Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 12

Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Business Research


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbusres

Is sharing up for sale? Monetary exchanges in the sharing economy T


Inken Küper, Laura Marie Edinger-Schons
University of Mannheim, Schloss, 68131 Mannheim, Germany

ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

Keywords: Past research has neglected the question of whether different exchange mechanisms and consumption or service
Sharing economy contexts (CSCs) in the sharing economy may lead to different outcomes. The authors develop a novel theoretical
Social exchange theory framework that proposes that willingness to participate in the sharing economy will be lower if exchange me-
Relational models theory chanisms and CSCs do not match—that is, if monetary/social exchange mechanisms are applied in hedonic/
Exchange mechanisms
utilitarian CSCs, taking into account the moderating role of materialism. Moreover, the authors propose that in
Utilitarian/hedonic consumption or service
contexts
the sharing economy, monetary exchanges may cause a crowding-out of prosocial behaviors and that this effect
Materialism will be especially pronounced for highly materialistic individuals. They test their hypothesized framework in
three experimental studies that support the theorizing and provide results with important implications for the
design of sharing economy offers as well as for society.

1. Introduction 2015; Sundararajan, 2019), and explaining how we have moved from
having a market economy to being a market society (Sandel, 2012).
Continuously, new offers in the sharing economy are being devel- Social exchange theory (SET) (Cropanzano & Mitchell, 2005) provides a
oped, making exchanges easier, more convenient, and cheaper. comprehensive account of the mismatches that can occur if economic
Interestingly, the exchanges within the sharing economy are everything transactions take place in social relationships (e.g., paying a friend to
but homogeneous (Belk, 2010; Cheng, 2016; Scaraboto, 2015; Schor & do a favor) or vice versa. We propose that a variety of exchange me-
Fitzmaurice, 2015), encompassing exchange mechanisms that range chanisms (i.e., monetary vs. social) in combination with a variety of
from conventional market exchanges involving negotiated prices to consumption or service contexts (i.e., hedonic vs. utilitarian) (Dhar &
exchanges that are based on gift-giving and reciprocity (Polanyi, 1944; Wertenbroch, 2000) may cause such mismatches, which may then af-
Blau, 1964; Cropanzano & Mitchell, 2005; Scaraboto, 2015; fect consumers’ willingness to participate in the sharing economy, de-
Sundararajan, 2019). In some cases, different exchange mechanisms are pending on their level of materialism (Richins & Dawson, 1992). We
used for the same commodity that is being exchanged. Airbnb and further propose that the application of monetary exchange mechanisms
Couchsurfing are illustrative examples: both platforms offer peer-to- in the sharing economy can erode social norms of sharing and that this
peer based sharing of accommodation. However, whereas Airbnb relies effect will be more pronounced for highly materialistic individuals.
on negotiated prices—a market-pricing mechanism—Couchsurfing is In a first step, we conducted four focus group interviews to gain a
based on social norms of gift-giving and reciprocity and no monetary holistic understanding of potential users’ perceptions of monetary ex-
payment is involved. change mechanisms in the sharing economy and their categorization of
Labeling market-pricing business models of the sharing economy the exchange relationships as economic or social. The interviews reveal
such as Airbnb as “sharing” has led to the question of whether such that consumers perceive utilitarian consumption and service contexts
activities should be referred to instead as “pseudo-sharing” (Belk, (CSCs), such as ride-sharing, as economic relationships in which
2014b, p. 1596), because they are, more accurately, short-term rental monetary exchange mechanisms are appropriate, but perceive hedonic
activities. Obviously, whereas sharing is a social practice, market-pri- CSCs, such as sharing a dinner, as social relationships where social
cing business models of the sharing economy belong to the realm of exchange mechanisms are appropriate and monetary exchanges would
market exchanges (Cropanzano & Mitchell, 2005; Eckhardt & Bardhi, lead to a mismatch.
2016). A growing body of literature has studied the progressive blurring Drawing on the results of this qualitative study, and drawing from
of economic and social relationships and exchanges, noting the conflicts social exchange theory (SET) (Blau, 1964; Cropanzano & Mitchell,
that may occur if they overlap (Eckhardt & Bardhi, 2016; Heyman & 2005) as well as relational models theory (RMT) (Fiske, 1991, 1992;
Ariely, 2004; Jenkins et al., 2014; McGraw & Tetlock, 2005; Scaraboto, Fiske & Haslam, 1997, 2005; Haslam & Fiske, 1999; Haslam, 2004), we

E-mail addresses: inken.blatt@bwl.uni-mannheim.de (I. Küper), schons@bwl.uni-mannheim.de (L.M. Edinger-Schons).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.08.020
Received 30 December 2018; Received in revised form 8 August 2020; Accepted 13 August 2020
Available online 03 September 2020
0148-2963/ © 2020 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

derive a conceptual framework on individual reactions to varying ex- (Eckhardt et al., 2019; Sundararajan, 2019).
change mechanisms in the sharing economy, depending on the type of The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. The next sec-
CSC and materialism. Specifically, we hypothesize that the willingness tion provides a brief review of the literature on the sharing economy on
to participate in the sharing economy depends on whether a match a macro- as well as a micro-level and identifies the research gaps this
exists between the respective exchange mechanism and the CSC. study aims to address. Then, on the basis of the results of the focus
Moreover, materialism as a trait has recently received widespread at- group interviews and drawing from existing theory, the research hy-
tention in micro-level sharing economy research (e.g., Bucher, Fieseler, potheses are derived. The formal tests of these hypotheses are presented
& Lutz, 2016; Akbar, Mai, & Hoffmann, 2016; Davidson, Habibi, & in the section on empirical study, and results of the three experimental
Laroche, 2018). We propose that the detrimental effects of mismatches studies are discussed in light of their implications.
will be less pronounced for materialistic individuals. Over and above
these antecedents of willingness to participate, following Sandel 2. Review of the literature
(2012), we hypothesize that participation in monetary exchanges in the
sharing economy may induce an erosion of social norms of sharing that 2.1. Outcomes of the sharing economy on a macro-level: Curse or blessing?
manifests as decreased prosocial behaviors, and that this effect will be
more pronounced for highly materialistic individuals. Although a vigorous discussion continues as to the definition of the
To empirically test our theorized framework, we conduct three ex- term “sharing economy,” and despite the fact that several overlapping
periments. The first 2 × 2 (i.e., monetary vs. social exchange me- terms are still used more or less synonymously— “collaborative
chanism; hedonic vs. utilitarian CSC) between-subjects scenario ex- economy,” “gig economy,” “collaborative consumption” (Martin, 2016;
periment reveals that indeed, in line with our basic theorizing, Schor, 2014)—the sharing economy can be summarized as all activities
willingness to participate in a monetary exchange in the sharing that include peer-to-peer based sharing of resources, often facilitated by
economy will be lower if the CSC is a hedonic one—that is, if a mis- the internet (Acquier, Daudigeos, & Pinkse, 2017; Belk, 2014a;
match exists between CSC and the exchange mechanism. In a second Eckhardt et al., 2019; Eckhardt & Bardhi, 2016; Etter, Fieseler, &
scenario experiment, we extend these findings by delving into the Whelan, 2019). The term “sharing” generally excludes forms of ex-
psychological mechanisms that mediate these effects. We find that a change in which monetary prices are involved (Belk, 2014b). Sharing
monetary exchange mechanism leads to activation of market norms, can be considered as “the act and process of distributing what is ours to
which increases the willingness to participate but that this process is others for their use and/or the act and process of receiving or taking
disrupted if the CSC is of a hedonic (versus utilitarian) type and, thus, a something from others for our use” (Belk, 2007, p. 126). Such sharing
mismatch exists. In line with our theorizing, we show that this mod- represents a type of innate human behavior that is conceivably more
erated mediation effect depends on the dispositional level of materi- natural and has a much longer tradition than market exchanges
alism (i.e., moderated moderated mediation). Results indicate that for (Polanyi, 1944). Food sharing, particularly the allocation of meat from
highly materialistic individuals, the negative effect of a mismatch be- large animals, has been an important element of foraging societies, and
tween the exchange mechanism and the service or consumption context mechanisms of sharing and reciprocity occur among toddlers (Levitt
is weaker than for less materialistic persons. A third, single-factor (i.e., et al., 1985). In contrast, sharing in the sharing economy has become
monetary vs. social exchange mechanism) between-subjects field ex- more strongly associated with large commercial platforms like Airbnb
periment reveals participants’ actual donation behavior and generates and Uber, fueling discussion around so-called “pseudo-sharing” (Belk,
support for the proposition that engaging in monetary exchanges in 2014a; Habibi et al., 2016).
situations that usually follow social norms of sharing (e.g., a swap Further, economic, environmental, political, and social impacts of
party) may crowd out highly materialistic participants’ prosocial be- the sharing economy are increasingly discussed in a critical way
haviors (e.g., donations). (Botsman & Rogers, 2011; Dillahunt & Malone, 2015; John, 2017;
By being the first study to empirically analyze the differential effects Martin, 2016; Schor, 2014; Schor & Fitzmaurice, 2015). The sharing
of varying exchange mechanisms and CSCs within the sharing economy, economy was first seen as enriching society by enabling more efficient
our research makes several contributions. First, we reveal that in- use of resources, building social connections, and providing economic
dividual consumers’ willingness to participate in the sharing economy benefits. However, recent criticism has characterized sharing as “lar-
depends on both the exchange mechanism (i.e., monetary vs. social) gely based on evading regulations and breaking the law” (Baker, 2014).
and the CSC (i.e., hedonic vs. utilitarian). This result significantly ex- The core questions are (1) What are the societal consequences of
tends knowledge on micro-level effects in the sharing economy, an area business models like Airbnb and Uber? and (2) Could these disruptive
that has enjoyed comparatively little research attention (Bucher et al., business models, instead of contributing to more sustainable forms of
2016; Eckhardt & Bardhi, 2016; Eckhardt et al., 2019). Our study business, be a Trojan horse of even more radical capitalist market lib-
thereby represents an empirical test of the mismatches proposed in eralism? On the positive side, such business models may lead to fa-
conceptual papers on SET (e.g., Cropanzano & Mitchell, 2005), RMT vorable outcomes: more efficient use of resources; cheaper prices for
(Fiske, 1991, 1992; Fiske & Haslam, 1996; Haslam, 1994), and “pseudo- consumers; freedom, empowerment, and enjoyment; trust-enhancing
sharing” in the sharing economy (Belk, 2014a; Habibi, Davidson, & effects; improved services; and increased economic activity and en-
Laroche, 2016). trepreneurship (Avital et al., 2015). On the downside, critics warn
Second, our investigation contributes to the emerging stream of about several potentially detrimental impacts: destruction of existing
research on of the role of materialism in the sharing economy (Bucher, business models; unfair competition (regulation rules do not apply,
Fieseler, & Lutz, 2016; Akbar, Mai, & Hoffmann, 2016; Davidson, such as for fire safety, hygiene, licensing fees, insurance); endanger-
Habibi, & Laroche, 2018). Specifically, we reveal that an individual’s ment of equal access to living space and mobility; safety risks owing to
level of materialism is an important contingency factor that may ex- lack of insurance; undermining of employment laws; and benefiting
plain variations in reactions to sharing economy offers. Third, the field from tax loopholes (and thus reduced tax incomes for the state).
experiment produced seminal evidence for a potential crowding- out of
individuals’ willingness to donate if market reasoning is increasingly 2.2. Micro-level research on the sharing economy
introduced to spheres of life previously governed by non-market norms
(Sandel, 2012). This finding elicits a need for intensified research as it As research on individual micro-level outcomes of participating in
has important implications for the potential societal consequences of the sharing economy is still in its infancy, “surprisingly little is known
market-pricing exchange mechanisms in the sharing economy, an area about the individuals who are at the heart of this phenomenon. What
which has recently been identified as a research void and priority motivates them to share their cars, apartments, gardens and bikes with

224
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

strangers?” (Bucher et al., 2016, p. 317). Recent research has generated the sharing economy, it is surprising that empirical research has ne-
first insights: individual participants in the sharing economy are de- glected the question of how these various mechanisms may affect
scribed as being motivated by economic, environmental, and social participation and sharing. An unaddressed question concerns the effects
factors (Hamari et al., 2015; Lamberton & Rose, 2012; Schor, 2014). of whether sharing platforms use money as a medium of exchange or
Economic factors relate to the fact that sharing economy business not (Schor & Fitzmaurice, 2015). An examination of car-sharing as
models create new income-earning opportunities, in that people are “access-based consumption” develops criteria that distinguish such
able to earn money easily by renting out spare bedrooms or cars or by business models (Bardhi & Eckhardt, 2012; Eckhardt et al. 2019) and
undertaking certain tasks. Furthermore, sharing economy platforms are suggests “market mediation” to refer to the varying degrees to which
often cheaper than market alternatives. Thus, a person who is looking business models rely on economic exchange as a central factor. A dis-
for accommodation can save money by booking a room via Airbnb cussion of Airbnb and Couchsurfing asserts that “money profanes the
rather than booking a hotel room (Cohen & Kietzmann, 2014; Eckhardt sharing transaction” and that “[w]here the main intent is to enjoy the
& Bardhi, 2016; Hamari et al., 2015). Economic factors are essentially human interaction of sharing, any thoughts and mechanisms of com-
monetary motives—“I share because it is economically wise” (Bucher modity exchange become antithetical to what is going on—like offering
et al., 2016, p. 318). $5 for helping get my car started” (Belk, 2014a, p.19).
Environmental factors relate to a reduction in ecological impact and First evidence on the proportion of people who share in commercial
a reduced demand for new goods. For example, “tool-sharing reduces versus non-commercial contexts shows that the group of non-commer-
new tool purchases” (Schor, p. 6, 2014; Hamari et al., 2015). Although cial sharers is much smaller (only 29% of the sample) than that of
no comprehensive studies have examined the real ecological impact of commercial sharers (Bucher et al., 2016). Other work offers a con-
the sharing economy (Schor & Fitzmaurice, 2015), many platforms tinuum of exchanges ranging from “pure sharing” (e.g., pooling re-
advertise themselves as green (Schor, 2014) and are driven by moral sources) to “pure exchange” (e.g., buying bread from store) along with
motives—“I share because it is the right thing to do” (Bucher et al., a method to calculate the “sharing score” of each practice (Habibi et al.,
2016, p. 319). Moral motives include all motives grounded in the no- 2016). However, so far, no empirical studies have examined how
tion that sharing is a more meaningful, sustainable, and en- market-pricing mechanisms in the sharing economy affect willingness
vironmentally friendly alternative to ownership-based forms of access to participate and sharing behaviors. This investigation addresses this
(Bardhi & Eckhardt, 2012; Botsman & Rogers, 2011; John, 2017). Re- research gap.
latedly, sharing has also been discussed as a new form of more “mindful Conceivably, the monetary exchanges in social relationships and
consumption” (Buczynski, 2013) or as “anti-consumption” (Ozanne & vice versa can lead to mismatches that may cause psychological injury
Ballantine, 2010). Some participants “are ideologically committed to and perhaps even permanent damage to the relationship (Cropanzano &
concepts of sharing and collaborating, and many have critiques of Mitchell, 2005). This possibility is in line with recent applications of
market provision” (Schor & Fitzmaurice, 2015, p. 414). relational models theory (Haslam & Fiske, 1999), in which conflicts
Social factors relate to the desire to increase social connections between social and market norms have been shown to lead to detri-
(Hamari et al., 2015; Mannak et al., 2004), resulting in social-hedonic mental outcomes (e.g., Heyman & Ariely, 2004). Similarly, in the
motives—“I share to connect with others” (Bucher et al., 2016, p. 319). sharing economy, the use of monetary exchange mechanisms in con-
In most cultures, sharing activities are social rituals, like sharing food sumption and service contexts that are categorized as hedonic or social
and drink, and form the cement of human social interactions (Belk, (e.g., as in the case of commercial dinner-sharing platforms) may result
2010; Eckhardt & Bardhi, 2016). As such, sharing “goes hand in hand in adverse reactions by participants. In contrast, the use of monetary
with trust and bonding” (Belk, 2010, p. 717). exchange mechanisms could be smoothly accepted and enhance will-
ingness to participate if the CSC is clearly categorized as a utilitarian or
2.3. Monetary versus non-monetary exchange mechanisms in the sharing economic one.
economy Further, Sandel (2012) claims that monetary exchange mechanisms
play an increasing role in our modern societies (e.g., prison cell up-
Previous research has also shed light on different types of ex- grades, line-standing services, private military services), and that in
changes. In traditional exchanges, we rely almost entirely on money to many cases, monetary incentives are used to solve social problems, as
transact with each other. However, the sharing economy opens the door when money is offered to female drug addicts to get sterilized or when
to a wide variety of exchange mechanisms. SET proposes that ex- school kids are paid for reading books. He contends that we have drifted
changes can take various forms, from (1) pure gift-giving/altruism, from “having a market economy” to “being a market society,” and ar-
where an object is transferred from one individual to another without gues that putting a price on every human activity may erode certain
the expectation of reciprocation, to (2) reciprocity, or the exchange of moral and civic goods worth caring about. Applying Sandel’s (2012)
goods between people who are bound with one another in non-market, basic logic to the sharing economy context, we could ask whether using
non-hierarchical relationships, and (3) market exchanges, in which the monetary exchange mechanisms in contexts in which people formerly
prices of goods exchanged are determined by the law of supply and shared resources voluntarily may lead to a crowding-out of the intrinsic
demand (Cropanzano & Mitchell, 2005). Many of the business models motivation to help and a subsequent erosion of prosocial behaviors. In
of the sharing economy are something in between gift-giving, re- our conceptual framework, we theorize how monetary exchanges in the
ciprocity and market exchange (Schor & Fitzmaurice, 2015; sharing economy affect both participation and prosocial behaviors.
Sundararajan, 2019).
Interestingly, in some cases, different exchange mechanisms can be 2.4. Utilitarian versus hedonic CSCs
observed for an identical commodity. For instance, whereas through
Airbnb owners list their spare bedrooms or apartments for rent, Consumer research has long distinguished between hedonic and
Couchsurfing allows people to offer their spare bed or improvised utilitarian products and services. Consumer behavior can be driven by
sleeping arrangements to community members without monetary either hedonic or utilitarian considerations, which map onto in-
compensation (although Couchsurfing switched from a non-profit dependent components of evaluations and attitudes and enable people
business model to a for-profit business model in 2010). Thus, while to differentiate between products and services according to their he-
both platforms offer sharing of accommodation, Airbnb relies on a donic or utilitarian nature (Dhar & Wertenbroch, 2000; Voss,
market-pricing mechanism and Couchsurfing is based on social norms Spangenberg, & Grohmann, 2003). Hedonic consumption is sensation-
of gift-giving and reciprocity (Sundararajan, 2019). driven and provides consumers with multi-sensory and emotive ex-
Given the wide variety of exchange mechanisms currently in use in periences (e.g., theme parks, vacation resorts, nightclubs), whereas

225
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

utilitarian consumption is focused on the functional aspects of products well as consumption and service contexts in the sharing economy, we
and services and aims to solve practical problems (e.g., car repairs, conducted a series of four focus-group interviews. We then used the
banking; Jiang & Wang, 2006). Typically, consumers’ evaluations of insights gained in the focus group interviews to derive our hypotheses.
hedonic products and services are based on the pleasure related to the
experience, whereas evaluations of utilitarian products and services are 3. Qualitative study and derivation of hypotheses
based on instrumental utility (Batra & Ahtola, 1991).
In the sharing economy, consumption and service contexts lie on a We conducted four focus groups with five to seven participants
continuum of offers ranging from more hedonic (e.g., dinner-sharing, each, who varied regarding age and occupational status. The inter-
swap parties) to more utilitarian (e.g., ride-sharing, tool-lending). Prior viewer first asked the participants how they would define the sharing
research on the sharing economy has ignored the different effects of economy (Dürrenberger et al., 1999). The interviewer then asked the
these two fundamentally different types of consumption on participa- participants what motives would lead them to participate, what atti-
tion and sharing. In our conceptual framework, we propose that con- tudes they have toward different exchange mechanisms, and whether
sumers’ reactions to monetary versus social exchange mechanisms de- they considered these exchange mechanisms appropriate for different
pend on the respective CSC (i.e., hedonic or utilitarian). CSCs and offers. We audio-recorded and transcribed all interviews.

2.5. The role of materialism 3.1. Motives to participate in the sharing economy

The notions of consumerism, anti-consumption, and materialism In all four focus groups, participants had a good understanding of
have been central to the public and academic debate around sharing in what the term sharing economy means, could describe specific offers in
recent years. Consumerism is typically described as a social and eco- the sharing economy, and could report own experiences. In line with
nomic order and ideology that encourages ever-increasing acquisition the literature, participants in all four focus groups reported economic,
of goods and services (Kasser & Kanner, 2004). The claim that western environmental/moral, and social motives for participating in the
societies are characterized by increasing consumerism is supported by sharing economy. However, participants considered environmental/
statistics showing that, for instance, the average size of the American moral motives as least important and some participants even regarded
home has nearly tripled over the past 50 years.1 them as irrelevant.
The importance a consumer attaches to worldly possessions has Economic motives were named first and most prominently in all
been referred to as materialism (Belk, 1985; Ger & Belk, 1990; Kilbourne four focus groups. Referring to offers in the sharing economy, one re-
& Pickett, 2008; Richins & Dawson, 1992). Besides investigating cul- spondent reported that
tural and historical differences in the level of materialism, past research it is often cheaper. For example, if you think of Airbnb, it is of course
has explored individual differences (Shrum et al., 2013) and considered cheaper to have an apartment or room in a house of a private person than
the striking range of consumption practices between, for example, to book a hotel room. Also ride-sharing is often cheaper than other forms
Buddhist monks and “shopaholics.” Materialism has been discussed as of transportation.
having multiple sub-dimensions, with an early categorization proposing
three facets—possessiveness, non-generosity, and envy, (Belk, 1985). A Interestingly, economic motives were most dominant in the case of
later approach suggested acquisition centrality, acquisition as the pur- mobility related offers such as car-sharing, ride-sharing, or bike-
suit of happiness, and possession-defined success, with materialistic sharing, and these services were categorized as more utilitarian in
individuals tending to value possessions and their acquisition more than nature. The discussion in the focus groups indicated that in these kinds
other life goals, to be self-centered, to pursue a life of material com- of service contexts, interactions are guided more strongly by market
plexity rather than simplicity, and to be less satisfied with their lot in norms than by social norms. Besides monetary savings, convenience
life (Richins & Dawson, 1992). was repeatedly stressed. For example,
Very recently, research on individual behaviors in the sharing We used Uber quite often in the US. It was very attractive, because it was
economy has started to investigate the role of materialism. For instance, much cheaper than taking a taxi. And it was much faster. It was often the
individual consumers’ level of materialism has been identified as the case that within a minute someone stood there and gave you a ride while
central determinant of the monetary motivation to participate in the you had to wait for over 20 minutes for a taxi. And you did not have to
sharing economy (Bucher, Fieseler, & Lutz, 2016). Further, results of an have any cash either, you could just pay via the app.
inquiry into how consumers who do not yet participate in the sharing
economy can be motivated to do so show that possessiveness is the In all groups, ecological motives formed another basis for partici-
strongest inhibitor of participation (Akbar, Mai, & Hoffmann, 2016). pating in models of sharing. One respondent stated:
Additionally, a cross-cultural study showed that materialism enhanced I think it is also an approach to promote sustainability, if you do not
participation in the sharing economy by very different mechanisms. US always buy something new but just share things with others. Thus, fewer
Americans sought transformative and hedonic experiences that were products have to be created.
expected to improve their self-image and well-being. For Indians, ma-
terialism led to participation via increased levels of perceived utility Another participant noted:
(Davidson, Habibi, & Laroche, 2018). While this incipient research field If you think of ride-sharing models then of course you might also be
has provided valuable insights into the role of materialistic predis- incentivized by sustainability motives. For example, you could think it
positions in the sharing economy, the interaction of such predisposi- would be good for the environment if we would share the ride instead of
tions with varying exchange mechanisms and CSCs has so far been driving separately.
neglected.
Thus, we derive our conceptual framework, which predicts in- However, in all four groups the discussion revealed that participants
dividual consumers’ reactions to monetary versus social exchange me- saw sustainability-related motives as less important than economic
chanisms in the sharing economy, depending on hedonic versus utili- motives:
tarian CSCs and consumers’ level of materialism. To first gain a deeper I would suggest that sustainability is less important than financial moti-
understanding of consumers’ perceptions of exchange mechanisms as vations. I even believe that sustainability could be partially overestimated
as a motivation in the sharing economy.
1
https://tradingeconomics.com/. One area of sharing in which the ecological or moral aspect seemed

226
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

to be very important to participants, however, was the topic of sharing situation in which people don’t do it for the social interaction but to
leftover food instead of throwing it out. make money and that would be a problem”).
Social motives for participation in the sharing economy were a topic This perception is very much in line with consumer research find-
for discussion in all four focus groups. For instance, two respondents ings that utilitarian services are purchased in a “work mentality”
commented: (Holbrook & Hirschman, 1982) and are seen as “necessities” and
“something one has to get through,” whereas hedonic services offer
I think that social factors also play an important role. If you look at
“fun and pleasure” (Babin, Darden, & Griffin, 1994). Obviously, sharing
Couchsurfing, it’s actually less about finding a place to stay, because you
economy offers that are more utilitarian in nature create economic
can usually find cheap offers in hostels. Rather, it’s about getting to know
relationships that aim to satisfy a functional need, whereas offers that
a local resident with whom you can talk about the city, which also shows
are more hedonic create social relationships that aim at entertainment
you new places in the city and as a consequence, you have a very dif-
and emotional worth. This contrast resembles a dichotomy of human
ferent experience during the journey than when you are alone in the
relationships that has evolved based on Fiske’s RMT and that has re-
hotel. If you are new in a city it is nice to get connected and have a bit of
cently received increased research attention. Whereas Fiske developed
sociality, right?
a typology of four relational models of communal sharing, authority
Thus, areas in which social motives obviously play a very important ranking, equality matching, and market pricing (e.g., Fiske, 1991, 1992;
role are consumption and service contexts that are more hedonic in Fiske & Haslam, 1996; Haslam & Fiske, 1999), recent contributions
nature, such as platforms for dinner-sharing. In such hedonic CSCs, the have distinguished between just two general categories: economic and
relationship is social and the interactions are obviously guided by social social relationships (e.g., Heyman & Ariely, 2004). These two categories
norms. These findings are very much in line with results from past of human relationships are guided by different norms of behavior, and
studies that propose that motives for participating in mobility-related conflicts can arise if they mix (e.g., Tetlock, 2003).
offers of the sharing economy are more economically related (e.g., Our basic proposition is that in the sharing economy, the type of
Bardhi & Eckhardt, 2012), whereas sharing a dinner is categorized as a CSC (i.e., hedonic vs. utilitarian) activates different relationship norms
social practice (Belk, 2014a). (i.e., social versus market norms) and that a (mis-)match between the
CSC and the respective exchange mechanism is an important determi-
3.2. Perceptions of exchange mechanisms in the sharing economy nant of the willingness to participate. Thus, in line with our qualitative
results and the propositions of RMT and SET, we propose that will-
In all four focus groups, participants were aware that various ex- ingness to participate in the sharing economy will be lower if a mis-
change mechanisms are employed, and the topic came up naturally match exists between the CSC and the exchange mechanism.
from the discussion. Non-economic types of exchanges were referred to We propose that this effect can be traced back to norm activation
as a “give and take,” evoking the notion of reciprocity. In general, the processes (Schwartz, 1970). The theory of norm activation proposes
discussion revealed that if the CSC is more utilitarian in nature, the that situational cues, which may be subconscious, activate different
economic motive is dominant and offers like Airbnb, which use a norms of behavior. The varying types CSCs (i.e., hedonic vs. utilitarian)
monetary exchange mechanism, are preferred. If the CSC is categorized can thus be expected to elicit very different norms of behavior. As the
as hedonic, the social motive is dominant and offers like Couchsurfing, respondents indicated in the interviews, hedonic services like dinner-
which use a social exchange mechanism, are preferred. sharing will activate social norms of sharing whereas utilitarian services
However, in line with the propositions of a potential mismatch of like ride-sharing will activate market norms. If the exchange me-
monetary exchanges in social relationships (Cropanzano & Mitchell, chanism matches the CSC—for example, if a utilitarian service uses a
2005), the discussion in all four focus groups indicated that participants monetary exchange mechanism— market norms will be activated and
felt that monetary exchanges are not suitable in all CSCs. Instead, participants’ willingness to participate will be elevated. However, if the
supporting the assumptions of SET, participants felt that in hedonic exchange mechanism does not match the CSC—for example, if a
CSCs, which typically create social relationships, monetary payment monetary exchange mechanism is applied in a hedonic CSC—the acti-
could be inappropriate or feel awkward. For instance, one respondent vation of market norms will be disrupted and subsequently the will-
expressed: ingness to participate will be reduced. Thus, we propose that monetary
exchange mechanisms enhance willingness to participate via an acti-
Couchsurfing is about interaction with the other person. Couchsurfing is
vation of market norms if the CSC is a utilitarian one—that is, if a match
indeed a platform, but on the platform people are looking for social
exists (moderated mediation).
exchanges and relationships. In my opinion, the social component should
be in the foreground and a monetary payment would be inappropriate. H1 (moderation). The type of CSC will moderate the effect of monetary
exchange mechanisms on willingness to participate in a way that the
Another participant stated:
effect of a monetary exchange mechanism will be less positive for
At dinner together I think it’s more the social aspect that prevails. It’s hedonic than for utilitarian CSCs.
about sharing a dinner with another person. It would be inappropriate if
H2a (moderated mediation). This interactive effect of exchange
you had to pay for it.
mechanism and CSC on willingness to participate will be mediated by
On the other hand, referring to more utilitarian CSCs related to the activation of market norms in a way that if monetary exchange
mobility, one participant argued: mechanisms are applied in hedonic CSCs, the activation of market
norms will be disrupted and subsequently lower the intention to
In car sharing I would really say “okay, we just share the costs.”
participate.
Transport from A to B is somehow an unavoidable evil, we have to put up
with that in order to somehow get to another city. In contrast, a dinner In the following, we hypothesize how the individual level of mate-
together is a nice occasion, from which we have a social benefit. rialism moderates these moderated mediation effects in the form of a
three-way interaction or moderated moderated mediation. Drawing
The focus groups unanimously revealed that utilitarian CSCs are
from the conceptualizations of trait materialism (Belk, 1985; Richins &
perceived as commercial services in which monetary payment is the
Dawson, 1992), we propose that the reactions of potential users to
right form of exchange (e.g., “ride-sharing is a service”) and hedonic
varying exchange mechanisms and CSCs in the sharing economy will
CSCs are perceived as social interactions in which monetary payment
depend on the individual level of materialism. In a first step, we pro-
would violate social norms (e.g., “at a shared dinner it would send out
pose that materialistic individuals will have a higher level of activation
the wrong signals if the host gets paid for it. This might lead to a

227
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

of market norms, independent of the characteristics of the situation. Airbnb, this student gives it a try and rents the spare room out for
This expectation is supported by research on the trait of materialism, money—re- categorizing the relationship with the visiting students as
which suggests that these individuals pursue happiness through ac- an economic relationship guided by market norms. As a consequence,
quisition of material goods instead of, for example, through social re- willingness to offer the room for free in the future may decline. Thus,
lationships (Richins & Dawson, 1992). Possessions and their acquisition we formally propose:
can assume a central role in these persons’ lives (Belk, 1985), and
H3a. Participating in monetary exchanges in the sharing economy will
“consumption for the sake of consumption becomes a fever that con-
lead to a reduced willingness to engage in prosocial behaviors.
sumes all the potential energy” (Csikszentmihalyi & Rochberg-Halton,
1978, p. 231). We deduce that these individuals will constantly ex-
perience a state of market norm activation, which will not be the case 3.4. Moderating role of materialism
for individuals with low levels of materialism.
In a second step, we propose that the moderated mediation hy- In line with the outlined characterization of materialistic in-
pothesized in H2a—that is, that monetary exchange mechanisms in dividuals, we propose that materialists will react differently than non-
hedonic CSCs will decrease consumers’ willingness to participate via a materialists to the introduction of monetary exchanges. Given that
reduction of market norm activation—will depend on the individual materialists are prone to focus on acquisition of material goods and
level of materialism. More specifically, we assume that for highly ma- their own self-benefits (Richins & Dawson, 1992), we propose that the
terialistic individuals, the decreased activation of market norms caused crowding-out of intrinsic prosocial behaviors will be significantly
by a mismatch between the monetary exchange mechanism and the stronger for high than for low materialists. Specifically, we propose that
hedonic service context will not be as pronounced as for low materi- the re-categorization of the relationship from social to economic and
alists because they have high levels of market norm activation in- the activation of market norms will more naturally happen for the high
dependent of the situational circumstances. As a consequence, the ne- materialists, who are predisposed to think according to this logic. More
gative effect of mismatches on willingness to participate will be less formally:
strong for this group of consumers. For consumers who have low levels
H3b. Materialism will moderate the effect of monetary exchanges on
of materialism, however, the mismatch between a monetary exchange
prosocial behaviors in a way that the reduction in prosocial behaviors
mechanism and a hedonic CSC will lead to a more substantive decrease
will be significantly stronger for individuals with a high level of
in the activation of market norms, which subsequently translates into
materialism than for those with a low level of materialism.
eroded levels of willingness to participate.
H2b (moderated moderated mediation). The moderated mediation
4. Empirical studies
hypothesized in H2a will depend on the individual level of
materialism. Specifically, the negative effect of monetary exchanges
To test our hypotheses, we conducted three experiments: two 2 × 2
in hedonic CSCs will be less pronounced for individuals with high levels
between-subjects scenario experiments and one single-factor between-
of materialism than for those with low levels of materialism.
subjects field experiment (N1 = 427; N2 = 208; N3 = 116). In studies 1
and 2, the two scenario experiments, we examined our first three pre-
3.3. Erosion of sharing dictions (H1, H2a, and H2b). In these experiments, we randomly as-
signed respondents to either a monetary or social exchange mechanism
In the focus groups, participants explicitly discussed potential con- (i.e., either a market-pricing mechanism was present or not). Further,
flicts between social and market norms. In one focus group, for in- we used two hypothetical offers of the sharing economy that re-
stance, a respondent described the example of a friend helping with a presented the two types of CSC (i.e., hedonic vs. utilitarian).
house move. The participant said it would feel strange to offer the In study 3, we examined our fourth and fifth predictions (H3a and
friend a monetary payment for the service and that he would rather buy H3b). We used a single-factor between-subjects field experiment in
a present like a box of chocolate. Other focus group participants ex- which either a monetary or social exchange mechanism was applied.
plicitly addressed the question of whether a monetary payment for such Participants organized swap parties and either swapped items using
services in social relationships could lead to a crowding-out of social negotiated monetary prices or exchanged items without any monetary
norms of helping (Frey & Jegen, 2001). One participant argued: payment or direct reciprocation. Fig. 1 gives an overview of the three
studies.
That could be a fundamental problem of the sharing economy. What
happens when people pay for such services? If we put a market price on
4.1. Study 1
everything—will voluntary helping disappear? For example, neighbor-
hood services, the neighbor helps with the move or something. Does he
4.1.1. Design of study
still do that if he could offer the same service on any website and get paid
We recruited 427 individuals through Prolific in May 2019 to
for it?
complete an online questionnaire in exchange for payment. The in-
Thus, if through the sharing economy monetary exchanges are in- dividuals were randomly assigned to one of the four conditions in our 2
troduced into areas of life that were previously based on non-market (i.e., monetary vs. social exchange mechanism) × 2 (i.e., hedonic vs.
exchanges, this insertion may crowd out individuals’ intrinsic will- utilitarian service) between-subjects design. The different treatments
ingness to help and share (Frey & Jegen, 2001; Sandel, 2012) because were integrated into the online questionnaire.
individuals re-categorize social relationships as economic relationships
(Cropanzano & Mitchell, 2005). Re-categorization might lead to an 4.1.2. Data collection and procedure
activation of market norms instead of social norms (Heyman & Ariely, We published a link to our online survey on Prolific. Once re-
2004), causing people to focus on their individual benefits and payoffs spondents accessed the survey, they were first provided with a short
instead of the collective benefits. We expect this focus on individual description of one of the two hypothetical offers that represented either
benefits to lead to a reduced willingness to engage in prosocial beha- a hedonic service (i.e., a dinner-sharing platform) or a utilitarian ser-
viors. vice (i.e., a ride-sharing platform). The choice of these offers was based
As an example, a student might have occasionally offered a spare on the insights from the focus group interviews in which participants in
room in his flat to visiting students because he enjoyed meeting new all four groups mentioned dinner-sharing as representative of a hedonic
people and exchanging stories and experiences. With the launch of CSC and ride-sharing as representative of a utilitarian CSC. All

228
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

Fig. 1. Overview of studies.

treatment materials are included in Web Appendix A. asked to provide their demographics.
Participants in the hedonic service condition (i.e., the dinner-
sharing platform) were asked to imagine that they were currently 4.1.3. Sample description
spending a weekend abroad (e.g., in Spain) and they wanted to try a The sample consisted of 427 individuals living in the U.S (43.1%
local dish. A friend introduced them to the dinner-sharing platform male; mean age = 32.9 years, SD = 11.7), with 216 respondents in the
Sharedine, where a local person would cook dinner for the individual monetary exchange condition (Ndinner-sharing = 107; Nride-sharing = 109)
and other guests at the host’s home. and 211 respondents in the social exchange condition (Ndinner-
Respondents in the utilitarian service condition (i.e., the ride- sharing = 107; Nride-sharing = 104).
sharing platform) were asked to imagine that they were currently
spending a weekend abroad (e.g., Spain) and they wanted to do a day 4.1.4. Measures and manipulation checks
trip to a different city by car (estimated travel time 1.5 h). A friend told To measure respondents’ willingness to participate, we developed a
them about Sharide, an online ride-sharing platform in which a private multi-item scale composed of three items: “The likelihood that I will
car owner would give an individual as well as other passengers a ride in make use of the service is high,” “I would consider participating in the
the driver’s car. service,” and “The probability that I would consider participating in the
Furthermore, we provided information on the underlying exchange service is high.” The construct was measured on a 7-point Likert scale
mechanism (i.e., monetary vs. social exchange) in each of the offers. In (1 = strongly disagree, 7 = strongly agree). The measure showed ac-
the monetary exchange conditions, participants were informed that the ceptable reliability and validity. A complete list of items and scale
dinner (ride) would cost $15 and that the dinner-sharing (car-sharing) evaluation is provided in Web Appendix B.
was based on monetary prices. The prices in dollars were adopted from To check whether the manipulation of the monetary versus social
comparable offers of actual sharing economy offers (i.e., eatwith.com exchange mechanism worked as intended, respondents were introduced
and blablacar.com). In the social exchange mechanism conditions, to the following two items: “The scenario worked on the basis of re-
participants were notified that the dinner (ride) would be for free and ceiving a free service without paying anything,” and “The scenario
no payment would be involved. Participants were told that the dinner- worked on the basis of paying a fee for the service.” Participants rated
sharing (ride-sharing) was based on helping and sharing. the items on a 7-point Likert scale, ranging from 1 = strongly disagree to
Finally, respondents were introduced to their potential host (dinner- 7 = strongly agree. We compared the means across groups using
sharing) or driver (ride-sharing). After the respondents viewed the ANOVAs and planned comparisons (Bonferoni post hoc tests) with IBM
treatment materials, they were asked to report their willingness to SPSS Statistics Version 25. The results show that our manipulations
participate in the respective offer. Subsequently, we measured the ex- worked as intended. Respondents who were assigned to the monetary
tent to which they categorized the CSC as hedonic or utilitarian and exchange mechanism treatment in the ride-sharing group had a sig-
whether they correctly understood the exchange mechanism to be ei- nificantly higher mean for the item “Paying a fee for the service” than
ther monetary or social. At the end of the survey, respondents were those who were assigned to the social exchange mechanism (Mmonetary

229
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

exchange mechanism = 6.59; Msocial exchange mechanism = 1.85; (F (1,


212) = 1201.164, p = .000)). For the item “Receiving a free service
without paying anything,” participants in the social exchange condition
had significantly higher ratings than those in the monetary exchange
condition (Msocial exchange mechanism = 6.02; Mmonetary exchange me-
chanism = 1.38; (F (1, 212) = 428.135, p = .000)). Likewise, individuals
in the monetary exchange mechanism conditions in the dinner sharing
group rated the item “Paying a fee for the service” significantly higher
than those in the social exchange mechanism condition (Mmonetary ex-
change mechanism = 6.28; Msocial exchange mechanism = 2.20; (F (1,
211) = 276.231, p = .000)), whereas participants in the social ex-
change mechanism conditions evaluated the item “Receiving a free
service without paying anything” significantly higher than those who
were assigned to the monetary exchange mechanism (Msocial exchange
mechanism = 5.93; Mmonetary exchange mechanism = 1.49; (F (1,
211) = 472.624, p = .000)). Fig. 2. Study 1: Willingness to participate depending on type of exchange
We further measured respondents’ perceived type of CSC with a 7- mechanism and type of CSC.
point semantic differential scale adapted from Voss, Spangenberg, and
Grohmann (2003). We used five items that describe a hedonic CSC and
significantly negative interaction effect between the monetary (vs. so-
five items that reflect a utilitarian CSC. An example item for the hedonic
cial) exchange mechanism and the hedonic (vs. utilitarian) CSC on
CSC is “Using the service is … not fun (1) – fun (7).” A sample item for
willingness to participate (b = -1.08; p = .002). A decomposition of the
the utilitarian CSC is “Using the service is … ineffective (1) – effective
interaction into its simple effects shows that the effect of a monetary
(7).” The measures and results of the scale evaluation are provided in
(versus social) exchange mechanisms on willingness to participate is
Web Appendix B.
significantly negative for the hedonic CSC (b = -0.844; p = .001) and
Using these measures, we conducted a manipulation check for the
insignificant for the utilitarian CSC (b = 0.235; p = .327). Thus, the
type of CSC manipulation. We integrated the items to equally weighed
results of our first study fully support our theorizing in H1 concerning
indices to test for mean differences across groups. Using analysis of
the effect of varying types of exchange mechanisms and CSCs in sharing
variance (ANOVA), we found results indicating that respondents who
economy offers.
were exposed to the dinner-sharing treatment perceived the type of CSC
as significantly more hedonic than respondents who were in the ride-
sharing group (Mdinner-sharing = 5.57; Mride-sharing = 4.79; (F (1, 4.2. Study 2
425) = 35.467, p = .000)). In turn, respondents who were exposed to
the ride-sharing treatment perceived the type of CSC as significantly 4.2.1. Design of study
more utilitarian than respondents who were in the dinner-sharing group This second study examined the psychological mechanisms that
(Mride-sharing = 5.57; Mdinner-sharing = 5.04; (F (1, 425) = 21.528, mediate the effects found in the first study. Specifically, we tested for
p = .000). Thus, our results reveal that our treatments worked as in- the mediating role of an activation of market norms as well as the
tended. moderating role of the individual level of materialism. Identical to
study 1, we conducted an online scenario experiment with a 2 (i.e.,
4.1.5. Results monetary vs. social exchange mechanism) × 2 (i.e., hedonic vs. utili-
The results of a two-way ANOVA with type of exchange mechanism tarian CSC) between-subjects design. We used exactly the same treat-
and type of CSC dummies as the independent variables, and the will- ment materials as in study 1.
ingness to participate as the dependent variable, indicate that the
willingness to participate in the respective offer varies significantly 4.2.2. Data collection and sample
across the different experimental groups (F (423) = 6.060, p = .000). The sample consisted of 208 individuals recruited on Amazon
Specifically, as we predicted in H1, we find evidence for the mismatches MTurk who participated for payment. In total, 50.5% of the re-
proposed by SET. While in the hedonic CSC (i.e., the dinner-sharing), spondents were male and the average age of the participants was
respondents who were assigned to the social exchange mechanism were 35 years (SD = 11.34), with 99 participants in the monetary exchange
significantly more willing to participate in the dinner (Msocial ex- condition (Ndinner-sharing = 44; Nride-sharing = 55) and 109 participants
change = 5.11) than participants who were assigned to the monetary
in the social exchange condition (Ndinner-sharing = 63; Nride-sharing = 46).
exchange mechanism (Mmonetary exchange = 4.29; (F (1, 211) = 10.528,
p = .001), in the utilitarian CSC (i.e., the ride-sharing), willingness to 4.2.3. Measures
participate did not differ significantly across the two exchange me- We measured respondents’ willingness to participate, respondents’
chanisms (Mmonetary exchange = 5.2 vs. Msocial exchange = 4.9, F (1, perceived type of exchange mechanism, and respondents’ perceived
212) = 0.977, p = .324, see Fig. 2). This finding is especially sur- type of CSC using the same scales as in study 1. To measure the acti-
prising, since rational consumers should prefer a free ride-sharing ser- vation of market exchange norms, we developed four items based on
vice to a costly one. The fact that willingness to participate is not higher the work of Bock et al. (2005) and van der Heijden (2004). An example
in the social exchange group than in the monetary exchange group for item is “I can save money through participating in the dinner-sharing/
the ride-sharing offer (the directionality is opposite although the dif- ride-sharing service.” All items were measured on a 7-point Likert scale,
ference is insignificant), thus provides first support for our mismatch ranging from 1 = strongly disagree to 7 = strongly agree. To measure
theorizing. materialism, we included all three sub-dimensions as proposed by
Furthermore, we ran a regression analysis using PROCESS macro for Richins and Dawson (1992): “acquisition centrality,” “acquisition as the
SPSS Release 3.3 (Model 1, Hayes, 2019) to formally test whether the pursuit of happiness,” and “possession defined success.” To obtain a
interaction between monetary versus social exchange and hedonic more concise measure, we chose to use only the non-reversed coded
versus utilitarian CSC on willingness to participate (as proposed in H1) items that had the strongest factor loadings in the original Richins and
is significant. We also included respondents’ age, gender, and monthly Dawson study (1992). The measures and results of the scale evaluation
net household income as control variables. The analysis reveals a are provided in Web Appendix B.

230
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

4.2.4. Results the offers as in studies 1 and 2.


In study 2, we tested H2a and H2b. In a first step, to test H2a, we ran We measured respondent’s perceived quality of the CSCs using the
a moderated mediation (Model 7) using Process macro for SPSS, using item “The described online platform offers a high-quality service.”
the monetary exchange mechanism dummy as the independent vari- Perceived valuation of the CSC was measured using the item “The de-
able, the hedonic CSC dummy as moderator, activation of market norms scribed service/event has a lot of value for me.” Furthermore, perceived
as mediator, and willingness to participate as the dependent variable. In trust was measured using two items. An example item is “I believe that
addition, we included respondents’ age, gender, and monthly net the described platform is trustworthy.” All items were measured on a 7-
household income as standard controls. point Likert scale anchored by strongly disagree and strongly agree. The
In line with H2a, the results reveal a significant and negative in- analysis reveals no significant differences in perceived quality, valua-
teraction of the monetary exchange dummy with the hedonic CSC tion, and trust across the experimental groups. More specifically, re-
dummy on market norm activation (b = -0.84; , p = .033). Specifically, spondents perceived the quality (Mride-sharing = 5.3 vs. Mdinner-
the effect of the monetary exchange mechanism on market norm acti- sharing = 5.0; (F (1, 203) = 2.113, p = .148)), the value (Mride-
vation is significantly negative for the hedonic CSC (b = -0.65; sharing = 5.3 vs. Mdinner-sharing = 5.0; (F (1, 203) = 1.774, p = .184)),
p = .021) and insignificant for the utilitarian CSC (β = 0.20; p = .461). and trust of the services (Mride-sharing = 5.1 vs. Mdinner-sharing = 4.8; (F
While the direct effect of the monetary exchange mechanism on in- (1, 203) = 2.469, p = .118)) similarly.
tention to participate is insignificant (b = 0.08; p = .619), the indirect Furthermore, we used the additional data to support our findings
effect via market norm activation is significant and negative for the from the focus group interviews that in hedonic CSCs like dinner-
hedonic CSC (b = -0.31; [-0.67;-0.04]) and insignificant for the utili- sharing, social exchanges are seen as more appropriate, whereas in
tarian CSC (b = 0.10; [-0.14; 0.40]). The index of moderated mediation utilitarian CSCs like ride-sharing monetary exchanges are seen as more
is significant (0.41; [0.04; 0.90]). naturally fitting. Respondents completed a three-item measure cap-
In a second step, we used a moderated moderated mediation ana- turing whether they found a monetary exchange mechanism appro-
lysis with the SPSS Process Macro (Model 11, 5000 bootstrap samples). priate (an example item is “the described event should be based on
In this analysis, the monetary exchange mechanism dummy was the monetary payment.”) and four items measuring whether they found a
independent variable, the hedonic CSC dummy and materialism were social exchange suitable: “the described event should be based on
the moderators, activation of market norms was the mediator, and helping and sharing.” (all rated from 1 = strongly disagree to 7 =
willingness to participate was the dependent variable. We again con- strongly agree). The multi-item scales were reduced to equally-weighted
trolled for respondents’ age, gender, and monthly net household income indices for the analyses. We compared the means across groups using
as standard controls. ANOVAs. The results indicate that respondents perceived a monetary
In line with H2b we find evidence of a moderated moderated exchange mechanism as significantly more adequate in the utilitarian
mediation. The results show a significant and positive three-way in- CSC condition compared to the hedonic CSC condition (Mride-
teraction of the monetary exchange mechanism dummy, the hedonic sharing = 5.8; Mdinner-sharing = 5.3; F (1, 203) = 6.816, p = .010).
CSC, and the individual level of materialism via the activation of Likewise, the social exchange mechanism was perceived as significantly
market exchange norms on willingness to participate (index of mod- more fitting in the hedonic CSC condition than in the utilitarian CSC
erated moderated mediation = 0.55, CI [0.10, 1.12]). More precisely, condition (Mdinner-sharing = 3.7; Mride-sharing = 2.9; F (1, 203) = 13.629,
in the hedonic CSC condition, at a low level of materialism (one stan- p = .000).
dard deviation below the mean), there is a negative indirect effect of Thus, these results from our additional study underline our findings
the monetary exchange mechanism on intention to participate via the from the focus group interviews. Respondents have the intuition that in
activation of market norms (effect = -0.58, CI [-1.16, -0.14]). Similarly, more hedonic CSCs, social exchange norms are suitable whereas in
at a medium level of materialism, the indirect effect of the monetary more utilitarian CSCs, monetary exchanges are more adequate.
exchange mechanism via market norm activation on intention to par- While these first studies were based on hypothetical scenarios of
ticipate is still negative and significant (effect = -0.36, CI [-0.73, sharing-economy internet platforms, the third study tested H3a and
-0.08]). However, at high levels of materialism this negative indirect H3b using the example of offline sharing practices—that is, swap par-
effect turns insignificant (effect = -0.03, CI [-0.23, 0.19]). ties. A special strength of our third study is that, instead of merely
The results of the moderated moderated mediation reveal that the studying behavioral intentions, we observed participants’ real sharing
interactive effect of monetary exchange mechanism and hedonic CSC behaviors in this offline context.
decreases the willingness to participate via a disruption of market norm
activation. Further, the significant three-way interaction indicates that, 4.4. Study 3
as predicted, this negative effect is less pronounced for consumers with
higher levels of materialism as compared to those with lower levels. 4.4.1. Design of study
We conducted a single-factor between-subjects field experiment
4.3. Confound checks (N = 116; monetary vs. social exchange mechanism). A team of 16
student assistants helped to conduct the field experiment. They were
To test whether the two CSCs (i.e., ride-sharing vs. dinner-sharing) asked to organize “swap parties” with small groups of friends of five to
were perceived as similar in their quality (Cronin, Brady, & Hult, 2000; six people. The data were collected through two questionnaires—an
Yang et al., 2005), valuation (Sirdeshmukh, Singh, & Sabol 2002), and online survey that was sent to the participants a week prior to the event
trust (Kennedy, Ferrell, & LeClair 2001), and to replicate the finding and one paper and pencil survey filled out at the end of each swap
from our qualitative study that social/monetary exchanges are seen as party.
more appropriate in hedonic/utilitarian CSCs, we collected additional
data. Participants were 205 US Americans (50.7% male; mean 4.4.2. Data collection and procedure
age = 32.2 years (SD = 13.1)) who were recruited through Amazon The student assistants were randomly allocated (by drawing lots) to
MTurk in February 2020, with 106 participants in the ride-sharing organize a swap party that was either based on negotiating monetary
condition and 99 participants in the dinner-sharing condition. As in the prices for the items or in which participants just brought items that the
previous studies, participants were first provided with a short descrip- others could freely choose to take home without any negotiation or
tion of one of the two hypothetical offers that represented either a monetary payment. At the end of the swap parties, the assistants asked
hedonic service (i.e., a dinner-sharing platform) or a utilitarian service the participants whether they would be willing to donate the leftover
(i.e., a ride-sharing platform). We used exactly the same descriptions of items for a good cause (i.e., the German Red Cross). This willingness to

231
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

donate as a prosocial behavior represents our central dependent vari-


able.

4.4.3. Sample description and measures


The total sample consisted of 116 participants (28.4% male; mean
age = 25.5 years, SD = 4.3) who took part in the swap parties. In total,
21 swap parties were organized (Nmonetary exchange = 10; Nsocial ex-
change = 11). We measured materialism in t1 and our dependent vari-
able as well as our control variables in t2. For the measurement of re-
spondents’ willingness to share leftover items, which represents our
dependent variable, we used a binary single-item question: “Have you
decided to donate the leftover items?” measured as yes or no. We
measured materialism using the same scale as in study 2. In addition,
we measured participants’ perceived atmosphere at the swap parties
using a three-item measure. An example item is “I enjoyed the atmo-
sphere at the event.” Furthermore, we measured participants’ general Fig. 3a. Study 3: Willingness to donate depending on type of exchange me-
attitude toward consumption using a three-item measure based on chanism and level of materialism.
Ozanne and Ballantine (2010)’s conceptualization of anti-consumption.
A sample item is “In our western consumer societies, we have way too interaction between monetary exchange mechanism and individuals’
many things.” We measured both constructs on a 7-point Likert scale materialistic traits on willingness to donate (b = -0.975, 95% CI
with the endpoints of the scale labeled as I do not agree at all and I fully [-1.774, -0.1753], t = -2.389, p = .017; β = -0.0729, p = .001).
agree. Finally, we measured participants’ perceived quality of the items To gain a deeper understanding of the interaction, we conducted a
that they brought to the event. The measurement and scale evaluation floodlight analysis using the Johnson-Neyman technique in SPSS
for all scales are provided in Web Appendix B. PROCESS. Results reveal that the effect of a monetary exchange me-
Participants’ perception of the atmosphere at the event and their chanism on willingness to donate is insignificant for low levels of ma-
attitude toward consumption were included in the analysis as control terialism but turns significant and negative for higher levels of mate-
variables. Results remain stable with and without inclusion of these rialism (above values of 3.29). Further, the analysis indicates that with
controls. We also included respondents’ age, gender, and monthly net increasing levels of materialism, the negative effect becomes stronger.
household income as standard controls. Additional analyses revealed Fig. 3b illustrates the results.
that none of these variables interacted with the treatment variables. We To summarize, in line with H3b, our results indicate that the
also checked whether controlling for the nested structure of the data crowding-out of the willingness to donate caused by the monetary ex-
(individuals are nested in parties) would make a difference. For this change is more pronounced the higher respondents score on the trait of
purpose, we ran fixed-effects regressions and included dummy variables materialism. Interestingly, we find a significant crowding-out for only
for 20 swap parties. The effects of these dummy variables were insig- the part of the sample that can be classified as highly materialistic.
nificant. Thus, this study generates tentative support for the proposition that
participating in monetary exchanges in the sharing economy may
4.4.4. Results crowd out materialistic individuals’ prosocial behaviors.
As a first step, we analyzed the effect of the experimental treatment We wondered whether participants, being aware of the exchange
on willingness to share leftover items using a cross-tabulation analysis. mechanisms before the event, decided to bring items of higher quality if
The results show that, in line with our theorizing, the willingness to they were invited to a swap party that used a monetary exchange me-
donate leftover items was significantly higher in the social exchange chanism. Conceivably, if they knew that prices would be negotiated and
group than in the monetary exchange group (75.8% vs. 48.1%, x2 (1, they would receive a monetary payment for their items, they would be
N = 116) = 9.465, p = .002), providing convergent support for H3a. more willing to bring high-quality products. This, in turn, might explain
Furthermore, as proposed in H3b, we expect the effect of the ex- why they would be less willing to donate the leftover items after the
change mechanism to also differ for high and low materialists. To de- party and thus might be a confounding factor in our study. To exclude
scriptively explore the moderating role of materialism, we partitioned
the sample using a median split into high and low materialists (the
median in the sample is 3.56). The results of this descriptive analysis
are displayed in Fig. 3a.
We find a significant difference in the willingness to donate leftover
items across the groups. The figure illustrates that for low materialists,
the percentage of respondents who were willing to donate the leftover
items does not differ between the monetary and the social exchange
group. However, for the high materialists, an interesting difference in
the willingness to donate can be observed between the groups. While
80.8% of the high materialists in the social exchange group were
willing to share the leftover items, only 36.7% were willing to do so in
the monetary exchange group.
To formally test H3b, we used SPSS PROCESS. We included in-
dividuals’ willingness to donate as our dependent variable. As in-
dependent variables, we included a dummy for monetary exchange (1
for monetary exchange, 0 for social exchange) and an equally weighted
index of all materialism items. We controlled for individuals’ perception
of the atmosphere at the swap parties, individuals’ general attitude
towards consumption and, respondents’ age, gender, and monthly net
household income. The regression analysis reveals a significant Fig. 3b. Study 3: Floodlight analyses.

232
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

this possibility, we tested whether the experimental group (i.e., differences in consumers in the sharing economy, but to the knowledge
monetary vs. social exchange) had a significant effect on participants’ about materialistic individuals in general. Further, our third study re-
perceptions of the quality of the items brought. Although the difference veals that high and low materialists have very different reactions when
was small, the effect was significant. However, it was opposite to what engaging in monetary exchanges in the sharing economy context. While
we expected: the perceived quality of items brought was significantly for high materialists the monetary exchange reduced their prosocial
higher in the social exchange group than in the monetary exchange behavior, this was not the case for those respondents with low levels of
group (Msocial exchange = 4.63, Mmonetary exchange = 4.02; p = .027). Still, materialism. Follow-up studies should seek to understand the psycho-
in both groups the means were above the scale midpoint of 4 and logical mechanisms that are at work here. Sensemaking theory (Weick,
controlling for the quality did not affect the model results. Thus, we 1995) could provide an interesting perspective: which rationales do
expect that this was not a confounding factor in our experiment. high versus low materialists apply to make sense of varying exchange
mechanisms, and how does this application affect their prosocial be-
5. General discussion haviors in the longer run?
Our three studies also have implications for entrepreneurs and
In our studies, we find interesting evidence for the assumption that managers in the sharing economy. Practitioners need to remember that
monetary exchanges in the sharing economy may lead to very different offers in the sharing economy must be designed with great caution.
outcomes than social exchanges. Studies 1 and 2 demonstrate that a More specifically, the exchange mechanisms applied in the business
match between exchange mechanisms and consumption and service models have to match the motives and the underlying relationship
contexts is an important determinant of willingness to participate in the expectations of potential users and participants. It is crucial for en-
sharing economy, especially for individuals with a low level of mate- trepreneurs and managers to understand that if the combination of type
rialism. Study 3 reveals that participation in monetary exchanges in the of exchange mechanism and type of consumption and service context is
sharing economy may lead to decreased prosocial behaviors, especially not carefully considered, a mismatch might occur, potentially leading
for highly materialistic individuals. to decreased willingness to participate in the newly developed business
Our results generate four key conceptual contributions. First, our model.
work contributes to micro-level research on the sharing economy. Study 3 generates results that have potential societal consequences.
Specifically, our results suggest that individuals’ willingness to parti- Findings suggest that for groups of consumers who are highly materi-
cipate in the sharing economy will increase if a match occurs between alistic, engaging in monetary exchanges in the sharing economy might
type of exchange mechanism and CSC. Individuals who participate in reduce their subsequent willingness to share resources with others. We
monetary exchanges in hedonic CSCs will be less willing to participate therefore have to ask whether the use of market-pricing business
in such offers owing to a disruption of market norm activation. models in the sharing economy will lead to a subsequent erosion of
Second, we contribute to the research on RMT (Fiske, 1991, 1992; helping and sharing. In other words, will Sandel’s claim that we have
Fiske & Haslam, 1997, 2005; Haslam & Fiske, 1999). The results of our moved from “having a market economy” to “being a market society”
focus group interviews as well as our results from studies 1 and 2 reveal prove true?
that consumers’ perceptions of CSC as hedonic versus utilitarian de- Further research is needed to better understand these issues. While
termine their perceptions of the relationship as either social or eco- we were able to observe real behavior in our second study, the study
nomic. This finding is an interesting and previously unaddressed topic. featured only one very specific social practice—a swap party. Future
Future research could take this study as a starting point and explore in research should replicate the findings using varying practices, and, if
more depth how consumers perceive the consumption and service possible, in longitudinal settings that could capture a potential erosion
contexts that are created in the sharing economy. Obviously, the of social norms over time.
boundaries between utilitarian and hedonic consumption and service
contexts increasingly blur and their intersection provides potential for Funding
conflict but also for meaningful research that can help us to understand
how people make sense of their environments. This research did not receive any specific grant from funding
Third, our findings provide an empirical test of the matches or agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.
mismatches between monetary and social exchange mechanisms and
hedonic and utilitarian consumption and service contexts in line with Declaration of Competing Interest
SET (Cropanzano & Mitchell, 2005). Such mismatches obviously play
an important role in the sharing economy. Our first study generates The authors declare that they have no known competing financial
evidence for such effects and indicates that individuals might try to interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influ-
avoid situations of mismatches (e.g., by reducing their willingness to ence the work reported in this paper.
participate). Future research should explore the psychological me-
chanisms underlying these findings. Potential avenues to follow include References
the explicit measurement of disfluencies caused by mismatches, the
seeking of an understanding of a potential (re-)categorization of re- Acquier, A., Daudigeos, T., & Pinkse, J. (2017). Promises and paradoxes of the sharing
lationships according to exchange mechanisms, and other cognitive and economy: An organizing framework. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 125,
emotional reactions to these conflicts. Further, it would be interesting 1–10.
Akbar, P., Mai, R., & Hoffmann, S. (2016). When do materialistic consumers join com-
investigate the processes of self-selection that may take place. Which mercial sharing systems. Journal of Business Research, 69(10), 4215–4224.
consumers would choose to participate in business models such as Avital, M., Carroll, J. M., Hjalmarsson, A., Levina, N., Malhotra, A., & Sundarajan, A.
Airbnb and which ones would go for Couchsurfing? Which individual (2015). The sharing economy: Friend or foe? In Proceedings of the 36th International
Conference on Information Systems. Fort Worth, Texas, USA.
difference factors characterize these potentially different segments of Babin, B. J., Darden, W. R., & Griffin, M. (1994). Work and/or fun: Measuring hedonic
users? and utilitarian shopping value. Journal of Consumer Research, 20(4), 644–656.
Fourth, we contribute to research on the role of the trait of mate- Baker, D. (2014). Don’t buy the ‘sharing economy’ hype: Aibnb and Uber are facilitating
ripoffs. The Guardian. https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2014/may/
rialism. Our first two studies reveal that the positive effects of matches 27/airbnb-uber-taxes-regulation (accessed September 10, 2017).
between exchange mechanisms and consumption and service contexts Bardhi, F., & Eckhardt, G. M. (2012). Access-based consumption: The case of car sharing.
are less pronounced for highly materialistic individuals owing to a Journal of Consumer Research, 39(4), 881–898.
Batra, R., & Ahtola, O. T. (1991). Measuring the hedonic and utilitarian sources of con-
notoriously high activation of market norms in these individuals. This
sumer attitudes. Marketing Letters, 2(2), 159–170.
result contributes not only to our understanding of individual

233
I. Küper and L.M. Edinger-Schons Journal of Business Research 121 (2020) 223–234

Belk, R. W. (1985). Materialism: Trait aspects of living in the material world. Journal of John, N. A. (2017). The age of sharing. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press.
Consumer Research, 12(3), 265–280. Kasser, T. E., & Kanner, A. D. (2004). Psychology and consumer culture: The struggle for a
Belk, R. W. (2007). Why not share rather than own? The ANNALS of the American Academy good life in a materialistic world. Washington, DC: American Psychological Association.
of Political and Social Science, 611(1), 126–140. Kennedy, M. S., Ferrell, L. K., & LeClair, D. T. (2001). Consumers’ trust of salesperson and
Belk, R. W. (2010). Sharing. Journal of Consumer Research, 36(5), 715–734. manufacturer: An empirical study. Journal of Business Research, 51(1), 73–86.
Belk, R. W. (2014a). Sharing versus pseudo-sharing in web 2.0. Anthropologist, 18(1), Kilbourne, W., & Pickett, G. (2008). How materialism affects environmental beliefs,
7–23. concern, and environmentally responsible behavior. Journal of Business Research, 61,
Belk, R. W. (2014b). You are what you can access: Sharing and collaborative consumption 885–893.
online. Journal of Business Research, 67(8), 1595–1600. Lamberton, C. P., & Rose, R. L. (2012). When is ours better than mine? A framework for
Blau, P. M. (1964). Exchange and power in social life. New York: John Wiley. understanding and altering participation in commercial sharing systems. Journal of
Bock, G., Zmud, R. W., Kim, Y., & Lee, J. (2005). Behavioral intention formation in Marketing, 76(4), 109–125.
knowledge sharing: Examining the roles of extrinsic motivators, social-psychological Levitt, M. J., Weber, R. A., Clark, M. C., & McDonnell, P. (1985). Reciprocity of exchange
forces, and organizational climate. MIS Quarterly, 29(1), 87–111. in toddler sharing behavior. Developmental Psychology, 21(1), 122–123.
Botsman, R., & Rogers, R. (2011). What’s mine is yours: The rise of collaborative consump- Mannak, R., de Ridder, H., & Keyson, D. V. (2004). The human side of sharing in peer-to-peer
tion. New York: HarperCollins. networks. In Proceedings of the 2nd European Union symposium on ambient intelligence.
Bucher, E., Fieseler, C., & Lutz, C. (2016). What’s mine is yours (for a nominal fee) – Martin, C. J. (2016). The sharing economy: A pathway to sustainability or a nightmarish
Exploring the spectrum of utilitarian to altruistic motives for internet-mediated form of neoliberal capitalism? Ecological Economics, 12, 149–159.
sharing. Computers in Human Behavior, 62, 316–326. McGraw, A. P., & Tetlock, P. E. (2005). Taboo trade-offs, relational framing, and the
Buczynski, B. (2013). Sharing is good: How to save money, time and resources through col- acceptability of exchanges. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 15(1), 2–15.
laborative consumption. Gabriola Island, British Columbia: New Society Publishers. Ozanne, L. K., & Ballantine, P. W. (2010). Sharing as a form of anti-consumption? An
Cheng, M. (2016). Sharing economy: A review and agenda for future research. examination of toy library users. Journal of Consumer Behavior, 9(6), 485–498.
International Journal of Hospitality Management, 57, 60–70. Polanyi, R. (1944). The great transformation: Economic and political origins of our time.
Cohen, B., & Kietzmann, J. (2014). Ride on! Mobility business models for the sharing Boston, MA: Beacon Press.
economy. Organization & Environment, 27(3), 279–296. Richins, M. L., & Dawson, S. (1992). A consumer values orientation for materialism and
Cronin, J. J., Jr, Brady, M. K., & Hult, G. T. M. (2000). Assessing the effects of quality, its measurement: Scale development and validation. Journal of Consumer Research,
value, and customer satisfaction on consumer behavioral intentions in service en- 19(3), 303–316.
vironments. Journal of Retailing, 76(2), 193–218. Sandel, M. J. (2012). What money can't buy: The moral limits of markets. Straus and Giroux,
Cropanzano, R., & Mitchell, M. S. (2005). Social exchange theory: An interdisciplinary New York: Farrar.
review. Journal of Management, 31(6), 874–900. Schor, J. B. (2014). Debating the sharing economy. Great Transition Initiative. http://
Csikszentmihalyi, M., & Rochberg-Halton, E. (1978). The meaning of things: Domestic www.greattransition.org/publication/debating-the-sharing-economy (accessed
symbols and the self. Cambridge: University Press. October 5, 2017).
Davidson, A., Habibi, M. R., & Laroche, M. (2018). Materialism and the sharing economy: Schor, J. B., & Fitzmaurice, C. J. (2015). Collaborating and connecting: The emergence of
A cross-cultural study of American and Indian consumers. Journal of Business the sharing economy. In L. A. Reisch, & J. Thøgersen (Eds.). Handbook of research on
Research, 82, 364–372. sustainable consumption (pp. 410–425). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing
Dhar, R., & Wertenbroch, K. (2000). Consumer choice between hedonic and utilitarian Limited.
goods. Journal of Marketing Research, 37(1), 60–71. Schwartz, S. H. (1970). Elicitation of moral obligation and self-sacrificing behavior: An
Dillahunt, T. A., & Malone A. R. (2015). The promise of the sharing economy among experimental study of volunteering to be a bone marrow donor. Journal of Personality
disadvantaged communities. In Proceedings of the 33rd Annual ACM Conference on and Social Psychology, 15(4), 283–293.
Human Factors in Computing Systems (pp. 2285–2294). Seoul, Republic of Korea. Scaraboto, D. (2015). Selling, sharing, and everything in between: The hybrid economies
Dürrenberger, G., Kastenholz, H., & Behringer, J. (1999). Integrated assessment focus of collaborative networks. Journal of Consumer Research, 42(1), 152–176.
groups: Bridging the gap between science and policy? Science and Public Policy, 26(5), Shrum, L. J., Wong, N., Arif, F., Chugani, S. K., Gunz, A., Lowrey, T. M., et al. (2013).
341–349. Reconceptualizing materialism as identity goal pursuits: Functions, processes, and
Eckhardt, G. M., Houston, M. B., Jiang, B., Lamberton, C., Rindfleisch, A., & Zervas, G. consequences. Journal of Business Research, 66(8), 1179–1185.
(2019). Marketing in the sharing economy. Journal of Marketing, 83(5), 5–27. Sirdeshmukh, D., Singh, J., & Sabol, B. (2002). Consumer trust, value, and loyalty in
Eckhardt, G. M., & Bardhi, F. (2016). The Relationship between Access Practices and relational exchanges. Journal of Marketing, 66(1), 15–37.
Economic Systems. Journal of the Association for Consumer Research, 1(2), 210–225. Sundararajan, A. (2019). Commentary: The twilight of brand and consumerism? Digital
Etter, M., Fieseler, C., & Whelan, G. (2019). Sharing Economy, Sharing Responsibility? trust, cultural meaning, and the quest for connection in the sharing economy. Journal
Corporate Social Responsibility in the Digital Age. Journal of Business Ethics, 159(4), of Marketing, 83(5), 32–35.
935–942. Tetlock, P. E. (2003). Thinking the unthinkable: Sacred values and taboo cognitions.
Fiske, A. P. (1991). Structures of social life: The four elementary forms of human relations. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 7(7), 320–324.
New York: Free Press. Van der Heijden, H. (2004). User acceptance of hedonic information systems. MIS
Fiske, A. P. (1992). The four elementary forms of sociality: Framework for a unified Quarterly, 28(4), 695–704.
theory of social relations. Psychological Review, 99(4), 689–723. Voss, K. E., Spangenberg, E. R., & Grohmann, B. (2003). Measuring the hedonic and
Fiske, A. P., & Haslam, N. (1996). Social cognition is thinking about relationships. Current utilitarian dimensions of consumer attitude. Journal of Marketing Research, 40(3),
Directions in Psychological Science, 5(5), 143–148. 310–320.
Fiske, A. P., & Haslam, N. (1997). The structure of social substitutions: A test of relational Weick, K. E. (1995). Sensemaking in organizations. London: Sage.
models theory. European Journal of Social Psychology, 27(6), 725–729. Yang, Z., Cai, S., Zhou, Z., & Zhou, N. (2005). Development and validation of an in-
Fiske, A. P., & Haslam, N. (2005). The four basic social bonds: Structures for coordinating strument to measure user perceived service quality of information presenting web
interaction. In M. Baldwin (Ed.). Interpersonal Cognition (pp. 267–298). New York: portals. Information & Management, 42(4), 575–589.
The Guilford Press.
Frey, B. S., & Jegen, R. (2001). Motivational interactions: Effects on behaviour. Annales Inken Küper is a Ph.D. candidate at the University of Mannheim, Germany. She holds a
d'Economie et de Statistique, 63, 131–153. Master of Science in Economics and Business Administration from the University of
Ger, G., & Belk, R. W. (1990). Measuring and comparing materialism cross-culturally. Bochum, Germany. Her research focuses on behavioral appeals and sharing-based busi-
Advances in Consumer Research, 17(1), 186–192. ness models. She studies in how far marketing strategies and business models of the future
Habibi, M. R., Davidson, A., & Laroche, M. (2016). What managers should know about the can increase individuals’ sustainable behavior using qualitative and quantitative methods.
sharing economy. Business Horizons, 60(1), 113–121.
Hamari, J., Sjöklint, M., & Ukkonen, A. (2015). The sharing economy: Why people par-
Laura Marie Edinger-Schons is Professor of Sustainable Business at the University of
ticipate in collaborative consumption. Journal of the Association for Information Science
and Technology, 67(9), 2047–2059. Mannheim. In her research she focuses on the question how organizations (from for profit
Haslam, N. (1994). Categories of social relationship. Cognition, 53(1), 59–90. to non-profit) can contribute to sustainable development as defined in the United Nations
Haslam, N. (2004). Relational models theory: A contemporary overview. Hove, UK: Sustainable Development Goals. Her work has been published in renowned academic
Psychology Press. journals including Journal of Marketing, Journal of Consumer Psychology, Journal of the
Academy of Marketing Science, and Journal of Business Ethics.
Haslam, N., & Fiske, A. P. (1999). Relational models theory: A confirmatory factor ana-
lysis. Personal Relationships, 6(2), 241–250.
Heyman, J., & Ariely, D. (2004). Effort for payment: A tale of two markets. Psychological
Science, 15(11), 787–793. She received the Overall Best Paper Award at the 2014 Winter AMA, was voted into the
Holbrook, M. B., & Hirschman, E. C. (1982). The experiential aspects of consumption: Top Ten Junior Academics 2015 (by Zeit and academics), and received the German
Consumer fantasies, feelings, and fun. Journal of Consumer Research, 9(2), 132–140. Science Award 2016 for the Best Collaboration with Private Business. For her teaching,
Jenkins, R., Molesworth, M., & Scullion, R. (2014). The messy social lives of objects: Inter- she received the AACSB Innovations that Inspire Award 2017. For her habilitation thesis
personal borrowing and the ambiguity of possession and ownership. Journal of she received the Wolfgang-Ritter Award 2017, the Roman Herzog Research Award 2018
Consumer Behaviour, 13(2), 131–139. as well as the Max Weber Award for Business Ethics 2018. In 2019, she was voted into the
Jiang, Y., & Wang, C. L. (2006). The impact of affect on service quality and satisfaction: Top 40 under 40 by the magazine Capital.
The moderation of service contexts. Journal of Services Marketing, 20(4), 212–218.

234

You might also like