Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 17

Int. J.

Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

International Journal of Production Economics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ijpe

Recovering and remanufacturing to fulfill EPR regulation in the presence of


secondary market
Jian Cao a, b, Sisi Wu c, *, Sanjay Kumar d
a
School of Management, Zhejiang University of Technology, Hangzhou, 310023, China
b
Center for Global & Regional Environmental Research, The University of Iowa, Iowa City, 52242, United States
c
School of Economics and Management, Zhejiang University of Science and Technology, Hangzhou, 310023, China
d
College of Business, Valparaiso University, Valparaiso, 46383, United States

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: To relieve competitive pressure from the secondary market and increase customer demand, producers may
Remanufacturing choose to recover and remanufacture used products. Extended Producer Responsibility (EPR) regulations have
EPR regulation been formulated to alleviate the waste-disposal problem, which may also affect the development of remanu­
Secondary market
facturing industry. We investigate how EPR affects the remanufacturing decision and analyze related perfor­
Used product
mance, including collection rate and producer profit. Our results demonstrate that EPR regulation is beneficial
during the early development phase of remanufacturing industry and help improve the collection rate. However,
our analyses also reveal that EPR may limit the producer’s profits, and stringent collection targets inhibit the
producer from remanufacturing. In addition, we find that high-durability used original/remanufactured products
are not conducive for remanufacturing. The model is calibrated with field-collected heavy truck engine rema­
nufacturing data. Three Model Extensions covering comprehensive regulation, duopoly competition, and recy­
cling used original products supplement the findings.

1. Introduction e-commerce platforms (e.g., Amazon and eBay).


The EPR regulations target both nondurable and durable products.
A variety of waste-disposal legislations have been enacted to alle­ Nondurable products (e.g., packaging, pharmaceuticals, and paints) are
viate environmental and social problems associated with discarded discarded after use. Durable products (e.g., automobiles, heavy ma­
products all over the world. Extended Producer Responsibility (EPR) chinery, electrical and electronic products), however, can enter the
regulations are the most common waste-disposal legislations employed secondary market where used products are resold and rebought by end
worldwide. Examples include the European Union (EU)’s WEEE Direc­ consumers after a portion of their useful life (Huang et al., 2019; Fu
tive, Michigan Beverage Container Deposit Law, and End-of-Life Vehicle et al., 2022). For instance, trading used automobiles in the secondary
Recycling Law in Japan. The legislation stipulates that a producer’s market is common. In this case, durable-goods producers face compe­
responsibility is not limited to production and extends to the entire life tition from the secondary market (Huang et al., 2014). Producers
cycle of a product, particularly to collecting and adequately disposing/ increasingly offer trade-in/buyback programs to recapture used prod­
treating their discarded products (Corsini et al., 2017; Gui, 2020; Shan ucts and increase customer demand. The collected products are used for
et al., 2021). Currently, EPR-based take-back legislation has been widely remanufacturing, recycling, and other types of product reuse (Li and Xu,
implemented in developed countries (e.g., the United States, Germany, 2015; Dong et al., 2023). Remanufacturing can reuse the durable core
and France) to manage the collection and recycling of waste after the components of returned products, and restore their quality and perfor­
consumption of certain products. Producers who fail to comply with EPR mance (Cole et al., 2017; Vedantam and Iyer, 2021). Automobile com­
regulations could be severely punished. For example, according to Law panies such as Toyota, BMW, Mercedes-Benz, and Ford often collect
2020–105 on Anti-Waste and Circular Economy, France imposes fines on their used products through trade-in programs and then sell them after
producers who do not comply with EPR and prohibit sales of products refurbishing and remanufacturing (Lacourbe, 2016; Li et al., 2019).
that fail to meet EPR requirements in France through cross-border Xerox remanufactures products returned from trade-in programs, which

* Corresponding author. Zhejiang University of Science and Technology, Hangzhou 310012, China.
E-mail address: sswu@zust.edu.cn (S. Wu).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2023.108933
Received 22 September 2022; Received in revised form 30 May 2023; Accepted 31 May 2023
Available online 7 June 2023
0925-5273/© 2023 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

saves them millions of dollars each year (Li and Xu, 2015). producer profit) would be. Some literature explores the remanufacturing
Remanufacturing can play a vital role in increasing profit as it strategy under EPR regulations and analyzes the effect of EPR regula­
potentially saves labor, raw material, and energy costs (Krystofik and tions (Esenduran et al., 2016; Chen and Ulya, 2019; Liu et al., 2022).
Gaustad, 2018; Nie et al., 2021). Examples from the industry show that Esenduran et al. (2016) find that take-back legislation with collection
there is a large market for remanufactured products. According to a targets may or may not increase remanufacturing, which depends on its
survey conducted by Remanufacturing Central in 2005, the estimated implementation, and the total environmental impact might increase as
total annual sales of 73,000 remanufacturing firms in the United States the collection target increases. However, these studies do not consider
was $53 billion in 1997 (Atasu et al., 2008). As a remanufacturing giant, the secondary market. In the presence of a secondary market, the effect
Caterpillar’s 20% of parts sold globally are remanufactured parts, and of EPR regulation on remanufacturing is more nuanced and deserves
the annual revenue of its remanufacturing business exceeded $4 billion further exploration.
in 2012. ReCellular, Inc. Remanufactures millions of products annually, Some studies investigate the problems of recovering used products
occupying more than 50% of the market share (Li et al., 2016). As the from the secondary market (Xiao, 2017; Alev et al., 2020; Dong et al.,
remanufacturing literature (Geyer et al., 2007; Chen and Chen, 2019; 2023), while they do not consider remanufacturing those used products.
Ramirez et al., 2020) points out, similar successful examples can be Alev et al. (2020) analyze the effect of EPR legislation on the secondary
found in many industries; for instance, those of Cummins, BMW, market interference from recovering used products and show that EPR
Volkswagen, and Xerox indicate that remanufacturing can be profitable. may reduce or increase secondary market interference by producers. Li
Although recovering and remanufacturing used products benefit et al. (2019) explore the producer strategy of remanufacturing used
enterprises, the operations involved encounter many challenges. Pro­ products collected through a trade-in program. They assume that the
ducers make decisions primarily to improve their profits. The central producer resells remanufactured products to a separate secondary
question durable-goods producers seem to face is, “Whether and how do market. In contrast, we assume that the producer sells those together
they benefit from recovering and remanufacturing used products?” In with new products.
the presence of a secondary market, some potential links exist between Furthermore, Li et al. (2009) mainly research the effect of the
customer demand, supply, recovery, and remanufacturing. The separate secondary market on trade-in remanufacturing decisions and
customer demand for remanufactured products is affected by the price ignore the impact of EPR regulation on remanufacturing. In sum, the
and supply. However, the supply of remanufactured products is con­ problem of remanufacturing used products collected from the secondary
strained by the volume of used products collected by producers. The market under EPR regulation requires further research. To fill this gap,
decision to collect and remanufacture used products is complex, and we aim to address these problems explicitly and provide firms and
producers need to understand the interaction mechanisms between governments with theoretical guidelines for practical operations.
customer demand, supply, recovery, and remanufacturing. However, This study aims to answer the following questions.
managers have little guidance, and there is limited research on this
issue. (1) What is the durable-goods producer’s optimal strategy for
Many EU countries have introduced EPR-based take-back legislation recovering and remanufacturing used products? We consider a
into the field of reuse/remanufacturing. For instance, the European secondary market, and the producer can either choose to do
Parliament suggested a 5% reuse target during the most recent recast of nothing or buyback used products from the secondary market and
the WEEE Directive. The European Environmental Bureau, RREUSE, then remanufacture and sell those together with new products.
ComputerAid, ACR+, and other environmental organizations support (2) If the government implements EPR regulation (setting collection
the target (Esenduran et al., 2016). However, it is unclear whether the targets for new and remanufactured products), what should the
producers need to be responsible for collecting and properly disposing of producer do to fulfill EPR obligations and achieve maximum
their discarded reused/remanufactured products. As with the discarded profits? Especially whether and how a producer could utilize EOL
original products, the discarded reused/remanufactured products also and used products to meet collection targets.
cause damage to the environment. Collecting and properly disposing (3) How does EPR regulation affect the producer’s remanufacturing
reused/remanufactured products is critical. Therefore, we consider that strategy? Do EPR regulations promote or hinder remanufacturing
remanufactured products should also be within the scope of EPR su­ and related performance improvement?
pervision; that is, the producer is responsible for collecting end-of-life
(EOL) remanufactured products and disposing them properly. Howev­ To further advance understanding of the remanufacturing decision
er, the recovery of remanufactured products is ignored in the actual and the effect of EPR on remanufacturing, we consider a durable-goods
operation and existing literature. We regard a remanufactured product producer that does not remanufacture without EPR regulations
as another new product that faces the same EPR regulation as the new (benchmark model, Model N), remanufacture without EPR regulations
product. (Model R), or remanufacture under EPR regulations (Model RE). Model
The implementation details of EPR-based take-back legislation N reveals that the existence of used products may reduce the producer’s
worldwide are quite diverse. Some involve setting a collection rate profit. Therefore, we develop Model R to further study whether and how
target, and the target is often defined as a minimum fraction of sales that the producer engages in remanufacturing used products to increase
producers are obliged to collect and dispose of. For example, the profits. Then considering implementing EPR regulations on both new
collection rate target for waste products was 45% for European Union in and remanufactured products, the impact of EPR regulations on rema­
2016, which was subsequently raised to 65% in 2019. Products recycled nufacturing strategies is analyzed in Model RE. We further compare and
under the EPR initiatives are mainly EOL products (Hickle, 2014; analyze the models from the perspectives of EPR regulation impacts,
Esenduran et al., 2016; Ameli et al., 2019). But EPR does not explicitly secondary market involvement, collection rate, and producer profit.
stipulate that used products cannot be recycled. In other words, a pro­ To the best of our knowledge, this paper is the first to research
ducer may recover used products in working conditions from the sec­ producers’ remanufacturing strategies and how EPR regulations affect
ondary market to fulfill EPR obligations (Alev et al., 2020). remanufacturing and related performance in the presence of a secondary
From the government’s perspective, the main objective of EPR market. Our analysis and results indicate producers’ recovery (of used
regulation (e.g., setting a collection target) is to reduce the amount of and end-of-life items) and production strategies vary in different
waste going to landfills by promoting product take-back. While it seems remanufacturing stages. High-durability used original/remanufactured
that EPR regulation would increase collection levels, it is not clear what products are not conducive to remanufacturing. With strict EPR regu­
the impact of EPR regulation on remanufacturing and related perfor­ lations by regulatory bodies of government, the producers may need to
mance (e.g., secondary market involvement, collection rate, and collect EOL products to make up for the insufficient collection.

2
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

Additionally, the producers may meet the collection target by recycling coordination decisions in a closed-loop supply chain when remanu­
all EOL products. Our results also suggest that EPR regulations help the facturing costs are disrupted. Similarly, Li et al. (2020) investigated the
remanufacturing industry in its nascent and early development stages, different acquisition strategies of used products and analyzed the pricing
leading to a higher collection rate. However, EPR regulations may be strategies for new and remanufactured products.
detrimental to increasing producer profits, and stringent collection tar­ Moreover, some studies highlight the core acquisition decisions for
gets inhibit the producer from remanufacturing. remanufacturing. Cai et al. (2014) explored the core acquisition problem
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 outlines for a manufacturing/remanufacturing system at two (high and low)
relevant literature; we outline the model and benchmark analysis in quality conditions. Various acquiring methods have been addressed,
Section 3; Section 4 provides the decision models for remanufacturing including collecting used products (Shi et al., 2011; Li et al., 2019) and
and EPR; Section 5 presents comparative analysis and case study; Sec­ recovering EOL products (Meng et al., 2017; Ramirez et al., 2020). The
tion 6 concludes the research. literature on collecting used products for remanufacturing is more
relevant to our work. Robotis et al. (2012) investigated the impact of the
2. Literature review collected used product quality on the remanufacturing cost and pro­
duction investments. Cole et al. (2017) compared the buyback and
Three streams of work are closely related to our study: (1) durable trade-in policies for acquiring used products for remanufacturing.
goods and secondary market; (2) remanufacturing; and (3) recycling Huang et al. (2019) considered two recycling approaches for trade-in
legislation. rebates to collect used products. However, the extant literature rarely
considers the existence of secondary markets.
2.1. Research on durable goods and secondary market Other literature focuses on the independent remanufacturers (Ors­
demir et al., 2014; Huang and Wang, 2019), while our work is related to
A rich stream of literature investigates issues related to durable studies that assume that the original producer (e.g., Caterpillar, Cum­
goods and secondary markets. Some papers explore the secondary mins, and SANY Heavy Industry) implements remanufacturing (Shi
market cannibalization problem that reduces firms’ new product sales et al., 2011; Zhou et al., 2013; Liu et al., 2018). In general, the main
and profits (Ishihara and Ching, 2019; Fu et al., 2022). For example, the distinguishing features between past papers and our work are as follows:
secondary trading of used goods in the automobile industry caused a (1) we consider the interaction between remanufacturing and the sec­
35% drop in retailers’ profitability (Chen et al., 2013). Strategic and ondary market, and (2) we analyze the producer’s production strategy
operational decision-making issues regarding the secondary market when new, remanufactured, and used products are simultaneously
have also been analyzed in various studies (Angelus, 2011; Huang et al., available on the market.
2019). Xiong et al. (2016) investigated the effects of manufacturers’
upgrading strategy on the decision to enter the secondary market and 2.3. Research on recycling legislation
established the optimal entry conditions. Li et al. (2019) analyzed the
original equipment manufacturers’ pricing, trade-in remanufacturing, Economics researchers have extensively studied the interactions
and entry decisions in the presence of a secondary market. between product recycling and environmental legislation. Hong et al.
Furthermore, several papers highlight enterprises’ strategies in (2016) examined the impacts of government subsidies on recycling
responding to secondary market competition. Oraiopoulos et al. (2012) electronic scrap products in reverse supply chains. Chen and Ulya
studied the original equipment manufacturers’ relicensing strategy and (2019) investigated green supply chain members’ recycling and rema­
the conditions that favor stimulating or deterring the secondary market. nufacturing strategies under a reward-penalty mechanism. The form of
Lacourbe (2016) explored the implications of exporting used durable take-back legislation relevant to our work primarily includes setting a
products to international secondary markets and found this practice may collection rate target (Esenduran et al., 2016; Alev et al., 2020). Esen­
significantly stimulate new product leases in the home market. Fu et al. duran et al. (2016) analyzed how the legislation with collection and
(2022) show that producers with sufficiently low product reliability can reuse targets affects the collection and remanufacturing decisions. In
use secondary market interference to avoid cannibalization from used addition, some studies compare the different forms of product take-back
products. A particularly relevant stream of the literature suggests pro­ legislation. Atasu et al. (2013a) investigated the implementation of
ducers can use buybacks, trade-ins, or remanufacturing strategies to manufacturer-operated and state-operated take-back legislation. Shan
counter the adverse effects of the secondary market (Xiao, 2017; Li et al., et al. (2021) compared the advanced recycling fee, pre-disposal fee, and
2019; Huang et al., 2023). Dong et al. (2023) investigated the impact of EPR legislation from the perspective of the manufacturer, the product’s
the secondary market on the choice of used product collection policies environmental impact, and social welfare.
and found that the buyback policy can effectively mitigate secondary The EPR system is a powerful tool for the government to implement
market competition. environmental regulations (Nnorom and Osibanjo, 2008; Kiddee et al.,
Our work is closest to Alev et al. (2020) among the related literature. 2013; Sun et al., 2022). Some papers focus on the effects of EPR legis­
They assume the producer interferes with the secondary market by lation on enterprises’ recovery and remanufacturing strategies. Jacobs
recovering and discarding used products. Unlike them, we consider the and Subramanian (2012) studied how to share the responsibility of
remanufacturing of used products collected from the secondary market product recycling under EPR to improve the total profit in the supply
and study the effect of remanufacturing strategies on the secondary chain. Johnson and McCarthy (2014) explored firms’ remanufacturing
market (e.g., consumer demand) and related performance (e.g., collec­ production plans through mathematical modeling in the context of EPR
tion rate and producer profit). legislation. Furthermore, a significant number of articles investigate the
performance of EPR legislation. Zhou et al. (2017) show that EPR
2.2. Research on remanufacturing legislation improves environmental performance but decreases the
manufacturers’ and recyclers’ total profits. Alev et al. (2020) investi­
A stream of literature on remanufacturing implementation explores gated a durable goods producers’ secondary market strategy under EPR
the strategic management issues such as pricing (Ferrer and Swamina­ and found EPR could reduce or increase producers’ secondary market
than, 2010; Abbey and Blackburn, 2015) and production decisions interference.
(Ferguson et al., 2009; Calmon and Graves, 2017) for new and rema­ However, to the best of our knowledge, the literature does not
nufactured products. Liu et al. (2018) explored the optimal production consider the effects of EPR regulations on remanufacturing strategies
and pricing strategies for a monopolistic manufacturer engaged in under the secondary market. Furthermore, existing EPR-based envi­
remanufacturing. Wu et al. (2018) studied the production and ronmental legislations treat the original product as the supervision

3
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

object (Shi et al., 2011). This article also includes remanufactured how the producer should recover and remanufacture used products. By
products within the scope of EPR supervision. comparing Model R and Model N, we explore whether remanufacturing
In summary, we contribute to the literature by analyzing a pro­ alleviates the secondary market competition and improves producer
ducer’s remanufacturing strategies and how EPR regulations affect profits. Finally, the impact of EPR regulations on remanufacturing sec­
remanufacturing and related performance in the presence of a secondary ondary market and related performance can be obtained by comparing
market. We find that existing research on remanufacturing and EPR has Model RE and Model R.
ignored the existence of the secondary market, thereby exaggerating the
product scope suitable for remanufacturing and the benefits of EPR 3.2. Model assumptions
regulations.
3.2.1. Product characteristics
3. Model and benchmark analysis The producer produces new and remanufactured products. The unit
cost of producing a new and remanufactured product is cn and cr ,
3.1. Model framework respectively. Remanufacturing production consumes fewer resources
(material and energy) than new products (Savaskan et al., 2004; Wu and
We consider a profit-maximizing producer that sells a durable Zhou, 2019). Therefore, 0 < cr < cn < 1. A summary of the notation is
product with two periods of useful life. The product reaches its end-of- shown in Table 1.
life at the end of two periods (Zhou et al., 2017; Alev et al., 2020). We The durability of new, used original, remanufactured, and used
first outline the product life flow (see Fig. 1). A product is new (n) when remanufactured products are represented by 1, δu , δr , and δru , respec­
it has never been used and has two periods of useful life left. After one tively. Products depreciate with use. Remanufacturing can improve a
period of use, a new product becomes a used original product (u) with product’s durability. Also, the durability of used remanufactured prod­
another period of useful life left. It may enter the secondary market, ucts is often lower than that of used original products. Therefore,
where they are sold and bought by consumers. The used original prod­ 0 < δru < δu < δr < 1.
ucts become EOL original products (eol-u) after a period of use. Eco­
nomic and environmental benefits could be achieved if used products 3.2.2. Recycling, remanufacturing, and EPR regulations
are remanufactured at an appropriate time before reaching the EOL. See The producer decides the quantity of new (qn ) and remanufactured
the Online Appendix (OA1.1) for a discussion on the best time to (qr ) products to produce and sell. As in the existing literature, we focus
remanufacture products. on a focal point at which the output of new and remanufactured prod­
We consider that the producer collects used original products from ucts remains the same as in the previous period (Huang et al., 2001;
the secondary market through a trade-in or buyback program, then re­ Agrawal et al., 2012). The maximum amount of recoverable products is
manufactures these products. We assume that after remanufacturing, a limited by the volume of products in the previous period. We assume
used original product becomes a remanufactured product (r), which also that only used original products could be remanufactured, while other
has two periods of useful life. Products can be remanufactured only collected EOL products (including eol-u and eol-ru) are recycled for
once. After one period of use, remanufactured products become used materials, and the unit recycling cost of EOL products is denoted by d.
remanufactured products (ru) which may enter the secondary market. A Moreover, we assume that the producer inspects the collected products
used remanufactured product becomes an EOL remanufactured product and ensures all used original products recovered can be used for rema­
(eol-ru) after one period of use. nufacturing. Therefore, the collected and remanufactured quantity of
As shown in Fig. 2(a), we first construct the benchmark model used original products cannot exceed the new product quantity
(Model N), in which remanufacturing is not considered, i.e., the pro­ (0 ≤ qr ≤ qn ).
ducer only produces and sells new products to consumers. After a period EPR implementations in some regions (e.g., the European Union, and
of use, new products become used items and enter the secondary market. Minnesota, Indiana, Wisconsin, and Michigan in America) commonly
In Model R, shown in Fig. 2(b), we consider the producer collects used impose collection and recycling rate targets, which are defined as a
original products from the secondary market, then remanufactures and fraction of sales that the producer has to collect and recycle (Alev et al.,
sells these products along with new products. The third model, i.e., 2020). We model a scenario where through EPR regulations, the gov­
Model RE in Fig. 2(c), considers EPR regulations. The producer also ernment imposes a collection rate target on both new (n) and remanu­
collects and remanufactures used original products, and any insuffi­ factured (r) products, which is indexed by τ0 , where τ0 ∈ (0, 1) .
ciency in meeting EPR regulations is addressed by collecting and recy­ Hereafter, we refer to this as the collection target for brevity. We model
cling EOL products. it by assuming that, if qn (qr ) denotes the sales of new (remanufactured)
Model N is intended to reveal the producer’s competitive pressure products, then the producer has to collect and recycle at least τ0 qn (τ0 qr )
from used products. Considering the producer that is already proactively products (Atasu et al., 2013b).
engaged in remanufacturing, Model R further investigates whether and To follow new product regulations, the producer may collect both

Fig. 1. Product life flow.

4
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

Fig. 2. Model framework.

used original products (u) and EOL original products (eol-u), and the durability δk (k = n, r, u, ru, and δn = 1) can be used to assess consumer
total collection amount must be at least τ0 qn . The recovery volume of u is preference, as well as the discount on performance and economic value
equal to the quantity remanufactured qr . Additionally, the producer of the product as compared with the new product (Ma et al., 2013; Chen
collects eol-u only to meet the shortages, if any, in the collection rate and Chen, 2019).
target set by the EPR regulations. Therefore, if the remanufactured In the presence of remanufacturing, the demand for new, remanu­
product quantity is higher than that of the collection amount target factured, used original, and used remanufactured products from con­
(qr ≥ τ0 qn ), the producer does not recover eol-u products. However, if sumers are given by qn = 1 − (pn − pr )/(1 − δr ), qr =
qr < τ0 qn , the producer recovers τ0 qn − qr eol-u products to recycle and (pn − pr )/(1 − δr ) − (pr − pu )/(δr − δu ), qu = (pr − pu )/(δr − δu ) −
meet EPR obligations. In addition, to meet the remanufactured product (pu − pru )/(δu − δru ), and qru = (pu − pru )/(δu − δru ) − pru /δru , respec­
regulations, the producer will collect and recycle τ0 qr eol-ru products. tively. Without remanufacturing, only new and used products exist in
the market. The demand for new products is qn = 1 − (pn − pu )/(1 − δu ),
3.2.3. Consumer characteristics and demand and the demand for used products from consumers is qu =
( )
Consumer’s willingness to pay is denoted by θ, which is uniformly (δu pn − pu )/ δu − δ2u . See Online Appendix (OA1.2) for details.
distributed on [0,1]. Each consumer purchases at most one unit of the
product. Product durability affects consumer utility. High-durability 3.2.4. Inverse demand functions
products have a high consumer utility. A consumer with valuation θ The producer collects used original products in a pattern similar to a
receives utility θ, δr θ, δu θ, and δru θ from using a new, remanufactured, trade-in or buyback program. The buyback price equals the market-
used original, and used remanufactured product, respectively, and re­ clearing price pu on the secondary market (Alev et al., 2020). The sup­
ceives 0 from remaining inactive. The assumptions are similar to those of plies of used original and used remanufactured products on the sec­
Ferrer and Swaminathan (2006) and Hong et al. (2017). Product ondary market are from consumers who purchased new and

5
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

Table 1 consumer demand for used products, which in turn intensifies the
Summary of notation. competition between used and new products. This increased competi­
Parameters tion can further suppress the demand for new products, leading to a
reduction in its output and ultimately causing a decrease in the pro­
cn The cost of producing a new product
cr The cost of producing a remanufactured product ducer’s profit.
δu Used original product durability, δu ∈ (0, 1) Therefore, a producer of high-durability and high-cost products
δr Remanufactured product durability, 0 < δu < δr < 1 seeking to improve profits may recover and remanufacture used prod­
δru Used remanufactured product durability, 0 < δru < δu < δr < 1 ucts. Such initiatives may also help ward off competitive threats from
τ0 The collection target set by the government
d The cost of recycling an EOL product
the secondary market of used original products. Our analysis for Model
θ Consumer valuations for product R and Model RE supports this premise.
Variables
qn Quantity of new products 4. Decision models for remanufacturing and EPR
qr Quantity of remanufactured products
pn The sale price of a new product
pr The sale price of a remanufactured product 4.1. Model for remanufacturing without EPR (model R)
pu The sale price of a used original product
pru The sale price of a used remanufactured product Competitive pressure from used products and the potential of
qu Consumer demands for used products remanufacturing profits may motivate the producer to collect used
qru Consumer demands for used remanufactured products
qeol− u Quantity of EOL original products recovered by the producer
original products from the secondary market for remanufacturing. The
qeol− ru Quantity of EOL remanufactured products recovered by the producer producer collects used original products in a pattern similar to a trade-in
τ Original product collection rate, τ = (qr + qeol− u )/qn or buyback program, in which the buyback price is equal to the market-
π Producer’s profit clearing price pu on the secondary market (Alev et al., 2020). With
remanufacturing, there are four types of products in the market: new,
remanufactured, used original, and used remanufactured products. Note
remanufactured products, respectively, in the previous period. There­
that a new product can only be remanufactured once. After one period of
fore, the quantity of used original and used remanufactured products on
use, new products may enter the secondary market as used original
the secondary market is constrained by qn and qr , respectively.
products; from these, some are recovered and remanufactured. Rema­
The demand for used original products originates from the producer
nufactured products can also enter the secondary market after one
and consumer, while the demand for used remanufactured products only
period of use. Used original products and used remanufactured products
comes from consumers. The producer’s demand for used original
reach EOL after one period of use. The producer determines the output
products is qr , and consumer demand for used original and used rema­
of new (qn ) and remanufactured (qr ) products. All products acquired as
nufactured products are qu and qru , respectively. Following Huang et al.
used original products are remanufactured. The producer makes de­
(2019) and Alev et al. (2020), using the market-clearing conditions of
cisions based on the following profit maximization problem.
used original and used remanufactured products, we can obtain that
( ) ( ) ( )
qn = qr + qu and qr = qru . Furthermore, we can get pn = 1 − (1 + δu )qn − max πR qRn , qRr = qRn pRn − cn + qRr pRr − cr − pRu
(δr + δru − δu )qr , pr = δr − (δr + δu )qn − (δr + δru − δu )qr , pu = δu (1 − (2)
s.t. 0 ≤ qRr ≤ qRn
2qn ) − δru qr , and pru = δru (1 − 2qn − qr ). See Online Appendix (OA1.3)
for details. In Model N, pn = 1 − (1 + δu )qn , pu = δu (1 − 2qn ). Note, pRn = 1 − (1 + δu )qRn − (δr + δru − δu )qRr , pRr = δr − (δr + δu )qRn −
( )
(δr + δru − δu )qRr , pRu = δu 1 − 2qRn − δru qRr , qRu = qRn − qRr and qRru = qRr .
3.3. Benchmark model (model N, without remanufacturing and EPR) See the Online Appendix (OA2.1) for the solution to the model. There
exist thresholds cRr1 and cRr2 (cRr1 ≤ cRr2 ) such that we have the following
In this model, remanufacturing and EPR regulations are not consid­ proposition.
ered. Only new and used original products are in the market. The pro­
Proposition 2. The producer’s recovering and remanufacturing stra­
ducer decides on the output of new products only. The producer’s
tegies depend on the remanufacturing cost cr , which can be divided into
decision-making problem is as follows:
three scenarios, as shown in Table 2.
( ) ( )
max πN qNn = qNn pNn − cn The producer’s remanufacturing choice is graphically illustrated in
N N
(1) Fig. 3. Note that, in general, the development of the remanufacturing
s.t. pn = 1 − (1 + δu )qn
industry is conducive to lower remanufacturing costs cr . Based on
Note that the superscript N indicates Model N. See the Online Ap­ remanufacturing costs (from high to low), Scenario R-III is the unde­
pendix (OA1.4) for the solution to the model. Then we have the following veloped or budding stage, R-II is the development stage, and R-I is the
proposition. most mature stage of the remanufacturing industry.
Proposition 1. Under Model N, the producer’s equilibrium output is In the budding period (R-III, cr > cRr2 ), the producer does not have
qN incentives to recover the used original products for remanufacturing.
n = (1 − cn )/[2(1 + δu ) ], the price of a new product is pn = (1 + cn )/2,
N
That is, the producer does not interfere with the secondary market.
and the profit is πN = (1 − cn )2 /[4(1 + δu ) ].
Therefore, R-III is the same as Model N. As the remanufacturing industry
Based on Proposition 1, it is easy to obtain the following corollary.
develops (R-II, cRr1 < cr ≤ cRr2 ), the potential of remanufacturing profits
Corollary 1. Unit profit pN n − cn decreases with cn , while qn and π
N N

decrease with cn and δu .


Corollary 1 indicates that in the absence of remanufacturing and EPR Table 2
regulations, faced with a high-cost and high-durability product, the Producer’s strategies without EPR
producer chooses to reduce the output of the new product, and its profit Scenario qRr qRu qRru Producer’s strategies
declines in this scenario. When the production cost cn increases, there is R-I (cr ≤ cRr1 ) qRn 0 qRn Recovering and
typically an increase in the product price (a decrease in unit profit), remanufacturing all u
resulting in a reduction in consumer demand. As a result of this lower R-II 0< qRr < qRn qRn − qRr Recovering and
demand, the producer reduces production scale. Eventually, the (cRr1 < cr ≤ cRr2 ) qRr remanufacturing some u
decrease in both unit profit and output leads to a reduction in total R-III (cr > cRr2 ) 0 qRn 0 Not recovering and
remanufacturing u
profit. Furthermore, the improved durability leads to an increase in

6
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

encourages producers to switch from no remanufacturing to remanu­


facturing. The producer enters the secondary market to repurchase used
original products and sells new and remanufactured products to con­
sumers. The remanufactured products flow into the secondary market
after a period of use. Consequently, used original and used remanufac­
tured products exist together in the secondary market, which enriches
consumers’ choices and increases the intensity of competition among
products.
As remanufacturing costs decrease further, producers expand the
collection and production scale of remanufactured products while
reducing the output of new products. Thus, the used original product
supply declines while a more extensive supply of used remanufactured
products is available on the secondary market. Used remanufactured
products gradually erode the market share of used original products.
When the remanufacturing industry enters a mature period (R-I,
cr ≤ cRr1 ), the producer recovers and remanufactures all used original
products. No used original products are available to the consumer, while
used remanufactured products completely occupy the secondary
market.
Based on Proposition 2, we can obtain the following corollary.
Fig. 3. Producer’s production and recovery strategies under Model R (cn =
0.4; δr = 0.7; δu = 0.4; δru = 0.25).
Corollary 2. cRr1 and cRr2 decrease with δu , δru , but increase with δr .
Corollary 2 reveals that high δr , and low δu and δru result in high
remanufacturing cost thresholds. A higher cRr1 (cRr2 ) means that it is easier
for the remanufacturing industry to enter the mature (development)

Fig. 4. Effects of δu , δr , and δru on Producer’s Decision under Model R

7
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

stage. Therefore, products with high δr , low δu , and low δru are more considered as a way to fulfill the new product EPR regulations. Any
suitable for remanufacturing. insufficiency in meeting the collection target for new products is met by
We use a numerical approach to investigate the effect of product collecting EOL original products. To follow new product regulations,
durability and the remanufacturing cost thresholds on producer de­ producers may collect both used original products and EOL original
cisions. The results are displayed in Fig. 4, which further supports Cor­ products, and the total collection amount must be at least τ0 qn . Based on
ollary 2. the collection quantity of used original products, two scenarios arise, i.
As shown in Fig. 4, for high-durability used original/remanufactured e., qr ≥ τ0 qn and qr ≤ τ0 qn .
products and low-durability remanufactured products, the producer If qr ≥ τ0 qn , the recovery rate of used original products is enough to
chooses not to remanufacture (R-III). Fig. 4(a) charts that with low meet the collection target. As the collection target is met, the producer
durability used original products, producers engage in remanufacturing does not recycle any EOL original product. The producer recovers qr
(R-I and R-II) even if the remanufacturing cost is relatively high; how­ used original products for remanufacturing and recycles τ0 qr EOL
ever, for high durability used original products, remanufacturing may be remanufactured products. The producer’s problem is then given by the
feasible only if the remanufacturing cost is sufficiently low. High dura­ following:
bility used original products would imply a high economic- and use- ( ) ( RE ) ( RE )
max π RE qRE RE
n , qr = qRE pn − cn + qRE pr − cr − pRE − τ0 qRE
r d
value, which makes recovering expensive, limiting producers’ involve­ n r u
(3)
RE RE RE
ment in remanufacturing and secondary markets. As seen in Fig. 4(b), s.t. τ0 qn ≤ qr ≤ qn
remanufacturing strategy is also affected by durability improvement If qr ≤ τ0 qn , collecting only used original products is not enough to
from remanufacturing. The higher the improvement in durability or the meet the collection targets. Therefore, the producer not only recovers qr
lower the remanufacturing cost to upgrade durability, the more attrac­ used original products but also recycles τ0 qn − qr EOL original products
tive it is for the producer to interfere with the secondary market through from consumers. The producer’s decision-making problem is as follows.

( ) ( RE ) ( RE ) [ RE ]
max πRE qRE RE
n , qr = qRE pn − cn + qRE pr − cr − pRE − τ0 qn − (1 − τ0 )qRE d
n r u r
(4)
s.t. 0 ≤ qRE RE
r ≤ τ 0 qn

remanufacturing. Finally, Fig. 4(c) shows that the high durability of used
remanufactured products would make it less likely for producers to
engage in the remanufacturing market. For high-durability used rema­ Note, pRE RE RE RE
n = 1 − (1 + δu )qn − (δr + δru − δu )qr , pr = δr − (δr + δu )
nufactured products, lower prices may lead to fierce competition with qRE
n − (δr + δru − δu )qr , pu = δu (1 − 2qn ) − δru qr , qRE
RE RE RE RE RE
u = qn − qr ,
RE

remanufactured products (attracting more consumers due to the cost- RE RE


and qru = qr . See the Online Appendix (OA2.2) for solution details. For
effectiveness), which are not conducive to the production and sales of remanufacturing cost thresholds cRE RE RE RE
r1 ≤ cr2 ≤ cr3 ≤ cr4 , we have the
remanufactured products. following proposition.
In summary, low-durability used original/remanufactured products
and high-durability remanufactured products are more suitable for Proposition 3. Based on the remanufacturing cost cr , the producer’s
remanufacturing. Remanufacturing is especially preferable for products strategies in the presence of EPR can be divided into the following five
that diminish in performance after a period of use but can be restored scenarios (shown in Table 3).
well through remanufacturing. Fig. 5 charts a producer’s remanufacturing strategies to comply with
the EPR obligations. The choice and quantity of used original (for
remanufacturing) and EOL original/remanufactured product recycled
4.2. Model with remanufacturing under EPR (model RE) by a producer depend on the remanufacturing costs. Similar to Model R,
we could consider the five cost scenarios to represent various remanu­
Building on Model R, we now analyze a producer’s recovering and facturing stages. We can state that RE-V is the most undeveloped or
remanufacturing strategies in the presence of EPR regulations. Both new budding stage of the remanufacturing industry; RE-IV, RE-III, and RE-II
and remanufactured products fall within the scope of EPR regulations could be considered as early, middle, and late development stages; RE-I
with a collection rate target of τ0 . Let qn (qr ) denote the sales volume of is the most mature stage of the remanufacturing industry.
new (remanufactured) products. The producer has to collect and recycle In the budding period (RE-V, cr > cRE r4 ), the producer does not
at least τ0 qn (τ0 qr ) products. remanufacture (qRE r = 0) and only recycles EOL original products
To meet the remanufactured product EPR regulation, the producer (qRE RE
eol− u = τ0 qn ) to meet the EPR regulations. As the remanufacturing
recycles τ0 qr EOL remanufactured products at a cost denoted by τ0 qr d. industry enters the early development stage (RE-IV, cRE RE
r3 < cr ≤ cr4 ), the
Furthermore, the producer collects used original products from the
producer’s best option is to adopt a mixed collection strategy. In
secondary market and remanufactures all of these, which can be

Table 3
Producer’s strategies in the presence of EPR
Scenario qRE
r qRE
eol− u qRE
eol− ru
Producer’s strategies

RE-I (cr ≤ cRE


r1 ) qRE
n
0 τ0 qRE
n
Recover all u for remanufacturing
r1 < cr ≤ cr2 )
RE-II (cRE RE
τ0 qRE
n < qr < qn
RE RE 0 τ0 qRE
r
Recover u that exceed the collection target for remanufacturing
RE-III (cRE
r2 < c r ≤ τ0 qRE
n
0 τ20 qRE
n
Recover u for remanufacturing based on the collection target
cRE
r3 )
RE
RE-IV (cr3 < cr ≤ 0 < qRE RE
r < τ 0 qn τ0 qRE RE
n − qr τ0 qRE
r
Recover a mix of u and eol-u to fulfill EPR obligations
cRE
r4 )
RE-V (cr > cRE
r4 )
0 τ0 qRE
n
0 Only recycle eol-u to fulfill EPR obligations and not recover u for remanufacturing

8
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

addition to recycling EOL original products (qRE RE RE


eol− u = τ0 qn − qr ), the
producer recovers and remanufactures used original products
(0 < qRE RE
r < τ0 qn ). As remanufactured and used remanufactured prod­
ucts enter the market, the market share of used original products
declines.
With a decline in remanufacturing costs, the remanufacturing in­
dustry enters the middle development stage (RE-III, cRE RE
r2 < cr ≤ cr3 ).
Producers adopt the benchmark collection strategy, which is recovering
and remanufacturing used original products based on the collection
target set by EPR regulation (qRE r = τ0 qRE
n ). Under this setting, con­
sumers’ product demand is relatively stable, and the market share of
used original and used remanufactured products are also relatively
stable.
As remanufacturing costs decrease further, the remanufacturing in­
dustry reaches the late development stage (RE-II, cRE RE
r1 < cr ≤ cr2 ). The
producer recovers used original products which exceed the collection
target for remanufacturing, i.e., τ0 qRE RE RE
n < qr < qn . We call this exceed
collection target strategy. The producer collects and remanufactures a
significant amount of used original products. A large volume of used
remanufactured products available in the secondary market cannibal­
Fig. 5. Production and recovering strategy under Model RE (cn = 0.4; δr =
izes the market share of used original products.
0.7; δu = 0.4; δru = 0.25; τ0 = 0.4; d = 0.05).
Finally, when the remanufacturing cost is sufficiently low, the in­
dustry could be considered mature (RE-I, cr ≤ cRE r1 ). The producer adopts
the all-collection strategy, which is recovering all used original products
for remanufacturing, i.e., qRE
r = qRE
n . There are no used original products

Fig. 6. Effects of δu , δr , δru , and τ0 on producer’s decision under Model RE (cn = 0.4; d = 0.05).

9
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

on the secondary market and used remanufactured products thoroughly Therefore, in the budding and early development period of rema­
saturate the secondary market. nufacturing industry, the higher the collection target is, the more diffi­
Based on Proposition 3, we obtain the following. cult it is for producers to remanufacture and engage in the secondary
market. In summary, during the budding and early periods of the
Corollary 3. cRE RE RE RE
r1 , cr2 , cr3 and cr4 decrease with δu , δru , and τ0 , but
remanufacturing industry, the government should set a moderate
increase with δr .
(relatively low) collection target. This would help in the development of
Corollary 3 indicates that the relationship between the remanu­
the remanufacturing industry.
facturing cost thresholds and product durability are similar to Model R,
In addition, by comparing the remanufacturing cost thresholds of
and the remanufacturing cost thresholds decrease with the increase of
Model RE and Model R, the following corollary can be obtained.
collection target.
Next, we explore the effect of δu , δr , δru , and τ0 on the producer’s Corollary 4. (i) cRE r4 > cr2 , the producer can profitably recover and
R

decision through numerical studies (see Fig. 6). Fig. 6 also supports remanufacture used original products at a higher remanufacturing cost
Corollary 3. In the presence of EPR regulations, low δu and δru and high under EPR regulation. (ii) cRE r1 < cr1 , the producer recovers all used
R

δr are also beneficial to remanufacturing initiatives. See Fig. 6(a)-(c). As original products for remanufacturing at a lower cost under EPR
shown in Fig. 6(d), as the collection targets increase, the producer regulation.
chooses strategies strategy from I to V. A high collection target set by the As seen from Corollary 4(i), a producer in Model RE finds it easier to
government would inhibit the development of the remanufacturing initiate remanufacturing and enters a remanufacturing development
industry. stage sooner. EPR regulations require the producer to recover a certain
In most practical scenarios (especially in the budding, early, and quantity of products in the budding stage of the remanufacturing in­
middle development periods of the remanufacturing industry), qr ∈ [0, dustry, which vastly increases the producer’s expenses and reduces its
τ0 qn ]. We further conduct a numerical analysis to investigate the impact profit. To compensate for the economic losses caused by EPR, the pro­
of EPR regulation on producer’s strategies under scenarios RE-III, RE-IV, ducer may choose to recover and remanufacture used original products
and RE-V. The results are presented in Fig. 7. For various values of to increase its profit. Therefore, EPR regulations motivate the producer’s
collection targets τ0,1 ≤ τ0,2 , if τ0 ≤ τ0,1 , the producer chooses strategy implementation of remanufacturing in the budding stage of the rema­
III (qREr = τ0 qRE RE
n ; qeol− u = 0); if τ0,1 < τ0 < τ0,2 , the producer adopts nufacturing industry.
strategy IV (0 < qRE RE RE RE RE
r < τ0 qn ; qeol− u = τ0 qn − qr ); and if τ0 ≥ τ0,2 , the
However, we find from Corollary 4(ii) that Model RE enters the
producer chooses strategy V (qRE 0; q RE
τ0 qRE remanufacturing industry maturity later than Model R. When the
r = eol− u = n ).
When τ0 ≥ τ0,1 , as τ0 increases, there is a decrease in the output of remanufacturing industry is relatively mature, due to the high output of
remanufactured products (i.e., the collection amount of used original remanufactured products, producers need to recycle a large quantity of
products) and an increase in the recovery amount of EOL original EOL remanufactured products to fulfill EPR obligations, which may lead
product. This means that if the collection target is set high, producers are to a heavy recycling burden. Affected by the recycling burden, compared
less likely to fulfill EPR obligations of original products by only recov­ with the situation without EPR regulations, the remanufacturing in­
ering used original products (RE-III). Instead, the producers may need to dustry matures later under EPR regulations.
collect EOL original products to make up for the insufficient collection In summary, EPR regulations help incentivize producers to reman­
(RE-IV), or they may meet the collection target by recycling EOL original ufacture in the budding stage while hindering the remanufacturing in­
products entirely (RE-V). dustry as it matures.
To mitigate the collection burden, producers may even consider
reducing the production scale of new products (RE-III and RE-V). When 5. Comparative analysis and case studies
the collection target is low, the remanufacturing volume increases with
the collection target (RE-III). It is worth noting that when the collection To further investigate the impacts of EPR regulations and remanu­
target is above a certain level, the production scale of remanufactured facturing, the models are compared and analyzed in this section. In
products is reduced with the increase in the collection target (RE-IV), or addition, a case study is presented using actual data on heavy truck
products are not remanufactured at all (RE-V). engine remanufacturing. The findings from the models are applied to the
case company.

5.1. Comparative analysis

We now perform numerical analysis to compare the models from the


perspectives of EPR regulation impacts, secondary market involvement,
collection rate, and producer profit. The unit cost of a new product is set
at 0.4, which is similar to Shi et al. (2016). The unit cost of a remanu­
factured product is necessarily lower than cn , for which we consider a
wide range of possible values based on Abbey et al. (2019); cr =
0 ∼ 0.25. Referring to relevant literature (Agrawal et al., 2012; Alev
et al., 2020) and actual investigation data, the values of product dura­
bility adopted are δr = 0.7, δu = 0.4, and δru = 0.25. Similar to Alev
et al. (2020), the unit recycling cost of EOL products is set to 0.05. The
value of the collection target is 0.4, which is based on the parameter
setting of Esenduran et al. (2016). Therefore, we adopt the parametric
values as follows: cn = 0.4, δr = 0.7, δu = 0.4, δru = 0.25, d = 0.05, τ0 =
0.4, and cr = 0 ∼ 0.25.

5.1.1. EPR regulation impacts


By comparing the output of remanufactured products in Model RE
Fig. 7. Analysis of the collection rate τ0 (cn = 0.4; cr = 0.15; δr = 0.7; δu = and Model R, we can analyze the influence of EPR regulations on the
0.4; δru = 0.25; d = 0.05). producer’s remanufacturing strategy (see Fig. 8) and then provide policy

10
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

5.1.2. Secondary market involvement


Producer’s recovery and remanufacturing affect the volume of the
used products that consumers can purchase, which in turn interferes
with the secondary market (affects consumer demand for used prod­
ucts). EPR regulations have an impact on remanufacturing and indi­
rectly affect the secondary market. By analyzing and comparing the
demands for used original products (qu ) and used remanufactured
products (qru ), we explore the interference effects of remanufacturing
and EPR regulations on the secondary market. Fig. 9 charts the inter­
action of various quantities of used products with the remanufacturing
cost.
Fig. 9 suggests that remanufacturing industry development leads to a
decline in the consumer demand for used original products. When the
remanufacturing industry enters the development period (cr ≤ cRr2 ),
remanufacturing enriches consumer options by adding remanufactured
and used remanufactured products to the market—accordingly, the
consumer demand for used original products declines (qRu < qN u ). With
the decrease in remanufacturing costs cr , the producer collects and re­
manufactures an increasing volume of used original products, and a
growing percentage of used remanufactured products flood the sec­
ondary market.
Fig. 8. Comparison of remanufacturing production in model r and RE Used original and used remanufactured products are highly com­
plementary in the secondary market; that is, when consumers’ demand
insights on the role of EPR in promoting the development of remanu­ for one product decreases (increases), their demand for the other
facturing industry. product increases (decreases). When the remanufacturing cost is below a
As depicted in Fig. 8, when the remanufacturing cost is below a threshold (e.g., cr < 0.0914), EPR regulations are not conducive to
certain threshold (0 < cr < crr ), EPR regulations decrease the recovering implementing remanufacturing, resulting in reduced remanufactured
and remanufacturing amount of used original products (qRE r < qr ).
R
products (as shown in Fig. 8, qRE r < qr ) and increased available used
R

Therefore, in such a developed stage, the government does not need EPR original products. This leads to increased consumer demand for used
regulations to guide the development of the industry. However, in most original products (qREu ≥ qu ). Furthermore, the reduction in remanu­
R

industrial sectors, the remanufacturing industry is in the development factured products directly results in decreased used remanufactured
stage and has a relatively high remanufacturing cost. When the rema­ products on the secondary market, thereby reducing consumer demand
nufacturing cost is above a certain threshold (crr < cr < cRE r4 ), EPR reg­ for used remanufactured products (qRE ru < qru ). On the contrary, when the
R

ulations help increase the recovering and remanufacturing amount of remanufacturing cost is above a threshold (e.g., cr > 0.0920), EPR reg­
used original products (qRE r > qr ). It is worth noting that when
R
ulations encourage the producer to implement remanufacturing, leading
cRr2 ≤ cr < cRE
r4 , the producer does not engage in remanufacturing without to increased remanufactured products and reduced available used
EPR regulations (qRr = 0); but with EPR regulations, the producer en­ original products, which reduces the consumer demands for used orig­
gages in remanufacturing (qRE RE
r > 0). Especially when crr < cr ≤ cr3 , the
inal products (qRE u < qu ). Moreover, the increase in remanufactured
R

remanufactured product output (i.e., the collected amount of used products directly results in increased used remanufactured products on
original product) under EPR regulations has already met the collection the secondary market, consequently growing consumer demands for
target (qREr = τ0 qREn > qr ). Consequently, government guidance, sup­
R used remanufactured products (qRE ru ≥ qru ).
R

port, and incentives are still needed for the industry’s growth. In summary, for producers, initiating remanufacturing will reduce
the consumer demand for used original products. EPR regulations will
improve the demand for used original products when the remanu­
facturing cost is low but suppress the demand when the remanufacturing
cost is high. When the remanufacturing industry is mature, it is mainly
remanufacturing that interferes with the secondary market. In contrast,
in the budding period, the secondary market is unaffected. When the
remanufacturing industry is in development periods (i.e., between
budding and maturity), both remanufacturing and EPR regulations
interfere with the secondary market.

5.1.3. Collection rate


The producer collects used and EOL products from the secondary
market or consumers. A higher collection rate is considered to have a
better environmental performance. The collection rate of remanufac­
tured products qeol− ru /qr , is 0 in Models N and R and is τ0 in Model RE
(except E-V, where it is zero). The collection rate of remanufactured
products in Model RE is the highest. In addition, based on the perspec­
tive of the entire life cycle from raw materials to product disposal, we
could consider (qeol− u +qeol− ru )/qn as a measure of total recycling. The
measure is 0 under Models N and R (no recycling EOL products).
Therefore, the recycling level of Model RE is the best.
Let τ denote the original product collection rate, τR = qRr /qRn , τRE =
Fig. 9. Comparison of the secondary market involvement. (qRE RE RE
r + qeol− u ) /qn . Fig. 10(a) illustrates the collection rate for Model R

11
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

Fig. 10. Collection rate(τ = (qr + qeol− u ) /qn )

and Model RE. The figure suggests that for high cr (cr > crt ) the collection development periods, EPR leads to a lower collection rate. EPR regula­
rate in Model RE is relatively higher than that of Model R (τRE > τR ). For tion does not affect the collection rate in a mature remanufacturing in­
sufficiently low cr values (cr ≤ cRE r1 ), the collection rate of Model RE is
dustry. In summary, based on the perspective of collection rate
equal to Model R (τRE = τR = 1). It is counterintuitive that for relatively (environmental performance), the governments should implement EPR
low cr values (cRE regulation in the budding and early stages of remanufacturing. They
r1 < cr < crt ), the collection rate of Model RE is some­
what inferior (τRE < τR ). When cRE RE RE should no longer interfere when it has developed to a certain stage.
r1 < cr < crt (cr2 < crt < cr3 ), the pro­
ducer adopts RE-II or RE-III strategy under EPR regulations (as per
5.1.4. Producer profits
Proposition 3, qRE eol− u = 0) and the recovery rate of used original prod­
Remanufacturing and EPR would be attractive to a producer if they
ucts is sufficient to meet the collection target of the original product
derive benefits from them. To assess the attractiveness, we compare the
(τRE = qRE RE R R RE RE
r /qn ≥ τ0 ). Therefore, the ratios qr /qn and qr / qn can be producer profits in different models. Fig. 11 illustrates the interaction of
used to compare the collection rates. Fig. 10(b) suggests that when cRE r1 < producer profits with the remanufacturing cost. Fig. 11 reveals that
cr < crt , to relieve the recovery pressure of EOL remanufactured prod­ when the remanufacturing cost is below a certain threshold (cr ≤ cRr2 ),
ucts under EPR regulations, the producer reduces the output of rema­ the producer profit under Model R is higher than that of Model N
nufactured products (qRE r < qr ) and increases the output of new
R
(πR > πN ). Therefore, when the remanufacturing industry has developed
products in most instances (qn > qRn ), resulting in τRE < τR (although it
RE
to a particular stage, the producer can improve profit by remanu­
is possible that qREn < qn , this does not affect the overall result).
R
facturing used original products, supporting a part of the conclusion in
During remanufacturing industry’s budding and early development Section 3.3. Our results highlight that remanufacturing is a profitable
periods, EPR leads to a higher collection rate. Therefore, the govern­ strategy for producers. With a gradual reduction in remanufacturing
ments’ EPR regulations will help improve environmental performance. costs, remanufacturing is conducive to improving enterprise benefits.
As the remanufacturing industry gradually enters its middle and later On the measures of producer profit, Model RE underperforms Model
R (πRE < π R ). For remanufacturing costs above a threshold (cr > crp ), the
producer profit of Model RE is even lower than that of Model N
(πRE < π N ). EPR regulations achieve collection targets (environmental
benefits) at the cost of enterprise benefits. When a producer can
remanufacture, but the remanufacturing cost is high (i.e., the early
period of remanufacturing development), the government’s imple­
mentation of EPR-related policies may not be conducive to increasing
producer profits. When the remanufacturing cost is below a threshold
(cr < crp ), the producer’s profit under Model RE is higher than that of
Model N (πRE > πN ). For a producer who implements remanufacturing
under EPR regulations, when the remanufacturing industry is relatively
mature, the improvement from remanufacturing on producer profits is
more significant than the reduction caused by the EPR regulations.

5.2. A case study

In this section, we present an actual case study to investigate further


the impact of EPR regulations on remanufacturing and the secondary
market. The case study helps us understand a producer’s remanu­
facturing strategies to obtain higher economic efficiency and meet the
EPR regulations. This analysis focuses on the Steyr336 heavy truck en­
Fig. 11. Producer profits. gine (from now on referred to as Steyr336) produced by Sinotruk Jinan

12
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

Fuqiang Power Co., Ltd (SJFP). Our analysis focuses on the EPR and the regard the SJFP as the producer under Model RE. Referring to the
secondary market involvement of the producer. SJFP, established in collection target stipulated in some developed countries or regions, we
1994, specializes in producing auto parts and is China’s first enterprise set the range of collection targets, then analyze SJFP’s optimal decision
to remanufacture automobile engines. The company can remanufacture under EPR regulations and compare it with the realistic situation. Our
20,000 units per year. analysis of the SJFP’s strategies under EPR is forward-looking, which
Our choice of automobile engines is motivated for several reasons. can provide valuable management enlightenment for the remanu­
First, automobile engine producers are subjected to EPR-based recycling facturing enterprise and government.
legislation in many countries worldwide. Second, automobile engines Based on the field investigation of SJFP, the following relevant in­
already have an active secondary market, with many used products formation and data were collected. The selling price of a new and
traded offline and online. Third, producers actively use marketing remanufactured Steyr336 is RMB 70,000 (1 dollar ≈ 6.87 RMB) and
methods to buy back used engines from consumers (e.g., engine “trade- RMB 44,000, respectively. Remanufactured Steyr336 sells for about
in” programs). 63% of the new product price. The production cost for a remanufactured
The SJFP recovers and remanufactures used Steyr336. According to Steyr336 is RMB 20,000. According to the investigation, the company’s
the investigation, the company has carried out recovery activities. Such new product profit is approximately 30% of the price. Therefore, the
recovery of used Steyr336 can be regarded as a trade-in or buyback production cost for a new Steyr336 is estimated to be RMB 49,000.
program, in which the buyback price equals the market-clearing price on As for the recycling cost of EOL Steyr336, the per-unit collection and
the secondary market. Therefore, the SJFP that uses strategy R-II in the per-unit transportation costs are RMB 7500 and RMB 500, respec­
actual operations can be considered the producer under Model R. The tively. The average weight of each Steyr336 is approximately 800kgs,
parameter values for our model are collected through the field investi­ and the discarded steel price is 2 RMB/kg, which results in a profit of
gation of SJFP. The company location (China) has established a tax- RMB 1600 by processing EOL Steyr336 as resources. Accordingly, the
subsidy mechanism (recycling fund system) to implement EPR regula­ unit recycling cost of EOL Steyr336 is d = 7500 + 500 − 1600 = 6400
tion. Regrettably, it has not yet imposed a collection rate target based on RMB. The product price and cost range defined in our model is 0~1.
EPR. However, China is exploring how to set collection targets in EPR- Therefore, by scaling the monetary values by a factor of 100,000, we
based environmental regulation policy design. Therefore, we also obtain pn = 0.7, pr = 0.44, cn = 0.49, cr = 0.2, and d = 0.064.

Fig. 12. Engine case analysis.


Note: cn = 0.49, δr = 0.95, δu = 0.58, δru = 0.46, and d = 0.064. “0”, “+“, and “-” in parentheses represent qRE
u = qu , qu > qu , and qu < qu , respectively.
R RE R RE R

13
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

The data collected for automobile engines in China does not indicate price (0.70–0.72). Of course, an important reason for the low price could
the applicable collection rate. However, precise data is available from be that the remanufacturing industry has just started in China. Con­
other parts of the world. For example, the EU stipulated a product sumers lack recognition and trust in remanufactured products, which
collection target rate of 45% in 2016. The target was raised to 65% in would require producers to sell remanufactured products at a lower
2019. Similarly, for Minnesota and Wisconsin, the target is currently at price. Compared with the new Steyr336, the profit margins from pro­
80%. Following these, we use a range of values τ0 ∈ [0.45, 0.8]. ducing remanufactured products are higher. Each remanufactured en­
The life of a typical heavy-duty truck engine is 15 years, and the gine’s price could be increased by 0.26–0.28. Therefore, the company
depreciation is about 7% per year. Following the model assumptions in should boost consumers’ perception of remanufactured Steyr336 by
Section 3, we assume that the product has a two-period use life, with an promoting remanufactured products, expanding the market share of
average of 7.5 years in each period. The durability of products that have remanufactured products, and ultimately, higher economic benefits
been used for one period is δu = (1 − 7%)7.5 = 0.58. SJFP has a tech­ through increased prices of remanufactured products.
nologically advanced and mature remanufacturing production line. The In summary, this case study demonstrates how our model research
performance of remanufactured Steyr336 is comparable to that of new results apply to the industry. The effect of EPR on the secondary market
products; consequently, its durability is estimated at δr = 0.95. The depends mainly on the characteristics of remanufactured products and
depreciation rate of a remanufactured Steyr336 is higher than that of the the intensity of government regulations. It is important to note that for
original product (about 12%/year), and its life span is slightly lower firms whose remanufacturing technology is still in the early develop­
(about 12 years). Therefore, the durability of used remanufactured ment period, EPR regulations will increase their involvement in the
Steyr336 is δru = (1 − 12%)6 = 0.46. secondary market. When remanufacturing technology gradually ma­
Based on remanufacturing cost and the collection target, SJFP can tures, EPR regulations will weaken the producer’s participation in the
adopt RE-(I–V) strategies, as shown in Fig. 12(a). For a given remanu­ secondary market.
facturing cost, a lower target collection rate could enable SJPF to collect
and remanufacture used original products. Note that Model RE includes 6. Model extensions
the considerations of EPR regulations while Model R does not. There­
fore, qRE 6.1. Comprehensive regulations
u − qu is used to measure the impact of the EPR regulation on the
R

secondary market (for the used original product). This measure reveals
three scenarios. See Fig. 12(b). In region A, the EPR regulations have no Various types of EPR regulations are used in practice. Most EPR
impact on the secondary market, i.e., qRE legislations do not identify the products that can or can’t be recycled. A
u = qu . In region B, EPR regu­
R
durable-goods producer can utilize both EOL (recycle) and used prod­
lations increase consumers’ demand for used Steyr336, i.e., qRE u > qu .
R
ucts (remanufacturing) to fulfill EPR obligations (Alev et al., 2020). Our
This, in turn, weakens the secondary market participation of SJFP. In
Model RE considers a regulation where original and remanufactured
region C, EPR regulation decreases consumers’ demand for used
products are considered individually. It also includes used original
Steyr336, i.e., qREu < qu . This leads to increased secondary market
R
products in the scope of the original product EPR regulations. In this
involvement.
section, we consider a comprehensive regulation on new and remanu­
The remanufacturing cost of a Steyr336 is 0.2 (unit: 100,000 RMB). If
factured products (i.e., producers, at their discretion, choose either one
the collection target is below 54%, SJFP prefers to recover used Steyr336
or both types of products to meet EPR regulations). New regulations
based on the target (benchmark collection strategy RE-III). See Fig. 12
regard remanufactured products as intermediate products. The gov­
(a). However, if the collection target is above 54%, the company collects
ernment stipulates the volume of EOL products the producers need to
used and EOL Steyr336 to meet the target (mixed collection strategy RE-
recycle. Therefore, the producer can use a mix of EOL original and EOL
IV). Under the circumstance that the remanufacturing cost remains the
remanufactured products to meet the EPR obligations. The recycling
same, regardless of collection target and remanufacturing strategy (i.e.,
amount only needs to meet qeol− u + qeol− ru = τ0 qn . The model is as fol­
III or IV), EPR increases the company’s secondary market involvement,
lows. See the Online Appendix (OA3.1) for solutions.
leading to a lower Steyr336 reuse rate and higher remanufacturing rate.
For SJFP at this stage, the government implementing EPR regulations max π (qn , qr ) = qn (pn − cn ) + qr (pr − cr − pu ) − τ0 qn d
(5)
will help reduce the competitive threat from the used Steyr336, thereby s.t. 0 ≤ qr ≤ qn
encouraging the development of the remanufacturing industry.
Similar to the other models in this paper, the producers’
Whether EPR regulations weaken or enhance secondary market
manufacturing strategy could be classified into three scenarios based on
participation mainly depends on the remanufacturing cost. However,
remanufacturing cost. Scenarios I, II, and III have the remanufacturing
when the remanufacturing cost is sufficiently low, a producer’s sec­
cost conditions of cr ≤ cr1 , cr1 < cr < cr2 , and cr ≥ cr2 , respectively. Sce­
′ ′ ′ ′

ondary market activities are also influenced by the intensity of gov­


narios I and III of the comprehensive legislation model are the same as
ernment regulations. Suppose SJFP reduces remanufacturing costs
Scenario I and V, respectively, of Model RE.
through technological innovation. In that case, the impact of the EPR
cr2 < cRE
r4 implies that under a comprehensive regulation, producers

regulation on the secondary market may fall into area B (see Fig. 12(b))
and may or even be into area A. For example, when the remanufacturing enter the remanufacturing market at a lower remanufacturing cost than
Model RE. However, since cr1 > cRE r1 , remanufacturing growth rate is

cost of Steyr336 is reduced to 0.11, the collection target is below 52%,
and EPR does not interfere with the secondary market. If the collection expected to be faster with the comprehensive regulation. The remanu­
target is above 52%, EPR regulations will restrain the company’s facturing industry will mature faster (i.e., maturity will be attained even
involvement in the secondary market. When the remanufacturing if the remanufacturing cost is higher) in the comprehensive regulations.
development of enterprises such as SJFP is relatively mature, high In addition, the total recovery amount of EOL products is never lower
profits drive enterprises to collect products for remanufacturing volun­ than that of EPR regulations on each product type. As a result, in the
tarily. The government may not need EPR regulations (if not considering budding and early development periods of the remanufacturing in­
the collection of EOL products). dustry, independent regulations on different types of products could be
We now explore the interaction of various prices with the collection effective. In comparison, a comprehensive regulation will bring higher
target. The prices of new and remanufactured Steyr336 are 0.7 and 0.44, collection rates in the later development stages.
respectively. Fig. 12(c) suggests that the new product price is slightly
lower than the optimal price (0.74–0.76) as per our models, while the
remanufactured product price is much lower than its optimal selling

14
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

6.2. Duopoly competition Compared with recycling EOL original products, the recycling
strategy used original products to fulfill EPR obligation has a more
This model considers a setting with two identical producers in a significant effect on the secondary market, which is more conducive to
secondary market. The model captures quantity competition between the producer to expand the production scale. Therefore, to weaken the
two producers with two types of products (new and remanufactured). competitive threat of used original products or to occupy higher market
The following model is established to analyze the impact of producer shares and secure the market, the producer may choose to increase their
competition on production decision-making and the secondary market. intervention in the secondary market, that is, entirely utilize used
The decision-making problem of producer i (i = 1, 2) is as follows: original products to comply with original product EPR obligation.
max πi (qni , qri ) = qni (pn − cn ) + qri (pr − cr − pu ) − τ0 qri d
(6) 7. Conclusions
s.t. τ0 qni ≤ qri ≤ qni

max πi (qni , qri ) = qni (pn − cn ) + qri (pr − cr − pu ) − [τ0 qni − (1 − τ0 )qri ]d To alleviate competitive threats from the secondary market to new
s.t. 0 ≤ qri ≤ τ0 qni products, a producer may choose to recover and remanufacture used
(7) products. EPR-related government regulations are intended to improve
the environmental impact and encourage remanufacturing industry.
The inverse demand functions of new products and remanufactured However, in practice, the application of EPR systems in remanufacturing
products are pn = 1 − (1 +δu )Qn − (δr +δru − δu )Qr and pr = δr − (δu + is still evolving, and EPR regulation’s impact on remanufacturing needs
δr )Qn − (δr + δru − δu )Qr . The market-clearing price of used products is further analysis.
pu = δu (1 − 2Qn ) − δru Qr , where Qn = qn1 + qn2 , Qr = qr1 + qr2 . In the presence of a secondary market, we analyzed the producer’s
See the Online Appendix (OA3.2) for detailed solutions. Analysis re­ production and remanufacturing strategies using different models,
veals that the main conclusions from Sections 4 and 5 remain unchanged which cover remanufacturing with and without EPR regulations. Equi­
in a duopolistic setting. Furthermore, the conditions (cost boundaries, librium solutions for the producer were expounded to understand how
strategies adopted, etc.) for the five scenarios remain the same as in the EPR regulations affect remanufacturing strategy in the presence of a
monopoly case (Model RE). The total remanufacturing and recovery rate secondary market. We then analyzed and compared the models based on
was also unchanged. EPR regulation impacts, secondary market involvement, collection rate,
The presence of producer competition leads to the following differ­ and producer profit. The model analysis leads to the following results.
ences from our main results for Model RE: (1) In the duopoly case, each
producer’s used original products recovery quantity, the output of new (1) In different development periods of the remanufacturing in­
products, and remanufactured products are less than those in the mo­ dustry, producers adopt different recovery and production stra­
nopoly market. (2) Compared with a monopolist, the total recovery tegies. The chosen strategies are affected by the remanufacturing
quantity of used original products and the total output of new and cost. Moreover, high-durability used original/remanufactured
remanufactured products increases. Consequently, duopoly competition products are not conducive to producing and selling remanufac­
is conducive to developing manufacturing and remanufacturing tured products.
industries. (2) When new and remanufactured products are subject to strict EPR
regulations (high collection targets), recovering used products
6.3. Recycling used original products to compensate for EPR regulations may not be enough. The producers may need to collect EOL
products to make up for the insufficient collection. Furthermore,
Model RE assumes that the producer compensates for the EPR reg­ they may meet the collection target by recycling EOL products
ulatory requirements of original products by recycling EOL original entirely.
products (the recycling cost of EOL products is lower than the used (3) EPR regulations (moderate collection targets) help the remanu­
original products). Now we assume that to control the competitiveness facturing industry in its budding and early development periods,
of used original products against remanufactured products and to reduce leading to a higher collection rate. However, EPR may not be
threats from used original products, the producer entirely uses used conducive to increasing producer profits, and stringent collection
original products to meet the original product EPR obligations. The unit targets inhibit remanufacturing industry’s development.
residual value of used original products is denoted by v.
When qr ≥ τ0 qn , the model remains the same as Model RE. When When designed appropriately, EPR regulations could help the
qr ≤ τ0 qn , the producer’s demand for used original products increases remanufacturing industry by promoting remanufacturing and increasing
from qr to τ0 qn , and the remaining τ0 qn − qr used original products are producer profits. However, ill-designed regulations (e.g., too high a
resourced (i.e., recycled for materials). At this time, the market-clearing collection target when remanufacturing costs are high) could hurt the
condition is adjusted to qn = τ0 qn + qu , we can get pn = 1 − (1 + δu − industry’s progress. EPR regulations are effective in the early and middle
δu τ0 )qn − (δr + δru )qr , pr = δr − (δr + δu − δu τ0 )qn − (δr + δru )qr , pu = development stages. Regulations are not needed for a mature remanu­
δu − (2 − τ0 )δu qn − (δu + δru )qr , and pru = δru [1 − (2 − τ0 )qn − 2qr ]. The facturing industry. Remanufacturing cost and product durability (for
producer’s problem is given by the following: used and remanufactured) are the most critical factors affecting a pro­
ducer’s strategic decisions. The results have practical significance for
max π(qn , qr ) = qn (pn − cn ) + qr (pr − cr ) − τ0 qn pu + (τ0 qn − qr )v − τ0 qr d
enterprise managers who choose remanufacturing strategies in the face
s.t. 0 ≤ qr ≤ τ0 qn
of competition in the secondary market. Our study is also relevant for
(8)
government policymaking bodies that intend to encourage producers to
See the Online Appendix(OA3.3) for the model and solutions. In brief, fulfill EPR obligations for environmental reasons. From a policymaking
similar to Model RE, this model can also be divided into five scenarios perspective, this study helped answer questions such as: Do remanu­
based on remanufacturing costs, among which Scenarios I-III remain factured products need to be regulated? If so, what kind of regulations
unchanged (same as Model RE). Scenario IV and V change qualitatively would be beneficial for the industry?
as follows: (1) Scenario IV changes to recover used original products There are several possible future research directions. We assume that
based on the collection target, remanufacture parts according to pro­ the government sets the same collection target for new and remanu­
duction needs, and treat the rest as resources. (2) Scenario V changes to factured products; however, this may not apply to all instances in
recover used original products based on the collection target, not practice. Future studies could relax this assumption. Additional types of
implement remanufacturing, and treat all as resources. EPR regulatory measures, such as environmental tax subsidies and

15
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

reward-penalty mechanisms, would help provide further insights. Hong, I.H., Chen, P.C., Yu, H.T., 2016. The effects of government subsidies on
decentralized reverse supply chains. Int. J. Prod. Res. 54 (13), 3962–3977.
Hong, X.P., Govindan, K., Xu, L., Du, P., 2017. Quantity and collection decisions in a
closed-loop supply chain with technology licensing. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 256 (3),
Declaration of competing interest 820–829.
Huang, S., Yang, Y., Anderson, K., 2001. A theory of finitely durable goods monopoly
None. with used-goods market and transaction costs. Manag. Sci. 47 (11), 1515–1532.
Huang, X.M., Atasu, A., Tereyagoglu, N., Toktay, L.B., 2023. Lemons, trade-ins, and
certified pre-owned programs. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. https://doi.org/10.1287/
Data availability msom.2022.1176.
Huang, X., Atasu, A., Toktay, L.B., 2019a. Design implications of extended producer
responsibility for durable products. Manag. Sci. 65 (6), 2573–2590.
Data will be made available on request. Huang, X., Gu, J.W., Ching, W.K., Siu, T.K., 2014. Impact of secondary market on
consumer return policies and supply chain coordination. Omega 45, 57–70.
Acknowledgment Huang, Y.S., Lin, C.J., Fang, C.C., 2019b. A study on recycle schedules for trade-in
rebates with consideration of product life cycle. IEEE Trans. Eng. Manag. 66 (3),
475–490.
This work was partially supported by the National Natural Science Huang, Y., Wang, Z., 2019. Pricing and production decisions in a closed-loop supply
Foundation of China (72274175, 71874159) and the Zhejiang Provin­ chain considering strategic consumers and technology licensing. Int. J. Prod. Res. 57
(9), 2847–2866.
cial Philosophy and Social Science Planning Project (22NDJC057YB). Ishihara, M., Ching, A.T., 2019. Dynamic demand for new and used durable goods
without physical depreciation: the case of Japanese video games. Market. Sci. 38 (3),
392–416.
Appendix A. Supplementary data
Jacobs, B.W., Subramanian, R., 2012. Sharing responsibility for product recovery across
the supply chain. Prod. Oper. Manag. 21 (1), 85–100.
Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https://doi. Johnson, M.R., McCarthy, I.P., 2014. Product recovery decisions with the context of
org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2023.108933. extended producer responsibility. J. Eng. Technol. Manag. 34, 9–28.
Kiddee, P., Naidu, R., Wong, M.H., 2013. Electronic waste management approaches: an
overview. Waste Manag. 33 (5), 1237–1250.
References Krystofik, M., Gaustad, G., 2018. Tying product reuse into tying arrangements to achieve
competitive advantage and environmental improvement. Resour. Conserv. Recycl.
135, 235–245.
Abbey, J.D., Blackburn, J.D., 2015. Optimal pricing for new and remanufactured
Lacourbe, P., 2016. Durable goods leasing in the presence of exporting used products to
products. J. Oper. Manag. 36, 130–146.
an international secondary market. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 250 (2), 448–456.
Abbey, J.D., Geismar, H.N., Souza, G.C., 2019. Improving remanufacturing core recovery
Li, K.J., Xu, S.H., 2015. The comparison between trade-in and leasing of a product with
and profitability through seeding. Prod. Oper. Manag. 28 (3), 610–627.
technology innovations. Omega 54, 134–146.
Agrawal, V., Ferguson, M., Toktay, L.B., Thomas, V., 2012. Is leasing greener than
Li, K., Liu, J., Fu, H., Liu, B., 2020. Acquisition and pricing strategies in hybrid
selling? Manag. Sci. 58 (3), 523–533.
manufacturing-remanufacturing systems. J. Manuf. Syst. 57, 217–230.
Alev, I., Agrawal, V.V., Atasu, A., 2020. Extended producer responsibility for durable
Li, X., Li, Y., Cai, X., 2016. On core sorting in RMTS and RMTO systems: a newsvendor
products. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 22 (2), 1523–4614.
framework. Decis. Sci. J. 47 (1), 60–93.
Ameli, M., Mansour, S., Ahmadi-Javid, A., 2019. A simulation-optimization model for
Li, Y., Feng, L., Kannan, G., Xu, F., 2019. Effects of a secondary market on original
sustainable product design and efficient end-of-life management based on individual
equipment manufactures’ pricing, trade-in remanufacturing, and entry decisions.
producer responsibility. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 140, 246–258.
Eur. J. Oper. Res. 279 (3), 751–766.
Angelus, A., 2011. A multiechelon inventory problem with secondary market sales.
Liu, Z., Che, J., Dialloa, C., 2018. Optimal production and pricing strategies for a
Manag. Sci. 57 (12), 2145–2162.
remanufacturing firm. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 204, 290–315.
Atasu, A., Ozdemir, O., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2013a. Stakeholder perspectives on E-
Liu, Z., Wan, M.D., Zheng, X.X., Koh, S.C.L., 2022. Fairness concerns and extended
Waste take-back legislation. Prod. Oper. Manag. 22 (2), 382–396.
producer responsibility transmission in a circular supply chain. Ind. Market. Manag.
Atasu, A., Sarvary, M., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2008. Remanufacturing as a marketing
102, 216–228.
strategy. Manag. Sci. 54 (10), 1731–1746.
Ma, W., Zhao, Z., Ke, H., 2013. Dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with government
Atasu, A., Toktay, L.B., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2013b. How collection cost structure
consumption-subsidy. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 226 (2), 221–227.
drives a manufacturer’s reverse channel choice. Prod. Oper. Manag. 22 (5),
Meng, K., Lou, P., Peng, X., Prybutokd, V., 2017. Multi-objective optimization decision-
1089–1102.
making of quality dependent product recovery for sustainability. Int. J. Prod. Econ.
Cai, X., Lai, M., Li, X., Li, Y., Wu, X., 2014. Optimal acquisition and production policy in a
188, 72–85.
hybrid manufacturing/remanufacturing system with core acquisition at different
Nie, J.J., Liu, J., Yuan, H.P., Jin, M.Y., 2021. Economic and environmental impacts of
quality levels. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 233 (2), 374–382.
competitive remanufacturing under government financial intervention. Comput. Ind.
Calmon, A.P., Graves, S.C., 2017. Inventory management in a consumer electronics
Eng. 159, 107473.
closed-loop supply chain. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 19 (4), 568–585.
Nnorom, I.C., Osibanjo, O., 2008. Overview of electronic waste management practices
Chen, C.K., Ulya, M.A., 2019. Analyses of the reward-penalty mechanism in green closed-
and legislations, and their poor applications in the developing countries. Resour.
loop supply chains with product remanufacturing. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 210, 211–223.
Conserv. Recycl. 52 (6), 843–858.
Chen, J., Esteban, S., Shum, M., 2013. When do secondary markets harm firms? Am.
Oraiopoulos, N., Ferguson, M.E., Toktay, L.B., 2012. Relicensing as a secondary market
Econ. Rev. 103 (7), 2911–2934.
strategy. Manag. Sci. 58 (5), 1022–1037.
Chen, Y., Chen, F., 2019. On the competition between two modes of product recovery:
Orsdemir, A., Kemahlioglu, E., Parlakturk, A.K., 2014. Competitive quality choice and
remanufacturing and refurbishing. Prod. Oper. Manag. 28 (12), 2983–3001.
remanufacturing. Prod. Oper. Manag. 23 (1), 48–64.
Cole, D., Mahapatra, S., Webster, S., 2017. A comparison of buyback and trade-in policies
Ramirez, F.J., Aledo, J.A., Gamez, J.A., Pham, D.T., 2020. Economic modelling of robotic
to acquire used products for remanufacturing. J. Bus. Logist. 38 (3), 217–232.
disassembly in end-of-life product recovery for remanufacturing. Comput. Ind. Eng.
Corsini, F., Rizzi, F., Frey, M., 2017. Extended producer responsibility: the impact of
142, 106339.
organizational dimensions on WEEE collection from households. Waste Manag. 59,
Robotis, A., Boyaci, T., Verter, V., 2012. Investing in reusability of products of uncertain
23–29.
remanufacturing cost: the role of inspection capabilities. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 140 (1),
Dong, C., Lei, Y., Liu, Q., 2023. (Un)conditional collection policies on used products with
385–395.
strategic customers. Prod. Oper. Manag. 32 (1), 82–97.
Savaskan, R.C., Bhattacharya, S., Van Wassenhove, L.N., 2004. Closed-Loop supply chain
Esenduran, G., Kemahlioglu-Ziya, E., Swaminathan, J.M., 2016. Take-back legislation:
models with product remanufacturing. Manag. Sci. 50 (2), 239–252.
consequences for remanufacturing and environment. Decis. Sci. J. 47 (2), 219–256.
Shan, F.F., Xiao, W.L., Yang, F., 2021. Comparison of three E-Waste take-back policies.
Ferguson, M., Guide, V.D., Koca, E., Souza, G.C., 2009. The value of quality grading in
Int. J. Prod. Econ. 242, 108287.
remanufacturing. Prod. Oper. Manag. 18 (3), 300–314.
Shi, J., Zhang, G., Sha, J., 2011. Optimal production and pricing policy for a closed loop
Ferrer, G., Swaminathan, J.M., 2006. Managing new and remanufactured products.
system. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 55 (6), 639–647.
Manag. Sci. 52 (1), 15–26.
Shi, T.Q., Gu, W.J., Chhajed, D., Petruzzi, N.C., 2016. Effects of remanufacturable
Ferrer, G., Swaminathan, J.M., 2010. Managing new and differentiated remanufactured
product design on market segmentation and the environment. Decis. Sci. J. 47 (2),
products. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 203 (2), 370–379.
298–332.
Fu, W.N., Atasu, A., Tereyagoglu, N., 2022. Warranty length, product reliability, and
Sun, B.B., Schnoor, J.L., Zeng, E.Y., 2022. Decadal journey of E-Waste recycling: what
secondary markets. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 24 (4), 2240–2255.
has it achieved? ES T (Environ. Sci. Technol.) 56 (18), 12785–12792.
Geyer, R., Van Wassenhove, L.N., Atasu, A., 2007. The economics of remanufacturing
Vedantam, A., Iyer, A., 2021. Revenue-sharing contracts under quality uncertainty in
under limited component durability and finite product life cycles. Manag. Sci. 53 (1),
remanufacturing. Prod. Oper. Manag. 30 (7), 2008–2026.
88–100.
Wu, H., Han, X., Yang, Q., Pu, X., 2018. Production and coordination decisions in a
Gui, L., 2020. Recycling infrastructure development under extended producer
closed-loop supply chain with remanufacturing cost disruptions when retailers
responsibility in developing economies. Prod. Oper. Manag. 29 (8), 1858–1877.
compete. J. Intell. Manuf. 29 (1), 227–235.
Hickle, G.T., 2014. An examination of governance within extended producer
responsibility policy regimes in North America. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 92, 55–65.

16
J. Cao et al. International Journal of Production Economics 263 (2023) 108933

Wu, X., Zhou, Y., 2019. Buyer-specific versus uniform pricing in a closed-loop supply Zhou, W., Zheng, Y., Huang, W., 2017. Competitive advantage of qualified WEEE
chain with third-party remanufacturing. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 273 (2), 548–560. recyclers through EPR legislation. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 257 (2), 641–655.
Xiao, Y., 2017. Choosing the right exchange-old-for-new programs for durable goods Zhou, Y., Xiong, Y., Li, G., Xiong, Z., Beck, M., 2013. The bright side of
with a rollover. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 259 (2), 512–526. manufacturing–remanufacturing conflict in a decentralized closed-loop supply chain.
Xiong, Y., Zhao, P., Xiong, Z., Li, G., 2016. The impact of product upgrading on the Int. J. Prod. Res. 51 (9), 2639–2651.
decision of entrance to a secondary market. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 252 (2), 443–454.

17

You might also like