Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 19

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance

S P R I N G 19 9 3 V O L U M E 6. 1

The Evolution of Buyout Pricing and Financial Structure


(Or, What Went Wrong) in the 1980s
by Steven N. Kaplan,
University of Chicago, and
Jeremy C. Stein,
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
THE EVOLUTION OF by Steven N. Kaplan,
University of Chicago, and
BUYOUT PRICING AND Jeremy C. Stein,
FINANCIAL STRUCTURE Massachusetts Institute of Technology*

(OR, WHAT WENT


WRONG) IN THE 1980s

he leveraged buyout boom of the late


T 1980s has given way to the buyout bust
of the early 1990s. After rising from less
than $1 billion in 1980 to a peak of more
than $60 billion in 1988, buyout volume fell dramati-
cally, to less than $4 billion in 1990 and to under $1
billion in 1991.
How does one make sense of this enormous
rise and abrupt fall? According to a wide range of
observers, from financiers to journalists, the story is
a straightforward one, albeit one that does not fit
comfortably with traditional notions of efficient
markets. Simply put, the buyout market over-
heated—the success of early deals attracted a large
inflow of new money and, by the late 1980s, too
much financing was chasing too few good deals.
The end result was that many transactions were
overpriced, recklessly structured, or both. In this
view, the decline in buyout volume since 1989
represents a warranted market correction.
Many statements of the “overheated buyout
market hypothesis” point directly to the widespread
use in later deals of publicly issued, subordinated
debt—that is, “junk bonds”—as an important factor.
Forbes quoted one buyout specialist as saying: “It
was so much easier to go to the public markets. It
was cheaper, and there were very few covenants...
It was fantasy.” The Forbes article went on to say, “As
long as the junk bond market existed, smart money
was able to raise dumb money from passive inves-
tors—money that would accept high risks for skimpy
rewards.”1

*This is a shorter, less technical version of an article originally published in


Quarterly Journal of Economics (May, 1993).
1. R. Smith, “The Takeover Game Isn’t Dead, It’s Just Gone Private,” Forbes,
October 1, 1990, 63.

72
JOURNAL
JOURNAL OFOF APPLIED
APPLIED CORPORATE
CORPORATE FINANCE
FINANCE
With the benefit of hindsight, there appears to provide useful information about the likelihood that
be some support for this “overheating” hypothesis. a company will fail to meet its contractual obliga-
We recently completed a study of 124 large manage- tions, they have less to say about the attendant costs
ment buyouts (MBOs) executed between 1980 and of default. In principle, very low coverage need not
1989. Of the 41 deals in our sample put together impose large costs as long as the debt is structured
between 1980 and 1984, only one defaulted on its in such a way as to lead to speedy, low-cost
debt—a default rate of just over two percent. In stark renegotiation. For this reason, we focus not just on
contrast, 22 of 83 deals completed between 1985 and the absolute magnitude of the debt burden, but also
1989 had defaulted as of August 1991—a rate of on the contractual features of the debt—seniority,
almost 27%. Nine of these defaulted transactions had maturity, and the division between public and
landed in bankruptcy court by that time. (Since private lenders.
August 1991, four more of the later buyouts have The third and final category of data we looked
defaulted and nine more have filed for bankruptcy.) at concerns the incentives of buyout investors. One
Of course, hindsight is always 20/20, and the of the supposed spurs to improved performance in
poor outcomes in the later deals may have been at buyouts is the increased equity stake of manage-
least partly the product of subsequent develop- ment; managers who own a large percentage of
ments, rather than poor deal pricing or structuring. post-buyout equity might be expected to do a better
Such developments could have included adverse job. On the other hand, managers who “cash out” a
macroeconomic conditions as well as regulatory large fraction of their pre-buyout equity holdings at
actions that made it more difficult and costly to the time of the deal may have more of an incentive
restructure troubled buyouts.2 The primary aim of to take part in an overpriced or poorly structured
our study of MBOs was to determine whether there transaction. A similar argument can be made when
were indeed important differences ex ante between large upfront fees are paid to other interested
the deals done in the latter part of the decade and parties. We examined whether these types of incen-
those done earlier. In other words, are there reasons tives changed over time.
to believe the later deals were the product of an Our study documented a large number of
overheated market and, thus, more likely to run into changes in the buyouts of the late 1980s relative to
difficulties, or should any such difficulties instead be those done earlier:
attributed largely to bad luck? Buyout price to cashflow ratios rose, though not
Our study focused on three broad categories of more sharply than market- or industry-wide ratios;
data that bear on the overheating hypothesis. The Prices were particularly high in deals financed
first relates to the overall prices paid to take with junk bonds;
companies private. Regardless of the details of the As prices rose, buyouts were undertaken in
capital structure, or the extent to which there are riskier industries, and with somewhat higher le-
costs of financial distress, it is clear that investors will verage ratios;
earn lower returns as the prices paid increase Banks took smaller positions in later deals and, at
relative to the fundamental value of company assets. the same time, accelerated required principal repay-
The second category of data we examined ments, leading to sharply lower ratios of cash flow
pertains to buyout capital structure. Even if the price to total debt obligations;
paid to take a company private is a reasonable Public junk debt displaced both private subordi-
multiple of cash flow, a poorly designed capital nated debt and the associated practice of “strip”
structure raises the probability and costs of financial financing (in which subordinated debtholders also
distress, thereby lowering the prospective returns to receive equity stakes), thereby raising the expected
some classes of investors. In evaluating this possibil- costs of financial reorganization;
ity, we went beyond relying just on aggregate Finally, management and other interested parties
measures of leverage such as interest coverage and such as investment bankers and deal promoters took
debt-to-capital ratios. While these measures can out more money up front in the later deals.

2. See Michael Jensen, “Corporate Control and the Politics of Finance, Journal such overheating were greatly exacerbated by regulatory obstacles to financial
of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 4 No. 2 (Summer 1991). Jensen subscribes to reorganization.
the view of an overheated buyout market, but then goes to argue that the costs of

73
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1993
TABLE 1 (3) (4) (5)
PRICING (1) (2) Net Cash Flow EBITDA Market (6)
Number Capital to Capital to Capital E/P ratio Premium
Year of MBOs ($ Millions) (as %) (as %) (as %) (as %)

1980-81 6 397.3 8.85 16.30 11.25 51.1


1982 8 164.2 13.27 17.18 13.24 64.8
1983 10 392.3 7.10 13.54 8.07 34.4
1984 17 383.4 7.85 14.34 9.86 40.8
1985 12 923.3 8.39 12.98 8.53 25.7
1986 15 371.1 7.54 13.48 6.01 38.7
1987 20 439.0 4.48 10.81 5.03 41.2
1988 31 476.7 7.27 11.48 6.93 48.1
1989 5 315.5 9.16 13.32 7.86 56.7

Total 124 395.4 7.56 12.75 7.65 43.0

N Obs. 124 120 124 124 122

Time Trend
(+) (–)** (–)*** (–)*** (+)
1980-82 vs. 1983-85
(+)* (–)** (–)*** (–)*** (–)***
1983-85 vs. 1986-89
(+) (–)** (–)*** (–)*** (+)**

*** Medians significantly different over time or in comparison periods at 1 percent level; ** at 5 percent level; and * at 10 percent
level.

THE SAMPLE 2), that trend was not statistically significant over the
entire period.
Our sample of buyouts was taken from compa- For each MBO in our sample, we gathered
nies listed either as leveraged buyouts or as acqui- information describing the transactions from proxy,
sitions by private companies in Securities Data 10-K, 13-E and 14-D statements, and the Wall Street
Corporation’s merger database, Morgan Stanley’s Journal, and collected post-transaction data from
merger database, and W.T. Grimm’s Mergerstat the COMPUSTAT Tapes. We also attempted to
Review from 1980 to 1989. We restricted this sample determine the extent of post-buyout financial dis-
to large management buyouts (those with transac- tress by searching the NEXIS database for the buyout
tion value greater than $100 million) in which at least companies and by reading post-buyout financial
one member of the incumbent management team statements. Post-buyout financial statements and
obtained an equity interest in the new private firm. other data were available for 89 of the 124 MBOs.
We focused on MBOs because pre-transaction data
for these transactions are generally more readily BUYOUT PRICING
available and more complete.
We found 124 buyouts completed between The first question we asked was, How did
1980 and 1989 that satisfied these criteria. As shown buyout prices vary over time relative to fundamen-
in Column 1 of Table 1, the number of such large tals? We measured the buyout price (which we also
MBOs increased steadily (with the exception of refer to as “total capital”) as the sum of (1) the market
1985) throughout the ’80s, and then fell off sharply value paid for the firm’s equity; (2) the value of the
after 1988. The median buyout in our sample had firm’s outstanding debt; and (3) the fees paid in the
total capital of $395 million; and although there is a transaction; minus (4) any cash removed from the
trend toward increasing size over time (see Column firm to finance the buyout.

74
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Of the 41 deals in our sample put together between 1980 and 1984, only one
defaulted on its debt—a default rate of just over two percent. In stark contrast, 22 of
83 deals completed between 1985 and 1989 had defaulted as of August 1991—a rate
of almost 27%.

Cash Flow to Price Ratios Over Time pricing phenomenon. Premiums showed no signifi-
cant trend during the 1980s.
We considered buyout prices in relation to two In sum, the time series data presented in this
primary measures of operating cash flow. The first section provide somewhat mixed support for the
was earnings before interest, depreciation, amorti- overheating hypothesis. Although buyout prices
zation, and taxes (EBITDA). EBITDA is a measure of increased over the decade, this increase was not
gross cash generated from operations, and thus specific to the buyout market; it was evident in the
represents an upper bound on the cash available to broader stock market as well. This is not, how-
pay investors. The second measure, net cash flow, ever, our final word on buyout pricing. We later
equals EBITDA less capital expenditures. discuss how such pricing was affected by other
The ratios of both net cash flow and EBITDA to variables in the buyouts, especially the use of junk
capital declined significantly over time, exhibiting a bond financing.
pattern (see Columns 3 and 4) broadly consistent
with the popular notion that buyout prices rose AGGREGATE DEBT BURDENS AND THE
relative to fundamentals in the 1980s. Furthermore, RISKINESS OF BUYOUT COMPANIES
both ratios were significantly lower for late-1980s
buyouts than for mid-1980s buyouts, and signifi- Pricing is only one of several factors that can
cantly lower for mid-1980s buyouts than for early affect the ultimate success of a buyout. Even if a
1980s buyouts.3 buyout is completed at the “right” price, it may be
The decline in buyout cash flow to price ratios structured in a way that leads to higher expected
over time was not, however, a phenomenon that costs of financial distress. We now examine whether
distinguished the LBO market from other U.S. capital capital structures in later deals changed in a way that
markets. As shown in column 5, the earnings to price might have increased the ex ante likelihood and
ratio of the entire S&P 500 also fell during the 1980s, costs of financial distress.
as the general level of the stock market rose.4
The fact that buyout prices seemed to move Changes in Buyout Company Risk
largely in line with the rest of the stock market can
be interpreted in two ways. On the one hand, if we One cannot, of course, look at debt and
maintain the assumption that the stock market as a coverage ratios in a vacuum. The extent to which
whole is efficient, then the absence of a buyout- a company’s debt ratio is deemed “high” or its
market-specific pattern in prices casts a measure of coverage is deemed “tight” should depend in part
doubt on the overheating hypothesis. On the other on the underlying riskiness of its assets. Thus, we
hand, it could be argued that if we are going to started by analyzing changes in company risk over
entertain the possibility of overheating at all, it may time.
be unnatural to expect it to be completely confined Our findings are summarized in Table 2, which
to just the buyout market. presents two measures of total risk. Column 1
Another way to gauge the extent of a buyout- presents a measure of total risk calculated using
specific trend in prices is to examine the “premiums” financial data for the individual buyout compa-
paid in buyout transactions. We measured such nies—specifically, the standard deviation of the
premiums as the percentage difference between the growth rate of operating margins (where operating
price paid for a firm’s equity and the price two margin equals the ratio of EBITDA to sales) over
months before the first announcement of buyout or the ten-year period leading up the the buyout. This
takeover activity. Here again, as shown in Column 6, measure trends upward throughout the 1980s
the data provided little support for a buyout-specific (though not significantly). The late 1980s buyouts,

3. In much of the analysis in this study, we used two different methods to 4. In our original study, we also provided crude market-adjusted measures of
quantify the statistical significance of the temporal patterns in the data. First, we buyout pricing by subtracting the earnings to price ratio of the S&P 500 (for the
measured the non-parametric or rank correlation between (all individual observa- quarter in which the deal was priced) from the buyout ratios of net cash flow and
tions of) our variables and a simple annual time trend over the entire period 1980 EBITDA to capital. These market-adjusted measures did not exhibit a significant
to 1989. Second, as in the results just cited, we also used non-parametric rank tests downward trend; in fact, the trend for the net cash flow to capital ratio was even
to compare the values of the variables in three distinct periods: 1980 to 1982 (or slightly positive.
the “early 1980s”); 1983 to 1985 (or the “mid-1980s”); and 1986 to 1989 (or the “late
1980s”).

75
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1993
TABLE 2 Risk measures
RISKa
(1) (2)
Std. Deviation Fractional Change Brookings Study Estimated
Year in Operating Margin Std. Deviation Industry Earnings

1980-81 0.18 [6] 0.213 [6]


1982 0.19 [8] 0.249 [7]
1983 0.17 [10] 0.074 [9]
1984 0.13 [16] 0.249 [16]
1985 0.13 [11] 0.249 [12]
1986 0.19 [12] 0.348 [13]
1987 0.20 [17] 0.249 [18]
1988 0.18 [24] 0.249 [28]
1989 0.18 [3] 0.262 [5]
Total 0.17 [108] 0.249 [114]
Time Trend (+) (+)**
1980-82 vs. 1983-85 (–) (–)
1983-85 vs. 1986-89 (+)** (+)*

a. The two columns under each Risk Factor are the median and number of observations, respectively.
*** Medians significantly different over time or in comparison periods at 1 percent level; ** at 5 percent level; and * at 10 percent
level.

however, have significantly more risk than those in total capital, where total post-buyout debt equals the
the mid-1980s. sum of (the market value of) new debt issued to
Column 2 presents a measure of industry total finance the buyout and (the book value of) pre-
risk used by a 1990 Brookings Institute Study buyout debt retained. As shown in Column 1 of
(hereafter referred to as “the Brookings Study”)5— Table 3, the median debt to total capital ratios
namely, the standard deviation of the growth rate of increased over time. The time trend was positive and
industry real earnings. The pattern of changes in this significant, and the ratios in 1986 to 1989 (with a
industry measure throughout the ’80s was similar to median of 90.3%) were significantly larger than
that of our firm-specific measure. The risk was those in 1983 to 1985 (median 86.5%).
significantly higher for buyouts of the late 1980s than Moreover, our measure of total debt may have
for those of the mid-1980s. understated the amount of debt in the capital
In sum, our measures of total risk suggest that structure because it excluded preferred stock with
buyout companies in the late 1980s were somewhat fixed commitments. In several cases, such preferred
riskier than those in earlier years. Other things equal, stock was exchangeable into subordinated debt.
this would seem to dictate a more conservative Accordingly, we calculated yearly medians of post-
capital structure. With this observation in mind, we buyout common stock to total capital, where post-
now turn to the aggregate capital structure data. buyout common stock included preferred stock
convertible into common stock (but not straight
Aggregate Debt Burdens preferred stock or preferred stock convertible into
debt). As shown in Column 2, these common stock
For each of the 124 companies in our sample, ratios fell significantly over the ’80s, with the lowest
we calculated the ratio of total post-buyout debt to ratios (median of 5.56%) from 1986 to 1989.6

5. See B. Bernanke, J. Campbell, and T. Whited, “U.S. Corporate Leverage: classification of the late 1980s. These buyouts took place as the public junk bond
Developments in 1987 and 1988,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I (1990), market began to falter and, thus, do not necessarily fit with the overheating
255-286. hypothesis. Indeed, the few observations we have suggest that the 1989 buyouts
6. As was true of buyout pricing multiples, and will be shown to be true of were different from those of the preceding three years. Nevertheless, eliminating
coverage ratios later, the equity ratios became more conservative in 1989, thus 1989 buyouts from the late 1980s sample has no effect on our statistical results.
suggesting a turning point. Arguably, the 1989 deals do not belong in our

76
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Consistent with the lower cash flow to price ratios and rising leverage ratios, we
found a negative time trend for both interest coverage measures, with both net cash
flow and EBITDA to interest reaching a minimum in 1987 and 1988.

TABLE 3
AGGREGATE DEBT AND COVERAGE RATIOSa

(1) (7) (8) (9)


Post- (2) (5) Req’d Debt Net Cash EBITDA to
Buyout Common (3) (4) Net Cash (6) Repay in 2 Flow to [Cash [Cash
Debt to Stock to Net Cash EBITDA Flow EBITDA Years to Interest + Interest +
Capital Capital Flow to to to Cash to Cash EBITDA (Repay in 2 (Repay in 2
Year (as %) (as %) Interest Interest Interest Interest (as %) Yrs)/2] Yrs)/2]

1980-81 88.3 10.53 0.56 1.15 0.56 1.15 0.0 0.56 1.15
6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 6
1982 87.3 6.67 0.90 1.28 0.90 1.28 0.0 0.75 1.16
8 8 8 8 8 8 6 5 6
1983 87.2 11.54 0.67 1.26 0.67 1.2 22.3 0.69 1.18
10 10 10 10 10 10 7 7 7
1984 88.7 7.91 0.74 1.29 0.74 1.29 32.3 0.66 1.12
17 17 17 17 17 17 11 11 11
1985 86.0 7.03 0.75 1.22 0.82 1.30 59.2 0.59 1.09
12 12 12 12 12 12 11 11 11
1986 90.7 5.60 0.73 1.50 0.73 1.75 160.0 0.36 0.72
15 15 13 15 13 15 10 8 10
1987 88.9 4.04 0.43 1.12 0.52 1.27 103.5 0.21 0.76
20 20 19 20 19 20 14 14 14
1988 90.5 6.13 0.60 1.11 0.70 1.16 103.5 0.41 0.66
31 31 30 31 30 31 21 20 21
1989 83.2 13.20 0.83 1.27 0.83 1.27 43.3 0.62 0.89
5 5 5 5 5 5 4 4 4
Total 89.1 6.52 0.68 1.20 0.74 1.27 60.0 0.46 0.89
124 124 120 124 120 124 90 85 90
Time Trend
(+)** (–)* (–) (–)* (–) (–) (+)*** (–)** (–)***
1980-82 v. 1983-85
(–) (+) (–) (–) (+) (+) (+)*** (–) (–)
1983-85 v. 1986-89
(+)*** (–)*** (–) (–) (–) (–) (+)*** (–)*** (–)***

a. The two rows in each cell are the median and number of observations, respectively.
*** Medians significantly different over time or in comparison periods at 1 percent level; ** at 5 percent level; and * at 10 percent level.

The increase in debt ratios and the decline in adequacy of current cash flows relative to contrac-
equity ratios are interesting and somewhat puzzling tual obligations. These measures use net cash flow
aspects of buyout financial structures. The higher and EBITDA in the last full year before the buyout.
prices paid relative to cash flows in late 1980s We calculated expected interest payments based on
buyouts, even if perfectly rational, would appear to the interest rates and debt amounts projected in the
suggest that these buyouts were associated with proxy or 14D statements describing the buyouts.
more optimistic growth expectations than earlier Columns 3 and 4 compare net cash flow and
ones. But if the later deals were associated with EBITDA to expected total interest payments in the
expected cash flows that were more “back-loaded” first post-buyout year. Consistent with the lower
in time (as well as somewhat riskier), one might have cash flow to price ratios and rising leverage ratios,
expected them to be structured with less debt we found a negative time trend for both interest
relative to total value. coverage measures, with both net cash flow and
To explore this issue further, the remaining EBITDA to interest reaching a minimum in 1987
columns of Table 3 present several measures of the and 1988.

77
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1993
The ratios in Columns 3 and 4 use total interest of operating cash flows. For example, a buyout with
obligations, which include both cash and non-cash the 1988 median ratio of 0.41—the highest median
interest. Non-cash interest is associated with de- of the 1986 to 1988 period—would have needed to
ferred interest debt, which includes zero-coupon increase net cash flow by 144% (0.59/0.41) in its first
and pay-in-kind (PIK) bonds. Including non-cash year to meet its debt obligations.7
interest payments may present a misleading picture These coverage numbers, however, present
because the use of such payments (as we point out only part of the overall picture on financial sound-
later) increased significantly in the second half of the ness. In many of the later buyouts, asset sales may
1980s. In fact, they may have been introduced have represented an alternative means of generating
precisely to allow firms with more “back-loaded” the cash to make debt-related payments.8 And even
cash flows to support high levels of debt. if planned asset sales failed to materialize, and
To test for this possibility we repeated our required payments could not be met, this would not
coverage calculations using cash interest payments necessarily have meant disaster. The costs at this
that excluded interest payments on deferred interest point would have depended critically on the ability
debt. As expected, this adjustment improved the of creditors to restructure their claims efficiently.
relative standing of the coverage ratios of the later In sum, then, the data in this section strongly
deals (see Columns 5 and 6). suggest that the buyouts of the late 1980s had a
Although interest coverage is an often-used higher ex ante probability of winding up in a
measure of financial soundness, it does not fully restructuring situation, particularly if planned asset
capture a firm’s ability to meet all its debt-related sales were subject to some uncertainty. The data
obligations. Cash flow must also be devoted to have thus far had less to say about the possible costs
making principal repayments. Ninety of the 124 of such restructurings.
transactions in our sample reported a principal
repayment schedule for their bank debt. As shown SENIOR BANK DEBT AND
in Column 7, the ratio of required debt payments THE ROLE OF ASSET SALES
(including principal repayments) for these 90 buyouts
rose sharply over time, with an pronounced break We now focus our attention on specific compo-
between 1985 and 1986, when principal repayments nents of buyout capital structures. The most senior
increased by a factor of more than 2.7. part of the capital structure for most of our MBOs
We next repeated our coverage calculations, was a term loan (and, often, an accompanying
this time considering how net cash flow and EBITDA revolving credit loan) arranged by one or more
compared to total cash debt obligations (including commercial banks. As we already have seen, banks
principal). As shown in Columns 8 and 9, these accelerated required principal payments over time.
coverages were substantially lower for 1986-1989 As shown in the Column 1 of Table 4, the ratio
buyouts than for earlier deals. For example, the of bank debt to total debt declined significantly over
median ratio of EBITDA to cash obligations was time, with a distinct break in 1985. Bank debt
always above one before 1986, but fell to between represented over 70% of total debt in the period 1982
0.76 and 0.66 for the 1986-88 period before recov- to 1984. In 1985, it dropped to 42% of all debt. After
ering somewhat to 0.89 in 1989. Similarly, the that, the ratio stabilized, ranging between 52% and
median ratio of net cash flow to cash obligations, 57% from 1986 to 1989. As we discuss in more detail
which was always above 0.56 before 1986, did not later, this decline in bank debt ratios coincided with
exceed 0.41 from 1986 to 1988. Again, the ratio increasing use of public bonds in the subordinated
recovered in 1989, rising to 0.62. debt tier of the capital structure.
This change in the coverage ratios after 1985 We next examined the interest rate terms of the
implies a sharp deterioration in the ability of buyout bank loans, in part to provide a measure of banks’
firms to meet their total debt-related obligations out assessments of the riskiness of buyouts. In most of

7. Given that Kaplan’s study found a roughly 40% increase in net cash flow 8. See A. Shleifer and R. Vishny, “Asset Sales and Debt Capacity,” Journal of
for a sample of management buyouts announced between 1979 and 1985, it is hard Finance, XLVII (1992).
to see how operating cash flows could be expected to meet required debt service
payments. See S. Kaplan, “The Effects of Management Buyouts on Operations and
Value,” Journal of Financial Economics, XXIV (1989), 217-254.

78
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
The ratio of bank debt to total debt declined significantly over time, with a distinct
break in 1985. Bank debt represented over 70% of total debt in the period 1982 to
1984, but dropped to 42% in 1985. This decline in bank debt ratios coincided with
increasing use of public bonds in the subordinated debt tier of the capital structure.

TABLE 4 (1) (2) (4) (5) (6)


BANK DEBTa Bank Bank (3) Fee-adjusted Asset Asset Sale
Debt Interest Bank Fees Bank Interest Sales Amount as %
to Total Rate versus to Bank Rate versus (% of of Capital (if
Year Debt Prime Debt Prime Deals) Asset Sale)

1980-81 39.0 0.75 0.21 N/A 50.0 15.5


6 5 1 0 6 3
1982 72.9 1.25 1.28 1.31 0.0 N/A
8 7 5 5 8 0
1983 75.7 1.38 0.40 1.44 33.3 21.1
10 8 8 8 9 3
1984 72.0 1.44 0.79 1.59 18.8 23.2
17 16 14 13 16 3
1985 42.0 1.50 1.94 2.13 33.3 14.2
12 11 7 7 12 4
1986 52.0 1.50 2.06 2.21 60.0 19.3
15 13 13 12 15 8
1987 54.3 1.50 2.06 2.13 40.0 22.4
19 17 15 15 20 8
1988 55.3 1.50 2.49 2.24 32.3 14.8
29 27 22 22 31 10
1989 57.1 1.50 2.38 1.98 20.0 11.4
5 5 4 3 5 1
Total 56.4 1.50 1.93 2.12 33.6 18.1
121 109 89 85 122 40
Time Trend
(–)** (+)*** (+)*** (+)*** (+) (–)
1980-82 vs. 1983-85
(–) (+) (–) (+) (+) (–)
1983-85 vs. 1986-89
(–)* (+)*** (+)*** (+)*** (+) (–)

a. The two rows in each cell are the median and number of observations, respectively.
*** Medians significantly different over time or in comparison periods at 1 percent level; ** at 5 percent level; and * at 10 percent
level.

the deals, the interest rate on the bank debt was set capital structure on all of them, one might expect a
as the minimum of a spread over the prime rate or great deal of variation in the riskiness of the debt
a spread over LIBOR. As shown in Column 2, and, hence, a good deal of variation in its pricing.
although the spreads over prime trended slightly One explanation for the lack of variation in
upward over time (the median values of the prime- loan pricing is that banks adjusted their fees over
based spreads were 1.125%, 1.50%, and 1.50% in the time. As shown in Column 3, the median fee was
early, middle, and late 1980s), they nevertheless 0.78% through 1984, and rose thereafter to a peak
seem to have been remarkably stable. of 2.49% in 1988. Since the increased fee income
The relative lack of variation in spreads showed may have been viewed as the economic equiva-
up in other tests we ran as well. For example, when lent of higher interest rates, we calculated a fee-
we pooled all deals between 1984 and 1989, we adjusted interest rate and a corresponding fee-
found that 58 of 89 buyouts had prime-based adjusted spread to the reference rate. As reported
spreads of 1.50%. The highest spread was 2%, the in Column 4, the fee-adjusted spreads over prime
lowest 1%. This uniformity in loan pricing seems rate jumped from 1.59% in 1984 to 2.13% in 1985,
puzzling. If we take a heterogeneous group of and remained between 1.98% and 2.24% from
companies and impose a similar highly leveraged 1985 to 1989. This finding is consistent with banks’

79
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1993
expectations that later buyouts were more likely asset sales were associated with ratios of net cash
to get into financial trouble.9 flow and EBITDA to debt obligations that were
Focusing on interest rate spreads also ignores roughly 0.25 lower than buyouts without expected
a potentially important set of “non-price terms of asset sales (that is, coverages were substantially
credit,” such as collateral and covenants, that bank- tighter in buyouts with expected asset sales). A third
ers can use to adjust their risk-return tradeoff. Non- regression suggested that buyouts with asset sales had
price credit terms are particularly relevant because net cash flow to buyout price ratios that were a full
banks are the senior lenders in the buyout transac- 2% lower than buyouts without asset sales. For
tions. Given that bank debt typically equals only 50% example, a typical 1987 buyout without asset sales
of total capital, it may have been possible for banks had a net cash flow to price ratio of 5.7%, whereas one
to structure their loans to largely eliminate default with expected asset sales had a ratio of only 3.7%.
losses. If so, it would have made sense to lend at the This last finding seems especially interesting
same interest rate in all deals. because it is not obvious why plans to sell assets
We were not able to get comprehensive data on should make companies more valuable in the
collateral or covenants for the bank loans in our aggregate. The first-order effect of asset sales would
sample. As we reported earlier, however, banks seem to be to transfer value from junior to senior
both reduced the amount they loaned and required creditors, not to create new value. To see this,
more rapid principal repayments in later deals. Both consider the extreme case where an asset sale would
of these reactions are consistent with banks protect- generate enough cash to repay all the senior debt.
ing themselves in reaction to lower overall buyout In this case, the use of asset sales would make the
quality. senior debt riskless, thereby increasing its value
As noted earlier, the acceleration of repayment while shifting more risk onto the junior debt. Given
schedules may have reflected an increased reliance this possibility, it is understandable why senior bank
on asset sales. In fact, these schedules (and the lenders would be willing to lend to more aggres-
correspondingly tighter coverages) might have been sively priced deals only if they could force asset
a mechanism for forcing buyout companies to sell sales. It is not at all clear, however, why junior
assets in order to raise cash. We attempted to lenders would be willing to participate in such deals.
determine the expected role of asset sales by To summarize the results of this section: senior
examining statements of the intent to sell assets that bank lenders appear to have placed a relatively small
appeared in the buyout proxy and 14D statements. emphasis on interest rate spreads in their structuring
As shown in Column 5, asset sales were ex- of buyout loans. Rather it seems that, over time, they
pected in 21% of the pre-1983 MBOs, 27% of the (1) increased fees, (2) reduced the fraction of the total
1983-1985 MBOs, and 39% of the 1986-1989 MBOs. debt they provided; and (3) imposed more rapid
For those companies that planned to make major repayment schedules. Such repayment schedules
asset sales, the assets to be sold represented a likely could be met only by firms selling assets and
roughly constant fraction of total capital (see Col- repaying banks with the proceeds. Asset sales look to
umn 6)—at medians of 15.5, 19.8, and 18.5%— have played a somewhat more prominent role in the
during the three different periods. more aggressively priced deals.
“Cross-Sectional” Tests. Although we do not The overall picture that emerges is one of the
report the results here, we also analyzed the strength banks making “defensive” structuring adjustments
of the correlation between low coverage ratios, high in the later, higher priced buyouts. While these
buyout prices, and asset sales by running a series of adjustments may have made sense from the banks’
regressions. The results of the first two regressions senior perspective, they raise several questions:
suggested, in effect, that buyouts with expected Who and why were the junior lenders agreeing to

9. There are, however, two reasons it may be misleading to treat fees and practices. Fee income shows up in earnings in the first year of the buyout. Because
interest income as economically equivalent. First, the fees bank lenders receive are this increases both book net worth and any compensation based on earnings, it can
not always proportional to the size of their loans. Conversations with bankers have a higher shadow value to banks and bankers than an economically equivalent
indicate that the originating bank retains some fee income even when it sells most interest rate. The greater fee income in the late 1980s buyouts may thus have
of the loan. If so, the fee-adjusted spreads reported in Table 4 overstate the returns tempted bankers to make buyout loans that offered a less favorable risk-return
to banks that actually fund the loan and bear the risk. Second, banks also might tradeoff.
plausibly prefer fee income because of capital regulations and compensation

80
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Banks both reduced the amount they loaned and required more rapid principal
repayments in later deals. Both of these reactions are consistent with banks
protecting themselves in reaction to lower overall buyout quality.

TABLE 5
SUBORDINATED DEBT

(4) (6)
(1) (2) (3) Average Junk (5) Average PIK (7) (8)
Number % of Deals % of Deals and Cram % of Deals or Discount Strips Average
of with Public with Cram Down to with PIK or Debt to (% of Strip Debt to
Year MBOs Junk Debt Down Debt Capital (%) Discount Debt Capital (%) Deals) Capital (%)

1980-81 6 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 83.3 36.6


1982 8 0.0 12.5 1.2 25.0 3.0 75.0 24.5
1983 10 0.0 10.0 1.1 10.0 1.1 70.0 27.5
1984 17 5.9 23.5 5.7 11.8 2.1 47.1 17.3
1985 12 58.3 58.3 25.9 50.0 7.6 50.0 19.7
1986 15 40.0 26.7 17.5 26.7 5.6 33.3 7.4
1987 20 50.0 45.0 24.9 50.0 9.7 10.0 4.4
1988 31 61.3 38.7 22.5 61.3 8.5 29.0 12.0
1989 5 60.0 40.0 21.5 60.0 10.6 20.0 9.4
Total 124 37.1 32.3 16.1 37.9 6.1 39.5 14.8
Time Trend
(+)*** (+)** (+)*** (+)*** (+)*** (–)** (–)***
1980-82 vs. 1983-85
(+)* (+)* (+)** (+) (+) (–) (–)
1983-85 vs. 1986-89
(+)*** (+) (+)*** (+)*** (+)*** (–)*** (–)***

*** Medians significantly different over time or in comparison periods at 1 percent level; ** at 5 percent level; and * at 10 percent level.

these structuring changes? And what are the impli- debt issued by the new buyout firm as part of the
cations of these changes for the likelihood and costs payment to the pre-buyout shareholders to take the
of financial distress? company private. Because the pre-buyout shares are
widely-held, so is the cram down debt. Column 3
SUBORDINATED DEBT also shows an increased reliance on the use of “cram
down” debt, particularly after 1984.
We now turn to an examination of the subor- Moreover, the ratio of new public buyout
dinated debt in our sample transactions. In what debt—that is, combined junk and cram down
follows, we focus on non-price attributes of this debt—to total capital also rises sharply over time
debt—private placement versus public issuance, the starting in 1985. Before 1985, new public debt
use of deferred interest securities, and the use of was a small fraction of total capital; from 1985
“strip” financing techniques. and beyond, it always exceeded 17% of total
As shown in Column 2 of Table 5, the financing capital (see Column 4).10
of buyouts with publicly issued low-grade, or junk, As we noted earlier, the trend toward increased
bonds effectively began in 1985. Only one buyout use of public subordinated debt coincided with the
prior to 1985 used public junk bonds. In contrast, adjustment by banks to reduce the size of their loans.
over 54% of the subsequent buyouts used them. To provide a more direct test of the argument that
Many buyouts also issued a second type of public debt effectively displaced bank debt in later
widely-held debt as part of the buyout financing— buyouts, we ran several regressions. Although not
commonly called “cram down” debt. Cram down is reported here, the results of these tests suggest that

10. Note that these are unconditional averages, including buyouts both with
and without widely-held debt. These averages, therefore, understate the impor-
tance of public debt in those transactions which actually use it.

81
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1993
the ratio of bank debt to total debt was from 11% to In most cases of strip financing, it is the subordinated
15% lower in buyouts that relied on junk bonds than debtholders who hold the equity. However, we also
in buyouts that did not. This pronounced “crowding found several cases in which the senior lender or
out” of the bank debt by junk bonds is consistent lenders purchased equity.
with the notion that overheated junk-bond investors As shown in Columns 7 and 8, both the
were willing to bid more aggressively for buyout percentage of transactions using some form of strip
loans than were the relatively defensive bankers. financing and strip debt as a fraction of total capital
We also found strong evidence of two addi- declined over the ’80s. Over 70% of the buyouts
tional trends in subordinated debt financing. First, before 1984 used some form of strip financing. Also,
the use of deferred interest debt increased sharply the debt owned by stripholders amounted to roughly
after 1984. As shown in Column 5, such debt was 25% of the total capital in these buyouts. In contrast,
used in only 12% of pre-1985 buyouts, but in more fewer than 25% of the post-1985 buyouts used strip
than 50% of the buyouts after 1984. Similarly, financing, with strip debt worth at most 12% of total
deferred interest debt as a percentage of total capital capital in those deals.
increased as well (see Column 6), exceeding 8.5% in As in the case of deferred interest debt, the use
all years after 1986. of strip financing was related to the use of public
The increase in deferred interest on the subor- debt, although in this case the relation went the
dinated debt likely had an effect similar to that of opposite way. Over 59% (35 out of 59) of the
accelerating senior debt repayment. That is, it buyouts that did not use public debt used strip
further “juniorized” the subordinated debt, poten- financing, compared to fewer than 22% (14 of 65) of
tially transferring value to the senior bank lenders. the buyouts that did use public debt.
In buyouts that used deferred interest debt, much of In sum, the results in this section indicate that
the bank debt was scheduled to be paid off before beginning in 1985, financing from the public junk
the buyout firm began cash payments on the bond market displaced not only private subordinated
deferred interest debt. Interestingly, the deferred debt, but also to some degree senior bank debt. Junk
interest debt was disproportionately public subordi- bond financing was more likely to involve deferred
nated debt—either junk or cram down. Of the 59 interest securities, less likely to involve strips, and was
buyouts that did not use junk or cram down debt, associated with higher buyout prices.
only three issued deferred interest debt. In contrast,
deferred interest securities were present in 44 of 65 INCENTIVES
buyouts that used public debt.
The use of public subordinated debt also The third and final category of data we exam-
appeared to be related to the overall pricing of ined concerns the incentives of buyout investors.
transactions. We ran a series of regressions (the Conventional economic wisdom holds that signifi-
detailed results of which, again, are not reported cant increases in managers’ percentage equity stakes
here) that showed the use of junk debt was associ- should lead to improvements in operating perfor-
ated with a decline in both net cash flow and mance and more successful buyouts generally. But,
EBITDA to total capital ratios of 1.6%. To illustrate as we shall show, the conventional wisdom failed to
the import of this finding, our regression coefficients take into account another important change in
imply that 1988 buyouts financed without junk incentives also taking place during the 1980s.
bonds had an EBITDA to total capital ratio of 12.4%, Columns 1 and 2 of Table 6 report the median
thus representing a multiple of roughly 8X operating percentages of pre-buyout and post-buyout equity
cash flow. By contrast, for those buyouts financed (fully diluted to account for stock options) owned
with junk bonds, the implied ratio was 10.8%, or by the post-buyout management team. Before the
about 9.25X. This finding also fits with the notion buyout, the new management team owned a me-
that junk bond investors were particularly aggres- dian 5% of the equity. This percentage increased
sive bidders for buyout loans. significantly during the ’80s, peaking at more than
Finally, at the same time that the use of deferred 8% in both 1987 and 1988. After the buyout, the
interest and public subordinated debt increased, the median management equity ownership of the post-
use of strip financing declined. Strip financing is buyout company was 22.3%, a figure that also
present when lenders invest in post-buyout equity. increased significantly over time.

82
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
The larger the capital gain they are able to “cash out” relative to their new
investment, the more managers may be tempted to go along with (or even
encourage) a buyout they know to be overpriced or poorly structured.

TABLE 6 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)


INCENTIVESa Old Mgmt. New Mgmt. New % / Old % New $ / Old $ Total Fees
Year Equity (%) Equity (%) Mgmt. Equity Mgmt. Equity to Capital

1980-81 1.5 10.1 7.58 0.707 2.05


6 6 6 6 6
1982 2.0 23.1 6.79 0.958 2.66
8 8 8 8 8
1983 5.2 15.5 3.42 0.524 2.58
10 9 9 9 9
1984 4.4 27.5 3.81 0.670 2.21
17 17 17 17 17
1985 3.5 22.5 4.51 0.334 3.69
12 11 11 11 12
1986 5.1 20.8 6.28 0.314 5.06
12 13 11 11 15
1987 8.1 19.0 3.54 0.410 4.32
17 14 14 14 20
1988 8.4 28.5 2.86 0.349 5.97
25 24 22 22 31
1989 6.2 15.3 2.93 0.542 5.73
4 4 4 4 5
Total 5.0 22.3 4.14 0.460 3.81
111 106 102 102 123
Time Trend
(+)** (+)* (–) (–)* (+)***
1980-82 vs. 1983-85
(+)** (+)** (–) (–) (+)
1983-85 vs. 1986-88
(+) (+) (–) (–)* (+)***

a. The two rows in each cell are the median and number of observations, respectively.
*** Medians significantly different over time or in comparison periods at 1 percent level; ** at 5 percent level; and * at 10 percent
level.

Column 3 combines the information in Col- This cashing out could have important and
umns 1 and 2 by calculating the ratio of the potentially adverse incentive effects on the choice,
percentage of post- to pre-buyout equity owned by pricing, and structuring of deals. In particular, the
the management team. This ratio provides a mea- larger the capital gain they are able to realize at the
sure of the change in the intensity of the relationship time of the deal, the more managers may be tempted
between managerial effort and compensation. The to go along with (or even encourage) a buyout that
median ratio for the 102 buyouts with both pre- and they know to be overpriced or poorly structured. At
post-buyout information was 4.14. (The ratio trended the extreme, a manager offered a significant owner-
downward over time, but not significantly.) ship stake in post-buyout equity at no cost may find
While their large percentage stakes in post- it hard to turn down what is, in effect, a free option,
buyout equity suggest that managers will work hard even if the buyout has only a small chance of success.
to maximize shareholder value once the buyout has As shown in Column 4, the median ratio of the
been completed, the large post-buyout stakes alone dollar value of post- to pre-buyout equity owned by
do not ensure they will enter only into well-priced the management team was 0.46. This means that the
and -structured transactions. It is important to recog- management team typically invested less than half as
nize that managers typically “cash out” in dollar terms much in post-buyout equity as in pre-buyout equity.
at the time of a buyout. Although their percent-age Even more telling, however, the time trend of this
ownership of the now-levered equity increases sharply, variable over the 1980s was significantly negative,
the dollar amount invested tends to fall. with a particularly sharp drop between 1984 and

83
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1993
1985. Before 1984, the median ratio was 0.57. From Even more so than the bankers, other interested
1985 to 1989, the median ratio was 0.35. Thus, the parties were also successful in extracting upfront
temptation for management to cash out appears to money from the deals. Ostensibly well-informed
have been far greater in the buyouts of the later players such as management, buyout promoters and
1980s than in earlier ones. investment bankers were increasingly able to earn
Management investors are not the only par- compensation simply for completing a transaction,
ties driven by incentives. So are buyout promot- rather than having their fortunes ride on its eventual
ers, investment banks, and lenders. Most buyout success or failure. Thus, instead of providing a
participants were compensated with both long- system of checks and balances, these “smart money”
term security interests and upfront fees. As we participants may have been quite eager to partici-
noted earlier, banks required higher upfront fees pate, even in deals they viewed as overpriced or
in the later 1980s than they did before. And, as poorly structured.
shown in Column 5, the same pattern was true of If this junk bond/“demand push” story is cor-
total buyout-related fees. The largest portion of rect, it implies two channels through which inves-
these fees was paid to buyout promoters, invest- tor returns in later deals could have been reduced.
ment banks, and commercial banks. The ratio of The first, and more obvious, channel was pricing;
total fees to total capital made its biggest jump in all else equal, higher prices relative to fundamen-
the late 1980s. It ranged from 2.05% to 2.66% tals would mean lower returns for some categories
before 1985, rose to 3.69% in 1985, and peaked at of investors. The second channel related to costs of
5.97% in 1988. financial distress. Although expected costs of finan-
cial distress are hard to assess, many of the capital
INTERPRETING THE EVIDENCE structure changes that accompanied the inflow of
junk bond financing could be viewed as increasing
The evidence we have presented thus far can such costs.
be used to tell a detailed story of overheating in the First was the dramatic shift from privately-
buyout market, one which centers largely on the placed to widely-held subordinated debt that began
role of publicly issued junk bonds. in 1985. With widely dispersed creditors, free-rider
problems were more likely to interfere with efficient
Junk Bonds and financial reorganizations. By “free-rider,” we mean
The Overheated Buyout Market that even though it can be in the collective interest
of subordinated debtholders to contribute new
The story goes as follows: Beginning in 1985, funds for investment, any single holder may find it
junk bond investors, attracted by the success of individually rational not to do so. Adding further to
earlier deals, poured large amounts of money into this “free rider” problem was the growing bank
the buyout market. This pushed up prices in general, practice of selling off senior bank buyout loans.
and especially prices in those deals in which junk A second change that may have increased the
bonds were actually used. Other, less aggressive potential for costly financial distress was the decline
classes of lenders such as banks and private subor- of the strip financing technique common in earlier
dinated lenders reacted defensively to the “demand buyouts. When a firm is highly leveraged, conflicts
push” from the junk bond market. They reduced of interest between lenders and equityholders can
their participation in deals, and the banks in particu- lead to distorted corporate behavior such as “risk-
lar took steps such as accelerating principal repay- shifting” and underinvestment that reduces overall
ments and forcing asset sales that would effectively firm value. By reducing such conflicts, strip financ-
enhance their senior status. The junk bond investors ing arguably limits these distortions.11 If this logic is
did not prevent themselves from being “juniorized” correct, the decline of strip financing in the late
in this way. Indeed, by accepting large quantities of 1980s is puzzling, to say the least.
deferred interest securities, they further encouraged In addition to the movement towards public
the process. debt and away from strip financing, other changes

11. See M. Jensen, “The Eclipse of the Public Corporation,” Harvard Business
Review, No. 5 (1989), 61-74.

84
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
A rapidly growing asset sales market could help explain rising buyout prices in
general, to the extent some buyouts created significant portions of their value
added by relocating assets to different owners. To the extent this was so, we would
expect to see a strong correlation between buyouts premised on large asset sales
and the use of junk bonds.

in buyout debt structure may also have increased the some buyouts created significant portions of their
expected costs of financial distress. One such change value added by relocating assets to different owners.
was the “juniorizing” of the public subordinated To the extent this was so, we would expect
debt that resulted from both faster principal repay- to see a strong correlation between buyouts pre-
ments on the senior bank debt and the trend toward mised on large asset sales and the use of junk
deferred interest junk bonds. bonds. Although junk bonds would clearly have
How did these changes raise the costs of made it more difficult for a distressed firm to
reorganizing troubled companies? First of all, as recast its capital structure, the possibility of asset
with conflicts between lenders and stockholders, sales could have been viewed by the planners of
conflicts between senior bank creditors and junior the buyout as a potential, low-cost alternative to
public debtholders can also reduce the ability of financial reorganization.13
distressed companies to secure new funds. The Such a correlation between asset sales and junk
logic is as follows: Suppose a firm is in financial bonds would help explain the more aggressive
difficulty and needs an infusion of funds to make a pricing of buyouts involving junk bonds. That is, the
positive net present value investment. On the one use of junk bonds may simply be an indicator that
hand, bank lenders would seem to be the best the firm in question had a lot of easily detachable
hope for putting up the new money, since they do and marketable assets. If the potential for asset sales
not face as severe a free-rider problem as the was in itself value-increasing, this “detachability” of
widely-dispersed junior lenders. On the other hand, assets may have legitimately commanded a higher
the banks’ senior status probably reduces their buyout price. Also, to the extent junk bonds were a
incentive to invest; the banks may already be well- reliable indicator of detachable assets, it would be
protected, and may not have much upside to gain wrong to conclude that deals with junk bonds had
from further investment.12 higher expected costs of financial distress.
Now consider what happens if the bank’s It should be noted that this alternative story
principal repayments are moved forward in time. does not explain all of our empirical findings. For
This has two negative effects. First, the higher debt example, increased liquidity in the asset sales mar-
service burden raises the probability that the firm ket would not appear to offer much insight into the
will be unable to meet its contractual obligations. trend toward more front-loaded compensation for
Second, the fact that the banks extract value more managers and other interested parties.
rapidly effectively enhances their senior status rela-
tive to the subordinated debt. This further protects EX POST EVIDENCE
the banks, and may correspondingly further reduce
their incentives to contribute new money. For this While it may be impossible to resolve fully the
reason, accelerated repayment schedules may well ambiguities raised above, we made an effort in this
increase the expected costs of financial distress. direction by examining post-buyout data. The over-
heating hypothesis holds that buyouts in the later
An Alternative Interpretation 1980s were less soundly structured than earlier
deals. This suggests that later deals, even with
A different reading of our evidence—one more significant operating improvements, would run into
consistent with investor rationality—might focus on difficulty more often. The alternative interpreta-
external changes in regulation, capital markets, and tion—that the deals were rationally priced and
the general economy. One likely candidate—though structured, but simply ran into unforeseeable exter-
by no means the only one—may have been fluctua- nal problems—would suggest that expected operat-
tions in the liquidity of the asset sales market. A ing improvements failed to materialize.
rapidly growing asset sales market could help Furthermore, the overheating hypothesis would
explain rising buyout prices in general, to the extent seem to imply that “poorly structured” deals—in

12. See R. Gertner and D. Scharfstein, “A Theory of Workouts and the Effects
of Reorganization Law,” Journal of Finance, XLVI (1991), 1189-1222.
13. Shleifer and Vishny [1992], cited earlier in note 9, argue that it was precisely
this increase in asset liquidity in the early and mid-1980s that made the large growth
of the public junk bond market possible.

85
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1993
terms of pricing, capital structure, or incentives— distress increased significantly over time, with 1985
should become financially distressed more often. as the apparent breakpoint. Before 1985, only 1 of
This should be especially true of deals financed with 41 buyouts experienced distress; from 1985 and
junk bonds because these deals tended to have both onward, 30 of 83 did. As shown in Column 2, the
higher prices as well as capital structures that were percentage of defaults among buyouts also in-
less easily renegotiated. creased significantly, again with 1985 appearing to
The alternative interpretation does not make the be the year of change.
same predictions about ex-post outcomes. Because The time trend for Chapter 11 filings, however,
variations in price, capital structure, and incentives although positive (see Column 3), was not significant.
may reflect legitimate differences in unobserved Fewer than one-half of the companies that have
fundamentals, they should not necessarily be corre- defaulted on debt payments have also filed for
lated with ex-post difficulties. For example, if junk Chapter 11. However, because defaults usually pre-
bonds were (sensibly) used only in deals where asset cede a Chapter 11 filing, this trend could (and has)
sales provide an alternative means of averting dis- become more pronounced with the passage of time.
tress, we should not see a disproportionate number
of junk-bond financed deals become distressed. Post-buyout Operating Performance
We now present evidence on (1) the extent to
which management buyouts experienced financial The increase in defaults may have been caused,
distress; (2) post-buyout operating performance; of course, by a combination of ex ante changes in
and (3) the degree of correlation between financial pricing and structuring as well as ex post surprises in
distress and various measures of pricing, capital performance. Columns 4 and 5 present the annual
structure, and incentives. Such evidence is inevita- medians of changes in EBITDA and net cash flow to
bly preliminary, especially for those buyouts com- sales in the first post-buyout year relative to the last
pleted in the last years of the ’80s. pre-buyout year. For the entire sample, the ratios
increased by 9% and 43%, respectively, in the first
Frequency of Distress year of operations. Over a two-year period follow-
ing the buyouts, the operating improvements are
We used three different indicators of financial roughly the same; as shown in Columns 6 and 7,
distress. We considered a buyout to have encoun- EBITDA operating margins increased by 12% and
tered distress if, by August 1991, the firm had net cash flow margins by almost 42%.14
(1) attempted to restructure its debt because of These patterns of operating changes, therefore,
difficulty in making debt payments, (2) defaulted on do not offer much support for the view that
a debt payment, or (3) filed for Chapter 11. Before economic conditions and performance surprises led
reporting our evidence on these three kinds of to the increase in financial distress over time. Many
distress, we should emphasize that they do not of the buyouts of 1985, 1987, and 1988 experienced
necessarily have the same import. For example, financial distress despite improvements in operating
encountering distress probably means that some performance.15 Thus, the results overall seem con-
class of investors has lost money (and, hence, may sistent with changes in buyout pricing and financial
suggest a deal was overpriced), but may well have structure having played an important role in in-
little to say about the deadweight costs of financial creased financial distress.
distress. In other words, a buyout that encounters
distress may be able to restructure at low cost. Correlation Between Distress and Ex Ante
As shown in Column 1 of Table 7, over 25% of Variables
the 124 buyouts in our sample firms had experi-
enced at least one of these three forms of financial Our final test was to determine the extent to
distress by August 1991. The incidence of financial which the three varieties of financial distress were

14. Only the changes in net cash flow margin in the second year trend operating margins and cash flow margins were, if anything, larger for later buyouts
downward significantly over time. And this is driven by the poor performance of than for earlier ones. See “Operating Performance in Leveraged Buyouts: Evidence
only the 1986 buyouts. from 1985-1989,” Financial Management, XXI, No. 1 (1992), 27-34.
15. In a study of 40 large leveraged buyouts completed between 1985-1989,
for example, Tim Opler finds that nominal and industry-adjusted increases in

86
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Many of the later buyouts experienced financial distress despite significant
improvements in operating performance. Thus, the results overall seem consistent
with changes in buyout pricing and financial structure having played the major a
role in increased financial distress.

TABLE 7 (4) (5) (6) (7)


POST-BUYOUT Actual Actual Actual Actual
(1) (2) Growth Growth Growth Growth
PERFORMANCEa Experience Default (3) Operating Cash Flow Operating Cash Flow
Financial on Debt Chapter Margins Margins Margins Margins
Year Distress Payment 11 t-1 to t+1 t-1 to t+1 t-1 to t+2 t-1 to t+2

1980-81 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.5 22.7 8.9 132.6


6 6 6 3 2 3 3
1982 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.6 29.4 26.6 48.5
8 8 8 5 4 5 4
1983 0.0 0.0 0.0 9.2 55.7 26.3 60.1
10 10 10 8 7 7 7
1984 5.9 5.9 5.9 –1.3 28.4 –1.5 40.0
17 17 17 12 12 11 11
1985 33.3 25.0 16.7 14.3 30.2 21.9 31.4
12 12 12 11 11 9 9
1986 46.7 46.7 26.7 –7.9 17.7 –32.6 –45.5
15 15 15 9 8 9 8
1987 45.0 30.0 15.0 15.6 67.0 22.5 30.8
20 20 20 17 16 15 14
1988 29.0 16.1 0.0 14.2 48.4 12.3 22.8
31 31 31 20 19 7 7
1989 20.0 20.0 0.0 25.2 40.7 N/A N/A
5 5 5 2 2
Total 25.0 18.5 8.1 9.1 43.0 12.1 41.8
124 124 124 87 81 66 63
Time Trend
(+)*** (+)* (+) (+) (+) (–) (–)*
1980-82 vs. 1983-85
(+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (–) (–)
1983-85 vs. 1986-89
(+)*** (+)** (+) (+) (+) (–) (–)**

a. Number of observations on second line.


*** Medians significantly different over time or in comparison periods at 1 percent level; ** at 5 percent level; and * at 10 percent
level.

correlated with measures of pricing, capital struc- counter distress and 14% more likely to default than
ture, and incentives that we found to have changed the average buyout.)
significantly during the ’80s. To measure the strength A high degree of cashing-out on the part of
of such correlations, we ran several series of (mul- management was associated with a significant in-
tivariate as well as univariate) regressions. Although crease—roughly 15%—in the probability of default.
detailed results are presented in the original study, The use of junk bonds was associated with
we simply summarize our findings below: statistically and economically significant increases in
The lower the ratio of EBITDA to capital (or, the probability of distress, default, and Chapter 11
alternatively, the higher the price paid as a multiple of, respectively, 21%, 10%, and 11%.
of cash flow), the greater the probability that a Because we viewed this last correlation to be
buyout encountered financial distress in any of its the most interesting, we investigated its “robustness”
three forms. to several multivariate specifications. When the four
High industry risk had a positive relation to the other independent variables cited above were added
likelihood of distress and default. (Indeed, buyouts both individually and as a group to the junk bond
in the highest industry risk quartile—for example, variable in a series of regressions, the estimated
MBOs in retailing—were 19% more likely to en- coefficients on the junk bond variable were signifi-

87
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1993
cant in all cases (as well as statistically similar to their that began around 1985 fundamentally altered both
values in the univariate regressions summarized the pricing and capital structure of later buyouts. We
above). view the changes in capital structure as particularly
We interpret this relatively strong and robust important. In an apparently defensive reaction,
ability of junk bonds to predict future distress as senior bank lenders participated less in the later,
supportive of the overheating hypothesis. According junk-bond financed deals and tried to extract their
to the story sketched above, one would expect the money more rapidly. While this reaction may have
presence of junk bonds to be an especially useful made good sense from the narrow perspective of the
summary statistic, as it captures a tendency towards senior lenders, it arguably increased the expected
both higher prices and more fragile capital structures. costs of financial distress by exacerbating conflicts
of interest between junior and senior claimants.
CONCLUSIONS Further support for this junk bond/demand
push interpretation comes from our analysis of the
We now come back to the question we asked ex post data, which finds the presence of junk bonds
at the outset: Were there differences in the pricing in a buyout to be a good predictor of various types
and capital structure of buyouts in the late 1980s that of financial distress. Presumably, this is because the
might have led one to expect disappointing investor presence of junk bonds captures a tendency toward
returns relative to those in earlier deals? In brief, our both higher prices and more fragile capital structures.
analysis of 124 large MBOs completed between 1980 If this interpretation is correct, the question
and 1989 yields the following conclusions: arises as to how the junk bond investors made the
Buyout price to cashflow ratios rose (although not mistakes they did. Although such a question is
more sharply than market- or industry-wide P/E inevitably difficult to answer satisfactorily, our data
ratios). do provide some hints. To the extent that junk
Prices were particularly high in deals financed bond investors miscalculated, they probably did so
with junk bonds. by focusing too much on stated coupon yields and
As prices rose, buyouts were undertaken in riskier past buyout successes, and too little on the subtle
industries, and with somewhat higher leverage capital structure details of the deals they were
ratios. investing in. Holding everything else constant, there
Banks took smaller positions in later deals, and at is a big difference between owning a debenture
the same time accelerated required principal repay- that does not begin to receive any cash payout until
ments, leading to sharply lower ratios of cash flow after the senior debt has been largely repaid, and
to total debt obligations. one that gets repaid along roughly the same sched-
The public junk bond financing that largely re- ule as the senior debt.
placed private subordinated debt beginning in 1985 Whether or not one accepts the overheating
was much more likely to include deferred interest interpretation, our data provide a useful post-
securities, and less likely to involve equity “strips.” mortem of the buyout boom. At least with the benefit
Finally, management and other interested parties of hindsight, it seems clear that some of the changes
such as investment bankers and deal promoters in capital structure and incentives seen in the deals of
were able to take more money upfront out of the the later 1980s were bad ideas. Thus, one might
later deals. expect future buyouts to look more like those of the
On balance, our evidence, while not unambigu- earlier 1980s: with less stringent principal repayment
ous, fits well with a version of the overheated buyout schedules, more closely-held subordinated debt and
market hypothesis. According to this version of the strip financing, and less front-loaded compensation
story, the demand push from the junk bond market for management and other interested parties.

STEVEN KAPLAN JEREMY STEIN

is Associate Professor, Graduate School of Business, University is Associate Professor of Finance at the Sloan School of
of Chicago, and a Research Fellow at the NBER. Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, and an
Associate at the NBER.

88
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance (ISSN 1078-1196 [print], ISSN Journal of Applied Corporate Finance is available online through Synergy,
1745-6622 [online]) is published quarterly on behalf of Morgan Stanley by Blackwell’s online journal service which allows you to:
Blackwell Publishing, with offices at 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, • Browse tables of contents and abstracts from over 290 professional,
USA, and PO Box 1354, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2XG, UK. Call science, social science, and medical journals
US: (800) 835-6770, UK: +44 1865 778315; fax US: (781) 388-8232, UK: • Create your own Personal Homepage from which you can access your
+44 1865 471775, or e-mail: subscrip@bos.blackwellpublishing.com. personal subscriptions, set up e-mail table of contents alerts and run
saved searches
Information For Subscribers For new orders, renewals, sample copy re- • Perform detailed searches across our database of titles and save the
quests, claims, changes of address, and all other subscription correspon- search criteria for future use
dence, please contact the Customer Service Department at your nearest • Link to and from bibliographic databases such as ISI.
Blackwell office. Sign up for free today at http://www.blackwell-synergy.com.

Subscription Rates for Volume 17 (four issues) Institutional Premium Disclaimer The Publisher, Morgan Stanley, its affiliates, and the Editor cannot
Rate* The Americas† $330, Rest of World £201; Commercial Company Pre- be held responsible for errors or any consequences arising from the use of
mium Rate, The Americas $440, Rest of World £268; Individual Rate, The information contained in this journal. The views and opinions expressed in this
Americas $95, Rest of World £70, Ð105‡; Students**, The Americas $50, journal do not necessarily represent those of the Publisher, Morgan Stanley,
Rest of World £28, Ð42. its affiliates, and Editor, neither does the publication of advertisements con-
stitute any endorsement by the Publisher, Morgan Stanley, its affiliates, and
*Includes print plus premium online access to the current and all available Editor of the products advertised. No person should purchase or sell any
backfiles. Print and online-only rates are also available (see below). security or asset in reliance on any information in this journal.


Customers in Canada should add 7% GST or provide evidence of entitlement Morgan Stanley is a full service financial services company active in the securi-
to exemption ties, investment management and credit services businesses. Morgan Stanley
may have and may seek to have business relationships with any person or

Customers in the UK should add VAT at 5%; customers in the EU should also company named in this journal.
add VAT at 5%, or provide a VAT registration number or evidence of entitle-
ment to exemption Copyright © 2004 Morgan Stanley. All rights reserved. No part of this publi-
cation may be reproduced, stored or transmitted in whole or part in any form
** Students must present a copy of their student ID card to receive this or by any means without the prior permission in writing from the copyright
rate. holder. Authorization to photocopy items for internal or personal use or for the
internal or personal use of specific clients is granted by the copyright holder
For more information about Blackwell Publishing journals, including online ac- for libraries and other users of the Copyright Clearance Center (CCC), 222
cess information, terms and conditions, and other pricing options, please visit Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA (www.copyright.com), provided
www.blackwellpublishing.com or contact our customer service department, the appropriate fee is paid directly to the CCC. This consent does not extend
tel: (800) 835-6770 or +44 1865 778315 (UK office). to other kinds of copying, such as copying for general distribution for advertis-
ing or promotional purposes, for creating new collective works or for resale.
Back Issues Back issues are available from the publisher at the current single- Institutions with a paid subscription to this journal may make photocopies for
issue rate. teaching purposes and academic course-packs free of charge provided such
copies are not resold. For all other permissions inquiries, including requests
Mailing Journal of Applied Corporate Finance is mailed Standard Rate. Mail- to republish material in another work, please contact the Journals Rights and
ing to rest of world by DHL Smart & Global Mail. Canadian mail is sent by Permissions Coordinator, Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford
Canadian publications mail agreement number 40573520. Postmaster OX4 2DQ. E-mail: journalsrights@oxon.blackwellpublishing.com.
Send all address changes to Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Blackwell
Publishing Inc., Journals Subscription Department, 350 Main St., Malden, MA
02148-5020.

You might also like