Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 47

18 India Infrastructure Report 2003

2 EXPENDITURE ACCOUNTABILITY AND


THE SOCIETY

2.1 EXPENDITURE ACCOUNTABILITY IN INDIA: THE INTERLINKAGES

Sebastian Morris

THE CHALLENGE OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURE to be accountable to the legislature is accommodated without


ACCOUNTABILITY much difficulty, because few believe that there are major
strategies (new things to do collectively) in the offing; for
The challenge of public expenditure accountability in which the state has to take the initiative. Elites of trans-
developing democracies is greater than in other societies forming democracies, though, could have an agenda that
that are already developed or have chosen to grow without goes beyond what can be voted and is acceptable to the
firm commitment to democratic political processes. Political legislature. Thus it would be difficult for a legislature to
processes in these countries are in many ways more complex endorse the vast subsidization, or more correctly, the
than in advanced democracies. Being still on the road to incentivization of exports, or the enormous financial re-
transition all ideologies, including fascist libertarian, pression that went on in South Korea or Taiwan. These
autarkic, communist, anarchic, and others, are possible. measures are known to have speeded up the industrial and
Their richness of extant political ideologies is similar to technological developments. Additionally, selective policies
that which existed in Europe in the 1890s, a little before that included inter alia the patently unfair ‘selection of
many countries of Europe completed their transformation. winners’, that South Korea adopted were instrumental in
Additionally, new ideologies like market socialism, mixed the country’s quick transformation. Executives in power
economy, and ‘green’ have also emerged. But much of possibly do realize the value of such agenda, which, by the
Europe obviously did not give itself the luxury of being standards of the mature democracies, would be unfair to
fully democratic while the process of the industrial the idea of equality of opportunity and hence not achievable
transformation was on. Monarchies, constitutional and through the consent of a legislature. Similarly, elites of Latin
absolute, and empires and republics without universal America, used the state to further their own agenda of
franchise constituted the great variety of political systems ‘dependent development’1. These have taken the form of
prevalent. the elites’ integration with global (western) capital even if
it meant slower growth, and vast capital flight from these
Late Industrialization and Accountability of the economies. More importantly, democracies that have still
Executive to carry out their industrialization are also weak in the sense
that many of their citizens (probably the majority), despite
Advanced countries having been successful would now have
having the power to vote, are handicapped by their poor
to contend with few competing ideologies. Differences are
endowments. We had earlier in India Infrastructure Report
marginal and differ only on ‘small’ issues—size of particular
subsidies, degree of commitment to the environment, the 1 A term due to Peter Evans (1984), but the idea of the
degree of resistance to import penetration, the desired size dysfunctional dependency of Latin American societies on world
of social security, and attitude to in-migration. So the need capitalism has an earlier origin. Cf. Frank Andre Gunder (1967).
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 19

IIR 2002 argued that good governance itself can be considered of the off-budget activities of the government as a whole.
as a public good whose value increases with development, They do not include the aspect of the guarantees and
and as people’s incomes rise beyond a certain critical level leveraged borrowings indulged in by the government.
above which they value good governance. Thus the legislature Despite their vast and pervasive nature, formal efforts at
itself may not be truly representative, and the scope for review/accountability, etc. that have emerged thus far may
pursuing an agenda though, not in the true interest of the amount to mere ritual efforts. Why is this so? Democratic
poor, but, nevertheless, addressing them at a token or govern-ments have the task of not only carrying out the
symbolic level, that is, rhetorically, may be large. functions of government (and, in less development countries,
the additional one of taking the country through the industrial
‘Off-budget’ Expenditures are Common transformation), but also of being fair, or at least appearing
to be fair. Being fair may not be completely consistent with
‘Off-budget’ or non-voted expenditures in developing the process of bourgeoisie development that brings about
democracies are more common than in mature ones, or the industrial transformation, so the task of appearing to
even autocracies. Contingent liabilities, cross subsidies, be fair has a special place. The discovery of hidden budgets
highly inefficient modes of subsidization, multiple tax and whom they subserve does not automatically lead to
rates, many deductions and exceptions in rates, change on that count alone. Significant political shifts or
administrative mech-anisms for allocation of land and strategies for systemic change are required, and little is
scarce public goods are all vehicles for by-passing legislatures. achieved by the mere public knowledge of hidden budgets.
Many of the above are initiated in the name of the poor, Hence there is a tendency to not correct major distortions
but could actually benefit many others than the poor. by eliminating or removing them, but to ‘work around
Despite an active opposition, the opposition itself when them’ sometimes through counteracting distortions. Cases
in power would derive much use from these ‘off-budget’ in point are the electricity subsidies or the oil subsidies,
measures so the opposition and discussion is not against which were discussed at length in the IIR (2002).
‘off-budget’ tran-sactions per se but their specific uses and
objectives. Thus left-wing parties would like to use the state Politics is Not Everything
in a manner that benefits their constituencies without
having to get the same voted. They would end up supporting The above is rather well known and easily admitted. But
food or agricultural subsidies that are implicit rather than that should not deter attention from the major gains that
explicit, because once in place such subsidies are most can be made through better and more efficient processes,
difficult to remove. An industrial lobby could similarly and reforms to correct many of these ills, even within the
push through administered cost-plus pricing regimes for constraints of the current state and politics. As was brought
products of mass consumption with built-in cross subsidies out in the IIR (2002), the vested interests of today may
have been only an unintended consequence of past policy
rather than clean budgeted subsidies. Middle classes could
errors. Reform has the potential to unlock forces in favour
support allocations through administrative mechanisms
of reform especially in democracies, when the strategically
rather than the market, or through universal rationing,
correct steps are taken. It means that reformers have the
because they could tilt such schemes to their advantage
added task of making and pushing for options that are
either because the really poor are not even in the market
politically feasible and enhance the size of the economy5.
for the good2, or because they are confident about
Moreover, as the competition for rents increases, the
influencing the actual allocation process3 given queues or
returns to competition and control decreases, and that in
shortages.
turn can release strong political process for reform and
In India just before the reform of the 1990s, there was
better management of the state. It is our belief that the
probably no group which did not enjoy (at least on paper)
reform of the early 1990s have resulted in forces (including
some benefit as a result of state controls and distortionary political) for the second round of reforms and change, but
policies, while the economy as a whole bore the costs4. policy-makers have not been able to live up to the task
The measures of implicit subsidies at 12 per cent of gross of providing alternatives that are sufficiently contextualized
domestic product (GDP) by the National Institute of and workable. The abundance of doctrinaire ‘solutions’,
Public Finance and Policy (NIPFP) is only a partial measure and the blanket blame of the politicians, only exposes the
2 This is, for instance, true of the subsidies on higher education,
inadequacies of the policy-makers today.
cooking gas, fertilisers, and even food in India. Accountability of government expenditure is an aspect
3 Examples of these would include drinking water in urban areas, of good governance in the conventionally understood sense.
already discussed in the last IIR.
4 The dead weight losses rather than the transfers may have been 5 See Ashima Goyal, Section 2.2, in this report on the political
far the greater. economy of expenditures, and investment by the state.
20 India Infrastructure Report 2003

We now discuss the case of the central government’s development finance institutions. The budgetary contri-
expenditure processes. bution to the Plan constituted the governments direct role
in investment. This non-discretionary way of spending
proved functional and kept the political pulls and pressures
DIMENSIONS OF EXPENDITURE ALLOCATION
at bay for quite some time, till the Plan collapsed in 1965.
We may usefully develop certain axes for the understanding The politicking and the pressures for investment as we see
of both central government expenditures and transfers to today began only after the collapse of the Plan. Nevertheless
state governments and parastatals. These we may identify: even in the Plan period upto 1965 there was one open
dimension wherein non-economic factors could have been
1. The spatial dimension: that is, where the money brought to bear—the spatial dimension. But this too may
is spent have been severely curtailed because the big investments
2. On what the money is spent: viz. the sector. in heavy industries and social overhead capital or
3. Social optimality: is the money spent on the best infrastructure were to a large extent location specific.
possible project that is on the project with the highest
social return given feasibility? Marginal Political Role
4. The performance dimension: do the project/prog-
ramme managers perform in the best possible manner? Some leeway for pulls and pressures in the choice of head
And does performance feed back into the budgetary offices of public sector corporations, investments in urban
(allocative) decisions? infrastructure, investments in softer areas like high-cost
technical education institutions, would, of course, have
The spatial and sectoral dimensions can have important
been there even when Nehru was alive. And sometimes
correlations and may not be considered as being entirely
may have been even perversely exercised.6 Determination
independent. Thus an emphasis on coal usage and coal
of social optimality involved discretionary choices—taking
development in national policy and its support through
the form of choice of technology and equipment and
central projects and sponsorship implies that regions with
sometimes location when there were many possible locations.
coal resources are recipients or beneficiaries of government
It would be facile to say that all the investment expenditures
expenditure.
in such industries and the choice of equipment and
technology were taken in a completely apolitical manner.
Planning and ‘Objectification’ of Expenditure
Nevertheless, the overwhelming role of politics, which
With planning and the fiscal process in the post-independence came about in the 1970s and the 1980s, would have been
period, in both form and in content, the first three dimensions quite absent then. The blatant direction of investments to
were sought to be institutionalized and taken out of the the minister’s constituency that we see today, or the
political process. The immediate result and basis of the same locational politics played by Indira Gandhi in 1966 was
was the creation of the Planning Commission.The Planning nonexistent.7 If the cases of the setting up of steel plants
Commission’s role is worth recalling in the context of or that of the oil industry in the 1950s and the 1960s were
government expenditures. It allowed the objectification of typical, then a strategy to build self-reliance and the long-
important expenditure decisions since a large part of term interests of the country were more overriding than
government expenditure (other than on routine adminis- the politics of location, and the locational tournaments, we
tration) was related to the Central (and State) Plans. And see today.
even when not formally designated as Plan expenditure had The earlier objectivity that was derived from the Plan
much to do with the carrying forth of previous Plan objectives, could also then be vitiated. The objectivity if at all was then
and the assets and organizations they created. entirely reduced to the sectoral allocations; and not to the
Interestingly, the Mahalanobis Plan’s four broad sectors details of the projects or investment nor the locational choices.
evolved to more than a hundred sectors, so that planning
became an exercise in intersectoral consistency, worked 6 A large factor in taking investments away from the spatial
out through elaborate input–output models, which were optimal was the intrusion of ‘balanced’ regional development into the
later expanded to bring in consumption demands. Plan itself, through its policy of freight equalizations, which shifted
The Planning Commission went beyond the sectoral the advantage of steel and coal-using industries out of eastern India.
7 Around this time the systematic rejection of Talcher (even
allocations, when it carried out project evaluation in the
today the world’s best site for a steel mill) for a second time, to
Project Investment Board (PIB). The PIB only considered counter the influence of the old Congress in Andhra Pradesh and
the projects of the government and its public enterprises. Karnataka led to the sanction of the Vijaynagar and Vizag steel
Private projects which were also part of the Plan were plants. Both locations were far inferior than Talcher. See K. Das
merely incorporated, and funded in part through (1997) and K. Das (1999).
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 21

SCB at Variance with Planning the proposers could put down the project in the stated
form.
The task of social cost benefit (SCB) analysis or cost
Equally important, the very framework of SCB and
benefit (CB) analysis was not entirely consistent with the
financial analysis may not have been appropriate for the
derivation of investment targets and expenditures thereof
country. It is well known that environmental costs are not
from the Plan. If the Plan warranted certain investments
taken into account in the governments’ SCB. Similarly, the
then neither SCB nor CB could say that they were not
costs of land used, and of displacement and rehabilitation
socially desirable or financially unviable. Private or
or compensation were not built into projects. Border prices
commercial viability is not an issue at all in such an
for tradables were not used systematically. Without border
intersectoral exercise. All that SCB/CB ought to do is to
prices but with social prices for goods and services the
select the best out of possible projects to achieve the
planning and expenditure patterns would have been consistent
investment and output targets. In this limited sense, therefore,
only either with autarky8 or with a large weight for the
SCB /CB would amount to locational, scale, equipment,
Indian economy in world trade. And the presumption of
and technology choices. In the latter the quality of the either is absurd. Equally importantly, by not using referral
technology transfers, and the possibility of linked credit prices elsewhere, inefficiency or administered pricing, which
and the concessions thereof would then have to be assessed. took the prices far from the social cost, could be fed back
It is interesting that as long as the role of project evaluation into investment decisions in a major way if border prices
was restricted to this role of choice of the best project, were rejected for tradables. Such inconsistencies had deeply
rather than investment choice, the Plan was functional. In distorted the economy. Other social prices, such as that
the 1970s the introduction of the financial return criteria, of labour, were not used systematically.9
that is, CB, would have acted to frustrate the Plan. The
requirement could contradict with the target investment Plan Targets and Competition for Expenditure
specified by the Plan model, and strict adherence to the
target return could mean underinvestments. That would, The above discussion in no way means that cost-benefit
through the input–output relations, create inconsistency, analysis or project evaluation was downplayed. Not only
and supply and demand linkages would then work in a did entities such as public enterprises carry out detailed
‘domino’ fashion to derail the Plan. Additionally, since the project analysis but the Planning Commission’s PIB virtually
Plan was largely closed to trade (and the exchange rate was duplicated the process when it examined every item at
mis-aligned by a wide margin) the traded sector could not great length and over much time—looking at it from all
have been used to overcome supply and demand limitations. possible ‘angles’ including security, foreign exchange
conservation, promotion of indigenous technology, and
IRRs Compromised use of local equipment, credit linkage, protection of small
industry, employment, and such like, before approval was
What concerns us here is the ambiguity and ritualized granted. The processes were long drawn out, wasteful, and
assessment of projects, particularly the SCB/CB analysis prone to being manipulated10. One could not exclude the
that emerged out of this contradiction, and the ‘solution’ possibility of projects being caught in the loop where so
that was found. Rather than conceptually contest the much time was being taken for approval that it was already
intrusion implied by commercial viability, the same was time to revise the estimates, and hence for re-appraisal.
accommodated as a ritual. The way the system got around Since 1965, the plan targets may have served principally
the problem was to report all desired and ‘predecided’ to define the resources available for particular constituents,
projects with internal rate of returns (IRRs) above the cut- not necessarily that going into a particular sector, unless
off rate of 12 per cent! There was, of course, no ranking it was a narrow one like power with its own department.
of projects based on financial IRR, since the ‘objective’
was to ‘maximize’ the social return ‘known better’ to the 8 The Soviet Union with its vast land and natural resources may
bureaus, subject to a satisfactory financial return as revealed have come as close to realizing planning under autarky as was
by the IRR for CB. With such ‘accommodation’ then, it possible for any real economy.
9 In any case the possibility of government (or enterprises) being
was a simple matter to frustrate serious project evaluation.
able to use labour intensive technology was seriously affected by the
If the IRR could be vitiated at the margin, then it was a schism in the labour market. But the government’s non-use of social
small step to violate it so completely that in effect the cost- price of labour could have seriously affected significant opportunities
benefit analysis was a mere ritual that the state went that were there especially during the 1970s. It would have also
through. Going through the form of SCB and CB analysis, reinforced the bias against exports right through to the present.
10 See Morris (1987) for a detailed analysis of the processes and
laying out the planned increase in sales, etc. could have
in what manner they were dysfunctional even from the logic of
at best constituted a hurdle, where the check was whether
planning and active state enterprise leading to industrialization.
22 India Infrastructure Report 2003

The total Plan investments included own resources of intersectoral consistency modelling. The ideology of the
public enterprises, market borrowings, and part of private ‘socialistic development’ of going directly to the poor, of
investments, besides the budgetary contributions to the poverty alleviation, of creating employment, etc. provided
Plan. It is the budgetary contributions to the Plan and the the intellectual basis for these ‘sop’ programmes. The rate
allowed market borrowings (since these were usually made of growth of the government and the bureaucracy should
on the guarantee of the centre) that contributed public ideally have slowed down after 1965, since, by then, the
resources, for which enterprises and departments on their basic institutions (control and regulating organizations),
behalf competed. and the productive enterprises had already come into place.
Sooner rather than later, the process of planning became But that rate was kept up to a steady 2 to 2.5 per cent
one of departments /ministries taking back with them the per annum due to the ‘space’ provided by these programmes.
target estimate of the Planning Commission (Perspective
Planning Dept) of growth rate of the economy and the Coordination Failure and Ritualized ‘Evaluation’
sector and the investment requirements, and working out
The ritualized assessment of financial viability that did not
the amount that can be assumed to come from the private
correctly assess the risks would have reinforced the lack
sector and the budgetary requirements. Also incorporated
of risk mitigating actions within government. The point
were other extension, promotion and other infrastructure
is not that the state should look at risks the same way the
that were seen as important in the upgradation of quality
private sector does. States can bear much larger risks
and technology and overall development of the sector.
especially when the levers of the economy, such as monetary
Departments such as Small and Village Industries,
and fiscal policy are with the state. Actually, the very
emphasized the latter a great deal. For others where the
purpose of state involvement in production is to overcome
private sector was absent, and which were investment heavy
the risk barrier as private industry would see the same.
the key aspect were the investments into the sector. Besides
Given the vast coordination economies that are waiting to
inter sectoral consistency, the formal division of tasks
be picked by states and very large corporations attempting
(sectors) between the centre and the states constituted
investments on a large scale, the Plan itself would have
another basis to determine the sectoral allocations. If transfers
reduced the risk of investments for society as a whole, and
(as in Power and Urban Development) from the centre to
for the private sector, and passed (communicated) this risk
the states are included, then the constitutional division may
reduction to individual enterprises through policies such
not have been as important in delimiting the sectors, as the
as licensing and import restrictions. But due to improper
formal list of state and central functions would indicate.
project analysis, the state, which bore a large part of this
contingent risk, may not have been aware of the nature
Programmes and Growth of the Bureaucracy
and extent of the risk it was bearing. We may usefully call
The Plan process was based on investment targets this contingent risk the economic coordination risk. And,
operationalized through projects setting up enterprises anew, therefore, mitigating efforts may not have been as vigorous
and existing enterprises setting up projects. The taking up as they may otherwise have been.
of the ‘HYV Strategy’ and, following from it, the constitution Thus a very large part of the delays and cost overruns,
of programmes such as SFDA (Small Farmers Development especially in the 1970s and the early 1980s, before the
Agency), MFDA (Medium Farmers Development Agency), environmental factor became very large, was due to ‘lack
the IRDP (Integrated Rural Developement Programme)— of coordination’ between various sectors or enterprises
the employment programmes, since 1965, brought in an implementing projects. Failures in coordination, arising
entirely new dimension to the allocation process of public inter alia out of bureaucratic slackening, hierarchical
funds. As other programmes were added, the capital part processes and structures which disallow project-level
of Plan expenditure declined over the period from 1965 interaction between persons implementing the projects,
to 1980. More importantly, they brought in discretion in barriers created by rank and department, have imposed
the hands of the government, and the politician. Indira severe penalties on projects. But this aspect of value arising
Gandhi’s Garibi Hatao at the level of public expenditures out of coordination would not have been clear to senior
must be seen as creating the space for significant government officers and managers at the departmental and project
expenditures outside investment for ‘direct targeting’, to levels so that adequate efforts would not have been made
create political support and for providing the bases for the to bring about the required coordination.
party in power to reward its vast numbers of field workers. Coordination always has a free rider aspect, and even
For the bureaucracy it provided a major avenue for expansion for governments this need not be false, unless consciously
and spread across sectors and regions not constrained by there is an agent whose primary task is to bring about the
the need for investments as they emerged out of the coordination. Or the positive externalities would have to
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 23

be correctly internalized through very large corporations, Public sector organizations that were better than others in
which presumably are integrated enough to garner these. expenditure management and efficient use of funds did not
The potential of very large projects, whose viability itself get more plan funds than others that were more wasteful.
depends upon the success of coordination, would go
unrealized if such organizational structures do not exist or ‘Achievement Equals Expenditure’
have been vitiated, even when they are taken up by the Processes may have even worked in a perverse manner to
state. The industrial and economic structures may still give more public money to poorly functioning organizations!
change and development (diversification) take place because Thus in the wake of structural adjustment, there was little
the public sector is investing, but at an unnecessary and central funding available to the National Thermal Power
additional cost. This is because the coordination risk and Corporation (NTPC) acclaimed as both an efficient
its lack of mitigation (failed coordination) works its way implementer of projects, and a manager of power businesses.
as large time and cost overruns. These would, of course, Instead large funds were still available to the National
slow down the growth, rates of the economy11. Hydro Power Corporation (NHPC) whose operational
efficiency and capacity in projects was nowhere near that
PERFORMANCE LINKAGE of NTPC. The logic was that ‘anyway NTPC would be able
to manage’ through market borrowings and internal
A major deficiency in public expenditure processes, that resources. There is not a sector or a field of funding where
has been there from the very beginning, is on the performance similar considerations did not hold. Under the cover of
dimension. If an authority/ministry/parastatal or state this approach lies a major failure in public expenditure
enterprise did poorly in a project or programme, then there management. Surprisingly, the idea that state funds are for
was little in the process that reduced its chance to get the weak, continues to have much circulation even today.
projects or programmes (expend money) in the next round; The analogy of the family is often quoted despite its
or made it expensive for that entity to do so. While the obvious irrelevance. A good part of public money even
devolved funds through the Finance Commission formula today maintains parts of the state organizations and arms
could not have had a performance link imposed by the of government including its productive apparatus,
central government, the Plan funds to the states and others irrespective of their contributions, need, or performance.
could easily have had performance linkage, which could It certainly contradicts the idea of public expenditure for
have positively affected the allocation and spending processes. the benefit of society! In this false idea the vehicle for
achievement of a task is being mistaken for the task.
A Major Failure
The only ‘performance linkage’, if one may consider it that No Learning from World Bank
way, may have been in putting forth projects and programmes
Despite the example of the World Bank whose lendings for
especially in the latter, when a certain component was to
projects were typically accompanied by close monitoring
come from the state. Many of the administratively and
and conditionalities relating to performance, there was no
fiscally weaker states not being able to make out the formal
attempt on the Planning Commission or Finance Ministry’s
proposal, or put in its share of contribution would have,
part to impose conditionalities relating to performance,
therefore, lost out in getting funds for projects and
pricing, etc. Had such measures evolved, the extremely
programmes from the central government. Poor project
poor performance of both projects and programmes could
implementation did not penalize the agency implementing
possibly have been avoided. The public expenditure system
the same. There were systematic differences between
could then have evolved in the direction of being ‘incentive
divisions of state Public Works Departments (PWDs)
compatible’. It is this lack of performance linkage in allocation
across the country in implementing highway projects but
of state funds that finally broke the back of the budget. No
the central ministry of road and surface transport, until
country could have borne a steady and system-wide cost
recently, never distinguished on that criteria between these
and time overrun in the range of 50 to 60 per cent on half
divisions. It was always the right of a certain state PWD
(virtually the entire public sector part) of its capital formation,
division, by virtue of its location, to oversee and maintain
and leakages in the same range or more out of its non-
a particular portion of the National Highway. Funds,
capital forming but programme-related expenditures, and
therefore, for National Highway Development were routed
not collapsed. Why has performance linkage been so difficult?
through these PWDs irrespective of their performance!
1. The Planning Commission in its expenditure
11 The relationship between cost and time overruns in public allocation and management aspect was entirely an extension
investments, and the growth rate of the economy is brought out in of the bureaucracy and therefore evaluation and examination
Section 5.1 by Sebastian Morris in this report. would simply have been broken down into particular tasks,
24 India Infrastructure Report 2003

ignoring their compositional aspect. In other words, there 5. There was incentive incompatibility in bundling
was no organ responsible and able to translate the overall the planning and project /programme roles together. Had
plan tasks for other organizations as their specific tasks the project role been carried out through an organization
and hold them responsible. This would have been important structured like an investment bank, the effectiveness of
because the total cost of non-performance of a part went projects and their implementation could have had some
beyond that part as we mentioned in the discussion on performance linkage. It is interesting that when the NTPC
coordination economies and contingent risks. used World Bank funds, it found the Bank’s conditionalities
2. Unlike a development bank, there is no possible useful in ‘disciplining’ the Indian government! It could
aggregate measure for the Planning Commission’s pressure the government to allow it to implement projects
performance as a whole that is meaningfully derived from quickly without the dysfunctional interference and
the subtasks, or projects’ and programmes’ performance. interventions by government departments. It also used the
For a development bank that does not have a monopolistic conditionalities to persuade the government to allow it
position in the economy the surplus, the total lendings, the rational prices for its output. The World Bank
recovery rate, and such other measures, are generated in conditionalities, even when its lending constituted a small
the natural course of the operations, and can be used for part of the total funds of projects, and even when guaranteed
measurement of its performance. The Planning by the government, put much weight in the hands of an
Commissions’ own money (capital or funds) are not at organization that was attempting to orient itself towards
stake. It is merely chanellizing public funds. Thus even its primary task. Thus the value of the World Bank assistance
when disbursing the budgetary support, had the loans/ or project funding may have been much more than that
grants from the government been routed through as the measured by its lending to development projects in India.
Commissions’, then certain appropriate measures of Had the same or similar procedures been adopted for
performance could have been generated. Thus deviations much of Plan Funds by the Commission especially from
from standard times and approved costs for projects could 1965 onwards, it is quite possible that things would have
have been one measure of the Planning Commissions’ been very different, and growth would have been much
performance. This could have been done at least when faster to unambiguously bring about the industrial
funds were rolled over as the productive enterprises it transformation in India. Growth in India was about 1.5
created were able to get an increasing portion of their per cent per annum slower than what it would otherwise
requirements from the markets and internal resources. have been due to the delays and cost overruns in public
3. Follow through in government bureaucracies to sector projects. A large part of the responsibility for the
moneys given is difficult, and the Planning Commission same should go to the Project Appraisal Division (PAD)
was no exception. Typically, governments take a great deal of the Planning Commission and the PIB. (Morris, 1987).
of time and spend much resources examining proposals
for spending but, once the money is given, there is little
ORGANIZATIONAL PROCESSES AND ACCOUNTABILITY
ability or motivation to follow through to ensure that the
primary purpose or task for the money has been achieved. While the political reasons for the poor state of public
The monitoring would be more in the form of the insistence expenditure accountability are recognized (but perhaps not
on periodic reports, or a completion certificate. These understood well enough), the bureaucratic and systemic
reports need not be actionable as management control forces that result in slack and waste are not admitted as
systems of corporations are, and could at best, be diagnostic. independent causal factors. Dilatory processes, very low
Most traditional government tasks like defence and general work loads on administrative staff, multiple objectives that
administration can only be measured in terms of expenditure. also tend to be ill defined, all these arise in part out of
So even in the case of projects and programmes it is easy the nature of the bureaucracy in India. The general belief
and ‘consistent’ to let the task be measured by expenditure, though is that political interference is the cause of
relative to allocations, even if they are contrary to the task administrative failure and inefficiency.
of adding to economic and productive capacity. Traditional There is virtually no discussion (contextualized to the
audit in government which is examination of ex-post specific social, political, and economic environment) of the
consistency with processes and rules could then continue government in India as an organization that is prone to
much as before. failure. Thus, the apparently innocuous system of reporting
4. Plan fund grants were not sought to be sharply to the Parliament imposed on the Public Sector Units
distinguished from devolved funds. So the idea of the (PSUs) have contributed a great deal to the dysfunctional
centre as a mere router of funds could have spilled over interface they have with the government. Their dysfunctional
on to the Planning Commission’s role. interface is the primary reason for the failure of the PSUs—
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 25

their lack of accountability and task orientation. This had had not discussed in the last IIR, and also review findings
been brought out at length in the IIR (2002). The more of the Expenditure Reforms Commission.
general phenomenon of sub-units of government, irrespective
of function or original design, to have very similar processes ERC Exposes Waste
and work practices—rule orientation to the point of losing
The government had in 1997 set up the Expenditure
sight of the task—is acute in India. Undue dependence on
Reforms Commission (ERC), which has now submitted its
leadership is another problem, Even when there is
various reports. The report pertaining to the Ministry of
commitment it is to the sub-tasks or to the functions and
sub-units rather than to the task as such. Urban Development and Poverty Alleviation12, is somewhat
more expansive and provides some measures of the waste
Preference for ‘Patch-work’ in government. Having approached the problem from the
financial angle, there are few, if any, discussions on the
Similarly, government procurement is also known to be very dysfunctionalities in the working of the ministry. The
problematic with no clear solution. The dysfunctional object, anyway, was expenditure reforms, as conventionally
relationship between the elected executive and the officers understood, and the Committee adopted the rather simple
is perhaps the most serious problem of all. We had argued approach of identifying and recommending the removal of
why responsibility embedment is difficult with a cadre- surplus manpower and expenditure. So large and obvious
based bureaucracy that is not under the control of the were the waste and surpluses that without much detailed
elected executive, especially at the lower levels of government. considerations it was possible for the Committee to
The political executive cannot promise task performance to recommend rather major downsizing. And in reading
his clients (the people) because he has little control over the
between the lines it was possible to gleam some of the
cadre and officials in general, and so there is little or no
crucial problems with governmental processes today.
scope for him to make political capital. That leaves him with
the option of corruption and graft as a pay off. With the
Ignoring the Limitations of Governments
passage of time only individuals with corruption and power
on their minds take to politics. Change has little chance The most glaring drawback is that there are too many
of coming from within the system. Only severe external schemes, and an inability to design these schemes in a
pressures would have a chance of leading to success. The manner that is coherent with the economic, social, and
system’s capacity and motivation to correct mistakes and political processes in society13. Widely recognized as an
distortions is weak, and ‘patch-work solutions’ are preferred. inappropriate mode are discretionary controls like quotas,
We had made these and related arguments in the last IIR, licences, and banns that were rampant in the Indian system
so there is no need to repeat them. We had also brought till the economic reform of the 1990s. Similarly, with
out the deep-seated reasons for a large part of the regard to the design of programmes and schemes of the
misgovernance and corruption—absurd policies, control Planning Commission and central ministries, is the
and subsidization measures and extension targets for assumption that every problem14 can be overcome through
governments. With better design of policy, especially subsidy direct administrative action. Typically,the assumption has
delivery mechanisms, and with incentive compatible been that a subsidy given to beneficiaries identified
structures for the same, many problems can be overcome. continually, a low interest loan, or the special allocation
Hence we had claimed that having the right policy and legal of an input considered as scarce or necessary for starting
framework would amount to attempting change with the an economic activity could be provided by the government,
advantage of acting ‘at a leverage point’ for change. We had directly to the intended beneficiary to solve the problem.
suggested that organizationally another crucial point of change Besides the incoherence with markets and the economy
is to make all top bureaucratic posts competitive, so that there was little or no recognition of the constraints that
experts outside the cadres could come in with new ideas emerge from the nature of bureaucracies that are inherently
and lateral thinking. Additionally, we had also argued that ill designed to perform complex ‘enterprise’ tasks.
the key to embedment of responsibility and accountability
of local bodies, is to make the salaried employees truly 12 For a more detailed review of this report see Section 5.3 by
accountable to the elected executive, by changing the working Biju Varkkey.
13 One aspect of this inadequacy, viz. the market-unfriendly
rules, and reporting relationship, rather than continuing
ways of control by the state, has been widely commented upon now
with the unbroken chain of command within the bureaucracy.
for over two decades.
These issues have an obvious and direct bearing on 14 Be it of poverty, unemployment, underdeveloped skills,
public expenditure accountability. Rather than restate the illiteracy, lack of education or nutrition, women’s ill health,
obvious, we will cover the ground of public procurement, marketing by petty producers, underdevelopment technology, social
and the lack of decentralization in government, which we deprivation or exclusion.
26 India Infrastructure Report 2003

The greater the task the more the number of posts and been done at the lower levels’, or which require the attention
the deployment, has been a standard assumption of most of multiple functionaries for their performance. Victims
bureaucracies. This in India has created a fast growing and senior civil servants then end up blaming the juniors
bureaucracy, that until the 1990s grew at rates faster than and lower levels of the bureaucracy. ‘Lower-down’ staff can,
the overall growth of the labour force in India. The problem of course, blame everything on ‘lack of powers’. The lack
of integration, of interdepartmental incongruity or conflict, of responsibility embedment is enhanced by the tendency
of duplication, etc. are only now being seriously discussed to have committees take decisions. Committees which
to find solutions15. disperse responsibility horizontally obfuscate the same.
The lack of vertical interaction in the committee form, or
Cadres Create Dysfunctional Pressures the splitting of a task into various processes, and the lack
Additionally, cadre pressures create the demand for too of decentralization results in little or no accountability in
many posts. Cadres have the dysfunctionality of being government despite hierarchical systems.
difficult to hold accountable to the executive. This aspect
had been discussed in the IIR 2002. The existence of Dysfunctional Oversight
multiple cadres creates a very significant problem. Thus The poor performance of various projects, schemes, and
there are the Indian Administrative Services (IAS), Indian programmes have in turn led to the creation of monitoring
Police Services (IPS), Indian Revenue Services (IRS), Indian cells and sub-organizations within the government. Their
Ordnance Factories Services (IOFS), Indian Supply Services systems and procedures are no different from the rest of
(ISS), etc. While the IPS and specialized services like the government and typically do not have the independence
Indian Audit and Accounts Services (IAAS), have meaning from the line officers. Instead of performance of this task,
in being separate, many others like the IAS, IOFS, Indian the task itself has got modified as ‘reporting’. It has been
Economic Services (IES) and ISS are not particularly different ritualized and become an aspect of misgovernance. This
in terms of the tasks the officer is called upon to perform. was true of the Department of Programme Implementation
But the separate identities create a strong pressure to continue (DPI). The periodic examination of government
within the government activities for which these cadres organizations and processes can itself get ritualized and
were created to provide the space for the growth of the bureaucratized to a point, so that it gets nullified. Then
cadre. The Ordnance Factories are top heavy because officers mere formal changes are recommended, when the need is
of the IOFS would otherwise not have had options. The for major overhaul, decentralization and incentive compatible
same is true of the Indian Supply Services. Their impact systems, simplification of the task, and ascription of
on overall employment growth, wage, salary, and general responsibility. Thus even the ERC whose reports are a great
administration expenses are severe. No wonder then that improvement over earlier reports is itself a victim of the
the ERC in its report on the Ministry of Urban Development approach that does not recognize the deep-seated nature of
and Poverty Alleviation reports huge ‘surplus’ of posts. the problems of the government in India.
Little Delegation Reform recommendations too surprisingly do not
recognize the constrains on governments, or what it can
Too little delegation within the government is one of the and cannot do. Governmental structure does not allow the
reasons for the massive over-manning. True delegation performance of complex or ill-defined tasks. Part of the
would, at the top, imply reduced power to accommodate reason for the committees, and the little or no delegation
dysfunctional tasks that could be thrust upon the bureaucracy lie in the poor design of schemes and programmes. Attempts
by corrupt politicians and others. Delegation implies that to do the impossible such as implement a price-based
there is better responsibility embedment since then the subsidization with no leakages, or ensure that despite low
tasks have greater coherence with the ability and power prices for ‘priority’ goods there is no under-investment in
of the person/position responsible for the same. When the same, create unadministrable situations. Then the task
there is little delegation then at the top there is the absolution itself gets displaced to suit the bureaucratic convenience.
of responsibility of ‘small tasks’ which should anyway have When rules cannot give direction, there is the natural
tendency to decide within the `security of a committee.’
15The depth of the morass within the Central Public Works The hard task of working against markets rather than with
Department (CPWD) is difficult to imagine. The contract value per them, have over the long period, especially from 1965,
man month that the department handles is a mere Rs 0.5 lakh when onwards, made the battle against rents hopeless. These,
its norm (itself a highly watered down one) was Rs 5 lakhs. Private
builders and others securing construction services do at least Rs 10
more than any inherent characteristic of Indian culture or
lakhs per man month. Draftsmen in the department made 1.5 the politics, have tended to corrupt the administration and
drawings per month against the norm of 10 per man month! render its processes and functioning wasteful.
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 27

Public Procurement in India and the Creation of in India. Blacklisting is vitiated by the legal loophole that
Market Failure allows the same person to operate multiple and ‘benami’
firms, and the formal identification of the bidder, as a
We had in a different context16 argued that the unnaturally
particular firm, being allowed to be hidder. Therefore
large space for shoddy goods in the country arises from
bringing in private information on the evaluation table,
the nature of the government’s procurement processes.
especially about the true identity of the bidder and his past
Government procurement is based on the belief that contracts
performance, into the evaluation process can act as a
can be complete, and the lowest price is the best way at
major determinant against wilful mis-performance, provided
which to purchase, irrespective of the nature of the product
the same is done transparently.
or the service. Low price does not automatically translate
itself into lowest costs to the procurer and herein lies one
of the major sources of waste in government expenditure. BUDGETING
As more aspects of the product are discovered, government
agencies tend to include them in the specifications on the As mentioned earlier, the expenditures incurred by a
contract, but the contract can never be complete, since in government have the dimension of location/ and sector of
any complex product or service there is functionality to the economic/ social activity. They additionally have the
whole that cannot be so easily specified and/or verified. dimension of the organizational form and the item type.
Then opportunities exist for rents, through formal or ritual Thus an item of expenditure could be spent in Gujarat
adherence to the specifications, but in the actual supply of (location), on the chemical industry (sector) by a central
poor quality or less quantity of the service or product. The government public sector enterprise (organization) on wages
usual bureaucratic response to such corruption in India has and salaries (item). Additionally, it could have the purpose
been to introduce even more sequential processes and to of supporting R&D (an activity) and may have been granted
involve many more officers laterally placed in the decision by the Department of Science and Technology (allocative
process. This could actually allow rents to continue, despite ministry or the department of the government), as part of
the (formal) adherence to the processes. Responsibility the Plan Expenditure.
displacement occurs. The huge firm side costs which these
processes then impose, result in good firms abandoning the Plan and Non-plan Expenditures
queue to sell to the public authority. The public authority The economic and functional classification of the budget
then sees only firms that are unscrupulous and have is really a two dimensional classification over the item
developed ways to overcome the costs of going through (economic aspect) and the purpose cum authority (the
cumbersome processes through corruption and influence. functional classification). Budgets with both dimensions
Thus the administrative (state) failure in inappropriate being simultaneously shown are of great value in analysis.
procurement breeds market failure and that combination The other dimensions are implicit in the disaggregation
imposes large costs on the economy. Beyond lowest prices by territory and around the entity making the expense.
there are interesting methods that can reduce the failure These dimensions are lost in the process of aggregation
and give incentives to losing firms to monitor the process. so that, for the nation as a whole, only the economic and
Thus performance clauses, performance guarantees, functional dimensions remain. An aspect of the purpose
specified evaluation process, independent certification though in terms of Plan and non-Plan, is also available.
engineers, revelation of names and identities of bidders This classification came about with the Planning that was
post contract, are just a few of the methods that could be put in place in the post-independence period. Plan funds
adopted. There is much that theoretical insights from the are those that emerge out of the approved Plan as budgetary
contracting and purchase literature can contribute17. support for the Plan. They would have been originally
whetted and approved by the Planning Commission18.
Private Information Is Important
Thus the funds required to set up a technical institute
Blacklisting of poorly performing firms which is part of would come from Plan funds, when such an institute is
any procurement process, even the simplest, is problematic part of the Plan. Once the Plan funds have been expended,
and the institute has been built, the further expenditures
16 In discussing government purchases of small scale industry
products, and the vendor development policies of many state-owned
18 In the period before redistributive programmes such as the
enterprises, we had brought out the dynamic nature of state failure.
See Morris (2001). Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP) etc. came into
17 For a discussion of the same and their extension to the case being, that is, in the period up to 1965, they were largely derived
of public procurement (by governments), see Section 4.2 by Ajay of the Plan model, essentially from intersectoral and growth
Pandey in this report. considerations.
28 India Infrastructure Report 2003

(unless incorporated into the Plan again) would be out of Developmental Expenditure
non-Plan expenditure. The same is true for programmes
Another dimension of government expenditure is in the
that are part of the Plan. Commentators on government
developmental, non-developmental categorization. It is
expenditure patterns have generally decried the decline in
assumed that expenditures on all economic and social
Plan expenditures, as the ratio of Plan to total government
services and on certain programmes will lead to
expenditures have declined. But this may not be entirely
development, and hence, are categorized as developmental.
justified. To the extent that many of the sop programmes
Non-developmental concerns the traditional functions of
are planned but have vast leakages, Plan expenditures could
state—police, defence, interest payments, pensions, and
be quite wasteful when they largely generate rents. Even
food subsidy. Thus many of the sop programmes and some
if rents are not generated, but the design of the programme
producer subsidies are categorized as developmental. The
is ineffective or wasteful, the Plan expenditure as such need
decline in the share of developmental expenditures have
not always be a good thing.
also been bemoaned in academic discussions but there is
But in the sense that there is little discretion in Plan
little basis for the same given the poor efficacy and efficiency
funds spending, decline in the proportion of Plan expenditure
in government expenditures. Equally important is the failure
is indicative of the decline of planning, and increase in
of the state in its vital state functions which no other
the discretionary part of government expenditure.
entities can perform. This is not unrelated to the
underfunding in crucial activities such as the conduct of
Capital Expenditures in the Plan
justice and the operations of the police force. Herein poor
A larger proportion of Plan expenditure (than of non-Plan) performance has imposed vast transactions cost on the
is capital expenditures, and these are seen as having value. economy. Thus, there is really little meaning in discussions
Despite the vast delays and cost overruns, which increase that infer quality of government expenditures purely on
the waste in capital expenditures, and the misdirection of account of share of developmental expenditure.
significant amount of capital formation, it is still true that
‘at the end of day there is usually a “productive” asset19’. Constitutional Transfers
Contrarily revenue expenditures could include maintenance
Transfers from the central government constitute another
expenditure of capital works. The functionality of physical
significant item. Transfers are largely determined by the
capital assets in a transforming economy is without doubt,
finance commissions and their formula /method and criteria
except when there are gross violations of allocative
have generally allowed transfers to state governments in a
efficiency20. This is not to deny the value of human capital
transparent way. The possible vitiation at this level is small
formation. In most areas of human capital formation except,
though the dysfunctionalities or waste would be a feature
perhaps, education, the programmes and expenditure
at the level of spending by the state governments. The same
processes do not result in any significant gain—the so-
can be said of transfers from state governments to local
called special employment schemes, sop schemes such as
bodies. The recommendations of the various state finance
the Prime Minister’s Rozgar Yojna (PMRY), etc., are no
commissions (SFCs) following Constitutional Amendments
doubt part of such waste, arising out of improper spending.
73 and 74, and further developments in decentralization
In education, though, spending on both revenue and capital
have as yet to be institutionalized. In many states the SFCs
result in direct benefits, subject, of course, to the off-item
recommendations have to be notified. On state transfers
leakages, and the efficiency of the education system in
the principal issues relate to the proportion of non-
most parts of the country21. It is debatable whether in
discretionary transfers that is, those that arise out of
areas like Bihar, with near total state failure, even spending
constitutional process—and the ad hoc support that has
on education would result in positive benefits.
increased over the 1980s and the 1990s. The FC-based
19 In Bihar, where the system has systematically vitiated the transfers have been robust to changes in government, and
difference between capital and revenue expenditures to misreport to different parties existing at the state and central levels.
expenditures, a significant part of which would be rents, this cannot So in transfers the mechanisms and criteria as outlined in
be said at all. the FC reports and adopted would be the central basis.
20 These have taken place. An example would be the setting up
Perversities are in the design of the devolution formula.
of the central business district of New Bombay with an occupancy
of 10–12 per cent close to 15 years after construction! Or gauge
conversion with traffic load less than before. Competition for Discretionary Funds
21 For a state’s presentation of the trends and patterns in social
Ad hoc grants are another matter. They, no doubt, have
expenditures see Section 6.2 by Mahendra Dev; and for the
discussions and thinking that precede the Central Budget see Section functionality in disaster relief and in urgent expenditure
6.3, also by Mahendra Dev. requirements which are difficult to foresee. They are not
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 29

tied to programmes and are not as deeply embedded in far greater, and he does not have to go through the usual
the expenditure process as the spending out of Plan funds. processes of justification and ritual for the projects that
There is much competition for these funds. In the best he initiates. It is interesting that despite the small size of
of cases these funds can be crucial for recovery out of just about a crore per MP, a few MPs have been able to
disasters, and there is scope for making political capital use the same for initiating significant projects to garner
for the party of the day to claim credit in usage of these much political capital without violating processes and
funds. More importantly, they can be more quickly spent creating rents. These not too numerous examples illustrate
until the bureaucratic processes finally catch up to introduce the potential that is there for the political and economic
delays and the formal processes. At worst, they are seen system to bootstrap out of the mess it is in currently.
as free and discretionary transfers, constituting a way of Administrative reform that cuts wasteful ritual, vestigial
favouring the government of the state. State governments processes derived out of past plans and needs now defunct,
generally tend to exaggerate the damage and destruction or out of programmes over the design of which nobody
in order to gain more central funds. seems to have any control is the need of the hour. Such
Once the disbursement process begins there would be reform would create the space for performance of the
the reverse tendency to assess the losses more realistically. politician and for appropriation of the same as political
As time passes and the real—unpublicized or uninfluential— capital. Corruption can then reduce considerably.
victims’ turn comes, the purse would inevitably tighten, as
the bureaucratic processes would have by then caught up. THE CENTRAL BUDGET AND TRANSPARENCY
Given that much of government expenditure is caught in
an interpenetrating quagmire of planning allocation and The annual budget of the central government attracts
disbursal processes, audit and ritual impact assessment, attention as no other economic event does. The presentation
the distance between the initiating politician or group and of the budget has become a ritual, a major media event
the realization of the objective for the spending is usually that lasts for days, and details are discussed and commented
so disjointed, that there is little scope for identification upon in the media in innumerable groups and meetings
and, hence, of deriving credit for good public actions. that follow. The tax side of the budget receives a lot of
Shorter political cycles (or life of elected officials and attention. Citizens and associations try to calculate their
politicians) and the more distant levers for initiating disposable incomes and gross revenues. The market also
expenditures, and the fact that much of it is already derived reacts, although, since the major announcements may have
out of plans and programmes, has resulted in much attention been anticipated, the reaction is spread over a longer
and competition for the little ‘open’ funds that exist. period. Since the reform process began, the fiscal deficit
The literature too has been critical of the rise in ad hoc has become a household term. Surprisingly, despite all the
expenditures. To the extent that through these allocations limelight, the expenditure side is rarely discussed except
particular governments in states are favoured or in rather simplistic ways that may amount to mere
discriminated, it is a creeping dysfunctionality. But they verbalization of the figures. The diagnoses of expenditures
do have the merit of being expended quickly without the are very rudimentary at best.
delays and ritual associated with regular government
expenditures. Only with reference to the ideal process of Bundling with Policy Announcements
project and programme expenditure could this distinction
The budget comes bundled along with major and minor
be maintained. It is only in capital expenditures on projects
policy announcements, as well as announcements of
and social expenditures in areas with vast externalities like
programmes for spending, subsidy and concessional credit,
education and health or highly constrained infrastructure,
of funds to support an activity, or the setting up of institutions
(despite all the weaknesses of the state) that one can say
and organizations. These proposals when they are new draw
that money spent therein is better than money spent
some attention, but it is the ‘overall thrust of the budget’
elsewhere. The by far more important problem of the
that hogs the limelight. Thus the budget is presumed to be
efficacy and efficiency of government expenditure has been
developmental if the outlays on social expenditures especially
typically downplayed.
education, or on rural development go up significantly. Or
it is considered as pro poor if subsidies are maintained and
MP’s Special Funds
administered prices do not rise. The large number of
There is much attention and expectation with regard to administered prices on public services and other products
the special funds which the Members of Parliament (MPs) like energy which are heavily taxed makes the budget
can disburse for their constituencies. This is not surprising proposals a major influence on prices. The fact that the
since there are ‘open’ funds. Here the MP’s discretion is economy has liberalized a great deal, and the role of taxes
30 India Infrastructure Report 2003

and administered prices have come down22 implies that fiscal deficit, in a meaningful way. Such analysis is standard
the budget should not be as dominant as it used to be. and routine, in management accounting for control and
Other major economic events such as the busy and lean budgeting in large firms. Herein, the deviation of costs
season credit policy announcements of the Reserve Bank from budgeted costs or of total sales from its target would
of India (RBI), or the stance of monetary policy, have in be routinely broken down into variances or factors for
reality become far more important than the budget in better understanding and control.
determining the course of the economy, but do not attract It would then be possible to differentiate between lack
the attention that the budget does. In Parliament despite of achievement of expenditure or the fiscal deficit, targets
the discussions (which tend to be polemical) there is little that arise because of regime shifts, and that due to non-
diagnoses of the budget, and in-voice voting on the strength realization of growth targets for example. More generally
of the majority of the government in the Lower House the ex-post diagnoses and holding the government to account
budget is passed. There are almost no discussions on the would be feasible, since the regime that the government
deviations of the actuals from the budget proposals of the set out to reach and the realized regimes could be inferred.
previous years and the reasons for the same. It is only now
that the data has begun to be presented to allow even a ‘Off-Budget’ Items
rudimentary discussion on this most vital aspect of fiscal
Similarly, the changes in the framework or the changes in
performance, and expenditure accountability.
the parameters of the model, brought about by the structural
changes in the economy would have to be mentioned and
Need for a Budget Model
explained whenever these are accommodated. When final
The focus on the fiscal deficit by the financial institutions outlays are announced, the basis of their allocation, and
and the investing community abroad has recently begun the macro variable with which the item in question is
to draw attention to expenditures and to the prospect of expected to have a relationship if any, would have to be
the government being able to meet its fiscal deficit targets. made explicit. For example, the introduction of a new
Attempts are made to make sense of past slippages, credit subsidy for small industries, would result in the
projecting the trends in the slippage onto the future, so expenditure on that count to be expected to be related to
that the ‘realistic’ likely fiscal deficit can be inferred. Such the capital formation in small firms.In other words the
discussions are common in academic and financial circles. ‘budget-makers’ need to share their assumptions, beliefs,
Unfortunately, any really meaningful discussion is precluded and expenditure frameworks. The Committee on Fiscal
because the budget rarely reveals the growth (and inflation) Transparency23 makes similar observations.
assumptions (targets) that have been made. Similarly, the Off-budget items like outstanding guarantees, contingent
relevant sub-sector growth and targets (assumptions) are liabilities and their details, with appropriate tabulations,
not explicit—exports, imports, industrial, and agricultural would help to focus the legislature’s attention on such items
growth. It is high time (and eminently feasible) to make which have typically been used by governments (the
the budget process and reporting truly transparent, and executive) to get over the need to have the authorization
allow meaningful discussion to take place. Thus presentation of the legislature.
of a model of the economy of the principal items of the
budget (let us say of 10 major items on the revenue and
REVIEWING THE TRENDS IN EXPENDITURE
expenditure side) is the starting point. The presentation
would have to separate the framework, or the model, from Interest payments and debt servicing show the fastest rise.
the estimates of the parameters or the structural variables See Fig. 2.1.1. Budgetary subsidies have had a slower
used, and the assumed growth rates of the economy of real growth largely because export subsidies were eliminated
gross domestic product (GDP), prices, exports, imports, over the period up to 1992–3. Since then subsidies have
etc. Forecasts/assumptions regarding key variables such as grown rapidly. Another dampener has been the removal
interest rates, exchange rates, would also have to be explicitly of universal food subsidies as ‘better’ targeting of the same
revealed. was attempted. Social service expenditures show a somewhat
With this information it becomes possible to judge the slower growth. See Fig.2.1.2.
‘performance’ of the government at least in terms of it
being able to achieve its budgetary targets, including the 23 B1 (2002), ‘Report of the Standing Committee on
International Financial Standards and Code’, under the chairmanship
22Nevertheless, the informal influence of government on PSUs of Y.V. Reddy, Deputy Governor, RBI. The same has been reviewed
and other enterprises keeps the deviation from economic prices in this report in Box ‘Fiscal Transparency and India’ in Section 4.1
large in some sectors. by Ajay Pandey.
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 31

Fig 2.1.1 Index of Plan and Other Expenditure of the


Fig. 2.1.3 Index of Revenue and Other Central Government
Central Government at Current Prices (1991–2 = 100)
Expenditure at Current Prices (1991–2 = 100)

Wide Differences largest relative decline. See Fig. 2.1.3. The same is true
of total capital Plan expenditures. Capital expenditures
The adjustments of expenditure on account of Plan have fallen as a proportion of Plan expenditure. See Fig.
expenditure were far more significant than on non-Plan. 2.1.4. Despite all odds the primary deficit has been under
When viewed as capital or revenue, capital has shown the control having fallen to less than 1 per cent.

Fig. 2.1.2 Index of Economic Services and Expenditure


of the Central Govt. at Current Prices (1991–2 = 100) Fig 2.1.4 Ratio of Certain Items of Expenditure
32 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Fig. 2.1.5 Deficits of the Central Government and Interest Fig. 2.1.6 Detrend of Log of GCF in Public and Private
Payments to GDP at Market Prices Sectors (GCF at current prices deflated by the GDP
deflator)
The revenue deficit continues to remain high at around in the Postal Department arise on account of salaries and
3.5 per cent of GDP despite the fall in the primary fiscal wages. The rise in the postal deficit would mirror the rise
deficit. This is largely because of interest payments which in expenditures on wages and salaries of the government
has risen from 4 per cent of GDP to about 4.5 per cent as a whole. Prices of postal services rose but not on main
of GDP. See Fig. 2.1.5. As a proportion of GDP non- items like inland letters and postcards. Pension payments
interest revenue expenditures have not risen. Debt service too show a sharp rise from 1997–8 onwards. Grants to
has kept pace with interest payments because government states have risen steeply over the last three years. These
has had to reroll cheaper debt taken earlier with more as we know have been made to the states to support their
expensive debt, as the SLRs on banks were sought to be implementation of the Fifth Pay Commission Award, and
reduced in a situation of tight monetary policy24. Non- to meet their rising deficits as they too began to face the
plan expenditures have grown faster than Plan expenditures. problem of rising interest rates.
See Fig. 2.1.1. This in itself is considered as resulting in
poor ‘quality’ of the fiscal deficit. However, because a large Plan Expenditure and Transfers
part of Plan expenditures have leakages and waste and
capital plan expenditures involve vast cost and time overruns, From Fig. 2.1.3 notice also that at current prices, there
from the point of view of reduction of waste and rents this is a sharp decline in capital expenditures from 1998–9
cannot always be claimed as poor quality of adjustment. onwards. Thus the attempt to continue to reduce the fiscal
deficit has also been marked by sharp slow down in capital
Fifth Pay Commission Award expenditures. Since private investments have not shown
any significant rise from that year either, the demand
The postal deficit rose from around Rs 243 crores in depressionary effect and the brake on the growth of capacity
1991–2 to around Rs 1440 crores in 2001–2, to become output that this imposes is obvious. Fig. 2.1.4 tells us that
an important item of government expenditure. The sharp the share of capital expenditure in the Plan expenditure
rise since 1996–7 is reflective of the wage and salary of the centre has gone down sharply. This precipitous fall
increases on account of the implementation of the Fifth
from a level close to 50 per cent to around 35 per cent
Pay Commission Award, since much of the expenditures
means that capital formation (even if of the wasteful variety)
24 Since the nominal interest rate has begun to fall, this has is down. The central assistance to the states’ overall plan
begun to reverse. expenditures which had been squeezed over the period
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 33

when the centre itself had made the adjustment (1991–2


to 1996–7), recovered but not fully, from 1997–8 onwards.
Share of central Assistance in Plan expenditure of the
centre had grown very slowly.

Private Capital Takes Over


From Fig. 2.1.6, which gives the detrend of the log of real
gross capital formation (GCF), as a whole and in the public
and private sectors, we see that the period of recovery of
the 1980s was accompanied by a revival of public investments
in the mid-1970s, which went back to the average growth
rate for the period (1950–1 to 2000–1) till 1986–7, after
which the growth rate had slowed down considerably. In
the 1990s the budgetary squeeze on capital expenditures
resulted in the slow down continuing and deepening. Private
investment revival is seen from the early 1980s which
continued up to 1995–6 (very sharply from 1992–3), after
which it has slowed down. Fig. 2.1.7 brings out the shares
of the private sector (the economy other than the public
sector) GCF, and of GCF in the economy. The latter is
at constant prices, and the former ratio at current prices.
Observe that the high growth in the 1980s was also a Fig. 2.1.8 Share of Public Administration and Defence in
period of high rates of investment, and by rising share of GDP at 1993–4 Prices
private investments. Post stabilization the investment rate
rose sharply to reach a level of 29 per cent of GDP! The Recession
rise encompassed the foreign and the domestic, including
This is the point that we had brought out in the IIR
the unregistered sector. After 1995–6 it collapsed sharply
2002, and as early as in 1997 we had called attention
remaining stagnant from that point onwards.
to this stagnation in private investments. (Morris,
1997)25. There is still no recovery of private or public
investments. The latter as much as in 1997–8, still awaits
the regulatory and policy clarity to enter into areas like
power, water, and urban services. Only in roads and
telecom has that clarity come26.

Fifth Pay Commission ‘Boosts’ GDP


Only services have grown, though a significant part of the
growth have access out of the Fifth Pay Commission
Award, which has steeply increased the GDP on account
of Public Administration and Defence. See Fig. 2.1.8,
which brings out the share of Public Administration and

25 The point then made remains valid even now: The high
growth of the 1990s, till about 1996–7, had three very important
causes (i) higher growth of exports at 20 per cent per annum in
dollar terms from 1993–4 onwards for four years; (ii) better
agricultural performance at 34 per cent per annum; (iii) reviewing
private investments which more than covered the fall in public
investments, and brought in an additional efficiency factor. Since
1997–8 the exports declined due to the exchange rate getting out
Fig. 2.1.7 Ratio of Real GCF to GDPFC at 1993–4 of line. The exchange rate still awaits correction.
26 Manufacturing has little space any more for private capital
Prices and of GCF in the Private Sector to All
GCF at Current Prices investments.
34 India Infrastructure Report 2003

monetary adjustments is over. Private investment is caught


in a quagmire of regulatory and policy anomie, and that
too needs correction. Otherwise the fiscal boost would
have to bring back public investments in a major way.
A more ambitious policy of money growth (interest-rate
targeting mentioned earlier) that lowers the nominal interest
rate and spurs growth (even if today it has to be kicked
off by public expenditures) can actually reduce the fiscal
deficit. It would work through high GDP growth, and
through higher growth on the revenue side; since the
elasticity of government revenue with industrial rather than
overall GDP growth is very high.27 Further expenditure
cutting to reduce the fiscal deficit, is not an alternative at
this juncture, since any politically feasible cuts on non-
interest revenue expenditures would be too small to do
anything worthwhile and would instead affect GDP growth
through the expenditure multiplier side. Cutting of
expenditure to bring down the primary fiscal deficit would
have to await major structural reform including significant
privatization, and regulatory and policy clarity in investment
Fig. 2.1.9 Detrend of Log of Macro Aggregates heavy sectors such as power and water28, that would
(1950–1 to 2000–1) guarantee further buoyancy in private investment. See
Boxes 2.1.1 and 2.1.2 for why reform efforts that tend to
Defence in the tertiary sector and shows a sharp rise in bring about efficiency and reduce waste or cut public
the Award. See also Fig. 2.1.9. It brings out the detrended expenditures have to worry about the demand side and be
series (of the log of real values) of GDP in the major prepared to actively bring about private investments.
sectors of the economy. Observe the ‘Hindu period’ 1965–
9 during which all segments of the economy grew more
slowly than during the period as a whole. Negative slopes,
SUMMARY
if one ignores the short period variations, imply slower The challenge of public expenditure accountability in
than average of growth. The economy turned in 1979 and developing democracies is greater than in other societies
the rapid growth of the 1980s was maintained into the that are already developed or have chosen to grow without
1990s till 1995–6, with the interruption during the firm commitment to democratic political processes.
stabilization interlude. Since 1995–6, very clearly there is Competing ideologies in post-independent India have led
a recession on account of both the slowing down of the to increase in ‘off-budget’ or non-voted expenditures. Many
agricultural (primary) sector and manufacturing; while GDP
of these expenditures are initiated in the name of the poor,
maintains its trend on account of the services sector’s more
but actually benefit many others than the poor. In India,
rapid growth. This as mentioned before is in a large
just before the reforms of the 1990s, there was hardly any
measure due to the growth in Public Administration and
group which did not enjoy some benefit as a result of state
Defence.
controls and distortionary policies, while the economy as
The fiscal deficit continues to be large because the
a whole bore the costs. The vested interests of such
elasticity of taxes and revenues is largest with respect to
government expenditure are an unintended consequence
manufacturing which has all but collapsed, thanks to the
of past policy errors.
monetary and fiscal conservation. The monetary
Large amount of government expenditure on programmes
conservatism is evident in the declining ratios of the
of the ‘Garibi Hatao’ variety must be seen as creating the
monetized part of the fiscal deficit, and the slow growth
space for significant government expenditures outside
of money supply especially since 1995–6. Real money
supply growth has gone up over the same period, as 27 We had made the same point in the IIR 2002, and
inflation reached very low levels, without giving a boost
developments since then have only further strengthened the logic of
to the economy. So now the situation is vintage keynesian, this alternative strategy outlined here.
that would require a fiscal boost, for the economy to 28 We had made this point in the last IIR, and the matter has
revive. As mentioned in this report, the time for mere become even more urgent today.
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 35

Box 2.1.1
Structural Reform, Government Expenditure, and Macroeconomic Policy

The waste in government expenditure in India is visible enough for all to recognize and admit it as a major problem. Even those
politicians who actively initiate wasteful expenditures in the garb of public services or some other laudable objective implicitly
admit to the waste inherent in most government expenditure when they themselves oppose similar acts by competing politicians;
typically when out of power. The more general ‘mai-bap’ view of the ‘sarkar’ is a reflection of the fact that the society itself has
been deeply affected by government expenditures and the spoils inherent in the same.
A good starting point to understand the role of government expenditure in the context of rents and waste, is the idea of
‘directly unproductive activity’—a term due to Jagdish Bhagwati. The sudden appearance of renta opportunity in an economy
(for example, due to licensing), would result in windfall gains to the parties able to get the licences. But soon enough if this
and similar other opportunities persist, the competition for the licences (rents) emerges. The rent-seeking activities result in people
‘working’ to earn rents, and such activities grow until the returns in working for rents itself becomes equal to the ‘normal’ returns
in productive businesses, adjusted, of course, for the differences in the risk. Such activities would result in agents and others trying
to influence bureaucrats and decision-makers. Bribes, then, slowly become more generalized, as even petty officials are able to
raise impediments to economic activity. These activities which are avoidable and not necessary to production or consumption
are obviously ‘unproductive’. This is not to suggest that they do not generate incomes. They do, as, for instance, for a typist
or a lawyer hired by an agent who works to get licences or permissions or the employees of a company working in the department
that interfaces with the government to get things done.
Rents and Waste
In other words the rent opportunity, when it stays long enough, converts what was a pure transfer from the people /consumer/
or government to an income generation and earning activity. Therefore, consumption, income distribution, and employment and
production patterns are affected. A significant part of the economy then has either supply or demand linkage with the points
of activities that generates rent. But it is impossible to extricate the one part from the other. Very humble activities, personal
services, clerical work, etc. could actually result out of the competition for rents. The entire economy in its occupational,
production, and consumption pattern is deeply affected by rents.
Waste, Rents, and Transactions Cost
The line between rents and the economic activities of the government, and the genuine transactions cost that any economy incurs
is not very clear cut especially when an empirical estimation of the two are sought. Wallis and Douglass (1996) estimate that some
40 to 50 per cent of US GDP arise out of transactions cost! Not all of this is unavoidable, and the existence of rents cannot be
ruled out. Many would agree that a significant part of the income that arises in the practice of law in the US is really nothing
but returns to the avoidable complexities in the law and the barriers to entry in the legal profession. Others may argue that the
large costs of supporting a thriving legal profession in the US is a necessary price to pay for a vibrant democracy. The unproductive
activities and waste in government expenditures in India, nor the rents and the activities spawned by these can be seen as ‘transactions
cost’ of the economy because implicit in the idea of transactions cost is the notion that in some sense they are unavoidable. b
Reduction in Waste Can be Demand Depressionary
The need to eliminate or reduce wasteful government expenditure and rents is well accepted. But it is often not realized that
their elimination or reduction suddenly could have macroeconomic effects working via the expenditure multiplier. A sudden
elimination of rents that were being earned (because of competition) would in the first instance increase the incomes of the
producers or consumers by the amount of the rent. It is not certain that the spending out of this income (both investment and
consumption) is going to be as large as the spending that took place earlier out of the same when the rent existed and was earnedc.
The result, therefore, on the demand side of wasteful government expenditure, may well be depressionary! Reformers are unaware
of this demand-side effect of large systemic improvements in efficiency that result from the elimination or vast reduction in
inefficiency. The same is true when public expenditure is reduced to make room for private expenditures. When, of course, reform
is accompanied by increases in private spending, especially on account of investments, resulting in the augmentation of both
physical and human capital in such a way that the total (autonomous) spending does not decline, then the effect on the economy
a Rents not in the sense of extra returns to genuinely scarce resources like land and particular non-duplicable skills, but of rents as return
to administrative and other powers and arising out of barriers in the decision-making process.
b This is not to deny that in the very long term when the laws of the land and the institutional processes themselves can change, these can
be considered at least in part as avoidable.
c As rents decline or as wasteful government expenditure declines following a period of reform there would be some changes in the consumption
pattern, since the kind of incomes generated by the rents and wasteful expenditures and their immediate multiplier spendings need not remain
the same as spending out out of sudden rise in incomes of consumers and producers. But this is expected to be a minor effect if adequate levels
of spending are kept up, but rising overall investment rates. It is their purpose that change dramatically. Thus a clerk or a peon employed in
a ‘fixer’s’ office is wasteful but in a factory is productive, and the spending pattern of both need not be very different.
36 India Infrastructure Report 2003

would be to improve the sustainable growth rates. The point that we are making is that the expected rise in private investment
and expenditure cannot always be assumed to be automaticd. Only a hard headed classical economist will be able to wish away
the problem, by denying the autonomous role of aggregate demand in determining the level of output of the economy. Many
reform efforts have faltered or had to be given up, as when the slowdown brought on by expenditure reduction, did not change
into a healthy recovery because nothing else was done to keep up the trends in autonomous and exogenous expenditures. The
fact that most reform efforts have been pushed by economists and policy-makers of a conservative hue has meant that depressionary
pressures have typically followed reforms that attempted elimination of waste and reduction in government spending.e This is
unfortunate. The reduction of government waste and rents when accompanied by rising private real investmentsf could actually
step up the growth rate of the economy. As such the real potential of structural reformg has been masked by the resulting demand
depressionary effects of the very same changes. The key really is to pay particular attention to private investment and, more
generally, to investment. What we have said above holds with particular force in transforming economies, which naturally have
higher investment rates and which owe a much larger part of their autonomous expenditures to investmenth.
Private Investment is not Always Bouyant
It is important to understand why the seemingly reasonable assumptions made that private investment would substantially replace
public investments, could more often than not go wrong. Firstly, private investments may have been held back by policies restricting
their operations in many sectors (now opened up), crowding out may have been a dominant feature for long, so that the private
sector may have declined or stunted sufficiently to not to be able to quickly fill the gaps left by withdrawal of public expenditures
and investments or of efficiency gains caused by the elimination or reduction of rents. Similarly, while sectors hitherto closed may
have been opened to the private sector, in many areas especially infrastructure, the lack of credible policies, and regulatory clarity
would (through high risks) keep the private sector off. The picture of a private sector ever alert to fill the gap caused by restrictive
fiscal policies and structural reform that de-facto eliminates waste and hence reduces spending is a myth in most instancesi. The
story of Indian reform where the savings rate rose and then fell with the investment rate, as private investment after 1995–6 stopped
growing at the high rate required to replace declining public investment and expenditures is illustrative.

d It is interesting that finally what was well known outside orthodoxy is in the popular press, due to the efforts of Stiglitz in his writings
against the IMF. The IMF’s assumption, that, in just starting to grow countries of Africa with weakly developed industries, the net exports would
respond with depreciation, or that private investments would rise if public investments decline, have been repeatedly proven to be wrong. Similarly
their monetary approach that gives equal weight to capital and current account autonomous flows in the determination of exchange rates, does
not make them see the merit of structural undervaluation of currencies to speed up exports in highly diversified poor economies with vast disguised
employment! It is shameful that so many academicians still take the IMF seriously, when they have gone so severely wrong in their predictions.
e More often than not a large part of government expenditure in most LDCs (excluding the East Asian NICs) could be wasteful, and as
such any reduction in government expenditure and in the size of government can have vast efficiency gain effects.
f One of the interesting possibilities is when post reform the investment rates remain the same when measured in current price terms, but
the share of private investment grows. With larger incremental output capital ratios (IOCRs), the overall growth rate goes up. Another possibility
even without an ownership mix change is when the standard graft associated with public capital formation is reduced, which lowers the cost of
investment, so that in real terms the investment level is maintained even if in current price terms it declines. Additional investments to that extent
(which replaces the spending out of rents) can then improve the growth rate of the economy.
g Structural reforms have included direct expenditure reduction by the government, tax reform, removal of rent generating discretionary controls,
lower taxes and subsidies.
h The decline in investments that have followed structural reform have been read as declines in the savings rate and, therefore, of the need
to improve savings rate, when in reality savings have fallen, following the decline in (investment) expenditures.
i A lot more on the sectoral policy and regulatory aspects would have to be done for this vision to be realized.

investment for ‘direct targeting’. This expenditure creates is, that the expenditures on the project are in some manner
political support and provides the bases for the party in influenced by the past performance of the entity or
power to reward its vast numbers of field workers. For the organization proposing the project.
bureaucracy it provides a major avenue for expansion and A very large part of the delays and cost overruns of large
spread across sectors and regions not constrained by the projects, especially in the 1970s and early 1980s, before
need for public investments. the environmental factor became dominant, can be attributed
In both the central government and transfers to state to ‘lack of coordination’ between various sectors or
governments and parastatals, expenditure has four important enterprises implementing the projects. Many of the
dimensions. First, the spatial scope, that is, where the administratively and fiscally weaker states who could not
money is spent; second, on what the money is spent; third, make up the formal project proposals, or put up its
social optimality, that is, to ascertain that the money is contribution to investment lost out in getting funds for
spent on the best possible project which will be useful to projects and programmes from the central government in
the society. And lastly, the performance dimension, that the last two decades.
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 37

Box 2.1.2
Efficient Expenditure and Growth

There is another thread of reasoning from the development economics literature that is of particular relevance in the discussion
of wasteful expenditures. In the 1950s the idea of the vicious circle of poverty and the low-level equilibrium brought to the
fore the notion of the big push required to break out the low savings–low investment equilibrium. That justified state involvement
in industrialization, planning, and the state’s role as a mobilizer of resources for investment spending. It also drew attention to
the coordinating role of the state, and of the need for vast foreign resources (savings) to support these efforts that would constitute
the big push above. In raising the investment rate the country would break out of the vicious circlea. Arthur Lewis’b (1954)
contribution to the debate was seminal when he showed that the problem was not so much the lack of (potential) savings as
its non-realization as savings. But the potential surplus is either wasted or exported out. That is crucial to the stability of the
low-level equilibrium trap. Existence of disguised unemployment means that resources are low. The wage is determined by the
average productivity in agriculture. Therefore, investments in modern industries result in vast surplus to potential investors. And
if sustained investments take place the enclaved modern capitalist sector can grow to embrace the entire economy. The rate of
investment, therefore, rises and the economy bootstraps itself.
Investment Rather than Savings Constraint
The existence of disguised unemployment in much of the economy makes this ‘getting out of the abyss’ very fast. In the low
level equilibrium the problem, therefore, is that investments are not being made, the potential surpluses are not being productively
used. Therefore, a lack of coordination (that results in demand being unrealized), inappropriate class structures and other political
and social factors that wastes the surplus, are the problems. Access to foreign funds is not the key to the solutionc.
The point is that rising systemic efficiencies manifest themselves principally in rising investment rates, while keeping the ICOR
from rising, and hence raising the growth rate of the economy. This is particularly true of transforming economies. The point
is that in these economies the transformation phase would show a large part of the growth as arising from input use and very
little from measurable efficiency.d Thus the gains from elimination of waste and rents, and in igniting the process of economic
transformation in late industrializing societies arise from allocative efficiencies and less from efficiencies due to new technology.
They arise from the extensification of modern technology on to the entire economy. The problem is really one of measurement.
As labour productivity rises it really takes place on the back of rising capital use, so that a total factor productivity (TFP) analysis
may still show only small rises in TFP , when both labour and capital are counted as inputs (as they would be in any particular
industry). But the social price of labour is very low—being close to its marginal product which is near zero, so that the only
relevant input for the economy as a whole is capital. And the relevant model to understand the process in its detail is the Lewis
model and its variants, and in the aggregate the Harrod Domar model—not the neoclassical model.
Efficiency Gains Implies Higher Growth
Thus efficiency gains due to reduction in wasteful expenditure and reduction of rents when matched by increases in other productive
expenditure, especially investments, would show up as increases in the growth rate of the economy following from a rise in the
investment and savings rate. Savings would be highly correlated with investments, and savings would get determined by the level
of investments, perhaps with a lag. This discussion was necessary because unlike in the already transformed economy the matter
of growth is different. When growth and its basis is treated as a universal category there can arise significant problems. Growth in
developed economies arise out of technical change, whereas in late industrializers, until they catch up, growth is the result of use
of idle resources—labour. Even after all strictly idle labour is used up, labour productivity can and still does rise as more capital
accumulation takes place. In other words, the measure of a successful structural reform is a sustained increase in the growth rates
and in the investment rates, especially when expressed in real price termse. Thus macroeconomic policies that keep investment rates
high are the key to growth and transformation, and true reform is one that can combine efficiency with high growth.
a Nurkse (1953), Rosenstein-Rodan (1943)
b A little before Lewis, Maurice Dobb (1948), describing the events in the Soviet Union and its economic transition, came to a similar
understanding of the process of change in late industrializing societies.
c Lack of demand could be. Hence the observation that the countries that have used the state and chaebols/zaibatsu like structures to bring
about coordination and overcome market failures and also redistributed land to create endowments (demand) succeeded. The East Asian economies
which did all of these also used export-led growth strategy to create the additional large external demand to very quickly come out of their low-
level traps.
d In all of East Asia this is observed. Typical growth accounting/factor productivity studies reveal that as much as 80 per cent of the growth
can be accounted for by input use, and only 20 per cent at best by improving efficiencies of factor use. Unlike what Krugman (1996b) and
others have led us to believe, there is nothing wrong per se in such economies as a result. Indeed one can argue that functionality would demand
that input use should, during the phase of transformation when idle resources exist, contribute to the bulk of growth. Given that the economy
starts from a situation of vast disguised unemployment, systemic change that lead to realization of potential surplus as investment leads to capital
accumulation that absorbs labour.
e The latter could happen when investment goods prices fall relative to that of other goods, so that at current prices the ratio still remain
the same.
38 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Box 2.1.3
The Burden of Programmes

When we look back now with the benefit of hindsight it is amazing that so much public expenditure for development could
take place without a performance linkage! It is only in the mid-1980s that data on delays and cost overruns were available
anywhere within the government! The DPI brings out in its annual report the data on public projects under implementation
at the central level. The actual task of the department is best seen as one of statistical compilation and ex-post reporting. It does
not have any influence on the process of project implementation.
DPI and Monitoring
The DPI came about out of the need to have centralized information on the vast numbers of programmes under implementation
out of central funds all over the country from the block and village level upwards. The enormous waste and leakage here prompted
the government in the mid 1980s to formally and centrally monitor the same and ‘weekly flash reports’ and monthly detailed
reports became the order of the day as the Prime Minister, Rajiv Gandhi, himself, was concerned with the progress of the
programmes. It is a moot point that despite these reports and the paraphernalia of monitoring nothing corrective is possible since
information alone cannot lead to corrections without any links between the those looking at these reports and the field staff.
Since there was hardly any responsibility embedding—given a little or no incentive compatibility—within the government to
ensure project execution on time, no organization or a part of an organization, could be held to be in charge, and there was
no scope for attributing failure in any meaningful sense. It is also of great significance that nearly all the performance measures
of programmes were in terms of expenditures (inputs) rather than the actual achievement. Achievement in these reports was
nothing more than spending!. This was the way the system (read, the bureaucracy) got the better of a Prime Minister with no
political baggage, and who really wanted to ‘make government work faster’.
Many Studies, No Learning
Earlier the Planning Commission itself had carried out scores, if not hundreds, of ‘evaluation studies’ of IRDP and IRDP-like
programmes. Some of these studies did point out that leakages were large, and the programmes were ill-structured and ill-
conceived, and the multiplicity at the field level made them beyond the organizational capacity of the officials and offices at
the field level (block, taluka, and district). Yet, virtually no changes, (forget innovations in design, organization or delivery) ever
took place. The only new factor has been the attempt to involve non-government organisations (NGOs). Here, too, except when
there was a rare NGO deeply committed and willing to spend much manpower and quality leadership and organizational
resources, programmes have continued much as they were with the added expense of NGO involvement, and ritualized
assessment, capacity building , participation, and training.
Ritual Studies
The bulk of the Programme Evaluation Studies (PES) related to IRDP-like schemes were ritualized studies without a critical
framework. Indeed their ‘framework’ was such that the possibility of coming to the conclusion that performance was poor was
ruled out by the framework of the study! In internalizing the administrative categories, and in accepting expenditure per se as
a measure of the output of these programmes, they were mere tautologies, in the form of an evaluation study. It is interesting
that even the bulk of the independent and academic studies too have been similarly flawed. An entire research institution the
National Institute of Rural Development (NIRD)—is caught in the ritualized assessment of government schemes arriving at inane
and meaningless conclusions, and correlations between performance and social demographic characteristics. The organizational
economic and financial aspects were usually completely ignored or brought in, in a way that could not have led to a diagnostic
form, from which actions for correction could have been derived.
From the rare critically-oriented studies by independent and perceptual scholars we know that on the whole the employment-
oriented schemes (like the Food for Work Programme and the Employment Guarantee Scheme) had rather better success than
asset formation schemes (small businesses, bicycle repair shops, loans to buy milch cattle, etc.).
Continual Redistribution is Problematic
The whole idea of directly targeting the poor, that is, continual redistribution through the state can be fundamentally critiqued
(Morris, 1991 and 2002). We have already mentioned that countries which did a one shot redistribution through land reform
ensuring basic endowments to all, went on to industrialize in the twentieth century; and theirs were the only truly independent
and successful transformations in this century. In contrast it is easy to see why the continual redistribution would not work.
Income distribution is one of the stable characteristics of any economy and this can change only slowly (than even economic
structure). There are obviously critical minimum changes for durability of the change. A small change in income distribution—
few poor (about one in a hundred) every year being ‘lifted out of poverty’—would not do much. The inertia and logic of the
existing structure would reassert itself in many ways; reversion of those ‘lifted up’ would only be one aspect. The actions which
do not affect the existing power and economic relations would not be sustainable, since they do not make for systemic consistency.
The ‘system’ would incorporate such programmes into the existing relations through leakages, influence over beneficiaries, slow
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 39

upward mobility of the beneficiaries, negative feedback effects as when one family below the poverty line is lifted up another
falls below! The principle of Le Chatelier would apply with vigour in this situation. Charity has never worked to reduce
widespread poverty, and the design of IRDP-like programmes, despite their apparent micro level productive aspect, need not,
at the meso or macro-levels, be consistent. The same may be true of training in activities for which demands do not exist or
are slowly growing or where barriers to entry are large. At any time what is being done is only a drop in the ocean.
‘Building’ on Weaknesses
There are other, perhaps more, weighty reasons from the supply side that would restrict the efficacy of such programmes. They
need to be continuously implemented. That means that they are crucially dependent upon an efficient and committed administration,
all the time. They cannot tolerate even small levels of state failure. Mistakes that result in leakages, modes of behaviour that are
dysfunctional continue to be reinforced. If the object was really redistribution, in a way that improves the productive potential
of the economy, there are other obviously more efficient and simpler ways of doing the same such as through food for work and
infrastructure based on food stamps that could have created employment, demand and productive assets. These at the same time
would not have demanded the efficiency and commitment of the administration continuously. Obviously, the real functionality
of these programmes is ‘sop’ and the neutralization of potential dissent among those without or with very little endowments.
Nearly all these programmes were based on continuous and repeated identification of the poor; and the task of identification
and issuance of the benefit—be it credit grant or training—being simultaneous, there was little basis or incentive to do the job
of identification thoroughly. But had the two been separated and the status of an individual /family identified once (for possibly
as long as a decade), then a queue that could self-monitor could have been built up. Transparency and public notification of
the beneficiaries could have contributed much to correct identification. Thus, even the possible gains in efficacy, and efficiency
possible within the paradigm of direct targeting through better design went unrecognized. See Appendix 2.1.1 for a very partial
but illustrative list of these and other programmes that attempt to ‘remove’ poverty and improve the living conditions of people
through schemes that have continual administrative overload. Notice that there is very little change in the form and structure
of these schemes. Schemes change names, the content remains the same. They merge into other schemes. Not just the intended
beneficiares but even few officials would be able tell or list out all the schemes that operate.
The budgetary and expenditure processes were problematic. The funds having to pass through various rungs of the
bureaucracy, those who designed the projects, were distanced from the officials who were to actually implement the projects.
The latter could hardly be held responsible for its failure, since the design was not theirs and responsibility embedment cannot
be assumed. Moreover, there are far too many schemes with different names and accounts and differing in marginal ways—the
asset or the purpose—but in most cases really amounting to some commercial credit or grant being delivered. The total number
of schemes would overwhelm the local officials and their infrastructure if they have to transparently and carefully implement
all the schemes. Failure was virtually guaranteed in the design.
Direct Transfer Schemes Fare Better
The schemes which attempted direct transfers have fared somewhat better. Typical of these have been widows’ pension, old age
pensions, and scholarships for poor people. In societies with much local awareness of policies and programmes, with somewhat
more equituous income distribution, and with the capacity among people to demand accountability from local officials (Kerala,
and, possibly, in parts of the southern and western states) a significant part of the spending would have gone to the intended.
In areas with much state failure, and no great local-level movements or consciousness among the people, such sums would have
been spirited away almost entirely as rent. In still others with state failure but with strong local consciousness there would be
a better chance for the same to reach the people since the activity being a mere transfer is not dependent upon the capacity
of the state to design and execute a complex task (programme). The accountability measure too is simple. The repetition in the
task gives incentives for people (recipients) to monitor the local officials.
The output of these programmes have been measured by the amount of expenditure incurred in these programmes. Thus
through a particular poverty eradication project a certain number of people would have been claimed to have been lifted above
the poverty line, since so much money was spent. This would obviously be a false measure. In many others expenditure itself
being the ‘target’ and the measure, the real purpose such as raising incomes, or improving nutrition would have been nearly
completely suppressed in evaluatory studies except in the assumed design sense.
Abhorring Output Measures
This is reflective of a more general tendency to use expenditure itself as a measure of government activities. At the accounting
level/information gathering level this is natural to the way the national income accounts treat purely public services, and the activities
of government. Here lack of excludability, which is total, and non-existence of markets make it infeasible to use any other method—
police and defence—make other measures that are also capable of being aggregated problematic. The GDP here is the expenditure
on wages and salaries and use of capital. The non-recognition of the performance-value axis of government expenditure means
that there is very little effort to find other measures including throughput measures (which may be possible when output measures
are not). It is also reflective of the lack of accountability in governments. Accountability itself is negated in terms of the primary
task when output measures do not exist. The only possible accountability then is to the rules and process of expenditure.
40 India Infrastructure Report 2003

True output measures would mean that the allocator /dispenser himself is being evaluated. The weak organizational separation—
‘after all it is all within government’—brings little or no pressures to search for true and possible measures of output of each
distinct department, activity or programme. Given such non-measurement of output, and when expenditures themselves are used
as output, there is little or no possibility of hardening of budgets. Practically then, only incremental budgeting is possible. The
search for output measures can be much resisted by bureaucracies, since they constitute an important element of change towards
greater functionality and task orientationa.
Thus output measures have come with great difficulty. And audit and accounting innovations like the value for money audit
of the British Government, which are functional rather than being purely procedural have had to face much resistance.
Discussions Ignore the ‘How To?’
Surprisingly, despite being studied for decades, this kind of state intervention through ‘targeted’ programmes, that are heavily
dependent on high levels of motivation and organizational capacity within government, have been routinely put forward as
‘solutions’ to all kinds of problems even by academics who clearly have no brief to restrict themselves to the governmental paradigm
in their thinking of alternatives. It is the ‘public policy orientation’ of the economists—the assumption that the state is an agent
of the common good of society,that is at the root of the problem. (For example, few non-right wing scholars have argued for
the abandonment of the PDS and sop programmes despite their vast leakages. They have typically asked for better efficiency
(how one brings that about was blissfully never their concern) and increased outlays. The public policy stance does not allow
us to recognize state failure that compounds market failure—and the latter that may well have been much smaller to start with.
The issue of ensuring incentive compatibility, organizational consistency and capacity with government are most remote from
the minds of such scholars, who unfortunately are well entrenched in the centre and left of centre (political) spaces. Similarly,
the right wing, in insisting on the removal of all subsidies and abandonment of all state extension, can be challenged to show
that alternative methods of subsidization and extension by the state can bring about major improvements to greatly reduce the
cost of subsidization. Today in many sectors the cost of one rupee of delivered subsidy can be as high as three or four rupees.
In the case of electricity the costs may be even higher, if the consumer side costs on paying customers, and the specific externalities
that improper use of electricity engenders on the firm are recognized. In some IRDP-type programmes, for instance, tribal
development programmes it may be as high as 50 times. In irrigation water if the externalities and cost of in-optimality in the
cropping pattern, wastage of water, and lack of use of water saving methods and technologies, etc. are included then they could
be very large and many times the value of the delivered subsidies.

a The experience of the DFID and the World Bank working with certain state governments to bring about expenditure accountability, reveals
the difficulties and the resistance in using output/more rational measures of performance, than expenditure itself. See Chapter 4.3 by Shantanu
Mitra and Vijay Pillai in this Report.

Multilateral agencies funding large infrastructure projects centre as a mere router of funds could have spilled over
have the comfort of the backing of the central government. on to the Planning Commission’s role.
And these projects are accompanied by close monitoring • There was incentive incompatibility in bundling the
and conditionalities relating to performance. But there was planning and project /programme roles together.
no attempt on the Planning Commission or Finance
While the political reasons for the dismal state of public
Ministry’s part to impose conditionalities relating to
expenditure accountability are recognized, the bureaucratic
performance, pricing, etc. The lack of performance linkage
and systemic forces that result in slack and waste are not
at the project levels were inter alia because:
admitted as independent causal factors. Dilatory processes,
• The Planning Commission in its expenditure very low work loads on administrative staff and ill-defined
allocation and management aspect was entirely an extension tasks give rise to poor implementation. The general belief
of the bureaucracy and, therefore, its evaluation and that political interference is the cause of administrative
examination was of particular tasks rather than a holistic failure and inefficiency is only part of the story.
evaluation of the project. Budgetary subsidies after 1992–3 have grown rapidly.
• Unlike a developmental bank, there is no possible At current prices, there is a sharp decline in capital
aggregate measure of performance or activity for all the expenditures from 1998–9 onwards. The attempt to
projects under the Planning Commission. continue to reduce the fiscal deficit has resulted in a slow
• Follow up in government bureaucracies to moneys down in capital expenditures. One would have assumed
given is difficult, and capital investment carried out by the that private expenditure would continue to rise, but after
Planning Commission was no exception. 1995–6 it has collapsed sharply remaining almost stagnant
• Plan fund grants were not sought to be sharply from that point onwards. The lack of policy and regulatory
distinguished from devolved funds. So the idea of the clarity in many investment-heavy sectors of infrastructure,
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 41

Box 2.1.4
The Fiscal Deficit

The fiscal deficit has emerged as the one single shorthand way of assessing the progress of reform. The Fund/Banks’ approach
to reform which sees bringing down the fiscal deficit continuously till it reaches very low and sustainable levels, has swamped
the attention space so much that there is virtually no discussion on this objective of reducing the fiscal deficit by expenditure
cutting in policy forums and in the media. It is therefore important at the risk of being trite to go over the issue. The argument
about the fiscal deficit essentially emanates from two sets of considerations.
Sustainability and Identities
One is sustainability and the other the greater efficiency of private rather than public expenditures—at least at the margin.
Sustainability, that is, the consideration that the fiscal deficit as a proportion of GDP should not keep rising implies a ceiling
on the level of the primary fiscal deficit under assumptions of desirable or ceiling levels of inflation and monetization. The
sustainable level of the fiscal deficit is essentially arrived at by using accounting and definitional relationships and identities, and
certain ‘data’ covering structural ratios and assumptions about growth, which are considered as being unaffected by the level of
government expenditures, the fiscal deficit or money supply in the economy. Inter alia these are the money multiplier, the money
GDP ratio in the economy, the real interest rate, and most importantly the growth rate of the economy and its exports! Assumed
maximum ‘realistic’ levels of growth, constancy in the structural ratios then give the sustainable (maximum) level of the primary
fiscal deficit. Thus the maximum level of the primary fiscal deficit in 1991–2 would have been 2.3 per cent for the entire NFPS,
thus necessitating major change since the primary fiscal deficit was running at close to 5.5 per cent (Joshi and Little, 1996).
An Inadequate Framework
The same identities but with different assumptions about the growth rate of the economy and the growth rate of exports, the
tolerable inflation and the real interest rates, would give vastly different levels of the fiscal deficit that is sustainable. See Table
2.1.1. Thus the accounting framework can at best be a crude guide useful in situations of crisis (crowding out with high inflationa)
when the need to cut the deficit by reducing expenditure is obvious, but of little use at other times. This is because the
government expenditures and the money supply which go into the computation of the sustainable primary fiscal deficit can have
large effects on growth. In other words the real sectors cannot be assumed to be independent of the monetary sector, nor can
they be considered as truly exogenous in the conceivable long run. The matter is particularly relevant in the transforming
economies where monetary and fiscal policies can make a big and lasting difference to the growth rates. The keynesian percept
to use these when there are idle resources is a real opportunity in the transforming economies. This is because the correct
composition of expenditures that raises the investment rate, not only shifts the equilibrium (market clearing) level of output but
also raises the underlying productive capacity of the economy. The existence of disguised employment can in such economies
(when wages are un-indexed or only in part indexed) result in high growth without bringing about inflation b. In short, in
transforming economies as long as rising expenditures take the form of investment (or more correctly the investment rate does
not decline, but rises at least as fast as the incremental (design) capital output ratios), the products of which have markets at
home and abroad (exports), then the resulting growth need not invite the danger of inflation c.
Crowding Out and the Fiscal Deficit
The second reason for worrying about the fiscal deficit is the possible crowding out of private expenditures it can result in. This
is a more serious ground for reigning in the fiscal deficit even when they are sustainable. Unfortunately, even here there cannot be an
unambiguous answer. That there are two sides to any expenditure is not often recognized. All expenditures including the most
wasteful and abhorrent contribute to demand and, hence, towards determining the equilibrium level of output. Sudden falls in
the autonomous components of expenditure lower the equilibrium level of output, and can therefore keep up the fiscal deficit as
a proportion of GDP if the resulting output fall is large. The other aspect is its impact on the productive capacity. When the
expenditure is investmentd then there is a direct addition to the productive capacity. Private investment when it replaces government
investment that had involved much waste and cost overruns can result in faster growth of capacity output. See Box 2.1.1.
Economic Structure and the Fiscal Deficit
There would be situations when if the fiscal deficit is attempted to be cut beyond a certain level by contracting public
expenditures, it would not be matched by private expenditures. In that situation the fiscal deficit is necessary at least temporarily.
It cannot be brought down without the pursuit of structural reform, which enhances the space for private sector and private
a More correctly when the current equilibrium level of output is above the capacity output of the economy.
b Inflation can be expected to be directly related to the gap between capacity and equilibrium output.
c High and unsustainable inflation in the LDCs in Africa and Latin America have their primate cause in the capital flight that occurs from
these economies, and the causation is not the other way round as is generally assumed.
d In economies that are skill constrained (perhaps not India) expenditures that increase the availability of skills directly required in industries
can also act like ‘investment in capacity creation.’
42 India Infrastructure Report 2003

expenditures. Thus large-scale privatizations (sell off ) in such a situation would be required to reduce the fiscal deficit further.
These structural limits (that is, the constraints posed by lagging structural reforms to macroeconomic and fiscal reforms) to cutting
the fiscal deficit are not generally recognized. Attempts to reduce the deficit when the structural conditions still warrant large
public expenditures and deficits (as, for instance, when major investment-hungry sectors such as power, urban services and water,
roads and railways remain with the public sector) would be problematic. Orthodox pursuit of fiscal deficit reduction even in
such a situation would only mean the imposition of demand recession on the economye, and the fiscal deficit as proportion of
GDP may well remain at the original level despite the expenditure reduction.
It could even increase it, if certain revenues like taxes have high elasticities with respect to outputs that show much amplitudinal
variations.
Growth the Only Way Out
In India inflation fell only after a gap of about four to five years that is, in 1996–7, after the expenditure reduction and switching
had begun in 1991–2. This is as expected by keynesians, and is observed all over in market economies, even in the advanced capitalist
economies, where price stickiness is bound to be less.f During the period up to 1995–6 when inflation remained high, at around
8 per cent and nominal interest rates were 14+ per cent, the real rate was 7 per cent and was expected to decline as inflation declined
by the less orthodox who believed in the law of one price in a more long-term sense. But even then the expected fall in the nominal
rates did not happen. Today although the nominal rates have fallen to 10 per cent or below the inflation too has fallen to about
5 per cent or less leaving the real rate at around 6 per cent! For the manufacturing industry where the real rate based on its own
inflation at 3 per cent or less is as high as 7 per cent, the growth rate of output is barely 4 per cent. That virtually rules out any
fresh investments other than of the maintenance varietyg. At real rates in excess of the growth rates the budget deficit can only rise!
The answer, of course, is not further cutting of government expenditures as is the conventional belief in policy making circles, but
higher growth. Indeed, the sooner the government realizes this the better it is. The only way the fiscal deficit can come down today
is either through inflation that brings down the real cost of borrowing below the government’s growth rate of revenue or through
growth which increases this revenue, and reduces the base for the fiscal deficit.

e Which we had anticipated much before the present recession. (See Morris, 1997).
f Recent evidenceand thinking would indicate that wage price stickiness may not be the real basis for the delayed response of monetary policy
on prices but the very nature of the productive system of monopolistic competition.
g The fischer-open or the unarbitraged difference in interest rates too remaining positive, would also additionally imply a capital cost disadvantage
to domestic firms currently.

such as power and water, are no doubt responsible. In The government had in 1997 set up the Expenditure
other areas, especially in public infrastructural services, Reforms Commission (ERC), which has submitted its
there are opportunities to leverage private investments that various reports. The objective of the Commission was
continue to be missed. expenditure reforms and the Commission adopted a simple
In the annual budget of the central government the tax approach of identifying and recommending for abolition/
side of the budget receives more public attention and the removing surplus manpower and expenditure. But, if one
expenditure side is rarely discussed except in rather simplistic reads between the lines of the ERC reports, it is possible
ways that may amount to mere verbalization of the figures. to gleam some of the crucial problems with governmental
The diagnoses of expenditures are very rudimentary. The processes today.
reason for this disparity is that the budget comes bundled The range of possible changes that need to be initiated
along with major and minor policy announcements, as well is vast—active privatization, incentive compatible
as announcements of programmes for spending, subsidy contracting, income rather than production subsidies, direct
and concessional credit, of funds to support an activity, rather than price-based subsidies, independent and light
or the setting up of institutions and organizations. This rather than government initiated and heavy (cost plus)
exercise of allocation of government expenditure is an end regulation, innovative ownership forms to bring about
in itself as this provides authority to respective ministries incentive compatibility. All of these instead of requiring
to spend the public money. There are almost no discussions all of the state to be well oiled, informed and motivated,
on the deviations of the actuals from the budget proposals require only a part of the state to be so since, once decided,
of the previous years because efficiency of public expenditure the policies and frameworks would tend to carry the
is generally accepted to be low. Fortunately, the data is now process of reform and efficiency further. To have the right
presented in a little more detail to allow a rudimentary policies and frameworks is to ensure implementation, and
discussion on this most vital aspect of fiscal performance, there cannot be a hiatus between the two. This we had
and expenditure accountability. argued at great length in the last IIR. Being too orthodox
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 43

Box 2.1.5
Employment and Administrative Expenses

Trends
Employment can hardly go down suddenly in government, and certainly not in India, where the government by past practice and
by the law cannot follow a policy of hire and firea. To a large extent, therefore, employment costs are due to the actions or non-
actions in the past. And current commitments to reduce expenditures and employment even when seriously pursued would have
only delayed effects. The employment growth in the 1980s in the public sector as a whole is worth recounting. In the private sector
employment growth was barely positive, despite the fact that the economy grew at rates close to 5.5 per cent per annum on the
whole, and the corporate sector at a couple of percentage points better. The reasons for this ‘jobless’ growth as it was then widely
called were rather simple. During the period of the late 1960s growth had been very slow, but labour militancy high, and managers
may have all but lost control over the shop floor. As the growth picked up, the impasse of the 1970s gave way to productivity
linked wage increases for wage labour, first in Mumbai and then elsewhere in western and southern India. This brought down
militancy and restored the control of the shop floor to the management. So the vast slack and over-employment of the past could
be gradually overcome in the 1980s by improving labour productivity through better control and by use of more capital. There
was therefore no real demand for fresh new workers. But when the growth continued into the 1990s after a short period of two
years of interruption during the stabilization, employment growth began again but on a very modest scaleb. In the public sector
though, the trends are revealing of the non-economic processes at work. Right through the end of the Mahalanobis Plan (the mid-
1960s) to the structural adjustment of the early 1990s, the employment growth rate has been at a steady practically unvarying
growth rate. The vast variations in output, has had little effect on the employment growth rate. The over-manning and over-
employment during the ‘Hindu Period’ 1965–79 had no impact at all on the 1980s when growth revived and shop-floor conditions
were better. Employment continued to grow and there was no taking in of the slack, that the private corporate sector witnessed.
Public Employment in the 1990s
After 1991–3, it was investment in the public sector that bore the brunt of the expenditure reduction that took place. As part
of the strategy and diktat there was a complete freeze on employment by PSUs. This was administratively hoisted on the PSUs
and, later extended to the general government. Employment growth rates turned negative, given zero new employment and the
natural attrition due to superannuation and resignations. So the benefits of slowdown and decline in employment growth at the
PSU and central government levels would only now be witnessed. Practically any TFP study of PSUs during the 1990s should
show strong productivity gains by the central government enterprises as a whole as their outputs rose in keeping with the growt h
of the economy but capital investments were either frozen or at very low levels and total employment declined. The huge gains
in productivity only tell us the enormous levels of slack that existed at the end of the 1980s in the PSU sector. The slack that
would have been there in the 1970s is mind boggling. By no stretch of imagination can the slack be said to have been roped
in even today! At the shop-floor level the slack today would be much less, but at white-collar levels it continues to be enormousc.
Effects Lag Actions
Let us consider the period of the 1980s when employment growth Eg was 2.5 per cent or more. An inflation level Ng of about
6 per cent, and a wage increase due to promotions /skill improvements, and a bracket increase Sg of 2 per cent is easily assumed.
If there is also a real wage increase (for the same bracket) Rg of 4.0 per cent then, take or leave a percentage point, the nominal
growth of salaries and wage expenditures Ng has to be of the order of 14.5 per cent.
Thus: Ng(14.5) = Pg(6.0) + Eg(2.5) + Sg(2.0) + Rg(4.0). If salaries and wage expenses of governments as a proportion of GDP
ought not to have risen, then the economy should have grown at rates in excess of 14.5 – 6 = 8.5 per cent in the 1980s. This
did not happen so the ‘adjustment’ was by rising inflation rates and delay in the implementation of partial indexation of
government employees wages to the general inflation. But the commitment to partial indexation while it could be shelved for
a while could not be indefinitely postponed and the implementation of the Fifth Pay Commission in the 1990s has suddenly
brought on to the government and PSU budgets major increase on account of salaries and wages.
Today the situation is characterized by a slower growth in the salary and wage expenses (excluding superannuation payments
and benefits) as follows: Ng(9.5) = Pg(5.0) + Eg(–0.5) + Sg(2.0) + Rg(3.0) which given an inflation of about 5 per cent implies
only a real rate of GDP growth of 5 per cent for the ratio to remain steady. As such the ratio can be expected to get steady
and would most certainly decline if the growth rate of the economy can be stepped up. The state governments not having as
yet reduced their employment growth rates to nil, would take much more time before the ratio stabilizes.

a It is not just the government proper but even enterprises and autonomous institutions that are so handicapped, because when the governments’
stake (or contribution) is 50 per cent or more, they have been ruled as state by the courts.
b In some new industries like the financial sector, IT and consulting and management services, all of much interest to professionals, the
employment growth rates were at record high levels.
c The wide spread use of IT and personal computers would have enhanced the slack even more.
44 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Box 2.1.6
Financial Sector Reform and the Fiscal Deficit

Early and simultaneous pursuit of financial sector reform raises the interest rates for the governments’ fresh borrowings. The
irrelevance of sequencing is based on the assumption of the law of one price, which actually is a mere conceptual abstraction. Indeed
the one thing that empirical investigations have revealed is that the law of one price is systematically violated. (Stein, Jerome, 1991)
‘Law of One Price’ is no Law
When financial sector reform in the key sense of market determined interest rate is pursued before or simultaneously with refor m
of the real sector, there is potential for the real side of the reform to be adversely affected, or to become more difficult. Firstly,
it is important to recognize that, unlike the widespread belief (essentially classical) of the interest serving as the price that brings
equilibrium between savings and investment, the nominal interest rate serves as an indicator of developments in the bond and
money markets. This essentially keynesian insight, would similarly tell us that there need not be any tendency, and certainly not
in the medium term, for the ‘law of one price’ to hold, that is for a constancy of the real interest rates. Constant real interest
rates is not something that emerges out of markets, but can be the result of a systematic and active pursuit of the same through
fiscal and monetary policy.
A period prior to reform when the public sector/government would have had access to savings funds at low interest rates (real-
nominal rates that are fixed and inflation being high) by bypassing the market. When it goes into the market for borrowings
the nominal rates would go up. At least till such time as there is downward pressure on money supply growth—given the need
to curtail expenditures—the interest rates would go up rather rapidly. Even when the price level falls or growth in the same
declines due to the delayed effect of restrictive monetary policy, the nominal rate need not fall since that would depend upon
the money supply growth. Only if investments in the rest of the economy decline and if the government is quickly able to shed
expenditures would it decline. But then the economy necessarily adjusts by deep contraction. If contraction beyond that required
for balance of payment (BoP) adjustment does not take place because private investments rise to keep the trend in investment
expenditures as a whole the same as before, interest rates would not decline. On sub-national governments, and parastatals and
local bodies with large borrowings from the centre and the markets, the fiscal deficit would widen significantly on this count,
and could even negate their efforts to reduce or slow down other expenditure growth.
Sequencing is Important
Many have, therefore, suggested the late pursuit of financial sector reform in adjustment. (Joshi and Little, 1996). The continuing
financial repression in such a strategy means that the burden of adjustment is shifted not only on the government (and on wage
and profit earners) but also on interest income earners. Since interest income accrues to accumulated financial savings, a small
adjustment therein can make room for much reduction in the adjustment required on the part of the productive enterprises
adding to real capital assets. This shift from interest earners (risk shirkers) to profit earners (risk takers) can speed up or maintain
the growth rate of the economy.
Indeed in such a delayed (or as many would call a correct sequencing of reforms) the fiscal deficit can actually be brought
down to very low levels as a proportion of GDP, since it is a strategy that builds on growth—the only ultimate basis for all
adjustment. The lower interest rates would mean that savers and investors in fixed income securities lose on their savings, but
they gain through the rise in opportunities for investment, and especially for such investments outside the government.
Unnecessary Burden on the Real Sector
Thus in India the early pursuit of financial sector reform resulted in vast and sudden income transfers via high interest rates
on to the banks (who in the repressed period held government securities) and to ‘small savers’ from whom government had
borrowed often at fixed tenures and rates. The key keynesian insight that the savings rate did not depend upon the interest
rates either nominal or real, but that savings is a residual aspect of the consumption function, implies that the possibility that
the real interest rates would affect savings is rather small.a Indeed low but positive real rates maintained through both price and
interest rate targets, the former in the short run and the latter in a more long run sense, even when repression is known to exist,
can result in vast increases in incomes and savings out of these, as the investment rate goes up. All successful East Asian
industrializers have shown this functional financial repression,b along with high and rising investment and savings rates. In short,
therefore, the fiscal situation and specifically the fiscal deficits of sub-national entities would have to be judged with reference
to the macroeconomic situation and the strategy of adjustment and reform pursued by the national government. To a large extent
the sudden and dramatic deterioration of the budgets of state governments, is due to this factor, compounded by the sharp rise
in salary and wage expenses due to the Fifth Pay Commission Awards.

a Except when they are permanently negative! This situation is better dealt with by the pursuit of policies that reduce the inflation rate below
the nominal rate of interest.
b The idea that ‘non-equilibrium’ low interest rates results in inefficient technology choice, in a growing economy is pure classical fib. But
such arguments without caveats have been made by the “financial repression” school led by Fry, Maxwell (1980).
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 45

‘Small Savings’
The Y.V. Reddy Committee on Administered Interest Rates looked inter alia at ‘small’ savings policies, and made many important
suggestions. For a critical review of the same see Box 2.1.7 of this chapter by S.K. Barua. The idea of ‘small savings’ to raise
the savings rate through mobilization of savings among very humble and poor people makes eminent sense in a poor but
transforming economy. The small additional benefit in the form of a higher rate of interest is also worthwhile, provided there
are limits to investments in small savings instruments, so that small savings remain small in the sense of being used by people
with small incomes. But a transforming economy that seeks to step up growth rates through high and rising rates of investments
would need to have an income policy that allows government an additional instrument (including the rate of interest) on certain
designated instruments into which savings could be mobilized (and de-mobilized), depending on the situation with regard to
the price level. Thus, if through an income policy that can postpone or retain consumption, when inflation tends to rise, and
vice versa, high rates of investment can be pursued. This had been proved by the East Asian economies.
Additionally, it may be worthwhile to insulate a certain nominal level of financial savings per person from inflation by creating
bonds whose yields are indexed to inflation. This can make the system bear somewhat higher levels of inflation. They could
substantially raise the savings rate among small-income earners. A complete determination of all interest rates by the market
through dependence or indexation with particular markets or instruments like the bank rate as the Reddy Committee suggests,
may impose major uncertainty and volatility on not only small savings but also on entrepreneurs and firms taking risks to make
‘real’ investments.

Table 2.1.1
The Primary Fiscal Deficit: An Accounting Exercise
(Assuming that nominal interest rates change to adjust to inflation and real interest rates)

Primary fiscal deficit/GDP x 0.0236 0.0344 0.0519 0.0543 0.0675


Domestic debt GDP ratio b 0.54 0.54 0.54 0.54 0.54
Safe seniorage/GDP s 0.0132 0.0132 0.0132 0.0156 0.018
Safe govt primary borrowing abroad/GDP f 0.005 0.005 0.0225 0.0225 0.0225
Nominal interest rate domestic i 0.1 0.08 0.08 0.1 0.1
Domestic inflation rate Pg 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.07
Growth rate of real income Yg 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.08 0.08
Ratio of high powered money (H)
to GDP nominal H 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12
Ratio of national foreign debt to exports D 2 2 2 2 2
Exports growth rate Eg 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2
Foreign dollar real interest rate r$ 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05
Exports to GDP nominal ratio E/yp 0.1 0.1 0.15 0.15 0.15
Govt share in national primary
borrowings abroad 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
Domestic real interest rate r 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.03
Alternatives Joshi Joshi Joshi Joshi Joshi

+r = 0.03 +Eg = 0.2 +Eg = 0.2 +Eg = 0.2


+E/yp = 0.15 +E/yp = 0.15 +E/yp = 0.15
+r = 0.03 +y~ = 0.08 +r = 0.03
yg = 0.08
pg = 0.07

about reform invites political resistance and does not lead every department there are significant tasks29—being
to a feasible path forward. This is rather silly when there currently done in-house and marked by little accountability,
are solutions to the principal problems that are not only vast inefficiencies, and waste—that ought to be privatized,
feasible politically but actually bring forth additional political
support for the reform and improved working of the 29 To name a few: printing and publishing, construction and
government and public services. maintenance of buildings, tree planting and gardens, cash handling,
The scope for privatization of significant parts of the kitchens and canteens, design and architecture, data analysis,
current government tasks is very large in India. In practically computer services, etc.
46 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Box 2.1.7
S ome O bservv ations on the ‘R
bser
Obser epor
eportt of the E
‘Repor xper
xpertt Committee to R
Exper evie
Revie
evieww the SSystem
ystem of A dminister
Administer ed
dministered
Interest Rates and Other Related Issues’

Samir K. Barua
The Expert Committee for reviewing the system of administered interest rates for small savings schemes including the Public
Provident Fund (PPF) scheme, under the chairmanship of Y.V. Reddy, Former Deputy Governor, Reserve Bank of India, was
constituted in April 2001 by the Finance Ministry, Government of India. The Committee submitted its report in September 2001.
The Committee examined all the relevant issues connected with small savings schemes from the point of view of three
constituencies, namely, the small savers, the state governments, and the central government. To ensure acceptability of its
recommendations, the Committee has attempted to strike a balance between the needs of the three constituencies. As a result,
however, it has come out with a set of recommendations that lacks clarity and focus. We highlight some of the significant
deficiencies of the report and the recommendations.
The Committee stated that its objective was to ensure that the small savers ‘continue to get a safe avenue for investment at
reasonable rate of return’. The recommendations of the Committee, however, are implicitly coloured by a belief that the current
rates of return on small savings schemes are high, and that they are unduly high if the tax benefits available to savings under
these schemes are taken into account. It has therefore recommended withdrawal of tax benefits on short and medium maturity
(less than six years) instruments and fixation of rates on these schemes using benchmarks such as the rates on term deposits with
commercial banks and yields on government securities. While making these recommendations, the Committee does not make the
necessary distinction between ‘small savers’ and ‘small savings’. The distinction is important because of asymmetry of returns from
small savings schemes to small savers and large savers (those with high personal incomes).
Tax Concessions is Not the Way
Small savers are unlikely to be tax-payers. Therefore, they do not benefit from the tax concessions on small savings schemes. As
a result, while a 9 per cent tax-free interest rate remains 9 per cent for a small saver (non-tax paying), it effectively becomes 13.85
per cent for a person who is in the 35% marginal (highest) tax bracket. There is, therefore, little justification for the recommendation
that tax-free concessions should continue on long maturity (above six years) instruments, if the objective was to benefit small
savers! The benchmarking of rates on small savings schemes to other rates prevailing in the economy would in fact reduce the
interest rates available to small savers significantly. The decline would hurt the small savers. If the objective were indeed to benefit
‘small savers’ then the correct approach would have been to offer higher taxable interest on investments upto specified limits,
while withdrawing tax concessions completely. Such an approach would have completely eliminated the distortions introduced
by tax concessions as well as ensured that the extra return being paid on savings up to a ceiling truly benefited small savers.
The targeting of the schemes would have been much better. Going back to the earlier example, taxable interest rate of 13.85
per cent is far better for small savers than 9 per cent tax-free interest rate.
To ensure acceptance of the recommendations by the state governments, the Committee has recommended that the entire
collection through the small savings schemes should be transferred to the states. However, recognizing that ‘complete decentralization’
would result in rise in the risks associated with investments in these schemes that ‘could have an adverse effect on the overall
mobilization of such savings’, the Committee recommended that the current arrangement of mobilization should continue. This
essentially implies that the central government would continue to guarantee payment on these instruments (to the investors) in
case of default by the state governments. Given the financial indiscipline of the state governments, such guarantee by the central
government could land the central government into a difficult situation. The guarantee also raises the issue of moral hazard—
the states might be tempted to raise resources through this route with abandon and mis-spend the resources raised. Decentralization
should, therefore, be accompanied with shifting of responsibility on the states to raise resources through small savings schemes
without guarantee from the central government. In such a case, it is quite possible that different states would have to offer different
rates on the investments, depending on the risk perception of investors about the financial viability and credibility of plans of
the states. Competition among the states would benefit the small savers and improve the state of public finances in the country.
Financial Discipline of State Governments is a Must
Since 100 per cent transfer of funds collected through the small savings scheme implies considerable loss of capital receipts t o
the central government, the Committee took care to highlight the benefits to the central government from the proposal in the
form of higher tax collections and higher contributions to General Provident Fund (GPF). Recognizing that despite these
additional inflows, there is likely to be a decline in the total resource available to the central government, the Committee suggested
that the attendant shortfall could be made up through additional market borrowing. Such a substitution would in fact reduce
the cost of funds for the central government. This suggestion essentially implies that the aggregate deficit of the central
government would rise, since higher transfer of funds collected from small savings schemes is not to be offset through lower
transfer of funds from the central to the state government under other heads. It, therefore, appears that the recommendation
was directed at increasing the transfer of resources to the states. Recognizing that alignment (and hence reduction in the current
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 47

scenario) of interest rates (to some benchmark rates in the economy) on small savings schemes could result in decline in the resource
mobilization through small savings schemes, the Committee suggested special market borrowing programmes for the states. This
would imply that the indebtedness of the states would rise. The recommendation, therefore brushes aside the need to bring about
greater financial discipline among states. The recommendation also implies that the states would be burdened with higher interest
costs (since the cost of funds from small savings scheme would be higher than market borrowing costs). As a result, the
recommendation potentially worsens the financial situation of the states. In the light of the above discussion on the fiscal situation
of both the states and the central government, the logic of the proposal of 100 per cent transfer to states is quite unclear.
The Committee also visualizes that in the foreseeable future, most small savers would join privately managed social security
schemes. It assumes that the change in management of savings would automatically bring about higher returns for the savers.
This may not be true for a variety of reasons. First, the government will have to permit far greater flexibility in the composition
of portfolios of the social security schemes that are to be managed by private agencies. Second, there is a paucity of investment
vehicles in the Indian economy for suitable diversification of investments for risk reduction. This is unlikely to disappear unless
the government permits investment of savings outside India (essentially permitting capital account convertibility). Third, going
by the performance of privately managed mutual funds, there is no reason to believe that private management of social security
schemes would necessarily result in better returns to subscribers.
Little Clarity
In summary, the report of the Committee appears to be a jumble of ideas that lack clear reasoning and recommendations that
conflict with each other and that sometimes go against the basic assumptions made for the analysis. In an attempt to please all
the constituencies, in particular, the state and the central governments, it has framed recommendations that are likely to prove
detrimental to fiscal management. The one concrete, unambiguous recommendation of aligning rates on small savings to certain
benchmark rates in the economy goes against the interests of the small savers, making a mockery thereby of the stated objective
of encouraging savings and providing adequate returns to the small savers.

recast as PFI contracts. Passing such sections/units around focus is on this aspect of government budgets since the
from one ministry to another in the name of rationalization, scope here is enormous, and it directly bears on public
as the ERC has recommended is hardly the best way out. services provisioning, that includes infrastructure. The
The singular lack of exploration of alternative ways of NIPFP of 1993 concluded that the total subsidies, both
subsidization and government procurement, and carrying budgeted and implicit, are as high as 15 per cent of GDP!
out extension that can potentially be much more efficient Since explicit subsidies then were about 3 per cent, the
than the processes that exist today is a major failure in the implicit subsidies were in the range of 12 per cent. Since
discussion. In so far as supply/procurement of infrastructure then there is little reason that this would have reduced in
services are concerned new designs for procurement are just any substantial manner. These estimates were on the basis
emerging in road construction and maintenance. But in of recovery of operating costs/operational losses of
nearly all other areas like irrigation and drinking water, enterprises, providing services such as electricity and
sewerage services, subsidy administration where simple irrigation. If the more reasonable assumption of recovery
changes in design could have plugged the vast leakages, at long run marginal cost/willingness to pay, whichever is
raised resources and increased the benefits to those intended less, is made, then the extent of the implicit subsidies that
there is still no improvement. could be reduced is considerable and even a modicum of
With such a system in place, internal officers with deep change here can bring the fiscal deficit down in a functional
knowledge of their departments would be willing to manner. If this is not attempted because it is difficult and
contribute to the task of identification and elimination of instead the investment or vital social services expenditures
the slack and waste, even as external consultants study are cut any further, then not only would they impose a
government departments to make their own assessments. demand depressionary effect, but in the medium to long
There is, of course, the third way which needs to be term, by slowing down the growth in the quantum of
pursued along with more expansionary monetary policy productive assets in the economy, could revive the
and that is to enhance revenues, especially non-tax, and inflationary pressures if in future demand picks up due to
reduction in the expenditure on subsidies. Our principal exogenous reasons.
48 India Infrastructure Report 2003

APPENDIX 2.1.1
Key Programmes and Schemes initiated by the Government of India during the Five Year Plans for the Rural,
Urban and Poverty Alleviation Areas (Programme; Plan Period)a

POVERTY ALLEVIATION EMPLOYMENT RELATED


Accelerated Rural Water Supply Programme (ARWSP); Fifth/ Self- Employment Programme for the Urban Poor (SEPUP)
1976 Nehru Rojgar Yojana (NRY); Seventh / 1989
Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP); Sixth / 1980 Swarna Jayanti Shahari Rojgar Yojana (SJSRY); Ninth/ 1997
Integrated Wastelands Development Programme (IWDP);
Seventh/1988 PUBLIC DISTRIBUTION SYSTEM (PDS)
Employment Assurance Scheme (EAS); Eight/ 1993 Antoyodaya Anna Yojana (AAY); Ninth/ 2000
National Social Assistance Programme (NSAP); Eight/ 1995 Annapurna ; Ninth/ 2000
Indira Awaas Yojana (IAY); Eight/ 1996
Swarn Jayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojana (SJGSY); Ninth/ 1999 SELECTED SPECIAL PROGRAMMES
Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana (JGSY); Ninth/ 1999
Integrated Development of Small and Medium Towns (IDSMT);
Credit cum Subsidy Scheme (CSS); Ninth/ 1999
Fifth/ 1979
Samagra Awaas Yojana (SAY); Ninth/ 1999
Low-Cost Sanitation (LCS); Sixth/ 1980Mega City Project
Rural Sanitation Scheme; Ninth/ 1999
(MCP); Eight/ 1993
Pradhan Mantri’s Gramodaya Yojana (PMGY); Ninth/ 2000
Accelerated Urban Water Supply Programme (AUWSP); Eight/
Food for Work Programme (FWP); Ninth/ 2001
1993
Economically Weaker Sections (EWS) Housing; First/ 1952
Providing Solid Waste Management and Drainage in Ten Selected
Urban Community Development (UCD); Third/ 1966
Towns having Airfields of India Air Force; Ninth/ 1999
Environmental Improvement of Urban Slums (EIUS); Fourth/
1972
Sources:
Sites and Services (S&S); Fifth/ 1974
Government of India, Annual Plan, 2001–2, Planning
Urban Basic Services for the Poor (UBSP); Eight/ 1992
Commission, New Delhi.
Prime Minister’s Integrated Urban Poverty Eradication
Government of India, Annual Report, 2001–2, Planning
Programme (PMIUPEP)
Commission, New Delhi.
National Slum Development Programme (NSDP); Eight/ 1996
Government of India, Approach paper to the Tenth Five Year
National Housing and Habitat Policy (NSHP); Ninth/ 1998
Plan- 2002–7, Planning Commission, New Delhi, 2001.
Government of India, Ninth Five Year Plan,1997–2002,
Thematic Issues and Sectoral Programmes, Planning Commission,
a Prepared by Mukesh P. Mathur Vol. II, New Delhi.

2.2 BUDGETARY PROCESSES: A POLITICAL ECONOMY PERSPECTIVE

Ashima Goyal

The perspective taken in this Section 2.2 is that political infrastructure spending, with some restraints on political-
structure influences incentives, choices, including those of bureaucratic choices, could create incentives for rapid
politicians, and their outcomes in a country. Historical growth. Growth eases political adjustments. It makes longer-
shocks and past administrative choices are responsible for term sustainable redistribution feasible, and raises returns
the current structure. Budgetary processes and policy are to choices that improve human capital. The popular
generally endogenous. There exist leverage points for change awareness of the long-term consequences of past choices
(Morris, 2001), and change can be rapid once it reaches that were focused on the short-term, and the bankruptcy
a critical mass. Well-coordinated macro policy, including of governments, may make some changes incentive-
compatible for politicians. Others would require public
The paper was presented at a workshop on the India Infrastructure awareness and pressure.
Report (IIR), 2003. Comments from and discussions with the Section 2.2 surveys theory, and the experiences of India
participants were very useful. The author thanks Arindam Das- and other countries to bring out the systemic incentives
Gupta, and Sebastian Morris for generous inputs, and Niraj Goyal
for helping her understand the cost and responsibility accounting
that affect political behaviour, government budgets, and
successfully introduced in a multi-national company. expenditure. The surveys are all partial. For example, only
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 49

the incentive features of choices made by fast-growing One definition of politics is ‘a mechanism for making
countries, such as the US and China, are explored. It is collective choices, for gaining power and using it in a
not possible to do justice to the enormous debate on India’s conflict of interest among economic actors.’ Political
development vis-à-vis the political economy. Although the economics recognizes the existence of political constraints
rapidly expanding debate on governance30 addresses some that cause actual policies to differ from optimal policies.
of these issues, the latters’ role in India’s developmental It leads to a normative research programme for discovering
history has been somewhat neglected. It is necessary to try which policy-making institutions produce better policy
to understand why policies that are known to be desirable outcomes. Since policies are endogenous, change can come
are not implemented, and what changes would make them only by changing underlying institutions. Ideology and
more feasible. The new feature is the emphasis on even ideals have a role in political decisions, but once
disincentives built in due to responses to macro shocks, perverse incentives affect a critical mass, it becomes difficult
given the structure and history. for the few to resist the trend.
There is a large body of recent theoretical and empirical A planner’s optimal solution frequently differs from one
work in the new political economics literature on the that is influenced by political forces. A planner’s solution
incentive effects of budgetary procedures and political for aggregating individual preferences to maximize social
processes. Lessons have been extracted both from theory welfare is Pareto efficient so that no one individual can
and country experience relevant to Indian conditions. be made better off without making another worse off. The
outcome is always on the Pareto frontier or set of such
SOURCES OF SURPLUS Pareto efficient points. In political economics the focus is
on the political process by which the policy choice emerges.
Laffont (1999) remarks that economists can serve as Therefore the outcome may not maximize social welfare,
technicians and give politicians information which will help and may not even be Pareto efficient. If a mechanism can
them favour their constituency at the expense of other be designed that moves society to the efficient point, a
groups. This leads to a worse average outcome. But they surplus becomes available that may help to incentivize the
have an alternative. ‘By suggesting constitutional rules which mechanism. The electoral process throws up political power,
decrease the discretion of politicians even at the cost of and the political process in its quest for appeasing
some efficiency losses, economists can enhance expected heterogeneous interests, determines expenditure allocations.
social welfare.’ This approach differs from the earlier Chicago Are changes that can lower waste and improve outcomes
school political analysis, since the latter took the political possible in these deep-seated institutions and processes?
structure as given and uncontrollable. It focused on interest Public goods are non-excludable so there is a free rider
groups and the deadweight losses of rent seeking activities problem in their provision, although some infrastructure
but ignored asymmetric information which gives the source can be priced. If consumers cannot be excluded from
or supply side of influence activities. Transaction costs and consumption of a good there is no direct incentive for
information imperfections are one reason for the inefficient them to pay for the good, leading to the collective action
political equilibrium, and potential distributive benefits. problem. In the latter, the net benefit to a participant in
Simple rules that take these factors into account reduce any group activity, after subtracting costs from gross benefits
inefficiencies and yield extra output which is then available arising from contributions to the group’s activity may be
to implement the rules. If political economy is a game of negative. It is analogous to the Prisoner’s Dilemma Game
redistribution of rents, the economics of incentives provides (PDG), in that, the rational outcome where everyone
the necessary tools for modelling interest-group rent capture maximizes their own welfare makes everyone worse off
as a function of deeper economic parameters. Hoff and since now public goods are under-provided (Hardin, 1982).
Stiglitz (2001) argue that for deep changes to be possible, There is a natural role for the state in coordinating to the
it is necessary to understand political interests. The role better equilibrium31. Thus although politics is about power,
of the politician is then in between, neither like the predatory conflicts, and re-distribution, it is also about solving the
Government of the Public Choice School, nor like the
optimal planner of neo-classical theory. The surplus out of 31 Basu (2000) argues for this view of the state and of law, as
change can be used in ways that further enhance it, which an equilibrium selection device, that solves a coordination failure.
in turn makes cumulative improvement possible. Since both are endogenous, they can change only the selection of
equilibrium, not the economy game. He points out that it was the
30 In particular the IIR, (3iNetwork, 2001 and 2002) focus on 19th century British philosopher, Hume, who first understood the
regulation and governance in the context of infrastructure. See the role of the state in this way. While our collective action problem
overview chapters by Morris (2001, 2002), and others by Anant and gives rise to a PDG, there can also be a simpler coordination failure
Singh, Morris, Pandey, and Varma. with multiple Nash equilibria.
50 India Infrastructure Report 2003

collective action problem. It can do this by changing zero effect because creative accounting was often able to violate
or negative sum conflicts into interactions that yield a their spirit33. For example, fiscal restrictions affected the
potential surplus. debt mix, but not the total. There was a shift to non-
To sum up, externalities can arise from higher growth, guaranteed debt. Indian national and sub-national
asymmetric information rents, and coordination problems. governments are also able to hide deficits by juggling
These are all potential sources of surplus, which if realized, extraordinary expenditure categories and so on. The problem
can incentivize change. But the collective action failure that is compounded by difficulties in measuring government
gives rise to coordination problems influences political and debt or deficits. Internal as well as external incentives for
budget processes. Asymmetric information adds ineffi- budget control are therefore required in addition to laws.
ciencies to the latter two. All these influence growth, which Examples of the former include norms, ethics, and accepted
is itself a source of surplus. Therefore deep and sustainable practices. Better-designed budgets should make it easier
change needs to act on these foundations. to plan and run programmes, and together with more
Dominant international ideas have influenced Indian transparency, work to increase voter pressure to limit
policy-makers. Independent India inherited a strong state, budget sizes. It would remedy the frequent complaint of
and wartime controls, from the British. The dominant Indian local governments about the imposition of rigid
development idea was of state-led industrialization. But as budgetary practices from above, without a consideration
growth slowed down after about ten years, political pressures of local needs and capabilities. Flexibility would moderate
resulted in direct short-term transfers that had indirect and the effect of rigid budget laws in inducing a larger initial
non-obvious long-term costs. The incentive properties of size to take care of unforeseen contingencies.
these interventions only harmed growth. Current dominant
ideas that suggest a more balanced role of government give Budgetary Procedures
an opportunity to set right some of these distortions. One basic reason a democratic government may end up
overspending is the common pool problem. This arises
BUDGETARY INSTITUTIONS whenever spending decisions are made in a decentralized
way, in favour of different groups, and the tax rate is then
Theoretical models allow sharp derivations of the residually determined. The concentrated benefits are fully
consequences of structure and behaviour. If the aspects internalized, but each group internalizes only a fraction of
focused on are dominant in real economies, such models the social marginal cost of the tax increase required for
aid in understanding actual tendencies at work. In the next funding, since the pool of tax revenue available for funding
two sub-sections we present such model-dependent results32, is common. There exist specific procedures to help
where the models capture some relevant aspects of Indian overcome the problem, and limit the size of the deficit.
reality, related to budgetary institutions and political Some that have been examined analytically and tested
processes. We briefly indicate in what respect the model empirically are discussed.
or result is relevant to India. In the sub-section ‘History’, Consider the following stylized budgetary process. Any
these results are used to explain aspects of a more detailed one representative, chosen to be the agenda setter, makes
Indian developmental history. a policy proposal. The legislature votes on the proposal,
The major rules and institutions that determine if a simple majority approves, it is implemented, otherwise
government spending are quantitative limits or budget the status quo remains. This is known as a closed rule since
laws, and procedural rules. Finally, implementation methods proposals cannot be amended. It turns out that spending
and tax-transfer policies also affect incentives. will be lower if ministers without constituencies, such as
the Prime Minister or the finance minister, are given
Laws and Rules special powers. These include agenda setting rights, right
of veto, and setting binding limits on allocations. It should
Limits can be legislated on different government deficits be clear who is responsible for an observed abuse of power.
and debt or targets set, and ceilings put on expenditure.
But it is always possible to evade a budget law. Empirical
33 See Drazen (2000), pp. 701. The Enron, Anderson and
work, with data for the US states, has shown that laws were
complied with but only in letter. The laws had very little WorldCom debacles have highlighted a similar problem in American
corporate governance. The letter of the law is often followed, but
many innovations including off balance sheet items violate its spirit.
32
The survey in this and the next sub-section is largely based Proposed reforms include stricter CEO accountability, control of
on Blanchard (2000), Drazen (2000), Goyal (1999, 2001), Laffont conflict of interest in the board of governors, transparency, and
(1999), and Persson and Tabellini (1999, 2000, 2002). market discipline.
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 51

This hierarchical process strengthens collective interests, 1999). But still deficits were in control until the period
against the selfish interests of ministers who, under a more of unstable coalition governments and competitive populism
democratic decision process, would push the interests of that set in from the 1980s. Although there are pre-budget
their specific constituencies. The drawback is that minority meetings with the different interest groups, these tend to
interests can be neglected. In addition, if the status quo be routine. Widespread media debate after the budget
entails zero-base budgeting, this acts as a further disciplining speech can lead to substantive changes34. A vote is taken
factor to control excess spending, since in that case the in the legislature before the budget bill is passed.
default alternative involves minimal spending. The basic
reason separation of powers reduces expenditure is because Implementation
it removes conflict of interest; whoever cuts slices from
Budgetary implementation through control and monitoring
the cake should not be responsible for the distribution of
make incentives low powered. The use of self-motivation
the slices. The agent who has proposal rights over expenditure
is minimal; agents are supposed to obey instructions. This
should not be the one who stands to directly gain from works better for simple processes or in the early stages of
it. The countervailing pressures generated induce, although development or planning when effective and low-cost
they may not ensure, a more fair and efficient division. monitoring is feasible. In more complex processes monitoring
Under an open rule other legislators have amendment needs to be complemented by delegation to residual
rights, and there can be separation of proposal powers. For claimants. The latter have high-powered incentives, since
example, there may be a vote on an amendment offered the returns from greater efficiency stay with them. Such
on an initial proposal, with further rounds of amendments. changes characterize the movement from planning to more
Although the possibility of amendments in the budgetary market-led development. If politicians plan to stay in power
process increases the size of the deficit, there is a theoretical for long, campaign contributions are important, and there
result that wasteful expenditure can be higher under a is little competition so that reputation does not matter, they
closed rule compared to an open rule (Baron, 1991). The will still prefer simple command-and-controls mechanisms
reason is, if legislators are forward looking and sophisticated, (Laffont, 1999). In India political fragmentation occurred
they internalize the stages of the budget process. Therefore rather than competition. Reputations were uniformly bad
in order for them to support a budget proposal, when no and a system was not devised for campaign funding.
amendments are allowed, the net benefits they gain must Therefore politicians clung to discretionary power to be
exceed those that could be expected if the proposal was able to implement short-term transfers and secure votes.
defeated and the budgetary process continued. To gain Following the control philosophy, budgetary
majority support such a proposal needs to be large enough implementation in India, although quite detailed, tends to
to please everyone. There may be non-budgetary or office focus on monitoring inputs. This makes participants strategic
related payoffs. and forward looking in trying to maximize their allocations,
A similar problem as occurs in the closed rule can defeat but with no incentives for delivery. The horizon is very
two-stage budgeting (2SB). Under 2SB, aggregate spending short-term regarding outcomes. Modern management
is decided before allocations of expenditure in order to information systems, in contrast, clearly allocate res-ponsibility
insulate the total from interest group pressures. But if for outcomes, measured as variance from budgeted amounts,
sophisticated legislators realize the implications of their right down the hierarchy, together with continuous feedback.
decisions for subsequent appropriations, 2SB need not Mid-term correction is possible and delivery is ensured.
lower budget size in equilibrium. A larger size would be The system is transparent and incentives are very different.
set at the first stage. The value of 2SB in lowering budgetary Daily expenditure control and tax-transfer mechanisms
waste has empirical support, however. Particularly when also affect budgetary implementation. One such mechanism
there are agency problems the separation of powers in 2SB is user charges for public services. In India, as a populist
helps voters to discipline their agents, the legislators. For measure in the context of low growth and major cost
example, if the agenda setter is not the ‘residual claimant’ shocks of the early 1970s, many such user charges were
at the second stage, he will have no interest in expanding frozen. Apart from expanding budget deficits, this had
the budget.
In Indian central government budget practices, primary 34 An example of this is the rollbacks announced in 2002. The

responsibility for the budget-size does lie with the finance budget initially attempted to burden the middle classes. It was
minister and the Prime Minister, although budgets tend perceived to be unfair and there was widespread protest in the media.
Finance Minister Sinha’s response was that he was not out to win
to be incremental so that this is not really exercised. And a popularity contest, but the Prime Minister intervened after the BJP
forward-looking beneficiaries are able to get what they lost some by-elections, a new, more politically savvy, finance minister
want by, for example, padding salary bills (Das-Gupta, was brought in who announced concessions for the middle class.
52 India Infrastructure Report 2003

major incentive effects on the provision of public services. Since the preferences of voters and their elected
Exploring these will help to understand the disincentives representatives are not perfectly aligned there is an agency
built into the Indian system. problem. Elected politicians know more than the voters do,
Two extremes in pricing rules have opposite effects on so that there will be information rents associated with the
the incentives of a provider of a public good or service, provision of any public service. A stronger media and other
to lower cost or to improve quality. With a price cap, measures to improve transparency can lower such rents, but
incentives are high-powered since the residual profit share not eliminate them altogether. Revelation mechanisms, such
lies with the producer. The latter is motivated to decrease as supervision or separation of powers, cannot fully extract
costs. Since rate of return regulation reimburses the cost politicians’ information (rent) or prevent the politician from
of the service, incentives are low-powered. Profits from favouring interest groups, unless there is perfect enforcement
improvements do not stay with the producer. Thus there by courts, perfect foresight, and rationality.
is a trade-off between rent extraction and providing There are three degrees of freedom—the electoral
incentives for additional effort. With a low enough price structure which selects the politician with residual control
cap the regulator extracts all rent, but incentives to invest rights, the discretionary decisions left with him, and the
and improve quality may fall. Since costs rise with quality non-contracted states of nature. There is a trade-off between
low-powered incentives are required for the provision of rents and efficiency. If the decisions of the politician are
quality. There is a disincentive to invest in the presence restricted, his discretion and rent or political capital-taking
of low price caps also because sunk costs made for falls, but ex-post efficiency may also be destroyed. If
investment may be expropriated. If even costs are not politicians chosen as residual decision- makers for ex-ante
covered rent is over-extracted35. non-contractible social decisions have more instruments
Optimal cross-subsidization is derived if social welfare available, the outcome is more efficient and, the under-
is maximized, subject to a budget constraint. This gives utilized surplus from asymmetric information is less, but
the Ramsey–Boiteux rule that the price marginal cost gap they have more discretion to favour their own constituencies.
should be inversely proportional to elasticities of demand.
Thus the poor should be charged higher prices if they have Separation of Powers
a lower elasticity of demand, but they can be cross-subsidized
as long as the budget is balanced. The rule has been The Constitution uses separation of powers, checks and
generalized into the theory of optimal non-linear tariffs. balances, and elections to align incentives, but it is an
These pricing principles are violated if, in the aggregate, incomplete contract. Under non-Contractability about ex-
charges do not even cover costs. Cross-subsidization is post states of nature there are cases where the constitution
then excessive and generates inefficiencies that raise cost provides no guidance and the politician has residual control
further. Moreover, competitive entry occurs if, with cross- rights. Features such as a specific allocation of proposal
subsidization, the price in any sub-market exceeds cost, and veto rights, that create a conflict of interest among
or if new technology lowers cost or breaks a natural politicians, can reduce the rent they capture.
monopoly. Then government revenues from these sub- One conflict of interest that the Constitution builds in
sectors fall further. This happened in the Indian is that between the legislature which makes laws, and the
telecommunication sector where expensive international judiciary which interprets them. The judge-based system
calls were used to subsidize local calls. imposed by the British government, was based on legislative
The underlying political structure influences the budget statutes meant to keep a subject-nation in control, unlike
processes adopted. This is discussed in the next sub-section. their own common law tradition based on past judgements.
There was a strong contempt of court clause to give more
power to the judges. Even after independence the heavy use
POLITICAL PROCESSES of law continued in order to enforce development, to enable
Since the focus is on systemic incentives, the role of confiscation of property, etc. So the legal system functioned
individual politicians, their leadership or the lack of it, is as an instrument of the government. Judges were also
abstracted from. It is possible for individuals to rise above expected to interpret the Constitution to maintain individual
a perverse system, but the majority gets affected adversely. liberty and social justice, and defend the weak against the
Consider voters (the principals) who delegate control rights strong. Conflicts often arose with the government. In the
and collective decision-making to elected officers (their 1980s public interest litigation (PIL) became a useful way
agents) because of costly and asymmetric information. to put pressure on the executive to deliver, and to cover
lapses in legislating, as governance failed. Conflicts
35
Many chapters in IIR 2001 cover these issues in detail. See sharpened; some landmark judgements were made. Since
the overview in 3iNetwork (2001). legislators will not pass laws against themselves they resist
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 53

attempts to enforce greater probity and transparency on alternative candidates are good substitutes for voters. But
them, leading some commentators to suggest an independent often neither condition holds. In conditions where pleasing
law board to pass laws that affect legislators (Haldea, 2002). the voters is very costly, or the politician has more discretion,
But there are limits to judge-based activism. Too much he may choose to grab as much rent as possible. Voters
power to any one arm tends to corrupt it. It also goes can punish a candidate if he has not performed, but the
against the native Indian jury system of wise men who did punishment is ex-post, not ex-ante. Reputation may not
not directly confront the ruler, but reminded him indirectly be sufficient to enforce ex-ante discipline if alternatives
of the Dharmashastras and local norms. Judicial instincts available are poor, as in India, where all politicians are
retain enough of the old value-based system to moderate tarred with the same brush.
conflict (Dhawan in Frankel et al., 2000). Moreover, the The structure of elections, written in a country’s
rule of law is expected to aid development of markets by Constitution, also affects politicians’ incentives. A
upholding certain basic principles, and ensuring representative democracy may have proportional or
predictability in transactions across agents, over space, and majoritarian (‘first-past-the-post’) voting. India has the latter
time (Trubeck, 1972). Excessive legislation, regulation, or system. In the pure form of the first, parties are given seats
judgements, can impede these developments and restrict proportional to their overall vote total. A minimum percentage
individual liberties, leading to corruption and delays, which vote is required for a party to enter a legislature. In the
make a mockery of the law. India has an archaic, second, each district elects a single member by plurality
cumbersome system of laws whose basic underlying principle vote. Varying mixtures of the two systems are possible. The
of control is no longer relevant. There are huge backlogs way voter preferences reflect in electoral outcomes will
and delays in justice. If the law is ineffective, then more differ in the two systems, especially when there are more
of it, or imposing stricter punishment, may not work. than two parties. In general, under proportional elections
Instead, simplifying it, and bringing it closer to the way in a single national district, the incumbent needs the support
people actually live, may work. Judges also do not have of a broader coalition of voters. So he provides more public
the technical knowledge to pass judgements on areas where goods, which serve a larger population. Under single member
expertise lies with the executive and should therefore just districts and plurality rule, it is necessary to win only in a
enforce contracts (Anant and Singh, 2002); other means few pivotal districts. Therefore incumbents make transfers
to smaller geographic voter-groups. This tendency has
of ensuring better governance are still required.
exacerbated India’s regional and caste-based electoral
Hardin (1999) argues that a Constitution is not only
polarization. A downside of proportional elections is since
a contract but also a coordination device that can serve
voters vote on party lists rather than for single individuals,
to moderate group conflicts and push society to a better
corruption and equilibrium rent rise for politicians. Their
outcome. Constitutions differ across countries. Hardin
incentives to work for voters fall.
suggests that the US Constitution, while protecting individual
Both voters and parties can behave strategically so
liberty, property rights, and social justice, was able to
conclusions have to be drawn with care. Even so, when there
coordinate the society around commerce and prosperity.
is sharp polarization among voters and multiple parties, the
Universal suffrage did not lead to expropriation as was
representatives of smaller parties in the legislature will normally
initially feared; opportunities expanded for the less well-
be below their strength in the electorate. But their power
off also. Elster (1995) has argued that since it requires a in the government may be disproportionate, because if no
super majority to change the Constitution, it is a means party has a majority they may be critical in a coalition.
of credibly binding the government against future reneging, Therefore legislative influence may not be monotonic in
much as Ulysses bound himself against the sirens. This vote share. For example, in a model with three parties it
reassures against future imposts and expands social surplus can be shown that first and third ranked parties form the
available. The Indian Constitution has many of these governing coalition (Austen-Smith and Banks, 1988). Voters
desirable features, and can serve such a purpose, but the will vote strategically, rather than sincerely. Sincere voting
electoral structure built in has had adverse effects. is according to actual preferences, and strategic takes account
of other’s choices. Opportunistic candidates will allow for
Electoral Structure this in taking up pre-election positions. Under proportional
Given the Constitution, elections impose ex-post discipline, voting the share of minorities in the legislature can increase,
and, together with lobbying and legislative bargaining, but their importance in winning and losing falls. It is not
influence outcomes. One general principle is that forward- true that a coalition government will necessarily be unstable36,
looking private maximization can lead to extreme outcomes, 36 While, in Italy, coalition governments have been highly
reversing institutional safeguards. Elections limit rent unstable, Germany, Luxemburg, and Austria have been governed by
extraction only if electoral promises are binding and if coalition governments, over much of the post-war period.
54 India Infrastructure Report 2003

but if there is a pivotal party this will dictate policy preferences. common interest. In a careful empirical study of the
Thus those with a small block of votes may have large power outcomes associated with democracy, Tavares and Wacziarg
if they are required to help form the government. In India, (2001) find that democracy reduces growth by reducing
since the 1990s, unstable minority-dependent coalition physical capital and raising government consumption, but
governments have become the rule. Shifting to some form stimulates growth by improving human capital and reducing
of proportional voting may increase the share of minorities inequality. Redistribution is responsible for the second set
but decrease their power, and make for more stable of factors, but excessive redistribution for the first set. Our
governments. argument is that the second set can dominate if interest
An interesting question is, will parties pamper swing groups are reconciled in a way that helps long-term growth,
voters, whose loyalties are fluid, or will they target core for example, by developing human capital rather than
supporters? The latter could either be groups they can making short-term consumption transfers (Goyal, 2001).
reach effectively, or those who are ideologically fully In the sub-section, ‘History’, we find these conceptual
committed to the party. Opportunistic politicians will categories to be useful in interpreting the Indian experience.
favour core supporters if they believe that is the cheapest
way to buy votes, otherwise they will take them for granted HISTORY
and court swing voters who may switch votes in exchange
for favours. Core supporters may even be taxed since the If the various aspects of the structure of an economy are
party knows how to effectively extract resources from captured by a theory, it is useful as an aid in bringing out
them, without any change in their loyalty. Indian voters underlying causal factors, and explaining stylized historical
have understood this and are beginning to insist on facts. Although one must always be aware that in a complex
performance, rather than being satisfied with ideology. system there are multiple interacting tendencies, the focus
There are dramatic reversals in election results and here is on the consequences of political structure and
incumbents often lose elections. macroeconomic shocks. These partly explain the perverse
If an electoral system favours many small parties, administrative choices and incentives that were built in.
governments tend to have short horizons and avoid tackling India has a parliamentary democracy, which is expected
hard choices. Grilli, Masciandaro and Tabellini (1991) find to lead to broader redistribution, larger government, and
that in Organization for Economic Cooperation and more public goods. It has majoritarian, as opposed to
Development (OECD) countries with such systems debts proportional, elections, which lead to less public goods,
and deficits rise. The greater the government more targeted transfers and larger government. They also
fractionalization, that is, the greater the number of policy- lead to less representation, but more power for minorities
making veto actors, the more difficult it is to devise plans under multiple parties and coalition governments. India’s
that distribute costs neutrally among their various poverty, caste, religious, and regional heterogeneity added
constituencies (Franzese, 2002). Therefore, reducing to the effects of the electoral structure as multiple parties
fractionalization in Indian politics is a priority. appeared. Provision of public goods has been falling and
A presidential-congressional regime is an alternative to transfers targeted to well-defined electoral groups have
a parliamentary regime. Equilibrium rents are lower in the been rising after the 1970s. We argue that these ill effects
first as separation of powers and conflict among politicians and pressures became apparent after growth faltered in the
help voters control the agency problem. But the presidential mid-1960s.
system supplies less public goods and more targeted
redistribution compared to the parliamentary system since, Macroeconomic Events
under the latter, incentives to form broad stable coalitions The post-war control regime was continued in order to
are higher. Thus, if public goods are under-provided, the target accelerated planned development with equity,
parliamentary system is better, but if rent extraction is high according to the development ideas of the time (Patel,
or punishment from losing the next election is small because 2001). This worked reasonably until the late 1960s when
entry barriers are high, the presidential system would work there was a growth slowdown, partly due to a series of
better for voters. In India public goods are under-provided shocks. There were, of course, inefficiencies due to the
and pressures to increase their supply must be maintained, import substitution regime, and the failure to carry out
so that a parliamentary system should be better suited. land reforms and develop a broad demand base. The
The democratic voice is valuable and must be preserved. country had not been able to make much of a dent on
It allows robust institutions to develop that reconcile poverty. This was also the period of the oil shocks and
different interests and make it possible to implement the sharp peaks in inflation, which hurt the poor. Realizing
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 55

that the latter were a large vote block37, Indira Gandhi were derived from the Congress in various ways. The third
coined the slogan of ‘garibi hatao’38, and used it aggressively phase, starting with the state assembly elections of 1993–
in the early 1970s, in her political battle with the old 5, was of a competitive multi-party system. In the 1998
Congress Guard. Disregarding the rise in costs, several elections, the Election Commission registered 176 parties;
user charges were kept fixed, which led to more and more 41 won representation to the Lok Sabha, but of these 7
distortions. In the years that followed, subsidies and transfers had two or three members and 14 had one member each
increased while current and future provision of public (Frankel, 2000). The current National Democratic Alliance
goods suffered. As these effects cumulated, the revenue (NDA) coalition of 1998, led by the Bhartiya Janta Party
deficit became positive, or government consumption (BJP), is the first genuinely non-Congress government.
exceeded its income. Figure 2.2.1, shows that the first year As the Congress lost dominance and intense multi-party
the revenue deficit became positive was in 1980–1 and it competition set in, populist schemes multiplied. By the
grew every year after that. The government was now 1980s populist Central Sponsored Schemes (CSS) became
borrowing for consumption, and accumulating debt. These a way for the central government to directly reach the
policies, once implemented, set in vicious or virtuous self- masses. New schemes were announced every year, although
sustaining dynamics partly by creating interest groups or targeting was poor and waste and corruption proliferated.
constituencies they favoured39. The majoritarian democratic With multiple competing parties, swing votes became very
regime was emphasizing targeted transfers at the expense important for winning in our first-past-the-post system.
of public goods. Identity politics, based on caste and religion, was a way
of cultivating these swing voters. The Congress cultivated
40000 the Muslim vote, encouraging a conservative backlash40.
Yadav provides evidence that electoral participation by
30000 minorities and backward castes has risen since the 1970s,
compared to other groups. He calls this the ‘second
20000
democratic upsurge’ (Frankel, 2000). Sometimes minority
1000 groups had enough electoral power to swing outcomes in
their favour, for example, when parties representing them
0 were pivotal in a coalition. Defections and frequent
elections, as was the norm with unstable coalition
–10000 governments, meant that politicians were concerned only
1980–81
1972–3
1974–5
1976–7
1978–9

1982–3
1984–5
1986–7
1988–9
1990–1
1992–3
1994–5

with the votes that would get them to power. Once in


power they were concerned with ‘loot’ in order to buy votes
and legislators in the future. Since state elections were
Fig. 2.2.1 Revenue Deficit (Rs Crores) separated from those at the centre in 1971 (Jha, 2002),
frequent elections kept this pressure up continually and
Political Changes
harmed longer-term development.
Political fragmentation made matters worse. In the first The democratic empowerment of the poor, with the
twenty years after independence the Congress Party provided lower castes and regional parties acquiring voice and vote,
a stable government. There was no serious opposition. A was a positive and necessary development in the path to
period of bipolar consolidation followed, with the gradual a stable, mature, and inclusive democracy. But it further
development of an opposition system to the Congress encouraged identity politics. The first reaction of new parties
(Frankel, 2000). The Congress first lost the elections after to the acquisition of power was consumption transfers to
the Emergency of the mid-1970s. In 1979, 1989 and the their support groups, especially as belief in a vibrant future
mid-1990s different governments were formed, but all was missing since the development policies of the past had
not delivered growth. Institutions of governance were
37 For example, 60 percent of Mumbai’s population lives in
undermined. Pai (2002) documents how, in Uttar Pradesh
slums, providing a concentrated target for politicians. This is not to (UP), identity and caste politics were responsible for poor
rule out that some politicians may be sincerely concerned to better
the lot of the people. But they still did not use the most effective 40 Vote bank politics created bitterness and set the communities
means of doing so. against each other. In Gujarat, Narendra Modi’s inaction and the
38 She first used the term while intervening in a debate in the NDA’s support to his government despite accumulating evidence of
Lok Sabha on the Constitution (24th Amendments Bill, 4 August the state government’s failure and even complicity in the anti-Muslim
1971, see GOI, 1975). riots of March–April 2002, are said to be motivated by the BJP’s
39 Stiglitz and Hoff (2001) develop the idea of past choices recent election losses, and the assembly elections due in Gujarat.
creating interest groups under the concept of dynamic political economy. Playing the Hindu card became an electoral strategy for the BJP.
56 India Infrastructure Report 2003

governance and low development expenditure. Each short- also subsidized this further reduced government revenues,
term coalition government reversed jobs given to other apart from raising pollution levels. The average rate per
caste groups and put its own group in positions of power. passenger kilometre was raised from 4 paise in 1980–1
Frequent transfers of officials politicized and demotivated to 15 paise in 1991–2, but the rise in the average rate per
the bureaucracy. It is true, as Pandian (2002) points out, tonne kilometre was more over the same period (from 10.5
that arguments about the common good and efficiency can to 35.1 paise), although the demand for freight is more
be used to keep the oppressed down. A creative ferment elastic. International call charges were kept high, to subsidize
is necessary for them to come up, but the policies followed domestic calls; again the aim was to tax the rich and
do not have to be regressive if a longer-term perspective subsidize the poor. In 1998, the cost of calling the USA
is taken. In the states of south India where the movement using Internet telephony was Rs 4 per minute but the
is older, it has achieved progressive reform, emphasizing public sector monopoly charged Rs 75 per minute.
education, and going beyond symbolic gestures such as Companies formed in the USA made it possible to call
building memorials to Ambedkar. from India and pay abroad. Thus price distortions invited
the entry of companies and the government could not
Administrative Choices retain its domestic monopoly and lost revenue. As new
technology and companies enter and cut international call
Administrative choices led by the populist stance, made
rates, the public sector giants are being forced to follow
matters worse. After the oil shocks, and in the presence
suit41. This is the history against which reform is taking
of an inflation sensitive electorate, many prices of public
place in the provision of public sector services.
services were kept fixed; incentives and efficiencies were
The special powers of the finance minister and the
sacrificed for consumption re-distribution. The choices
Prime Minister were not able to protect the Central Budget
made amounted to protecting the poor through current
once the era of competitive populism set in. In addition,
transfers, rather than building their assets and human
perverse incentives adopted in the accounting procedures,
capital, when it was the latter that was the sustainable
led to problems on both the revenue and expenditure side.
option. This was a rational social outcome because the rich
Budgeting is only incremental, with a mechanical increase
could often escape imposts in the long-term, and the poor
in Plan expenditure42. The division between Plan and non-
had high discount rates and pessimistic growth projections.
Plan expenditures, together with the focus on starting new
The objective of providing government services at
schemes, has harmed maintenance. After the shocks of the
affordable prices led to cross-subsidization both in the
1970s, as fund constraints appeared, it was easier to
provision of specific products and across government
postpone investment plans. Moreover, decision-making
functions. Low price-caps for many public goods led to
and monitoring procedures became inadequate as
systematic incentives to lower quality and investment. Thus
complexity increased and contributed to delays.
falling efficiency and rising costs compounded the problem
The centre has constitutional powers to restrict borrowing
of low user charges, and prevented a natural fall in prices
by states, and states do not have the ability to monetize
from improvements in technology and organization. But
their debt43. This works to limit their deficits but a
where the government had monopoly power and was servicing
number of avenues are available to soften their budget
the rich, prices were raised much above costs of production,
constraint. Disbursements from the Finance Commission,
or indirect charges, such as the prices of intermediate
Central Schemes and the Planning Commission are multi-
goods, which were not obvious to voters, were raised (Morris,
2001). As the rich turned to private providers, revenue 41 See Goyal (1999) for more details and examples. IIR (2001)
losses contributed to the inability to service the poor documents many such examples. The point made (see Morris, 2001)
adequately. The cross-subsidization was not sufficient to that cross-subsidization often raised the prices of intermediate goods,
cover costs. General revenues did not even cover government again provides evidence of the politician’s tendency to give short-
term or direct benefits at the expense of rising long-term or indirect
consumption expenditures, as the widening revenue deficit costs.
shows. Long-term human and physical capital formation 42 These points are well accepted in the Indian debate. Amaresh
(including infrastructure) were harmed. Again we see public Bagchi and Govinda Rao reiterated them at a meeting in IGIDR
good provision suffering in order to raise targeted transfers. and at a Mumbai University seminar respectively in 2001. See also
Power, telecommunications, railways, roads, education, Rao (2002).
43 Armijo (2002) argues that since inflation hurt the poor, and
all illustrate the effects of these incentives. Quality and
there was universal franchise, macro policies were conservative in
availability of services fell. Poor quality served as a cost India. One aspect of this was limits on the states’ ability to
that lowered consumption demand. For example, freight undertake deficit financing. In Brazil, where universal franchise was
rates were raised to subsidize passenger travel. The railways granted only in 1986, credit limits on states were lower and inflation
steadily lost customers to diesel trucks. Since diesel was much higher.
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 57

purpose, poorly designed, and, therefore, fungible. The environment indirect benefits are often discounted because
presence of multi-lateral lending institutions may worsen of their uncertainty and greater chance of going to others.
the problem. States can float special purpose vehicles to Moreover, in the absence of a viable two-party system voters
borrow funds, and do other smart accounting to soften had little choice. If status quo is lower the agenda setter
budget constraints (see Rao, 2002). Good performance has can extract more of the surplus from voters. In the more
not been rewarded, so even though more equality in recent period, however, a strong anti-incumbency vote has
revenue sharing was built in across the states, equality in developed, suggesting that delivery has begun to matter.
per capita incomes was not achieved. The Eleventh Finance Citizens are seeing the long-term consequences of short-
Commission put in some performance incentives, and term populism. Political parties are careful to listen to the
improvements in the states’ revenue collection have been people. There are signs that they have realized this. Governance
reported. On the other side, delays in specific funding is the new slogan; for example, the Congress has moved
further delay projects and expand their costs. Poor from ‘garibi hatao’ to governance at its 2002 meeting.
management practices and bankruptcy is making these Even after reforms and the move towards more market
problems more acute. Low recovery of user charges and oriented high-powered incentives, government procedures
the absence of a service tax are constraining the states’ often continue to be based on the philosophy of monitoring
revenue. The direction of reform towards simpli-fication, and control. Sometimes rules and procedures appropriate
rationalization, and harmonization is well known, but is in one stage persist in another where they become harmful.
not being speedily implemented, even after being initiated Many improvements are possible, but deep and sustainable
in 1993. There are similar problems at the third tier, the changes require addressing the underlying causes. Politicians
Urban Local Bodies (ULBs) and the Panchayats. The centre have to be motivated to push the changes. It may be useful
has not performed its coordinating function well. States here to see how better-performing countries have ensured
were able to hold it to ransom especially as regional parties a stimulating macro-environment and used high-powered
became critical. Adversarial positions taken in negotiations incentives.
on issues that affected a number of parties contributed to
delays (Basu, 1995). The common pool problem was
aggravated and free riding became pervasive. The centre
OTHER COUNTRIES
used its power over states only to impose distorting policies Two countries that have grown rapidly in the past decade
that fragmented markets. and used macro- policy and incentives to do so are China
The choices made led to the conflict between rich and and the US45. Non-transparency moderated international
poor, labour and capital, the present and the future, being pressures and allowed China to use massive fiscal-monetary
handled in a way that lowered incentives for expansion of stimuli according to domestic requirements. One-party
the cake. The plan emphasis was on long-term capital goods dictatorship made it possible to reverse direction quickly
but implementation led to a short-term focus. Redistribution when inflation rose too high. Thus stop-go cycles led to
concentrated on short-term consumption subsidies rather some waste but facilitated required structural changes, and
than on assets, education, health, and infrastructure. The induced high savings. Moreover, China successfully used
poor were needed for votes, the rich for buying votes. Apart economic incentives, even without full property rights. The
from short-term consumption redistribution to woo voters, US succeeded when it shifted from an overly strict budget
the rich were given opportunities for rent seeking in a law to a more realistic one that allowed counter-cyclical
system of controls and distortions44. Labour laws secured fiscal stimulus and monetary accommodation, in an interest
jobs for a small labour elite, but restricted the expansion rate-targeting regime.
of such jobs. Indians became used to direct subsidies and
indirect costs, or short-term benefits and disguised long- The United States of America
term costs. Although these measures did not deliver long-
term benefits voters valued them because in a low-growth In the 1990s, the American budget deficit, which had
mushroomed in the 1980s, was converted into a surplus
44 Bardhan has developed the idea of warring interest groups in while the economy prospered. Among the factors that
a number of articles. Bardhan (2002) sums up his position as that made this achievement possible, were rules that limited
there were multiple interest groups with the power of veto, but no wasteful government expenditure, and allowed monetary
one was strong enough to take over the government. Therefore the
stimulus to which the economy responded. Supply-side tax
collective action problem could not be solved, and the country settled
for short-run transfers at the cost of long-term growth. The position
45 The discussion of the US experience follows that in Goyal
in this Section 2.2 differs in that democracy should be able to achieve
common interests, but macro shocks, the electoral structure, and (2002), and that of China follows Goyal and Jha (2002). See also
administrative choices created perverse incentives in the Indian case. Morris (2002).
58 India Infrastructure Report 2003

cuts in the Reagan era were expected to stimulate output. After 1978, economic decision-making was decentralized
But they could not deliver, and since there was no to farmers, firms, and lower-level governments and incentives
compensating cut in government expenditure, the deficit were given. The people by now had the skills to respond
grew rapidly. It fluctuated around a peak ratio to Gross rapidly. The government policy of ‘crossing the river while
Domestic Product (GDP) of 6.1 per cent in 1983. The feeling the stones’, prevented too large and disruptive changes.
Gramm–Rudman–Hollings Act passed in 1985, set yearly Mistakes were made, but were as quickly reversed.
ceilings for the deficit with a target of a zero deficit by Decentralization and a conscious policy of taking intellectuals
1991. It had some effect, but creative accounting—because abroad, preparing thoroughly, and examining alternate future
of design flaws (including overstrictness)—prevented the scenarios, overcame some of the information inadequacies
realization of the target. The Bill also lost credibility because of a dictatorship. More drastic reforms such as privatization,
a very large deficit was required to fund the 1990 crisis closing down bankrupt banks, restructuring the bureaucracy,
in savings and loan institutions. Therefore, it was replaced and introducing the Voluntary Retirement Scheme (VRS)
by the Budget Enforcement Act of 1990, which corrected were only undertaken in the late 1990s after twenty years
the design flaws shown up by experience. First, rather than of rapid growth. China had always controlled its labour
restrict the deficit itself, constraints were placed only on markets tightly. As the boom in exports absorbed labour and
spending. Caps that enforced small reductions in migration restrictions were relaxed, urban decay was
discretionary spending were set, but escape clauses were minimized through policies like the one that new firms had
provided for emergencies. A ‘pay-as-you-go’ rule meant that to provide housing for workers. The idea was to make those
new transfer payments to individuals could be made only who stood to benefit most from it, to contribute to
if these transfers were demonstrated to have assured funding, infrastructure development.
so that they would not increase deficits in the future. As The official debt GDP ratio remained at around 10 per
revenues fell in a recession, the deficit could increase, since cent, but official data on government debt are suspect.
restraints only covered spending. This macro-stabilization Lower-level borrowing is not well captured. There are
provided another escape clause. Such flexibility lowered many contingent and hidden liabilities in the banking and
pressure to break rules, gave the Act more credibility, and pension systems. Recent reports suggest that, properly
contributed to its success. There was a systematic attention measured, deficit ratios are as high as Indian ones. But
to incentives. For example, there was a shift from matching the lack of transparency and capital controls deflected
to block Federal grants for state welfare payments; the international pressure for macro-stabilization, and allowed
former had motivated the states to overspend. After twenty- them to implement large macro-stimuli and create a good
nine years America had a balanced budget. infrastructure for growth. In the 1998 slowdown, for
example, the fiscal stimulus from large-scale public sector
China infrastructure projects was about 2.5 per cent of GDP.
China is a one-party dictatorship, but before its high growth Rules to restrain credit expansion were enacted later. After
phase, it shared with India the pressures of a large number a new Budget Law in 1995, the central government could
of poor. Both had a rigid bureaucracy and controls that were not borrow from the central bank on current account,
meant to ensure redistribution and to reduce inequalities. although deficit financing was permitted on capital account.
Even without private property rights and functioning markets, The deficit had to be financed with government bonds.
China was quicker than India to decentralize, create intense More stringent budget balance restrictions were imposed
local competition, and incentivize economic decision-making. on local governments. The law strictly controlled their
In India checks on economic decisions created delays and bond issuance and restricted their borrowing in the financial
discouraged productive activity. China focused more clearly market. An independent auditing system was also
on high growth, and was thus able to overcome other introduced for enforcing the budget law.
obstacles and allow the regime to adapt. Till 1993, 70 per cent of the central bank’s loan to state
Partly because of the socialist ideas of equality, without banks were made by the central bank’s local branches,
populist pressures of ensuring votes, protecting the poor which were heavily influenced by the local governments.
largely took the form of human capital development— In 1993, the central bank centralized its operation. In
improvements in health, education, and endowments. 1995, China passed the Central Bank Law to give the
During the period when food remained a major part of central bank the mandate for the monetary policy
the average household budget, adequate supplies and low independent of the local governments. These reforms
prices of essential foods were maintained. As long as these reduced the influence of the local governments on the
minimum requirements were met, the government was monetary policy and credit allocation decisions. In 1998,
able to extract obedience. the central bank replaced its 30 provincial branches with
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 59

9 cross-province regional branches. This reform further • A presidential system would probably be too
minimized the influence of the local governments on authoritarian to balance India’s diversity. Moreover, since
monetary policy, and closed inflationary loopholes. the supply of public goods needs to expand, a parliamentary
These changes were part of the new feature of the 1990s system is better. But shifting to a system with some features
worldwide—the adoption of fiscal and monetary rules to of the proportional voting, with some lower limits on the
improve incentives. The rules have worked best when they minimum size of parties, would raise the supply of public
have been used to facilitate macro-policy coordination and goods, reduce transfers, decrease swing votes, vote blocks,
stimulus. The appropriate structure varies with levels of fractionalization, and instability in politics.
development. A democracy cannot afford Chinese-style • Hung assemblies that give importance to identity-
stop-go cycles, or make the quick reversals. Therefore, in based splinter groups can also be reduced if a variant of
the former, self-enforcing general rules, which allow sufficient the French system is followed whereby, in the absence of
discretion for flexibility, should work better. a clear majority, there is a re-poll among the two parties
with the highest totals. This would lower instability in
governments, frequent elections, and their ill effects. Some
POLICY AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE change is required because of extreme fragmentation in
Indian politics. If state and central elections are coupled
We have demonstrated the importance of macroeconomic
once more, governments will not have to continually
shocks and the disincentives that can be built in by
implement populist schemes to appease voters (Jha, 2002).
inadequate responses to them. Therefore discretion needs
Unfortunately, the recently concluded Venkataswami
to be constrained by rules that would ensure adequate Commission on constitutional review has not suggested
responses to future shocks, without long-term damages. any serious reform.
Even in a complex system it is possible to identify marginal • The anti-defection law has effectively stopped single
feasible changes that can trigger others. defections, but since it does not rule out splits or group
• A Fiscal Responsibility Act would restrain fiscal defections, we have the spectacle of groups of MLAs
populism. It should have escape clauses to allow counter- being hidden away to keep them from temptation in
cyclical stimulation of the economy, and protect investment toppling episodes as was observed in Maharashtra in
in human and physical infrastructure. Monetary policy 2002. Splits were allowed because it was thought that they
then can be supportive and stimulate growth. Such a set might be based on principle rather than on the lure of
of policies is self-enforcing, given democracy and existing office or lucre. But that does not seem to be the case,
economic structure. Monetary policy can be bound less leading to suggestions that the anti-defection law be
strictly than fiscal policy because democratic pressures extended to splinter groups (Parikh 2002). This would
work to force it to keep inflation low46. Higher growth make coalition governments less hostage to vested
will facilitate the removal of political hurdles, and changing interests, while democratic freedoms of choice could still
incentives in administration. be exercised before elections.

Electoral Reform Political Changes

Deep structural changes would also minimize perverse Some political changes are feasible even without changes
responses to shocks, and have better incentive features. in the electoral structure.
Electoral reform may be possible in the longer-term. Even • There are signs that the political system is moving
a few of the structural reforms suggested below have the towards single party-led broad coalitions, one towards the
potential to reduce populist pressures on Indian politicians. right and the other towards the left of the political spectrum.
The long history of backwardness, in some sections of This could lower electoral competition, but this would
society, makes measures to empower these sections require the large parties to become more inclusive and
necessary. Bhargava points out that many such measures sensitive to regional aspirations. If two big parties, one on
are provided in the Constitution itself (Frankel, 2000). The the moderate right and the other on the moderate left,
reforms suggested below would actually increase the accommodate local satraps, and each sits regularly in
representation of minorities, but reduce their power over opposition, there could be more genuine consultation
political outcomes, so that more long-term measures to across parties and more stability (Chidambaram, 2002).
benefit them could be taken. • Even without such an outcome, it may be possible
46 This policy coordination is discussed in detail in Goyal to achieve consensus across parties on major economic
(2002). Morris (2001, 2002) also argues for interest rate targeting policies. All parties more or less agree to the necessity of
and a high growth target. reform today; bankrupt governments have no other choice.
60 India Infrastructure Report 2003

The broad coalition governments of the 1990s have school meals or dry rations to girl students, illustrate how
hammered out large areas of consensus (see Box 2.2.1). policy can improve returns to choices that raise human
If an all-party consensus can be reached banning populist capital. The latter carries externalities for society that
policies, such as free electricity, no government would fear benefit all. Another example is if mandated contributions
an electoral reversal from implementing the policy, and it to a worker’s welfare fund across industries47 accompany
would become politically feasible. It is the fear of the other laws that make it easier to fire workers. This illustrates
party using populism to gain electoral mileage that is another general way of solving the collective action problem:
preventing deeper reform today. Such self-binding would gainers should partially compensate short-term losers. If
improve governance and basics. Voters have begun not to such laws increase employment both industry and workers
reward governments that give populist sops but do not would gain in the longer-term. Democracy is one of the
deliver the basics. They have voted out incumbents on non- best ways to integrate heterogeneous groups. Moreover, its
performance. Both rich and poor are converging on balance and variety allow it to survive shocks better. As
governance. As controls dissolve, the ability of the politicians India’s polity and economy matures, it is showing resilience
to extract rent from the rich is falling, and the poor are in the face of shocks that would have precipitated a crisis
now in a position where they see the decay in vital economic earlier48. Some parts benefit from adverse shocks and can
services that affect them in the long-term. Political parties have positive feedback for others.
have realized this, and therefore may be willing to agree • It is said that the Indian democracy has too many
to a consensus that would allow them to deliver on checks that paralyse decision-making. But because of the
governance. Then short-term transfers would fall and allow past emphasis on monitoring and the use of law to enforce
a rise in public goods provision. development, these checks and balances apply more on
citizens. If some of these are designed for politicians and
Using Democracy bureaucrats to create conflict of interest among them, it
would restrain the legislature and the executive from using
Democracy is not just about voting. There are other ways
power to benefit themselves, and would align officials
in which democratic pressures can enforce governance.
interests with the common good. Separation of power
• The media and the people, bolstered by special concentrates information rents in a single office. If the
institutions, can function as watchdogs in areas where other office is not a residual claimant on rent, its interests
politicians use power for personal gains or do not deliver would be aligned with voters, and it would share information,
(Paul and Gopakumar, 2002) New communication resulting in more transparent policy. If one office has the
technologies and norms favouring transparency make this power of initiative and a veto but not an amendment right
easier. India has a long tradition of open discussion and (and therefore is not a residual claimant), and the other
respect for different views. But the peoples’ right to knowledge has allocation rights, the two have a strong conflict of
needs to be better implemented. It is time the Official interest and no incentive to collude, which helps the voter
Secrets Act, inherited from British times, was modified. control their rents. If combined with other design features
Citizens’ groups and non-government organizations (NGOs) to speed decision- making, this need not increase delays.
have become active in enforcing civic rights and improving
urban infrastructure (Raval, 2002). If they publicize the Administrative Changes
failures of politicians and indirect costs of populist policies,
Administrative changes, both at the design and procedural
it will increase the accountability of politicians and motivate
level, can improve efficiency. Changed circumstances
them in the right directions. For example, in cross-
sometimes make it possible to change set ways of doing
subsidization, the government keeps ‘poor’ class consumer
prices low, raises ‘luxury’ goods prices, but increases things.
intermediate prices (Morris, 2002a). This eventually raises • Independent professionals should be appointed as
a wider range of prices, besides bringing about severe regulators, not retired bureaucrats. The present generalist
distortions. Such effects should be made transparent. bureaucracy could be modified, giving it a core with more
• More feedback is a strength of democracy, and
today’s technologies allow faster feedback, so that the speed 47 Kavita Khanna, as a representative of the confederation of
of decision-making can be raised. Inequality and low Indian Industry (CII), made the suggestion during an episode on
growth heighten conflicts that make a democracy slow labour laws in the programme, The Big Fight, Star News.
48 Bimal Jalan, Governor of the Reserve Bank of India (RBI),
moving. Therefore conflict-resolution strategies that focus
made the point that although shocks had regularly led to crises in
on the common good, and not on specific groups will help. the past, India faced a number of adverse shocks in the late 1990s
Mechanisms that resolve conflicts in ways that increase the without a crisis. Speech at the release function for the India
surplus or growth are required. For example, giving free Development Report, May 2002.
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 61

Box 2.2.1
Is Consensus Possible on Policy?

The United Front and the National Democratic Alliance (NDA) were both broad coalition governments, one to the left and
the other to the right of the Indian political spectrum. The first came up with the Common Minimum Programme (United
Front, 1996), and the second with a Joint Manifesto. Studying the two statements gives an indication of the extent to which
a consensus across parties is possible in economic policies. Each involves a consensus among the parties comprising the coalition;
the two together give an idea of feasible consensus across the Indian right and the left.
Being political statements, both emphasize food security, health, water, housing, education, and governance. The United Front
puts more emphasis on price stabilization, provision of basic needs, and technology, while the NDA places emphazis on agriculture
and infrastructure for employment, swadeshi with openness, privatization, commercial principles in general but protecting farmer
subsidies.
Thus both are concerned with higher growth, and there is a general agreement on the reforms and other measures required
to achieve it. The left is more concerned with affecting transfers to the poor and preserving public property. But it is willing
to accept that more of these transfers should come in the form of building human capabilities, and to make allowances for the
bankruptcy of government.
There are sensitive electoral issues like subsidies and user charges that neither document touches upon. These are precisely
the areas in which all parties would gain, if there were an all-party agreement that none could gain political mileage by reneging.
They would be able to deliver better governance, and compete on that basis.
The NDA document for the first time talks of the necessity of consensus across the political spectrum. ‘Governance must
become unifying, not divisive, in its practice. It is this mindless manner of the domination of the majority that has led to bitterness,
hostility, and confrontation—and has even made the opposition and ruling parties like permanent adversaries. This destructive
trend of politics of negativism and political untouchability which has distorted our body politic in the last few decades calls for
an immediate corrective. We will, therefore, strive to develop national consensus on all major issues confronting the nation by
involving the opposition parties and all section of society in dialogue. We will also try for a consensual mode of governance as
far as practicable.’ Words need not imply actions but they are a first step.
There are other initiatives to achieve this. The CII has set up a public policy council to facilitate policy dialogue and consensus
across political parties. Sanjiv Goenka is the current head (Soota, 2002). Chidambaram (2002) is also of the view that such
consensus is feasible. Prime Minister Vajpayee went to brief Sonia Gandhi, the leader of the Opposition, after the Jammu terrorist
attack in May 2002, in order to involve all political parties in India’s response, and in his Independence Day speech again
emphasized the necessity to build consensus on economic policies.

independence from politicians (limiting their rights to the illegal cut in loans sanctioned, that is common at
transfer officers) plus a contract system where an incoming present.
government appoints its own officers, but based on strict • Well-sequenced, contextual policies can be designed
professional criteria and skills. like those in China where construction firms were asked
• Like China India should give civil servants some to provide housing for workers, thus making direct
benefits from growth, so that they are motivated to encourage beneficiaries contribute to infrastructure development, or
it instead of using their discretion to create delays to make regional bank branches were closed down to contain the
money. The rewards need not be only monetary but could inflation of credit. New transfer schemes must be asked
be in terms of professional development or reputation, to demonstrate the source of future funding. The systematic
thus creating a strong work ethic. Since bureaucrats have removal of discretionary controls will reduce sources of
multiple tasks monetary incentives alone are insufficient corruption and delay. As complexity and asymmetry of
and can take attention away from essential tasks whose information increases, outcome oriented, market-based
output cannot be measured. Even so, better management delegation works better.
systems can ensure accountability and transparency, with • India has a three-tier budgeting process—at the
emphasis on delivery (Morris, 2002b). Better pay and central, state and local levels. ULBs49 give an example of
equipment must accompany incentive payments linked to problems at lower levels. Services are generally poor. ULBs
performance. Monitoring on outcomes should be designed start with a balanced budget, since the law requires it, but
to encourage risk taking in bureaucracy. For example,
49 The workshop on the IIR 2003, gave the author an
bankers should be judged on their entire loan portfolio,
not on individual loans, and the emphasis should be on understanding of ULB financing. In particular she would like to
thank K.P. Krishnan and Ravikant Joshi for detailed discussions on
the quality of the loans, not quantity. They should be given this topic and refers the reader to their chapters in this Report for
an official incentive payment on loans repaid, instead of more details.
62 India Infrastructure Report 2003

end the year with deficits. These are adjusted in creative states can continue by having higher block grants for the
ways, contributing to the general opacity of the budget. latter; but an incentive component linked to fiscal prudence
Data are either not current or are difficult to interpret. and efficiency may motivate them to take on more
Schemes are delayed for lack of funds, while sometimes responsibility. This, together with reforms such as allowing
money is available but authorities do not know of it. The them to levy service tax, making user charges more feasible,
required reforms are known but are not implemented. tighter budget constraints and better accounting,
Opacity continues in spite of many training sessions, competition among states, openness to the world, may help
capacity building, and attempts at standardization. Perhaps spread better practices among the states. Tax mobilization
it facilitates the siphoning off of money, so political bosses in the states has been better than that at the centre in 2002,
do not want transparency. Politicians must be motivated because of the competition and the incentive features that
to actively push for these changes or at least stop resisting the Eleventh Finance Commission built in.
them. This can happen if deeper changes in the political • Public investment in human and physical infrastructure
structure make the provision of public goods to a broad continues to be essential given the severe shortages in this
set of the population rather than to narrowly targeted area and the large externalities it carries. The public sector
transfers in the politicians’ interest. also has the advantage of being able to borrow more cheaply
• Alternatively, conflicts of interest could be used or to finance such activities. But some commercial principles
created to decrease political power in administration, or are required in allocation and pricing. Otherwise the
voter pressure could be used to monitor and ensure asymmetric information and rent-seeking activities that
performance. It may be possible to introduce management have been examined so far imply that politicians may follow
accounting if the utility of the capacity created is demonstrated self-serving policies such as building huge highways to their
at the local level. Transparency and standardization improve small villages. Innovative public–private joint initiatives
implementation. Information technology gives fast useful and independent agencies for finance, allocation, and
feedback, makes decentralization and faster decision-making regulation, need to be established in this area. But attention
possible. Coordination of central transfers and their quick should be paid to the dynamic sequencing of reform. For
disbursement according to simple non-discretionary rules example, more competition should accompany privatization,
will also be motivating. On the expenditure side, performance to prevent the creation of private monopolies (Hoff and
clauses must emphasize maintenance. Programme budgeting, Stiglitz, 2001), and interest groups that impede further
with a clear idea of cost-effective expenditures targeted to reform. Political forces are actually working to make such
programmes demarcated on functional grounds, such as changes more likely. More and more bankrupt public bodies
administrative, or social headings, rather than the present are welcoming private participation as a means of protecting
classification into development and non-development them from voter and worker pressure. It is a way of tying
expenditure, would be much more effective. Simple forward- their hands; they can say it is the private partner who is
looking rules can prevent bottlenecks, even in complex insisting on payment, performance, and raising prices.
situations (Basu, 1995). Market procedures can short-cut delays due to adversarial
• Increasing the rewards to self-policing works better negotiations. For example, auctions can be used as a way
than a strict law, which is kept in letter but violated in to determine values available to settle claims50. Although
spirit. This often happens with the PILs where citizens’ these changes would reduce their discretion, it is possible
groups bring court injunctions against the executive to politicians will be forced to adopt them.
enforce service delivery. Direct voter pressure on politicians
and changes in the incentives of politicians and bureaucrats
will deliver more genuine changes. Tough penalties often CONCLUSION
require tougher evidence, so that conviction becomes
In India politicians get too much rent and too many resources
more difficult. Rewards motivate relatively more, compared
are dissipated in short-term transfers to build vote banks.
to punishment. Under asymmetric information a carrot
In this Section 2.2 some systematic changes have been
relaxes both the participation and incentive compatibility
discussed that can release resources for activities that generate
constraint, since it improves returns to the better alternative.
externalities and stimulate growth. Politics has two basic
A stick just relaxes the incentive compatibility constraint
functions. It can solve the collective action problem and
since it reduces returns to the worse alternative. And
coordinate for a better outcome, but it can also use conflict
growth makes more carrots available.
among groups to maintain power. India has seen too much
• Awards to states have been based on filling trend
of the latter function. Conflicts make a democracy slow
non-plan revenue gaps. This rewards fiscally profligate
states, but has not succeeded in closing gaps in per capita 50 Raghuram Rajan pointed out, in a lecture at IGIDR, that this
incomes (Rao, 2002). Transfers from the rich to the poor is used in Sweden to determine the value of bankrupt firms.
Expenditure Accountability and the Society 63

moving under inequality and low growth, therefore changes of governments is forcing reforms, reforms are changing
that improve outcomes for all, and not only for specific incentive structures, and higher growth rates are reducing
groups, are required. Higher growth reduces group conflict. the conflicts and short-term perspectives. Indians had
The general principle is that policies should improve returns become used to direct subsidies and indirect costs, or
to choices that raise human capital. The latter benefits more short-term benefits and disguised long-term costs. But they
than just the recipient and improves future prospects. are beginning to see the long-term consequences of short-
When the underlying political structure has major effects, term populism. Political parties have understood this
the question arises, will politicians allow the changes perception; for example, the Congress’ slogan, has changed
required? If they are aware of the consequences they will from ‘garibi hatao’ to governance.
only allow changes that are in their own interest. If policy Changes will occur, but with conscious design they can
is endogenous so are institutions. Ideas do have an effect be surer and faster. It is often said that a few good-
but take time to acquire a critical mass. Deep political principled people can make a difference; but good systems
changes may be some time in coming, but the bankruptcy can induce better behaviour from most people.

REFERENCES

Anant, T.C.A. and J. Singh (2002), ‘The Framework of Drazen, A. (2000), Political Economy in Macroeconomics, New
Regulation’, in S. Morris, (ed.), India Infrastructure Report: Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Governance Issues for Commercialization, New Delhi: Elster, Jon (1995), ‘The Impact of Constitutions on Economic
3iNetwork and Oxford University Press. Performance’, Proceedings of the World Bank Annual
Armijo, L.E. (2002), ‘Democratic Inclusion and Macroeconomic Conference on Development Economics, 1994, Washington
Moderation: Counterintuitive Observations on India and D.C.: World Bank.
Brazil’, paper prepared for the workshop ‘Creating and Engerman, Stanley L. and Robert E. Gallman (eds) (1986),
Revitalizing Democratic Institutions: Context and Challenge Long-Term Factors in American Economic Growth’, Studies in
in Latin America and South Asia,’ Institute of International Income and Wealth Series, Vol. 51, Chicago and London,
Relations, University of British Columbia. University of Chicago Press.
Austen-Smith, D. and J. Banks (1988), ‘Elections, Coalitions, Evans, Peter (1984), Dependent Development: The Triple Alliance
and Legislative Outcomes,’ American Political Science Review, of MNC, State and Local Capital in Brazil, Princeton, New
82, 405–22. Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Bardhan, P. (2002), ‘The Political Economy of Reform in India’, Frank, Andre Gunder (1967), Capitalism and Underdevelopment
in R. Mohan (ed.), Facets of the Indian Economy, New in Latin America. Historical Studies of Chile and Brazil,
Delhi: Oxford University Press. New York and London: Monthly Review Press.
Baron, D. (1991), ‘Majoritarian Incentives, Pork Barrel Programs, Frankel, F.R. (2000), ‘Introduction/Contextual Democracy:
and Procedural Control,’ American Journal of Political Science, intersections of society, culture and politics in India’, in
pp. 35, 57–90. F.R.Frankel, Z. Hasan, R. Bhargava, and B. Arora
Basu, A. (1995), Public Expenditure Decision Making: the Indian (eds),Transforming India: social and political dynamics of
experience, New Delhi: Sage. democracy, New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Basu, K. (2000), Prelude to Political Economy, New York: Oxford Franzese, R.J. (2002), Macroeconomic Policies of Developed
University Press. Democracies, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Chidambaram, P. (2002), ‘On Economic Reforms and Political Fry, Maxwell J. (1980) ‘Saving, Investment, Growth, and the
Cost of Financial Repression’, World Development Report,
Compulsions’, at the Maharashtra Economic Development
8(4), 317–27.
Council meet on 10 April, Taj Rooftop,
GOI (1979–80), ‘Performance Budget of Ministry of Energy
Das Gupta, Arindam (1999), ‘Expenditure Management and
(Dept. of Power)’, Government of India.
Budgeting in India’, background paper for chapter 4,
GOI (1987–88a), ‘Performance Budget of Ministry of Energy
‘Governance, the Business of Government’, in World Bank,
(Dept. of Power)’, Government of India.
India: Reducing Poverty and Accelerating Development, New
GOI (1987–88b), ‘Performance Budget of Ministry of Water
Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2000.
Resources’, Government of India.
Das, K. (1999a), ‘Politics of Industrial Location: Indian Federalism Government of India (1975), ‘The Call of Change’, in The Years
and Development Decisions’, Economic and Political Weekly, of Endeavour: the Selected Speeches of Indira Gandhi, August
Vol.32, No.51, pp. 3268–74. 1969–August 1972, New Delhi: Director, Publication
Das, K. (1999b)‚ ‘Underdevelopment by Design? National Planning division, Ministry of Information and Broadcasting.
and Vital Infrastructure in Orissa’, Working Paper No. 107, Goyal, A. (2002), ‘Coordinating Monetary and Fiscal Policies:
Gujarat Institute of Development Research, Ahmedabad. a role for rules?’, chapter 11, in Kirit S. Parikh and R.
Dobb, Maurice (1948), Soviet Economic Development Since 1917, Radhakrishna (eds.), India Development Report, 2002, New
New York: International Publishers. Delhi: IGIDR and Oxford University Press.
64 India Infrastructure Report 2003

——— (2001),’Governing a Democracy: Constrained Discretion Morris, Sebastian (1994), ‘Some Issues in the Debate in Policy’,
for Development’, presented at the GDN 2001 Conference, Economic and Political Weekly, July 2, 1994, pp.1669–73.
Rio de Janeiro, December 10–13, 2001. Available at http:/ Morris, Sebastian (1997), ‘Why not Push for a 9 Per Cent
/ctool.gdnet.org/conf_docs/CP_(Ashima_Goyal).pdf. Growth Rate?’, Economic and Political Weekly, May 17–24,
——— (1999), ‘The Political Economy of the Revenue Deficit’, pp. 1153–65.
in Kirit S. Parikh (ed.), India Development Report, 1999, Morris, Sebastian; Rakesh Basant, Keshab Das, K. Ramachandran
New Delhi: IGIDR and Oxford University Press. and Abraham Koshy, (2001), The Growth and Transformation
Goyal, A. and A.K. Jha (2002), ‘Dictatorship, Democracy and of Small Firms in India, New Delhi, Oxford University Press.
Decentralisation: Macro Policy in China and India’, presented Nurkse, R. (1953), Problems of Capital Formation in
at seminar on Foreign Investment and Economic Underdeveloped Economie’, Oxford: Blackwell; New York:
Development in India and China’, IIM Calcutta. Oxford University Press.
Grilli, V., D. Masciandaro, and G. Tabellini (1991), ‘Political and Pai, S. (2002), ‘Electoral Identity Politics in Uttar Pradesh:
Monetary Institutions and Public Financial Policies in the Hung Assembly Again’, Economic and Political Weekly, 6
Industrial Countries’, Economic Policy, 13 October 341–92. April, pp. 1334–41.
Haldea, G. 2002, ‘Rescue Reforms: Players Cannot Also Be Pandian, M.S.S. (2002), ‘One Step Outside Modernity: caste,
Umpires’, Times of India, 24 July. identity politics and public sphere’, Economic and Political
Hardin, R. (1999), Liberalism, Constitutionalism, and Democracy,
Weekly, 4 May Vol. 37, No. 18, pp. 1735–41.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Parikh, K.P. (2002), ‘Overview: Ten Years of Reforms, What
——— (1982), Collective Action, Baltimore: Resources for the
Next?’, in K.S. Parikh and R. Radhakrishna (eds.) India
Future and John Hopkins Press.
Development Report, 2002, New Delhi: IGIDR and Oxford
Hoff, K., and J. E. Stiglitz (2001), ‘Modern Economic Theory
and Development’, in G. M. Meier and J. E. Stiglitz (eds.), University Press.
Frontiers of Development Economics, New York: Oxford Patel, I.G. (2002), Glimpses of Indian Economic Policy: An Insider’s
University Press and World Bank. View, New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
IIR (2002), India Infrastructure Report: Governance Issues for Paul, S. and K. Gopakumar (2002), ‘How Public Feedback Aids
Commercialization, (eds.) Morris, S. and Rajiv Shekhar, Public Accountability’, in S., Morris (ed.), India Infrastructure
3iNetwork, New Delhi, Oxford University Press. Report: Governance Issues for Commercialization, New Delhi:
Jha, P.S. (2002), ‘Centre cannot hold’, Hindustan Times, 29 3iNetwork and Oxford University Press.
March, Delhi. Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (2002), ‘Political Economics and
Joshi and Little (1996), India’s Economic Reforms: 1991–2000’, Public Finance’, in A.J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein (eds),
Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Handbook of Public Economics, Vol. 3, chapter 24, North-
Krugman, Paul (1996a), Pop Internationalism, Cambridge and Holland: Elsevier Science.
London, MIT Press. ——— (2000), Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy,
Krugman, Paul (1996b), ‘The Myth of the East Asian Miracle’, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
in Krugman, Paul (1996) ——— (1999), ‘Political Economics and Macroeconomic Policy’,
Laffont, J.J. (1999), Incentives and Political Economy, 1997 in J.B. Taylor and M. Woodford (eds), Handbook of
Clarendon Lectures, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, chapter 22, North-Holland: Elsevier
Lewis, Arthur W. (1954), ‘Economic Development with Science.
Unlimited Supplies of Labour’, Manchester School, Vol.22, Rao, M.G., (2002), ‘State Finances in India: Issues and Challenges’,
May, pp. 139–91. Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 37, No. 31, 3 August.
Mankiw, George (2000),’The Inexorable and Mysterious Trade Raval, S. (2002), ‘Urban Heroes’, India Today, 13 May.
off Between Inflation and Unemployment’, Series: Harvard RBI( 2001), ‘Report of the Standing Committee on International
Institute of Economic Research Working Papers, Harvard Financial Standards and Codes’, Chairman : Y.V. Reddy,
Institute of Economic Research, No.1905. (http://post. Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai.
economics.harvard.edu/hier/2000papers/HIER1905.pdf) Rosenstein-Rodan, P.N. (1943), ‘Problems of Industrialisation
Morris, S. (2002a), ‘Overview’, in 3iNetwork, India Infrastructure of Eastern and South Eastern Europe’, Economic Journal,
Report: Governance Issues for Commercialization, New Delhi: Vol. 53, June–Sept., pp. 202–11.
3iNetwork and Oxford University Press. Soota, A. (2002), ‘CII’s New Mindset’, The Times of India, 6 May.
———2002b, ‘The Challenge to Governance in India’, in Stein, Jerome L. (1991), International Financial Markets:
3iNetwork, India Infrastructure Report: Governance Issues for Integration, Efficiency, and Expectations, Cambridge: Blackwell.
Commercialization, New Delhi: 3iNetwork and Oxford Tavares, J. and R. Wacziarg (2001), ‘How Democracy Affects
University Press. Growth’, European Economic Review, 45(8), pp. 1341–78.
——— (2001), ‘Overview’, in 3iNetwork, India Infrastructure Trubek, D.M. (1972), ‘Towards a Social Theory of Law: An
Report: Issues in Regulation and Market Structure, New Delhi:
Essay on the Study of Law and Development’, The Yale
3iNetwork and Oxford University Press.
Law Journal, Vol. 82, No. 1, pp. 1–50.
Morris, Sebastian (1987), ‘The Process of Investment Decisions:
United Front (1996), Common Minimum Programme, text reported
A Study of Delays and Cost Overruns in Public Sector
in the Economic Times, Mumbai edition, 6 June, pp. 22.
Projects’, mimeo, Institute of Public Enterprise, Hyderabad.
Wallis, John and Douglass North (1986), ‘Measuring the
Morris, Sebastian (1990), ‘Cost and Time Overruns in Public
Sector Projects’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.25, No.47, Transaction Sector in the American Economy’, in Engerman,
pp.154–68. L. Stanley and Robert E. Gallman (eds) (1986).

You might also like