Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 44

Business, Government and Economic

Institutions in China 1st Edition Xiaoke


Zhang
Visit to download the full and correct content document:
https://ebookmass.com/product/business-government-and-economic-institutions-in-ch
ina-1st-edition-xiaoke-zhang/
More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant
download maybe you interests ...

Unpacking EU Policy-Making towards China: How Member


States, Bureaucracies, and Institutions Shape its China
Economic Policy 1st ed. Edition Bas Hooijmaaijers

https://ebookmass.com/product/unpacking-eu-policy-making-towards-
china-how-member-states-bureaucracies-and-institutions-shape-its-
china-economic-policy-1st-ed-edition-bas-hooijmaaijers/

American government : institutions and policies


Sixteenth Edition Bose

https://ebookmass.com/product/american-government-institutions-
and-policies-sixteenth-edition-bose/

Media and Conflict in the Social Media Era in China 1st


Edition Shixin Ivy Zhang

https://ebookmass.com/product/media-and-conflict-in-the-social-
media-era-in-china-1st-edition-shixin-ivy-zhang/

Human Security In China: A Post-Pandemic State 1st


Edition Chi Zhang

https://ebookmass.com/product/human-security-in-china-a-post-
pandemic-state-1st-edition-chi-zhang/
Managing Expatriates in China: A Language and Identity
Perspective 1st Edition Ling Eleanor Zhang

https://ebookmass.com/product/managing-expatriates-in-china-a-
language-and-identity-perspective-1st-edition-ling-eleanor-zhang/

How Trade with China Threatens Western Institutions:


The Economic Roots of a Political Crisis 1st Edition
Robert Gmeiner

https://ebookmass.com/product/how-trade-with-china-threatens-
western-institutions-the-economic-roots-of-a-political-
crisis-1st-edition-robert-gmeiner/

Economic Transition and Labor Market Reform in China


1st ed. Edition Xinxin Ma

https://ebookmass.com/product/economic-transition-and-labor-
market-reform-in-china-1st-ed-edition-xinxin-ma/

American Government: Institutions and Policies 16th


Edition – Ebook PDF Version

https://ebookmass.com/product/american-government-institutions-
and-policies-16th-edition-ebook-pdf-version/

Family Business in China, Volume 2: Challenges and


Opportunities 1st Edition Chen

https://ebookmass.com/product/family-business-in-china-
volume-2-challenges-and-opportunities-1st-edition-chen/
International Political Economy Series

Business, Government and


Economic Institutions in China

Edited by
Xiaoke Zhang and Tianbiao Zhu
International Political Economy Series

Series editor

Timothy M. Shaw
Visiting Professor
University of Massachusetts Boston, USA

Emeritus Professor
University of London, UK
The global political economy is in flux as a series of cumulative crises
impacts its organization and governance. The IPE series has tracked its
development in both analysis and structure over the last three decades. It
has always had a concentration on the global South. Now the South
increasingly challenges the North as the centre of development, also
reflected in a growing number of submissions and publications on indebted
Eurozone economies in Southern Europe. An indispensable resource for
scholars and researchers, the series examines a variety of capitalisms and
connections by focusing on emerging economies, companies and sectors,
debates and policies. It informs diverse policy communities as the estab-
lished trans-Atlantic North declines and ‘the rest’, especially the BRICS,
rise.

More information about this series at


http://www.palgrave.com/series/13996
Xiaoke Zhang • Tianbiao Zhu
Editors

Business, Government
and Economic
Institutions in China
Editors
Xiaoke Zhang Tianbiao Zhu
Alliance Manchester Business School Institute for Advanced Study in
University of Manchester Humanities and Social Sciences
Manchester, UK Zhejiang University
Hangzhou, Zhejiang, China

International Political Economy Series


ISBN 978-3-319-64485-1    ISBN 978-3-319-64486-8 (eBook)
DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-64486-8

Library of Congress Control Number: 2017959575

© The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s) 2018


This work is subject to copyright. All rights are solely and exclusively licensed by the
Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of
translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on
microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval,
electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now
known or hereafter developed.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this
publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are
exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information
in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the pub-
lisher nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the
material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. The
publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institu-
tional affiliations.

Cover image © Rob Friedman/iStockphoto.com

Printed on acid-free paper

This Palgrave Macmillan imprint is published by Springer Nature


The registered company is Springer International Publishing AG
The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland
Acknowledgements

As editors, we wish to thank all the authors for their willingness to respond
to our editorial suggestions and their valuable contribution to the book.
We also extend our appreciation to Wyn Grant, Gregory Noble, Richard
Whitley, Yongping Wu and the anonymous reviewer for their comments,
criticisms and support. While organizing the international symposium in
August 2014 and the publication workshop in January 2016 from which
this book was born, we received and gratefully acknowledge financial sup-
port from China’s National Social Science Fund (project number:
13BJL027) and the Zhejiang University Research Fund (project number:
188020-193810401/054). Finally, we are grateful to Timothy Shaw, the
series editor, and Christina Brian, editorial director for politics and inter-
national studies at Palgrave Macmillan, for encouraging the project.

Xiaoke Zhang
Tianbiao Zhu

v
Contents

Part I Introduction   1

1 Understanding Business–Government Relations in China:


Changes, Causes and Consequences   3
Xiaoke Zhang and Tianbiao Zhu

2 State–Business Relations in China’s Changing


Economic Order  47
Tak-Wing Ngo

Part II Changes and Variations in Business–Government


Relations  79

3 The Evolution of Government–MNC Relations in China:


The Case of the Automotive Sector  81
Gregory T. Chin

4 Regional Business Associations in China: Changes


and Continuities 105
Juanfeng Liu and Jianjun Zhang

vii
viii CONTENTS

5 Trapped into Collusion: The Under-­Institutionalized


Taxation System and Local Business–State Relations
in China 139
Changdong Zhang

6 Chinese Private Entrepreneurs’ Formal Political


Connections: Industrial and Geographical Distribution 165
Jiangnan Zhu and Yiping Wu

7 International Context and China’s Business–Government


Relations 195
Tianbiao Zhu

Part III Institutional Consequences of Changing


Business–Government Relations 223

8 Business–Government Relations and Corporate


Governance Reforms 225
Richard W. Carney

9 The Changing Business–State Relations in China:


The View from Socialist Corporatism 255
Yukyung Yeo

10 State Structures, Business–State Relations,


and Multinational Corporate Behaviours: A Case
Study of Chinese Multinational Oil Companies 281
Jin Zhang

11 Business–State Interactions and Technology Development


Regimes: A Comparative Analysis of Two Metropolises 313
Xiaoke Zhang

12 Conclusions and Reflections 341


Tianbiao Zhu and Xiaoke Zhang

Index 345
Notes on Contributors

Richard W. Carney is Fellow at the College of Asia and the Pacific,


Australian National University.
Gregory Chin is Associate Professor at the Department of Political
Science, York University, Canada.
Juanfeng Liu is Assistant Professor at the School of International
Relations, University of International Business and Economics, China.
Tak-Wing Ngo is Professor at the Department of Government and
Public Administration, University of Macau.
Yiping Wu is Associate Professor at the School of Public Economics and
Administration, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics.
Yukyung Yeo is Associate Professor at the College of International
Studies, Kyung Hee University, South Korea.
Changdong Zhang is Associate Professor at the School of Government,
Peking University.
Jianjun Zhang is Professor at the Guanghua School of Management,
Peking University.
Jin Zhang is Senior Research Fellow at the Cambridge China
Development Trust and university lecturer at Judge Business School,
University of Cambridge.

ix
x Notes on Contributors

Xiaoke Zhang is Professor at Alliance Manchester Business School,


University of Manchester.
Jiangnan Zhu is Associate Professor at the Department of Politics and
Public Administration, University of Hong Kong.
Tianbiao Zhu is Executive Dean and Professor at the Institute for
Advanced Study in Humanities and Social Sciences, Zhejiang University.
List of Figures

Fig. 6.1 The distribution of LPC across provinces 181


Fig. 6.2 The distribution of CPPCC across provinces 182
Fig. 8.1 The contribution of SOEs and private firms to the industrial
output of Shanghai and Guangdong, 2005–2011  235
Fig. 9.1 Profits and numbers of central state firms, 2003–2014 264
Fig. 9.2 Five hard years 265
Fig. 9.3 China’s anti-monopoly regime 272
Fig. 10.1 Governance structure of the Chinese oil industry  293

xi
List of Tables

Table 1.1 Four ideal types of business–government relations 11


Table 1.2 State and market influences on the four varieties of
business–government relations 30
Table 2.1 Expectations of government–business relations under
different frameworks 50
Table 2.2 China in comparison with dominant models of state–business
relations52
Table 5.1 Typologies of state-business relationships 142
Table 5.2 Basic facts of seven counties 145
Table 5.3 Entrepreneurs with different levels of political connection
and their enterprise sizes 153
Table 6.1 Number of firms classified by industries in the sample 173
Table 6.2 Number of firms classified by provinces in the sample 174
Table 6.3 Average level of political connections across sectors 175
Table 6.4 Average level of political connections across provinces 179
Table 6.5 Overall LPC distribution across sectors 184
Table 6.6 Overall CPPCC distribution across sectors 185
Table 6.7 Overall LPC distribution across provinces 186
Table 6.8 Overall CPPCC distribution across provinces 188
Table 8.1 Business–government relations and their corporate
governance implications 234
Table 9.1 Return on assets of central SOEs 266
Table 9.2 SOE financial performance 266
Table 9.3 NDRC’s approval of investment projects, 2005–2013
(Yeo 2012) 269

xiii
xiv LIST OF TABLES

Table 10.1 Corporate governance and overseas investment of the


Chinese multinational oil companies 283
Table 10.2 State structure and state-business relations 284
Table 10.3 Co-evolution of state structure, industry structure, and
corporate governance in the Chinese oil industry 285
Table 10.4 Multinational corporate behaviour and state-business
relations287
Table 11.1 Divergent technology development regimes 318
Table 11.2 Business–state interactions and technology development
regimes330
Table 11.3 Business–state interactions, technology development
regimes, and innovation outcomes (2013) 337
PART I

Introduction
CHAPTER 1

Understanding Business–Government
Relations in China: Changes, Causes
and Consequences

Xiaoke Zhang and Tianbiao Zhu

Introduction
This book brings together conceptual and empirical analyses of the causes
and consequences of changing business–government relations in China
since the 1990s, against the backdrop of the country’s increased integra-
tion with the global political economy. More specifically, it provides an
interdisciplinary account of how the dominant pattern of interactions
between state actors, firms and business organizations has changed differ-
ently across regions and industries and how the changing varieties of these
interactions have causally interacted with the evolution of key economic

X. Zhang (*)
Alliance Manchester Business School, University of Manchester, Manchester, UK
T. Zhu
Institute for Advanced Study in Humanities and Social Sciences, Zhejiang
University, Hangzhou, China

© The Author(s) 2018 3


X. Zhang, T. Zhu (eds.), Business, Government and Economic
Institutions in China, International Political Economy Series,
DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-64486-8_1
4 X. ZHANG AND T. ZHU

institutions in China. The basic theoretical premise of the book is that


business–government relations comprise a key linchpin that defines the
Chinese political economy and calibrates the character of its constitutive
institutional arrangements.
In line with this analytical focus, the book has three different yet inter-
related objectives. In the first place, building on the recent comparative
political economy literature (Crouch et al. 2009; Hancke et al. 2007;
Zhang and Whitley 2013), it develops a typological framework for identi-
fying key dimensions to be included in cross-regional and cross-sectoral
comparisons and for establishing the guiding principles for elucidating the
diversity of business–government relations in China. Furthermore, the
book advances novel theoretical propositions concerning the primary
causes of changes and variations in the organization of state and business
actors and in the configuration of power relations and interactions between
them. Finally, it explores the causal pathways through which business–
government relations, as a key set of sociopolitical structures and pro-
cesses, have shaped emergent systems of economic control and coordination
across the regional and sectoral levels of analysis.
This introductory chapter sets the general backdrop against which the
central analytical objectives of the book are defined and its major contribu-
tions to theoretical and policy debates specified. It introduces a typology
of business–government relations, advances the main causal propositions
of changes and variations in business–state interactions, and explores the
impact of such interactions on the emergence of new market institutions.
It does so by drawing on, but not confining itself to, empirical evidence
presented in individual contributions to the book. The chapter concludes
by discussing the organization of the volume.

Key Contributions
By focusing on the above-mentioned three analytical objectives, the book
is intended to make a number of contributions to current theoretical and
policy debates on the changing nature of business–government relations
and its impact on newly emerging economic institutions in China.
To begin with, existing studies of business–government relations in
China have tended to be narrow in theoretical focus and fragmented in
analytical perspectives. Some have shown political actors in the state domain
as the causal agents of changes in business–government interactions and
UNDERSTANDING BUSINESS–GOVERNMENT RELATIONS IN CHINA… 5

portrayed business actors and their organizations largely as passive and sub-
ordinate objects of control and co-optation through state corporatist
mechanisms (Alpermann 2006; Dickson 2003, 2008; Foster 2008; Ong
2012; Unger 2008a; Walder 1995, 2003). Others have granted analytical
primacy to the growing role of economic actors and firms in structuring
relations with the state and emphasized horizontal interactions mediated
through market institutions, business associations and social networks as an
important defining feature of state–firm relations (Nee 1992; Nee and
Opper 2012; Peng 2004; Sun, Wright and Mellahi 2010; Tjosvold et al.
2008; Xin and Pearce 1996). Still others have sought to advance a micro-
theory of business and politics that explains the motivation of individual
firms to develop connections with various party and governmental entities,
the choices they make on tactics and strategies, and the impact of political
ties on their performance (Du and Girma 2010; Guo et al. 2014; Li et al.
2006; Park and Luo 2001; Peng and Luo 2000).
While these approaches shed important light on the manifestations and
consequences of changing business–government relations in China, they
do not exhaust the categories of potential patterns of such relations. They
have mainly concentrated on one set of analytical dimensions, largely to
the exclusion of others that are constitutive of interactions between the
state and businesses. As a result, they have precluded the theoretical pos-
sibility of more than one pattern of state–business ties existing in the
Chinese political economy. The typological framework to be developed in
this book, which focuses on both the authoritative governance of the
economy and the market coordination of socioeconomic activities, pro-
vides a more encompassing analytical tool for developing a holistic under-
standing of changing and divergent forms of state–business relations, as
will be shown below. This is particularly relevant, given that the ultimate
objective of the book is to illustrate how the interrelationship between
state agencies, firms and business organizations has varied across different
regions and industries and explain how these regional and sectoral varia-
tions have shaped the pattern and trajectory of economic institutional
changes in China.
Furthermore, the emphasis of many extant studies has tended to be
more on understanding how business–government relations in China have
been changing over time, particularly against the backdrop of the coun-
try’s increased integration with the global economy and continuous mar-
ket reforms, than on examining how and why such relations have changed
6 X. ZHANG AND T. ZHU

differently at the regional or sectoral levels of analysis. To the extent that


some studies have explored cross-regional or cross-sectoral variations in
state–business interactions (see Ernst and Naughton 2008; Huchet and
Richet 2002; McNally 2011; Segal 2003; Thun 2006), they have failed to
provide a systematic explanation of the sources of these variations (the few
exceptions include Kennedy 2005 and Tsai 2007). There has yet to be any
satisfying account of why economic agents have been more powerful in
shaping socioeconomic relations, business associations more autonomous,
or state–firm relations more cooperative and development-oriented in
some regions or industries than in others.
As indicated above, the typological framework that focuses on how
authoritative governance and market coordination interact to generate
different forms and patterns of state–business relations facilitates a com-
parative analysis of why such relations vary across divergent regional or
sectoral sociopolitical environments. In advancing their respective causal
propositions, individual contributions to the book explore how the impact
of global and market forces on changes in the structure and practice of
business–government ties have been mediated through the region-specific
or sector-specific characteristics of ideological orientations, state institu-
tions and market structures. By examining the causes and consequences of
changing business–government relations within a cross-regional and
cross-sectoral framework, this book introduces a more dynamic perspec-
tive into the study of the Chinese political economy and thus fills an
important analytical lacuna in the literature.
Finally, the literatures on business–government relations in China and
on economic institutions and institutional change have, until recently,
developed largely in isolation from each other. While there have been
scholarly efforts to integrate the analysis of state–firm interactions and
industrial transformations (Breznitz and Murphee 2011; Kennedy 2005;
McNally 2008; Segal 2003; Thun 2006), empirical studies on the impact
of changing interactions between state and business actors on the emer-
gence of new market institutions have been rare; cross-regional or cross-­
sectoral analyses of the causal linkage between different forms of
business–government ties and divergent patterns of economic institutional
reforms have been even rarer. This book aims to bring together both the
temporal and spatial comparisons of how the structure of business–gov-
ernment relations has varied and of how these variations have exerted
shaping influence on the process of institutional changes in China.
UNDERSTANDING BUSINESS–GOVERNMENT RELATIONS IN CHINA… 7

A Typology of Business–Government Relations


This section delineates the defining features of key analytical dimensions
that underpin business–government relations, develops some guiding
principles for categorizing and comparing the organization of these
dimensions that generates the varied contours of interactions between
state and business actors, and describes the different configurations of
such interactions across regions and industries in China.

Key Analytical Dimensions


Developing a typology of business–government relations, in such a vast
and diverse country as China, that is both conceptually parsimonious and
empirically encompassing is difficult. The difficulty mainly rests with the
lack of commonly accepted conceptual criteria for identifying key analyti-
cal dimensions that characterize business–government relations and for
ascertaining the number of distinct types of state–firm interactions,
although the regional and sectoral diversity of such interactions is widely
recognized (Breslin 2012; Kennedy 2005; Ngo this volume; Unger
2008b). However, there appears to be general agreement in the emerging
literature on the constitutive institutions of Chinese capitalism that the
authoritative governance of the economy and the market coordination of
socioeconomic activities are crucial components of interrelationships
between state actors, firms and business organizations (Fligstein and
Zhang 2010; Redding and Witt 2007; Zhang and Peck 2016).
The authoritative governance of the economy concerns the extent to
which the state structures its relationships with the business sector through
industrial targeting and intervention, market regulations and controls over
associational arrangements among various economic agents. Despite the
continuous process of market-oriented reforms, both central and local
governments in China have remained involved in steering and organizing
economic activities and outcomes, though the nature and levels of such
involvement have varied significantly across regions and industries (Huang
2008; McNally 2008; Naughton and Tsai 2015). On the other hand,
socioeconomic producer groups, particularly business, are also crucial
agents that coordinate economic action and structure market transactions
(Nee and Opper 2012; Redding and Witt 2007). Thus, to understand the
organizational diversity of business–government relations in China, the
authoritative governance of the economy needs to be viewed in close
8 X. ZHANG AND T. ZHU

interaction with the market coordination of socioeconomic activities that


pertains to the ability of business actors to organize themselves for collec-
tive action purposes. Such an ability is embodied in the degree of interfirm
collaborations, the development of business associations and the density of
interlinkages between firms and such third-party entities as financial and
research institutions.
In the first place, the state structures its relationship with business
actors through its efforts to protect or promote specific firms, sectors or
industries. These efforts affect the development of new technologies, the
restructuring of ailing industrial sectors and the performance and fortunes
of various enterprises. Here, we are concerned with how the state manage-
ment of industrial development shapes state–firm relations. In the less
state-led form of intervention, the state facilitates industrial development
and adjustment by organizing its strategies around public–private partner-
ships and even private initiatives and providing policy and institutional
support; it often does not target specific sectors or firms for special promo-
tion and discriminate against private domestic or foreign firms. In the
more dirigiste form, the state deploys a wide array of elaborate policy
instruments to manage resource allocation, production activities and
investment flows directly, with the view to aligning the behaviour and
incentives of market players with its industrial policy goals and socioeco-
nomic development imperatives.
The extent to which state actors are actively involved in governing the
economy through industrial targeting and intervention both derives from
and influences their approaches towards managing and regulating the
development of product, labour or financial markets. Such approaches
vary, for instance, between the more market-oriented modes of regulation
and the more state-controlled pattern of market development. These dif-
ferences that have prevailed across regions and industrial sectors in China
exert differential shaping influence over both state–firm relations and
interactions among various socioeconomic actors. They are particularly
manifest in the extent to which: state actors orchestrate the distribution of
financial resources between economic agents through ownership means
and administrative decrees; bureaucratic procedures favour some firms
over others by restraining entry and reducing competition; and regula-
tions influence relations between business and labour and their respective
ties with state actors.
A final attribute of authoritative governance concerns the extent to which
the state sets the rules and conventions that structure interlinkages between
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
By the physical hypothesis, he meant the doctrine that the time of
a planet’s describing any part of its orbit is proportional to the
distance of the planet from the sun, for which supposition, as we
have said, he conceived that he had assigned physical reasons.

The two last hypotheses came the nearest to the truth, and
differed from it only by about eight minutes, the one in excess and
the other in defect. And, after being much perplexed by this
remaining error, it at last occurred to him 41 that he might take
another ellipsis, exactly intermediate between the former one and
the circle, and that this must give the path and the motion of the
planet. Making this assumption, and taking the areas to represent
the times, he now saw 42 that both the longitude and the distances of
Mars would agree with observation to the requisite degree of
accuracy. The rectification of the former hypothesis, when thus
stated, may, perhaps, appear obvious. And Kepler informs us that he
had nearly been anticipated in this step (c. 55). “David Fabricius, to
whom I had communicated my hypothesis of cap. 45, was able, by
his observations, to show that it erred in making the distances too
short at mean longitudes; of which he informed me by letter while I
was laboring, by repeated efforts, to discover the true hypothesis. So
nearly did he get the start of me in detecting the truth.” But this was
less easy than it might seem. When Kepler’s first hypothesis was
enveloped in the complex construction requisite in order to apply it to
each point of the orbit, it was far more difficult to see where the error
lay, and Kepler hit upon it only by noticing the coincidences of certain
numbers, which, as he says, raised him as if from sleep, and gave
him a new light. We may observe, also, that he was perplexed to
reconcile this new view, according to which the planet described an
exact ellipse, with his former opinion, which represented the motion
by means of libration in an epicycle. “This,” he says, “was my
greatest trouble, that, though I considered and reflected till I was
almost mad, I could not find why the planet to which, with so much
probability, and with such an exact 301 accordance of the distances,
libration in the diameter of the epicycle was attributed, should,
according to the indication of the equations, go in an elliptical path.
What an absurdity on my part! as if libration in the diameter might not
be a way to the ellipse!”
41 De Stellâ Martis, c. 58.

42 Ibid. p. 235.

Another scruple respecting this theory arose from the impossibility


of solving, by any geometrical construction, the problem to which
Kepler was thus led, namely, “To divide the area of a semicircle in a
given ratio, by a line drawn from any point of the diameter.” This is
still termed “Kepler’s Problem,” and is, in fact, incapable of exact
geometrical solution. As, however, the calculation can be performed,
and, indeed, was performed by Kepler himself, with a sufficient
degree of accuracy to show that the elliptical hypothesis is true, the
insolubility of this problem is a mere mathematical difficulty in the
deductive process, to which Kepler’s induction gave rise.

Of Kepler’s physical reasonings we shall speak more at length on


another occasion. His numerous and fanciful hypotheses had
discharged their office, when they had suggested to him his many
lines of laborious calculation, and encouraged him under the
exertions and disappointments to which these led. The result of this
work was the formal laws of the motion of Mars, established by a
clear induction, since they represented, with sufficient accuracy, the
best observations. And we may allow that Kepler was entitled to the
praise which he claims in the motto on his first leaf. Ramus had said
that if any one would construct an astronomy without hypothesis, he
would be ready to resign to him his professorship in the University of
Paris. Kepler quotes this passage, and adds, “it is well, Ramus, that
you have run from this pledge, by quitting life and your
professorship; 43 if you held it still, I should, with justice, claim it.” This
was not saying too much, since he had entirely overturned the
hypothesis of eccentrics and epicycles, and had obtained a theory
which was a mere representation of the motions and distances as
they were observed.
43 Ramus perished in the Massacre of St. Bartholomew. 302
CHAPTER V.

Sequel to the epoch of Kepler. Reception, Verification, and Extension of


the Elliptical Theory.

Sect. 1.—Application of the Elliptical Theory to the Planets.

T HE extension of Kepler’s discoveries concerning the orbit of


Mars to the other planets, obviously offered itself as a strong
probability, and was confirmed by trial. This was made in the first
place upon the orbit of Mercury; which planet, in consequence of the
largeness of its eccentricity, exhibits more clearly than the others the
circumstances of the elliptical motion. These and various other
supplementary portions of the views to which Kepler’s discoveries
had led, appeared in the latter part of his Epitome Astronomiæ
Copernicanæ, published in 1622.

The real verification of the new doctrine concerning the orbits and
motions of the heavenly bodies was, of course, to be found in the
construction of tables of those motions, and in the continued
comparison of such tables with observation. Kepler’s discoveries had
been founded, as we have seen, principally on Tycho’s observations.
Longomontanus (so called as being a native of Langberg in
Denmark), published in 1621, in his Astronomia Danica, tables
founded upon the theories as well as the observations of his
countryman. Kepler 44 in 1627 published his tables of the planets,
which he called Rudolphine Tables, the result and application of his
own theory. In 1633, Lansberg, a Belgian, published also Tabulæ
Perpetuæ, a work which was ushered into the world with
considerable pomp and pretension, and in which the author cavils
very keenly at Kepler and Brahe. We may judge of the impression
made upon the astronomical world in general by these rival works,
from the account which our countryman Jeremy Horrox has given of
their effect on him. He had been seduced by the magnificent
promises of Lansberg, and the praises of his admirers, which are
prefixed to the work, and was persuaded that the common opinion
which preferred Tycho and Kepler to him was a prejudice. In 1636,
however, he became acquainted with Crabtree, another young 303
astronomer, who lived in the same part of Lancashire. By him Horrox
was warned that Lansberg was not to be depended on; that his
hypotheses were vicious, and his observations falsified or forced into
agreement with his theories. He then read the works and adopted
the opinions of Kepler; and after some hesitation which he felt at the
thought of attacking the object of his former idolatry, he wrote a
dissertation on the points of difference between them. It appears
that, at one time, he intended to offer himself as the umpire who was
to adjudge the prize of excellence among the three rival theories of
Longomontanus, Kepler, and Lansberg; and, in allusion to the story
of ancient mythology, his work was to have been called Paris
Astronomicus; we easily see that he would have given the golden
apple to the Keplerian goddess. Succeeding observations confirmed
his judgment: and the Rudolphine Tables, thus published seventy-six
years after the Prutenic, which were founded on the doctrines of
Copernicus, were for a long time those universally used.
44 Rheticus, Narratio, p. 98.

Sect. 2.—Application of the Elliptical Theory to the Moon.

The reduction of the Moon’s motions to rule was a harder task


than the formation of planetary tables, if accuracy was required; for
the Moon’s motion is affected by an incredible number of different
and complex inequalities, which, till their law is detected, appear to
defy all theory. Still, however, progress was made in this work. The
most important advances were due to Tycho Brahe. In addition to the
first and second inequalities of the moon (the Equation of the Centre,
known very early, and the Evection, which Ptolemy had discovered),
Tycho proved that there was another inequality, which he termed the
Variation, 45 which depended on the moon’s position with respect to
the sun, and which at its maximum was forty minutes and a half,
about a quarter of the evection. He also perceived, though not very
distinctly, the necessity of another correction of the moon’s place
depending on the sun’s longitude, which has since been termed the
Annual Equation.
45 We have seen (chap. iii.), that Aboul-Wefa, in the tenth
century, had already noticed this inequality; but his discovery had
been entirely forgotten long before the time of Tycho, and has
only recently been brought again into notice.

These steps concerned the Longitude of the Moon; Tycho also


made important advances in the knowledge of the Latitude. The
Inclination of the Orbit had hitherto been assumed to be the same at
all 304 times; and the motion of the Node had been supposed
uniform. He found that the inclination increased and diminished by
twenty minutes, according to the position of the line of nodes; and
that the nodes, though they regress upon the whole, sometimes go
forwards and sometimes go backwards.

Tycho’s discoveries concerning the moon are given in his


Progymnasmata, which was published in 1603, two years after the
author’s death. He represents the Moon’s motion in longitude by
means of certain combinations of epicycles and eccentrics. But after
Kepler had shown that such devices are to be banished from the
planetary system, it was impossible not to think of extending the
elliptical theory to the moon. Horrox succeeded in doing this; and in
1638 sent this essay to his friend Crabtree. It was published in 1673,
with the numerical elements requisite for its application added by
Flamsteed. Flamsteed had also (in 1671–2) compared this theory
with observation, and found that it agreed far more nearly than the
Philolaic Tables of Bullialdus, or the Carolinian Tables of Street
(Epilogus ad Tabulas). Moreover Horrox, by making the centre of the
ellipse revolve in an epicycle, gave an explanation of the evection,
as well as of the equation of the centre. 46
46 Horrox (Horrockes as he himself spelt his name) gave a first
sketch of his theory in letters to his friend Crabtree in 1638: in
which the variation of the eccentricity is not alluded to. But in
Crabtree’s letter to Gascoigne in 1642, he gives Horrox’s rule
concerning it; and Flamsteed in his Epilogue to the Tables,
published by Wallis along with Horrox’s works in 1673, gave an
explanation of the theory which made it amount very nearly to a
revolution of the centre of the ellipse in an epicycle. Halley
afterwards made a slight alteration; but hardly, I think, enough to
justify Newton’s assertion (Princip. Lib. iii. Prop. 35, Schol.),
“Halleius centrum ellipseos in epicyclo locavit.” See Baily’s
Flamsteed, p. 683.
Modern astronomers, by calculating the effects of the perturbing
forces of the solar system, and comparing their calculations with
observation, have added many new corrections or equations to
those known at the time of Horrox; and since the Motions of the
heavenly bodies were even then affected by these variations as yet
undetected, it is clear that the Tables of that time must have shown
some errors when compared with observation. These errors much
perplexed astronomers, and naturally gave rise to the question
whether the motions of the heavenly bodies really were exactly
regular, or whether they were not affected by accidents as little
reducible to rule as wind and weather. Kepler had held the opinion of
the casualty of such errors; but Horrox, far more philosophically,
argues against this opinion, though he 305 allows that he is much
embarrassed by the deviations. His arguments show a singularly
clear and strong apprehension of the features of the case, and their
real import. He says, 47 “these errors of the tables are alternately in
excess and defect; how could this constant compensation happen if
they were casual? Moreover, the alternation from excess to defect is
most rapid in the Moon, most slow in Jupiter and Saturn, in which
planets the error continues sometimes for years. If the errors were
casual, why should they not last as long in the Moon as in Saturn?
But if we suppose the tables to be right in the mean motions, but
wrong in the equations, these facts are just what must happen; since
Saturn’s inequalities are of long period, while those of the Moon are
numerous, and rapidly changing.” It would be impossible, at the
present moment, to reason better on this subject; and the doctrine,
that all the apparent irregularities of the celestial motions are really
regular, was one of great consequence to establish at this period of
the science.
47 Astron. Kepler. Proleg. p. 17.
Sect. 3.—Causes of the further Progress of Astronomy.

We are now arrived at the time when theory and observation


sprang forwards with emulous energy. The physical theories of
Kepler, and the reasonings of other defenders of the Copernican
theory, led inevitably, after some vagueness and perplexity, to a
sound science of Mechanics; and this science in time gave a new
face to Astronomy. But in the mean time, while mechanical
mathematicians were generalizing from the astronomy already
established, astronomers were accumulating new facts, which
pointed the way to new theories and new generalizations.
Copernicus, while he had established the permanent length of the
year, had confirmed the motion of the sun’s apogee, and had shown
that the eccentricity of the earth’s orbit, and the obliquity of the
ecliptic, were gradually, though slowly, diminishing. Tycho had
accumulated a store of excellent observations. These, as well as the
laws of the motions of the moon and planets already explained, were
materials on which the Mechanics of the Universe was afterwards to
employ its most matured powers. In the mean time, the telescope
had opened other new subjects of notice and speculation; not only
confirming the Copernican doctrine by the phases of Venus, and the
analogical examples of Jupiter and Saturn, which with their Satellites
306 appeared like models of the Solar System; but disclosing
unexpected objects, as the Ring of Saturn, and the Spots of the Sun.
The art of observing made rapid advances, both by the use of the
telescope, and by the sounder notions of the construction of
instruments which Tycho introduced. Copernicus had laughed at
Rheticus, when he was disturbed about single minutes; and declared
that if he could be sure to ten minutes of space, he should be as
much delighted as Pythagoras was when he discovered the property
of the right-angled triangle. But Kepler founded the revolution which
he introduced on a quantity less than this. “Since,” he says, 48 “the
Divine Goodness has given us in Tycho an observer so exact that
this error of eight minutes is impossible, we must be thankful to God
for this, and turn it to account. And these eight minutes, which we
must not neglect, will, of themselves, enable us to reconstruct the
whole of astronomy.” In addition to other improvements, the art of
numerical calculation made an inestimable advance by means of
Napier’s invention of Logarithms; and the progress of other parts of
pure mathematics was proportional to the calls which astronomy and
physics made upon them.
48 De Stellâ Martis, c. 19.

The exactness which observation had attained enabled


astronomers both to verify and improve the existing theories, and to
study the yet unsystematized facts. The science was, therefore,
forced along by a strong impulse on all sides, and its career
assumed a new character. Up to this point, the history of European
Astronomy was only the sequel of the history of Greek Astronomy;
for the heliocentric system, as we have seen, had had a place
among the guesses, at least, of the inventive and acute intellects of
the Greek philosophers. But the discovery of Kepler’s Laws,
accompanied, as from the first they were, with a conviction that the
relations thus brought to light were the effects and exponents of
physical causes, led rapidly and irresistibly to the Mechanical
Science of the skies, and collaterally, to the Mechanical Science of
the other parts of Nature: Sound, and Light, and Heat; and
Magnetism, and Electricity, and Chemistry. The history of these
Sciences, thus treated, forms the sequel of the present work, and will
be the subject of the succeeding volumes. And since, as I have said,
our main object in this work is to deduce, from the history of science,
the philosophy of scientific discovery, it may be regarded as
fortunate for our purpose that the history, after this point, so far
changes its aspect as to offer new materials for such speculations.
The details of 307 a history of astronomy, such as the history of
astronomy since Newton has been, though interesting to the special
lovers of that science, would be too technical, and the features of the
narrative too monotonous and unimpressive, to interest the general
reader, or to suggest a comprehensive philosophy of science. But
when we pass from the Ideas of Space and Time to the Ideas of
Force and Matter, of Mediums by which action and sensation are
produced, and of the Intimate Constitution of material bodies, we
have new fields of inquiry opened to us. And when we find that in
these fields, as well as in astronomy, there are large and striking
trains of unquestioned discovery to be narrated, we may gird
ourselves afresh to the task of writing, and I hope, of reading, the
remaining part of the History of the Inductive Sciences, in the trust
that it will in some measure help us to answer the important
questions, What is Truth? and, How is it to be discovered?
BOOK VI.

THE MECHANICAL SCIENCES.


H I S T O R Y O F M E C H A N I C S,
INCLUDING

FLUID MECHANICS.
ΚΡΑΤΟΣ ΒIΑ ΤΕ, σφῷν μὲν ἐντολὴ Διὸς
Ἔχει Τέλος δὴ, κ’ οὐδὲν ἐμποδῶν ἔτι
Æschylus. Prom. Vinct. 13.

You, FORCE and POWER, have done your destined task:


And naught impedes the work of other hands.
INTRODUCTION.

W EfromenterAstronomy
now upon a new region of the human mind. In passing
to Mechanics we make a transition from the
formal to the physical sciences;—from time and space to force and
matter;—from phenomena to causes. Hitherto we have been
concerned only with the paths and orbits, the periods and cycles, the
angles and distances, of the objects to which our sciences applied,
namely, the heavenly bodies. How these motions are produced;—by
what agencies, impulses, powers, they are determined to be what
they are;—of what nature are the objects themselves;—are
speculations which we have hitherto not dwelt upon. The history of
such speculations now comes before us; but, in the first place, we
must consider the history of speculations concerning motion in
general, terrestrial as well as celestial. We must first attend to
Mechanics, and afterwards return to Physical Astronomy.

In the same way in which the development of Pure Mathematics,


which began with the Greeks, was a necessary condition of the
progress of Formal Astronomy, the creation of the science of
Mechanics now became necessary to the formation and progress of
Physical Astronomy. Geometry and Mechanics were studied for their
own sakes; but they also supplied ideas, language, and reasoning to
other sciences. If the Greeks had not cultivated Conic Sections,
Kepler could not have superseded Ptolemy; if the Greeks had
cultivated Dynamics, 1 Kepler might have anticipated Newton.
1Dynamics is the science which treats of the Motions of Bodies;
Statics is the science which treats of the Pressure of Bodies which
are in equilibrium, and therefore at rest. 312
CHAPTER I.

Prelude to the Epoch of Galileo.

Sect. 1.—Prelude to the Science of Statics.

S OME steps in the science of Motion, or rather in the science of


Equilibrium, had been made by the ancients, as we have seen.
Archimedes established satisfactorily the doctrine of the Lever, some
important properties of the Centre of Gravity, and the fundamental
proposition of Hydrostatics. But this beginning led to no permanent
progress. Whether the distinction between the principles of the
doctrine of Equilibrium and of Motion was clearly seen by
Archimedes, we do not know; but it never was caught hold of by any
of the other writers of antiquity, or by those of the Stationary Period.
What was still worse, the point which Archimedes had won was not
steadily maintained.

We have given some examples of the general ignorance of the


Greek philosophers on such subjects, in noticing the strange manner
in which Aristotle refers to mathematical properties, in order to
account for the equilibrium of a lever, and the attitude of a man rising
from a chair. And we have seen, in speaking of the indistinct ideas of
the Stationary Period, that the attempts which were made to extend
the statical doctrine of Archimedes, failed, in such a manner as to
show that his followers had not clearly apprehended the idea on
which his reasoning altogether depended. The clouds which he had,
for a moment, cloven in his advance, closed after him, and the
former dimness and confusion settled again on the land.
This dimness and confusion, with respect to all subjects of
mechanical reasoning, prevailed still, at the period we now have to
consider; namely, the period of the first promulgation of the
Copernican opinions. This is so important a point that I must
illustrate it further.

Certain general notions of the connection of cause and effect in


motion, exist in the human mind at all periods of its development,
and are implied in the formation of language and in the most familiar
employments of men’s thoughts. But these do not constitute a
science of 313 Mechanics, any more than the notions of square and
round make a Geometry, or the notions of months and years make
an Astronomy. The unfolding these Notions into distinct Ideas, on
which can be founded principles and reasonings, is further requisite,
in order to produce a science; and, with respect to the doctrines of
Motion, this was long in coming to pass; men’s thoughts remained
long entangled in their primitive and unscientific confusion.

We may mention one or two features of this confusion, such as we


find in authors belonging to the period now under review.

We have already, in speaking of the Greek School Philosophy,


noticed the attempt to explain some of the differences among
Motions, by classifying them into Natural Motions and Violent
Motions; and we have spoken of the assertion that heavy bodies fall
quicker in proportion to their greater weight. These doctrines were
still retained: yet the views which they implied were essentially
erroneous and unsound; for they did not refer distinctly to a
measurable Force as the cause of all motion or change of motion;
and they confounded the causes which produce and those which
preserve, motion. Hence such principles did not lead immediately to
any advance of knowledge, though efforts were made to apply them,
in the cases both of terrestrial Mechanics and of the motions of the
heavenly bodies.

The effect of the Inclined Plane was one of the first, as it was one
of the most important, propositions, on which modern writers
employed themselves. It was found that a body, when supported on
a sloping surface, might be sustained or raised by a force or exertion
which would not have been able to sustain or raise it without such
support. And hence, The Inclined Plane was placed in the list of
Mechanical Powers, or simple machines by which the efficacy of
forces is increased: the question was, in what proportion this
increase of efficiency takes place. It is easily seen that the force
requisite to sustain a body is smaller, as the slope on which it rests is
smaller; Cardan (whose work, De Proportionibus Numerorum,
Motuum, Ponderum, &c., was published in 1545) asserts that the
force is double when the angle of inclination is double, and so on for
other proportions; this is probably a guess, and is an erroneous one.
Guido Ubaldi, of Marchmont, published at Pesaro, in 1577, a work
which he called Mechanicorum Liber, in which he endeavors to
prove that an acute wedge will produce a greater mechanical effect
than an obtuse one, without determining in what proportion. There is,
he observes, “a certain repugnance” between the direction in which
the side of the wedge tends to 314 move the obstacle, and the
direction in which it really does move. Thus the Wedge and the
Inclined Plane are connected in principle. He also refers the Screw
to the Inclined Plane and the Wedge, in a manner which shows a
just apprehension of the question. Benedetti (1585) treats the
Wedge in a different manner; not exact, but still showing some
powers of thought on mechanical subjects. Michael Varro, whose
Tractatus de Motu was published at Geneva in 1584, deduces the
wedge from the composition of hypothetical motions, in a way which
may appear to some persons an anticipation of the doctrine of the
Composition of Forces.

There is another work on subjects of this kind, of which several


editions were published in the sixteenth century, and which treats
this matter in nearly the same way as Varro, and in favour of which a
claim has been made 2 (I think an unfounded one), as if it contained
the true principle of this problem. The work is “Jordanus Nemorarius
De Ponderositate.” The date and history of this author were probably
even then unknown; for in 1599, Benedetti, correcting some of the
errors of Tartalea, says they are taken “a Jordano quodam antiquo.”
The book was probably a kind of school-book, and much used; for
an edition printed at Frankfort, in 1533, is stated to be Cum gratia et
privilegio Imperiali, Petro Apiano mathematico Ingolstadiano ad xxx
annos concesso. But this edition does not contain the Inclined Plane.
Though those who compiled the work assert in words something like
the inverse proportion of Weights and their Velocities, they had not
learnt at that time how to apply this maxim to the Inclined Plane; nor
were they ever able to render a sound reason for it. In the edition of
Venice, 1565, however, such an application is attempted. The
reasonings are founded on the Aristotelian assumption, “that bodies
descend more quickly in proportion as they are heavier.” To this
principle are added some others; as, that “a body is heavier in
proportion as it descends more directly to the centre,” and that, in
proportion as a body descends more obliquely, the intercepted part
of the direct descent is smaller. By means of these principles, the
“descending force” of bodies, on inclined planes, was compared, by
a process, which, so far as it forms a line of proof at all, is a
somewhat curious example of confused and vicious reasoning.
When two bodies are supported on two inclined planes, and are

You might also like