Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 35

Economics 12th Edition Michael Parkin

Solutions Manual
Go to download the full and correct content document:
https://testbankfan.com/product/economics-12th-edition-michael-parkin-solutions-man
ual/
More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant
download maybe you interests ...

Macroeconomics 12th Edition Michael Parkin Solutions


Manual

https://testbankfan.com/product/macroeconomics-12th-edition-
michael-parkin-solutions-manual/

Microeconomics 12th Edition Michael Parkin Solutions


Manual

https://testbankfan.com/product/microeconomics-12th-edition-
michael-parkin-solutions-manual/

Economics 11th Edition Michael Parkin Solutions Manual

https://testbankfan.com/product/economics-11th-edition-michael-
parkin-solutions-manual/

Macroeconomics 12th Edition Michael Parkin Test Bank

https://testbankfan.com/product/macroeconomics-12th-edition-
michael-parkin-test-bank/
Microeconomics 12th Edition Michael Parkin Test Bank

https://testbankfan.com/product/microeconomics-12th-edition-
michael-parkin-test-bank/

Economics 11th Edition Michael Parkin Test Bank

https://testbankfan.com/product/economics-11th-edition-michael-
parkin-test-bank/

Microeconomics 9th Edition Michael Parkin Solutions


Manual

https://testbankfan.com/product/microeconomics-9th-edition-
michael-parkin-solutions-manual/

Microeconomics 11th Edition Michael Parkin Solutions


Manual

https://testbankfan.com/product/microeconomics-11th-edition-
michael-parkin-solutions-manual/

Microeconomics 11th Edition Michael Parkin Test Bank

https://testbankfan.com/product/microeconomics-11th-edition-
michael-parkin-test-bank/
C h a p t e r

8 UTILITY AND
DEMAND

The Big Picture


Where we have been:
Chapter 8 uses marginal utility theory to derive the downward-sloping demand curve introduced
in Chapter 3 (and used throughout Chapters 4 to 7). Utility theory will also further explain the
factors that change demand. Consumer surplus has been used in multiple chapters and will be
reinforced in this chapter to help explain the diamond-water paradox and the difference between
total utility and marginal utility.

Where we are going:


Chapter 9 presents a parallel analysis of the consumer problem using indifference curves. Each
chapter is self-contained, so either can be omitted. Marginal analysis is used in this chapter to
describe marginal utility and the utility maximizing choice for consumers. The importance of
marginal analysis will be reinforced in future chapters as we move through profit maximization and
choice making in factor markets. Chapter 19, which deals with risk, uses some of the concepts
from this chapter, although Chapter 19 also is self-contained.

New in the Twelfth Edition


The chapter introduction has been updated to focus on sugary drink consumption. The data in the case
study on maximizing utility from downloading music have been updated. A new Worked Problem has
been added. The Worked Problem presents Jake’s income and his marginal utility schedules for songs
and cookies. It then shows the students how to calculate Jake’s utility-maximizing combination of
cookies and songs and how this combination changes when the price of a song rises. To include the
new Worked Problem without lengthening the chapter, some problems have been removed from the
Study Plan Problem and Applications. These problems are in the MyEconLab and are called Extra
Problems.

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


UTILITY AND DEMAND 83

Lecture Notes
Utility and Demand
• Economists assume that people behave to make themselves as well off as possible.
• Consumption possibilities tell us what the consumer can afford to buy given a limited income and the
prices of the goods and services they are considering.
• Preferences are reflected in the discussion of utility maximization
I. Consumption Choices
• Consumption possibilities are all the things a consumer can afford to buy.
The Budget Line
• The limits of consumption possibilities are illustrated with
a budget line.
• The budget line marks the boundary between those
combinations of goods and services that the consumer
can afford to buy and those that it cannot afford.
• The budget line shown illustrates the possible
combinations of pizza and books that a consumer with
$50 income could purchase if the price of pizzas were
$10 and the price of books were $10.
• The budget line constrains choices: Points on the budget
line and inside the budget line are affordable and within
the consumer’s consumption possibilities. Points beyond
the budget line are not affordable.

Changes in Consumption Possibilities


• Consumption possibilities change when income or prices change.
• An increase in income shifts the budget line rightward without changing its slope.
• A change in the price of one of the goods changes the intercept on its axis and changes the slope of the
budget line.
• These changes are used again in the alternate consumer choice model in chapter 9.
Preferences
• The choice a consumer makes depends on preferences.
Total utility Quantity of Total Quantity Total
• Total utility is the total benefit that a person movies utility of books utility
gets from the consumption of goods and services. 0 0 0 0
As more of a good or service is consumed, total 1 24 1 20
utility increases. 2 44 2 30
• The table provides an example of utility from 3 72 3 38
consuming movies and paperback books in a given 4 80 4 44
week. 5 84 5 48
6 86 6 50

Where do the utility numbers come from? Year after year, you will get this question from the curious student.
While the numbers for utility are ordinal rather than cardinal, using those terms to explain utility to
undergraduates will generally result only in many blank stares. To help with one answer to this question, try the
following story: Lisa likes movies and books. We tell Lisa that we’re going to call the utility she gets from 1 movie a
month 24 units of utility. Then we ask her to tell us, using the same scale, how much she would like 2, 3, or more
movies, and 1, 2, 3, or more books.

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


84 CHAPTER 8

Marginal Utility
• Marginal utility is the change in total utility that results Quantity of Total Marginal
from a one-unit increase in the quantity of a good movies utility utility
consumed. The table shows the marginal utility from 0 0
movies. 24
• When a good generates value, it has a positive marginal 1 24
utility. Total utility increases as the quantity consumed 20
increases. 2 44
18
Diminishing Marginal Utility
3 72
• Diminishing marginal utility is the principle that as
8
more of a good or service is consumed, its marginal utility
4 80
decreases. In the table the marginal utility diminishes as
more movies are consumed.

II. Utility-Maximizing Choice


• A consumer’s choices influence the total level of his or her utility because different combinations of goods
generate different amounts of utility. The key assumption of marginal utility theory is that the household
consumes the combination that maximizes its utility.
• We have to combine the constraint imposed by the budget line with the consumer’s preferences to find
the combination of products that gives the consumer the maximum available utility.

Consumer Equilibrium
• Consumer equilibrium occurs when a situation in which a consumer has allocated all available income in a
way that maximizes utility given the prices of the products.

A Spreadsheet Solution
• The most direct way to find the quantity of goods Quantity of Total Quantity Total
and services is to make a table with the choices movies utility of books utility
available. Suppose the price of a movie is $8, the 0 0 0 0
price of a book is $4, and the consumer has income 1 24 1 20
of $24.
2 44 2 30
• Calculate the combinations of products that 3 72 3 38
exhaust the available income given the prices of
4 80 4 44
the goods. In the table, the consumer can
5 84 5 48
afford (3 movies/0 books), (2 movies/2 books),
6 86 6 50
(1 movie/4 books), and (0 movies/6 books).
While the consumer can also afford the combinations of products inside the budget line, the smaller
quantities associated with those points would have less utility than the points on the budget line.
• From the utility figures given for each product, calculate the total utility from the combination of the
two products. In the same order as the affordable combinations above, these total utilities are 72, 74,
68, and 50. Emphasize that it is total utility from the combination of the two products that the
consumer is trying to maximize.
• Select the combination that gives the maximum total utility, (2 movies/2books for total utility of 74)
in this case.
• While in a model we might calculate the total utility from all the possible combinations of products and
then select the combination with the highest utility, this is not a likely approach for consumers in practice.
• A more natural way to find the consumer equilibrium is to use marginal analysis to make the decision.

Choosing at the Margin


• A consumer’s utility is maximized when the consumer spends all available income and equalizes marginal
utility per dollar for all goods. The marginal utility per dollar is the marginal utility from a good divided
by its price.

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


UTILITY AND DEMAND 85

• If the consumer is left Marginal Marginal


with money to spend, Quantity Marginal utility per Quantity Marginal utility per
opportunities for of utility dollar of books utility dollar
increasing utility are left movies
unused, so the 1 22 2.75 1 15 4.75
consumer can only be 2 18 2.25 2 9 2.25
maximizing utility when
3 13 1.63 3 7 1.75
all available income is
4 6 0.75 4 5 1.25
spent.
5 3 0.38 5 3 0.75
• The table to the right
has the marginal utility schedules that are computed from the total utility schedules in the table above.
(The marginal utilities are the averages of the two adjacent marginal utilities for each quantity.) Given the
price of a movie of $8, the price of a paperback book of $4, the table also has the marginal utility per
dollar schedules. Assume the consumer has $24 to allocate between movies and books. To maximize
utility, the individual buys 2 movies and 2 books because that combination of movies and books spends all
the available income and sets the marginal utility per dollar from a movie equal to that from a book. (Both
equal 2.25.)

Do people really calculate and compare marginal utilities and prices? One of the challenges in teaching the
marginal utility theory is getting the students to appreciate the fundamental role of a model of choice. The goal is
to predict choices, not to describe the thought processes that make them. Gary Becker has made the following
point, updating the reference to the pitcher (from Parkin, Economics, first edition, 1990, p. 154): Justin Verlander
(or substitute a currently hot pitcher) unanimously won the 2011 Cy Young award for the American League. He
effectively knows all the laws of motion, of hand-eye coordination, about the speed of the bat and ball, and so on.
He’s in fact solving a complicated physics problem when he steps up to pitch, but obviously he doesn’t have to
know physics to do that. Likewise, when people solve economic problems rationally they’re really not thinking,
“Well, I have this budget and I read this textbook and I look at my marginal utilities and the prices and determine
what maximizes my utility.” People don’t do that, but it doesn’t mean they’re not being rational. Just because a Cy
Young Award winner isn’t Albert Einstein doesn’t mean he can’t make rational decisions about pitching.

• The rule to spend all income and equalize marginal utility per dollar from each good maximizes utility
because anytime the marginal utility per dollar from one good exceeds that of another good, the
consumer can increase his or her total utility by spending a dollar less on the good with the lower
marginal utility per dollar and spending the dollar on the good with the higher marginal utility per dollar.
Counterexamples can help. To help the students see that maximizing total utility requires equalizing the marginal
utility per dollar on each good, work with the case when they are not equal. Suppose the marginal utility per dollar
from a movie is 20 and the marginal utility per dollar from a soda is 10. Ask “If you gained an additional dollar,
what would you spend it on and by how much would your total utility increase?” The students will spend it on
movies and their total utility will rise by 20. Now ask the students “If you lost a dollar, what you cut back on and
how much would your total utility decrease?” The students will cut back on sodas and their total utility will fall by
10. Now tell the students that they can gain a dollar by cutting back a dollar on sodas. Ask them the net change in
their total utility, which is +10. The point to make is that anytime the marginal utility per dollar from one good
differs from that for another good, consumption can be rearranged by cutting back on the good with the low
marginal utility per dollar and spending the dollar on the good with the high marginal utility per dollar and
increasing total utility.

Why don’t consumers simply choose the goods with the highest marginal utility? Students will find it
relatively easy to simply memorize the rule that maximizing utility requires that the marginal utility per dollar is
equal across all goods, but, intuitively, students still often expect marginal utility to be the only determinant of
utility maximization. To provide some additional intuition, ask them to think about two goods they’re trying to
choose between, like a new shirt and a new download of a song. Say a new shirt would have a marginal utility of
20, while the download would have a marginal utility of 1. The price of a new shirt is $30, while the price of the
download is $1. Should you purchase the new shirt because it has a higher marginal utility? No! You may prefer

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


86 CHAPTER 8

the shirt, but it costs thirty times as much as the download. Even though the download has the lower marginal
utility, it has a higher marginal utility per dollar (1 as opposed to 2/3).

The Power of Marginal Analysis


• The goal of maximizing utility does not require a computer and spreadsheet, but simply comparing the
marginal utility per dollar of each of the products.
• In the example the person’s choice between movies and books, the person maximizes his or her utility
where the marginal utility per dollar from movies is equal to the marginal utility per dollar from books.
Mathematically, this is represented by the equation:
MU Movie MU Book
= .
PMovie PBook

Other applications of marginal reasoning. Help your students to appreciate that marginal reasoning is one of
the most important tools for understanding the economic perspective. Remind them that we have been using
marginal reasoning for many chapters now: In Chapter 2 we derived the marginal cost of production from the PPF.
In Chapter 5 we discovered that competitive equilibrium is efficient because marginal social benefit (from the
demand curve) equals the marginal social cost (from the supply curve). In this chapter, we discover that equating
the marginal utility per dollar across all goods and services maximizes a consumer’s utility. More generally, marginal
analysis shows that if the marginal gain from an action exceeds the marginal loss, take the action.

Revealing Preference
• We don’t have to ask a consumer to state preferences because we can figure them out by observing what
is purchased at various prices.
• The units we use to measure preference don’t matter. Any arbitrary unit will work; for instance, if utility
is multiplied by 2, the marginal utility per dollar equation shows that the equilibrium consumption bundle
does not change.

III. Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory


Marginal utility theory predicts the law of demand. It also predicts that a decrease in the price of a substitute
good increases the demand for the good; and, for a normal good, an increase in income increases demand.

A Fall in the Price of a Movie


A Change in the Quantity Demanded
• If the price of a good falls and other things remain the same, the marginal utility per dollar from that good
rises. As a result, the consumer increases his or her purchases of that good in order to maximize utility.
(As more of the good is purchased, its marginal utility decreases; as less of other goods are purchased,
their marginal utilities increase. Eventually the consumer reaches a new equilibrium at which the marginal
utility per dollar for all the goods is equal.)
A Change in Demand
• When the price of a good falls, it will have an impact on the demand for related goods (substitutes and
complements in consumption). In the example above, when movie prices fall, the demand for paperback
books decreases, implying that movies and books are substitute goods.
A Rise in Income
• If a consumer’s income increases, the consumer will reach a new consumer equilibrium in which all the
income is spent and the marginal utility per dollar from all goods is equal. Marginal utility theory predicts
that as the consumer’s income increases, the demand for normal goods increases and the demand for
inferior goods decreases.
Paradox of Value
• The paradox of value is that water, which is essential to life, costs little, but diamonds, which are useless
in comparison to water, are expensive.

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


UTILITY AND DEMAND 87

• The resolution to this paradox comes from distinguishing total utility from marginal utility. The total utility
from water is much more than from diamonds. But we have so much water that its marginal utility is
small. And we have so few diamonds that their marginal utility is high. When a household maximizes its
utility, it makes the marginal utility per dollar equal for all goods. Because diamonds have a high marginal
utility, they have a high price. Because water has a low marginal utility, it has a low price.
• Consumer surplus also can be used to resolve the paradox as well. The consumer surplus from
consuming water is vast but the consumer surplus from consuming diamonds is small.

Temperature as an Analogy
• Temperature and utility are both abstract concepts.
• The concept of utility allows economists to make predictions about human choices just as temperature
allows predictions of physical phenomena.
• Utility may not be as precise a thermometer in making some types of predictions but is still useful.
An Economics in Action case considers the utility from recorded music and concludes that the availability and
convenience of downloading individual songs increases consumer surplus. The utility from playing an album is
greater using a CD, so most albums are played on CDs.

IV. New Ways of Explaining Consumer Choices


Behavioral Economics
• Behavioral economics studies the ways in which limits on the human brain’s ability to compute and
implement rational decisions influences economic behavior—both the decisions that people make and the
consequences of those decisions for the way markets work.
• There are three impediments to rational choice: bounded rationality, bounded will-power, and bounded self-
interest.
Bounded Rationality
• Bounded rationality is rationality that is bounded by the computing power of the human brain. Faced
with uncertainty, consumers cannot rationally make choices and instead rely on other decision-making
methods such as rules of thumb, listening to the views of others, or gut instinct.
Bounded Willpower
• Bounded willpower is the less-than-perfect willpower that prevents us from making a decision that we
know, at the time of implementing the decision, we will later regret.
Bounded Self-Interest
• Bounded self-interest is the limited self-interest that sometimes results in suppressing our own
interests to help others.
The Endowment Effect
• The endowment effect is the tendency for people to value something more highly simply because they
own it.

Endowment effect in the housing market: The housing market entered a severe slump in the late 2000s and
took years to even begin to emerge. One factor might have been the endowment effect: The price that home
buyers were willing to pay for a house is lower than what homeowners, with the endowment effect, believe their
home is worth. Consequently homes might sit on the market for long periods of time.

Neuroeconomics
• Neuroeconomics is the study of the activity of the human brain when a person makes an economic
decision. Different decisions appear to activate different areas of the brain. Some decisions are made in
the pre-frontal cortex, which is where memories are stored and data are analyzed. These decisions might
be deemed rational. Other decisions are made in the hippocampus, which is where memories of anxiety
and fear are stored. These decisions might be deemed irrational.

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


88 CHAPTER 8

Controversy
• Whether economics should focus on explaining the decisions we observe or on what goes on inside
people’s heads is the source of controversy.

The Reading Between the Lines case at the end of the chapter about efforts to outlaw large, sugary drinks should
draw student reaction and interest about the role of government in helping citizens make better decisions.
Although the students have not yet learned about externalities, part of the discussion can include whether
government can protect itself as a payer of health care costs for the poor and elderly.

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


UTILITY AND DEMAND 89

Additional Problems
1. Mary enjoys classical CDs and travel
Quantity Total utility from Total utility from
books and spends $50 a month on them.
per month classical CDs travel books
The table shows the utility she gets from
each good. 1 30 30
2 40 38
a. Compare the two utility schedules.
3 48 44
Can you say anything about Mary’s
4 54 46
preferences?
5 58 47
b. What do the two utility schedules tell
you about Mary’s preferences?
c. If a classical CD and a travel book cost $10 each, how does Mary spend the $50 a month?
2. Rob enjoys rock concerts and the opera.
The table shows the marginal utility he Concerts Marginal utility Marginal utility
gets from each activity. Rob has $100 a per month from rock from operas
month to spend on concerts. A rock concerts
concert ticket is $20, and an opera 1 90 120
ticket is $10. How many rock concerts 2 80 90
and how many operas does he attend? 3 60 60
4 40 30
3. In problem 2, Rob’s uncle gives him $30 5 20 20
to spend on concert tickets, so he now
has $130. How many rock concerts and how many operas does he attend now that he has $130
to spend?
4. In problem 2, if the price of a rock concert decreases to $10, how many rock concerts and
operas will Rob attend?

Solutions to Additional Problems


1. a. Mary gets the same utility from 1 classical CD as from 1 travel book, but at quantities greater than 1 she
gets more utility from any number of classical CDs than she does from the same number of travel books.
b. Mary receives the same marginal utility from her first classical CD as from her first travel book. At
quantities greater than 1, Mary gets more marginal utility from an additional classical CD than she gets
from an additional travel book when she has the same number of each.
c. Mary buys 3 classical CDs and 2 travel books.
When Mary buys 3 classical CDs and 2 travel books she spends $50. Mary maximizes her utility when she
spends all of her money and the marginal utility per dollar from classical CDs and travel books is the
same. When Mary buys 3 classical CDs her marginal utility per dollar spent is 0.8 units per dollar and
when Mary buys 2 travel books her marginal utility per dollar spent is 0.8 units per dollar.
2. To maximize his utility, Rob attends 3 rock concerts and 4 opera concerts.
Rob will spend his $100 such that all of the $100 is spent and that the marginal utility per dollar from each
type of concert is the same. When Rob attends 3 rock concerts and 4 operas, he spends $60 on rock
concerts and $40 on operas—a total of $100.
The marginal utility from the third rock concert is 60 and a rock concert ticket is $20, so the marginal utility
per dollar from rock concerts is 3. The marginal utility from the fourth opera is 30 and an opera ticket is
$10, so the marginal utility per dollar from operas is 3. The marginal utility per dollar from rock concerts
equals the marginal utility per dollar from operas.
3. To maximize his utility, Rob attends 4 rock concerts and 5 operas.
Rob will spend his $130 such that all of the $130 is spent and that the marginal utility per dollar from each
type of concert is the same. When Rob attends 4 rock concerts and 5 operas, he spends $80 on rock

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


90 CHAPTER 8

concert tickets and $50 on operas—a total of $130.


The marginal utility from the fourth rock concert is 40 and a rock concert ticket is $20, so the marginal
utility per dollar from rock concerts is 2. The marginal utility from the fifth opera is 20 and an opera ticket
is $10, so the marginal utility per dollar from opera is 2. The marginal utility per dollar from rock concerts
equals the marginal utility per dollar from operas.
4. To maximize his utility, Rob attends 5 rock concerts and 5 operas.
Rob will spend his $100 such that all of the $100 is spent and that the marginal utility per dollar from each
type of concert is the same. When Rob attends 5 rock concerts and 5 operas, he spends $50 on rock
concert tickets and $50 on opera tickets—a total of $100.
The marginal utility from the fifth rock concert is 20 and a rock concert ticket is $10, so the marginal utility
per dollar from rock concerts is 2. The marginal utility from the fifth opera is 20 and an opera ticket is $10,
so the marginal utility per dollar from operas is 2. The marginal utility per dollar from rock concerts equals
the marginal utility per dollar from operas.

Additional Discussion Questions


1. Have you ever eaten or drank “too much”? Use the students’ personal experience with food or
drink to show them that the marginal utility for a good can be increasing, diminishing, or even
negative. The example works well for many types of food and drink consumption, but college
students often especially enjoy sharing their experiences (or their friends’ experiences) with
alcohol.
Can alcohol consumption exhibit increasing marginal utility? The first drink may not induce
the euphoric feeling that many students seek, but two drinks might, with the third drink increasing
the euphoria even more than the second drink. In this range of consumption, the student
experiences increasing marginal utility. Point out that this increasing marginal utility isn’t likely to
last forever.
Can alcohol exhibit diminishing marginal utility? By the fourth or fifth drink of the evening, the
additional euphoria from each drink is not as much as the prior drink, meaning the student is in
the zone of diminishing marginal utility.
Can alcohol exhibit negative marginal utility? After the fifth or sixth drink for the evening,
most students quickly feel the discomfort of intoxication and suffer a significant decline in euphoria
mixed with a significant increase in discomfort and disorientation. Continued consumption of
alcohol can eventually bring the onset of alcohol poisoning, when the body starts to reject further
intake of alcohol by ejecting the excess alcohol. Most students would agree that, at that point, an
additional drink would generate negative marginal utility.

2. If the Surgeon General (and the American Medical Association) concludes that moderate
wine and beer consumption can have a positive influence on cardiovascular health, how
will utility and demand be affected? Ask the students to use utility theory to explain how
changes in the marginal utility of beer and wine consumption will cause the demand for beer and
wine to increase, despite unchanged short-run prices or consumer incomes.

3. Would people voluntarily pay for something seemingly undesirable? Get students to see that
the utility they get from one good is oftentimes dependent on the level of other goods and
services consumed. Ask the students to use utility theory to explain:
1) Why do people regularly put themselves through undesirable, rigorous exercise programs?
(better health increases our marginal utility of engaging in other activities)
2) Why do students forgo lots of leisure time to take college classes? (better education increases
our appreciation of the world and allows us make better choices in our lives)

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


UTILITY AND DEMAND 91

Help the students see that consumers invest in apparently undesirable goods the same way society
invests in capital to increase future consumption—except it is human capital that consumers are
investing in.

4. How could utility theory help us understand the difference between a federal income tax
and a federal sales tax on consumer consumption patterns? This is a real-world application of
utility theory designed to boost student confidence.
• Mention that federal sales tax proponents point out that sales taxes do not penalize savings
whereas income taxes penalize both savings and consumption, motivating consumers to save
less and consume more.
• Recall how Chapter 2 used the production possibilities frontier model to show that higher
present consumption and lower present investment (which is largely based on savings)
decreases future consumption for society through slower economic growth.
• Explain how consumers allocate their income across affordable consumption and savings
combinations by equating the ratio of marginal utility per dollar for both. If the same tax
revenue was collected by a federal sales tax rather than the income tax, the tax price for
savings would decrease and the tax price for consumption would increase. (Make sure you
explain that “savings” is an example of a “good.” In the examples used in the text, there is no
savings. All income is spent on goods. When savings exists, not all of a consumer’s income is
spent, but all of the income is allocated to either consumption goods or savings.)
• Show how consumers adjust these ratios by increasing the marginal utility of consumption
through less consumption and decreasing the marginal utility of savings by saving more. Utility
is maximized at a higher level of savings when consumption is penalized through a
consumption tax instead of an income tax.

5. How does utility theory differentiate a “need” from a “want”? If you are really in the mood
for a very heated discussion on utility analysis, just ask the students what the marginal utility
function for a “necessity” looks like. The students should recognize that it is perfectly vertical,
where no increase in price is sufficiently large to cause the person to decrease consumption of a
necessity in order to equate the marginal utility per dollar ratios across all goods and services. All
income is spent on necessity until the consumer is sated, and remaining income is allocated across
goods and services until the marginal utility per dollar ratios equalize. (This type of a utility
function reflects lexicographic preference orderings.)
Is a vertical utility function a reasonable outcome to expect for any good, even medicine or
food? Point out that even the poorest of people allocate their meager incomes across more than
just one good or service (the necessities). Somehow the income is allocated despite the supposed
vertical marginal utility curve.
How is income allocated across multiple “necessities” if all have vertical marginal utility
functions? Point out that if there is more than one “necessity,” then there is more than one
marginal utility function involved in allocating income. Help students to recognize that because in
the real world the poor allocate their income across multiple goods, then the marginal utility per
dollar ratios involved cannot be vertical, but they may be very steep. Emphasize that for these
consumers to maximize their utilities, each of the marginal utility per dollar ratios will need to be
equalized, making the income allocation process indistinguishable from mere “wants.”
Is it even meaningful to differentiate needs from wants among multiple goods or services?
There is no positive answer to this question—only a normative one. Utility analysis has just
proven that there is no positive definition of a necessity. Now step back and let the sparks fly!
6. It is often difficult to create incentives for behavior that is very good for us in the long run
but not necessarily pleasurable in the short run (studying, eating right, and exercising) and
disincentives for activities that lead to future pain but present pleasure (smoking, eating
whatever is convenient and tasty, sleeping through class). Have students suggest possible
incentives/disincentives that they think might address this problem. Attendance and being

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


92 CHAPTER 8

prepared for class, eating right and moving more, and all kinds of other things promote our long
run best interests but we live in world where diabetes is a growth industry and where many
students think that access to notes in classroom technology packages means they don’t need to
attend or read the book. What do they think would work, both personally and at the level of
social policy? How does this relate to marginal utility theory?
7. Type 2 Diabetes is often related to poor diets and lack of exercise. If it is avoidable, how
does the material in this chapter help us understand why it is on the rise around the world?
The answer to this question might well be related to bounded rationality. It definitely ties in well
with a discussion of the Reading Between the Lines case.

© 2016 Pearson Education, Inc.


Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
KÉPJEGYZÉK.

1. A szerencsétlenek nem szóltak 59


2. Erzsébet s Vilma bámulva néztek a belépőre
142
3. Igazságod van, – monda Tengelyi keserűen
209
4. Tengelyi az emberi élet bámulatos
bonyodalmairól gondolkozott 309
5. Nyugtasd meg magadat, barátom, – mondá
Vándory mélyen meghatva 334
6. Az alispánné egy darab ideig mozdulatlanul
állt 352
7. Segíteni nem lehetett többé 361
8. Ákos e szavaknál mintegy akaratlanul a szt.-
vilmosi erdő felé fordult 394
9. Gyümölcsfákat ültetett a házak és utak mellé
400

Javítások.
Az eredeti szöveg helyesírásán nem változtattunk.
A nyomdai hibákat javítottuk. Ezek listája:

19 mélyről szólunk melyről szólunk


22 kendenk nincs kendnek nincs
26 feje fölört feje fölött
35 megggyőződjék meggyőződjék
50 fucsább furcsább
95 mogállt megállt
108 kogy fiát hogy fiát
120 beszélgetes beszélgetés
121 kogy hozzájok hogy hozzájok
121 kedvad kedved
151 íehet-e lehet-e
156 menyilt megnyilt
181 hatá- ha határai, s ha
202 esak mint csak mint
203 Macskabázynak Macskaházynak
205 lgpásért lopásért
208 teljeitését teljesitését
243 azonbán azonban
266 foka főokai
277 maradandő maradandó
282 Boldizsár.« Boldizsár.»
301 vígabbb vígabb
307 kerdeztük Peti kérdeztük Peti
326 megvetó megvető
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK A FALU
JEGYZŐJE (2. KÖTET): REGÉNY ***

Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.

Creating the works from print editions not protected by U.S.


copyright law means that no one owns a United States copyright in
these works, so the Foundation (and you!) can copy and distribute it
in the United States without permission and without paying copyright
royalties. Special rules, set forth in the General Terms of Use part of
this license, apply to copying and distributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works to protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG™ concept
and trademark. Project Gutenberg is a registered trademark, and
may not be used if you charge for an eBook, except by following the
terms of the trademark license, including paying royalties for use of
the Project Gutenberg trademark. If you do not charge anything for
copies of this eBook, complying with the trademark license is very
easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose such as
creation of derivative works, reports, performances and research.
Project Gutenberg eBooks may be modified and printed and given
away—you may do practically ANYTHING in the United States with
eBooks not protected by U.S. copyright law. Redistribution is subject
to the trademark license, especially commercial redistribution.

START: FULL LICENSE


THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE
PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK

To protect the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting the free


distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work (or
any other work associated in any way with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg”), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full
Project Gutenberg™ License available with this file or online at
www.gutenberg.org/license.

Section 1. General Terms of Use and


Redistributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works
1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg™
electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree
to and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property
(trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all
the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or
destroy all copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in your
possession. If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a
Project Gutenberg™ electronic work and you do not agree to be
bound by the terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from
the person or entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in
paragraph 1.E.8.

1.B. “Project Gutenberg” is a registered trademark. It may only be


used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people
who agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a
few things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg™ electronic
works even without complying with the full terms of this agreement.
See paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with
Project Gutenberg™ electronic works if you follow the terms of this
agreement and help preserve free future access to Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works. See paragraph 1.E below.
1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation (“the
Foundation” or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the
collection of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works. Nearly all the
individual works in the collection are in the public domain in the
United States. If an individual work is unprotected by copyright law in
the United States and you are located in the United States, we do
not claim a right to prevent you from copying, distributing,
performing, displaying or creating derivative works based on the
work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg are removed. Of
course, we hope that you will support the Project Gutenberg™
mission of promoting free access to electronic works by freely
sharing Project Gutenberg™ works in compliance with the terms of
this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg™ name
associated with the work. You can easily comply with the terms of
this agreement by keeping this work in the same format with its
attached full Project Gutenberg™ License when you share it without
charge with others.

1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the terms
of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.

1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg:

1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other


immediate access to, the full Project Gutenberg™ License must
appear prominently whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg™
work (any work on which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” appears, or
with which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” is associated) is
accessed, displayed, performed, viewed, copied or distributed:
This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United
States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with
almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away
or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License
included with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you
are not located in the United States, you will have to check the
laws of the country where you are located before using this
eBook.

1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is derived


from texts not protected by U.S. copyright law (does not contain a
notice indicating that it is posted with permission of the copyright
holder), the work can be copied and distributed to anyone in the
United States without paying any fees or charges. If you are
redistributing or providing access to a work with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg” associated with or appearing on the work, you must
comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1 through
1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the Project
Gutenberg™ trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is posted


with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution
must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any
additional terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms
will be linked to the Project Gutenberg™ License for all works posted
with the permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning of
this work.

1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project


Gutenberg™ License terms from this work, or any files containing a
part of this work or any other work associated with Project
Gutenberg™.

1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this


electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without
prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with
active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project
Gutenberg™ License.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense
to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means
of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original “Plain
Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must include the
full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.

1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying,


performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg™ works
unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.

1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing


access to or distributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works
provided that:

• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from
the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”

• You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who


notifies you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt that
s/he does not agree to the terms of the full Project Gutenberg™
License. You must require such a user to return or destroy all
copies of the works possessed in a physical medium and
discontinue all use of and all access to other copies of Project
Gutenberg™ works.

• You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of


any money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in
the electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90
days of receipt of the work.

• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.

1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg™


electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set
forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the manager of
the Project Gutenberg™ trademark. Contact the Foundation as set
forth in Section 3 below.

1.F.

1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend


considerable effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe
and proofread works not protected by U.S. copyright law in creating
the Project Gutenberg™ collection. Despite these efforts, Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works, and the medium on which they may
be stored, may contain “Defects,” such as, but not limited to,
incomplete, inaccurate or corrupt data, transcription errors, a
copyright or other intellectual property infringement, a defective or
damaged disk or other medium, a computer virus, or computer
codes that damage or cannot be read by your equipment.

1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except


for the “Right of Replacement or Refund” described in paragraph
1.F.3, the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner
of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark, and any other party
distributing a Project Gutenberg™ electronic work under this
agreement, disclaim all liability to you for damages, costs and
expenses, including legal fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO
REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT LIABILITY, BREACH OF
WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE
PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH 1.F.3. YOU AGREE THAT THE
FOUNDATION, THE TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY
DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE LIABLE
TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL,
PUNITIVE OR INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE
NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH DAMAGE.

1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you


discover a defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it,
you can receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by
sending a written explanation to the person you received the work
from. If you received the work on a physical medium, you must
return the medium with your written explanation. The person or entity
that provided you with the defective work may elect to provide a
replacement copy in lieu of a refund. If you received the work
electronically, the person or entity providing it to you may choose to
give you a second opportunity to receive the work electronically in
lieu of a refund. If the second copy is also defective, you may
demand a refund in writing without further opportunities to fix the
problem.

1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth in
paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.

1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied


warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages.
If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the
law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be
interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted
by the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any
provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions.
1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the
Foundation, the trademark owner, any agent or employee of the
Foundation, anyone providing copies of Project Gutenberg™
electronic works in accordance with this agreement, and any
volunteers associated with the production, promotion and distribution
of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works, harmless from all liability,
costs and expenses, including legal fees, that arise directly or
indirectly from any of the following which you do or cause to occur:
(a) distribution of this or any Project Gutenberg™ work, (b)
alteration, modification, or additions or deletions to any Project
Gutenberg™ work, and (c) any Defect you cause.

Section 2. Information about the Mission of


Project Gutenberg™
Project Gutenberg™ is synonymous with the free distribution of
electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of
computers including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers.
It exists because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and
donations from people in all walks of life.

Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the


assistance they need are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg™’s
goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg™ collection will
remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a
secure and permanent future for Project Gutenberg™ and future
generations. To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation and how your efforts and donations can help,
see Sections 3 and 4 and the Foundation information page at
www.gutenberg.org.

Section 3. Information about the Project


Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation
The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non-profit
501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the
state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal
Revenue Service. The Foundation’s EIN or federal tax identification
number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg
Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent
permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state’s laws.

The Foundation’s business office is located at 809 North 1500 West,


Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887. Email contact links and up
to date contact information can be found at the Foundation’s website
and official page at www.gutenberg.org/contact

Section 4. Information about Donations to


the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation
Project Gutenberg™ depends upon and cannot survive without
widespread public support and donations to carry out its mission of
increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can
be freely distributed in machine-readable form accessible by the
widest array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small
donations ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax
exempt status with the IRS.

The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating


charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United
States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a
considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and
keep up with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in
locations where we have not received written confirmation of
compliance. To SEND DONATIONS or determine the status of
compliance for any particular state visit www.gutenberg.org/donate.

While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where


we have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no
prohibition against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in
such states who approach us with offers to donate.

International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make


any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from
outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff.

Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation
methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of
other ways including checks, online payments and credit card
donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate.

Section 5. General Information About Project


Gutenberg™ electronic works
Professor Michael S. Hart was the originator of the Project
Gutenberg™ concept of a library of electronic works that could be
freely shared with anyone. For forty years, he produced and
distributed Project Gutenberg™ eBooks with only a loose network of
volunteer support.

Project Gutenberg™ eBooks are often created from several printed


editions, all of which are confirmed as not protected by copyright in
the U.S. unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not
necessarily keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper
edition.

Most people start at our website which has the main PG search
facility: www.gutenberg.org.

This website includes information about Project Gutenberg™,


including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how
to subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.
back
back
back

You might also like