Acquisitions database. While the deal
values from firms’ premerger review filings with the FTC would be useful in our analysis, such data
are not publicly available (nor are they privately available from the FTC for the below-threshold deals
of interest in our study) and are also exempt from the FTC’s Freedom of Information Act (FOIA)
disclosure requirements. Nonetheless, our deal values should conceptually be the same as those
filed with the FTC, for several reasons:

a. For publicly traded targets, the FTC requires the use of acquisition price (AP) or
market price (MP), whichever is greater. Since AP includes MP + deal premium, it
will be greater than MP and therefore AP will be the price used in the premerger
filing.
b. For private targets, if the AP can be ―determined‖ then the FTC requires the use of
AP. If AP cannot be determined (e.g., includes post-acquisition contingency
payments, such as an earnout, that cannot be determined at announcement date) then
the FTC requires the use of fair market value (FMV). Since the FTC requires that
FMV includes intangibles (such as goodwill), the AP and FMV should be the same.
We can confirm this: for public acquirers, we can observe details on the acquisition
contained in the 10-K, including the allocation of the AP across the asset and liability
classes, and the assignment of a portion of the AP to intangibles and goodwill. An
example of this allocation (shown below) is the acquisition of PureWellness (private
firm) by Cerner Corp (public firm) for $69.1 million on February 25, 2013; note that
the deal included an earnout.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

67
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
To further align the SDC deal values that we use with those submitted in the premerger
filings, we take the additional step of adjusting the deal value to include the value of the acquirer’s
“toehold” in the target. Specifically, to determine whether the deal value is above or below the
threshold, the premerger notification rules require that the parties include the market value of the
portion of the target that the acquirer may already hold prior to the transaction (i.e., the value of the
toehold). As such, we follow the same process prescribed by the antitrust regulators and calculate
the total value of the target held by the acquirer on the announcement date (e.g., by using the
announcement-date deal value as an indication of the market value of X% of the target and then
applying this to the percent of the target already held by the acquirer). We then add the toehold
value to the announcement-date deal value to obtain the total value to be held by the acquirer.

REFERENCES

Abrevaya, Jason, 1997, The equivalence of two estimators of the fixed effects logit model, Economics

Letters 55, 41-43.

Agrawal, Anup, Jeffrey Jaffe, and Gershon Mandelker, 1992, The post-merger performance of

acquiring firms: A re-examination of an anomaly, Journal of Finance 47, 1605-1621.

Asquith, Paul, 1983, Merger bids, uncertainty, and stockholder returns, Journal of Financial

Economics 11, 51-83.

Azar, José, Martin Schmalz, and Isabel Tecu, 2018, Anticompetitive effects of common

ownership, Journal of Finance 73, 1513-1565.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

68
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Bebchuk, Lucian, 2004, The case for increasing shareholder power, Harvard Law Review, 118, 833-

914.

Bebchuk, Lucian, 2005, Letting shareholders set the rules, Harvard Law Review, 119, 1784-1813.

Burgstahler, David, and Ilia Dichev, 1997, Earnings management to avoid earnings decreases and

losses, Journal of Accounting & Economics 24, 99-126.

Card, David, Carlos Dobkin, and Nicole Maestas, 2008, The impact of nearly universal insurance

coverage on health care utilization: Evidence from Medicare, American Economic Review 98,

2242-2258.

Chevalier, Judith, 1995a, Capital structure and product-market competition: Empirical evidence from

the supermarket industry, American Economic Review 85, 415-435.

Chevalier, Judith, 1995b, Do LBO supermarkets charge more? An empirical analysis of the effects of

LBOs on supermarket pricing, Journal of Finance 50, 1095-1112.

Cunningham, Colleen, Florian Ederer, and Song Ma, 2021, Killer acquisitions, Journal of Political

Economy 129, 649-702.

Dasgupta, Sudipto, and Alminas Žaldokas, 2019, Anticollusion enforcement: Justice for consumers

and equity for firms, Review of Financial Studies 32, 2587-2624.

David, Joel, 2021, The aggregate implications of mergers and acquisitions, Review of Economic

Studies 88, 1796-1830.

De Loecker, Jan, Jan Eeckhout, and Gaberiel Unger, 2020, The rise of market power and the

macroeconomic implications, Quarterly Journal of Economics 135, 561-644.

DOJ, 2014, Non-reportable transactions and antitrust enforcement, Leslie C. Overton Deputy

Assistant Attorney General for Civil Enforcement antitrust Division U.S. Department of Justice

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

69
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Remarks as Prepared for the 14th Annual Loyola Antitrust Colloquium, Institute for Consumer

Antitrust Studies Chicago, Illinois April 25, 2014.

Eckbo, B. Espen, 1983, Horizontal mergers, collusion, and stockholder wealth, Journal of Financial

Economics 11, 241-273.

Eckbo, B. Espen, 1992, Mergers and the value of antitrust deterrence, Journal of Finance 47, 1005-

1029.

Edmans, Alex, 2021, Grow the Pie: How Great Companies Deliver Both Purpose and Profit–Updated

and Revised (Cambridge University Press).

Einav, Liran, Amy Finkelstein, and Neale Mahoney, 2018, Provider incentives and healthcare costs:

Evidence from long‐term care hospitals, Econometrica 86, 2161-2219.

Eliason, Paul, Paul Grieco, Ryan McDevitt, and James Roberts, 2018, Strategic patient discharge: The

case of long-term care hospitals, American Economic Review 108, 3232-3265.

Eliason, Paul, Benjamin Heebsh, Ryan McDevitt, and James Roberts, 2020, How acquisitions affect

firm behavior and performance: Evidence from the dialysis industry, Quarterly Journal of

Economics 135, 221–267.

Fathollahi, Maryam, Jarrad Harford, and Sandy Klasa, 2021, Anticompetitive effects of horizontal

acquisitions: The impact of within-industry product similarity, Journal of Financial Economics

144, 645-669.

Fich, Eliezer, Jie Cai, and Anh Tran, 2011, Stock option grants to target CEOs during private merger

negotiations, Journal of Financial Economics 101, 413-430.

FTC, 2004, 27th Annual Report, https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/reports_annual/

27th-report-fy-2004/050810hsrrpt_0.pdf.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

70
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
FTC, 2008, To file or not to file: When you must file a premerger notification form,

https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/attachments/premerger-introductory-

guides/guide2.pdf.

FTC, 2020, Q&A Session 3: Topics in the Advanced Notice of Proposed Rulemaking – HSR Rulemaking

Initiative, https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_events/1582354/

hsr_rulemaking_session_3.pdf.

Garmaise, Mark, 2015, Borrower misreporting and loan performance, Journal of Finance 70, 449-

484.

Goncharov, Igor, Vasso Ioannidou, and Martin Schmalz, 2021, (Why) do central banks care about

their profits? Journal of Finance, Forthcoming.

Goodwin Procter LLP, 2005, Private Equity Update, Available online at:

https://www.goodwinlaw.com/~/media/B9B6DB0A80C34DF7BE5AA66548FE71EE.ashx.

Goodwin Procter LLP, 2020, What has contributed to the rising cost of directors and officers (D&O)

liability insurance for new public companies? Available online at:

https://www.lifesciencesperspectives.com/2020/02/06/rising-cost-of-directors-and-officers-do-

liability-insurance-for-new-public-companies/.

Gowrisankaran, Gautam, Aviv Nevo, and Robert Town, 2015, Mergers when prices are negotiated:

Evidence from the hospitality industry, American Economic Review 105, 172-203.

Guay, Wayne, John Kepler, and David Tsui, 2019, The role of executive cash bonuses in providing

individual and team incentives, Journal of Financial Economics 133, 441-471.

Harrington, Joseph, and Andrzej Skrzpacz, 2011, Private monitoring and communication in cartels:

Explaining recent collusive practices, American Economic Review 101, 2425-2449.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

71
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Heltzer, Gregory, and Lisa Peterson, February 14, 2018, Mitigating antitrust risks in nonreportable

transactions, Law360. Available online at: https://www.law360.com/articles/1012135/

mitigating-antitrust-risks-in-nonreportable-transactions.

Hoberg, Gerard, and Gordon Phillips, 2010a, Product market synergies and competition in mergers

and acquisitions: A text-based analysis, Review of Financial Studies 23, 3773-3811.

Hoberg, Gerard, and Gordon Phillips, 2010b, Real and financial industry booms and busts, Journal of

Finance 65, 45-86.

Hoberg, Gerard, and Gordon Phillips, 2016, Text-based network industries and endogenous product

differentiation, Journal of Political Economy 124, 1423-1465.

Hou, Kewei, and David Robinson, 2006, Industry concentration and average stock returns, Journal of

Finance 61, 1927-1956.

Jäger, Simon, Benjamin Schoefer, and Jörg Heining, 2021, Labor in the boardroom, Quarterly Journal

of Economics 136, 669-725.

Kamepalli, Sai, Raghuram Rajan, and Luigi Zingales, 2021, Kill zone, Working paper, National Bureau

of Economic Research.

Kleven, Henrik, 2016, Bunching, Annual Review of Economics 8, 435-464.

Latham & Watkins, 2008, The curious case of how to sell securities obtained in an M&A transaction:

Rules 144 and 145, Available online at: https://www.wowlw.com/Article/Index/77

Lee, David, and Thomas Lemieux, 2010, Regression discontinuity designs in economics, Journal of

Economic Literature 48, 281-355.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

72
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Mason, Mary Anne and Shawn Johnson, 2016, Antitrust—healthcare industry in the spotlight,

Westlaw Journal’s Antitrust Report.

McCrary, Justin, 2008, Manipulation of the running variable in the regression discontinuity design: A

density test, Journal of Econometrics 124, 698-714.

Mehta, Mihir, Suraj Srinivasan, and Wanli Zhao, 2020, The politics of M&A antitrust, Journal of

Accounting Research 58, 5-53.

Moeller, Sara, Frederik Schlingemann, and René Stulz, 2005, Wealth destruction on a massive scale,

Journal of Finance 60, 757‐782.

Morck, Randall, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, 1988, Characteristics of targets of hostile and

friendly takeovers, In A.J. Auerbach (Ed.), Corporate Takeovers: Causes and Consequences

(University of Chicago Press).

Rose, Nancy, and Jonathan Sallet, 2020, The dichotomous treatment of efficiencies in horizontal

mergers: Too much? Too little? Getting it right, University of Pennsylvania Law Review 168,

1941-1984.

Rudnicki, Jeff, Kate Siegel, and Andy West, 2019, How lots of small M&A deals add up to big

value, McKinsey Quarterly. Available online at: https://www.mckinsey.com/capabilities/

strategy-and-corporate-finance/our-insights/repeat-performance-the-continuing-case-for-

programmatic-m-and-a#/.

Schipper, Katherine, and Rex Thompson, 1983, Evidence on the capitalized value of merger activity

for acquiring firms, Journal of Financial Economics 11, 85-119.

Shahrur, Husayn, 2005, Industry structure and horizontal takeovers: Analysis of wealth effects on

rivals, suppliers, and corporate customers, Journal of Financial Economics 76, 61-98.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

73
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Shapiro, Carl, 2018, Antitrust in a time of populism, International Journal of Industrial

Organization 61, 714-748.

Sheen, Albert, 2014, The real product market impact of mergers, Journal of Finance 69, 2651-2688.

Stigler, George, 1964, A theory of oligopoly, Journal of Political Economy 72, 44-61.

Stillman, Robert, 1983, Examining antitrust policy towards horizontal mergers, Journal of Financial

Economics 11, 225-240.

Thomson Reuters Practical Law, February 1, 2020, Merger control thresholds, Available online at:

https://content.next.westlaw.com/2-557-0145?__lrTS=20200910135919459&transition

Type=Default&contextData=(sc.Default)&firstPage=true.

Wilson, Christine, and Rohit Chopra, 2020, Commissioner Statement Concerning Non-Reportable

Hart-Scott-Rodino Act Filing 6(b) Orders, Federal Trade Commission.

Wollmann, Thomas, 2019, Stealth consolidation: Evidence from an amendment to the Hart-Scott-

Rodino Act, American Economic Review: Insights 1, 77-94.

Wollmann, Thomas, 2020, How to get away with merger: Stealth consolidation and its real effects on

U.S. healthcare, Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

74
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Annual Premerger Notification Threshold from 2001 to 2019 (in $ millions)
20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20
Year 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19
Thres 50 50 50 50 53 56 59 63 65 63 66 68 70 75 76 78 80 84 90
hold .0 .0 .0 .0 .1 .7 .8 .1 .2 .4 .0 .2 .9 .9 .3 .2 .8 .4 .0

Figure 1. Premerger notification and review process. The Hart-Scott-Rodino Act established the
federal premerger notification program, which provides the Federal Trade Commission and the
Department of Justice with information about mergers and acquisitions before they become
effective. This figure depicts the premerger notification and review process from start to completion.
Arrows indicate the flow of the process. Positive symbols indicate that the merger closes
successfully, whereas a negative symbol indicates that the agency seeks to prevent the merger from
closing.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

75
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Figure 2. Density of public and private M&As around FTC premerger review threshold. This figure
depicts the estimated kernel densities of the distance (in $ millions) of deal values from the FTC
premerger review threshold. Confidence bands (at the 95% level) are depicted by the thin lines. The
circles, which describe scaled frequencies, are analogous to histogram bins. For ease of
interpretation, we restrict our kernel density estimations to distances within +/- $30 million of zero,
where zero represents the FTC threshold. The estimation procedure follows the method in McCrary
(2008).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

76
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Figure 3. Histogram of M&A deals around FTC premerger review threshold. This figure depicts the
frequency of deals involving public and private targets around the FTC premerger review threshold.
For ease of interpretation, we restrict our histogram to deals within +/- $25 million of zero, where
zero represents the FTC threshold. Bin widths are set to $2.5 million and constructed such that when
the distance from the threshold equals zero, the deal is included in the bin to the left of the
threshold (i.e., [-2.5, 0)), indicating the deal would be exempt from premerger review, which is
consistent with the regulation.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

77
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Figure 4. Falsification test: Placebo thresholds. This figure depicts t-statistics for discontinuities at
points along the distribution of deals. The level of the t-statistic is measured on the y-axis.
Thresholds, as the percent distance from the actual threshold, are shown on the x-axis. The actual
threshold is at zero. All other “placebo” thresholds begin at a distance of +/−1% from the actual
threshold and end at a distance of +/−25% from the actual threshold. To construct a placebo
threshold, we adjust the actual threshold in each year by x%, where x is the same for each year, and
then standardize all 19 years of “adjusted” thresholds. As an example, to measure the discontinuity
when the placebo threshold is +1% from the actual threshold, we first adjust all thresholds (from
2001 to 2019) by 1%. We then standardize these new thresholds (at zero) and calculate the McCrary

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

78
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
(2008) t-statistic at the discontinuity. For ease of interpretation, we display the absolute value of the

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

79
t-statistic.
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Figure 5. Falsification test: Density of always-exempt M&As involving public and private targets.
This figure depicts the estimated kernel densities of the distance (in $ millions) of deal values from
the FTC premerger review threshold for deals involving real estate and hotels, which are always
exempt from the premerger notification and review process. Confidence bands (at the 95% level) are
depicted by the thin lines. The circles, which describe scaled frequencies, are analogous to histogram
bins. For ease of interpretation, we restrict our kernel density estimations to distances within +/-
$30 million of zero, where zero represents the FTC threshold. The estimation procedure follows the
method in McCrary (2008).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

80
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Figure 6. Falsification test: Density of M&As around FTC premerger review threshold involving
public and private targets (using one-year ahead threshold level). This figure depicts the estimated
kernel densities of the distance (in $ millions) of deal values from the FTC premerger review
threshold when we substitute the one-year-ahead threshold level for the current year’s threshold
level. Confidence bands (at the 95% level) are depicted by the thin lines. The circles, which describe
scaled frequencies, are analogous to histogram bins. For ease of interpretation, we restrict our
kernel density estimations to distances within +/- $30 million of zero, where zero represents the FTC
threshold. The estimation procedure follows the method in McCrary (2008).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

81
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Figure 7. Product pricing before and after horizontal mergers. This figure plots monthly normalized
average prices of approximately 1.9 million retail scanner observations collected before the
announcement date and after the effective date for three horizontal mergers: one just below the
threshold, one just above the threshold, and one further below the threshold. All data are for
product sales of acquirers and rivals of the acquirer. Products are those that are common to the
target and the acquirer (and rivals). Given these mergers occur at different points in time, the x-axis
shows months relative to the announcement date (blue dotted line) and the effective date (red
dotted line) for each merger. On the y-axis, normalized prices (i.e., mean=0 and variance=1) are
displayed in the form of standard deviations, and thus observations on the graph can be interpreted
as the number of standard deviations from the mean. Section III of the Internet Appendix provides
details on the method used to define common products. We provide results from regressions using
this sample in Table XI, which includes standard errors and tests of statistical significance.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

82
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Table I

Sample Selection and M&A Descriptive Statistics


This table presents the sample selection procedure for the full sample of M&As (Panel A) and for the near-
threshold sample of M&As (Panel B). The sample is constructed using the universe of deals from the Securities
Data Company (SDC) Mergers and Acquisition database announced between February 1, 2001 and February
27, 2020. In addition, Panel C presents the top 10 industries in our full sample of 19,886 deals, using Fama-
French 48-industry classifications, Panel D presents the comparable distributions for the top 10 industries in
two subsamples representing deals with transaction values that are within 10% of the annual FTC notification
threshold, that is deal values that are either ≥ 0% but ≤ 10% below the threshold or ˃ 0% but ≤ 10% above the
threshold (i.e., just-below-threshold deals and just-above-threshold deals, respectively). Panel B presents the
top 10 industries separately for below- and above-threshold deals.

Panel A. Sample Selection (Full Sample)

All U.S. public and private M&As ( > $1 mil.) from Feb 1, 2001 to Feb 6, 2020 34,839

Less: Deals with missing data on % acquired, % owned before, or % owned


after (6,225)

Less: Deals involving financial firms or utilities (7,212)

Less: Deals involving real property for rental or investment purposes, or hotels (1,495)

Less: Deals when acquirer purchases remaining interest of its own subsidiary (21)

Full sample of deals 19,886

Panel B. Near-Threshold Sample

Just-above-threshold M&As 274

Just-below-threshold M&As 366

Sample of near-threshold deals 640

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

83
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Panel C. Industry Distribution (Top Ten industries)

Fama-French 48-Industry Groups Number of Deals % of All Deals


Top 10
Business services 6,417 32.27
Pharmaceutical products 1,305 6.56
Healthcare 1,012 5.09
Electronic equipment 991 4.98
Wholesale 776 3.90
Retail 753 3.79
Medical equipment 716 3.60
Communication 665 3.34
Computers 570 2.87
Transportation 503 2.53

Total (Top 10) 13,708 66.40

Table I—Continued

Panel D. Industry Distribution (within +/– 10% of annual threshold)


Just-Below Threshold Just-Above Threshold
Fama-French 48-Industry Number % of deals Number % of deals
Groups of deals “below” of deals “above”
Top 10
Business services 123 33.61 93 33.94
Pharmaceutical products 22 6.01 17 6.20
Electronic equipment 22 6.01 11 4.01
Medical equipment 20 5.46 13 4.74
Retail 18 4.92 15 5.47
Healthcare 13 3.55 16 5.84
Wholesale 13 3.55 7 2.55
Personal services 12 3.28 7 2.55
Computers 12 3.28 13 4.74
Construction 10 2.73 3 1.09

Total (Top 10) 265 72.40 195 71.13

Table II

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

84
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Descriptive Statistics
This table presents the distribution of key variables used in our analysis. All variables are defined in Appendix
A. Panel A presents descriptive statistics for all variables for both the pooled and the near-threshold analysis,
and Panel B presents descriptive statistics for key variables in the near-threshold analysis (split by below versus
above the premerger review threshold).

Panel A. Key Variables (Pooled and Near-Threshold Analysis)


Variable N Mean Std. 25th Median 75th
Deal analysis
PublicAcquirer 19,886 0.69 0.46 0.00 1.00 1.00
PrivateAcquirer 19,886 0.15 0.36 0.00 0.00 0.00
PublicTarget 19,886 0.23 0.42 0.00 0.00 0.00
Public-Public 19,886 0.12 0.33 0.00 0.00 0.00
Public-Private 19,886 0.57 0.49 0.00 1.00 1.00
Private-Private 19,886 0.09 0.29 0.00 0.00 0.00
Private-Public 19,886 0.06 0.24 0.00 0.00 0.00
AllCash 19,886 0.32 0.47 0.00 0.00 1.00
AllStock 19,886 0.08 0.28 0.00 0.00 0.00
AllCashandOther 19,886 0.78 0.41 1.00 1.00 1.00
AllStockandOther 19,886 0.48 0.50 0.00 0.00 1.00
Horizontal 19,886 0.28 0.45 0.00 0.00 1.00
Intrastate 19,886 0.19 0.39 0.00 0.00 0.00
Earnouts 19,886 0.10 0.30 0.00 0.00 0.00
EarnoutPerc 19,886 3.60 13.11 0.00 0.00 0.00
AcqTermFeePercent 19,886 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00
PublicTargetDealPremium 3,642 64.58 456.29 14.34 31.46 54.28
EconomicTie 603 0.75 0.43 0.00 1.00 1.00
PrivateTargetDealPremium 222 55.74 22.84 40.63 57.21 73.40
EarnoutPayoff 45 0.69 0.47 0.00 1.00 1.00
Financial contracting analysis
ExtendedLiabilityCoverage 234 0.53 0.50 0.00 1.00 1.00
DeductibleThreshold 192 0.33 0.47 0.00 0.19 0.50
Returns and gross margin analysis
RivalRet 594 0.00 0.03 –0.01 0.00 0.01
∆ GrossMargin 364 0.01 0.04 –0.01 0.00 0.02

Table II—Continued

Panel A: Key Variables (cont’d)

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

85
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
N Mean Std. 25th Median 75th
Product pricing analysis
NormalizedPrice 1,915,291 0.05 1.02 -0.70 0.00 0.71
JustBelowThreshold 1,915,291 0.21 0.41 0 0 0
Post 1,915,291 0.49 0.50 0 0 1
Product pricing analysis
Below-Threshold
Price 77,835,861 6.46 3.31 3.99 5.67 8.09
CommonProduct 77,835,861 0.01 0.07 0.00 0.00 0.00
Post 77,835,861 0.46 0.50 0.00 0.00 1.00
Above-Threshold
Price 4,091,337 19.65 25.16 6.79 9.99 23.74
CommonProduct 4,091,337 0.06 0.24 0.00 0.00 0.00
Post 4,091,337 0.49 0.50 0.00 0.00 0.00
Further-Below-Threshold
Price 4,760,492 3.64 0.91 3.00 3.69 3.99
CommonProduct 4,760,492 0.26 0.44 0.00 0.00 1.00
Post 4,760,492 0.53 0.50 0.00 1.00 1.00
Controls
DealValue 19,886 400.33 2,625.67 7.50 26.00 120.00
TenderOffer 19,886 0.04 0.19 0.00 0.00 0.00
PrivateTarget 19,886 0.77 0.42 1.00 1.00 1.00
NumRivals 594 40.54 55.77 4.00 14.00 49.00
RepsSurvive 232 0.59 0.49 0.00 1.00 1.00
SurvivalPeriod 222 0.85 0.95 0.00 1.00 1.50
TargetTermFeePercent 19,886 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00
Table II—Continued

Panel B. Near-Threshold Sample (+/-10% of threshold)

Just-Below Threshold Just-Above Threshold


Diff. in Diff. in
Variable N Mean Median N Mean Median means medians
Deal analysis
PublicAcquirer 366 0.73 1.00 274 0.73 1.00 0.00 0.00
PrivateAcquirer 366 0.10 0.00 274 0.13 0.00 –0.03 0.00
PublicTarget 366 0.19 0.00 274 0.23 0.00 –0.04 0.00
Public-Public 366 0.08 0.00 274 0.12 0.00 –0.04* 0.00*
Public-Private 366 0.65 1.00 274 0.61 1.00 0.04 0.00
Private-Private 366 0.05 0.00 274 0.07 0.00 –0.02 0.00
Private-Public 366 0.05 0.00 274 0.07 0.00 –0.02 0.00
AllCash 366 0.36 0.00 274 0.33 0.00 0.02 0.00

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

86
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
AllStock 366 0.04 0.00 274 0.09 0.00 –0.05** 0.00***
AllCashandOther 366 0.85 1.00 274 0.76 1.00 0.09** 0.00***
AllStockandOther 366 0.42 0.00 274 0.47 0.00 –0.05 0.00
Horizontal 366 0.28 0.00 274 0.26 0.00 0.02 0.00
Horizontal(Continuous) 366 0.43 0.33 274 0.35 0.15 0.08** 0.18**
Intrastate 366 0.17 0.00 274 0.20 0.00 –0.03 0.00
Earnouts 366 0.16 0.00 274 0.11 0.00 0.05* 0.00*
EarnoutPerc 366 4.62 0.00 274 3.57 0.00 1.05 0.00
AcqTermFeePercent 366 0.00 0.00 274 0.00 0.00 0.00** -0.00**
PublicTargetDealPremium 50 93.46 47.36 51 65.62 49.05 27.84 –1.69
PrivateTargetDealPrem 133 55.00 56.60 89 56.87 56.60 -1.87 0.00
EconomicTie 343 0.80 1.00 260 0.68 1.00 0.12*** 0.00***
EarnoutPayoff 28 0.64 1.00 17 0.76 1.00 –0.12 0.00
Financial contracting analysis
ExtendedLiabilityCoverage 123 0.54 1.00 111 0.51 1.00 0.03 0.00
DeductibleThreshold 105 0.39 0.24 87 0.27 0.06 0.12** 0.18
Returns and gross margin analysis
RivalRet 344 0.00 0.00 250 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
∆GrossMargin 206 0.01 0.01 158 0.01 0.02 0.00 -0.01
Controls
DealValue 366 59.35 58.27 274 66.66 65.13 –7.31*** –7.86***
TenderOffer 366 0.03 0.00 274 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00
RepsSurvive 122 0.61 1.00 110 0.56 1.00 0.05 0.00
SurvivalPeriod 116 0.87 1.00 106 0.84 1.00 0.03 0.00
TargetTermFeePct 366 0.00 0.00 274 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00*
NumRivals 344 39.66 14.00 250 41.76 13.50 –2.10 0.50

Table III

Tests of the Difference between the Frequency of Below-Threshold and


Above-Threshold Deals

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

87
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
This table presents results of tests of the statistical difference between the frequency of just-below-threshold
deals and just-above-threshold deals. In Panel A, we report results for the difference in density heights around
the threshold related to Figures 2 and 5. The log difference in heights is from the perspective of the bin just to
the right of the threshold (i.e., a negative sign indicates the right bin is lower than the left bin). In Panel B, we
report results for the difference between actual and estimated frequencies of deals occurring in the bins just
to the left and just to the right of zero related to Figure 3. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and
1% level, respectively. The estimation procedure follows the methods in McCrary (2008) in Panel A and
Burgstahler and Dichev (1997) in Panel B.

Panel A: Difference in Density Heights


Log Diff. in Heights t-statistic
Difference around threshold (Figure 2) –0.680*** –5.019
Falsification test (Figure 4) 0.129 0.445
Panel B: Difference in Estimated and Actual Bin Heights (Figure 3)
Bin Frequency (Actual) Frequency (Estimated) Difference t- statistic
JustBelowThreshold 176 121 55*** 4.046
JustAboveThreshold 96 141 –45*** –3.103

Table IV

Acquirer-Target Characteristics and Below-Threshold M&As


This table presents results from OLS regressions of M&As on acquirer-target characteristics. The dependent
variable, JustBelow, is an indicator that assumes the value of one if a deal’s transaction value is within a 10%
window below the FTC annual premerger review threshold, and zero otherwise. The main variables of interest
in columns (1) to (4) are indicator variables that assume the value of one based on combined acquirer-target
characteristics, and zero otherwise. The main variables of interest in columns (5) to (8) are indicator variables
that take the value of one if the deal’s payment terms are structured as 100% cash, 100% stock, 100% cash and

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

88
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
other (i.e., debt and earnouts), or 100% stock and other, respectively. We control for the size of the deal
(DealValue) in all specifications and for public targets (PublicTarget) in columns (5) to (8). All variables are
defined in Appendix A. All columns include target-firm industry fixed effects (using Fama-French 48-industry
classifications) and year fixed effects. Robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses and calculated using
standard errors clustered at the target-firm industry and year levels. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%,
5%, and 1% level, respectively.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Dependent JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow
Variable

Public-Public –0.007**
(–2.64)
Public-Private 0.005**
(2.71)
Private-Private –0.010***
(–3.40)
Private-Public –0.004
(–1.57)
AllCash 0.005*
(2.01)
AllStock –0.013***
(–12.16)
AllCashandOther 0.008***
(4.01)
AllStockandOther –0.006*
(–1.95)
DealValue –0.000*** –0.000*** –0.000*** –0.000*** –0.000*** –0.000*** –0.000*** –0.000***
(–3.82) (–5.96) (–5.08) (–5.60) (–4.22) (–4.49) (–3.47) (–4.47)
Constant 0.019*** 0.016*** 0.020*** 0.019*** 0.018*** 0.021*** 0.013*** 0.023***
(231.01) (17.09) (238.40) (362.25) (51.04) (132.57) (11.17) (16.50)
Observations 19,886 19,886 19,886 19,886 19,886 19,886 19,886 19,886
Adjusted R2 0.001 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.002
Year Fixed Effects yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Industry Fixed yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Effects
Table V

Financial Characteristics and Below-Threshold M&As


This table presents results from OLS regressions of M&As on financial contract characteristics. The sample is
restricted to observations for which the deal value falls within a +/-10% window centered on the FTC threshold
(see Table I, Panel B). The dependent variable, JustBelowThreshold, is an indicator variable that assumes the
value of one if a deal’s transaction value is within a 10% window below the FTC annual premerger review

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

89
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
threshold, and zero otherwise. The main variable of interest in column (1) is an indicator variable that assumes
the value of one if the financial contract includes a provision for earnouts, and zero otherwise. Results
presented in column (2) are conditional on the inclusion of an earnout provision, where the main variable of
interest is a continuous variable that measures the percent of the transaction value represented by earnouts.
All variables are defined in Appendix A. All columns include target-firm industry fixed effects (using Fama-
French 48-industry classification) and year fixed effects. Robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses and
calculated using standard errors clustered at the target-firm industry and year levels. *, **, *** indicate
significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. The sample comprises 637 deals (base sample of 640
less three singletons).

(1) (2)
Dependent Variable JustBelow JustBelow

Earnouts 0.062**
(2.42)
EarnoutPerc 0.001
(0.66)
DealValue –0.071*** –0.108***
(–11.01) (–6.53)
Constant 5.022*** 7.295***
(12.60) (7.25)
Observations 637 79
2
Adjusted R 0.440 0.530
Year Fixed Effects yes yes
Industry Fixed Effects yes yes

Table VI
Merger Agreement Terms and Below-Threshold M&As

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

90
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
This table presents results from OLS regressions of M&As on financial contract terms. The dependent variable,
JustBelowThreshold, is an indicator that assumes the value of one if a deal’s transaction value is within a 10%
window below the FTC annual premerger review threshold, and zero otherwise. The main variable of interest
in column (1), ExtendedLiabilityCoverage, is an indicator variable that assumes the value of one if the acquirer
extends D&O coverage for the former directors and officers of the target, and zero otherwise. The main
variable of interest in column (2), DeductibleThreshold, is a continuous variable that measures the threshold
(as a percent of the total deal value) above which the target is responsible for post-acquisition claims against
the acquirer. We also include controls for whether the representations and warranties survive beyond the
effective date (RepsSurvive), the length of the survival period (SurvivalPeriod), and whether the holdback funds
are held in escrow or otherwise (Escrow). All variables are defined in Appendix A. All columns include target-
firm industry fixed effects (using Fama-French 48-industry classification) and year fixed effects. Robust t-
statistics are reported in parentheses and calculated using standard errors clustered at the target-firm industry
and year levels. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. The sample
comprises 122 deals in column (1) (base sample of 640 less 132 public targets less 366 deals with missing data
to construct main independent variables less 12 deals with missing data to construct control variables less
eight singletons). The sample comprises 99 deals in column (2) (base sample of 640 less 132 public targets less
379 deals for which terms do not survive beyond the closing date less 11 deals with missing data to construct
main independent variable less nine deals with missing data to construct control variables less 10 singletons).

(1) (2)

Dependent Variable JustBelow JustBelow

ExtendedLiabilityCoverage 0.131**

(2.16)

DeductibleThreshold 18.705**

(2.19)

DealValue –0.108*** –0.095***

(–19.99) (–14.36)

Constant 7.125*** 6.020***

(19.16) (11.56)

Observations 122 99
2
Adjusted R 0.603 0.609

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

91
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Controls yes yes

Year Fixed Effects yes yes

Industry Fixed Effects yes yes

Table VII

Private-Target Deal Premiums and Below-Threshold M&As


This table presents results from OLS regressions of M&As on private-target deal premiums. The dependent
variable, JustBelowThreshold, is an indicator that assumes the value of one if a deal’s transaction value is
within a 10% window below the FTC annual premerger review threshold, and zero otherwise. The main
variable of interest in column (1), PrivateTargetDealPrem, is a continuous variable that measures the premium
paid for private targets. The main variable of interest in column (2), PublicTargetDealPrem, is a continuous
variable that measures the premium acquirers pay for publicly traded target firms. All variables are defined in
Appendix A. All columns include target-firm industry fixed effects (using Fama-French 48-industry
classification) and year fixed effects. Robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses and calculated using
standard errors clustered at the target-firm industry and year levels. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%,
5%, and 1% level, respectively. The sample comprises 219 deals in column (1) (base sample of 640 less 132

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

92
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
public targets less 102 deals with nonpublic acquirers less 184 deals with missing data to construct main
independent variable less three singletons). The sample comprises 84 deals in column (2) (base sample of 640
less 508 private targets less 31 deals with missing data to construct main independent variable less 17
singletons).

(1) (2)
Dependent Variable JustBelow JustBelow

PrivateTargetDealPrem –0.199*
(–1.96)
PublicTargetDealPrem –0.000
(–0.25)
DealValue –0.069*** –0.060**
(–7.54) (–2.80)
Constant 4.966*** 4.030***
(9.57) (3.19)
Observations 219 84
2
Adjusted R 0.449 0.373
Year Fixed Effects yes yes
Industry Fixed Effects yes yes

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

93
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Table VIII
Acquirer-Target CEO Economic Ties and Below-Threshold M&As
This table presents results from OLS regressions of M&As on acquirer-target CEO economic ties. The
dependent variable, JustBelowThreshold, is an indicator that assumes the value of one if a deal’s transaction
value is within a 10% window below the FTC annual premerger review threshold, and zero otherwise. In Panel
A, the main variable of interest, EconomicTie, is an indicator that takes the value of one if the target CEO is
retained by the acquiring firm and/or has an economic interest in the surviving firm. We also control for
whether the acquirer is public (PublicAcquirer) and for whether the merger is horizontal (Horizontal). In Panel
B, column (1), the main variable of interest is EarnoutPayoff, and in column (2) the main variable of interest in
the interaction term EconomicTie × EarnoutPayoff. All variables are defined in Appendix A. We include target-
firm industry fixed effects (using Fama-French 48-industry classification) and year fixed effects. Robust t-
statistics are reported in parentheses and calculated using standard errors clustered at the target-firm industry
and year levels. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. The sample
comprises 423 deals in Panel A (base sample of 640 less 208 deals with missing data on economic ties less nine
singletons). The sample comprises 39 (29) deals in column (1) ((2)) of Panel B (base sample of 640 less 551
deals without earnouts less 44 deals with missing data on earnout payoffs less six singletons).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

94
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Panel A: Economic Ties and Below-Threshold M&As

(1)

Dependent Variable JustBelow

EconomicTie 0.084**

(2.15)

DealValue –0.078***

(–8.67)

Constant 5.341***

(9.66)

Observations 423
2
Adjusted R 0.466

Controls yes

Year Fixed Effects yes

Industry Fixed Effects yes

Table VIII—Continued

Panel B: Economic Ties and Earnout Payoffs

(1) (2)

Dependent Variable JustBelow JustBelow

EarnoutPayoff 0.059 –0.386

(0.49) (–1.78)

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

95
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
0.590***

–0.151***

9.682***
–0.198

(–1.31)

(–6.06)
(9.04)

(6.84)

0.505

yes

yes
29

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


–0.144***

9.190***
(–10.12)

(12.11)

0.753

yes

yes
39

96
EconomicTie × EarnoutPayoff

Industry Fixed Effects


Year Fixed Effects
Observations
EconomicTie

2
Adjusted R
DealValue

Constant
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Table IX

Acquirer-Target Industry and Location and Below-Threshold M&As


This table presents results from OLS regressions of M&As on acquirer-target industry and location
characteristics. The sample is restricted to observations for which the deal value falls within a +/-10% window
centered around the FTC threshold. In Panels A and B, the dependent variable, JustBelowThreshold, is an
indicator variable that assumes the value of one if a deal’s transaction value is within the 10% window below
the FTC annual premerger review threshold, and zero otherwise. In Panel A, the main variables of interest in
columns (1) and (2) are indicator variables that assume the value of one based on whether the target and
acquirer share the same four-digit SIC code (i.e., horizontal merger) or share the same state of operations (i.e.,
intrastate). In column (3), the main variable of interest is the interaction term, Horizontal × Intrastate, which
takes the value of one if the merger is both horizontal and intrastate, and zero otherwise. All variables are
defined in Appendix A. In Panel B, columns (1) and (4), the main variable of interest, HighConc, is an indicator
that assumes the value of one if the target firm’s industry is above the median concentration, and zero
otherwise. In columns (2) and (5) and (3) and (6), the main variables of interest are interaction terms
Horizontal × HighConc and Intrastate × HighConc, which assume the value of one when the target firm’s
industry is above the median concentration and the acquirer and target share the same four-digit SIC code (in
columns (2) and (5)), or share the same state of operations (in columns (3) and (6)), and zero otherwise. In
columns (1) to (3) industry concentration is estimated using the methodology in Hoberg and Phillips (2010b)
(Conc_HP). In columns (4) to (6), industry concentration is estimated using net sales by four-digit SIC code, by
year (Conc_Sales) (Hou and Robinson (2006)). All variables are defined in Appendix A. All columns in Panel A
include target-firm industry fixed effects (using Fama-French 48-industry classifications) and year fixed effects,
while all columns in Panel B include industry fixed effects. Robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses and
calculated using standard errors clustered at the target-firm industry and year levels. *, **, *** indicate
significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. The sample comprises of 637 deals in Panel A (base
sample of 640 less three singletons). The sample comprises 501 in columns (4) to (6) in Panel B (base sample of
640 less 136 deals with missing data to construct HHI measure less three singletons).

Panel A. Horizontal and Intrastate M&As


(1) (2) (3)
Dependent Variable JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow

Horizontal 0.066** 0.028


(2.61) (1.43)
Intrastate –0.061 –1.26*
(–1.31) (–1.92)
Horizontal × Intrastate 0.194***

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

97
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
(2.91)
DealValue –0.072*** –0.072*** –0.072***
(–10.81) (–11.06) (–11.45)
Constant 5.048*** 5.064*** 5.076***
(12.35) (12.66) (13.17)
Observations 637 637 637
2
Adjusted R 0.442 0.440 0.447
Year Fixed Effects yes yes yes
Industry Fixed Effects yes yes yes

Table IX—Continued

Panel B. Highly-Concentrated Industry M&As


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Dependent Variable JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow JustBelow
Measure of HighConc Conc_HP Conc_HP Conc_HP Conc_Sales Conc_Sales Conc_Sales

HighConc –0.003 –0.024 –0.009 0.011 –0.014 0.050


(–0.12) (–1.15) (–0.36) (0.28) (–0.27) (1.30)
Horizontal 0.005 0.013
(0.25) (0.55)
Horizontal x HighConc 0.100** 0.133**
(2.24) (2.27)
Intrastate –0.105* 0.036
(–1.80) (0.45)
Intrastate x HighConc 0.051 –0.223
(0.60) (–1.62)
DealValue –0.071*** –0.072*** –0.072*** –0.074*** –0.074*** –0.075***
(–11.11) (–11.32) (–11.47) (–10.45) (–10.64) (–11.59)
Constant 5.035*** 5.055*** 5.069*** 5.111*** 5.110*** 5.173***
(12.53) (12.76) (13.01) (11.86) (12.18) (12.96)
Observations 640 640 640 501 501 501
2
Adjusted R 0.444 0.447 0.446 0.460 0.464 0.467
Year Fixed Effects yes yes yes yes yes yes
Industry Fixed Effects no no no no no no

Table X

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

98
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Horizontal Rivals’ Announcement Returns, Gross Margins, and Below-
Threshold M&As
This table presents results from OLS regressions of announcement returns and gross margins on M&As. In
columns (1) and (2), the dependent variable, RivalRet, is a continuous variable that represents the equal-
weighted (three-day) market-adjusted portfolio returns of horizontal rivals of acquirers. In columns (3) and (4),
the dependent variable, ∆ GrossMargin, is a continuous variable that equals the change in the industry-
average gross margin measured as the difference between the industry-average gross margin before the
merger and the industry-average gross margin after the merger, where gross margin equals sales minus cost of
goods sold all scaled by sales. The main variable of interest in columns (1) and (3), JustBelowThreshold, is an
indicator variable that assumes the value of one if a deal’s transaction value is within a 10% window below the
FTC annual premerger review threshold, and zero otherwise. In columns (2) and (4), we present results for the
association between announcement returns (in column (2)) and gross margins (in column (4)) and an
interaction term, Horizontal × JustBelowThreshold, which assumes the value of one if the deal is below the
threshold and the acquirer and target share the same four-digit SIC code, and zero otherwise. All regressions
also include as controls DealValue, PublicAcquirer, PublicTarget, and LowNumRivals. All variables are defined in
Appendix A. All columns include acquirer industry fixed effects (using Fama-French 48-industry classification)
and year fixed effects. Robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses and calculated using standard errors
clustered at the acquirer industry and year levels. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level,
respectively. The sample comprises 543 deals in columns (1) and (2) (base sample of 640 less 94 deals with
missing data to construct variables less three singletons). The sample comprises 359 deals in columns (3) and
4) (base sample of 640 less 276 deals with missing data to construct variables less 5 singletons).

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Dependent Variable RivalRet RivalRet ∆ GrossMargin ∆ GrossMargin

JustBelowThreshold 0.005 0.002 –0.002 –0.005


(1.05) (0.49) (–0.39) (–1.05)
Horizontal –0.006* –0.009***
(–1.79) (–3.18)
Horizontal × JustBelowThreshold 0.009* 0.011**
(1.78) (2.82)
Constant –0.064*** –0.066*** 0.039 0.037
(–2.92) (–2.91) (0.77) (0.74)
Observations 543 543 359 359
2
Adjusted R 0.115 0.115 0.066 0.066
Controls yes yes yes yes
Year Fixed Effects yes yes yes yes
Industry Fixed Effects yes yes yes yes

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

99
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Table XI
Product-Level Prices for Below-Threshold M&As
This table presents results from difference-in-differences OLS regressions of normalized average weekly
product prices on three mergers: one just below the threshold, one just above the threshold, and one further
below the threshold. The dependent variable, NormalizedPrice, is a continuous variable that represents the
normalized average weekly prices for common products of the acquirer and its rivals. The main variable of
interest, JustBelowThreshold × Post, is an interaction term that takes the value of one if the observation
belongs to the merger occurring just below the threshold and the week falls after the effective date of the
merger, and zero otherwise. All variables are defined in Appendix A. We vary the inclusion of week and
geographic fixed effects across columns such that column (5) represents our fully specified model. For our
week fixed effect, we count weeks relative to the effective date of the merger, since the three mergers occur
in different years. Robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses and calculated using standard errors
clustered at the product and week levels. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level,
respectively.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)


Dependent Variable Normalized Normalized Normalized Normalized Normalized
Price Price Price Price Price

JustBelowThreshold –0.000 0.002 –0.043 0.168 0.181


(0.00) (0.03) (–0.54) (0.36) (0.39)
Post 0.087 –0.200*** –0.207***
(1.29) (–2.79) (–2.85)
JustBelowThreshold × Post 1.30* 1.28* 1.27** 1.23** 1.22**
(1.93) (1.98) (2.00) (2.21) (2.30)
TimeTrend 0.001*** 0.001*** 0.064 0.088
(3.58) (3.49) (0.41) (0.57)
Constant –0.000 0.149* 0.162* 0.812 1.114
(0.00) (1.71) (1.93) (0.44) (0.62)
Observations 1,915,291 1,915,291 1,915,291 1,915,291 1,915,291
2
Adjusted R 0.004 0.010 0.137 0.044 0.173
Week Fixed Effects no no no yes yes
Geographic Fixed Effects no no yes no yes

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

100
15406261, ja, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.13256 by Quratulain Benish - Bahauddin Zakariya University , Wiley Online Library on [25/06/2023]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

101

You might also like