Download Fundamentals of Investments 6th Edition Jordan Solutions Manual all chapters

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 31

Fundamentals of Investments 6th

Edition Jordan Solutions Manual


Go to download the full and correct content document:
https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-investments-6th-edition-jordan-soluti
ons-manual/
More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant
download maybe you interests ...

Fundamentals of Investments 6th Edition Jordan Test


Bank

https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-investments-6th-
edition-jordan-test-bank/

Fundamentals of Investments 8th Edition Jordan Test


Bank

https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-investments-8th-
edition-jordan-test-bank/

Fundamentals of Investments Valuation and Management


8th Edition Jordan Solutions Manual

https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-investments-
valuation-and-management-8th-edition-jordan-solutions-manual/

Fundamentals of Investments Valuation and Management


7th Edition Jordan Solutions Manual

https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-investments-
valuation-and-management-7th-edition-jordan-solutions-manual/
Fundamentals of Investments Canadian 3rd Edition Jordan
Test Bank

https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-investments-
canadian-3rd-edition-jordan-test-bank/

Fundamentals of Investments Valuation and Management


7th Edition Jordan Test Bank

https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-investments-
valuation-and-management-7th-edition-jordan-test-bank/

Fundamentals of Investments 3rd Edition Alexander Test


Bank

https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-investments-3rd-
edition-alexander-test-bank/

Fundamentals of Economics 6th Edition Boyes Solutions


Manual

https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-economics-6th-
edition-boyes-solutions-manual/

Fundamentals of Thermodynamics 6th Edition Sonntag


Solutions Manual

https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-
thermodynamics-6th-edition-sonntag-solutions-manual/
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

Chapter 7
Stock Price Behavior and Market
Efficiency
Slides:
7-1. Title Slide
7-2. Learning Objectives
7-3. The Market
7-4. Controversy, Intrigue, and Confusion
7-5. Market Efficiency
7-6. What Does “Beat the Market” Mean?
7-7. Three Economic Forces that Can Lead to Market Efficiency
7-8. Forms of Market Efficiency, (i.e., what information is used?)
7-9. Information Sets for Market Efficiency
7-10. Why Would a Market be Efficient?
7-11. Some Implications of Market Efficiency: Does Old Information Help Predict
Future Stock Prices?
7-12. Some Implications of Market Efficiency: Random Walks and Stock Prices
7-13. Random Walks and Stock Prices, Illustrated.
7-14. How New Information Gets into Stock Prices, I.
7-15. How New Information Gets into Stock Prices, II.
7-16. Event Studies, I.
7-17. Event Studies, II.
7-18. Event Studies, III.
7-19. Event Studies, IV.
7-20. Event Studies, V.
7-21. Event Studies, VI.
7-22. Event Studies, VII.
7-23. Informed Traders and Insider Trading, I.
7-24. Informed Traders and Insider Trading, II.
7-25. Informed Trading
7-26. Legal Insider Trading
7-27. Who is an “Insider”?
7-28. Illegal Insider Trading
7-29. It’s Not a Good Thing: What did Martha do? (Part 1)
7-30. It’s Not a Good Thing: What did Martha do? (Part 2)
7-31. Are Financial Markets Efficient, I?
7-32. Are Financial Markets Efficient, II?
7-33. Some Implications if Markets are Efficient
7-34. Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money Managers, I.
7-35. Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money Managers, II.
7-36. Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money Managers,
III.
7-37. Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money Managers,
IV.
7-38. Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money Managers, V.
7-39. Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money Managers,
VI.
7-40. Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money Managers,
VII.

7-1
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

7-41. Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money Managers,


VIII.
7-42. Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money Managers,
IX.
7-43. What is the Role for Portfolio Managers in an Efficient Market?
7-44. Anomalies
7-45. The Day-of-the-Week Effect: Mondays tend to have a Negative Average
Return
7-46. The Amazing January Effect, I.
7-47. The Amazing January Effect, II.
7-48. The Turn-of-the-Year Effect, I.
7-49. The Turn-of-the-Year Effect, II.
7-50. The Turn-of-the-Month Effect, I.
7-51. The Turn-of-the-Month Effect, II.
7-52. Bubbles and Crashes
7-53. The Crash of 1929
7-54. The Crash of 1929—The Aftermath
7-55. The Crash of 1987
7-56. The Crash of 1987—Aftermath
7-57. Circuit Breakers
7-58. The Asian Crash
7-59. The Asian Crash—Aftermath
7-60. The “Dot-Com” Bubble and Crash, I
7-61. The “Dot-Com” Bubble and Crash, II
7-62. The Crash of October 2008
7-63. The Dow Jones Average, January 2008 through April 2010
7-64. Chapter Review, I.
7-65. Chapter Review, II.

Chapter Organization
7.1 Introduction to Market Efficiency
7.2 What does “Beat the Market” Mean?
7.3 Foundations of Market Efficiency
7.4 Forms of Market Efficiency
7.5 Why Would a Market Be Efficient?
7.6 Some Implications of Market Efficiency
A. Does Old Information Help Predict Future Stock Prices?
B. Random Walks and Stock Prices
C. How Does New Information Get into Stock Prices?
D. Event Studies
7.7 Informed Traders and Insider Trading
A. Informed Trading
B. Insider Trading
7.8 How Efficient are Markets?
A. Are Financial Markets Efficient?
B. Some Implications of Market Efficiency
7.9 Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money
Managers
7.10 Anomalies

7-2
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

A. The Day-of-the-Week Effect


B. The Amazing January Effect
C. Turn-of-the-Year Effect
D. Turn-of-the-Month Effect
E. The Earnings Announcement Puzzle
F. The Price-Earnings (P/E) Puzzle
7.11 Bubbles and Crashes
A. The Crash of 1929
B. The Crash of October 1987
C. The Asian Crash
D. The “Dot-Com” Bubble and Crash
E. The Crash of October 2008
7.12 Summary and Conclusions

Selected Web Sites


 www.e-m-h.org/ (for information on market efficiency)
 www.zakon.org/robert/internet/timeline (documentation of the growth of the
internet)

Annotated Chapter Outline


7.1 Introduction to Market Efficiency

Market efficiency: Relation between stock prices and information


available to investors indicating whether it is possible to "beat the market;"
if a market is efficient, it is not possible except by luck.

Efficient market hypothesis (EMH): Theory asserting that, as a practical


matter, the major financial markets reflect all relevant information at a
given time.

The primary question is: Can you, or can anyone, consistently "beat the market?"
(Note that the duck on slide 7-5 is trying to “beat the market” with his hammer. In
PowerPoint 2007, the duck is animated (This is the only animated slide in the
supplements). The duck attempts to beat the market, but fails. This is intended to
provide a bit of levity to the subject.)

7.2 What does “Beat the Market” Mean?

Excess return: A return in excess of that earned by other investments


having the same risk.

7-3
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

To judge if an investment "beat the market," we need to know if the return was
high or low relative to the risk involved. We need to determine if the investment
has earned a positive excess return in order to say it "beat the market."

7.3 Foundations of Market Efficiency

Three economic forces can lead to market efficiency. These conditions are so
powerful that any one of them can result in market efficiency.

These conditions are:

1. Investor Rationality. If every investor always made perfectly rational


investment decisions, earning an excess return would be difficult. If everyone is
fully rational, equivalent risk assets would all have the same expected returns.
Put differently, no bargains would be there to be had, because relative prices
would all be correct.

2. Independent Deviations from Rationality. Even if the investor rationality


condition does not hold, the market could still be efficient. Suppose that many
investors are irrational, and a company makes a relevant announcement about a
new product. Some investors will be overly optimistic, while some will be overly
pessimistic, but the net effect might be that these investors cancel each other
out. In a sense, the irrationality is just noise that is diversified away. As a result,
the market could still be efficient (or nearly efficient). What is important here is
that irrational investors do not have similar beliefs.

3. Arbitrage. Suppose there are many irrational traders and further suppose that
their collective irrationality does not balance out. In this case, observed market
prices can be too high or too low relative to their risk. Now suppose there are
some well-capitalized, intelligent, and rational investors. This group of traders
would see these high or low market prices as a profit opportunity and engage in
arbitrage—buying relatively inexpensive stocks and selling relatively expensive
stocks. If these rational arbitrage traders dominate irrational traders, the market
will still be efficient. We sometimes hear the expression “Market efficiency
doesn’t require that everybody be rational, just that somebody is.”

Lecture Tip. Students, like all of us, look at the world through their own
experiences. They have met some irrational people in their lives. It is easy for
them to think that these irrational people could be representative investors and
that market efficiency simply cannot hold because of investor irrationality.

7-4
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

7.4 Forms of Market Efficiency

Weak-form efficient market: A market in which past prices and volume


figures are of no use in beating the market.

Semistrong-form efficient market: A market in which publicly available


information is of no use in beating the market.

Strong-form efficient market: A market in which information of any kind,


public or private, is of no use in beating the market.

"A market is efficient with respect to some particular information if that


information is not useful in earning a positive excess return." So, a market can
only be determined to be efficient with respect to specific information. The three
forms include:

• Weak-form efficiency, with respect to information reflected in past price


and volume figures.

• Semistrong-form efficiency, with respect to any publicly available


information.

• Strong-form efficiency, with respect to any information, both public and


private.

To be clear, if the information allows an investor to earn excess returns on an


investment, the market is not efficient with respect to that information. Therefore,
if an investor uses past price information to earn an excess return, then the
market is not weak-form efficient. If an investor uses a firm's financial statements
to earn an excess return, the market is not semistrong-form efficient. Finally, if an
investor uses inside information to earn an excess return, the market is not
strong-form efficient.

7.5 Why Would a Market Be Efficient?

The driving force toward market efficiency is simply competition and the profit
motive.

Consider a large mutual fund such as the Fidelity Magellan Fund (one of the
largest equity funds in the United States, with about $45 billion under
management). Suppose Fidelity was able, through its research, to improve the
performance of this fund by 20 basis points for one year only. How much would
this one-time 20-basis point improvement be worth?

7-5
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

The answer is 0.0020 times $45 billion, or $90 million. Thus, Fidelity would be
willing to spend up to $90 million to boost the performance of this one fund by as
little as one-fifth of 1 percent for a single year only.

This example shows that even relatively small performance enhancements are
worth tremendous amounts of money and thereby create the incentive to unearth
relevant information and use it.

7.6 Some Implications of Market Efficiency

If markets are efficient:

• Security selection is less important; investors may as well hold index funds
to minimize their costs.

• There is little need for professional money managers.

• Investors should not try to time the market. (In fact, successful market
timing is very difficult to achieve, even ignoring market efficiency.)

Lecture Tip: It may be helpful to restate the implications of market efficiency with
respect to the forms of market efficiency, as follows:

• Weak-form efficiency: If weak-form efficiency holds, then technical


analysis is of no use, and the efforts of technical analysts are of no benefit
to investors.

• Semistrong-form efficiency: If semistrong-form efficiency holds, then


fundamental analysis using publicly available information is of no benefit,
and most of the financial analysts and mutual fund managers are not
providing any value.

• Strong-form efficiency: If strong-form efficiency holds, then inside


information is of no value, suggesting that there should be no restrictions
on insider trading.

A. Does Old Information Help Predict Future Stock Prices?

In its weakest form, the efficient market hypothesis is the simple statement that
stock prices fully reflect all past information. If this is true, this means that
studying past price movements in the hopes of predicting future stock price
movements is really a waste of time.

7-6
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

There is also a very subtle prediction at work here. That is, no matter how often a
particular stock price path has related to subsequent stock price changes in the
past, there is no assurance that this relationship will occur again in the future.

Researchers have used sophisticated statistical techniques to test whether past


stock price movements are of any value in predicting future stock price
movements. This turns out to be a surprisingly difficult question to answer clearly
and without qualification. In short, although some researchers have been able to
show that future returns are partly predictable by past returns, the predicted
returns are not economically important, which means that predictability is not
sufficient to earn an excess return.

In addition, trading costs generally swamp attempts to build a profitable trading


system on the basis of past returns. Researchers have been unable to provide
evidence of a superior trading strategy that uses only past returns. That is,
trading costs matter, and buy-and-hold strategies involving broad market indexes
are extremely difficult to outperform.

B. Random Walks and Stock Prices

Ask your students whether stock market prices are predictable: many of them will
say yes. To their surprise, it is very difficult to predict stock market prices. In fact,
considerable research has shown that stock prices change through time as if
they are random. That is, stock price increases and decreases are equally likely.

When the path that a stock price follows shows no discernible pattern, then the
stock’s price behavior is largely consistent with the notion of a random walk. A
random walk is related to the weak-form version of the efficient market
hypothesis because past knowledge of the stock price is not useful in predicting
future stock prices.

We illustrate daily price changes for Intel stock in the text. These daily price
changes are not truly a random walk. To qualify as a true random walk, Intel
stock price changes would have to be independent and identically distributed.
Still, the graph of daily price changes for Intel stock is essentially what a random
walk looks like. It is certainly hard to see any pattern in these daily price changes.

C. How Does New Information Get into Stock Prices?

In its semistrong form, the efficient market hypothesis is the simple statement
that stock prices fully reflect publicly available information. Stock prices change
when traders buy and sell shares based on their view of the future prospects for
the stock. The future prospects for the stock are influenced by unexpected news
announcements. Prices can adjust to news announcements in three ways:

7-7
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

• Efficient market reaction: The price instantaneously adjusts to, and


fully reflects, new information. There is no tendency for subsequent
increases or decreases to occur.

• Delayed reaction: The price partially adjusts to the new information,


but days elapse before the price completely reflects new information.

• Overreaction and correction: The price over-adjusts to the new


information; it overshoots the appropriate new price but eventually
falls to the new price.

D. Event Studies

We have included an event study for Advanced Medical Optics, Inc. (EYE) in the
text. On Friday, May 25, 2007, executives of Advanced Medical Optics Inc.
recalled a contact lens solution called Complete MoisturePlus Multi Purpose
Solution. The company took this voluntary action after the Centers for Disease
Control and Prevention (CDC) found a link between the solution and a rare
cornea infection called acanthamoeba keratitis, or AK for short.

Executives at Advanced Medical Optics chose to recall their product even though
they did not find evidence their manufacturing process introduced the parasite
that can lead to AK.

Researchers use a technique known as an event study to test the effects of news
announcements on stock prices.

It has been our experience that students really like to get a glimpse of an “actual”
technique used by finance researchers. You will note that we strove to focus our
exposition on the reaction to the news, rather than the methods of event studies.

7.7 Informed Traders and Insider Trading

Recall that if a market is strong-form efficient, no information of any kind, public


or private, is useful in beating the market. However, inside information of many
types clearly would enable you to earn essentially unlimited returns. This fact
generates an interesting question: Should any of us be able to earn returns
based on information that is not known to the public?

In the United States (and in many other countries, though not all), making profits
on nonpublic information is illegal. This ban is said to be necessary if investors
are to have trust in U.S. stock markets. The United States Securities and
Exchange Commission (SEC) is charged with enforcing laws concerning illegal
trading activities.

7-8
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

As a result, we present the distinctions among informed traders, illegal insider


trading, and legal insider trading.

A. Informed Trading

When an investor makes a decision to buy or sell a stock based on publicly


available information and analysis, this investor is said to be an informed trader.
The information that an informed trader possesses might come from reading The
Wall Street Journal, reading quarterly reports issued by a company, gathering
financial information from the Internet, talking to other traders, or a host of other
sources.

Lecture Tip. You will notice that we do not talk about noise traders here. We left
them out here because the focus of this section is on information. Talking about
noise traders (and their lack of information) could deflect the discussion away
from information and the types of information-based trades.

B. Insider Trading

Illegal Insider Trading: For the purposes of defining illegal insider trading, an
insider is someone who possesses material nonpublic information. Such
information is both not known to the public and, if it were known, would impact
the stock price. A person can be charged with insider trading when he or she
acts on such information in an attempt to make a profit.

Legal “Insider Trading”: A company’s corporate insiders can make perfectly


legal trades in the stock of their company. To do so, they must comply with the
reporting rules made by the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. When
they make a trade and report it to the SEC, these trades are reported to the
public. In addition, corporate insiders must declare that trades that they made
were based on public information about the company, rather than “inside”
information. Most public companies also have guidelines that must be followed.

It’s Not a Good Thing: What did Martha Do? Martha Stewart was accused, but
not convicted, of insider trading. She was accused, and convicted, of obstructing
justice and lying to investigators.

7.8 How Efficient are Markets?

A. Are Financial Markets Efficient?

There are four reasons why market efficiency is difficult to test:


• The risk-adjustment problem
• The relevant information problem
• The dumb luck problem

7-9
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

• The data snooping problem

There are three generalities based on research that are relevant to market
efficiency:
• Short-term stock price and market movements are very difficult to predict
with accuracy.

• The market reacts quickly and sharply to new information. There is little
evidence that a market under (or over) reaction can be profitably
exploited.

• If the stock market can be beaten, it is not obvious, so this implies that the
market is not grossly inefficient.

B. Some Implications of Market Efficiency

Even if all markets are efficient, asset allocation is still important because the
risk-return tradeoff still holds.

7.9 Market Efficiency and the Performance of Professional Money


Managers

There have been a number of studies that compare the performance of mutual
fund managers with market indices. The results of almost every study indicate
that the market indices outperform the mutual fund managers. This is further
evidence in favor of market efficiency. Mutual fund managers should be experts
in technical and fundamental analysis, and they should be able to use these tools
to earn excess returns, if anybody can.

Lecture Tip: An interesting study by Fortin and Michelson [Journal of Financial


Planning, February 1999] compares the performance of a large sample of mutual
funds categorized by investment objective, to their respective market indexes.
For example, growth funds were compared to the S&P 500, corporate bond
funds were compared to the Lehman Brothers Corporate Bond index,
international funds were compared to the Morgan Stanley EAFE index, and small
company equity funds were compared to the Wilshire 2000. This study found
that, on average, the benchmark indices significantly outperformed the mutual
funds for all fund categories but one. The one category that the funds
outperformed the index was small company equity funds. Apparently the fund
managers are able to exploit enough market inefficiencies in the small firm equity
market to allow excess returns to accrue.

7-10
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

7.10 Anomalies

In this section, several well-known market anomalies are discussed: the Day-of-
the-week effect; the amazing January effect (and two of its extensions), and;
Bubbles and Crashes (including the Market Crashes of 1929, 1987, the Asian
Crash, and the “Dot-Com Bubble and Crash).

A. The Day-of-the-Week Effect

Day-of-the-week effect: This is the term for the tendency for Monday to
have a negative average return.

Table 7.2 shows the day-of-the-week effect, which indicates that Monday is the
only day with a negative average return. Notice that Friday has a high positive
return. This effect is statistically significant, but it is difficult to exploit it to earn a
positive excess. About all we can do is use this in our trading decisions;
purchase a stock late on Monday and sell our stocks late on Friday.

B. The Amazing January Effect

January effect: This is the term for the tendency for small stocks to have
large returns in January.

Figures 7.9a and 7.9b show the results of the January effect. Small stocks tend
to have much higher returns in January, whereas larger stocks (S&P 500) do not
show this result. The bulk of the return occurs in the first few days of January.
The effect is more pronounced for stocks that have significant declines. This
effect exists in most major markets around the world. Two factors are important
in explaining the January effect: tax-loss selling and institutional investors
rebalancing their portfolios.

C. Turn-of-the-Year Effect

Researchers have delved deeply into the January effect to see whether the effect
is due to returns during the whole month of January or to returns bracketing the
end of the year. Table 7.4 shows our calculations concerning this effect. The
returns in the “Turn-of-the-Year Days” category are higher than returns in the
“Rest-of-the-Days” category. Further, the difference is apparent in the 1984-
2009 period. However, the difference was more than twice as large in the 1962-
1983 period.

D. Turn-of-the-Month Effect

Financial market researchers have also investigated whether a turn-of-the-month


effect exists. Table 7.5 shows the results of our calculations. It appears that this
effect was stronger in the 1984-2009 period than in the 1962-1983 period.

7-11
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

E. The Earnings Announcement Puzzle

Researchers have found that it takes days (or even longer) for a market price to
adjust fully to information about earnings surprises. In addition, some
researchers have found that buying stocks after positive earnings surprises is a
profitable investment strategy.

F. The Price-Earnings (P/E) Puzzle

The P/E ratio is widely followed by investors and is used in stock valuation.
Researchers have found that, on average, stocks with relatively low P/E ratios
outperform stocks with relatively high P/E ratios, even after adjusting for other
factors, like risk. Because a P/E ratio is publicly available information, it should
already be reflected by stock prices. However, purchasing stocks with relatively
low P/E ratios appears to be a potentially profitable investment strategy.

7.11 Bubbles and Crashes

A bubble occurs when market prices soar far in excess of what normal and
rational analysis would suggest. Investment bubbles eventually pop because
they are not based on fundamental values. When a bubble does pop, investors
find themselves holding assets with plummeting values.

A crash is a significant and sudden drop in market wide values. Crashes are
generally associated with a bubble. Typically, a bubble lasts much longer than a
crash. A bubble can form over weeks, months, or even years. Crashes, on the
other hand, are sudden, generally lasting less than a week. However, the
disastrous financial aftermath of a crash can last for years.

A. The Crash of 1929

Although the Crash of 1929 was a large decline, it pales with respect to the
ensuing bear market. As shown in Figure 7.11, the DJIA rebounded about 20
percent following the October 1929 crash. However, the DJIA then began a
protracted fall, reaching the bottom at 40.56 on July 8, 1932. This level
represents about a 90 percent decline from the record high level of 386.10 on
September 3, 1929. By the way, the DJIA did not surpass its previous high level
until November 24, 1954, more than 25 years later.

B. The Crash of October 1987

NYSE circuit breakers: This is the name for rules that kick in to slow
trading when the DJIA declines by more than a preset amount in a trading
session. In fact, if the DJIA declines far enough, trading will halt.

7-12
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

On October 19, 1987 (Black Monday) the Dow plummeted 500 points to 1,700
with about $500 billion in losses that day. There are several explanations for
what happened:

• Irrational investors bid up stock prices and the bubble popped.

• Markets were volatile, the economy was shaky, and Congress was in
session considering anti-takeover legislation.

• Program trading quickly created very large sell orders.

Interestingly, the market recovered very quickly. The market was up in 1987 and
the bull market continued for many years after the crash. As a result of the crash,
NYSE circuit breakers were introduced. These circuit breakers required trading
halts based upon 10, 20, and 30 percent declines in the DJIA. The trading halts
vary from 30 minutes, to two hours, to the rest of the trading day.

C. The Asian Crash

The crash of the Nikkei Index, which began in 1990, lengthened into a
particularly long bear market. It is quite like the Crash of 1929 in that respect. In
three years from December 1986 to the peak in December 1989, the Nikkei 225
Index rose 115 percent. Over the next three years, the index lost 57 percent of its
value. In April 2003, the Nikkei Index stood at a level that was 80 percent
off its peak in December 1989.

D. The “Dot-Com” Bubble and Crash

By the mid-1990s, the rise in Internet use and its international growth potential
fueled widespread excitement over the “new economy.” Investors did not seem to
care about solid business plans—only big ideas. Investor euphoria led to a surge
in Internet IPOs, which were commonly referred to as “dot-coms” because so
many of their names ended in “.com.” Of course, the lack of solid business
models doomed many of the newly formed companies. Many of them suffered
huge losses and some folded relatively shortly after their IPOs.

The Amex Internet Index soared from a level of 114.60 on October 1, 1998, to its
peak of 688.52 in late March 2000, an increase of about 500 percent. The Amex
Internet Index then fell to a level of 58.59 in early October 2002, a drop of about
91 percent. By contrast, the S&P 500 Index rallied about 31 percent in the same
1998–2000 time period and fell 40 percent during the 2000–2002 time period.

7-13
Chapter 07 - Stock Price Behavior and Market Efficiency

E. The Crash of October 2008

Although still under debate, many agree that one of the underlying causes of the
crash of 2008 was excess liquidity, which allowed unworthy borrowers to obtain
financing, primarily for mortgages. Moreover, much of this was done at low
“teaser rates.” When these rates reset, require payments increased, resulting in
bankruptcies for these so-called subprime loans. If house prices had continued to
climb, borrowers could have refinanced, avoiding trouble. However, this did not
happen.

7.12 Summary and Conclusions

7-14
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
Transcriber’s Note
This transcription follows the text of the edition published by
Robert M. McBride & Company in 1919. The following alterations
have been made to correct what are believed to be unambiguous
printer’s errors:
“inheritence” to “inheritance” (Ch. I);
“anum” to “annum” (Ch. I);
“testatively” to “tentatively” (Ch. IV);
“noncommital” to “noncommittal” (Ch. IV);
“hershe” to “herself” (Ch. IV);
“irration” to “irritation” (Ch. IX);
“negotations” to “negotiations” (Ch. X);
“undveloped” to “undeveloped” (Ch. XI);
“possesssion” to “possession” (Ch. XII);
“thicker than flees” to “thicker than fleas” (Ch. XIII);
“satisisfaction” to “satisfaction” (Ch. XIII);
“tremondous” to “tremendous” (Ch. XIV);
“gussed” to “guessed” (Ch. XIV);
“comfortabe” to “comfortable” (Ch. XIV);
“nervelesly” to “nervelessly” (Ch. XV);
“tumultous” to “tumultuous” (Ch. XV);
“caught up the try” to “caught up the tray” (Ch. XV);
“purposly” to “purposely” (Ch. XVII);
“organizatin” to “organization” (Ch. XVII);
“innividual” to “individual” (Ch. XVII);
“susided” to “subsided” (Ch. XVII);
“comosed” to “composed” (Ch. XVII);
“adressing” to “addressing” (Ch. XVIII);
“serenly” to “serenely” (Ch. XIX);
“scarely” to “scarcely” (Ch. XIX);
“dependant” to “dependent” (Ch. XX);
“interupted” to “interrupted” (Ch. XXII);
“wondeful” to “wonderful” (Ch. XXII);
“accuresd” to “accursed” (Ch. XXII);
“twenty-eigth” to “twenty-eighth” (Chs. XXIII & XXVII);
“wthout” to “without” (Ch. XXVII).

Any other apparent errors and/or inconsistencies have been


preserved.
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK ASHES TO
ASHES ***

Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.

Creating the works from print editions not protected by U.S.


copyright law means that no one owns a United States copyright in
these works, so the Foundation (and you!) can copy and distribute it
in the United States without permission and without paying copyright
royalties. Special rules, set forth in the General Terms of Use part of
this license, apply to copying and distributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works to protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG™ concept
and trademark. Project Gutenberg is a registered trademark, and
may not be used if you charge for an eBook, except by following the
terms of the trademark license, including paying royalties for use of
the Project Gutenberg trademark. If you do not charge anything for
copies of this eBook, complying with the trademark license is very
easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose such as
creation of derivative works, reports, performances and research.
Project Gutenberg eBooks may be modified and printed and given
away—you may do practically ANYTHING in the United States with
eBooks not protected by U.S. copyright law. Redistribution is subject
to the trademark license, especially commercial redistribution.

START: FULL LICENSE


THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE
PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK

To protect the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting the free


distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work (or
any other work associated in any way with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg”), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full
Project Gutenberg™ License available with this file or online at
www.gutenberg.org/license.

Section 1. General Terms of Use and


Redistributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works
1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg™
electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree
to and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property
(trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all
the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or
destroy all copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in your
possession. If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a
Project Gutenberg™ electronic work and you do not agree to be
bound by the terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from
the person or entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in
paragraph 1.E.8.

1.B. “Project Gutenberg” is a registered trademark. It may only be


used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people
who agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a
few things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg™ electronic
works even without complying with the full terms of this agreement.
See paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with
Project Gutenberg™ electronic works if you follow the terms of this
agreement and help preserve free future access to Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works. See paragraph 1.E below.
1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation (“the
Foundation” or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the
collection of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works. Nearly all the
individual works in the collection are in the public domain in the
United States. If an individual work is unprotected by copyright law in
the United States and you are located in the United States, we do
not claim a right to prevent you from copying, distributing,
performing, displaying or creating derivative works based on the
work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg are removed. Of
course, we hope that you will support the Project Gutenberg™
mission of promoting free access to electronic works by freely
sharing Project Gutenberg™ works in compliance with the terms of
this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg™ name
associated with the work. You can easily comply with the terms of
this agreement by keeping this work in the same format with its
attached full Project Gutenberg™ License when you share it without
charge with others.

1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the terms
of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.

1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg:

1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other


immediate access to, the full Project Gutenberg™ License must
appear prominently whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg™
work (any work on which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” appears, or
with which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” is associated) is
accessed, displayed, performed, viewed, copied or distributed:
This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United
States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with
almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away
or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License
included with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you
are not located in the United States, you will have to check the
laws of the country where you are located before using this
eBook.

1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is derived


from texts not protected by U.S. copyright law (does not contain a
notice indicating that it is posted with permission of the copyright
holder), the work can be copied and distributed to anyone in the
United States without paying any fees or charges. If you are
redistributing or providing access to a work with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg” associated with or appearing on the work, you must
comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1 through
1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the Project
Gutenberg™ trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is posted


with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution
must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any
additional terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms
will be linked to the Project Gutenberg™ License for all works posted
with the permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning of
this work.

1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project


Gutenberg™ License terms from this work, or any files containing a
part of this work or any other work associated with Project
Gutenberg™.

1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this


electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without
prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with
active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project
Gutenberg™ License.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense
to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means
of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original “Plain
Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must include the
full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.

1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying,


performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg™ works
unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing


access to or distributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works
provided that:

• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from
the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”

• You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who


notifies you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt that
s/he does not agree to the terms of the full Project Gutenberg™
License. You must require such a user to return or destroy all
copies of the works possessed in a physical medium and
discontinue all use of and all access to other copies of Project
Gutenberg™ works.

• You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of


any money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in
the electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90
days of receipt of the work.

• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.

1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg™


electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set
forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the manager of
the Project Gutenberg™ trademark. Contact the Foundation as set
forth in Section 3 below.

1.F.

1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend


considerable effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe
and proofread works not protected by U.S. copyright law in creating
the Project Gutenberg™ collection. Despite these efforts, Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works, and the medium on which they may
be stored, may contain “Defects,” such as, but not limited to,
incomplete, inaccurate or corrupt data, transcription errors, a
copyright or other intellectual property infringement, a defective or
damaged disk or other medium, a computer virus, or computer
codes that damage or cannot be read by your equipment.

1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except


for the “Right of Replacement or Refund” described in paragraph
1.F.3, the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner
of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark, and any other party
distributing a Project Gutenberg™ electronic work under this
agreement, disclaim all liability to you for damages, costs and
expenses, including legal fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO
REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT LIABILITY, BREACH OF
WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE
PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH 1.F.3. YOU AGREE THAT THE
FOUNDATION, THE TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY
DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE LIABLE
TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL,
PUNITIVE OR INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE
NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH DAMAGE.

1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you


discover a defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it,
you can receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by
sending a written explanation to the person you received the work
from. If you received the work on a physical medium, you must
return the medium with your written explanation. The person or entity
that provided you with the defective work may elect to provide a
replacement copy in lieu of a refund. If you received the work
electronically, the person or entity providing it to you may choose to
give you a second opportunity to receive the work electronically in
lieu of a refund. If the second copy is also defective, you may
demand a refund in writing without further opportunities to fix the
problem.

1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth in
paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.

1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied


warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages.
If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the
law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be
interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted
by the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any
provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions.
1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the
Foundation, the trademark owner, any agent or employee of the
Foundation, anyone providing copies of Project Gutenberg™
electronic works in accordance with this agreement, and any
volunteers associated with the production, promotion and distribution
of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works, harmless from all liability,
costs and expenses, including legal fees, that arise directly or
indirectly from any of the following which you do or cause to occur:
(a) distribution of this or any Project Gutenberg™ work, (b)
alteration, modification, or additions or deletions to any Project
Gutenberg™ work, and (c) any Defect you cause.

Section 2. Information about the Mission of


Project Gutenberg™
Project Gutenberg™ is synonymous with the free distribution of
electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of
computers including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers.
It exists because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and
donations from people in all walks of life.

Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the


assistance they need are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg™’s
goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg™ collection will
remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a
secure and permanent future for Project Gutenberg™ and future
generations. To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation and how your efforts and donations can help,
see Sections 3 and 4 and the Foundation information page at
www.gutenberg.org.

Section 3. Information about the Project


Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation
The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non-profit
501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the
state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal
Revenue Service. The Foundation’s EIN or federal tax identification
number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg
Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent
permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state’s laws.

The Foundation’s business office is located at 809 North 1500 West,


Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887. Email contact links and up
to date contact information can be found at the Foundation’s website
and official page at www.gutenberg.org/contact

Section 4. Information about Donations to


the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation
Project Gutenberg™ depends upon and cannot survive without
widespread public support and donations to carry out its mission of
increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can
be freely distributed in machine-readable form accessible by the
widest array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small
donations ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax
exempt status with the IRS.

The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating


charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United
States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a
considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and
keep up with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in
locations where we have not received written confirmation of
compliance. To SEND DONATIONS or determine the status of
compliance for any particular state visit www.gutenberg.org/donate.

While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where


we have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no
prohibition against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in
such states who approach us with offers to donate.

International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make


any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from
outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff.

Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation
methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of
other ways including checks, online payments and credit card
donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate.

Section 5. General Information About Project


Gutenberg™ electronic works
Professor Michael S. Hart was the originator of the Project
Gutenberg™ concept of a library of electronic works that could be
freely shared with anyone. For forty years, he produced and
distributed Project Gutenberg™ eBooks with only a loose network of
volunteer support.

Project Gutenberg™ eBooks are often created from several printed


editions, all of which are confirmed as not protected by copyright in
the U.S. unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not
necessarily keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper
edition.

Most people start at our website which has the main PG search
facility: www.gutenberg.org.

This website includes information about Project Gutenberg™,


including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how
to subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.

You might also like