water_funds_and_payments_for_ecosystem_services_practice_learns_from_theory_and_theory_can_learn_from_practice

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

Water funds and payments for ecosystem

services: practice learns from theory and theory


can learn from practice
REBECCA L. GOLDMAN-BENNER, SILVIA BENITEZ, TIMOTHY BOUCHER,
A L E J A N D R O C A L V A C H E , G R E T C H E N D A I L Y , P E T E R K A R E I V A , T I M M K R O E G E R and
AURELIO RAMOS

Abstract Payments for ecosystem services (PES) are emer- additional/side objectives but partnerships are likely to
ging worldwide as important mechanisms to align invest- lower transaction costs and provide transparent, long-term
ments in human and natural well-being. PES projects are landscape-scale watershed management.
often defined as voluntary transactions where well-defined
Keywords Additionality, conditionality, payment for eco-
environmental/ecosystem services (or land uses likely to
system services, PES, South America, trust fund, water fund
secure those services) are bought by a minimum of one
service buyer, from a minimum of one service provider, if
and only if the service provider continuously secures service
provision (conditionality). Further criteria of PES include Introduction
limiting additional objectives and ensuring that payments
reward behaviour that would otherwise not occur (addi-
tionality). Together these best practices for PES are
W ith a growing number of conservation projects
aiming to benefit human well-being by providing
ecosystem services (the goods and services such as water
increasingly accepted as the most efficient means to achieve
purification and carbon sequestration that nature provides;
desired outcomes and are guiding funding for PES projects.
Daily, 1997) there is a need for metrics to evaluate the
We used a series of water funds (watershed-oriented PES
effectiveness of current projects and to determine best
projects based on a trust fund model) to examine how
designs and enabling conditions for new ones. Many
theoretical best practices could inform and improve practice
projects that aim to conserve or enhance the provision of
and also how theory could learn from practical efforts. We
ecosystem services, among other conservation benefits,
conclude that thoughtful consideration is required when
employ what is generally referred to as payments for
evaluating the promise of a PES approach against a
ecosystem services (PES; Landell-Mills & Porras, 2002;
theoretical ideal. We found that requiring conditionality
Porras et al., 2008). A definition of PES and associated best
may limit the use of creative finance mechanisms such as
practices has been emerging (Wunder, 2005, 2006, 2007)
trust funds that can provide long-term benefits for
that is heavily based on economic theory (specifically,
conservation and human well-being, and that requiring
efficiency considerations) and is becoming broadly accepted
additionality can exclude benefits from social diffusion and
in the academic literature (e.g. Sommerville et al., 2009) and
result in the inefficient targeting of PES funds. Finally,
among practitioners (e.g. CIFOR, 2006; Forest Trends et al.,
public–private partnerships in water funds lead to multiple
2008). Recently, funding criteria have been guided by these
best practices (e.g. Global Environment Facility STAP
guidelines; Wunder et al., 2010). Although this provides a
REBECCA L. GOLDMAN-BENNER* (Corresponding author), TIMOTHY BOUCHER and rubric for evaluating PES projects, we argue here that some
TIMM KROEGER The Nature Conservancy—Conservation Science, 4245 North
Fairfax Drive, Suite 100. Arlington, Virginia 22203-1637, USA. E-mail of the criteria would best be expanded or relaxed while
rebeccagoldman@stanfordalumni.org recognizing the potential benefits of achieving theoretical
SILVIA BENITEZ and ALEJANDRO CALVACHE The Nature Conservancy—Northern ideals. Here we use a series of practical projects to highlight
Andes Conservation Program, Quito, Ecuador where and how practice can learn from theory and theory
GRETCHEN DAILY Biological Sciences, Stanford University, Stanford, California, from practice.
USA
PES projects aim to provide financial incentives to land
PETER KAREIVA The Nature Conservancy—Conservation Science, Seattle, owners or managers for implementing conservation actions
Washington, USA
that benefit others but that they would not have adopted
AURELIO RAMOS The Nature Conservancy—Latin America Conservation
Program, Cartagena, Colombia
without those incentives (Sommerville et al., 2009).
Research indicates that integrating ecosystem services into
*Current address: Inter-American Development Bank, 1300 New York Avenue
NW, Washington, DC 20577, USA conservation approaches can diversify the types of stake-
Received 19 February 2011. Revision requested 13 April 2011.
holders who provide funding for conservation (Goldman
Accepted 27 May 2011. et al., 2008). The use of ecosystem services in projects is

© 2012 Fauna & Flora International, Oryx, 46(1), 55–63 doi:10.1017/S0030605311001050

https://doi.org/10.1017/S0030605311001050 Published online by Cambridge University Press


56 R. L Goldman-Benner et al.

diverse and widespread (Tallis et al., 2009) but which of projects using in-kind or indirect payments and emphasize
these schemes performs best? Given limited funding, which the need for creative solutions.
strategies should take priority? We seek to answer these questions for several purposes.
According to the emerging dominant definition, PES Firstly, we hope that in this early stage of experimentation
projects are those that include voluntary transactions where and evolution of PES approaches, funding opportunities will
well-defined environmental (or ecosystem) services (or land not be restricted to projects that fit the strict PES best-
uses likely to secure those services) are bought by a practice definition. In other words, we argue that the
minimum of one service buyer, from a minimum of one currently prevailing best-practice definition should not be
service provider, if and only if the service provider cont- what determines the constitution of a PES project. Water
inuously secures service provision (conditionality; Wunder, funds are PES, as are many other successful payment
2005, 2007; Dillaha et al., 2007; Southgate & Wunder, 2007; approaches that do not meet the ideal advocated. Secondly,
Engel et al., 2008). Further research on PES best practices we have observed that water funds are replicable in
has expanded these conditions to include differentiated particular areas precisely because they violate some of the
payments (payments are scaled/proportionate to services best-practice criteria. Thirdly, we want to emphasize the
returned or actions taken), spatial targeting (e.g. prioritiza- importance of encouraging creativity in PES design whilst
tion of landowners based on benefits, risk of loss and using best practices to guide actions to achieve greater
opportunity cost), limiting side objectives (few or no economic efficiency wherever possible.
additional or supplemental objectives) and additionality There are numerous PES approaches that do not meet all
(only pay for actions that would otherwise not occur; Engel of the proposed best practices (Engel et al., 2008). We use
et al., 2008; Wunder et al., 2010). water funds because the deviations are consistent within
PES schemes have received considerable attention these PES projects and help to illuminate further good
(Landell-Mills & Porras, 2002; Pagiola et al., 2002, 2007; practices that would help to expand the definition of PES
Jack et al., 2008; Sommerville et al., 2009; Farley & Costanza, meaningfully. Water funds are more than a financial model:
2010) analysing both their theory and practice and the they are an institutional, financial and biophysical mech-
appeal and drawbacks of market creation (Goldman & anism that link water services users to providers through
Tallis, 2009; Daniels et al., 2010; Koellner et al., 2010; payments. Specifically, we define a water fund as a PES
Reynolds et al., 2010). Debate continues about the effective- approach that for financial management uses a trust fund
ness of these financial incentive systems in attracting managed by an external entity. In addition, water funds
landowners, their benefit to the poor and the scale of share the following criteria: (1) multiple water service users
biodiversity benefits they yield (Engel et al., 2008; Porras or user groups, (2) payments that support implementation
et al., 2008). Nevertheless, these schemes are no longer rare of watershed best-management practices and conservation,
(Asquith & Wunder, 2008; Porras et al., 2008). and (3) a board of directors with stakeholder representation
For economic efficiency and for establishing metrics that decides how to spend the revenue.
to determine optimal investments over time, the PES
definition may be theoretically ideal but in practice few if
any PES projects meet all the criteria (Wunder, 2005). Does What is a water fund?
this mean such projects are presently not successful or that
they will fail in the future? Are donations and conservation With 113 active/operational payment for watershed service
investments being spent inappropriately, or is the definition (PWS) projects (a type of PES focusing on water-related
simply too rigid to account for the variable social/ services; Stanton et al., 2010), water funds are only one of
institutional conditions and ubiquitous information con- many PES schemes actively focusing on delivery of hydro-
straints in conservation? logical services. Each PWS scheme has its own unique
Here we compare a set of practical, sustainably financed characteristics: finance schemes, payment forms, stake-
watershed PES projects, called water funds, with the PES holders involved, activities implemented and institutional
definition advocated by Wunder (2005) and others. Firstly, arrangements. We focus on how the unique qualities of
we introduce the projects and how they function. Secondly, water funds can benefit from PES ideals and how good
we use three best-practice criteria (conditionality, addition- practice can help inform PES best practices.
ality and limiting side objectives) to answer two key Water funds are increasingly being used in Ecuador and
questions: how have and how can water funds learn from Colombia but are also found in Bolivia and Peru. The
proposed PES best practices and modify their approaches to central defining characteristic of a water fund is a trust fund
achieve greater efficiency, and how can lessons learned from financial model that is independently governed for long-
ongoing PES projects such as water funds demonstrate the term benefits (some for up to 80 years). Other very similar
required definitional modifications? Thirdly, we discuss a PES projects, such as the case of Pimampiro in Ecuador, also
final concern about enforcement mechanisms for PES use a sustainable finance source (a savings account) but lack

© 2012 Fauna & Flora International, Oryx, 46(1), 55–63

https://doi.org/10.1017/S0030605311001050 Published online by Cambridge University Press


Water funds and PES 57

the independence, political security and long-term horizon Water funds are governed by a multi-institutional body,
of a trust fund (Wunder & Alban, 2008). In addition, water i.e. a public–private partnership that includes service buyers,
funds have an institutional framework composed of key and in some cases sellers, which makes decisions about how
stakeholders who prioritize the use of payments that, at least to spend water-fund revenue. This partnership accesses
in part, go towards conservation management of the opportunities for cost savings by investing in nature for
watershed and biodiversity protection. water purification and for regularity of flows (thereby
There are currently seven operational water funds, with avoiding costs of finding water further from the out-take
at least four more projected to become operational by 2012. point; Goldman et al., 2010).
A wide variety of stakeholders has been involved in the The trust fund of a water fund acts as both a means to
creation of each of these funds. The oldest water fund is finance conservation projects and, in some cases, a reserve
Fondo de Protección del Agua (FONAG) in Quito, Ecuador, fund. The trust is a long-term, sustainable investment.
which was launched in 2000 through the efforts of Interest from the trust, additional investments from water
The Nature Conservancy (TNC) and Fundación Antisana users or from other external donors, and a portion of the
along with key partners such as the mayor of Quito and the trust itself may be used to pay for conservation projects,
Quito water utility. Since its launch, TNC has worked with although this varies by water fund. In some cases, such as
numerous partners throughout Ecuador and Colombia to water funds in Colombia, a portion of the trust’s principal
operationalize four more water funds: two more in Ecuador creates a reserve fund. This reserve is used to cover some
and two in Colombia. Beyond these TNC-affiliated and/or operational costs, to pay for some transaction costs asso-
supported initiatives, two regional water funds exist in this ciated with conservation agreements with watershed com-
same general region. One is Fondo Regional del Agua munities when other payments are not available, and to
(FORAGUA) launched in 2009 by the municipal govern- manage risk but mostly it is used to guarantee long-term,
ments of the southern region of Ecuador in partnership with sustainable funding for conservation. Through this finance
Nature and Culture International, an NGO that mainly mechanism and their governing boards, the water funds in
works in Ecuador and Peru. Another key partner is the Andean region have brought together a wide variety of
Corporación para el desarrollo de los Recursos Naturales, stakeholders (e.g. local communities, public agencies,
an Ecuadorian NGO. This fund includes three prov- private corporations) to cooperatively decide how to ensure
inces. The other water fund is FONACRUZ, initiated by the provision of ecosystem services through investments in
Fundación Natura Bolivia working with the departmental biodiversity conservation.
and municipal government in Santa Cruz, Bolivia. All of The watersheds in this region of the Andes share
these water funds aim to provide clean, regular water conditions that facilitate water fund creation. These include
flows through watershed conservation. upstream natural ecosystems (forests and, in many cases,
Water funds allow downstream water users (service páramo; i.e. high-altitude valleys and plains with a variety of
buyers) to finance upstream provision of a clean, regular lakes and wet grasslands intermingled with shrublands and
supply of water. In all these cases the services originate forest patches). These ecosystems are essential for capturing,
within natural ecosystems (e.g. public protected areas) but it storing and regulating the release of water. They are also
is the land management and land use by the human natural water purifiers and erosion control mechanisms. If
communities living on private, public and communal lands these natural ecosystems are converted then water quality,
in the watershed that determine service delivery; these flow regularity and biodiversity can be compromised
communities are the key service providers. Water users (Buytaert et al., 2005, 2006, 2007). Many of these watersheds
(e.g. utilities, municipalities and industries) contribute to are also home to poor, rural ranching and farming com-
the fund. In TNC-related funds the contribution is munities that surround the native ecosystems and rely on
voluntary (although in Quito the municipality has now the rich soils and abundant grasses for grazing and crops. In
passed an ordinance requiring that at least 2% of the fees the some areas the use of fertilizers and agrochemicals is
water utility collects goes to the water fund but the fee for the increasing, further threatening water quality. Ensuring good
individual user has not increased) and with FONACRUZ conservation management and providing incentives suffi-
and FORAGUA some of the financing comes from cient to discourage further encroachment on, and degrada-
increased water fees paid by water users (FORAGUA tion of, these natural ecosystems can provide long-term
actually used FONAG as a model and has similar municipal protection for the watershed.
ordinances). Each water fund has its own location- Finally, many northern Andean watersheds share down-
dependent objectives and goals but in general they invest stream users who depend on the water and who are often
in conserving watersheds to improve or maintain water able to pay for service provision. These users include public
quality for downstream users, maintain regular flows of agencies such as urban water utilities, municipal and
water throughout the year and maintain or enhance natural departmental governments, hydropower companies, private
ecosystems. industries such as beer companies (specifically SABMiller

© 2012 Fauna & Flora International, Oryx, 46(1), 55–63

https://doi.org/10.1017/S0030605311001050 Published online by Cambridge University Press


58 R. L Goldman-Benner et al.

Bavaria) and water bottling companies (such as Tesalia), contractually agreed goods or services; best-practice
and others such as sugar cane producers in the Cauca Valley proponents argue the same relationship should exist for
of Colombia where the producers associated under Asocaña PES schemes. The more tightly coupled the relationship
are the main buyers of water fund services. between money spent and goods or services received, the
Water funds invest in a variety of strategies in the greater the conditionality of the payment; i.e. providers/
watershed to ensure service delivery; the activities vary by sellers are paid only if they actually provide the goods or
fund. For example, in many TNC-affiliated funds strategies services. The merits of conditionality are clear: it ensures
include training and paying for community-based park service provision or, alternatively, avoids wasting resources
guards to support the national system. All the water funds by paying ‘money for nothing’ (Ferraro & Pattanayak,
aim to protect natural ecosystems and to work with the 2006), and it ensures that the practices paid for generate net
watershed communities to implement best-management benefits for users, as presumably the latter would otherwise
practices, reforestation and restoration activities. Best- not be willing to purchase those services at the given price.
management practices can include fencing off headwaters Furthermore, conditionality promotes the development of
and riparian areas, planting live fences, managing fires and methods for measuring the impact of conservation invest-
revegetating (Fundación Natura, 2010; Goldman et al., 2010). ments on ecosystem services. Even proponents of this
In FORAGUA revenue also goes towards land purchase. feature of PES schemes recognize that currently what is paid
The water funds work with the watershed communities for, almost ubiquitously, are practices that should return
on these projects, finding ways to secure or improve desired services but water funds demonstrate how, even with
livelihoods. For example, many funds finance projects that this relaxed definition, necessitating conditionality can
compensate for potentially negative livelihood impacts from inhibit creative, sustainable finance solutions for cost-
conservation actions (e.g. reduced crop acreage because of effective conservation.
riparian revegetation) and that improve social conditions. As previously described, water funds accumulate money
Such projects include diversifying income sources such in a trust fund, the interest from which finances conserva-
as introducing guinea pig farms or of alternative food tion. Service buyers are downstream users who contribute to
sources (e.g. organic vegetable gardens) and investments in the fund although, in practice, the fund itself is the buyer as
education. it is the source of conservation payments. As only the
Given the newness of many of these funds, changes in interest and/or a portion of the principal in the fund are
land use and resource management are only just being used to finance conservation projects, the trust fund creates
measured. FONAG, the oldest fund, has data to indicate that a sustainable source of financing. This sustainable finance
it has revegetated and maintained c. 600 ha of land per year mechanism violates conditionality because buyers are
over the past 4 years; reforested 2,033 ha of land with unable to withdraw their contributions if they perceive
. 2,000,000 trees; involved 30,500 children in environ- that services are not being delivered (although because
mental education programmes; hired, trained and employed outcome-based measures are now being implemented in
11 community-based park guards to help conserve protected various water funds, providers will be able to know if
areas; and engaged . 200 families in community develop- services are not being delivered). Likewise, if a buyer, such as
ment projects in rural basins (FONAG staff, pers. comms.). a water utility, finds a better, more cost-effective investment
In an assessment of three FONAG community- for decreasing sedimentation, the buyer is unable to
conservation project areas (including c. 62,500 ha of withdraw its accumulated contribution in the fund. Buyers
páramo) it was found that the ecosystems have been or users can stop supporting the fund with additional
maintained in a pristine state. Compared to similar sites payments but contributions already made are sunk costs
outside the conservation areas, burning has stopped and and will continue to generate interest.
cattle grazing, which is critical to hydrological service There are advantages to using the trust fund as a
provision, has been greatly reduced (Buytaert et al., 2006; conservation revenue source. The interest-based, non-
T. Boucher et al., unpubl. data). Altogether, FONAG is capital reducing financing is sustainable and thus not
working in watersheds around the Quito metropolitan completely vulnerable to market fluctuations (e.g. the de-
region that span . 500,000 ha, of which c. 120,000 ha are valuing of conservation or watershed management). Sunk
intact páramo and c. 50,000 ha are natural forest (Boucher, contributions also provide an incentive for service users to
in press). remain on the board of directors for the long term to
influence future investments, which leads to improved
Conditionality and ‘true’ financial sustainability understanding and knowledge about conservation and
in PES: are both possible? ‘green’ alternatives and creates a ‘knowledge community’
of major stakeholders that provides a platform for active
In a conventional market (e.g. for an apple or a car) sellers engagement and learning about conservation opportunities,
receive payment only if they actually provide the approaches and benefits.

© 2012 Fauna & Flora International, Oryx, 46(1), 55–63

https://doi.org/10.1017/S0030605311001050 Published online by Cambridge University Press


Water funds and PES 59

Recognizing both the timely need to invest in conserva- important to acknowledge this potential and to relax
tion projects (it takes time to build interest on the fund’s conditionality as an absolute criterion for qualifying as
principal) and to create a more direct relationship between PES, recognizing some of the benefits of financial sustain-
user and provider, some water funds have adjusted their ability. Ideally, both conditionality and financial sustain-
financial models and now build a trust fund as a reserve fund ability are possible for conservation efforts. However, given
whereas the majority of the contributions are spent more market volatility and numerous externalities, and given the
immediately on conservation activities in the watershed. current level of outcome-based measures, it may, for now, be
Compared with the FONAG model, withdrawing user worth partially sacrificing one to ensure the other. Failure to
support in this case means there is significantly less money recognize the benefits of achieving true financial sustain-
available for action. For example, in Tungurahua, Ecuador, ability, in spite of some sacrifices to conditionality, risks
water fund contributions are managed by a trust but only sacrificing good practice to theory.
60% goes to capitalize the principal and 40% finances
immediate conservation actions. In Bogota, users’ contri-
butions are not yet capitalizing the trust; instead, the water Additionality: where efficiency assessments
fund is financing actions first to demonstrate progress and ignore the benefits of social diffusion
results to help attract new contributions.
Even using the trust as a reserve violates PES best Additionality is the incremental gain in service delivery that
practices but confers several advantages. It buys time to seek results from implementing PES compared with the counter-
new donations and revenue if the cost of the environmental factual baseline (the world that would exist without the
externality exceeds the available fund resources while project; Wunder, 2007). Establishing the correct baseline is
beginning to implement corrective actions immediately. therefore crucial for accurately assessing project outputs,
The reserve fund helps weather the impact of short-term cost-effectiveness and efficiency (Wunder, 2005). Advocates
market fluctuations that could threaten the viability of PES of additionality argue that paying for services that would
programmes fully funded from ongoing cash flow and it have been provided in absentia of financial incentives is
provides reserve funding for unforeseen management and inefficient (Engel et al., 2008). Ideal participants in PES
operational costs not captured in cost estimates for direct projects are those landowners who pose a credible and
actions. significant (current or future) threat to service provision and
Trust funds can operate in a wide variety of financial and who will bear opportunity costs for conservation actions but
institutional settings; these include both public and private whose land use is only marginally more profitable than
bodies. Securing the investments in a trust and thereby alternatives that conserve ecosystem service flows. Under
protecting them from political instabilities is one of the such conditions, a PES subsidy can have maximum impact
major reasons FORAGUA chose to establish a trust fund. (Wunder, 2005).
Trust-based PES schemes are flexible; the most efficient Several concerns have been raised about additionality as
scheme for a particular PES project depends on local a strict means for judging the effectiveness of PES. Firstly,
context. If market fluctuations or government intervention without a comprehensive, in-depth evaluation of current
could imperil conservation actions, a sustainable trust and future threats, it is difficult to assess the security of
reasonably well insulated from both could be the most currently conserved lands. Because of limited information at
efficient and effective way to provide services. At the same a fine spatial scale, in most cases it is difficult to assess the
time it is important to recognize that a trust may not be likelihood that one landowner will maintain good steward-
institutionally or politically feasible or that government ship and another will not (e.g. Wünscher et al., 2008).
regulations may favour a different finance mechanism. In Establishing accurate baselines for measuring additionality
Brazil, for example, several PWS projects make use of a can thus be expensive (Sommerville et al., 2009). Secondly,
government regulation to make direct payments to land- Wunder (2005) notes potential inequities that could arise.
owners, with no trust or reserve funds as intermediaries. Good land stewards, or landowners with small holdings,
Trust funds remove the direct connection between often do not pose a credible threat to achieving conservation
service sellers and individual buyers by interjecting a goals and are therefore unable to access the financial
financial intermediary. In other words, financial sustain- incentives of a PES project. Nevertheless, additionality is a
ability leads to a violation of conditionality. Although over key consideration for evaluating PES schemes to ensure
time some water funds have adapted their trust funds to efficiency and to avoid investments in environmental service
increase conditionality by using them only as reserve funds projects that do not yield increases in service flows above the
rather than as the sole financing source for conservation baseline (Ferraro & Pattanyak, 2006; Wunder, 2007; Engel
actions, even this violates the conditionality requirement for et al., 2008; Sommerville et al., 2009).
the ideal PES scheme. However, this can yield great benefits. Water funds are starting to use tools to prioritize
In evaluating PES projects for possible funding it is therefore conservation actions to achieve additionality. For example,

© 2012 Fauna & Flora International, Oryx, 46(1), 55–63

https://doi.org/10.1017/S0030605311001050 Published online by Cambridge University Press


60 R. L Goldman-Benner et al.

scientific models (specifically integrated valuation of spatial scale beyond the scope of an individual PES project,
ecosystem services and trade-off models) have been run in thus capturing potential scale effects in service production.
the Cauca Valley of Colombia, the site of the Fondo de Agua The fund board includes water users and sometimes
por la Vida y la Sostenibilidad (FAPVS) water fund community representatives (often service providers) and
(H. Tallis, pers. comm.), to determine priority areas for makes decisions about how to use funds. Board members
investment based on greatest threat. However, even with are very diverse. In the Fondo del Agua para la conservación
such baselines an analysis of lowest opportunity cost for de la Cuenca del Río Paute near Cuenca, Ecuador, for
greatest service provision and conservation benefits is example, the board includes two water companies (inter-
lacking. Nevertheless, we argue that even if high-quality ested in water quality and flow regularity), two hydropower
baseline assessments are conducted for potential PES target companies (concerned about sedimentation), Cuenca Uni-
areas (such as in FAPVS) they may fail to account for versity, and TNC and Fundación Cordillera Tropical
additional benefits stemming from the social dynamics of (concerned about biodiversity conservation).
the region. Because of the varied interests of their board members,
Without accounting for social spillover effects (the water funds necessarily have a variety of objectives, or a
diffusion of action(s) through a population once the main objective and various side objectives, thus violating
action(s) is taken up by at least one person), additionality PES best practices because if the objectives do not align
cannot be measured accurately. As Yates & Aronson (1983) perfectly, one or more stakeholders may invest in actions
argued ‘To design effective public policy, the social, that are not linked to the results they seek or are not the
cognitive, and personal forces that, in addition to the preferred actions to achieve those results. Hydropower
economic realities, define the situation must be understood’. companies, for example, may care more about sedimenta-
Social diffusion theory posits that changing the behaviour of tion whereas water utilities may care more about faecal
a small percentage of people (in some cases as little as 15% of coliforms. When service providers have a seat on the board
a population) can have transformational impacts on the (such as in FAPVS), interests become even more diverse.
entire population (AtKisson, 1999). If the 15% are those who Joint decision making thus may divert service buyers’
are easy to convince, who do not require large payments to investments from the services they most care about.
change behaviour, and who are inclined to continue Nevertheless, we argue that these public–private insti-
conservation practices once adopted, then it may be more tutional mechanisms, with their multiple objectives, may in
socially and financially efficient to include these individuals some cases be more efficient despite the challenges the
in a project. In the context of PES, this means that it is not structure poses for achieving strong conditionality. Joint
necessarily inefficient to target landowners whose actions decision making leads to large-scale, integrated watershed
may not yield high additionality. As commonly measured, management. Water funds bring together stakeholders as
however, additionality does not account for these diffusion different as sugar cane producers and local watershed
effects. communities (e.g. FAPVS), and such partnerships provide a
We thus argue for caution when evaluating additionality way to include social criteria as well as biophysical and
in a PES scheme because benefits from social diffusion may economic measures in defining optimal investment portfo-
be ignored, and excluding them may result in the inefficient lios.
targeting of PES funds. In the Bogota water fund, for
example, there is qualitative evidence of peer pressure and
community encouragement for participation and for strict Enforcement and in-kind payments: how do we
enforcement of fund practices, benefits that are now being make this work?
quantitatively measured in FONAG and FAPVS.
Water funds use a variety of payment types, including
indirect and in-kind payments such as materials, manpower
Side objectives: friends or foes? and/or expertise to reward farmers and ranchers for
changing their management practices. Wunder (2005)
Although a particular water user may be interested in highlights the relevance and importance of careful con-
specific ecosystem services, individual contributions are sideration of possible enforcement mechanisms when such
pooled and invested in projects that deliver a bundle of payments are used in PES design. Large, non-refundable,
services. One key advantage of this collective approach is up-front benefits or payments do not create strong
lower transaction costs compared with those for financing incentives for long-term service provision (Wunder, 2005)
various individual PES projects. Joint decision making can as even with a contract there are no credible penalties for
lead to conservation projects that yield a range of benefits. violations. For example, as mentioned earlier, water funds
Furthermore, by pooling the contributions of several users, may help diversify family incomes or reduce expenditures
water funds can implement ecosystem service projects on a by providing supplies and training to plant organic

© 2012 Fauna & Flora International, Oryx, 46(1), 55–63

https://doi.org/10.1017/S0030605311001050 Published online by Cambridge University Press


Water funds and PES 61

backyard gardens or to rear guinea pigs. The benefits are conservation. Nevertheless, despite the fact that they are PES
multiple: food security is increased, resources formerly models, water funds do not exhibit all PES best practices
spent on obtaining meat and vegetables can be used and, therefore, despite certain advantages, they would not
elsewhere and nutrition can improve. But what options even be evaluated for potential funding if that funding were
does the water fund have if a family later removes the fund- based only on the theoretical PES ideal. Although a trust
sponsored fence and again allows its cows to enter the river? fund violates conditionality (the direct connection between
Ripping up the organic garden or taking back the guinea the ecosystem service user and the service provider) the
pigs surely would not be morally defensible sanctions for model offers an important approach for achieving long-
contract violations. term, stable financing for projects that reduce negative
Payment in the form of educational infrastructure environmental externalities in contexts where cash pay-
provides another example. No organization is going to ments are not feasible or institutional complexity or con-
tear down a school it helped to finance (Wunder, 2005) or to straints make strict conditionality impractical or too costly.
stop teaching children because one child’s family is not in As such, the fund model is an important PES approach that
compliance with the PES project. Beyond blacklisting the enlarges the set of contexts in which PES solutions can
family or community for future PES programmes, there are be applied. Likewise, although there is currently not a
no obvious means of promoting compliance with PES strong focus on additionality in water funds, attempts
contracts. In other words, how do water funds stop paying to incorporate narrowly defined additionality criteria to
families when they are not paying them directly in the first improve the economic efficiency of water funds may in fact
place? This problem is faced by any programme that be counterproductive unless the effects of social diffusion
includes up-front payments of any kind, not just water are adequately incorporated into the analysis. Finally, the
funds. There is no question that enforcement is necessary funds’ public–private, multi-stakeholder decision-making
but, as Wunder (2005) discusses and as practical experience mechanism inevitably leads to side objectives but this
demonstrates, such issues are not easily resolved. structure facilitates cross-collaboration, transparent govern-
Thus, if up-front or in-kind payments are the only option ance, information exchange and learning, and ensures that
(if service buyers want to make in-kind payments only, if conservation investments target outputs that are collectively
service sellers prefer alternatives to cash, or if government considered desirable.
restrictions do not allow cash payments) ensuring enforce- While the challenge to improve the long-term compli-
ment is a challenge. We see this as a valuable new field of ance with contractual agreements for service supply re-
research and inquiry, with the opportunity to learn from mains, water funds have engaged new stakeholders in
projects that have used these forms of payments. One conservation efforts, invested in environmental education
possibility may be to launch all conservation activities for both rural and urban children, conserved some of the
communally. In Bogotá, for example, the major water utility most diverse ecosystems, and created a model for financially
(Empresa de Acueducto y Alcantarillado de Bogotá) has sustainable conservation. In some ways it is the flexibility of
been working on community conservation projects for a the water fund model that allows it to succeed in different
number of years. As in projects soon to be launched by the institutional contexts. Impact measures to ensure water
Bogotá water fund, families engage in conservation activities funds are delivering on their promised objectives are
such as fencing areas around rivers. To encourage com- currently being developed and implemented.
munal enforcement members of participating households
erect the fences together on all participants’ properties (in Acknowledgements
this case it is often a group of women). Any family that tries
to renege on contract requirements, for example by putting We would like to thank all of our partners throughout the
their fence closer to the river than stipulated in the PES Latin American region. Without them there would be no
contract, faces intense peer pressure that, thus far, has water funds. We also would like to thank Karin Krchnak for
virtually ensured compliance. Mechanisms that enhance the helpful comments and revisions and numerous other staff
success of community-level enforcement should be studied throughout The Nature Conservancy for fruitful discussions
and better understood because evidence, for now, is largely and support, helping us to refine our research and our
anecdotal. questions, and two anonymous reviewers whose comments
greatly strengthened this article.

Conclusion References
The water fund PES model has been replicated, has catalysed A S Q U I T H , N. & W U N D E R , S. (eds) (2008) Payments for Watershed
conservation actions and pooled investments to bring them Services: The Bellagio Conversations. Fundación Natura Bolivia,
up to scale, and has engaged new stakeholders in financing Santa Cruz de la Sierra, Bolivia.

© 2012 Fauna & Flora International, Oryx, 46(1), 55–63

https://doi.org/10.1017/S0030605311001050 Published online by Cambridge University Press


62 R. L Goldman-Benner et al.

A T K I S S O N , A. (1999) Believing Cassandra: An Optimist Looks at a K O E L L N E R , T., S E L L , J. & N AVA R R O , G. (2010) Why and how much are
Pessimist’s World. Chapter 9 – The Innovation Diffusion Game. firms willing to invest in ecosystem services from tropical forests? A
Chelsea Green Publishing Company, Vermont, USA. comparison of international and Costa Rican firms. Ecological
B O U C H E R , T. (in press) A Terrestial Ecological Impact Assessment of Economics, 69, 2127–2139.
the Quito Waterfund. The Nature Conservancy, Arlington, USA. L A N D E L L -M I L L S , N. & P O R R A S , I. (2002) Silver Bullet or Fools’ Gold? A
B U Y T A E R T , W., C E L L E R I , R., D E B I È V R E , B., C I S N E R O S , G.W., Global Review of Markets for Forest Environmental Services and their
D E C K E R S , J. & H O F S T E D E , R. (2006) Human impact on Impact on the Poor. International Institute for Environment and
the hydrology of the Andean páramos. Earth-Science Reviews, 79, Development, London, UK.
53–72. P A G I O L A , S., L A N D E L L -M I L L S , N. & B I S H O P , J. (2002) Making
B U Y T A E R T , W., I Ñ I G U E Z , V. & D E B I È V R E , B. (2007) The effects of market-based mechanisms work for forests and people. In Selling
afforestation and cultivation on water yield in the Andean páramo. Forest Environmental Services: Market-based Mechanisms for
Forest Ecology and Management, 251, 22–30. Conservation (eds S. Pagiola, J. Bishop & N. Landell-Mills),
B U Y T A E R T , W., W Y S E U R E , B., D E B I È V R E , B. & D E C K E R S , J. (2005) pp. 261–289. Earthscan, London, UK.
The effects of land-use changes on the hydrological behaviour of P A G I O L A , S., R A M I R E Z , E., G O B B I , J., D E H A A N , C., I B R A H I M , M.,
Histic Andosols in south Ecuador. Hydrological Processes, 19, M U R G U E I T I O , E. & R U I Z , J.P. (2007) Paying for the environmental
3985–3997. services of silvopastoral practices in Nicaragua. Ecological
CIFOR (C E N T E R F O R I N T E R N AT I O N A L F O R E S T R Y R E S E A R C H ) Economics, 64, 374–385.
(2006) What are “payments for environmental services”? Http:// P A G I O L A , S., R I O S , A. & A R C E N A S , A. (2008) Can the poor participate
www.cifor.org/pes/_ref/about/index.htm [accessed 7 September in payments for environmental services? Lessons from the
2011]. silvopastoral project in Nicaragua. Environment and Development
D A I LY , G. (1997) Nature’s Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Economics, 13, 299–325.
Ecosystems. Island Press, Washington, DC, USA. P O R R A S , I., G R E I G -G R A N , M. & N E V E S , N. (2008) All that Glitters: A
D A N I E L S , A.E., B A G S T A D , K., E S P O S I T O , V., M O U L A E R T , A. & Review of Payments for Watershed Services in Developing Countries.
R O D R I G U E Z , C.M. (2010) Understanding the impacts of Costa Rica’s Natural Resource Issues No. 11. International Institute for
PES: are we asking the right questions? Ecological Economics, 69, Environment and Development, London, UK.
2116–2126. R E Y N O L D S , T.W., F A R L E Y , F. & H U B E R , C. (2010) Investing in human
D I L L A H A , T., F E R R A R O , P., H U A N G , M., S O U T H G AT E , D., and natural capital: An alternative paradigm for sustainable
U P A D H Y A Y A , S. & W U N D E R , S. (2007) Payments for Watershed development in Awassa, Ethiopia. Ecological Economics, 69,
Services: Regional Syntheses. USAID PES Brief 7, Washington, DC, 2140–2150.
USA. S O M M E R V I L L E , M.M., J O N E S , J.P.G. & M I L N E R -G U L L A N D , E.J. (2009)
E N G E L , S., P A G I O L A , S. & W U N D E R , S. (2008) Designing payments for A revised conceptual framework for payments for environmental
environmental services in theory and practice: an overview of the services. Ecology and Society, 14, 34–47.
issues. Ecological Economics, 65, 663–674. S O U T H G AT E , D. & W U N D E R , S. (2007) Paying for Watershed Services
F A R L E Y , J. & C O S T A N Z A , R. (2010) Payments for ecosystem services: in Latin America: A Review of Current Initiatives. Working paper
from local to global. Ecological Economics, 69, 2060–2068. No. 07-07. USAID, Washington, DC, USA.
F E R R A R O , P.J. & P AT TA N AY A K , S. (2006) Money for nothing? A call S TA N T O N , T., E C H AVA R R I A , M., H A M I LT O N , K. & O T T , C. (2010) State
for empirical evaluation of biodiversity conservation investments. of Watershed Payments: An Emerging Marketplace. Ecosystem
PLoS Biology, 4, e105. Marketplace. Http://www.foresttrends.org/documents/files/
F O R E S T T R E N D S , T H E K AT O O M B A G R O U P & UNEP (U N I T E D doc_2438.pdf [accessed 2 September 2011].
N AT I O N S E N V I R O N M E N T P R O G R A M M E ) (2008) Payments for T A L L I S , H., G O L D M A N , R., U H L , M. & B R O S I , B. (2009) Integrating
Ecosystem Services Getting Started: A Primer. Forest Trends and The conservation and development in the field: implementing
Katoomba Group. Http://www.katoombagroup.org/documents/ ecosystem services projects. Frontiers in Ecology and the
publications/GettingStarted.pdf [accessed 7 September 2011]. Environment, 7, 12–20.
F U N D AC I Ó N N AT U R A (2010) Fundación Natura Bolivia y Fondo de W U N D E R , S. (2005) Payments for Environmental Services: Some Nuts
Agua para Santa Cruz (FONACRUZ), Ganadores del Premio and Bolts. Occasional paper. CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia.
Internacional ReSource 2010 por el manejo sostenible de cuencas W U N D E R , S. (2006) Are direct payments for environmental services
hidrograficas del Parque Nacional Amboro. Naturalia, El boletin de spelling doom for sustainable forest management in the tropics?
Fundacion Natura Bolivia, Santa Cruz, Bolivia. Ecology and Society, 11, 23–34.
G O L D M A N , R.L., B E N I T E Z , S., C A LVA C H E , A. & R A M O S , A. (2010) W U N D E R , S. (2007) The efficiency of payments for
Water Funds: Protecting Watersheds for Nature and People. The environmental services in tropical conservation. Conservation
Nature Conservancy, Arlington, USA. Biology, 21, 48–58.
G O L D M A N , R.L. & T A L L I S , H. (2009) A critical analysis of ecosystem W U N D E R , S. & A L B A N , M. (2008) Decentralized payments for
services as a tool in conservation projects: the possible perils, the environmental services: the cases of Pimampiro and PROFAFOR in
promises, and the partnerships. In The Year in Ecology and Ecuador. Ecological Economics, 65, 685–698.
Conservation Biology (eds R.S. Ostfeld & W.H. Schlesinger), W U N D E R , S., W E R T Z -K A N O U N N I KO F F , S. & F E R R A R O , P. (2010)
pp. 63–78. Wiley-Blackwell Publishing, Massachusetts, USA. Payments for Environmental Services and the Global Environment
G O L D M A N , R.L., T A L L I S , H., K A R E I VA , P. & D A I LY , G.C. (2008) Field Facility: A STAP Advisory Document. UNON Publishing Services
evidence that ecosystem service projects support biodiversity and Section, Nairobi, Kenya. Http://www.unep.org/stap/LinkClick.aspx?
diversify options. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of fileticket=N1-tMo87PkA%3d&tabid=2912&language=en-US
the United States of America, 105, 9445–9448. [accessed 2 September 2011].
J AC K , B.K., K O U S K Y , C. & S I M S , K.R.E. (2008) Designing payments for W Ü N S C H E R , T., E N G E L , S. & W U N D E R , S. (2008) Spatial
ecosystem services: lessons from previous experience with targeting of payments for environmental services: a tool
incentive-based mechanisms. Proceedings of the National Academy for boosting conservation benefits. Ecological Economics, 65,
of Sciences of the United States of America, 105, 9465–9470. 822–833.

© 2012 Fauna & Flora International, Oryx, 46(1), 55–63

https://doi.org/10.1017/S0030605311001050 Published online by Cambridge University Press


Water funds and PES 63

Y AT E S , S.M. & A R O N S O N , E. (1983) A social psychological perspective work applies remote sensing data and spatial analyses to a wide
on energy conservation in residential buildings. American range of conservation issues. A L E J A N D R O C A L V A C H E works on the
Psychologist, 38, 435–444. creation and strengthening of financial mechanisms for the provision
of ecosystem services at the watershed scale. G R E T C H E N C . D A I L Y
does research that strives to incorporate environmental issues into
business practice and public policy. P E T E R K A R E I V A studies and tests
Biographical sketches conservation outcomes to deliver credible tools that allow routine
consideration of nature’s assets in decision-making. T I M M
R E B E C C A L . G O L D M A N - B E N N E R researches the links between K R O E G E R ’ s research focuses on the application of economic
ecosystem service provision, biodiversity conservation, climate change, valuation, economic analyses of conservation and environmental
poverty alleviation and the enhancement of human well-being. S I L V I A quality projects, and evaluation of economic incentives for conser-
B E N I T E Z works in natural resources management and biodiversity vation. A U R E L I O R A M O S works on designing innovative, incentive-
conservation and conservation planning. T I M O T H Y B O U C H E R ’ s based conservation financing to improve conservation practice.

© 2012 Fauna & Flora International, Oryx, 46(1), 55–63

https://doi.org/10.1017/S0030605311001050 Published online by Cambridge University Press

You might also like